sme development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

78
SMALL AND MEDIUM SIZED ENTERPRISES (SME) Development, Constraints, Credit Risk and Islamic Banking Solutions PhD Candidate Mace Abdullah MBA, CPA (Inactive) LL.M. (Taxation), Juris Doctorate

Upload: mace-abdullah

Post on 23-Jan-2018

267 views

Category:

Economy & Finance


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Page 1

SMALL AND MEDIUM SIZED ENTERPRISES (SME)

Development, Constraints, Credit Risk and Islamic Banking Solutions

PhD Candidate

Mace Abdullah

MBA, CPA (Inactive)

LL.M. (Taxation), Juris Doctorate

Page 2: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

SMALL AND MEDIUM SIZED ENTERPRISES (SME)

Development, Constraints, Credit Risk and Islamic Banking Solutions

Abstract

This analytic paper examines the status of small and medium sized enterprises (SME)

worldwide, provides theoretical information and explores issues regarding their development,

constraints and credit risk. SME have been heralded worldwide as being the economic “engine”

of economic development. Certainly, from an Islamic finance perspective, the development of

SME represents a propitious opportunity, a vital step towards an epistemological response to

criticism of Islamic finance and should play an indispensible role in forging a more robust

Islamic capital market. Yet, SME face persistent identifiable obstacles to growth and

development. This paper focuses on SME development, particularly as it relates to the so-called

“credit gap” and the concomitant credit risk. The SME “credit gap” is pervasive worldwide;

particularly so in emerging economies. Accordingly, this paper analyzes: the determinants and

drivers of SME development; constraints on SME development; the SME “credit gap” and

concomitant credit risk; and the role Islamic banking can play in meeting the challenge of SME

development.

Key words: Small and Medium Size Enterprises (SME); SME development constraints; SME

credit gap; SME credit risk; Islamic banking

Introduction

SME foster economic growth and are central to productivity, job creation, entrepreneurship and

innovation. They invariably contribute to the gross domestic product (GDP) of economies

worldwide. Yet, providing them with the capital to finance their growth, development and

sustainability has proved challenging to banks and other financial institutions internationally.

Financial intermediation is the “backbone” of capital allocation within an economy. Efficient

financial intermediation requires credit risk assessment in order to avoid adverse selection and

moral hazards. Therefore, it is important to identify the overall financial characteristics of SME

in order to improve their credit risk assessment.

Determinants of SME Development

Size, growth and age are significant determinants of SME development. In order to produce

development, growth must be sustainable. Sustainability is the ability to support a defined level

of activity, e.g. sales, job creation or capital asset base, over time. Economic and financial

determinants are factors, often inter-related, that limit or define economic or financial activity.

They are therefore, often measurable; thus, quantifiable. SME determinants and classifications

vary by country. Many economies use the term “micro, small and medium sized enterprises.”

This term is sometimes used to estimate the size and growth of “informal” vis-à-vis “formal”

Page 3: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

SME. Some economies require ownership by a citizen as a necessary criterion for SME

classification. Others, e.g. China, Japan, Korea, Malaysia and Mexico, vary their SME measures

by real economic sector (OECD, 2015). Efforts have been made to harmonize SME definitions,

but homogeneity has proven elusive (OECD, Promoting Entrepreneurship and Innovative SMEs

in a Global Economy: Towards a More Responsible and Inclusive Globalisation, 2004). Even

with its challenges, the definition and metrics of SME are necessary for some very important

reasons, e.g.: preparation of statistics and the monitoring of their development over time;

benchmarking SME development as between different economies, regions and within sectors of

an economy; providing thresholds for tax and fiscal policy or other regulations; and determining

eligibility for particular forms of private and public support (Gibb, 2004).

Size. SME “size” is measured as a determinant by one or more of the following: number of

employees (emphasizing job creation); total assets (emphasizing their economic “balance

sheet”); sales or turnover (emphasizing production); and/or loan volume (emphasizing their

credit access). However, some of these measures are intermediate steps to determining other

more meaningful measures. Total assets, for example, are based on historical costs and do not

necessarily reflect ongoing fair values of assets, but may still measure periodic capital

investment. Jobs created, similarly may not measure productivity; which may require period-to-

period ratios of real changes in GDP, as well as job creation. Moreover, shear employment

growth does not necessarily account for the quality of the workforce or human capital

development and assessment of an economy’s knowledge base.

Virtually all economies use SME size determinants; some placing emphasis on more than one of

them. The most common determinants used by regulators are the number of employees, sales and

loan size. Of these, the number of employees is used most often. A study of 68 countries that

provided information on the SME measures used by their regulators, found that 50 use the

number of employees criterion, and 29 of these 50 also used one or more of the other criteria.

Out of the sample, 41 regulators used the sales value criteria and 15 used loan value criteria to

measure SME development (Ardic & Mylenko, 2011).

Lack of SME standardization, growth measurement criteria and inter-country PPP, can make

a robust analysis of SME size arduous. As noted above, sundry growth rates may focus on

employment, sales, value added, productivity, loan value or a combination of these.

Measurement criteria may have differing economic effect on different industries, firms and

economies (Kolar, 2014). New measures and data sets have been developed as research in

SME intensifies. See (Ayyagari, 2007), (OECD Statistics Directorate, 2009) and (Ardic &

Mylenko, 2011). Some analysts use gross value added (GVA) as a measurement

(Airaksinen, 2016). Still others, while not necessarily using loan size as a metric, monitor it

regularly. Malaysia’s regulator is such an example. Examples of basic SME development

determinants used by selected regulators are listed in Tables 1 (World Bank), 2 (European

Commission) and 3 (Malaysia).

Page 4: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Table 1-World Bank SME Measures in USD ($)

Category Employees Total Assets Annual Sales Medium >50

≤ 300

>$3 million to

≤ $15 million

>$3million to

≤ $15 million

Small 10 to

≤ 50

$100,000 to

≤ $3 million

$100,000 to

≤ $3 million

Micro <10 ≤ $100,000 ≤ $100,000

Source: (Group, 2008)

Size, as a determinant, is important because it’s indicative of the stage of development of

SME. Given the heterogeneity of SME, size is an important determinant for policymakers that

want to target SME for stimulus, capital allocation and tax revenue building capacity (see infra).

Table 2- European SME Measures in Euros (€)

Category Employees Total Assets Annual Sales Medium < 250 ≤ €43 million ≤ €50 million

Small 10 < 50 < €10 million < €10 million

Micro < 10 < €2 million < €2 million

Source: (OECD, 2015)

Malaysia revised its measurement of SME in 2014. Such measurement changes can distort

growth data, as may the effects of inflation, PPP adjustments and the nuances of industry

differences on data. Malaysia’s new SME measurements require higher sales turnover and

segregate the “Manufacturing” sector determinants.

Table 3-Malaysian SME Measures in Malaysian Ringgit (MYR)

Category Micro Small Medium

Manufacturing Sales turnover of <MYR

300,000;

or < 5 employees

Sales turnover MYR 300,000

to < MYR 15 million;

or 5 to < 75 employees

Sales turnover MYR 15 million

to ≤ MYR 50 million;

or >75 to 200 employees

Other Sectors Sales turnover of <MYR

300,000;

or >0 to <5 employees

Sales turnover MYR 300,000

to < MYR 3 million;

or 5 to < 30 employees

Sales turnover >MYR 3 million

to MYR ≤ 20 million;

or >30 to 75 employees

Source: (SME Corp Malaysia, 2015)

Growth. SME growth is measured by increases in employment and contributions to production

and GDP. Growth is measured on a period-to-period basis in nominal or real terms; the latter

accounting for the effects of inflation and purchasing power parity (PPP) in some instances.

Economic growth occurs as a result of: discovery, exploitation or better utilization of resources;

increased workforce critical mass and productivity; innovation and technology improvements;

and economic specialization in goods and services. The ground swell for each of these is SME

development.

Fast growing firms are of particular interest in financial intermediation, and are notably more

likely to be younger, as larger firms comprise less than 10% of fast growing SME (Kolar, 2014).

Fast growing SME have been classified as either high-growth or hyper-growth (so-called

“gazelles”). High-growth in SME can be sporadic, spurious and of limited duration. Hyper-

Page 5: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

growth SME, by contrast, experience an extraordinary growth in sales over a relatively short

timeframe, accompanied by the accumulation of employees and assets. Hyper-growth firms

exhibit absolute growth rather than relative growth, as between short-term periods and in the

midst of inflation and PPP. Thus, they have been defined as a firm that grows from small to large

over a short timeframe (e.g. 5 years), exhibiting high real growth in each period therein. Hyper-

growth firms are also typically younger, but are distinguishable because they tend to be more

involved in merger and acquisition (M&A) and listing activities as their rapid accumulation of

workforce and assets makes them attractive to equity investors. However, along the way to M&A

and initial public offerings (IPO), they often raise higher levels of debt; relying relatively more

upon investments in fixed assets (Minola, Cassia, & Paleari, 2015).

It is estimated that 600 million new jobs will be needed over the next 15 years to absorb the

growing global work force. It is estimated that SME will create roughly 4 out of 5 of those new

jobs (World Bank, 2015). In high-income countries, SME contribute, on average, 50 percent of

GDP. In many economies, the majority of job creation occurs in the SME sector; up to 60

percent in the manufacturing sector (Ayyagari, 2007); (Burgstaller, 2015). In the European

Union (EU), approximately 99 per cent of all economic activity can be traced back to SME.

There, SME account for two-thirds of all jobs in the private sector (Gama, 2012). In OECD

countries, SME with less than 250 employees, employ two-thirds of the formal work force

(Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, & Peria, Bank Financing for SMEs Around the World: Drivers,

Obstacles, Business Models, and Lending Practices, 2008).

SME development is closely correlated with GDP growth; notably a robust, positive correlation

between the size of the SME sector and economic growth (after controlling for other growth

determinants) has been observed (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, & Levine, SMEs, Growth, and Poverty:

Cross-Country Evidence, 2005). In 2011, there were a total of 645,136 SME operating in

Malaysia; representing 97.3% of total business establishments (Department of Statistics,

Malaysia, 2011). Table 4 shows the Malaysian SME sectors’ contribution to overall GDP.

Table 4-Malaysian SME Contribution to GDP by Real Subsector (Percentage of GDP)

Sector 2010 2011 2012 2013e 2014

p

Agriculture 4.3 4.3 4.1 4.0 4.5

Mining/Quarrying 0.05 0.05 .1 .1 .1

Construction 0.9 0.9 1.0 1.1 2.0

Manufacturing 7.2 7.2 7.4 7.5 7.8

Services 19.6 19.9 20.0 20.5 21.1

Import Duties 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.4

SME GDP to

Total GDP

32.2

32.8

33.0

33.5

35.9

Source: (SME Corp, Malaysia, 2015); e Estimate/p Preliminary

Table 4 also shows which Malaysian real economic sector is fastest growing. It further shows

the SME contribution to the overall GDP by real economic sector. Notably, the “Services” sector

in the Malaysian economy looms large as a percentage of GDP. However, its contribution to

Page 6: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

GDP grew by 2.9% between 2013-14. “Construction,” on the other hand, registered the fastest

growth in contribution to GDP at 81.8%; while the “Agriculture” contribution grew at 12.5%

during the same period. The “Mining/Quarrying” sector was stagnant, while the

“Manufacturing” contribution grew at 4%. It is noteworthy that Malaysia’s “ease of doing

business” index for dealing with construction permits is one of the highest in the world (World

Bank Group, 2016). Overall, SME contribution to GDP grew at 7.2% from 2013-14. These

metrics demonstrate that growth can be “tricky” as noted by the work of (Kolar, 2014) supra.

The vagaries of growth can further be seen from the compounded annual growth rate of the same

SME real sectors to GDP over the 5 year period. Faster growing SME in one time period may

slow or become faster during another time period. Table 5 illustrates the volatile nature of

growth in fast growing SME by comparing the 2010-14 compounded growth per sector versus

the more recent 2013-14 growth. Table 5-Comparison of 1 Year and 5 Year Growth of SME in Malaysia as % Contribution

Sector 2013-14 % Change*

2010-14 % Change Difference

Agriculture 12.5 6.7 5.8

Mining/Quarrying 0.0 39.3 -39.3

Construction 81.8 28.9 52.9

Manufacturing 4.0 7.5 -3.5

Services 2.9 7.3 -4.4 SME GDP to Total

GDP**

7.2

8.3

-1.1 Source: Compiled from Table 5 and Table 2.1 of (National SME Development Council, 2015)

* Compounded Annual Growth Rate (CAGR); ** Includes import duties

Finally, understanding financial constraints on a sector like “Services” is important. If financial

constraints are more severe in a services sector; particularly where technology-intensive, both

innovation and technological diffusion (infra) will be significantly affected, to wit economic

growth will likely be adversely affected as well (Kukuk & Stadler, 2001); (Silva & Carreira,

2016).

Age. Age as a determinant of SME development is important for several reasons. One is that it

provides an operating history of financial data that ameliorates the perceived credit risk in SME

financing. Further, during a SME’s business life cycle, it develops financing relationships with

banks and other financial intermediaries. Age can be measured in several ways. Research has

focused on survival rates and business life cycles as two primary determinants of SME age.

Survival Rates. Survival rates are an important determinant of default intensity. Though national

survival rates may be too “broad a brush” with which to paint a credit risk profile, they do give a

macroeconomic level indication of SME development. Specifically, size and age, as key

variables, have been observed to significantly affect their credit risk (Cassar, 2004), as both

variables have been negatively correlated to SME failure. SME failures are difficult to measure

because SME often “fail” because of closures or non-financial reasons. Further, there are no

Page 7: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

formal reporting requirements for “informal” SME, making reliable information difficult, if not

impossible, to obtain.

Default prediction models have been introduced into the study of SME failures using financial

statement data (Altman E. , 1968) and later further developed (Altman & Sabato, Modeling

Credit Risk for SMEs: Evidence from the US Market, 2005). Three variables have been

developed to predict SME failures using this approach: (1) loss of profitability and competitive

strength due to a fall in demand or a drop in internal efficiency; (2) deterioration of solvency and

liquidity conditions due to an increase in debt weight by external events (e.g. raising of costs of

debt) or by internal causes such as reduced cash flow or an unbalanced financial structure; and

(3) deterioration in the quality of the credit relationship, especially in relation to short term lines

of credit (Dainelli & Fabrizio, 2013). Using data from Italian firms, and applying these default

prediction determinants, credit historical data was found to be the predominant variable in the

credit rating of SME; followed by the quality of the credit relationship (measured by short-term

lines of credit usage) and loss of profitability (measured by deterioration of operating margins

(Id). These finding confirm theories noted herein below, i.e. the importance of information

asymmetry and the importance of banking relationship persistence.

Research has grouped SME failures into five categories: (1) ceasing to exist (discontinuance for

any reason); (2) closing, or a change in ownership; (3) filing for bankruptcy; (4) closing to limit

losses; and (5) failing to reach financial goals. (Altman, Sabato, & Wilson, 2010). Moreover,

(Headd, 2003) found that only a third of new firms closed because owners considered them

“unsuccessful.” Many insolvency regimes, and indeed banks, often do not distinguish between

the causes. Thus, a SME that has financial difficulties in its early or intermediate stages of

development, but fails for non-default reasons, may be “lumped in” with SME that fail due to

poor management or higher credit risk. This creates a so-called “fresh start” dilemma for SME

owners (Bergthaler, Kang, Liu, & Monaghan, 2015).

Although (Watson & Everett, 1996) used the size of the shopping center firms were located in as

a proxy for firm size, their research found evidence in a study of Australian SME failures that “if

bankruptcy is used to define failure, there is a positive association between size of shopping

center within which a business is located and propensity to fail. However, if failure is defined as

either discontinuance of ownership or discontinuance of business there is a negative relationship

between size of shopping center within which a business is located and propensity to fail.

Between these extreme definitions, if failure is defined as failed to ‘make a go of it’ or disposed

of to prevent further losses, no significant relationship is found between failure rates and size of

shopping center within which a business is located.”

Younger firms have a higher failure rate than older firms. Over half new firms fail by their 5th

year, regardless of their size. Although, this phenomenon may be influenced by the

Page 8: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

macroeconomic environment in which the firm operates, it also buttresses other studies that show

a high rate of volatility among younger firms (Kolar, 2014). The longer a young firm survives,

the better its chances of survival. Firms with more employees have a higher survival rate than

firms with fewer employees within the first two years (Cook, Campbell, & Kelly, 2012). There is

evidence that industrial classification is factor in failure rates since SME within the same

industrial class have similar capital structures (Romano, Tanewski, & Smyrnios, 2001). A 2012

OECD compilation of survival rate data among new firms among selected OECD members is

illustrated the phenomenon in Table 6, as failure rates uniformly drop with years 1 to 5.

Table 6-Failure Rates of New Businesses in the First 5 Years

Source: (OECD, 2015); OECD calculations based on OECD Structural and Demographic Business Statistics

Although survival rates within an economy and among sectors is an important determinant of

SME credit risk with application through their stages of development, loan impairment is also a

harbinger of default. Impairment accounting has attracted more attention since the 2008 financial

crisis. A loan is considered impaired when the ongoing monitoring of bank loan portfolios

indicates that an individual borrower or group of borrowers probably will not fulfill their

contractual credit commitments. Impairment may result from asset or income deterioration at the

firm level, or sector or macroeconomic shocks. When this occurs, banks must make accounting

allowances for that probability. Figure 1 shows SME loan impairment has steadily improved in

the aftermath of the 2008 global financial crisis.

Figure 1-Malaysian Bank SME Impaired Loans to Total SME Loan (%)

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Source: (OECD, 2016)

Page 9: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

A loan is impaired if there is objective evidence that impairment exists as a result of a loss event.

The identification of a single, discrete is not required. Rather, it may be the combined effect of

several events that cause the impairment. In either case, losses “expected” to result from future

events, no matter how probable, are not recognized for accounting standards purposes. A loss

event occurs when substantial objective evidence indicates any of the following circumstances:

(1) significant financial difficulty of the issuer or obligor exists; (2) the bank, for economic or

legal reasons relating to the borrower’s financial difficulty, grants the borrower a concession that

the bank would not otherwise consider; (3) it becomes probable that the borrower will file

bankruptcy or seek other financial reorganization; (4) an active market disappears for loan or

financial asset because of financial shocks; or (5) observable data indicates there is a measurable

decrease in the estimated future cash flows from a borrower or group of borrowers since the loan

initiation (International Accounting Standards Board, 2011).

Business Life Cycles. Both size and age significantly affect the capital structure of SME

(Gregory, Rutherford, Oswald, & Gardiner, 2005). Financing methods in SME vary according to

their age and size. Financing more or less evolves through their business life cycles from initial

internal sources, such as owner–manager’s savings and retained profits (Wu, 2008); to informal

outside sources, e.g. financial assistance from family and friends (Abouzeedan, 2003); to more

formal outside sources, e.g. payables credit, bank financing, venture capital and angel financiers

(He, 2007). Inevitably, formal external capital sourcing through financial intermediaries such as

banks, “shadow banks,” leasing and factoring institutions and securities markets represent a SME

“tipping point” of development and growth (Chittenden, 1996). Even though early stage SME

represent a significant credit risk class for banks, as SME grow and look more to external

financing, credit risk becomes more of a concern as well.

(Berger & & Udell, 1998) posit that the financial needs and options of SME change throughout

the various phases of their business life cycles. Different stages in their business cycles may

require different financing strategies, products and intermediation. In their start-up phase, SME

show a unique characteristic of informational opacity (Berger & & Udell, 1998), little or no track

record or history (Cassar, 2004) and a high risk of failure (Huyghebaert, 2007). Thus, SME have

been found in this stage to depend heavily on insider funding sources. Moreover, at this stage,

SME are frequently viewed by banks and financial institutions as having a higher credit risk:

thus, requiring a higher commensurate expected rate of return.

During subsequent growth stages, SME mature, establish a track record and the ability to provide

collateral. This improves the creditworthiness, investor perception of their credit risk and

external financing sources are more willing to extend credit to SME. The capital constraints

endemic to SME during their start-up phases typically decreases over time as they are no longer

dependent so heavily on internal capital. As SME advance through their business cycle, they

become more transparent and access to collateralized debt financing and equity sources becomes

Page 10: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

more available (Berger & & Udell, 1998). Again, monitoring, registration and regulation of SME

throughout their stages of growth and development ameliorate credit risk that may otherwise

persist due to a prolonged “informal” status.

It is noteworthy that SME benefit less from economies of scale and have limited access to a wide

resource base (Burgstaller, 2015); (Lavia Lopez, 2014). Their unusually low equity ratio makes

them more vulnerable to external events compared to larger companies (Altman E. S., 2010),

who have both a wider resource base and larger retained capital. Moreover, a SME’s capital

structure in the early stages might tend to be debt based external financing because of the

advantages leverage in debt financing has on returns, as well as its tax advantages (Modigliano &

Miller, 1958). Thus, this proclivity towards debt financing in the intermediate stages of SME

development makes the credit risk process vis-à-vis SME all the more important. Yet,

unavailable market valuation information (because few are listed, makes SME valuation and

riskiness even more difficult to ascertain).

The business life cycle progression of capital preferences among SME sounds all too familiar to

the “pecking order” theory. The pecking order theory describes the preferences of financial

managers in rising new capital and may just as well apply to owner-managers in the SME

context. The main difference between large firms and smaller SME, when considering the

“pecking order” hypothesis, is the distance between owners and managers in larger firms. In

smaller SME, the owner and the manager may be the same person. Because of this nexus of

roles, the incentives affecting the owner-manager may be riskier than in larger firms. In short, the

bank account of the owner-manager may be at the same bank as the firm’s. In other words,

income and wealth come from the same source. This dilemma is discussed below as a potential

moral hazard after credit is authorized.

Notwithstanding the risk associated with the SME owner-manager nexus, in the “pecking order”

theory, managers first choose to use internal financing or retained earnings, if available. It

follows that if the firm does not possess enough internal capital to fund its growth projects, the

second option will be external financing. External financing is either debt or equity, and the

theory posits that there is a preference towards debt. Debt financing is deemed less risky because

informational costs associated with releasing firm information, e.g. possible trade secrets that

have thus far given the SME competitive advantage. The words of the theory’s founding

proponents illuminate this point. “The firm cannot convey that information by saying: ‘We have

great prospects, but we can’t tell you the details.’” They go on to postulate through equilibrium

analysis that firms may pass on good equity opportunities as a result of this scenario (Myers &

Majluf, 1984). It should be noted that the applicability of the “pecking order” theory to SME has

drawn some dissent. That dissent is based on the “contentment theory” which posits that SME

owner-managers are less concerned with growth per se than they are for financial security (Vos

Page 11: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

& Roulston, 2008). It can be surmised that “informal” SME care very little about growth and

often secret fairly large amounts of cash savings off the banking grid.

As SME age and grow, their banking relationships help improve their viability. SME often

enlarge the circle of banks from which they obtain credit through their business life cycles. SME

that deal with multiple banks and financial institutions are roughly twice as large as those that

finance through only one bank or financial institution, notwithstanding any adverse signaling

effect lender changes may pose. Studies show that contrary to the commonly held belief that

banks are not interested in financing SME, banks actually do consider the SME segment

strategically important. Moreover, research points to functional “distance” as a determinant of

access to credit. Proximity between the lender and borrower eases the costs of collection and

“soft” information (Petersen & Rajan, 1994).

A longer the SME-banking relationship in time promotes access to credit overall (Berger &

Udell, 2006). Nevertheless, the credit may gap persist. (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, & Levine, SMEs,

Growth, and Poverty: Cross-Country Evidence, 2005); (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, & Peria, Bank

Financing for SMEs Around the World: Drivers, Obstacles, Business Models, and Lending

Practices, 2008); and (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, & Martinez Peria, Bank Financing for SMEs:

Evidence Across Countries and Bank Ownership Types, 2010) provide a series of studies

attempting to understand SME financing. Based on surveys, they provide evidence of how banks

seek out and serve SME through a number of “lending technologies and organizational setups.”

They found few differences in the extent to which SME are reached by banks, e.g. whether the

bank’s ownership structure is public, private or foreign-owned. They did find significant

differences in the SME lending practices between banks in developed and developing

economies. Thus, they concluded that the “enabling environment” is the most important

determinant of SME financing.

Finally, (De la Torre, Martinez Peria, & Schmukler, 2010) studied bank lending to SME,

focusing on business models and risk management. They surveyed 48 bank and leasing

companies in 12 countries and found that banks are indeed interested in lending to SME and do

so through separate organizational units, offering a wide range of products and applying different

credit risk technologies, e.g. credit scoring or risk-rating approaches. They further concluded that

both large and smaller banks have similar interests in SME. A survey study of 139 banks in 16

countries involved in SME financing in the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) found that

the SME sector there remains largely underserved by private banks. There, direct government

intervention through public banks, credit or loan guarantee schemes and other forms of

subsidized and government intervention based financing did help ameliorate the “credit gap”

dilemma. They attribute the phenomenon in the MENA market to weak financial infrastructures

(Rocha, Farazi, Khouri, & Pierce, 2011).

Page 12: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Drivers of SME Development

Any economic or financial variable that materially affects a financial or economic decision or

condition is a “driver.” Drivers often have no quantifiable measurement. Every decision or

condition will have its own unique set of drivers. The unique set of drivers may contain

resources, processes or conditions that affect a change in an economic phenomenon. SME have

been observed to have economic and financial drivers that materially affect their development.

Hence, aside from the quantitative determinants associated with SME development, the

qualitative drivers that were identified by (Beck et al, 2004), have been shown to be significant

factors in overcoming SME developmental constraints, as well as the “credit gap.” They include:

ease of entry; ease of doing business; financial and legal environments (of the economy hosting

the SME); innovation and technology; management capabilities and training; access to markets;

and government intervention programs.

Ease of Entry. Ease of entry for SME has been measured by the number of firms less than 2

years old as a ratio to all firms in an economy. The ability to form businesses within an economy

and the bureaucratic paperwork that goes with formation is commonly associated with the

“business environment” of the particular economy. However, there is a cost-benefit trade-off

because making registration too easy may attract business charlatans that form companies with

the intention of “fleecing” lenders and investors; while rigid registration may inhibit entry

(Klapper, Laeven, & and Rajan, 2004). This is the moral hazard and adverse selection associated

with weak regulation.

However, overly rigid bureaucratic regulations have been hypothesized as being in the “private

interest” as opposed to the “public interest.” This theory posits that the “protected” private

interests of a few well-entrenched firms are served by rigid entry requirements, while public

interests are impeded. Evidence supporting this theory suggests that countries with more rigid

entry regulation, also have higher incidents of fraud and corruption (often due to political

connections), as well as larger “informal” SME economies (Dijankov, La Porta, Lopen-de-

Silanes, & and Schleifer, 2002). Closely associated with this phenomenon is the finding that cost

of entry, as measured as a percentage of per capita GDP is higher in those economies deemed to

favor “private interests” (Klapper, Laeven, & and Rajan, 2004). Thus, it is surmised that more

rigid entry regulation is less effective in societies with “better developed information systems,

better product inspections and quality control, better contract and law enforcement, and

consequently, an entrepreneurial population less subject to misbehavior” (Id). Additionally,

foreign direct investment (FDI) may be adversely affected by a financial system that

unreasonably impedes the “ease of entry.”

Ease of Doing Business. “Ease of doing business” is tantamount to “ease of entry” in financial

parlance. The World Bank formulates its “ease of doing business” composite indices, by

Page 13: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

variables including, but not limited to: time and cost of starting a business; time and cost of

registering property; strength of investor and minority investor protection; the tax system; the

time and cost to export and import; and the time and cost of enforcing contract claims. Other

variables include: the ease of getting construction permits; access to electricity; insolvency

resolution; labor market regulation and access to credit. Creditor rights vis-à-vis private and

public access to credit are indexed in the access to credit measure (World Bank Group, 2016).

In the area of access to credit, the World Bank’s Ease of Doing Business Index relies heavily on

research done by (Djankov, McLiesh, & and Shleifer, 2007), testing existing theories, which set

forth two broad “power theories” of what drivers influence how much private credit a financial

institution extends to firms. The first view posits that the power of creditors within a country

influences access to credit. The ease at which lenders can enforce repayment, attach collateral, or

seize control of a debtor firm, all strongly influence the willingness of creditors to extend credit.

The second view posits that “information” is king. The more lenders know about borrowers, their

credit history, operations or references, the less they are concerned about adverse selection; and

therefore, extend credit more readily. Further, impediments to “doing business” inhibit the

registration of SME, that may otherwise remain unregistered in the so-called “informal” SME

economies. If, for example, a streamlined registration is made a prerequisite to accessible

financing, increased registration should undoubtedly occur.

Table 7-World Bank Ease of Doing Business Indices

Country/Classification 2014 2015 The World 95 95

Australia 12 13

Canada 13 14

Denmark 3 3

Finland 10 10

Germany 15 15

Hong Kong 5 5

Indonesia 120 109

Korea 4 4

Malaysia 17 18

New Zealand 2 2

Norway 8 9

Pakistan 136 138

Saudi Arabia 84 82

Singapore 1 1

Sweden 9 8

Turkey 51 55

United Arab Emirates 32 31

United Kingdom 6 6

United States 7 7

The Arab World 122 122

MENA 110 111

High Income-OECD 25 25

Source: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/IC.BUS.EASE.XQ

Table 7 shows the World Bank’s “ease of doing business” indices for 2014 and 2015 of selected

countries. While the perfect score is 1, Malaysia, for example, has a relatively favorable ease of

Page 14: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

doing business index according to the World Bank. Malaysia’s 2015 rating of 18 is comparable

to other successful economies, e.g. Australia (13), Canada (14) and Germany (15). It is also

better than the OECD-High Income rating (25).

Financial Environment. Overall, broad institutional development is vital to alleviating SME

financing constraints. This premise suggests that for SME, the supply-leading hypothesis (infra)

is more important. The supply-leading financial intermediation hypothesis posits that financial

development drives economic development. The findings of (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, Laeven, &

Maksimovic, 2004) suggest “that it is hard to distinguish the effects of financial, legal and

economic development from the underlying institutional development.” Accordingly, firms in

financially and economically developed countries face fewer financing obstacles. This may also

have nexus to the degree of market efficiency in those markets, as information asymmetry is less

an obstacle as financial development increases (see the discussion of financial intermediation and

innovation infra).

SME development is a function of the “host” country’s financial system. Financial systems

improve information dissemination, reduce transaction and monitoring costs, facilitate the

transfer and sharing of risks, increase investment and lending activity, and generally result in

more efficient capital allocation. These observed functions of financial development help

determine whether a financial system is efficient. If efficient a financial system produces

“financial deepening;” thus its services become more accessible at all levels of society, including

SME, which are underserved in developing countries (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, & Martinez Peria,

Bank Financing for SMEs: Evidence Across Countries and Bank Ownership Types, 2010).

Financial deepening can induce both “formal” and “informal” SME to incorporate so as to

benefit from the resulting opportunities to diversify risks and obtain limited liability. Moreover,

financial deepening helps foster more sophisticated, independent and “formal” SME; thus,

moving the larger emerging economies away from family-owned SME predominance. The end

result is a more inclusive financial system with better SME composition and competition. Banks

are a major source of external finance for all firms, regardless of size; and thus, key financial

intermediaries (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, & Honohan, Access to Financial Services: Measurement,

Impact and Policies, 2009). In Malaysia, for example, as of the end of 2011, 71% of its SME

were sole proprietorships, 18.4% were private limited companies, 8.5% were partnerships and

2.1% were classified as “other” (SME Corp, Malaysia, 2015).

Financial Intermediation. Efficient financial intermediation ameliorates financing constraints in

SME (Steven M. Fazzari, 1988). Financial intermediation occurs when financial firms, e.g.

banks, insurance companies, brokerages and other financial institutions, take on liabilities by

taking money and other assets from the “surplus units” of society and channeling the cash and

other sources of capital to “deficit units” (ostensibly firms), allowing the latter to finance the

production of goods and services. Financial intermediation processes differ in bank-based and

Page 15: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

market-based financial systems. In bank-based financial systems, equity markets are not

significant competitors with banks. Banks take on added risk associated with debt and deal with

that added risk through “inter-temporal smoothing.” They increase their buffer of short-term

liquid assets when the economy is booming; and reduce this buffer when it is more constricted.

The capital adequacy requirements of banks are adjusted based on their liquidity positions. As a

result, households that hold most of their assets in bank assets are largely shielded from the

added risk and smooth their consumption streams.

In market-based financial systems, with developed or developing financial markets, the equity

market provides competition to banks which makes the inter-temporal smoothing increasingly

more difficult. Financial markets allow high returns in boom times, providing an incentive for

investors to move their savings from banks to financial markets. In order to remain competitive

in such circumstances, banks must cease inter-temporal smoothing (Allen & Santomero, 2001).

This phenomenon has also been referred to as countercyclical capital buffering (Bank of

International Settlements, 2016). The measure is significant since it has been shown that banks

that retain liquidity levels in excess of regulatory requirements are more reluctant to finance

SME (Sacerdoti, 2005).

In either case, financial intermediaries allocate capital to firms through “pricing mechanisms,”

which more or less put the rate of return afforded on the loans and investments in a state of

equilibrium with the credit risk appetites of lenders and investors. This “price discovery” or what

has been called risk adjusted pricing, results in intermediaries providing agency cost savings on

transactions, solving asymmetric information problems, diversifying risks, reducing adverse

selection and helping capital providers assess credit risk. Financial intermediaries are

distinguishable from nonfinancial firms in the real economic sector, inasmuch as the former’s

assets and liabilities are predominantly financial in nature (Bodie, 2011); to wit the term-

“financial” intermediation. (Schumpter, 1934) is credited with hypothesizing that financial

intermediation plays a central role in economic growth because intermediaries largely determine

which firms get “society’s savings.” Financial development is associated with economic growth

in three ways (Patrick, 1966).

The first is referred to as “demand-following,” in which firm production leads finance. This

hypothesis postulates a causal relationship from real economic growth to financial development.

Financial development, according to this hypothesis, is a mere response to real economic growth.

The faster the economic growth, the greater will be the demand by firms seeking capital. Which

sectors of the real economy garner the most capital, under this hypothesis will be those that are

fastest growing. This suggests that SME should garner a significant allocation of capital be it not

for offsetting credit risk factors. Capital allocation based on growth is regarded as efficient and is

thought to occur more or less in an automatic, relatively passive, manner. However, according to

Patrick, this passive, automatic allocation “mechanism” of price discovery can be inhibited in

Page 16: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

less liberalized economies or where rigid religious restrictions are placed on the financial market.

In the case of SME development, the impediment is more likely associated with credit risk

factors.

The second type of financial development is termed “supply-leading.” It posits that the supply of

financial intermediation capital occurs in advance of demand for it. It has two functions: (1)

transferring resources from the traditional low growth sectors to the modern high-growth sectors

of the economy; and (2) promoting, and stimulating an entrepreneurial response in these modern

sectors. Thus, growth in the supply of capital stimulates the demand for it and its services (e.g.

price discovery, information symmetry, etc.) of efficient capital allocation to firms in the

modern, growing economy (Id). This process can stimulate both growth and innovation,

particularly in SME.

Thirdly, Patrick proposed a “stage of development hypothesis,” wherein he posits that the two

competing financial development behaviors (demand-following and supply-leading) may

intersect at some juncture. For example, the growth and improvement in financial services opens

up new opportunities for banks and other financial institutions, and in so doing, pulls the real

sector towards sustained economic growth. As financial development and economic growth

strengthen, the supply-leading characteristics of financial development gradually shift the reins

of economic growth to demand-following dominance. Thus, it would seem important that

policymakers know, with some particularity, whether financial development is at the supply-

leading or demand-following stage. Interestingly enough, collateral research in the area of SME

growth and development parallels this stage of financial development hypothesis. The stage of

development business cycle studies (infra) indicate that SME sources of capital change from

internal to external as they grow and begin to “dominate” the financial intermediation process by

being able to demand or “choose” between multiple sources of capital.

Legal Environment. SME face greater financial, legal and corruption constraints compared to

large firms. The impact of these constraints on firm growth is inversely correlated to firm size.

SME benefit the most from improvements in financial development and reduction in corruption.

Thus, improvements in these areas are important in promoting the development of the SME.

Taking into account national differences between financial/legal development and corruption,

SME that operate in underdeveloped systems with higher levels of corruption are impacted most

by all constraints. Generally, legal constraints and corruption, particularly the amount of bribes

paid, the percentage of senior management’s time spent with regulators and corruption of bank

officials also constrain firm growth significantly. Corruption of bank officials affects firm

growth. This evidences the existence of “institutional failure” which supports Basel initiatives

discussed herein that seek a greater monitoring role of financial institutions in overcoming

market failures due to informational asymmetries. For example, empirical evidence indicates that

corruption was found to be highly inversely correlated to within a 1% significance level to the

Page 17: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

following growth determinants and drivers: 33%-Per Capita GDP; 18%-Firm Growth; 28%-

Financing Constraints; and 58% Legal Constraints (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, & Maksimovic,

Financial and Legal Constraints on Firm Growth: Does Size Matter?, 2005).

An economy’s legal system’s determinants are inversely correlated with SME growth (Id). It is

noteworthy that the legal environment encompasses not only the regulatory system of

government per se, but also the legal protections afforded to creditors and investors and property

rights (including intellectual property) through the laws of the jurisdiction. Legal environments

largely determine the size of credit markets and banking rights around the world. Banking rights,

e.g. loan enforcement rights, drive bank credit expansion. Collateral is a banking lever that

offsets asymmetric information. Collateral increases creditor willingness to lend to

informationally opaque firms, e.g. SME. The quality of the legal system influences the bank’s

willingness to accept collateral. Bank rights vis-à-vis collateral is dispositive. Legal

environments that provide strong creditor rights are considered “creditor friendly” if they do not

hinder creditor collection efforts on collateral. This shifts bank lending portfolios towards the

private sector capital formation. European banks, for example, allocate their loans between:

SME, large firms, mortgages, consumer lending and government. In legal systems with weaker

creditor protections, banks lend more heavily to larger firms and government; and less to SME.

The quality of the legal system expands banks’ choice as to various types of collateral. The

measurement of the quality of a legal system is largely qualitative (although one can imagine

setting some measures based upon the level and results of legal proceedings, judgments,

bankruptcies, etc). Hence, some studies survey banker perceptions of the legal environments.

Qualitatively, some drivers include: expectation of recover, time of recovery and the simplicity

or complexity of the legal process to recover (Haselmann & Wachtel, 2010).

A study of creditor protections in 88 countries worldwide, found other debt enforcement drivers

to include: time and cost of legal proceedings, and the likely disposition of the assets (i.e.

preservation of the borrower as a going concern versus piecemeal sale). These drivers are used to

describe debt enforcement efficiency. They have been used to forecast debt market development

in a cross-section of 88 countries, where they were correlated to per capita income, private credit

to GDP ratios and origin of legal environment (English, French, German and Nordic). Debt

enforcement procedures, e.g. the structure of appeals and the availability of floating finance

charges, also influence efficiency. Interestingly, per capita income influences a legal

environment. As it increases, the time to collect or enforce a creditor claim decreases, i.e. there’s

a negative correlation. In more advanced economies, debt enforcement was approximately a

year. In lower-income countries it could take up to 5 years. These timeframes were also

correlated with legal processes of foreclosure, reorganization and liquidation vis-à-vis borrower

continuation and piecemeal liquidation. Per capita income levels also influenced the cost of debt

enforcement and the ultimate recovery. In terms of legal origin, common law jurisdictions were

found to be most efficient, followed by German and French civil law jurisdictions. Finally, it was

Page 18: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

determined that from a macroeconomic perspective, the higher the private credit to GDP ratio,

the more developed the debt market appeared (Djankov, Hart, McLiesh, & Schliefer, 2008).

Innovation and Technology. Innovative products and services have been linked to both age

demographics and e-commerce. Malaysian SME and their owners were found to be younger than

the average Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) counterpart at 74.2% being under

40 vis-à-vis 53.2%. The ASEAN group shows a strong correlation between younger business

owners and those that expect to “grow, sell online, use social media for business purposes, and

innovate through the introduction of new products, processes or services” (CPA Australia Ltd.,

2016). Among Malaysian SME, 29% believe they will definitely introduce a new product,

service or process that is new to their market or the world within the next 12 months (Id).

Innovation. The OECD in the Oslo Manual (Organization for Economic Co-operaton and

Development, 2005), defines innovation as “the implementation of a new or significantly

improved product (good or service) or process, a new marketing method, or a new organizational

method in business practices, workplace organization or external relations.” Innovation can

maintain existing advantages, create new ones and make today’s products and services better

(Moreno & Flores, 2016). The OECD further estimates that innovation can contribute up to 50%

of the economic growth in an economy, depending on the host country, the level of economic

development and the phase of the economic cycle (OECD, 2015).

In today’s technology driven global village, technology diffusion is a key to innovative success;

particularly in the “services” sector. Traditionally, OECD countries have emphasized invention

as the key indicator of innovation. However, research in economics suggests that it is diffusion

that yields the greatest benefits through the speed at which firms commercialize innovative ideas,

products and services in a globally competitive marketplace. Technology diffusion can be

defined as the process by which innovations, e.g. new products, processes, methods and

techniques spread. The process of technological diffusion is considered essential to economic

growth and development. Technologic diffusion is time sensitive and is measured in two ways

from an economic viewpoint: the number of firms that use and own the technology (inter-firm

diffusion); and the intensity of use within particular firms (intra-firm diffusion). Technology

diffusion runs its course or path through: invention (generation of new ideas, e.g. patents,

trademarks, copyrights, trade secrets, etc. resulting from research); innovation (the development

of those new ideas through the testing, marketing, use and ownership of the resulting techniques,

products or services); and finally diffusion (the creation of an infrastructure that allows the new

technology to spread across the potential market of users and owners).

The benefits of technology diffusion, from an economic view, are balanced against the

associated costs. This process is called the welfare optimal diffusion path. On this path, the rate

of adoption (diffusion) matches the present value of the associated costs and benefits. Stated

Page 19: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

differently, it is the point in time where the marginal benefits of use/ownership (an economic

surrogate might be marginal revenue, though other measures might be seen over a range of time)

equal the marginal costs of producing the technology (Stoneman & Diederen, 1994). Technology

diffusion has given “birth” to a distinguishable subset in the area of financial technologies.

Financial Innovation. Financial innovation has been considered important to economic growth

for several centuries. Stated differently, research has concluded that institutions, laws,

regulations, and policies that impede financial innovation slow technological change as well as

economic growth (Laeven, Levine, & Michalopoulos, 2015). Financial innovation occurs when

banks and other financial institutions “invent” more effective processes, e.g. for “on-boarding”

(screening) and servicing new customers. Screening modalities have been found to be less

effective as entrepreneurial technologies advance. Therefore, financial institutions must continue

to enhance their screening and servicing modalities as technology innovation move their way up

the “Schumpterian quality ladder” in order to identify the best entrepreneurs. Hence, dynamic

financial innovation reduces the risk of adverse selection. This is, in part, the thrust of FinTech

infra.

Financial innovation is not without costs. The costs of financial innovation increase

proportionally with the “world technology frontier.” The world technology frontier (WTF) has

been defined as the level of technological innovation shared by the world’s most advanced

economies. Countries where it is more expensive to financially innovate, tend to experience

slower rates of technological growth. Counties with legal systems that rely less on case law, tend

to be more conducive to financial innovation (Id). Theory posits that economies can be “stuck”

in investment-based strategies vis-à-vis innovation-based strategies. Investment-based strategies

can be costly from a social perspective over time. They may further entrench the “rent shield

effect;” i.e. where “cash (rents) in the hands of insiders creates a shield that protects them from

more efficient newcomers.” This, in turn, may lead to an economy staying in the investment-

based strategy too long. Thus, delaying the switch to the innovation-based strategy and reducing

growth because the “economy is not making best use of innovation opportunities.” The delay, if

lengthy, can lead to a longer developmental distance to the WTF and can cause a “non-

convergence trap,” where convergence towards the WTF stops. Conversely, efficiently switching

to innovation-based strategies as quickly as possible can lead to what economist call

“leapfrogging” past economies that were once ahead of the “switching” economy (Acemoglu,

Zilibotti, & Aghion, 2006).

The ability of banks and financial institution to innovate their credit risk assessment of SME may

be exacerbated by the fact that SME have been found to react to shocks quicker than larger firms.

Thus, monitoring them as borrowers has increased importance. Since the 2008-9 financial crises,

SME have attracted attention from economists as a sort of economic harbinger (Ardic &

Mylenko, 2011). SME show a heightened sensitivity to economic shocks. This sensitivity has

Page 20: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

been attributed to SME ability to compete with larger enterprises by being more flexible and

faster in responding to customer needs and by adapting to change quickly because of their

relatively simple internal organizations (Lavia Lopez, 2014). There is empirical evidence that

supports the hypothesis that SME performance, in the form of entrepreneurial activity, especially

of an innovative nature, can be a leading indicator of the broader economic cycles; i.e. increasing

ahead of economic recovery and falling ahead of economic downturns (Thurik, 2014). Research

published by the OECD shows that entrepreneurial activity had already fallen by 2007, well

ahead of the economic downturn of 2008–9 (OECD Statistics Directorate, 2009).

Information technology (or IT) can reduce paperwork submission inefficiency and bureaucratic

“red tape” can be streamlined. Information technology may be used to improve SME access to

customer and potential customer databases, as well as market information, both domestically and

internationally. Thus, technology innovation plays a key role in SME development and growth

through information gathering and dissemination used to evaluate and monitor SME, particularly

“fast” growing SME and innovation focused firms. Financial and information technologies

reduce transaction costs and improve portfolio risk management. SME loans in Hong Kong, for

example, are not accepted on the basis of traditional information in financial statements, cash

flow projections and business plans alone. Credit risk assessment techniques that gather

information on customers, sales and payments in real time, enabling a more dynamic risk

management and loan servicing model for SME financing have proved successful in Hong Kong.

Loans are extended against the current actual cash flow and business performance and secured

by accounts receivables (OECD, 2004).

Other technological approaches to information gathering may be used to screen prospective SME

firms for their financing needs using the internet. An example of such an approach is Malaysia’s

SME Bank Group’s online screening (Small Medium Enterprise Development Bank Malaysia

Berhad, 2016). SME Bank is a specialized financial institution geared to be a “one-stop

financing and business development centre” for SME development. It exemplifies many of the

advancing approaches to SME development discussed herein, e.g. financial innovation. Further,

from a credit risk management approach, it is established best practices for financial institutions

to aggregate and monitor SME by industry, stage of growth, risk profile and a number of other

financial and business considerations (e.g. branches, departments, groups, etc.) for financial

intermediation, credit risk assessment and capital allocation purposes.

Financial Technology (FinTech). FinTech is a more recent financial innovation. It should help

banks and others meet their Basel III initiatives (infra) and reduce the information asymmetry

typical of SME. Real time risk analytics enable banks to track and monitor borrower risk and

market exposure. This is accomplished by the development of data platforms that collect trade

data needed to conduct real-time analytics and provide automated reporting. It emphasizes

“knowing your customer” (“KYC”) reporting. Such platforms facilitate bank internal risk

Page 21: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

management, stress tests, and mitigating of other risks, e.g. concentration risk. Malaysia’s Bank

Negara Malaysia (BNM) has introduced a “regulatory sandbox approach” that places banks,

FinTech firms and companies in a “live environment” to test the effectiveness of FinTech and

explore innovative business models (Bank Negara Malaysia, 2016). It effectively creates a

FinTech cluster, although the program is not necessarily focused on SME.

Application Interface Programs. As noted above, financial innovation demands that banking

services encompass customer “on-boarding,” KYC, payment, transaction history, and account

information. Current finTech initiatives seek to create a digital financial services exchange,

through application program interface platforms, generically referred to as API, that drive the

standardization and implementation of a common set of banking platforms. These platforms will

reduce both time-to-market and investment needed by banks over time. If established

successfully, this “open” exchange would also lead to the development of a range of innovative

customer centric solutions, e.g. universal digital wallets, self-service financial advice, and

efficient trade solutions. API fintech can also employ “machine learning technologies” to

identify aberrant transaction patterns or possible trouble signs that are “flagged” for further

review, including flexible, automated API regulatory rule-based engines.

Moreover, API exchanges will help establish digital marketplaces that include banks, insurance

companies, credit agencies, marketplace lenders (e.g. leasing companies and peer-to-peer

lenders) servicing the SME sector on a global, regional or national basis. Trade financiers can be

“interfaced” to list products and services available to the SME sector with online applications,

basic terms, and contracts. SME would be able to post trade finance needs and opportunities with

contact information and credit scoring. Ideally this platform would leverage on blockchain1

distributive technology to improve reliability and international visibility, while incorporating a

mobile solution to track, settle and monitor transaction flows.

Management Capabilities and Training. Certain competencies are requisite for effective

business management. Competencies such as finance, accounting, quantitative methods,

information technologies, marketing and human resource management are no less important to

SME than to larger, well staffed firms. In fact, those competencies are even more important for

SME, whose managers are often owners as well. Because of today’s fast changing technological

innovation and globalization, SME competencies must include both, i.e. innovative technologies

and international marketing procedures.

1 A “blockchain” is a distributed database that maintains a continuously, growing list of records called blocks. Each block is

secured from unauthorized access, revision and hacking. Each block is time-stamped and a link its predecessor block. Blockchain

serves as a digital ledger of transactions; thus, ameliorating information asymmetry. Compatible banks, lenders and firms are

able to connect to the network, send new transactions to it, verify transactions, and take part in the competition to create new

blocks. The competition to create new blocks is known as mining (Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., 2016).

Page 22: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

SME tend to be flat organizationally and owner-managers are “key” persons; often wearing

numerous “hats” within the SME. The lack of owner-manager skill sets (competencies)

commensurate with their “key” responsibilities has been found to be one of the main causes of

SME failures (Pansiri & Temtime, 2006). Managerial skills, experience and education have all

been found to influence the management capability of SME owner-managers. SME without the

requisite competencies, account for a significant portion of SME failures. SME managed by

owners who have these competencies, find it easier to access financing; particularly when

coupled with interpersonal skills used to acquire political and business connections (Fatoki &

Asah, 2011).

Although there are some polemics about what competency in business actually is, given the stark

reality of the “credit gap” that most SME face, it seems appropriate that some focus be given to

finance as a core competency. Working capital management is particularly challenging for SME

owner-managers, since in their early stages, current assets comprise a large part of their asset

base and current liabilities (often trade payables) represent a significant source of external

financing. Both account receivables and payables (working capital) are current balance sheet

items and components of the cash conversion cycle resulting from turnover or sales and payment

of operating expenses, respectively. Thus, from an operational and financial standpoint, they are

fundamentally important to early stage SME development (Tauringana & Afrifa, 2013). There is

a negative correlation between days in the cash conversion cycle and SME profitability.

Financially, cash from operations is a vital part of cash flow for SME since they lack substantial

capital assets, which might provide other sources of cash flow, e.g. capital gains and

depreciation.

Although there are distinctions between managerial and entrepreneurial competencies, terms e.g.

competency, competencies, skills, knowledge and expertise are often used interchangeably

without sufficient attention to their meanings. One working definition offered is that

“competencies mean the capability of (an) entrepreneur and of her/his collaborators in acquiring,

using and developing successfully resources for their business purpose, in the specific context in

which firm operates.” Whatever definition selected, the consensus is that competency must lead

to value creation and a firm strategy that leads to growth. Moreover, research suggests that the

entrepreneurial competencies required to start a business and the competencies to operate one

over a term of years may be different, or otherwise change through the stages of development in

order to sustain growth (Mitchelmore & Rowley, 2010). That said, there still does not exist a

common framework for both competencies. Given the correlation between SME failures and

management competencies, formal training has emerged as vital; and in the United Kingdom

believed to cut SME failures in half. Moreover, the ability to provide formal training is

negatively correlated to SME size (OECD, 2002); i.e. the smaller the SME, the less likely it will

engage in formal training of its key employees.

Page 23: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Since the number of employees is a determinant of SME development, human capital

development in SME is important, possibly indispensible. The OECD has found that among its

member countries, education and formal training is significantly inferior in SME than among

larger firms. Several larger economies have sought to improve the “quality” of owner/managers

in SME. Governments have sought to enhance their “quality” by subsidizing training and/or

advisory, consultancy and specialized training services (Id). Because technology and innovation

are both fluid, continuous upgrading of management capabilities and focused training are among

the best practices; and are not limited to owner-managers, but rather the quality of the SME

workforce as a whole is important.

As important as formal training to SME development is, the lack of business discipline and

integrity are equally important. It has been noted that the incentive for moral hazards in SME

exists; notably after financing is in place. Once funds are placed, SME owners may mismanage

financing, reducing efforts and returns (Jensen & Mecklin, 1976); (Scholtens, 1999). Risk-taking

entrepreneurs might undertake excessively risky projects since they will gain from any “upside”

of the project, while a banker would prefer less risk, even if less profitable. Larger firms have a

range of financing options and can undertake risky projects by sharing risk, such as equity

financing.

Banks try to minimize the moral hazards caused by agency problems when they evaluate the “C”

for character in the static acronymic model. Nevertheless, it is anecdotal that early stage small

businesses are analogous to young children. There exists an inherent conflict between the self-

interest of an owner of a small business and what is in the best interests of the SME. The sound

principles of business discipline that result from education and training often conflict with the

self control of owner/managers (or the lack thereof).

Access to Markets. The OECD has recommended two “marketing” opportunities that should be

enhanced for SME: international marketing and government intervention programs. That SME

contribute significantly to employment and a nation’s GDP is well-established. However, their

contribution to international trade is far less pronounced. In Malaysia, for example, the SME

share of exports is approximately 19%. Though some variation in SME definitions disrupts data

comparability, that ratio would nevertheless appear to leave room for significant improvement.

Figure 2 shows comparable data among countries worldwide.

Although the opportunity for SME to increase exports can be facilitated by easing their access to

foreign markets and the promotion of local SME products and services internationally, it has

associated costs that necessitate financing in many instances. These costs may include: difficulty

in entering new markets, e.g. price discovery, gathering trade contact information and

establishing marketing and distribution channels; difficulty in defending products, services and

interests in foreign markets; and the lack of necessary trade export skills in-house to deal with

Page 24: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

foreign trade standards, regulations and customs procedures (International Trade Centre; World

Trade Organization, 2014).

Figure 2-SME % Share of Selective County Exports

Source: (Yoshino & Wignaraja, 2015) from various statistical

agencies (ASEAN SME data, Business in Asia, DTI Philippines,

PRC Ministry of Industry and Information Technology, European

Commission fact sheet, Small Business and Entrepreneurship Council)

Handling the associated export trade costs may be challenging for many SME. There exists a

global trade finance gap of $1.4 trillion; $693 billion of which is in developing Asia, including

India and China (DiCaprio, Beck, & Daquis, 2015). Among firm types surveyed by the Asian

Development Bank (ADB), SME were consistently underserved.

Figure 3-SME Share of World Supply Chains

Source: (Yoshino & Wignaraja, 2015)

Moreover, the SME path to international marketing can be both direct and indirect. Indirect

participation in “supply chain trade” has been defined as trade in parts and components using the

Page 25: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

final trade approach (Athukorala & Nasir, 2012). This approach can be illustrated by the

following hypothetical example. A mobile phone sold by Samsung in the United States is made

in China. A Chinese SME participates in Samsung’s larger firm supply chain by manufacturing

or assembling parts used in the mobile phone. Figure 3 shows the impact this trade phenomenon

has for SME in selected countries.

SME face higher rejection rates than other firm types, globally, as well as in Asia. Banks

reported that 47% of all trade applications are submitted by SME; but rejected 52% of the time.

By contrast, approximately 79% and 87% of large and multinational applications are accepted,

respectively. Hence, there is a correlation between firm size, the need for export financing and

the credit rationing based on firm size. Figure 4 illustrates this disparity graphically.

Figure 4-Trade Applications Rejected by Business Type

Source: ADB. 2015 Trade Finance Gaps, Growth, and Jobs Survey

Government Intervention Programs. Government promotion of SME is a natural response to

their economic significance to the overall economy and a socially responsible policy of “income

inclusion.” Government “set aside” or procurement programs or “schemes” can facilitate an

increasing share of government contracts and/or resources being allocated to SME. A

comprehensive approach to government programs links both public and private institutions,

firms, channels, products and services. These programs may “map” technology “incubators,”

college and university training, consulting and technical expertise, government development

policies and related funding. The OECD has promoted “competitiveness clusters” as an approach

to SME development. Clusters are defined as “the combination, within a given geographic area,

of businesses, training centers and public and private research facilities working together in

partnership to generate synergies in connection with innovative joint projects having the requisite

critical mass for international visibility” (Potter & Miranda, 2009).

An example of government sponsored SME focused credit facilities is in the United States,

where a Small Business Lending Fund (SBLF) was enacted into law in 2010 as part of the US

Jobs Act with the aim of encouraging SME lending. The US Treasury provides capital to

Page 26: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

community banks through preferred shares incentivize them to lend to SMEs. These incentives

are provided by reducing the rate of the dividends on Treasury’s shares, with the reduction being

based on the amount of SME lending generated. For example, if a bank increases its small

business lending by 10 % or more above baseline (based on its 2007 SME lending) then

dividends will be reduced from the maximum rate of 5 % to 1 % (U.S. Department of the

Treasury, 2016). Thus, as SME lending is increased by the community bank, its dividend rate on

the preferred shares in it owned by the Treasury is reduced.

Figure 5 shows how Malaysia has structured its “financial landscape for SME.” Not shown on

the “landscape” is the National Innovation Agency Malaysia, which also promotes innovation

focusing on stimulating and developing an innovation ecosystem in Malaysia. Moreover,

Malaysia has a variety of BNM sponsored loan schemes for SME; 147 schemes are enumerated.

Some are specifically microfinance focused, others are geared towards rural and agricultural

development and assistance, while others are provide varied financing arrangements, e.g.

working capital loans, revolving credit and international trade based assistance (SME Corp

Malaysia, 2016). SME Corp uses a “one-stop” referral system that is linked to government

ministries across the board, as well as the SME Bank and other SME focused entities.

Figure 5-Malaysian Financial Landscape for SME

Souce: (SME Corp Malaysia, 2015); BNM is Bank Negara Malaysia (Malaysia National Bank)

State or governmental ownership of firms has shown increase in recent years; even among

developed economies. This trend has been referred to as “state intervention” and even “state

capitalism.” Accordingly, research literature has been developing that seeks to explain the impact

state ownership has on investment structures. See discussion by (Jaslowitzer, Megginson, &

Rapp, 2016). They define state ownership as “stockholdings by any type of government-owned

or controlled entity, including shareholdings of national government ministries and central

Page 27: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

banks; equity stakes held by state-owned financial and non-financial enterprises; stockholdings

of local and regional governments; and portfolio investment holdings by public pension funds

and sovereign wealth funds, which are frequently controlled by foreign governments.” They

further posit that evidence suggests that overinvestment by the state is systemically related to

“empire-building.”

Empire-building precipitates two agency problems. The first is that state ownership is associated

with weak monitoring of managers and is negatively correlated to corporate governance quality

because of less exposure to external disciplining forces, product market competition and

takeover pressures. Secondly, from a political perspective, state ownership may have multiple

socio-economic objectives that promote overinvestment, a willingness to “subsidize inefficiently

high output to maximize employment or achieve other socially desirable goals, e.g. locating

production capacities in economically underdeveloped but politically important regions,

providing cheap goods and services, and producing unnecessary products.” With that in mind,

their empirical testing suggests only marginal additional investment value results from state

ownership, which often is based on political connections, even ethnic favoritism (Id).

Constraints on SME Development

Notwithstanding the importance of SME to economies worldwide, there exist obstacles to their

growth and development. European research shows that insufficient market demand is

followed by access to financing as the primary obstacles to SME growth (European

Commission, 2009). The availability of finance has been determined to be a major factor in the

development, growth and success of SME (Ou, 2006); (Cook, 2001). A World Bank study

covering 98 countries identified 15 macro level obstacles to SME growth that included: access to

finance; access to land; business licensing and permits; corruption; courts; crime, theft and

disorder; customs and trade regulations; electricity; inadequately educated workforce; labor

regulations; political instability; practices of competitors in the informal sector; tax

administration; tax rates; and transportation.

The World Bank study (Figure 6) shows the top 6 obstacles to firm growth in developing

countries with access to finance being cited as the second most important obstacle overall; and

more among SME than larger firms. Moreover, it is also instructive to note, that tax

administration, tax rates and practices, customs and trade regulations, practices of competitors in

the informal economy and several ease of going business factors are all cited as affecting firm

growth in developing economies.

Although all constraints to SME development are important and worthy of analyses and

amelioration, three are especially so: access to finance, tax rates (and the related tax

administration) and practices of the informal sector.

Page 28: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Figure 6-Most Commonly Cited Obstacles to Firm Growth in Developing Countries

Source: Enterprise Surveys Dataset (Kushnir, Mirmulstein, & Ramalho, 2010)

Access to Financing. Access to finance is markedly a very significant “bottleneck” to SME

development, as it is essentially the “credit gap.” SME are less likely to obtain bank financing

than larger companies. The World Bank estimates that 50 percent of all “formal” SME don’t

have access to “formal” credit. It further estimates that there exists a “credit gap” among both

“formal” and “informal” SME worldwide of $2.1 to $2.6 trillion. For the “formal” SME sector,

the “credit gap” is estimated to be between $.9 to $1.1 trillion worldwide. Thus, more than half

of the “credit gap” in SME exists with respect to “informal” SME; who represent both an

“untapped” line of business for banks and other financial institutions, as well as an obstacle to

development of the formal SME sector. The effects of financing constraints on growth, as noted

between large and small firms, have been identified by empirical research as indicated below in

Figure 7.

Figure 7-Growth Reduction Due to Various Financing Constraints

Source: (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, & Maksimovic, Financial and Legal Constraints on Firm Growth: Does Size Matter?, 2005)

Figure 7 identifies important constraints on small business financing; not the least of which is

financing barriers discussed elsewhere in this paper. The “catch all” financing obstacle factor

includes such determinants descriptive of the various financial systems, e.g. access to: foreign

bank financing, export financing, lease financing, operations financing and non-bank equity.

Specific finance constraining variables as lack of money, special connections, interest rates,

Page 29: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

bureaucracy and collateral are all indicative of the presence of credit rationing. Credit rationing

in some economies results in external financing being more costly than internal financing due to

the premium (“high interest rates”) on external financing caused by asymmetric information and

macroeconomic factors. Figure 8 shows the interest rate “spread” between large firms and SME

in Malaysia.

Disentangling the determinants of credit rationing has proven difficult for economists. One study

in Japan did identify land collateral as an ameliorating determinant to credit rationing there

(Ogawa & Suzuki, 2000). Clearly, a SME’s asset base will mitigate credit constraints caused by

credit rationing (Atanasova & Wilson, 2004). Macroeconomic factors relating to bank market

power (increases credit availability) and bank competition (decreases in competition increase

credit rationing) have also been noted as credit rationing drivers (Carbo-Valverde, Rodriguez-

Fernandez, & Udell, 2009). In total, the reduction in small firm growth associated with credit

“gap” and credit risk related factors in Figure 7 is approximately 57%.

Figure 8-Malaysian SME Borrowing Rate Spread

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

Source: (OECD, 2016)

Credit rationing is a by-product of financial intermediation of credit instruments that exchange

money credit for promises to repay based on information relating to borrower future cash flows.

Where demand for credit is greater than the supply of money, and information is imperfect, as it

invariably is, the bank’s perception of which borrower promise is more trustworthy may cause

banks to ration credit money based on “special connections,” interest rates and/or collateral.

These factors, along with bank paperwork, combine to form a credit constraint for many SME.

The credit allocation under instances of inchoate or asymmetric information can lead to adverse

selection, forgoing of innovative profitable projects and moral hazards. Measuring credit

rationing can be exacerbated by the “inter-termporal smoothing” and “countercyclical capital

buffering” practices of individual banks, as well as the difficulty in forecasting macro-level

variable lags and multiplier effects (Jaffee & Stiglitz, 1990).

Page 30: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Notwithstanding the progress Malaysia has made, access to finance is still perceived as difficult

by many of its SME. Malaysian SME that sought finance in 2015, still perceived access to

finance as more difficult. Approximately 32% of Malaysian SME found access to finance easy or

very easy, as compared with an ASEAN average of approximately 48%. As theory and other

research suggests, relatively difficult financing conditions impact the demand for external

financing. In During 2015 in Malaysia, the percentage of SME demanding external finance fell

from approximately 74% to 58% (CPA Australia Ltd., 2016). Those results suggest that a “credit

gap” may be present in the Malaysian SME sector. Figure 9 seems to confirm the survey results.

However, Malaysia’s acceptance rate for SME loans is relatively high at 91.4%.

Figure 9-Malaysian SME Loans Requested & Approved (MYR million)

Source: (OECD, 2016)

The “Informal” SME Conundrum. Studies often focus on the “formal” SME sector. Yet, the

“informal” SME sector, though obscure, is equally important. An informal SME can be defined

as a SME that is not registered with any regulatory body within an economy. Registration may

take many forms, from obtaining licenses and permits, employment benefit registrations and

filing of requisite tax forms stating the existence of a company. The “formal” vis-à-vis

“informal” classification employed by the World Bank is premised on registration and regulation

data (World Bank Group, 2016). Many SME that might be regarded as “micro” enterprises, often

operate “off the grid” and are not registered with any governmental agency, may not file tax

information returns; and as a result linger in obscurity. Moreover, as noted in Figure 6, the

practices of the “informal” SME sector are viewed as an obstacle to firm growth in developing

countries by approximately a quarter of all formal SME surveyed. This may be due to the tax and

other registrations costs that “formal” SME include in their cost structure, while “informal” SME

escape those costs.

Empirical research buttresses the survey results. The quality of institutional environments in

exacerbating or in alleviating the impact the “informal” SME sector has on the “formal” sector

has been empirically observed. Weak institutional environments increase costs and decrease

benefits to “formal” SME. A large “informal” SME sector “influences perceptions about the

Page 31: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

substitutability between formal and informal goods,” as well as corruption (law evasion).

Moreover, “registered SME facing competition from informal firms are more likely to be credit-

constrained than other formal SME that are not confronted with such competition.” This result is

termed the ‘‘parasite” view, which posits that “informal” SME are capable of competing against

formal SME and hurting the latter’s profits. This economic phenomenon is generally found in

countries with weak rule of law and a higher degree of corruption and bureaucracy. For a

discussion of the concept of rule of law as it applies to development, see (Krever, 2011).

Registered micro and small firms are more likely to be hurt by these parasitic “informal” SME

than medium-sized firms because one of the benefits of medium-sized SME status is increased

access to credit; reflected in their progression through the SME business cycle. In short, it has

been recommended that “governments must enhance their role in increasing access to credit to

smaller firms and in providing incentives for informal firms to be integrated in the formal

economy” (Distinguin, Rugemintwari, & Tacneng, 2016).

The World Bank estimates that there are between 285-345 million “informal” SME in emerging

markets (when “micro” enterprises are included in the data). The failure to monitor, register and

regulate these SME can have a significant impact on pricing of credit risk, tax revenue building

capacity, amelioration of asymmetric information and the resulting adverse selection in the

financial intermediation and capital allocation processes by banks and other financial institutions.

Table 8 illustrates that the relative size of the “informal” SME sector. Information obtained

through registration and regulation might include such econometric data as demographic product

mapping, International Standard Industrial Codes (ISIC), OECD Structural Analysis (STAN)

Codes and important fiscal information. It is noteworthy that developed, high-income economies,

as a rule, have smaller “informal” SME sectors as percentages of GDP. The United States (8%),

Australia and the United Kingdom (11%), Canada (13%), Singapore and China (14%), all have

relatively small “informal” SME sectors. Moreover, the average worldwide percentage is

relatively small at 13%. This appears, at least at first glance, to draw correlation between

economic development and SME registration and regulation.

Table 8-Global and Selected Country SME Contributions (2010)

Country

Formal SME

% of Employees

Formal SME

% of GVA

Informal SME

% of GDP Total Worldwide 77 50 13

Malaysia 56 32 33

United Kingdom 59 51 11

Singapore 62 42 14

China 88 60 14

Pakistan 78 30 40

Hong Kong 50 21 19

Canada 70 45 13

Australia 64 50 11

Nigeria 75 10 63

UAE 63 45 29

United States 58 51 8

Russia 49 21 52

Source: (The Association of Chartered Certified Accountants, 2010)

Page 32: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

It is also noteworthy that, in general, as the size of the “informal” SME sector increases, the size

of the “formal” SME section decreases. The ability to register, monitor and collect data on SME

activity is pivotal to ameliorating the SME “credit gap,” higher credit risk and avoiding adverse

selection by banks and other financial institutions. Yet, even without the input of the “informal”

SME sector, an estimated 77% of all employees worldwide work in the “formal” SME sector.

Tax Building Capacity. A significant “informal” SME sector suggests the loss of tax building

capacity. Tax uilding capacity is measured by “taxable capacity,” “tax effort” and “tax

diversity.” Taxable capacity is the estimated tax-to-GDP ratio, regressed using estimated

coefficients taking into account the country specific characteristics. Tax effort is the ratio of

actual tax collected-to- GDP and taxable capacity (Le, Moreno-Dodson, & Bayraktar, 2012). Tax

effort is the tax authority’s enforcement efforts. Tax diversity of revenue sources and not just

reliance on value added taxes has been central to keeping tax revenues from collapsing in the

face of trade liberalization.

Tax incentives can improve the attractiveness of registration to “informal” SME and may

include: jobs, investment, enterprise zone, research & development and productivity credits

against potential tax liabilities; amnesty for past delinquent tax returns; and private retirement,

insurance and/or annuity benefit tax incentives. Tax policy may also be used to incentivize SME

technology development through research and development (R&D) tax credits, as well as

promoting “green” SME technologies through similar credits (or conversely de-incentivizing

undesirable SME activities). Figure 10 illustrates a systematic tax approach that addresses many

of the SME tax concerns, as well as the emerging global concern for inclusive growth vis-à-vis

growth for the sake of growth.

Malaysia recently revised its tax system from a graduated income tax to a consumption based

general sales tax (GST) system (National SME Development Council, 2015). Malaysia also

made paying taxes easier and less costly by implementing a mandatory electronic payment

system for companies depositing employee benefit systems contributions and by reducing the

property tax rate. Yet, it also increased the capital gains tax, which can be a disincentive to

investors on the capital market. Nonetheless, it also ranked first among 30 nations, including the

United Kingdom, United States and France, in advancing shareholder protections (World Bank

Group, 2016).

Interestingly, research in the area of taxation and government monetary policy reveals a

correlation between taxes paid in an economy’s fiat money and money demand; thus, promoting

the development of financial systems built around an economy’s fiat money is linked to taxation.

“Except for relatively highly taxed countries, where taxes may encourage tax avoidance and

holding bank deposits, the level of taxation is a positive factor boosting financial development.”

A study using Granger causality testing on 65 countries over the past half-century concluded that

Page 33: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

the relationship between taxation and money demand is generally supported in the 60 countries

making up the three higher income groups (Ott & Tatom, 2016).

Figure 10-Tax Policy Design to Achieve Inclusive Growth

Source: (Brys, Perret, Thomas, & O'Reilly, 2016)

SME Credit Risk

Access to credit and the resulting “credit gap” makes credit risk assessment of SME more

arduous than with larger firms. Their opacity exacerbates the difficulty. As with all risk, the

process of managing credit risk is one of identification, analysis, measurement, mitigation,

monitoring and controlling. Management often mitigates risk by transference, containment and

hedging against it. However, because of the special challenges presented by SMEs, the process

of credit risk management requires that creditors apply credit risk management policies and

procedures specific to SMEs in segregated portfolios and make a more targeted assessment of

individual credit applicants. The determinants of SME credit riskiness are: financial opacity

(which may be linked to a period of “informality;” informational asymmetry (particularly in their

early stages of their business cycles); lack of collateral (i.e. most of their assets are movable);

substandard records (e.g. unaudited or certified financial statements and possibly lack of

managerial training/coaching), shorter operating histories and little or no credit history (which

may require owner/SME combined scoring),; poorer management quality; and an array of other

constraints on credit accessibility particular to SMEs, e.g. those noted in Figure 7.

SME are privately held firms; few are publically held or have access to capital markets. Thus,

banks are the primary source of financial intermediation for SME. Major credit rating agencies

seldom maintain credit database information on SME. Thus, for banks, SME are generally

considered riskier than larger firms. This perception of riskiness significantly affects the SME

“credit gap.” Unlike larger firms, when credit tightens, SME cannot substitute longer bond debt

Page 34: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

or equity financing for bank lending. Moreover, the perceived risk generally results in banks

requiring higher expected returns on credit to SME. Thus, the SME “credit gap” is exacerbated

by both credit rationing during credit tightening cycles and higher expected returns on loans due

to perceived riskiness. In determining the level of risk and return, banks look to credit risk as the

primary risk for evaluating their exposure to loss and price (return) discovery. Credit risk is the

risk of extending credit to a borrower or borrowers in a portfolio of loans. It is the risk of loss or

diminution of financial reward to a lender resulting from the likelihood of a borrower’s failure to

repay a present contractual obligation from future cash flows. Thus, the process of identification,

analysis, measurement, mitigation, monitoring and controlling credit risk is more difficult for

SME.

Methods used by banks to identify, analyze and measure the inherent risks of SME have led to an

evolution of credit risk models. This has been ushered on by the importance and growth of the

SME sector and the failure of larger banks that lend primarily to larger firms (but, whose failure

resulted in banking regulations that affect SME nonetheless). Acronymic and balance sheet

accounting attempts to measure credit risks have proven to be of limited application due to their

static and periodic natures. Credit rating agencies, e.g. Fitch’s, Moody’s and Standard & Poors

also are less useful in evaluating SME credit risks as few SME have credit profiles by the major

credit rating agencies. Thus, banks have turned to systematic and internal models to manage

SME credit risk.

Because of the proclivity of SME to internally finance their early stage development, SME credit

scoring should be based on the analysis of historical data about the SME’s owner as well as the

firm; thus removing some of the opacity of the SME. The data are entered into an internally

developed or purchased loan risk prediction model for credit scoring. Moreover, there exist

credit reference agencies or national credit bureaus that provide credit scoring historical

databases, where a particular bank lacks such a database. These databases encompass both the

business and the individuals in the business, based on their personal credit experience and the

business rating where available (DeYoung, Frame, Glennon, & Nigro, 2010).

Bank Credit Risk and FinTech. Existing credit risk models do not leverage new sources of

qualitative and quantitative information that encompasses both for individual owners and SME.

API technologies can leverage nontraditional data points and sources to selectively refine

existing models. These Fintech solutions offer an interactive, smarter seamless customer

monitoring interface through the use of instant messaging and smart devices. It may integrate

machine learning and artificial intelligence (“AI”) to produce faster and more accurate responses

to customer activities, including their changing needs and circumstances. This, in turn, enables

banks to lend to new customers that they would have otherwise rejected. Scalable APIs with

micro-service “app” capabilities that interface large multi-purpose relational bank databases can

create “micro-service” models that are agile and adaptable.

Page 35: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Credit risk assessment has traditionally used audited financial statements of companies.

However, many SME, both “formal” and “informal” may not need audited financial statements,

making credit evaluation challenging. Moreover, financial statements are not dynamic as to time

or value. Financial statements may only be issued annually or quarterly, and weeks, if not

months after the accounting period has ended. In the digital economy, banks can leverage new

data points through social media and connectivity in the market as an alternative to their existing

credit scoring model and as encouraged by Basel III.

The so-called “finternet” can develop integrated solutions that provide banking and SME

connectivity based on size, age, growth stage, and service requirements through “cloud” API.

These services are broader than simple financial services and may include business management,

cash management, working capital and other financial and consulting services. These services

may be linked to API exchanges that interface with SME focused programs, training, cluster and

integrated SME development systems and other mobile financial literacy tools. For example,

human centered disclosure statements (“HCDS”) that are legally binding but easier to read and

understand, combined with interactive digital ecosystems, e.g. working capital management

tools, can be leveraged using robo-advisor AI technology, that would allow bankers to offer

advice when appropriate.

Digital documentation and authentication may sooner than later become obsolete. Yet many

banks still communicate with customers via paper statements and advice through traditional mail

(“snail mail”), which is slow in today’s digital world, has security flaws, and involves inefficient

manual paper shuffling labor. Mobile user-friendly apps targeted at SME can provide access to

aggregated financial transaction details (if possible across different financial institutions),

customized reports from various accounts and/or financial institutions, information storage

capabilities, personal data, and real time notifications. At the SME firm level, the continued use

and reliance on paper-based methods to reconcile payments, accounts, returned checks, lost

invoices and T+2 processing time for telegraphic transfers can result in time management and

informational inefficiencies. Banks can and should develop a full product suite for SME to

manage their sales, receivables, costs, purchase orders, invoices, working capital and cash flows.

This information can be platformed into information needed by banks to monitor SME loans as

part of a risk management lending technology framework (infra). These finance technological

innovations and more are part of the emerging “internet of things” IoT, sometimes called the

“finternet of things” (Monetary Authority of Singapore; The Association of Banks in Singapore,

2016).

Systematic Approach to Credit Risk Management. Credit risk, like all risk, once identified, can

never be completely diversified away or hedged against. The idiosyncratic nature of some

portion of credit risk, for example, remains due to the underlying debtor, its business model, its

industry, the subject matter of the financing and the systemic risks that are part of both local and

Page 36: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

global economies. The methods used to measure credit risk are not disjointed. Credit risk

analysis is not a standalone component of financial analysis. Managing credit risk requires

analyses of borrowers, their products, industries, operations and personnel. Lending to SMEs, for

example, not only involves tailored risk management techniques, but also managing the

concomitant risks which result from the additional costs associated with those techniques, e.g.

investigation, monitoring, advisory and collection costs. They are quite often used together and

integrated as part of systematic credit risk analysis method employed by the financial institution.

Hence, once identified and analyzed, the process of measuring, monitoring and controlling credit

risk, as with all risk, is ongoing. In this sense, the process of credit risk management begins with

the identification of the risk and continues analytically and systematically as long as the specific

credit risk exists.

Technology has facilitated the systematic process. Accordingly, many modern banks use an

overall systematic credit risk framework, which includes such tools as data management, risk

profiles, monitoring and feedback; as well as a variety of credit risk measurements (Bluhm,

Overbeck, & Wagner, 2010). One such approach to systematic credit risk management employed

for SMEs is shown in Table 9 below (International Finance Corporation, 2010).

Basel. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, based in Basel, Switzerland, was

mandated by the Bank of International Settlements (BIS) in the 1980s in order to promote

standards to enhance bank safety through risk measurement and monitoring methods. Basel I

(1988) or the Basel Capital Accord, as it is called, emphasizes a bank balance sheet by protecting

the regulatory capital of banks. Regulatory capital is the amount of capital a bank must maintain

as required by the bank’s regulator and is generally a ratio of bank equity that must be

maintained relative to the “weighted” riskiness of the assets the bank holds. The method is

measured in two steps: the measurement of weighted risk exposures assigned to assets classes;

and the quantification of the regulatory capital available relative to the risk measured (Iqbal &

Mirakhor, 2007).

Regulatory capital is divided into Tier 1 and Tier 2. Tier 1 is the core measure of a bank's

financial strength as determined by its regulator and it typically comprised of the bank’s common

stock, disclosed reserves, stock surpluses or retained earnings; and may also include non-

redeemable non-cumulative preferred stock. Tier 2 is supplemental to the core capital component

and is typically comprised of revaluation reserves, undisclosed reserves, hybrid instruments and

subordinated term debt. The ratio of regulatory capital (Tier 1 and 2) to risk-weighted assets is

the minimum level of recommended regulatory capital or capital adequacy ratio (CAR). In the

wake of banking volatility and rapidly changing financial markets, including financial product

innovation, Basel II was promulgated in 2004. Basel II introduced enhanced prudential

supervisory review processes and more effective market discipline. Market discipline placed

greater emphasis on bank transparency and risk disclosure (Investopedia LLC, 2016).

Page 37: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Basel III was adopted in general in 2010 and was scheduled to be gradually implemented from

2013 until 2015 but delayed full implementation to 2019 (Basel Committee on Banking

Supervision, 2011).

Table 9-World Bank Systematic Approach to SME Risk Management

Understand the SME

Market

Develop

Products &

Services

Acquire & Screen

SME Customers

Manage & Service

the SME

Customers

Manage Data,

Information &

Knowledge

Identify and quantify risks in the targeted market; leverage

existing research and bank data

Develop loan

pricing

models that

match client

risk profile

Lend to current

customers first,

Integrating portfolio

information

Dedicate staff to

identify signs of SME

default early

directly liaison with

SME management to

minimize losses

Establish centralized

teams to monitor loan data for risks &

early warning signs, &

to incorporate data &

improve credit policies

Sub-segment the market by risk profile and target

according to bank risk appetite

Incorporate

innovative

forms of

collateral,

such as

accounts

receivable

Use internal rating &

scoring methods to assess loans &

customers

Provide advisory

services

to assist SMEs in cash

flow management

Use portfolio data to

customize models

for statistical credit

scoring

Enhance predictive capabilities

by gathering information on local

SME success factors

Prioritize

role of non-

lending

products;

establishing

customer

relationship

& providing

predictive

data

Use transparent

external data

such as credit bureau

reports; Separate sales

from

credit approval

for more rigorous

underwriting

Dedicate processes

& staff to SME

segment to streamline

Operations

Enhance profitability

analysis capabilities

to disaggregate

revenue & costs by

revenue, cost & profit

centers, e.g. branches,

products, customers

Implement pricing &

operational approaches

by understanding level & nature

of unmet SME demand;

including service preferences

Sophisticate

standardized

products

to minimize

transaction

costs

Focus customer

acquisition

on clients

“close to” the current

portfolio; Automate

screening processes

to reduce underwriting

costs

Use direct channels

e.g. branches & call

centers to reduce

relationship

management cost

Learn from & apply

cost-saving

innovations discovered

from branches,

products, customers,

etc.

Segment the market by costs

in order to identify & limit

effects of cost drivers linked to

SME characteristics

Increase the

overall

value of each

SME

customer by

offering &

bundling a

wide variety

of products &

services

Separate business

development from

relationship

management

for efficiency

Adjust level of

personal service

to SME size or value

Revise qualitative &

quantitative internal

credit scoring models

based on the data,

information and

knowledge obtained;

Implement modified

restructuring,

collection & transfer

policies & procedures

Source: (International Finance Corporation, 2010); modified by author

Basel III has mandated that banks pay closer attention to measuring and managing credit risk. Its

requirements affect large and small banks alike. Smaller banks, whose business model focuses

on small business, are the primary SME lenders in many economies. In Germany, as in many

other EU countries, these banks issued almost 60% of all SME loans (Angelkort & Stuwe, 2011).

While these smaller banks were not the real cause of the financial crisis, they are included in the

Page 38: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

gamut of the Basel III regulations. Moreover, the liquidity coverage ratios introduced by Basel

III exclude commercial paper of SME. Nevertheless, Basel III is particularly important to SME

because SME seldom have external credit ratings. That has proved to be an impediment to bank

measurement of credit risk for SME. However, the introduction of internal rating based approach

to credit risk and the automatic credit scoring models approved by Basel III have shown a

positive effect on SME. Banks are increasing their use of small business credit scoring (SBCS)

as an internal rating approach to credit risk. SBCS uses statistical evaluation of historical

financial information (including credit profiling) for both the SME owner and the SME.

Empirical tests of the result of using these methods by “community banks,” which are generally

smaller, but frequent SME lenders, shows that their use is positively correlated with SME credit

availability (broadly defined). The determinants of credit availability included: quantity of

lending; riskier (marginal) lending; lending in low-income and high-income areas; and lending

over greater distances. These methods are often combined with other credit risk techniques.

(Berger & Frame, Small Business Credit Scoring and Credit Availability, 2006). Moreover,

research shows that the use of credit scoring is associated with an increase in credit availability

for credit facilities to $100,000, without any significant change in the quality of the banks’ loan

portfolios. There appears to be a learning curve in using the technology (Berger, Cowan, &

Frame, The Surprising Use of Credit Scoring in Small Business Lending by Community Banks

and the Attendant Effects on Credit Availability and Risk, 2009).

Table 10 SME Credit Risk Management Competencies

Description Core Competency Criteria Assess the bank’s ability to

shift from a traditional

risk management approach,

based on risk avoidance,

systematic collateralized

lending, and relationship

lending to an industrial and

objective approach to risk

based on adequate risk

assessment, mitigation and

pricing. A good credit risk

management framework

should ensure that

(1) credit risk is appraised in

a thorough and consistent

way across the institution,

(2) segregation of duties

between origination,

underwriting, and

disbursement is adequate,

(3) mechanisms are in place

to efficiently manage and

monitor the portfolio, and to

learn from negative

experiences

Management and

Organization

Credit underwriting

Portfolio monitoring

Bad debt management

Risk modeling

Organization of the

credit risk function

Credit policy

Approval criteria

Credit

administration

Monitoring process

Early warning

signals

Early arrears

management

Portfolio reviews

Recovery process

Rescheduling

Provisioning

Analytics

Risk modeling

culture

Systems

Source: (International Finance Corporation, 2010)

Page 39: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Notwithstanding the advance of internal credit scoring models, credit risk management extends

beyond the origination of the actual loan. As noted in other sections of this paper, ex poste risks

for SME must be monitored in order to properly manage credit risk in a holistic manner. Table

10 annotates credit risk management competencies related to a holistic approach.

Information Asymmetry. Because SME typically suffer from opacity and substandard records,

and because credit risk assessment is in large part based on information, an asymmetric

information problem among SME should be viewed as a major determinant of perceived credit

risk. In a financial sense, banks trade in financing. In the SME sector, banks exchange finance at

a price that is intermediated according to the information the SME possesses and has given to the

bank. The exchange of information reduces the bank’s risk of adverse selection; and hence,

credit risk. A bank needs this information to write a loan contract. It needs as much symmetry as

possible not only to determine its required return and the loan size, but also to ascertain whether

there is a “better” borrower to ration credit. Table 11 summarizes a conceptual framework for

SME lending technologies at a “loan-level granularity.”

Table 11-SME Lending Technology Conceptual Framework

Technology Information Source Screening &

Underwriting Policies

Contract

Structure

Monitoring

Mechanisms

Small business credit scoring

Hard information (data points) about the

Enterprise

Based on the SME’s score in a statistical model

No collateral required, higher expected returns

Observation of timely Repayments

Financial statement Lending

Audited financial Statements

Based on the strength (and credibility) of the

SME’s financial ratios

Contracts may vary but future cash flow is

primary source of

repayment

Ongoing review of financial statements

(suggesting possible

mechanisms, e.g. debt covenants)1

Relationship

Lending

Soft information on

the SME, owner, and

community, gathered over time

Based primarily on the

decision or

recommendation of the loan officer

Variety of structures Continued observation

of the enterprise’s

performance on all dimensions of its banking

relationship (suggesting

possible mechanism, e.g. compensating balances)1

Factoring Value of collateral:

accounts receivable

Based on the quality of

the enterprise’s clients

Factor purchases the

accounts receivable outright, thus taking over

credit and collections

Lender owns the accounts

receivable

Asset-based Lending

Value of collateral: accounts receivable or

inventory

Based on value of collateral

Primary method of repayment is asset

collateral

Problematic, as value of the assets must be

regularly updated

(suggests the feasibility of fair value and asset

impairment actg)1

Leasing Value of the asset

Leased

Based on value of the

asset

Lessor purchases asset

and rents to borrower;

purchase option at end of

lease

Observation of timely

Repayments

Fixed-asset Lending

Value of collateral: real estate,

equipment

Based on the assessed market value of the

asset, and coverage ratios

measuring the SME’s ability to service debt

Collateral (asset) worth over 100 percent of loan,

throughout amortization

schedule; lien prevents borrower from selling

asset

Observation of timely Repayments (suggests the

feasibility of fair value

and asset impairment accounting)1

Source: (Berger & Udell, 2006); 1 Comments are the author’s.

Page 40: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Monitoring SME information and activity is important because it not only results in increased

registration and promotes data gathering, but thereby helps ameliorate asymmetric information in

the SME sector. Addressing information asymmetries is pivotal to SME development.

Information infrastructures for credit risk assessment, such as local, regional or national credit

registries or data warehouses with “loan-level granularity,” can reduce the perceived credit risk

in SME financing. Similarly, reducing the perceived credit risk may also reduce financing costs,

which are typically higher for SME than for large firms. In the “digital age,” where information

“blockchains” and application program interfaces “feed” on wider and wider information

gathering, a systemic approach to gathering SME information and the “reeling in” of the

“informal” SME sector loom far more important than in any time heretofore.

The SME “informal” sector provides “fertile ground” for both banking lending capacities and

various forms of moral hazards. The failure to monitor the “informal” SME sector and moral

hazards associated with lax registration and regulation, greatly increases the likelihood of

lawlessness (showing a disregard for the “rule of law”), secreting profits (due to a tendency

among them to deal on a cash basis) and other forms of inappropriate financial conduct; possibly

crimes. The obvious implication for tax revenue building capacity is tax evasion and/or fraud.

Finally, even in the “formal” SME sector, the ex ante monitoring of SME information can

prevent moral hazards.

Islamic Finance and SME Development

Islamic finance emphasizes risk sharing, as must Islamic banking, if it is to remain true to its

epistemology. When Islamic banking does so, it exhibits characteristics that render it “inherently

stable.” Conventional banking, because of its emphasis on debt-based products that are

uniformly interest-based, has proven “inherently unstable.” Modern historical analysis shows

that most, if not all, banking crises, can be traced back to debt leveraging crises and monetary

policies that place too great an emphasis on interest rate manipulation. Governments are no less

susceptible. Bankruptcy and insolvency have marked the 21st century geopolitical map in

Europe, e.g. Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain. Speculative financing nearly brought the

international financial system to the brink of destruction during the 2007-2009 global financial

crises. Islamic banking prohibits speculative financial transactions and securitizations that are

un-tethered to real assets, just as it prohibits interest-based systems. These governments

borrowed at level they thought were reasonable debt vis-a-vis their GDP; and ultimately found

themselves in an “unsustainable debt spiral” and forced into painful austerity programs

(Mirakhor & Krichene, 2010).

Islamic banks are mandated to promote benefit and prevent harm. At their core are the

underlying moral foundations of Islam that serve as the epistemology upon which Islamic

banking rests. Islamic banking contracts require Islamic Law (Shari’ah) compliance in the legal

banking relationships on both the asset and liability sides of banking balance sheets. Islamic

Page 41: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

banks are tasked with providing financial products and services that meet the Objectives

(Maqasid) of Islamic Law. To ensure that the Islamic banking contracts and Objectives are

fulfilled in practice, Islamic banks are overseen by Shari’ah supervisory boards, both at the

individual bank and regulator levels. These aspects of Islamic banks serve as safeguards. First,

they mandate that Islamic banking transactions are fair and transparent, avoid exploitation and

promote the wellbeing of society’s stakeholders in its financial system through normalized

prohibitions. Secondly, they provide stability in financial relationships by following rules

(ahkam) that govern banking contracts. These “rules” provide a systematic approach to banking

contracts that are tethered to Islam’s moral foundation.

The Islamic Epistemology of Sharing. Islamic banking has at its core the financial preference

of sharing both risks and profits or losses. Hermeneutically, this is the natural result of the

obligations and prohibitions derived from the sacred texts (nusus) or sources of the Islamic Law

(Al-Shari’atul Islamiyyah or Shari’ah for short). Those texts include preeminently the Qur’an2

and Hadith3. Other texts, sources and legal methods to derive rules (ahkam) from Shari’ah are

used, including, but not limited to: consensus (ijma), analogy (qiyas), statements of the

companions of the Prophet, PBUH (qawl al-sahabi), custom (‘urf), juristic preference

(istihsaan), public welfare (istislah or maslahah), presumption of continuity (istishaab), blocking

the means to sin (sadd al-dharaa’i), preceding Scriptures (Shar’u man qablanaa), the practices

of the people of Madinah4 (amal ahl al-Madinah) and exegesis (ijtihad).

Because of its religious and moral underpinnings, Islamic finance prefers risk sharing to risk

taking and risk shifting whenever possible. This does not mean that equity financing is the goal

of all financing in Islam. Islamic banking contracts provide a formative line-up of both debt-

based and equity-based financing. Moreover, the prohibition against “interest” does not proscribe

debt. Debt, in fact, is specifically mentioned in the Qur’an. For example, Verse (Ayat) 285 in the

2nd

Chapter (Surah) states in an unambiguous manner: “O you who have believed, when you

contract a debt for a specified term, write it down…” (Saheeh International, 1997). It is further

given legitimacy in the Sunnah and other sources of Islamic Law. Thus, the misnomer that

Islamic banking proscribes debt is inappropriate and misleading.

Islamic banking proponents proffer that it is different from conventional banking. Most look to

the prohibition of “interest” (infra) as the distinctive feature of Islamic banking. Some claim the

distinction is more form than substance. See (Al-Gamal, 2006), (Hamoudi, 2010) and (Kuran,

Islamic Economics and the Islamic Subeconomy, 1995), who see Islamic economics and finance

2 Al-Qur’an (literally meaning The Recitation) is the central sacred text in Islam; considered literally the Word or Speech of the

God, Who in Arabic translates to Al-Illah or contracted form Allah. 3 Hadith or sometimes called Sunnah are written collections of the sayings, actions and approvals (tacit or otherwise) of the

Prophet Muhammad, PBUH. The six major collections are Saheeh Bukhari, Saheeh Muslim, Jami’a Tirmidhi, Sunan an-Nasa’ai,

Sunan Abu Dawud and Sunan Ibn Majah. Other collections exist as well. 4 Madinah is the second holiest city in Islam, next to Makkah. It is the city that the Prophet, PBUH, resided while many of the

rules of law were established and implemented during and after his lifetime.

Page 42: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

as being either a façade of legal pluralism, illusionary or dysfunctional. In their nascent modern

history, Islamic banks have not always carried their moniker that well. They have consistently

favored debt-based modes of financing. This trend “creates suspicions amongst unconvinced

Muslims and other critical outsiders who observe that Islamic banks in reality are no different

from conventional banks since the net result of Islamic banking operations is the same as that of

conventional banking” (Dusuki A. , 2007). Moreover, there are disparate views of what Islamic

banking should be.

One view emphasizes profit and loss sharing in the bank-customer relationship and places

greater social welfare as an overriding objective, including “social justice, equitable distribution

of income and wealth, and promoting economic development.” This view encompasses

consideration of all seven Islamic banking stakeholders, i.e. customers, depositors, shareholders,

managers, employees, regulators, Shari’ah advisors and local communities (Id). The other view

posits that Islamic banks should operate as conventional commercial banks inasmuch as they

should seek to maximize shareholder profits and honor their responsibilities to depositors, but do

so in a Shari’ah compliant manner. The latter “view is somewhat similar to the Western

worldview, particularly Friedman’s concept of corporate responsibility which contends that

society is served by individuals pursuing their self-interest (ala Adam Smith’s invisible hand)”

(Id).

Shari’ah vis-à-vis Smith. The Shari’ah is regarded in Islamic finance, as in all other aspects of

life, as superseding guidance as to human interaction (mu’amulat); a substantial part of which

governs financial and economic transactions. Islam’s ultimate objectives require financial

transactions to serve the interests of all human beings (jalb al-masaalih) and to save them from

harm (daf’a al-mafasid). This is tantamount to social responsibility and accountability.

Protection of human needs is established under the Objectives of Islamic Law (Maqasid al-

Shari’ah), by not only removing harm as it relates to human beings, and in particular as it relates

to the necessities of life (dururiyyat), but also in removing hardship (raf’ al-haraj). These human

rights, which require protection from harm and hardship, encompass at least five (5) essential

areas, to wit: faith (din), life (nafs), family (nasl), intellect (‘aql) and property (ma’al) (Dusuki,

2011). These objectives protect the rights of individuals (khassan) and the public (amma) in

general (Auda, 2008). Economics as a social science; and finance, as an outgrowth of economics,

have socioeconomic implications. Islamic banks have collective religious obligations (furud

kifayyah) imposed on them by the Shari’ah, which once fulfilled by some members of society,

relieves all other members of the specific obligations. Those obligations extend far beyond

prohibiting riba or so-called interest and include the necessity that Shari’ah-based products and

services mitigate harm to individuals and society (Farook, 2007).

By contrast, epistemology of modern finance can trace its genesis back to Adam Smith’s

treatises on the “The Theory of Moral Sentiments” (“Moral Sentiments”) and “An Inquiry into

Page 43: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations” (“Wealth of Nations”). Smith’s Moral

Sentiments starts by examining the vested self-interest of mankind and the motivation of

individuals to avoid poverty so passionately as to cause them to pursue riches with “avarice and

ambition,” even as seen in “the wages of the meanest labourer” (Smith, The Theory of Moral

Sentiments, 1759). Smith’s view of economics is one that starts from an individual’s inward

motivations. It is individualist occidentalism; narrowly construed. While he makes good use of

the notion of men wanting for others what they want for themselves, the subjective nature of

what men want, its vagaries and the notion that man’s desires or “disapprobations” as he calls the

opposite of approbations, guide human beings in their financial affairs, is positivistic in origin.

Smith posits that human beings have “sentiments” that are both good and bad. He labors to find a

cohesive system of explaining mankind’s proclivities toward “self-love, reason and sentiments.”

Finally, he admits that no systematic set of rules governing natural jurisprudence, other than as

applies to “justice,” can be identified because those he has examined are “loose, vague and

indeterminable.” (Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments, 1759). From the Islamic perspective,

this is exactly why an overriding moral framework in the form of a systematic set of rules, with

objectives, is required to avoid the vagaries of sentiments and errant rationalization.

Smith posits that it is only individual security that motivates each person; and by directing his

industry to produce the greatest value that he intends only for his own gain, that he is led by an

“invisible hand” to “promote an end which was no part of his intention.” He infers from his

personal observations that an individual, by “pursuing his own interest…frequently promotes

that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it.” He dismisses the

notion of social welfare and public good by concluding: “I have never known much good done

by those who affected to trade for the public good” (Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and

Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 1776). One is left to ask: what then of the goals of social

welfare and nation building? One might say that in contrast to Smith’s “invisible hand,” in Islam,

the Hand, though invisible, is evident, axiomatic and part of the normative Islamic worldview.

Moreover, the Hand does not so much emanate from the individual’s desires as it does from the

community striving together for common good, as Muhammad, PBUH5 said: “Indeed, Allaah’s

Hand is on the community.”6

This is, in part, why ‘urf and ‘aadah are, within proscribed limits of the Shari’ah, are considered

sources of law in Islam. The term ʿurf, means "to know" things that are well established in a

given society, e.g. customs or traditions. ‘Aadah refers to conventions or usage of those customs

and traditions that are brought or carried forward. Technically, these terms overlap. They also

form the basis for acceptance of pre-Islamic financing traditions incorporated into Islamic

banking (Ghani, 2011). Thus, the quwaid al-Fiqiyyah or legal maxim: customary practice is

5 PBUH is tradition acronym for sending salutations on Prophet Muhammad, i.e. “May God’s Peace and Blessings be upon him.” 6 Sunan an Nasa’ai. Ruled authentic by Shaykh Nasirdin al-Albani. Also, found in Jami’a Tirmidhi with the version: “Indeed my

community will not agree on error and the Hand of Allaah is upon the community; he who sets himself apart from it will be set

apart in Hell.

Page 44: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

among the juridical authorities or al-‘aadat al-muhakkamah. And further, in order to repel public

harm, private harm is to be tolerated or ‘yutahammal al-darar al-khas li daf’ darar ‘am.’

Turning to banking; it is a collective enterprise nearly by definition. It is the depositor

stakeholders that play a fundamental role in banking and financial intermediation. The notions of

an individual’s sentiments or desires to avoid poverty are not eminent, but are preserved and

protected. Thus, the Islamic principles of protecting the interests (maslahah) of individuals

(khassan) and the public (amma). Maslahah is the juristic set of principles that preserve and

promote the Objectives (Maqasid) of the Law (Shari’ah), and further, secure benefits and protect

harm to all (Laldin, 2013).

American Capitalism. Smith’s fixation with self-interest, self-love and sentiments in pursuit of

wealth ultimately gave birth to the notions of the “profit motive” and capitalism. Profit is

mentioned in Smith’s Wealth of Nations innumerable times; but loss relatively seldom. For

Smith, self-interest results in social benefit through commercial intercourse of merchants and

other members of society, e.g. a “butcher,” who’s production was of benefit to others; becoming

so, almost by chance, as a result of his own selfish sentiments. Smith believed this intercourse

resulted in a satisfaction to the butcher; further providing incentive for his profit motive. A bit of

history helps see the progression and divergence that emerges from an abstract, universal drive

for an asocial, if not antisocial “profit motive (Levy, 2014).

The single-minded obsession and longing for money and power gave rise to capitalists, like

Rockefeller and Carnegie. Rockefeller7 and Carnegie;

8 both appeared on the American economic

landscape in a little over a century after Smith. In America, the bastion of capitalism, Scottish

financial thought (e.g. the Carnegie and the Forbes family) became a “stable mate” of the post-

revolutionary quest for freedom from the sentiments against poverty that resulted from centuries

of feudalism and coveted wealth by the ruling families and aristocracies of Europe. During this

period, various American state legislatures began to grant corporate charters, (then considered

concessions of popular sovereignty), on a discretionary basis. These property-based corporate

concessions were private, but states brought them into existence only if they fulfilled some

“public purpose.” Such public purposes might be the construction of a road, highway or turnpike,

or the issuing of money, or other government or benevolent work of charity. The language of

these corporate charters held them to a public accountability. Further, the charter restricted

corporate activity so as not to violate these “public trusts.” A banking corporation, for example,

could not build a railroad simply because doing so would increase its profits (Hovenkamp,

1988).

7 Rockefeller founded Standard Oil Company, Inc. in 1870 the state of Ohio; as a partnership. The U.S. Supreme Court later ruled

(1911) that it must be broken up into 34 separate entities because it violated federal “anti-trust laws.” Those entities became

ExxonMobil, Chevron, and others. 8 Andrew Carnegie was an Scottish American, who founded Pittsburgh's Carnegie Steel Company, which later became U.S.

Steel.

Page 45: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Towards the middle of the nineteenth century, states began to pass general incorporation laws,

liberalizing access to corporate charters. By the end of the second half of the nineteenth century,

the legal personality of American corporations had transformed and public expectations were

largely abolished by joint-stock or stock corporations, which were decidedly “private actors,”

even if they maintained many of the privileges once granted in return for public purposes;

including limited liability. This, among other things, freed these private corporate actors to

pursue “profits” anywhere. Corporations, rather than receiving charters that expired in a term for

years, enjoyed perpetual legal existence; conveying profits, wealth and property into the

“limitless future” (Hurst, 1970). In the decades after 1850, the privatized language of corporate

charters replaced “public purpose” with “lawful purpose;” and lawful purpose became profit; to

wit the “profit motive.”

Partnerships as a Common Thread. Obviously, commerce and banking did not begin in America.

Commerce is as old as human history or immemorial. Aside from the butcher or ironsmith and

similar trades, commerce took on collective, feudal, joint ventures very early in human history.

The epistemology of conventional partnerships and their concomitant laws can be traced to Near

Eastern, North African (Egypt) and Medieval European societies; all long before Smith’s time

(Henning, 2007). See also (Rodriguez, 2002). Roman expansion and conquest gave shape to lex

mercatoria or merchant laws. These laws contributed several important concepts. Foremost

among them was the idea of parties “coming together” for consensual good faith dealings inter

se or among themselves. Moreover, lex mercatoria advanced another fundamental legal

principle, i.e. the doctrine of agency or each partner having the right to participate in the

management of a business (mutua praepositio), as well as the liability of all the partners (in

solidum) to third parties for “partnership obligations and the entity theory of the legal nature of

partnership” (Id).

Another form of partnership known as a commenda or “an arrangement by which an investor

(commendator) entrusted capital to a merchant (commendatarius) for employment in business on

the understanding that the commendator, while not in name a party to the enterprise and though

entitled to a share of the profits, would not be liable for losses beyond his capital” (Id). The

commendatarius would only lose the value of his labor and time; possibly reputation. It parallels

the modern limited partnership, as well as the Islamic mode of finance known as mudarabah

(infra). In fact, some scholars have specifically attributed this mode of financing to Islamic trade

origins (Udovitch, 1970) and to the Hebrew ‘isqa and Islamic qiraad ( (Udovitch, At the Origins

of the Western Commenda: Islam, Israel, Byzantium?, 1962).

In fact, among the Mediterranean merchants, there were other contracts in commenda, i.e. the

collegantia maris, which in contrast to the societas maris, did not involve a joint expedition or

travel to obtain profit. In this form of contract, the limited partner does not travel (socius stans -

Page 46: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

one who stands), but instead borrows two thirds of capital required, and the traveling partner

(socius tractator) the other third. The loss was covered according to the invested capital, but the

profits were shared equally between the two parties. Onshore collectives arose in the form of

compagnia and societas terrae, which handled expansions from major ports to inland traders.

The compagnia was predominantly a family company, which included the father, sons, brothers

and other relatives (con-with and panis-bread), being based on unity and responsibility of capital,

labor and results. Later, they were called by their collective name, societas terrae, because its

members were jointly responsible, not only within the part that participated, but also to guarantee

of all their goods. (Pacala, 2016).

Others believe that the partnership origins can be traced to early societal “merchant houses” or

family businesses that ultimately formed ventures and companies with other “merchant houses”

(Kohn, 2003). Taking a more “organic” view of how partnerships developed, Kohn draws a

similitude between these family “houses” of merchandising and trades with family agricultural

endeavours. He traces these origins to “sea lions” or commerce in the Mediterranean Sea (as this

sea served as a Medieval “super-highway” between the West and East) and the Roman forms

noted above. He repeats another theme found in other literature in this area and that is that one of

the motivations for using the partnership form in the Roman and European environments was to

avoid Roman edicts against usury (Id). In other words, a partner might be able to secure

legitimate profits at a rate suitable to him through the partnership form that he would not be able

to charge by simply loaning money to a merchant. This is certainly an interesting phenomenon

from the Islamic perspective, as it is a fundamental norm in Islamic banking.

Still other historical research ties commercial development more closely to the “collective.” The

association of individuals into groups pursuing a common goal as a “collective” was critical to

both family and state in early Roman jurisdictions. Under Roman law, the state, not the

individual, was empowered to hold “property and transact with natural individuals as though it

was itself a person." Collectively held Roman tax farms called societas publicanorum outlived

the individual partners and had representatives who acted for the company as a unit, and allowed

the trading of their shares (Kuran, 2006). Even though Kuran sees the religious restrictions in

Islamic Law as an impediment to growth, it may be seen alternatively as a stabilizing force that

prevented Islamic societies from rushing headlong into a individualistic, capitalistic financial

model that is now, more than ever, being questioned by many economists and financial

professionals because of its lack of inclusiveness, inability to alleviate poverty; not to mention its

instability and volatility that seem to plague it in cycles, if not perennially.

Hence, what we find instead of Smith’s individualist, occidental view of commerce and finance,

we find an evolution of non-banking finance and commerce based on profit and loss sharing

arrangements among families, merchants and collectives. This approach to commerce and

finance can be found in Asian commerce long before the Northern-to-Southern Europe to

Page 47: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Mediterranean-to-Egyptian line of merchandising practices and laws. Early Chinese traders

spread their merchandise over several ships, instead of putting all their property on one ship. If

one ship sank, no individual trader bore the loss or was “wiped out.” If two traders spread their

goods over two ships and one sank, each trader lost only half of his goods rather than everything.

The Chinese and Babylonians, in the 3rd

and 2nd millennium BCE, respectively, also engaged in

practices of risk, and profit and loss, sharing and the latter codified such practices in the Code of

Hammurabi, circa 1750 BCE (Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., 2016).

Early Banking Origins. Banking as a business can be seen historically in Babylonia in the 2nd

millennium BCE, where there were written standards of practice in the Code of Hammurabi.

Obviously, these early banking practices were very different from modern-day banking practices.

For example, deposits were not made with money but with livestock, grain or other commodities;

eventually precious metals. These deposits were accepted, loans were made and fees were

charged. These same basic concepts underlie today’s banking system were present in these

ancient arrangements. Similar banking practices were found in ancient Egypt. These resulted

from the requirement that grain harvests be stored in centralized state warehouses. Depositors

could use written orders for the withdrawal of a certain quantity of grain as a medium of

payment. This system continued to exist even after private banks dealing in coinage and precious

metals were established there (Davies, 1994).

More modern banking practices can be traced to the Mediterranean Italian cities of Florence,

Venice, and Genoa. Italian bankers made loans to princes to finance wars and and to merchants

engaged in international trade. Again, these early banks tended to be organized by trading

families as a part of their more general merchant activities. The Bardi and Peruzzi families were

dominant in Florence in the 14th century; establishing branches in other parts of Europe to

extend their merchant activities. Both of these banks eventually failed when Edward III of

England defaulted after financing the “100 Year War” with France (Hoggson, 1926). The most

successful Italian banking family was the Medici family and Medici Bank established by

Giovanni Medici in 1374. The Medici began as money changers, eventually expanding to

London. The Medici Bank’s principle customers were merchants, royalty and the Pope; the latter

being the primary reason for the bank’s success.

International business of the Medici banks was facilitated through the use of bills of exchange.

This usually involved a creditor providing local currency to the debtor in return for a bill stating

that a certain amount of another currency was payable at a future date, e.g. the date of a big

international fair. In order to circumvent the Roman Catholic Church’s prohibition on usury or

directly charging interest, these banks were closely affiliated with merchants. Bankers took

deposits in one city, made a loan to merchants transporting goods to another city and received

payment at the destination. In short, it was international trade and the varying currency exchange

Page 48: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

rates provided a means of concealing interest charges; thus, circumventing the Christian usury

prohibitions (Goldthwaite, 1995).

During the 17th and 18th centuries, Dutch and British banks improved Italian banking

techniques. Key to this development was the notion of fractional reserve banking. By the middle

of the 17th century, Europe was engulfed in wars. Goldsmiths transitioned from forging gold and

silver to becoming bailsmen for the safekeeping of precious metals. In return, they issued a

“receipt” for the deposits. The receipts began to circulate as a medium of exchange; a form of

fiat money. Keen to their advantage, the goldsmiths realized that all depositors would not

withdraw their gold and silver simultaneously. They began to issue more receipts than they had

precious metal in their vaults (Davies, 1994).

Ultimately, banking reached the shores of North America. Banks became an integral part of the

fledgling American economy almost from the start of the colonies. In 1781, just five years after

the Declaration of Independence, the first chartered bank was established in Philadelphia; by

1794, there were 17 more. Initially, bank charters could only be obtained through a legislative

act. However, by 1838, New York had adopted the Free Banking Act, which allowed anyone to

engage in banking business as long as they could meet the statutory requirements. Each state

then passed its own banking act and soon banks from the various states had differing bank notes.

Bank failures made matters worse. The American Civil War to end slavery ushered in federal

legislation for nationally chartered banking. A national currency was adopted and a tax placed on

state issued bank notes. The national bank notes came with a federal guarantee; protecting the

holder in the eventuality of an individual bank’s failure. This centralized legislation placed all

banks under federal supervision; ultimately leading to the present day federal reserve system

(Klebaner, 1974).

Much of the world has now forgotten the international merchant-banker, partnership and

collective origins of commerce and banking, Smith’s view is one of individual maximizing

behavior, self-motivating and self-reinforcement. It provided a rationale for the capitalist “profit

motive,” but little else. Islamic finance has largely retained the “sharing” aspects of humanity’s

early commercial origins and after a hiatus caused by colonialism, now seeks to resurrect the

collective spirit of broad-based stakeholder accountability, and the sharing of risks, profits and

losses. These values are inherent in the sanctity of its contracts, socioeconomic objectives and

norms. Therein lays the challenge of Islamic banking, which is at an embryonic evolutionary

crossroads seeking to synchronize its legal banking instrumentals to modern markets in the face

of stiff competition from a well-entrenched and formidable conventional international banking

system. What will be the trajectory of Islamic banking; one positively or negatively aligned with

its underlying epistemology? Kuran9, though a critic of Islamic finance offers an observation that

seems noteworthy:

9 Timur Kuran is a professor of economics and law at the University of Southern California and the King Faisal professor of

Islamic Thought and Culture.

Page 49: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

“I reject…the view that laws evolve instrumentally to track hanging material

needs in a perfectly synchronized manner. However, I also reject the counter-

view that laws are fully autonomous from market outcomes. In my analytical

framework institutions not only constrain activities but they shape the

incentives to modify them. In formal terms, I recognize path dependence10

as

well as the impact that material outcomes have on the specific "path" the

economy subsequently follows…As such, my argument falls within the rubric

of "historical institutional analysis" (which) distinguishes among self-

enforcing, self-reinforcing, and self-destroying institutions. In the short run, a

self-enforcing institution perpetuates itself as the expected actions of agents

motivate and enable other individuals to follow the associated behavioral

regularity. Such an institution is also self-reinforcing if it exhibits positive

feedback, in other words, it expands the range of situations in which the

behaviors in question are observed…A self-enforcing institution is self-

destroying if, while perpetuating itself in the short-run, it exhibits negative

feedback by sowing the seeds of its own eventual demise” (Kuran, The Islamic

Commercial Crisis: Institutional Roots of Economic Underdevelopment in the

Middle East, 2003).

Normative Prohibitions and Obligations. The juristic foundation of Islamic Law is in its

simplest expression is based on prohibitions (tahrim) and obligations (ijab). Islamic banking

incorporates the prohibitions in its rules regarding usury (riba), speculation (gharar) and

exploitation (zulm). Islamic banking is also prohibited from financing proscribed transactions,

i.e. those dealing in impermissible (haram) goods (e.g. alcoholic and addictive substances),

services (e.g. night clubs or places where alcoholic beverages are served or illicit contact

between genders is commonplace, pornographic media, etc.) and practices (e.g. gambling or

maysir, which has been found to exist in certain conventional insurance contracts). Thus, these

products, services and practices, among others not enumerated here, are strictly prohibited in

Islam, i.e. they are impermissible or unlawful per se. Islamic Law prohibits usury (riba),

speculative or excessively ambiguous dealings (gharar) and exploitative business practices

(zulm). It also commands and encourages the sharing of profits by mandating an assessment on

profits, encouraging the sharing of them and discouraging the hoarding of them.

Riba. The term riba is commonly equated with interest in conventional (and some Islamic)

financial texts. However, the term has a much broader application in Islamic finance. In Islam,

riba and interest are not the same; the former being more expansive than the latter. Riba is

10 Path dependence can be described as an historical economic theory that sometimes minor, even fleeting advantages of some

technology, product, standard or legal precepts, can have important and sometimes irreversible influences on the ultimate market

allocation of resources, even in an economy dominated by voluntary decisions and individually maximizing behavior.

Page 50: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

defined differently depending on its usage. The particular form of riba called interest has been

prohibited in other religions and societies before the formal establishment of Islam as a world

religion; most notably in the Law of Moses, Peace be upon him, i.e. the Torah. The Catholic

theologian, Thomas Aquinas, condemned all interest as usury; while Martin Luther, the

Protestant, likened usury to murder (Goetz, 1952). The conceptual condemnation does not end in

religions, but also includes ethical and philosophical condemnations. The classical Greek

philosophers, Plato and Aristotle, both prohibited interest on loans. Aristotle described this form

of commerce as the “birth of money from money” and the most unnatural form of commerce.

Aristotle wrote that money is “intended to be used in exchange, but not to increase at interest” Id.

Notwithstanding its broad condemnation, it persists and is the foundation of modern

conventional finance; thus fulfilling the prophecy: “There will certainly come a time for mankind

when everyone will take riba and if he does not do so, its dust will reach him.” This Hadith11

is

reported in Abu Dawood, Vol. 2, #3325; Ibn Majah, Vol. 3, #2278 and in both Ahmad’s Musnad

and An-Nasa’i.

Riba comes from the Arabic verbal root rabaa and literally means something increased or

augmented. It has the secondary connotations (ishaarat) of excess, growth, addition, swelling,

high, being big and usury (Lane, 1863). The inference clearly has financial connotations, i.e.

money lent in expectation of receiving more in return. Riba has several technical meanings as

well, which centre on the notion that it is “any excess without any corresponding counter-value

recognized by the Shari’ah” (ISRA, 2010). This is sometimes modified by adding the phrase

“recognized by the Shari’ah at the time of the transaction, or with a delay in exchange of either

or both counter-values” (Id). Some scholars extend the meaning of riba to any prohibited “sale”

or wealth acquired illicitly, regardless of how acquired (Id). In short, it is an unjustified increase

in wealth at the expense of another (Lewis, Ariff, & Mohamad, 2014).

There are some unique forms of riba, e.g. riba al-fadl, which “occurs when commodities of the

same genus are exchanged in unequal quantities in a spot sale” (Id). The rules governing these

exchanges generally falls upon 6 commodities: gold, silver, wheat, barley, dates, salt “and the

like.” The rules have been juristically extended to modern currency trading. The rules governing

these exchanges are termed bai’ al-sarf (or bai’ meaning sale and sarf meaning exchange).

While they may seem cumbersome to the uninitiated, their significance can be seen when viewed

through the prism of consumer protection. For example, it is related that Bilal (a companion of

Muhammad) brought to the Prophet, PBUH, some barni (good quality) dates, whereupon the

Prophet asked him where they were from. Bilal replied: “I had some inferior dates which I

exchanged for these - two sa’ for a sa’ (a measurement used during the time).” The Prophet said:

“Oh no, this is exactly riba. Do not do so, but when you wish to buy, sell the inferior dates

11 Hadith or plural Ahadith are the sayings and actions of Prophet Muhammad, PBUH; as well as his approvals (tacit or

otherwise) of words or actions of others. This particular Hadith as a weakness in its transmission, but is reported in 4 different

collections of Ahadith.

Page 51: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

against something (medium of exchange) and then buy the better dates with the price you

receive.” Reported in Sahih Muslim, Vol. 3, # 3871; also Musnad Ahmad). This Hadith provides

insight into rules (bai’ al-sarf) that seek to provide consumer protection, as well as the

importance that Islamic finance places upon the marketplace as a price discovery mechanism.

Gharar. Literally, gharar comes from the Arabic root meaning to deceive, beguile, to show

inexperience or ignorance in affairs, to act childish, to expose to danger, perdition or destruction

without knowing, danger, hazard, delusion and deficiency or imperfection. The related word

taghreer means to expose to danger. Technically, gharar implies uncertainty and/or ignorance of

one or both parties in a contract over the substance or attributes of the object of sale, or doubt

over its existence and availability at the time of contract or any of the other salient terms of an

agreement. Gharar yasir is minor or acceptable uncertainty; as few financial events are without

any uncertainty. A contract that has this level of uncertainty will not be invalidated. However,

gharar fahish is major or unacceptable uncertainty and is fatal to an Islamic banking contract,

resulting in the contract being void or voidable. Its presence eviscerates mutual consent (ridaya)

or the “meeting of the minds” that is essential to contract formation. Since Islamic contracts, as

conventionally, come in a variety of forms, the effect of gharar on each has been interpreted

somewhat differently among jurists. Ijma or consensus or unanimity of opinion exists as to the

impermissibility of the lower threshold of gharar or ambiguity in mu’awadaat contracts or

exchange contracts which contain promises (al-Dareer, 2004).

Gharar is also prohibited in Islamic financial intermediation caused by excess ambiguity, excess

uncertainty and speculation (which increases credit risk). Banking has inherent risks. The legal

maxim, no reward without risk (al ghorm bil ghonm) capsulizes this financial phenomenon

(Rosly, 2005). Though the perceived difference between ghonm and gharar may be subtle in the

mind of consumers, Islamic banking professionals must nevertheless guard individuals and

society against the spread of gharar. Thus, Islamic banks are prohibited from speculative

investing of deposits, which are treated as liabilities by all banks.

Finally, gharar in Islamic banking contracts may be caused by asymmetric information (jahl),

ambiguity (taghreer), lack of “mutual consent” (ridha), misrepresentation (ghabn), and doubt

(shubuhat). Islamic banking contracts that are unduly complex, verbose or combine within them,

two or more contracts (ijtima al-uqud), can easily lead to gharar. Onerous and unfair terms and

conditions in Islamic contracts may lead to exploitation (zulm). Misleading advertising and

marketing (khalabah) can lead to gharar and zulm for the unwary (Abdullah, Amanbayev, Omer,

& Elobeid, 2012).

Zulm. Zulm is derived from the Arabic zalama or to do wrong or evil, to treat unjustly, oppress,

harm, deprive another of his or her rights (huqouq), injure, to be unjust, act wickedly or to

misuse another. The sacred texts of Islam are replete with commands, prohibitions and

Page 52: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

statements against zulm and warnings against it in all facets of human interactions (mu’amulat).

As noted above, the Objectives of the Islamic way mandate that Islamic society and its

institutions (and specifically its financial system) strive to be beneficial to humanity and protect

it from harm. Since the Almighty has forbidden injustice by Himself, He has also forbidden it

among humanity. In financial transactions, taking the money or property of others unjustly is a

form of zulm. The taking may be by “trick” or connivance, deceit, dishonesty, improper

measurement and accounting, theft or by any number of other means, e.g. unfair bargaining

power. It may also exist due to the lack of compassion or mercy on others, including debtors.

Zulm is often overlooked as an Islamic norm although it is proscribed in Islamic banking. The

Islamic norm against zulm includes, but is not limited to: (1) untrustworthiness; (2)

untruthfulness; (3) lack of generosity in bargaining; (4) inflated claims; (5) harshness towards the

debtor; and (6) “cut-throat” business practices (Hassan, 2006) .

Zakat. Linguistically, Zakah comes from the root zakwa, meaning to increase, augment, grow

well, flourish, prosper, produce fruit, to make pure or good and to enjoy a plentiful life. Its

technical meaning is that of a specific portion of wealth (after the passage of a year on it) that

must be given annually to a specific group of recipients. Items of accumulated wealth that exceed

the minimum levels (nisab) are subject to mandatory zakat. The rate of zakat varies somewhat by

the nature of the nisab. The nisab may include the impact on wealth resulting from debt to a

creditor, receivables, merchandise, agricultural goods, animals, jewelry, precious metals and

other items according to prescribed calculations in the texts. For purposes of Islamic banking,

zakat is mandatory on the profits from the operations, as reflected in the retained earnings and

capital of an Islamic bank that is owned by Muslims.

Zakat is one of the five pillars of the Islamic way. It encompasses both mandatory (the formal

zakat) and voluntary (sadaqat) charitable giving. It also encompasses non-monetary giving, e.g.

acts of kindness. Among the traditions of Islam is that even a smile can be a form of charity; as

can removing something harmful from a road or walkway. Sadaqat is derived from the Arabic

root, sadq or sidq, meaning to be truthful and sincere. Technically, sadaqat means charitable

giving that has 4 elements: it comes from a pure source (sometimes called one’s legitimate

holdings); it has sincerity of intention; altruistic motives; it is done or given first and foremost for

Almighty God’s pleasure (Khokhar, Dabas, & Zarabozo, 1991).

The recipients of zakat are: the poor (fuqooraa); the needy (masaakeen); those who collect zakat

(‘amiloona ‘alaihaa); those whose hearts are in need of reconciliation (mu’allafatu qulubuhum);

freeing captive or slaves (ar-riqab); debtors (ghareemoon); those stranded away from their

homes without the means to return (abna’ as-Sabil); and soldiers (mujaahideen). There is deep

meaning for each class. Overall, zakat (including sadaqat) is designed to promote solidarity and

allegiance (unity), kindness and compassion (selflessness and mercy) and social realignment or

the alleviation of poverty and income inequality (Id).

Page 53: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Kanz. Linguistically, the Arabic for hoarding is kanz, meaning to collect and store up, to bury a

treasure. Thus, linguistically, kanz means to hide wealth, be it food, gold, silver, fiat money,

intellectual property, etc. Property and wealth are a means to greater prosperity; not just for the

few, but for the many. That is why, in the Islamic Law, zakat is not voluntary, but mandatory;

while that which is even better, sadaqah, is best. There is some difference of opinion as to what

the technical meaning of kanz is. Some believe it applies to food and specifically to those who

hoard food in order to create shortages to increase their profits. Others believe it is that upon

which zakat is not paid. In other words, hoarding is not that upon which zakat has been paid. The

broadest view is that the prohibition of hoarding applies to everything that people need and will

be harmed if it is withheld. This view infers that hoarding applies to all forms of wealth.

This latter view also encapsulates Islam’s financial epistemology that dictates the use wealth in

production. Thus, the goal in Islam is to spread wealth. That is a basis for zakat and sadaqah and

the fact that the poor and needy have a share in the wealth of others. Moreover, an underpinning

of Islamic economics is the utilization of wealth (capital) to make the resources of labor and

natural resources productive, i.e. the sharing of profit and loss by the constituents. Hoarding can

be ameliorated in modern societies by financial intermediation. Those with surplus allow their

excess wealth to be circulated in society through credit, thus reducing the “credit gap.” The

command to circulate wealth can be gleamed from the following, powerful Verse from Qur’an:

“Is it they who would apportion the Mercy of your Lord? It is We Who apportion

between them their livelihood in this world and We raised some of them above others

in ranks, so that some may employ others in their works. And the Mercy of your

Lord is better than what they amass” (Az-Zukhruf 43:32).

Again, the Islamic epistemological notions of sharing of profit and loss are emphasized in the

sacred texts of the Islamic Law and fortify thereby a way of life tethered to principles of

socioeconomic wellbeing. Though there may exist wealth and income inequality, the “push” and

“pull” principles engrained in the Islamic Law, its Objectives and Rules thereon, act

systematically to keep wealth, wellbeing, income and fairness tethered.

Sanctity of Contracts. Economically, the goal of ensuring individual protections necessitates

transparency and fairness in contracts (uqud, plural for aqad) and what follows them (tabi’) in

normative economic behavior. There were no banking institutions during the genesis of Islam.

Fiat currency was nascent at best and the great majority of transactions were handled by

pawning, gold and silver measurements, investment through sharing contracts, exchanges and

mark-up sales. These early practices are retained in the Islamic Law of contracts. Moreover, the

sacred texts of Islamic Law compel that contracts be honored and fulfilled. The Islamic Law of

contracts is a subject in and of itself. There are a variety of forms, including what are known in

western cultures as unilateral, bilateral and trusts. In Islam, transparency and mutual consent as

to lawful goods and services are central to generic contracts. Capacity of parties to enter into

Page 54: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

contracts is also central to formation. As in any society, where there are disputes as to the “basis

of the bargain” between parties, methods of resolving the breaches are applied. As noted,

however, a hallmark of the Islamic Law of contracts is the favoring of leniency towards a debtor

during periods of difficulty and hardship.

Islamic System of Banking Contracts. As can be seen from Figure 11, there are 6 basic

classifications of contracts in Islamic finance. The list is not exhaustive and there are hybrid

contracts structures, e.g. sukuk or securities contracts as well. Additionally, there are gratuitous

contracts, which are used in takaful (or Shari’ah-based risk sharing contracts), charitable

contribution pledges (e.g. waqf or endowments) and bank depository accounts. There are also

contracts that effectuate certain purposes, e.g. trade letters of credit. These contracts use one or

more of the basic contracts in modified form to suit the underlying transaction. It is noteworthy

that there is only one loan contract called Qard. The essence of that classification is that money

is not lent as in conventional finance at interest. Qard is a loan, but it is repaid in principal only.

As will be briefly noted under FinTech and Islamic finance infra, qard may also be the basis for

so-called “soft loans.” The prohibition against riba as discussed earlier applies to these loans.

Fiat or paper money is viewed as a medium of exchange, not a real asset. It is a financial asset in

that sense, but represents some underlying real asset, be it gold, accumulated wealth, etc.; much

as it did in the early years of “banking.” The Islamic financing contracts on the right are fee

based contracts, i.e. pawning (rahnu), guarantees (kafalah) and service (ujrah) contracts. As

noted, the list is not exhaustive. Much of the financing by Islamic banks, including that afforded

SME takes the form of sales, lease and manufacturing financing, as well as equity (or profit and

loss sharing) contracts. A distinguishing feature of Islamic banking is that much of its financing

is asset-based and tied to the real sector of the host economy.

Figure 11-General Classification of Islamic Banking Contracts

Source: Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM)

Sale Based Contracts. Murabahah contracts are cost plus contracts. They are sales contracts

because the bank buys the good wanted by the SME and then sells it to the SME at cost, plus a

mark-up (or profit) that includes the bank’s costs, risks and associated expected return. Although

Page 55: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

the mark-up may be negotiable, they typically include: stamp duties and other regulatory fees,

general and administrative costs and risks. The risks may include credit risk, business risk and

price risk. Murabahah financing theoretically requires the disclosure of the cost basis of the

good. Typically, the sale will be on a deferred payment plan, i.e. in installments or payment in

full at a future date. Normally this sale is with deferred term, sometimes abbreviated as BBA

(bai’ bithaman ajil) or (bai’ mu’ajjil). Obviously, it may be used by SME to finance equipment,

inventory, etc. Similarly, payment can be made upfront with delivery of the commodity at a date

certain in the future, e.g. agricultural goods, at a later date. This is called purchase with deferred

delivery or literally a peaceful or firm sale (bai’ salam). The advantage to the SME in this sale is

that it receives cash in order to acquire seeds, materials, labor and other inputs to deliver the

commodities. Since farming is seasonal, it was originally a carved-out exception to the general

rule of selling that which is not known, in order to facilitate farming.

A reverse murabahah is called tawarruq. Thus, a SME would buy a commodity (ostensibly one

which it has knowledge of its market or uses a broker to do so as a murabahah purchase, i.e.

deferred payment (either in installments or in full at some future date) at cost plus. The SME

then sales the commodity to a 3rd

party at the “spot” or market price to obtain the money needed

to conduct the SME’s business, e.g. for working capital purposes. The SME will then pay the

initial seller the murabahah price over time. There are different versions of the transaction. One

such version is called a deposit placement sale. In it the SME’s bank buys the commodity from a

broker at “spot” and sells it to the SME as a bai’ bithaman ajil (BBA) or deferred cost plus. The

SME then sells it to another broker at “spot.” Placement or brokerage houses are established to

handle the brokerage part of the transaction. Malaysia’s commodities brokerage house is called

Suq al-Sila’. The end result is that the SME has monetized the commodity and ends up with cash

flow amounting to the deferred price less spot price and costs, as working capital.

Bai’ Inah and bai’ dayn are both highly controversial, but are used by some. Bai’ inah is a sale

by a SME to a bank or other financier on a deferred basis, bai mu’ajjil, and subsequent

repurchase of the same commodity the spot price. It is essentially a sale and buy-back. The net of

the prices is working capital and considered riba by many. This contract is sometimes used as a

transitory supporting contract for a larger transaction. It still remains controversial. Bai’ dayn is

the sale of debt. With only very narrow exceptions, an existing debt, can be sold. Typically, it is

by offset (muqaassah), transference (hawakah) or securities with a mixture of debt and equity

ingredients (khultah). Transference and offset might be used by SME to factor receivables,

assign debts and create a novation. Similarly, an offset might be used to relieve an SME of a debt

by offsetting it with an amount due the SME. Mixed debt and equity hybrids are generally found

in sukuk or securities. Again, there are differences of opinion on each, but each is being used in

the Islamic finance market.

Page 56: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Lease Based Contracts. Leases in Islamic banking are called ijarah, which comes from the

Arabic root ajr, meaning to use property or reward for services. Its technical meaning is that of

usufruct or the legal right to use and enjoy another person's property or the rents or profits there

from. Leases are useful financing vehicles for SME as they generally don’t require much capital

upfront and allow the SME to utilize the property, e.g. land, building, equipment or even services

on an ongoing basis while in operation. Islamic banks use 3 types of leases: a straight operating

lease (ijarah); lease with an option to purchase (ijarah muntahia bit tamlik) and sometimes

abbreviated as AIMAT; and lease with intention to buy (ijarah thumma al-bai), sometimes

abbreviated as AITAB. There are subtle differences between AIMAT and AITAB. The former

gives the lessee several options as to when to buy or not or to renew the lease. The latter is a

lease with the intent to enter into a purchase agreement to buy the usufruct at the end of the lease

term. There are issues that have arisen with respect to these two contracts relating to the joining

of two contracts and the issue of resembling bai’ inah. However, they are widely used by Islamic

banks and therefore available to SME.

Manufacturing Contracts. Though classified as a “construction-based” contract, istisna’ is similar

to bai’ salam. However, it is specifically designated for manufacturing something and payment

may be made in advance, deferred or made in installments. Like bai’ salam, an istisna’ contract

get be concluded without the subject matter of the contract being in existence. The seller may

also have a 3rd

party manufacture or produce the subject matter. This is sometimes referred to as

the parallel istisna’. Specifications must be precise. Banks may use parallel istina’ to contract

with the SME to manufacture the subject matter and in turn contract with a manufacturer to

actual manufacture the subject matter.

Equity Based Contracts. The 3 equity based contracts are partnership contracts. Mudarabah has

been referred to a “silent” partnership. Mudarabah have been called the “work horse” of Islamic

finance. It is a partnership of where one party provides the capital and the other party provides

the labor and/or expertise. There is no khalt or mixture of capital. The distinction is that in

mudarabah there is sharing of profits based on the efforts of the mudharib and capital of the

rabb al-mal. However, losses are borne by the financier and the SME would lose its effort and

labor. Mudarabah contracts are used by Islamic banks as both liabilities and assets. However,

they offer great potential as a stage of development financing “tool” that could be used by banks

for SME as the relationship grows and as the SME positions itself for venture capital, the

issuance of a sukuk or an initial public offering. Sukuk are often syndicated by larger banks in

many bank-based economies. Hence, an existing banking relationship with growth and hyper-

growth SME may easily development into further financial relationship beneficial to both SME

and bank. These contracts can have restrictions placed on them by the financier. Moreover,

though limited, silent partnerships are widespread in conventional finance, few if any

conventional banks form partnerships with banking customer. With the emergence of FinTech

and other financial innovations and given the need for the scaffolding of an Islamic capital

Page 57: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

market based on Shari’ah-based versus Shari’ah-compliant equities, mudarabah initiatives in

Islamic banking could prove beneficial to all concerned.

Musharakah contracts are similar to general partnerships in conventional finance. The classical

company in Islam is the sharikat. This Arabic word signifies the mixing of two capital inputs in a

manner that makes it difficult to separate them. These partnerships are flexible as to partner

contributions. Again, in the context of the SME “capital gap,” they provide a flexible and useful

vehicle for SME development. As with mudarabah, these accounts might be used in “clusters,”

are as part of specialized funds or banking branches designated to develop the best SME that

have the greatest potential for growth. Unlike mudarabah accounts, all partners’ capital will

share in the profits and losses of operation. Thus, they might have application more fitting for an

SME that has passed the 5 year survival age and transitioning to venture capital and/or IPO. Both

mudarabah and musharakah contracts can specify the term of the partnership. These partnership

banking contracts are the most versatile banking contracts available to SME. There are at least 4

types of musharakah: ‘inan (joint limited); mufawada (joint unlimited); ‘amal (based on joint

labor or expertise); and al-wujooh (reputation based credit partnership).

Musharakah mutanaqisah are diminishing partnerships. They are used extensively in residential

financing, but could have important application in SME development. It is a partnership in which

the Islamic bank gradually transfers to the SME partner bank’s share in the partnership, so that

the bank’s share declines while the SME’s share increases until the SME becomes 100% owner

of the subject of the contract or project. Figure 12-Typical Islamic Bank Balance Sheet Contracts

Source: (Dusuki A. , Islamic Financial Instruments, 2011)

Liability Based Contracts. As can be seen in Figure 12, these contracts are used on the liability

side of Islamic bank balance sheets. They are either depository accounts held in safekeeping

(wadi’ah) or in loan in trust (qard). Wadi’ah accounts may be contractually added with a

Page 58: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

suretyship or guarantee and become known as wadi’ah yad dhaman. It is noteworthy, that

depository accounts cannot contractually require that interest be paid on them. However, many

Islamic banks will give depositors a gift from its profits, which are sometimes called hibbu,

which literally means “love.”

There are, as noted earlier, investment accounts, which are primarily mudarabah contracts.

However, they may be tawarruq and hybrid accounts. Wakalah bi istithmar is a fiduciary

account whereby an investor enters into a contract with the Islamic bank to management an

investment fund on behalf of the SME. Stipulations to the contract may be negotiated, e.g. what

types of investments may be acquired from the investment fund. This may be used by SME as a

cash and investment management account, whereby excess cash on hand may be “swept” away

into investments on an ongoing basis; or likewise accessed to provide cash flow to the SME.

Shari’ah Supervision of Contracts and Activities. Islamic banks are subjected to the same

regulatory standards of good governance and risk management as conventional banks, including

those promulgated by Basel and national central banks and regulators. In addition, they are

required to have their products and services supervised through a review, certification and

approval process by religious committees and/or boards comprised of Shari’ah scholars who

establish operating procedures verifying and certifying that no product or service is authorized

by management that does not conform to Islamic Law (Shari’ah), its Objectives (Maqasid) and

rulings (ahkam) pertaining to Islamic finance.

These Shari’ah committees or boards must be competent in the specialized knowledge of Fiqh

al-Mu’amulat (the jurisprudence or body of law, rules and objectives of Islamic Law) and best

modern financial practices and products. They must also be independent of the bank’s board of

directors, yet provide the board of directors with competent consultative and advisory services.

Shair’ah committee and board members must be objective and consistently responsible for the

approval of banking and other financial products and services offered on an ex ante and ex poste

(sometimes called the tabi’ of that which follows the approval of the products and services)

basis. Ex ante procedures include the issuance and dissemination of Shari’ah resolutions12

, while

ex poste procedures include the periodic and annual reviews.

The Shari’ah supervision function must answer questions relating to whether proposals for new

transactions or products conform to the Shari’ah, as well as perform an investigatory review of

the operations of Islamic bank to insure that its conduct in compliance with the norms

established by Islamic Law, its Objectives and rules, as well as resolutions passed by it or a

12

A resolution is a collective opinion by a Shari’ah board on a matter of Shari’ah compliance that is intended as guidance for

banks under its supervision in order to establish standardization and harmonization within a jurisdiction and is not a fatwa

(authoritative ruling having the force of jurisprudence) that may have much broader implication, e.g. regionally or globally.

Resolutions are based upon collective ijtihad (a thorough and exhaustive study, discussion and evaluation) of the sacred texts of

Shari’ah as relative to the conduct (contract, product or service) being examined.

Page 59: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

national centralized supervising board. It ensures that the Islamic banks contracts and activities

comply with that conduct and that they are transparent and not exploitative of the bank’s

stakeholders, including the communities and society in which it operates. It encompasses

research and collective decision-making, thus providing a system of internal control over the

banks products and services.

Figure 13-Malaysia’s Shariah Governance Framework Model for Islamic Financial Institutions

Source: Bank Negara Malaysia

This Shari’ah review function may be conducted by an outside Shari’ah advisory firm or group

of individual scholars, or it may be comprised of an appointed standing embedded Shari’ah

board within the bank’s internal governance. Different Islamic jurisdictions have different

Shari’ah governance approaches, i.e. some are centralized, while others are decentralized and

still others a hybrid of both. Malaysia uses a centralized approach to Shari’ah governance with

fatawa or legal rulings being made at the national level. Individual banks must then have their

own Shari’ah compliance reviews. The Shari’ah Governance Framework that encompasses these

practices to ensure compliance with Malaysia’s formidable body of legislation and guidance

from it government, regulator and central Shari’ah Supervisory Board. Figure 13 shows

Malaysia’s Shari’ah Model Framework. The Shari’ah audit function should follow an audit

program designed to ensure Shari’ah compliance at the bank, identify any issues needing further

attention, write a report of its findings and disseminate it to the Shari’ah committee and the

bank’s management and make recommendations to them of ways to correct any deficiencies.

Page 60: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Shari’ah audits should be done periodically and annually and may be done by firms or an

internal audit function.

Islamic Banking and SME Development. The OECD recently identified what it considered to

be approaches to improve SME and entrepreneurship financing (OECD, New Approaches to

SME and Entreprenuerial Financing: Broadening the Range of Instruments, 2015). Among the

recommendations are: the importance of bank financing to SME; the need to de-leverage through

transitional or business cycle stages; the concern that credit constraints will become the “new

normal” for SME; the need to broaden the range of financing instruments available to SME,

including “asset-based finance,” “alternative debt,” “hybrid instruments,” and “equity

instruments;” the need for alternative debt forms that differ from traditional lending inasmuch as

investors, rather than banks, provide the financing for SME; the need to develop SME focused

venture capital funds, SME public equity markets and private equity investors; and a regulatory

environment that enables the above structures to develop while ameliorating the credit risk

perceived by investors. Many of these recommendations are easily addressed by well established

contracts and financing instrument that are part of Islamic banking. It is so much so that it like

the OECD was writing directly to Islamic bankers. Table 12 below enumerates Islamic

banking’s prodigious repertoire of financing instruments and Malaysia’s formidable enabling

environment.

FinTech and Islamic Finance. Though nascent, FinTech offers promise for Islamic finance

because of the former’s innovative base and the latter’s full array of profit and loss and risk

sharing products. Islamic banking’s role is key to the future of the collaboration and, again,

offers a propitious opportunity for Islamic banking to become innovative while retaining its

sanctity of contract. The examples are many, but several are noteworthy.

SME Corp Malaysia, which has been mentioned supra has its Shari’ah-Compliant SME

Financing Scheme 2.0 as well as Soft Loans for SMEs. The former scheme’s stated goal is “(t)o

provide financing assistance to eligible Malaysian SMEs whereby the Government of Malaysia

has agreed to pay 2% (percentage point) of the profit rate charged on the financing provided by

Participating Financial Institutions” (SME Corp Malaysia, 2016). Qualifying SME may apply

through the SME Corp website or directly at participating banks. Interestingly, in addition to the

Shari’ah screening criteria, preference is given to ethical/environmental/technology focused

SME, e.g. biotechnology, “green” technology and multi-media firms. Moreover, micro-SME are

also eligible (Id). Most firms will be required to have SCORE or MCORE ratings.13

See (SME

Corp Malaysia-SCORE, 2016) for further FinTech tools for SME evaluation and assessment.

13 SCORE is a diagnostic tool which assigns star ratings to indicate the performance level of SMEs based on a seven assessment

criteria such as financial strength, business performance, human resource, technology acquisition and adoption, certification and

market presence. Micro Enterprise Competitiveness Rating for Enhancement (M-CORE) is a simplified version of SCORE, that

identifies the performance of micro enterprises in four areas: business performance, financial capability, operation and

management.

Page 61: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Table 12-Islamic Banking Solutions to the OECD Recommendations

OECD Recommendation Islamic Banking Solution(s)

Importance of bank financing to SME -Islamic banking is growing on average circa

16%/yr.(see EY World Islamic Banking

Competitiveness Report-2016)

-Malaysia approves approx. 91% of its SME loan

requests (see Fig. 9)

Need to de-leverage through transitional or business

cycle stages

-Islamic banking has full range of banking contracts to

help SME transition, including debt, equity and build to

order financing

Concern that credit constraints will become the “new

normal” for SME

-Islamic banking industry is well aware that Islamic

banks must increase their profit & loss sharing “book”

Need to broaden the range of financing instruments

available to SME, including “asset-based finance,”

“alternative debt,” “hybrid instruments,” and “equity

instruments;”

-Islamic banks have a full range of “in house” contracts

and instruments, including its epistemological

preference for asset based financing and profit and loss

sharing banking contracts

-Islamic banking’s murabahah, tawarruq, parallel salaam

and istisna’ are all “alternative debt”

-mudarabah and musharakah are both equity instruments

-structured financing, sukuk and parallel hybrids are part

of the Islamic banking arsenal of instruments

Need for alternative debt forms that differ from

traditional lending inasmuch as investors, rather than

banks, provide the financing for SME

-Parallel mudarabah; tawarruq and parallel salam &

istisna’ are all alternative forms of debt

Need to develop SME focused venture capital funds,

SME public equity markets and private equity investors

-Islamic banks and particularly those in Malaysia are

perfectly positioned to do just that as noted under

Sanctity of Contracts and as can be seen in Figures 5

and 11

Regulatory environment that enables the above

structures to develop while ameliorating the credit risk

perceived by investors

-Malaysia’s Islamic finance regulatory framework is the

best in the world; all that is needed is to incentivize

Islamic banks to use FinTech and gradually increase

their profit and loss sharing book Source: (OECD, New Approaches to SME and Entreprenuerial Financing: Broadening the Range of Instruments, 2015)

Other FinTech initiatives include a number of FinTech and crowdfunding SME. They include the

following:

IFT Alliance is an alliance of Islamic crowdfunding platforms. Among its evolving goals

is “to facilitate the adoption of finance technology among Muslims...(and) bring together

Muslim-focused technologies and innovations in finance so as to better synergize and

harmonize these initiatives (IFT Alliance, 2016).

Launch Good is an Islamic crowdfunding platform that supports a variety of projects

worldwide, e.g. education, environmental, SME, ethical, informational and other projects

through its launch approach (Launch Good, 2016).

Narwi is a Islamic crowdfunding site that plans to be based on the Islamic endowment

(waqf) approach. It states that is “a non-profit Islamic crowdfunding platform which

allows donors to support microentrepreneurs of their choice by establishing an

endowment, or “Narwi-Waqf,” with as little as USD 25” (Narwi, 2016).

KapitalBoost is another Islamic crowdfunder. It stated goal is “all about growing

communities. Whether it's helping small businesses grow big or protecting the social

Page 62: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

welfare of less-priviledged communities, our Singapore-based hybrid crowdfunding

platform allows our members to invest or donate in a way that is ethical and Shariah-

focused.” KapitalBoost has a emphasis on SME development and states “SMEs are often

disadvantaged in their access to funds for business expansion. Kapital Boost addresses

this problem by offering small businesses short-term financing alternatives with fast and

friendly approval process and at competitive rates. Via a Murabaha (cost plus profit)

structure, SMEs can raise financing for working capital needs. They may also finance

projects through a Mudharabah (profit sharing) structure” (KapitalBoost, 2016).

Ethis is a Islamic real estate crowdfunder. EthisCrowd.com states it is the world's first

Real Estate Islamic Crowdfunding Platform. It further says: “Our international

community of 10,000 private investors crowdfunds investments in entrepreneurial,

business, trade and Real Estate activities in Emerging Asia. We are headquartered in

Singapore, with branches and representative offices in Jakarta, Kuala Lumpur and

Sydney” (Ethis, 2016).

Conclusions and Recommendations for Further Research

It is unmistakable that Islamic banking, notwithstanding the bedrock of its Shari’ah based

contracts and religious epistemology, is still nascent institutionally given its relatively short

modern history. Therein lays the heart of the challenge facing Islamic banks in the 21st century.

Islamic banking, as a modern institution is by and large being developed on the infrastructure of

conventional banking institutions. But, it has retained its form due to it overriding epistemology

that is bound to the Shari’ah, the Maqasid and the Ahkam thereof; the sanctity of its contracts

and the vigilance in safeguarding its normative prohibitions and obligations. Islamic banking

grew from $490 billion in assets in 2010 to $882 billion in 2014; an average growth rate of 16%

despite the political turmoil affecting many of its host countries (EY, 2016). And while the

global sukuk market plummeted in 2015, Malaysian issuances still comprised 78.7% of the

global issuances (International Islamic Finance Market, 2016).

Conclusions. If banks can be “too big to fail,” then SME are “too important to ignore.” The list

of multinational corporations (MNC) that started as SME is impressive. Without much thought, a

partial list of such household names McDonalds, Apple, Alphabet and Microsoft come to mind.

This paper has identified how to “spot” SME from “infancy” to maturity, what hinders their

development, what promotes it and what their capital needs and corresponding credit risks are.

Moreover, it is shown how the Islamic finance epistemology, sanctity of contracts and norms, as

found in the Shari’ah, the Maqasid thereof and the Ahkam that follow, all make Islamic finance,

and in particular, Islamic banking, a “perfect match” for SME development in the 21st century.

As noted in Table 12, Islamic banking currently safeguards ethical, real economic sector, asset-

based financing, inclusive of debt, equity, hybrid and structured financing models through its

sanctity of contracts and normative prohibitions and obligations. Because Islamic financing is

tethered to underlying assets and not solely to promises of repayment, the credit rationing

Page 63: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

dilemma discussed hereinabove is minimized; as are some of the potential for moral hazards.

Studies have shown that financing based on assets reduces credit rationing. Moreover, Shari’ah

supervision of Islamic banking not only monitors and seeks to ensures that Islamic banking

relationships conform to the contracts and norms of the Shari’ah, but also promotes the Maqasid

al-Shari’ah and the epistemology of risk, and profit and loss sharing, which is conducive to SME

long-term development.

Islamic finance has taken harsh criticism for mimicking conventional finance. Certainly, the

Islamic bank “book” still reflects heavy debt financing. Exacerbating the obvious is the fact that

most Islamic countries are bank-based, thus “hobbling” the ability of SME to seek equity

financing during their intermediate growth business cycles. Yet, Islamic banks are very active in

the sukuk market, which offers new hope for financing innovation. Islamic banking can “cut”

new cloth and distinguish itself further from conventional banking by solving the “rubik’s cube”

of bank-based equity financing in the modern era. If successful, truly Shari’ah-based (vis-à-vis

the façade of Shari’ah-compliant) SME and MNC should emerge and derision of Islamic finance

end. With respect to MNC, studies have shown that capital market development is slow at best

without MNC presence. Regressing then, alas, MNC have the celebrated habit of starting as

SME.

Recommendations. There are a few general recommendations that can be made:

1. First and foremost is that of the registration and regulation of the “informal” SME sector; if

not their taxation. Many of these SME operate on the cash basis and stow away significant sums

of cash and otherwise impede the growth for the “formal” SME sector in a parasitic manner, as

noted in Figure 6 and the discussion there under. Preliminary data appears to show an inverse or

negative correlation between the development of the “formal” SME sector and the size of the

“informal” SME sector. While the goal does not need to be one of punishing the “informal”

SME, it should be one of registration and regulation. Such an approach will likely have several

benefits. One is that of information and data gathering, which will ameliorate the information

asymmetry problem faced by all SME. Further, it will likely further the development of the

“formal” SME sector and formalize the “informal” sector; moving both away from “mom and

pop” status to more modern organizational status, e.g. private company status (Sdn in Malaysia).

As it stands, many of these “informal” SME operate “off the grid” and essentially “hoard” cash

that better serves society if circulated in the monetary system, thereby deepening financial

development.

2. Islamic banking has a well-known “branding” problem. In order for it to assume a position of

a preferred global banking system, this problem has to be solved. Assuming the “garb” of ethical

banking will help. But, full utilization of all of its Islamic banking contracts will, as noted herein

above, put to rest much of the derision that presently plagues Islamic banking; even among

skeptical Muslims, who believe Islamic banking to be no different than conventional banking.

This may require Islamic banking “literacy” initiatives that may be greatly helped by requiring

Page 64: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

financing contracts to be easily understood or simplified. Maybe standardization or harmonizing

are keys to unlocking the rubric. Most consumers, for example, sign banking contracts and don’t

understand exactly what they’re signing because they are confronted with the “legalese” of

existing contracts. The result is effectively gharar. It may also be as simple as living up to its

epistemology of making the wellbeing (falah) by “planting the seeds” of social trust (amanah)

among all stakeholder a central objective of Islamic banking whenever and wherever feasible.

Islam has always spread its magnificent “wings” through trade and trust. In the modern world,

that same manhaj or approach is as vital as ever. Partnering nationally, regionally and globally

may be the viable means to a noble end of corporate social responsibility.

3. Hopefully, as Islamic banking begins to use more of its equity contracts in the SME sector,

monitoring and related costs can be contained. This seems to be an impediment to that

expansion. The use of “clusters” and “incubators” and the allocation of shared costs will help.

Additionally, the use of university-based training programs linked to coursework may provide

practical experience to finance and banking students, while helping to contain costs of

monitoring. FinTech may also be coupled with such approaches to further reduce and contain

costs.

4. Islamic banks may need to be given further incentives for utilization of their full array of

Islamic contracts. This may be done by setting realistic “targets” for Islamic banks from the

central banking authority or self-regulating banking associations. While it is not proposed that

the “free enterprise” mechanisms of the marketplace be overridden, it is recommended that all

available lawful and viable means of increasing Islamic bank utilization of musharakah and

mudarabah contracts be examined and implemented where possible. The narrative of the past

that these contracts are too costly to monitor by banks, and similar objections, should not be

assumed as the narratives of the future. Change is pervasive and few things change faster than

technology. Moreover, as noted herein, new and innovative SME level financing instruments are

recommended by the OECD. It may be that the use of the equity-based contracts are more

suitable for SME that are deemed high growth or “gazelles” in addition to scoring high on initial

screening credit risk scoring. Entering into equity-based banking relationships with “gazelles” on

segregated projects would seem propitious, for example, in R&D.

Further research, both empirical and qualitative, can be done to help meet the challenges of SME

Islamic financing and the constraints on SME development, including the “credit gap” and the

concomitant credit risk inherent therein. The following further research from an Islamic

perspective, are illustrative of what kind of research may help solve some of the challenges

facing both SME and Islamic banking:

1. Regressions and correlations can be run on Islamic banking-SME lending to identify factors

that contribute to or detract from SME determinants, e.g. growth, size and age. Of particular

interest might be high and hyper growth (gazelles).

Page 65: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

2. Regressions might be run on SME survival rates, loan performance and profitability by

financing contracts at Islamic banks.

3. Case studies of Islamic SME gazelles may identify factors that are the “ingredients” successful

SME from an Islamic perspective.

4. Some finance scholars believe religion to be an inhibiting factor for SME growth and market

development. That narrative should be challenged from the Islamic banking perspective by

testing hypotheses that regress Islamic banking against entrepreneurship, innovation, technology

and other variables.

5. Further study of the correlation between the “informal” and “formal” sectors of SME in

countries where Islamic Law is the prevalent legal system (as opposed to common and civil law

jurisdictions).

6. Testing as to whether Islamic banking meets the challenges of SME credit risk better than

conventional banking, while accounting for economic size and financial development among

countries.

7. Survey the use of internal scoring of SME credit risk among Islamic banks.

8. Test and compare Islamic and conventional banking against a matrix of moral hazards in

SME.

9. Study and compare adverse selection in SME as and between Islamic and conventional banks.

10. Study the impact of corruption, private interests and “empire building” on SME development

as and between predominantly Islamic and conventional economies.

Page 66: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

REFERENCES

Abdi, A. (2011). The Relative Ability of Earnings and Cash Flows in Forecasting Future Cash Flows:

Evidence in Malaysia. Kedah, Darul Aman, Malaysia: University Utara Malaysia.

Abdullah, M. (2013). The Islamic Law of Contracts: Fraud and Deceit. Kuala Lumpur:

Academia.edu.

Abdullah, M., Amanbayev, Y., Omer, G., & Elobeid, A. (2012). Overview of Takaful in Malaysia.

Kuala Lumpur: www.academia.edu.

Abouzeedan, A. (2003). Financing Swedish Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises (SMEs):

Methods, Problems and Impact. 43rd European Congress of the Regional Science Association.

Jyväskylä, Finland: European Congress of the Regional Science Association.

Acemoglu, D., Zilibotti, F., & Aghion, P. (2006). Distance to Frontier, Selection and Economic

Growth. Journal of the European Economic Association , 37-74.

Airaksinen, A. e. (2016). Statistics on Small and Medium Sized Enterprises. Finland: Eurostat.

al-Dareer, S. (2004). The Amount of Gharar that Prevents Transactions from Being Valid. 4th

conference of the Shari'ah Boards of Islamic Financial Institutions (pp. 1-29). Manama, Bahrain:

College of Law – Khartoum University.

Al-Gamal, M. (2006). Islamic Finance: Law, Economics and Practice. New York: Cambridge

University Press.

Allen, F., & Santomero, A. (2001). What Do Financial Intermediaries Do? Journal of Banking and

Finance , 274-294.

Allen, L. (2002). Credit Risk Modeling of Middle Markets. Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, USA:

Wharton.

Altman, E. (1968). Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate

Bankruptcy. Journal of Finance .

Altman, E. S. (2010). The value of non-financial information in small and medium-sized enterprise

risk management. Journal of Credit Risk , 95-127.

Altman, E., & Sabato, G. (2005). Modeling Credit Risk for SMEs: Evidence from the US Market.

Social Science Electronic Publishing , 1-48.

Altman, E., Sabato, G., & Wilson, N. (2010). The Value of Non-Financial Information in SME Risk

Management. The Journal of Credit Risk , 1-33.

Angelkort, A., & Stuwe, A. (2011). Basel III and SME Financing. Berlin: Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung and

Zentrale Aufgaben.

Page 67: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Ardic, O., & Mylenko, N. a. (2011). Small and Medium Sized Enterprises: a Cross-County Analysis

with a New Data Set. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Atanasova, C., & Wilson, N. (2004). Disequilibrium in the UK Corporate Loan Market. Journal of

Banking & Finance , 595-614.

Athukorala, P., & Nasir, S. (2012). Global Production Sharing and South-South Trade. Geneva:

UNCTAD.

Auda, J. (2008). Maqasid al-Shari'ah as Philosophy of Islamic Law: a Systems Approach. Herndon,

Virginia: International Institute of Islamic Thought.

Ayyagari, M. B.-K. (2007). Small and medium enterprises across the globe. Small Business

Economics , 415-434.

Bank Negara Malaysia. (2016). Regulatory Sandbox Discussion Paper. Kuala Lumpur: BNM.

Bank of International Settlements. (2016, July 20). Basel Committee on Banking Supervision.

Retrieved August 30, 2016, from Countercyclical Capital Buffer (CCyB):

https://www.bis.org/bcbs/ccyb/

Barth, M., Cram, D., & Nelson, K. (2001). Accruals and the Prediction of Future Cash Flows.

Journal of Accounting Review , 27-58.

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. (2011). Basel III: a Global Regulatory Framework for

More Resilient Banks and Banking Systems. Basel: Bank of International Settlements.

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. (2000). Principles for Management of Credit Risk. Basel:

Basel.

Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Honohan, P. (2009). Access to Financial Services: Measurement,

Impact and Policies. Oxford: The World Bank Research Observer.

Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2005). SMEs, Growth, and Poverty: Cross-Country

Evidence. Journal of Economic Growth , 199-229.

Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Maksimovic, V. (2005). Financial and Legal Constraints on Firm

Growth: Does Size Matter? Journal of Finance , 137-77.

Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Martinez Peria, M. (2010). Bank Financing for SMEs: Evidence

Across Countries and Bank Ownership Types. Journal of Financial Services Research , 35-54.

Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Peria, M. (2008). Bank Financing for SMEs Around the World:

Drivers, Obstacles, Business Models, and Lending Practices. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Laeven, L., & Maksimovic, V. (2004). The Determinants of Financing

Obstacles. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Page 68: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Berger, A. N., & & Udell, G. F. (1998). The Economics of Small Business Finance: The Roles of

Private Equity and Debt Markets in the Financial Growth Cycle. Journal of Banking and Finance ,

613-673.

Berger, A., & Frame, W. (2006). Small Business Credit Scoring and Credit Availability. Journal of

Small Business Management , 5-22.

Berger, A., & Udell, G. (2006). A More Complete Conceptual Framework for SME Finance. Journal

of Banking and Finance , 2945–2966.

Berger, A., Cowan, A., & Frame, W. (2009). The Surprising Use of Credit Scoring in Small Business

Lending by Community Banks and the Attendant Effects on Credit Availability and Risk. Atlanta,

GA, USA: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta: Working Paper 2009-9.

Bergthaler, W., Kang, K., Liu, Y., & Monaghan, D. (2015). Tracking Small and Medium Sized

Enterprise Problem Loans in Europe. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

Bluhm, C., Overbeck, L., & Wagner, C. (2010). Introduction to Credit Risk Modeling. Boca Raton,

Florida, USA: Chapman & Hall/CRC.

Bodie, Z. K. (2011). Investments and Portfolio Management. New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.

Brys, B., Perret, S., Thomas, A., & O'Reilly, P. (2016). Tax Design for Inclusive Economic Growth:

OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 26. Paris: OECD Publishing.

Burgstaller, J. a. (2015). How do family ownership and founder management affect capital

structure decisions and adjustment of SMEs? Evidence from a bank-based economy. The Journal

of Risk Finance , Vol. 16 No. 1.

Carbo-Valverde, S., Rodriguez-Fernandez, F., & Udell, G. F. (2009). Bank Market Power and SME

Financing Constraints. Review of Finance , 309-340.

Cassar, G. (2004). The Financing of Business Start-Ups. Journal of Business Venturing , 26-283.

Chittenden, F. H. (1996). Small Firm Growth, Access to Capital Markets and Financial Structure:

Review of Issues and an Empirical Investigation. Small Business Economics , 59-67.

Cook, P. (2001). Finance and Small and Medium-Sized Enterprise in Developing Countries.

Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship , 17.

Cook, R., Campbell, D., & Kelly, C. (2012). Survival Rates of New Firms: An Exploratory Study.

Small Business Institute® Journal , 35-42.

CPA Australia Ltd. (2016). The CPA Australia Asia-Pacific Small Business Survey 2015-Malaysia

Report. Victoria: CPA Australia Ltd.

Page 69: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Dainelli, F. F., & Fabrizio, C. (2013). Determinants of SME Credit Worthiness under Basel Rules:

the Value of Credit History Information. PSL Quarterly Review , 21-47.

Davies, G. (1994). A History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day. Cardiff: University of

Wales Press.

De la Torre, A., Martinez Peria, M., & Schmukler, S. (2010). Bank Involvement with SMEs: Beyond

Relationship Lending. Journal of Banking and Finance , 2280-2293.

Demerjian, P. (2007, January 11). Financial Ratios and Credit Risk: the Selection of Financial Ratio

Covenants in Debt Contracts. Ann Arbor, Michigan, USA: Ross School of Business, University of

Michigan.

Department of Statistics, Malaysia. (2011). SMEs Census, 2011. Kuala Lumpur: Department of

Statistics, Malaysia.

DeYoung, R., Frame, W., Glennon, D., & Nigro, P. (2010). The Information Revolution and Small

Business Lending: the Missing Evidence. Atlanta: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

DiCaprio, A., Beck, S., & Daquis, J. (2015). ADB Briefs: 2015 Trade Finance Gaps, Growth, and Jobs

Survey. Manila: Asian Development Bank.

Dijankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopen-de-Silanes, F., & and Schleifer, A. (2002). The Regulation of

Entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics , 117-135.

Distinguin, I., Rugemintwari, C., & Tacneng, R. (2016). Can Informal Firms Hurt Registered SMEs’

Access to Credit? World Development , 18-40.

Djankov, S., Hart, O., McLiesh, C., & Schliefer, A. (2008). Debt Enforcement Around the World.

Journal of Political Economy , 1105-49.

Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & and Shleifer, A. (2007). Private Credit in 129 Countries. Journal of

Financial Economics .

Duffie, D., & Lando, D. (2001). Term Structures of Credit Spreads with Incomplete Accounting

Information. Econometrica , 633-664.

Duffie, D., & Singleton, K. (1998). Simulating Correlated Defaults. Credit Risk Modeling and

Regulatory Implications (pp. 21-22). London: Bank of England.

Dusuki, A. (2011, September). Islamic Financial Instruments. Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia.

Dusuki, A. (2011). Maqasid al-Shari'ah and its Implications for Islamic Finance. ISRA Research

Paper No. 22/2011 , 22/2011.

Dusuki, A. (2007). The Idea of Islamic Banking: A Survey of Stakeholder Perceptions. Review of

Islamic Economics , 29-52.

Page 70: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Efi, L. (2015). Basel III and SME Access to Credit: Later Years Evidence from France. Aquitaine,

France: University of Bourdeax.

Ethis. (2016). Ethis. Retrieved October 2016, from Ethis: http://ethiscrowd.com/

European Commission. (2009). European SMEs Under Pressure: Annual Report on EU Small and

Medium-Sized Enterprises 2009. Brussels: European Commission.

EY. (2016). World Islamic Banking Competitiveness Report 2016. London: EYGM Ltd.

Farook, S. (2007). On Corporate Social Responsibility of Islamic Financial Institutions. Islamic

Economic Studies , Vol. 15, No. 1.

Fatoki, O., & Asah, F. (2011). The Impact of Firm and Entrepreneurial Characteristics on Access to

Debt Finance by SMEs. International Journal of Business and Finance , 170-79.

Finger, C. (1994). The Ability of Earnings to Predict Earnings and Cash Flows. Journal of

Accocunting Research , 210-223.

Gama, A. a. (2012). “Credit risk assessment and the impact of the New Basel Capital Accord on

small and medium-sized enterprises: an empirical analysis. Management Research Review , 727-

749.

Gardner, M., & Mills, D. (1994). Manaaging Financial Institutions: an Asset/Liability Approach.

Orlando, Florida: The Dryden Press.

Ghani, H. (2011). ‘Urf -o-Ādah (Custom and Usage) as a Source of Islamic law. American

International Journal of Contemporary Research , 178-85.

Gibb, A. (2004). Effective Policies for Small Business. Istanbul: OECD-UNIDO.

Goetz, P. (1952). The Great Ideas. Chicago: Encyclopaedia Britannica.

Goldthwaite, R. (1995). Banks, Places and Entrepreneurs in Renaissance Florence. Aldershot,

Hamshire, UK: Variorum.

Gregory, B., Rutherford, N., Oswald, S., & Gardiner, L. (2005). An Empirical Investigation of the

Growth Cycle Theory of Small Firm Financing. Journal of Small Business Management , 382-392.

Group, I. E. (2008). Financing micro, small, and medium Enterprises. Retrieved 1 29, 2015, from The

World Bank: http://econpapers. repec.org/repec:wbk:wbpubs:6485

Hamoudi, H. (2010). The Death of Islamic Law. Pittsburgh: U. of Pittsburgh Legal Studies Research

Paper No. 2010-02.

Haselmann, R., & Wachtel, P. (2010). Institutions and Bank Behavior: Legal Environment, Legal

Perception, and the Composition of Bank Lending . Money, Credit and Banking , 965-84.

Page 71: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Hassan, A. (2006). Sales and Contract in Early Islamic Commercial Law. New Delhi: Kitab Bhavan.

He, W. &. (2007). Small Business Financing: Survey Evidence in West Texas. The Journal of

Entrepreneurial Finance and Business Ventures , 27.

Headd, B. (2003). Redefining Business Success: Distinguishing between Closure and Failure. Small

Business Economics , 51-61.

Henning, J. (2007). The Mediaeval Contractum Trinius1 and the Law of Partnership. Fundamina

Journal of Legal History , 13-2.

Hoggson, N. (1926). Banking through the Ages. New York: Mead & Company.

Hovenkamp, H. (1988). The Classical Corporation in American Legal Thought. Georgetown Law

Journal , 1593-1689.

Hurst, J. (1970). The Legitimacy of the Business Corporation in the Law of the United States.

Charlottesville, North Carolina: University of Virginia Press.

Huyghebaert, N. &. (2007). The Determinants of Financial Structure: New Insights from Business

Start-Ups. European Financial Management , 101-133.

IFT Alliance. (2016). Retrieved October 2016, from LinkedIn:

https://www.linkedin.com/pulse/islamic-fintech-alliance-ift-born-umar-munshi

International Accounting Standards Board. (2011, 2 18). International Accounting Standard 39-

Financial Instruments: Recognition and Measurement. EC Staff Consolidated Version . London,

UK: IASB.

International Finance Corporation. (2010). The SME Knowledge Guide. Washington, D.C.: World

Bank Group.

International Islamic Finance Market. (2016). Sukuk Report. Manama: International Islamic

Finance Market.

International Trade Centre; World Trade Organization. (2014). SME Competitiveness and Aid for

Trade: Connecting Developing Coountry SMEs to Global Value Chains. Geneva: ITC and WTO.

Investopedia. (2016, July 23). Credit Risk. Retrieved July 23, 2016, from Investopedia:

http://www.investopedia.com/exam-guide/cfa-level-1/fixed-income-investments/credit-risk.asp

Investopedia LLC. (2016, 1 1). Bank Capital. Retrieved 9 1, 2016, from Investopedia:

http://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/advanced-company-tsx-venture.asp

Iqbal, Z., & Mirakhor, A. (2007). An Introduction to Islamic Finance: Theory and Practice.

Singapore: John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte Ltd.

Page 72: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

ISRA. (2010). ISRA Compendium of Islamic Financial Terms (Arabic-English). Kuala Lumpur:

International Islamic Academy for Research on Islamic Finance.

Jaffee, D., & Stiglitz, J. (1990). Handbook of Monetary Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science

Publishers B.V.

Jarrow, R., Lando, D., & Turnbull, S. (1997). A Markov Model for the Term Structure of Credit

Spreads. Review of Financail Studies , 481-523.

Jaslowitzer, P., Megginson, W., & Rapp, M. (2016). Disentangling the Effects of State Ownership on

Investment-Evidence from Europe. Marburg, Germany: Philipps-Universität Marburg.

Jensen, C., & Mecklin, H. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and

Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics , 305-360.

Kahf, M. (2005). Basel II: Implications for Islamic Banking. 6th International Conference on Islamic

Economics and Banking. Jakarta, Indonesia: 6th International Conference on Islamic Economics

and Banking.

KapitalBoost. (2016). KapitalBoost. Retrieved October 2016, from KapitalBoost:

http://www.kapitalboost.com/

Khokhar, A., Dabas, M., & Zarabozo, J. (1991). Fiqh us-Sunnah. Indianapolis: International Islamic

Publishing House.

Klapper, L., Laeven, L., & and Rajan, R. (2004). Business Environment and Firm Entry: Evidence

from International Data. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Klebaner, B. (1974). Commerical Banking in the United States: a History. Hinsdale, Illinois, USA:

Dryden Press.

Kohn, M. (2003). Business Organizations in Pre-Industrial Europe. Working Papers: Dartmouth

College Department of Economics , pp. 3-9.

Kolar, J. (2014). Policies to support High Growth Innovative Enterprises. Final Report from the 2014

ERAC Mutual Learning Seminar (pp. 1-24). Brussels: European Commission.

Krever, T. (2011). The Legal Turn in Late Development Theory: the Rule of Law and the World

Bank's Development Model. Harvard International Law Journal , 287-319.

Kukuk, M., & Stadler, M. (2001). Financing Constraints and the Timing of Innovations in the

German Services Sector. Empirica , 277-292.

Kuran, T. (1995). Islamic Economics and the Islamic Subeconomy. The Journal of Economic

Perspectives , 155-73.

Page 73: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Kuran, T. (2006). The Absence of the Corporation in Islamic Law: Origins and Persistence. Los

Angeles: University of Southern California-Department of Economics.

Kuran, T. (2003). The Islamic Commercial Crisis: Institutional Roots of Economic

Underdevelopment in the Middle East. The Journal of Economic History , 414-46.

Kushnir, K., Mirmulstein, M., & Ramalho, R. (2010). Micro, Small and Medium Enterprises Around

the World: How Many are there and What Affects Count? Washington, D.C.: World Bank-IFC.

Laeven, L., Levine, R., & Michalopoulos, S. (2015). Financial Innovation and Endogenous Growth.

Journal of Financial Intermediation , 1-24.

Laldin, M. (2013). Understanding the Concept of Maslahah and its Parameters when Used in

Islamic Financial Transactions . Journal of Islamic Business and Finance , 151-74.

Lane, E. W. (1863). An Arabic-English Lexicon. Beirut: Librairif du Liban.

Launch Good. (2016). Launch Good. Retrieved October 2016, from Launch Good:

https://www.launchgood.com/

Lavia Lopez, O. a. (2014). Management accounting in small and medium-sized enterprises:

current knowledge and avenues for further research. Journal of Management Accounting Research

, 509-515.

Le, T., Moreno-Dodson, B., & Bayraktar, N. (2012). Tax Capacity and Tax Effort: Extended Cross-

Country Analysis from 1994 to 2009. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Levy, J. (2014). Critical Historical Studies, Vol. 1: Accounting for Profit and the History of Capital.

Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Lewis, M., Ariff, M., & Mohamad, S. (2014). Foundations of Islamic Finance: Risk and Regulation of

Islamic Banking. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing.

Lopez, J., & Saidenberg, M. (2000). Evaluating credit risk models. Journal of Banking and Finance ,

151-165.

Merton, R. (1974). On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: the Risk Structure of Interest Rates. Journal

of Finance , 449-470.

Mester, L. (1997, September-October). What's the Point of Credit Scoring. Federal Reserve Bank of

Philadelphia Business Review , pp. 3-16.

Minola, T., Cassia, L., & Paleari, S. (2015). Are Hyper-Growth Firms Inherently Different?

Preliminary Evidence from a Sample of European SMEs. International Journal of Entrepreneurial

Venturing , 1-39.

Page 74: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Mirakhor, A., & Krichene, N. (2010, May 7). New Horizon Magazine. Retrieved September 2016,

from http://www.ibsintelligence.com:

http://www.ibsintelligence.com/index.php?view=article&catid=245%3Anewhorizon-feature

Mitchelmore, S., & Rowley, J. (2010). Entrepreneurial Competencies: a Literature Review and

Development Agenda. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior and Research , 92-111.

Modigliano, F., & Miller, M. (1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporate Finance and the Theory of

Investment. The American Economic Review , 261-297.

Monetary Authority of Singapore; The Association of Banks in Singapore. (2016). Singapore

FinTech Festival. Singapore: Singapore FinTech Festiva.

Moreno, M., & Flores, M. (2016). Identification of Innovation Capabilities for Micro and Small

Enterprises in Morelos, Mexico. Review of Business and Finance Studies , 79-92.

Myers, S., & Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions when Firms have

Information that Investors Don't Have. Journal of Financial Economics , 187-221.

Narwi. (2016). Narwi Launch. Retrieved October 2016, from Narwi: http://launch.narwi.org/

National SME Development Council. (2015). 2014/15 SME Annual Report. Kuala Lumpur: National

SME Development Council.

Nissim, D., & Penman, S. (2001). Ratio analysis and equity valuation: from Research to Practice.

Review of Accounting Studies , 109-154.

OECD. (2016, September 8). Basel III and SME Lending: Thematic Focus - Financing SMEs and

Entrepreneurs. Retrieved September 8, 2016, from OECD Scorecard: http://www.oecd-

ilibrary.org/malaysia

OECD. (1997). Diffusing Technology to Industry: Government Policies and Programmes. Paris:

OECD.

OECD. (2015). Innovation Strategy: An Agenda for Policy Action. Paris: OECD Publishing.

OECD. (2002). Management Training in SMEs. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-Operation

and Development.

OECD. (2015). New Approaches to SME and Entreprenuerial Financing: Broadening the Range of

Instruments. Istanbul: OECD Secretary-General.

OECD. (2004). Promoting Entrepreneurship and Innovative SMEs in a Global Economy. 2nd

OECD Conference of Ministers Responsible for SMEs (p. 24). Istanbul, Turkey: OECD.

Page 75: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

OECD. (2004). Promoting Entrepreneurship and Innovative SMEs in a Global Economy: Towards

a More Responsible and Inclusive Globalisation. Second OECD Conference of Ministers

Responsible for Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises (SMEs) (p. Executive Summary). Paris: OECD.

OECD. (2013). SME financing: Roadmap for future work-Addendum. Paris: OECD.

OECD Statistics Directorate. (2009). Measuring Entrepreneurialship: a Collection of Indicators.

Paris: Secretary-General of OECD.

OECD. (2015). Taxation of SMEs in OECD and G20 Countries, OECD Tax Policy Studies No. 23.

Paris: OECD Publishing.

Ogawa, K., & Suzuki, K. (2000). Demand for Bank Loans and Investment under Borrowing

Constraints : a Panel Study of Japanese Firm Data. Journal of the Japanese and International

Economies , 1-21.

Organization for Economic Co-operaton and Development. (2005). The Measurement of Scientific

and Technological Activities. Oslo: European Commission & Eurostat.

Ott, M., & Tatom, J. (2016). Government Finance and the Demand for Money—The Relation

between Taxation and the Acceptability of Fiat Money. Economic Notes , 53-77.

Ou, C. &. (2006). Acquisition of Additional Equity Capital by Small Firms – Findings from the

National Survey of Small Business Finances. Small Business Economics , 157-168.

Pacala, A. (2016). The Modern Enterprise-Successor of Business Organization Forms in Ancient

Rome and Medieval Europe. Oradea Journal of Business and Economics , 7-16.

Pansiri, J., & Temtime, Z. (2006). Assessing Managerial Skills in SMEs for Capacity Building.

Journal of Management Development , 251-60.

Patrick, H. (1966). Financial Development and Economic Growth in Underdeveloped Countries.

Economic Development and Cultural Change , 174-189.

Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1994). The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small

Business Data. Journal of Finance , 3-37.

Potter, J., & Miranda, G. (2009). Clusters, Innovation and Entrepreneurship. Paris: OECD.

Rocha, R., Farazi, S., Khouri, R., & Pierce, D. (2011). The Status of Bank Lending in the Middle East

and North Africa Region. Washington, D.C.: World.

Rodriguez, A. (2002). Lex Mercatoria. RETTID . Aarhus, Denmark: University of Aarhus, School of

Law, Dept. of Private Law.

Romano, C., Tanewski, G., & Smyrnios, K. (2001). Capital Structure Decision-Making: a Model for

Family Business. Journal of Business Venturing , 285-310.

Page 76: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Rosly, S. (2005). Critical Issues on Islamic Banking and Financial Markets. Kuala Lumpur: Dinamas

Publishing.

Sacerdoti, E. (2005). Access to Bank Credit in Sub-Saharan Africa: Key Issues and Reform

Strategies. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

Saheeh International, T. (1997). The Qur'an: Arabic Text with Corresponding English Meansings.

Riyadh: Abul Qasim Publishing House.

Scholtens, B. (1999). Analytic Issues in the External Financing Alternatives of SBEs. Small Business

Economics , 137-148.

Schumpter, J. (1934). The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University

Press.

Silva, F., & Carreira, C. (2016). The Role of Financial Constraints in the Services Sector: How

Different is it from Manufacturing? Paris: OECD.

Small Medium Enterprise Development Bank Malaysia Berhad. (2016). SME Bank Group.

Retrieved August 29, 2016, from SME Bank Group: http://www.smebank.com.my

SME Corp Malaysia. (2016, October ). Financing Schemes. Retrieved October 3, 2016, from SME

Corp Malaysia-Official Website: http://www.smecorp.gov.my/index.php/en/programmes/2015-12-

21-09-39-08/access-to-financing

SME Corp Malaysia. (2016, October). Shari'ah-Compliant SME Financing Schemes. Retrieved

October 2016, from SME Corp Malaysia-Official Website:

http://www.smecorp.gov.my/index.php/en/programmes/2015-12-21-09-39-08/ssfs

SME Corp Malaysia. (2015, 12 21). SME Annual Report 2012/13. Retrieved 2016, from SME Corp

Malaysia: http://www.smecorp.gov.my/index.php/en/resources/2015-12-21-11-07-06/sme-annual-

report/

SME Corp Malaysia-SCORE. (2016). Retrieved October 2016, from SCORE:

http://www.score.gov.my/index.php/about-us-score

SME Corp, Malaysia. (2015, 12 21). SME Corp Malaysia. Retrieved 5 1, 2016, from SME Masterplan:

http://www.smecorp.gov.my/index.php/en/resources/2015-12-21-11-07-06/sme-

masterplan/book/11-sme-masterplan-english/3-sme-masterplan

Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Scotland:

Feedbooks.

Smith, A. (1759). The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Sao Paulo: MetaLibri.

Steven M. Fazzari, R. G. (1988). Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment. Brookings

Papers on Econoomic Activity , 141-195.

Page 77: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions

Stoneman, P., & Diederen, P. (1994). Technology Diffusion and Public Policy. The Economic

Journal , 918-930.

Tauringana, V., & Afrifa, G. (2013). The Relative Importance of Working Capital Management and

its Components to SME Profitability. Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development , 453-

69.

The Association of Chartered Certified Accountants. (2010). Small Business: a Global Agenda.

London: ACCA.

Thurik, R. (2014). Entrepreneurialship and the Business Cyle. IZA World of Labor , 1-10.

U.S. Department of the Treasury. (2016, July 13). Small Business Lending Fund. Retrieved

September 4, 2016, from Resource Center: https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/sb-

programs/pages/small-business-lending-fund.aspx

Udovitch, A. (1962). At the Origins of the Western Commenda: Islam, Israel, Byzantium?

Speculum , 198-207.

Udovitch, A. (1970). Partnership and Profit in Medeival Islam. Princeton, New Jersey, USA:

Princeton University Press.

Vos, E., & Roulston, C. (2008). SME Owner Involvement and Business Performance: Financial

Security Rather than Growth. Journal of Small Enterprise Research , 70-85.

Watson, J., & Everett, J. (1996). Small Business Failure Rates: Choice of Definition and Size Effect.

The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance , 271-285.

Wikimedia Foundation, Inc. (2016, September ). Blockchain (Database). Retrieved September 13,

2016, from Wikipedia: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Blockchain_(database)

Wikimedia Foundation, Inc. (2016, September 1). History of Insurance. Retrieved September 25,

2016, from Insurance: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Insurance#History_of_insurance

World Bank Group. (2016, June 29). Doing Business: Measuring Business Regulations. Retrieved

June 29, 2016, from Methodology: http://www.doingbusiness.org/methodology

World Bank. (2015, September 1). Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs) Finance. Retrieved April

23, 2016, from World Bank-Financial Sector Brief:

http://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/financialsector/brief/smes-finance

Wu, J. S. (2008). An Empirical Evidence of Small Business Financing in China. Management

Research News , 959-975.

Yoshino, N., & Wignaraja, G. (2015). SMEs Internationalization and Finance in Asia. Frontier and

Developing Asia: Supporting Rapid and Inclusive Growth. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank.

Page 78: SME development, constraints, credit risk & islamic banking solutions