some modern principles of taxation

Upload: kubojajoram

Post on 03-Jun-2018

222 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    1/23

    Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    Adam Smith Revisited

    Ian T.G. Lambert

    [A paper delivered at the Third Annual Convention of the Congress of Political Economists in Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, in January 1992. Ian Lambert

    is a graduate in Mathematics and Law from Trinity College, Cambridge. At the time of this paper, he practised law in the Cayman Islands]

    INTRODUCTION

    Is taxation just democratic theft? There is a modern tendency to think that it is and that any tax is

    just, provided it is levied by a democratically elected government and is impartially enforced.However, the mere fact that the rules are the same for everyone is no guarantee that they are just.

    We do not make murder and theft just, merely by allowing everyone to commit such acts on the

    same terms.

    The search for justice in taxation has been virtually abandoned, except by those who seek to use

    the tax system as a means of redistributing wealth and promoting what they call "social justice",

    i.e., as an attack on property rights. It seems to be readily conceded by everyone that all taxation

    must be an attack on property, in the sense that the government (if democratic) is entitled to take

    without giving anything in return. We need a tax system that embodies the ideas of economic

    justice and genuinely respects property rights.

    At the outset, I should emphasise that by "taxation" I mean the funding of government

    expenditure where that expenditure cannot properly be funded through any market mechanism, because it is for an essentially intangible service. There are many tangible services which the

    government provides and which can be put on a proper contractual basis. Typical examples

    include nationalised or state-owned industries, from telecommunications to coal and steel. These

    are tangible services and products, which the consumer directly receives and uses. Why,

    therefore, do governments make it hard for themselves? Surely it is easier to provide the

    consumer with a service or product for which he is charged a price, and is happy to pay it, than to

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    2/23

    take a tax begrudgingly handed over to pay for the same service, which is consequently not

    properly understood or valued by either the producer or the consumer. Throughout the world,

    such services and products are (rightly) the subject of privatisationprogrammes, where the

    consumer is once again made sovereign and dictates the product and its quality, through the

    market.

    However, there are other services which government provides that are essentially intangible and

    from which the citizen indirectly benefits, such as defence, police, embassies in foreign countries,

    parliament etc. The provision of these cannot be put on the same market basis as for tangible

    services and products directly consumed. They must therefore be funded by a levy on the citizen

    which is necessarily compulsory, and is therefore properly termed "taxation".

    This paper considers the principles according to which such taxation should be levied. It uses

    Adam Smith's four maxims of taxation (put forward over two hundred years ago) as a starting

    point for sixteen modern principles of taxation which will form the basis of a tax system which is

    simple, just and lasting.

    These principles are founded on a philosophy which does not accept the theory of the "social

    contract" as the basis for society. Under that theory, every citizen is deemed to have contracted

    with the state to become a member of society and assume the benefits and burdens of such

    membership. Under that theory, the taxpayer is already deemed to have agreed to pay the taxes

    levied on him; and there are consequently no natural limits on the power of the state to tax him.

    By contrast, Lambert's Modern Principles of Taxation are founded on the long hallowed principleof restitution -- the moral obligation to restore to another -- in the case of taxation it is the

    community -- the property or value conferred on him by that other (otherwise than by way of gift

    or contract). He who takes the benefit must take the burden, but only to the extent and measure of

    the bent it conferred. On this theory, taxation is not theft (democratic or otherwise); it is a means

    of restoring to the community, the value bestowed upon the taxpayer by the community.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    3/23

    ADAM SMITH'S FOUR MAXIMS

    Adam Smith is generally considered (certainly in the English speaking world) to be the father of

    modern political economy. In "The Wealth of Nations" (1776)[1] he set forth four maxims, or

    canons, of taxation, saying that "the evident justice and utility of (these) maxims have

    recommended them more or less to the attention of all nations.[2] The maxims were as follows:-

    I. The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of the government, as nearly

    as possible, in proportion to their respective abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue which

    they respectively enjoy under the protection of the state.

    II. The tax which each individual is bound to pay ought to be certain, and not arbitrary. The time

    of payment, the manner of payment, the quantity to be paid, ought all to be clear and plain to the

    contributor, and to every other person.

    III . Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in which it is most likely to be

    convenient for the contributor to pay it.

    IV. Every tax ought to be contrived as both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the

    people as little as possible over and above what it brings into the public treasury of the state.

    These four maxims have been summarised in four words: Equity, Certainty, Convenience andEfficiency. If we measure our existing tax systems against these four maxims arid according to

    these criteria, we can see just how far they fall short of the ideal.

    Maxim IV provides grounds alone for condemning our tax systems on the grounds of efficiency.

    Not only does the government have to employ armies of inspectors and assessors, investigators,

    prosecutors and other officials (including judges), the poor taxpayer is forced by economic

    circumstances -- to stay competitive he must take full advantage of the tax system -- to engage

    teams of tax managers, advisors, accountants and lawyers at his own expense. The costs of all

    these people mean that there is a large difference between the revenue to the government (net of

    administration expenses) and the total outlay by the taxpayer.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    4/23

    Maxim III is self-explanatory, but universally ignored. It is somehow presumed that

    inconvenience in payment is legitimised by the fact that the government is democratically

    accountable - as if this gives the government carte blanche to do what it likes.

    Maxim II makes it clear that the requirement of certainty means certain to the man in the street --

    to all of us, not just to the "tax profession". If any society is to cohere, its members must know

    and be capable of understanding their basic rights under the society's constitution. Likewise, a

    society's tax system must be known and understood by all its adult members; otherwise, they

    cannot play their part to the full, and we are all the worse for it.

    Maxim I , I have deliberately left to the last. It is the most controversial. It appears to be justifyingthe "ability to pay" principle; but whoever heard of taxing people according to inability to pay? In

    fact the ability to pay principle gets us no further forward. Does it, for example, require a

    proportional income tax or a progressive income tax?

    Levying a tax on existing riches according to their amount is not taxing someone according to his

    ability; it is merely expropriating existing wealth. To look at tax in these terms is, as Henry

    George pointed out, to fail to see that production and distribution are inseparable; they are two

    sides of the same coin. Taxation falls on and necessarily affects, future production and

    distribution, and distorts it. Taxing someone truly according to their "ability" requires taxing them

    according not to the income or wealth which they do in fact enjoy but according to the income or

    wealth which they have the capability of enjoying.

    There is a danger in interpreting Smith outside the context of the society in which he lived andabout which he wrote. Upon a more detailed consideration of Smith's maxims, in the context of

    their time, it is clear that he considered that under Maxim I taxation should be levied mainly on

    economic rent (the rental value of land in its unimproved state -- ground rent). In Smith's day,

    "Rent" and "Revenue" were virtually synonymous. Certainly, the term "Revenue" only covered

    income from an investment and did not include wages and salaries; and in eighteenth century

    Britain most investment was in landed property. So when Smith proposed in Maxim I a tax on the

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    5/23

    subjects of a state "in proportion to the revenue which they respectively enjoy under the

    protection of the stale", he was not advocating the modern proportional or progressive income tax,

    but really a tax on economic rent. This would be tax on private property in land according to its

    annual value, being the creation of and protected by the state. Most state expenditure at that time

    was on civil and national defence, which largely meant securing landowners in their privileged position. (A tax on economic rent is something to which I shall return later.)

    It is time to revisit Smith's Maxims, for they were relevant to a simpler life, but their simplicity

    should be applied to the depressing complexities of modern taxation. Lambert's Modern

    Principles of Taxation serve as a foundation for a tax system which is simple, just and lasting.

    LAMBERT'S MODERN PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION

    1. Taxation must be simple.

    2. Taxation must be certain, both now and for the future.

    3. Taxation must be neutral to production, to consumer spending and to saving.

    4. The costs of determination and collection of taxation should be the lowest possible.

    5. Net tax beneficiaries should not pay tax; net taxpayers should not receive benefit

    payments from the government.

    6. There must be no double taxation.

    7. AH taxation should be levied at source.

    8. Taxation should be legally levied on the persons by whom it is economically borne.

    9. Continuous variations in circumstances should not result in discontinuous variations in

    the amounts of tax levied.

    10. The points at which taxation ceases or starts to be payable should be drawn along borders

    of economic substance not legal form.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    6/23

    11. The action by reference to which taxation is levied must correspond with reality.

    12. Taxation should be payable at times convenient to the taxpayers.

    13. The taxpayer should be entitled to free and unlimited advice on his tax position from and

    at the expense of the government.

    14. Since the government has neither the duty nor the power to be generous, no discretions

    should be vested in its revenue officials; likewise, taxation should be strictly enforced by

    the courts.

    15. Since the government has neither the duty nor the power, through taxation, to destroy

    anything, taxation must be distinguished from criminal fines and penalties.

    16. Since there is no contractual basis for taxation, taxation should be based on the principle

    of restitution, and should therefore restore to the taxing community the value bestowed

    on the taxpayer by that community.

    In the rime allotted to me here, I can only very briefly outline each Principle, and must leave you

    to consider their practical applications and implications.

    1. Taxation must be simple.

    This means "simple" to you and me, not just to the tax profession. It should be noted that in his

    second maxim, Adam Smith specifically requires that "the time of payment, the manner of

    payment, the quantity to be paid, ought to be clear and plain to the contributor, and to every other

    person." If we take this principle seriously it requires the abolition of most of our tax legislation.

    There are some simple taxes (not many) -- for example, duties on the retail sale of gasoline or petrol, the UK. Community Charge (poll tax); perhaps best of all is the Cayman Islands departure

    tax (of CI$6 per person), collected at the airport.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    7/23

    2. Taxation must be certain, both now and for the future.

    This means what it says, and is one of the reasons why tax reform should be more of a

    constitutional issue, commanding cross-party support, than a party political football. The

    government must be prepared to commit itself more than a year in advance, it is, for example,

    grossly hyprocritical of the Chancellor in Britain to condemn "short-termism" in the investment

    markets when the British government never commits itself to a revenue budget (which is

    necessarily part of the private sector's expense budget) more than a year in advance. And what is

    true of Britain is true of America and other countries.

    3. Taxation must be neutral to production, to consumer spending and to saying.

    This may sound like an ideal, but nevertheless it is an ideal we must aspire towards. If we believein a truly free market economy, we must get government out of the market and stop it disrupting

    and distorting the market. This principle probably require; the abolition of more tax legislation

    than any other. Even the (seemingly innocuous) Cayman Islands departure tax is a tax on tourism

    and therefore on international trade.

    4. The costs of determination and collection of taxation should be the lowest possible.

    This is a reiteration of Adam Smith's fourth maxim, which was even preceded by Jean Baptiste

    Colbert's famous maxim that "The art of taxation consists of so plucking the goose as to obtain

    the largest possible amount of feathers with the smallest possible amount of hissing."

    It should be noted, however, that included in the equation must be the taxpayer's private costs, of

    a whole army of tax managers, advisors, accountants and lawyers, whom he has to employ at his

    expense. The major costs of the tax system lie hidden here, not in the Inland Revenue's or IRS's

    operating budget. (Moreover, the demand for such private services necessarily takes talent away

    from other industries and professions.)

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    8/23

    5. Net tax beneficiaries should not pay tax; net taxpayers should not receive benefit

    payments from the government

    This means abolishing the lunacy of paying taxes and then claiming refunds, and the taxation of

    grants, subsidies and benefits (such as the taxation of social security payments). But it also means

    such things as abolishing income tax on government employees' salaries. (When the British

    government purports to deduct PAYE income tax from its employees' wages, who does it pay it

    to?) It means combining the existing tax and welfare legislation.

    6. There must be no double taxation.

    Double taxation occurs where you pay (or bear) tax twice in respect of the same asset or sum of

    money. For example, if you own a house through a company, upon disposal of the house thecompany may pay tax on the capital gain; when you subsequently dispose of the shares in the

    company, you have to pay tax on the net capital gain, this time on the shares. Effectively, you pay

    tax twice on the same profit (the profit arising upon a sale of a house).

    Similarly, you may be liable to pay two different governments (one local and one national, or two

    national). A US citizen working in the UK is liable to pay tax to the US and the UK governments.

    Such double taxation is alleviated (in part) by complex double tax treaties, but these only add to

    the bureaucracy and expense of international trade. Far better to have a tax which (if universallyadopted) would preclude the possibility of double taxation.

    7. AH taxation should be levied at source.

    There are many reasons for this, but the most important is to enable the taxpayer to carry on the

    transactions of daily life secure in the knowledge that the government has already been paid and

    therefore has no further claim and will not disrupt or distort the market. PAYE income taxdeducted from wages, and taxation of interest at source are typical examples. If w. believe in

    taxing wages and interest, this is the way to tax them. Moreover, we now have sophisticated

    technology which enables us to deduct tax and issue tax invoices relatively painlessly, reducing

    deduction of tax to a mere by-product of the transaction.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    9/23

    8. Taxation should be legally levied on the persons by whom it is economically borne.

    Governments tend to prefer to put taxes on intermediaries, such as banks, employers or retailers.

    However, such taxes merely become hidden costs and the taxpayer is really misled about the tax

    he is bearing, if people really knew the true amount of the taxes they were suffering, they would

    be much more committed to tax reform and economy in public expenditure and would take a

    much greater interest in politics generally (surely a feature of a healthy democracy). The prime

    example in recent years has been the UK Community Charge, levied on each individual citizen.

    Everyone Lad to pay this personally, and it hurt all the more - provoking violent reaction. That is

    precisely why governments do not like taxing the persons who in the end have to suffer the tax.

    So they substitute indirect taxes (e.g. VAT) for direct taxes (such as the Community Charge). In

    the absence of knowledge and understanding by the taxpayer, direct taxation is often a vote loser.

    However, if indirect taxation is reversed and the reasons for it demonstrated, governments couldwin elections by demonstrating that direct taxes actually impose a lesser burden in real terms.

    At first sight, it may be thought that this principle conflicts with Principle 7, for much taxation

    paid or deducted at source is not legally levied on the persons by whom it is economically borne.

    The challenge lies in devising taxes that cannot be "shifted" by the persons on whom they are

    legally levied; and I believe there are such taxes.

    9. Continuous variations in circumstances should not result in discontinuous variations in

    the amount of tax levied .

    The great majority of all tax cases (certainly in the UK) involve a dispute between the Revenue

    and the taxpayer about some borderline transaction. If the government puts a different tax on red

    wine from that on white, inevitably someone will end up in court arguing about whether or not a

    bottle of rose or blush wine is for these purposes "red" or "white". Such cases involve all sorts of

    mental contortions by our judges in an effort to make sense of what is intrinsically nonsensical.

    The problem can only be solved by the government arbitrarily drawing the line, by legislation.

    But, while this provides certainty, it also interferes with the natural operation of the laws of

    supply and demand, and distorts the market.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    10/23

    Moreover, it is precisely these sorts of case which spawn the myriad anti-avoidance legislation

    which gives the Revenue draconian powers to tax the taxpayer according to a transaction which

    he never actually carried out. (For example", m the UK a contractual provision by a company to

    pay interest variably according to profits can be treated by the Inland Revenue as a dividend, even

    though it clearly is not).

    This apparently quite innocuous principle has some devastating effects. For one thing, it means

    the abolition of all taxes levied according to residence or domicile in the taxing jurisdiction (i.e.

    how long you spend in the country). It also means abolishing any differences between the taxation

    of investment income and the taxation of capital gains. In economic terms, all income from

    capital is a capital gain.

    10. The points at which taxation ceases or starts to be payable should be drawn along

    borders of economic substance (not legal form).

    This is similar to Principle 9, above, but not quite the same. It certainly requires not levying

    different taxes on wines according to their colour. But it also requires, for example, the abolition

    of all taxes on employment as such. In economics there is no intrinsic difference between the

    labour that is applied through services, employment or self-employment. Accordingly, a propertax system should not levy taxes differently according to such distinctions of form. (A vast

    number of legal cases in the UK have originated from a dispute about whether or not someone

    was employed or technically engaged on a contract for services.)

    11. The action by reference to which taxation is levied must correspond with reality.

    This should be enshrined in any country's constitution. It requires the abolition and prohibition ofall anti-avoidance legislation that seeks to levy tax on the taxpayer according to a transaction

    which never took place. (Imagine how you would feel if you were prosecuted for murder on the

    basis that, although everyone knew you had not killed someone, nevertheless you would be

    deemed to have done so.)

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    11/23

    12. Taxation should be payable at times convenient to the taxpayer.

    This is a reiteration of Adam Smith's third maxim. It is almost universally breached. Far from

    trying to accommodate the taxpayer's business concerns better, governments tend to be very

    inflexible about payment. Other creditors of businesses are prepared to extend credit or vary

    payments; not so the government. A prime example is the British VAT system, which now has

    harsh financial penalties for late payers. Not only is the government rarely prepared to require

    payments of tax at times which accord with the taxpayer's actual cashflow, and where appropriate

    extend credit to the taxpayer, in many cases the government borrows from the taxpayer on an

    interest-free basis (for example where lax is deducted at source from interest and must be

    reclaimed by the non-taxpayer at the end of the year).

    It is only the government's monopoly of the tax system that enables it to abuse its consumers in

    tins way. We must move to a position, where as with other services, the consumer (i.e., the

    taxpayer) conies first.

    13. The taxpayer should be entitled to free and unlimited advice on his tax position from

    and at the expense of the government

    If the taxpayer owes money to the government, absolutely or contingently in the future, he must

    surely be entitled to be fully informed of the amount and how it can be reduced. If new businesses

    are to thrive, they must be allowed to compete on equal terms with existing ones. It is large

    businesses that can afford lo indulge m expensive but highly rewarding tax planning, much of it

    wholly artificial. We need to move to a system where everyone has equal access to proper legal

    advice on taxation and where there are no loopholes to be ruthlessly exploited by the better off.

    After all, there are many other areas of law in which the government funds free legal advice and

    assistance (in the UK under Legal Aid). Moreover, if the government were to provide thetaxpayer with free and unlimited tax advice, it would receive vital feedback from the private

    sector about the economy; for it would rapidly realise just how much time, money and talent is

    dissipated in the economy by the whole tax industry, which could be put to more productive use

    by making the tax system simpler.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    12/23

    14. Since the government has neither the duty nor the power to be generous, no discretions

    should be vested in its revenue officials; likewise, taxation should be strictly enforced by the

    courts.

    This means the abolition of all "extra -statutory concessions", which are the Revenue's method of

    making a tax system which is inherently nonsensical and unfair at least a little more sensible and

    fair, thereby doing parliament's job for it. It also means overruling a large body of case law in

    which judges have taken upon themselves the responsibility for ending artificial tax avoidance

    schemes.

    15. Since the government has neither the duty nor the power, through taxation, to destroyanything, taxation must be distinguished from criminal fines and penalties.

    This means, for example, that the Chancellor in Britain must make up his mind whether he is

    raising revenue through taxing the sale of leaded petrol or fining it. It also means rejecting the US

    Supreme Court maxim that "the power to tax is the power to destroy". No government has the

    right to destroy using the tax system; that is the province of the criminal justice system.

    16. Since there is no contractual basis for taxation, taxation should be based on the principle

    of restitution, and should therefore restore to the community the value bestowed on the

    taxpayer by the community.

    The equitable principles of restitution are embedded in the law of most common jurisdictions.

    Restitution is the remedy awarded to someone who claims that another has been unjustly

    enriched. For example, a person may not profit from his crime; and property or money paid over

    under a contract which is void cannot (lawfully) be retained. In the context of taxation, which ipso

    facto cannot be levied on a contractual basis, the application of this principle means that the

    taxpayer cannot take the benefits of government expenditure without taking their burden. He must

    must restore to the taxing community the value which it has bestowed upon him.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    13/23

    This principle forms the basis of a whole political economy, indeed a whole political philosophy.

    It rejects the fiction of the "social contract". It restores equality to the dealings between the

    taxpayer and the slate. It places limits on the state. It makes justice a central feature of a proper

    system of taxation. It translates into action the Christian principle that we should render unto

    Caesar the things which are due to Caesar.

    Whatever one's personal philosophy or religion may be, fairness and justice are international

    objectives, understood in every language of mankind. Justice must be a paramount objective in

    devising a system of taxation, and such justice lies in the application of the principles of

    restitution.

    I have left Principle 16 to the last, although it is the most important of all the Principles; for

    Principles 1-15 outline how not to tax; they indicate the problem, whereas Principle 16 tells us

    how to tax, and gives us the solution.

    ARE THERE ANY ALTERNATIVE EQUITABLE TAXES?

    If we use these Principles as a critique of our existing tax system, it will be readily seen that most

    of our taxes ought to be repealed forthwith. After reflecting on the scope of these Principles, one

    might doubt whether there is any tax that would satisfy all these criteria, and be attempted to

    agree with Winston Churchill when he said "There is no such thing as a good tax".[3]

    However, there is one tax which does meet all these criteria: a tax charged on the annual rental

    value of every piece of land within the taxing authority's jurisdiction, levied on the value of land

    without improvements (or in its unimproved state) at a rate of up to 100%.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    14/23

    Such a tax (a "site value tax") would be simple (Principle 1).

    It would be certain both now and for the future (2).

    It would be neutral to production, to consumer spending and to saving (3), for most political

    economists agree with Ricardo that "a tax on rent would affect rent only; it would fall wholly on

    landlords, and could not be shifted to any class of consumers".[4]

    The costs of determination and collection ought to be quite low (4) -- you cannot hide land!

    There would be no question of taxing benefits or giving benefits to taxpayers (5), assuming the

    site value tax was accompanied by a commitment to free trade.

    There would be no scope for double taxation (6), since the tax would be levied once only, at

    source, and only levied on land within the taxing authority's jurisdiction-It would be the ultimate

    tax levied at source (7), for all taxation must ultimately be paid out of production, and all production takes place on land.

    It would be legally levied on the persons by whom it was economically borne (8).

    Continuous variations in circumstances should not result in discontinuous variations in the

    amount of tax levied (9). The tax would not be charged according to residence or domicile, butaccording to land ownership.

    The points at which taxation would start to be payable would be drawn along borders of economic

    substance (10) -- the distinction between land, labour and capital.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    15/23

    The action by reference to which taxation was levied would correspond with reality (11) -- land

    ownership.

    The tax could be made payable at times convenient to the taxpayers (12) by making it payable in

    arrears (annually or quarterly).

    The taxpayer could quite easily be given free and unlimited advice on his tax position from and at

    the expense of the government (13), precisely because of the simplicity of the site value tax.

    No discretions need to be vested in the government's revenue officials, and the tax could bestrictly enforced by the courts (14).

    Such a tax would be clearly distinguishable from criminal fines and penalties; (15).

    Finally, and most importantly, the site value tax would be based on the principle of restitution

    (16), for as Henry George said:

    "The tax upon land values is the most just and equal of all taxes. It falls only upon those who

    receive from society a peculiar and valuable benefit, and upon them in proportion to the benefit

    they receive. It is the taking by the community, for the use of the community, of that value which

    is the creation of (the community. It is the application of the common property to common uses.

    When all rent is taken by taxation for the needs of the community, then will the equality ordained

    by nature be attained."

    Such a tax would be nigh impossible to avoid. Its introduction would see the rapid decline of

    complex and artificial tax avoidance schemes. Any country that introduced it would become its

    own tax haven, overnight, and gain a significant edge over its competitors.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    16/23

    Such a tax would also abolish the need for complex double tax treaties (6). Each state would tax

    the land within its jurisdiction, and the tax would be levied on both citizens and aliens. Likewise,

    each state would not tax its citizens in respect of foreign land ownership, the economic rent

    thereof and thereon being due to the state where the land was located.

    The tax would therefore promote economic justice within a nation state and between nation states.

    If universally adopted it could form the basis for lasting harmony and give great encouragement

    to international trade.

    CONCLUS1ON

    We need a tax system that is simple and just. Contrary to the belief of many politicians, these are

    not incompatible objectives. If we are to create a tax system that meets these objectives, then before we consider the fine detail of the legal drafting we must first consider the basic principles

    according to which such a system should be devised. Lambert's Modern Principles of Taxation

    provide such a basis.

    A site value tax would comply with all of these Principles, and could be used gradually to replace

    all our existing taxes, without reducing the total revenue to government. Of course, a land value

    tax raises other questions. Could such a tax raise sufficient revenue to enable all other taxes to be

    abolished? Would such a tax be fair, given that it discriminates against the person who invests in

    land rather than in capital? Is such a tax really compatible with property rights? These are

    important questions. Many political economists, including myself, have no hesitation in

    answering all these questions in the affirmative; but the arguements are beyond the scope of this

    particular paper.

    Lambert's Modern Principles of Taxation constitute the bedrock of a system of taxation which is

    simple, just and lasting, for it should command the support of everyone, all parties and all nations.

    The adoption of such a system of taxation on an international scale is essential to the promotion of

    economic justice and harmony across the globe.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    17/23

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    18/23

    Eight ways to fail to make law:

    1. Failure to achieve rules at all -- so that every issue must be decided on an ad hoc basis.

    2. Failure to publicise, or at least to make available 'o the affected party, the rules he is

    expected to observe.

    3. The abuse of retroactive legislation, which not only cannot itself guide action, but

    undercuts the integrity of rules prospective in effect, since it puts them under the threat of

    retrospective change.

    4. Failure to make rules understandable.

    5. The enactment of contradictory rules.

    6. Rules that require conduct beyond the powers of the affected party.

    7. Introducing such frequent changes in the rules that the subject cannot orient his action by

    them.

    8. Failure of congruence between the rules as announced and their actual administration.

    Fuller maintained that a failure on any one of these grounds would totally undermine a legal

    system. Yet our systems of tax law tend to fail on every one of these grounds.

    Take the UK as an example:-

    1. Failure to achieve rules at all.

    In certain areas, such as the distinction between "income" and "capital", or between "trading" or

    "dealing" and "investment", it is arguable that there are almost no rules and that decisions are

    made on an ad hoc basis.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    19/23

    2. Failure to publicise.

    Certainly, the government makes the legislation available, eventually; but in practice the taxpayer

    needs a whole army of advisors to keep him informed as to developments. Further, certain

    changes introduced in the Budget (typically March/April) are often not clarified for months until

    the Finance Act is passed (in August) and made publicly available (in the Autumn), by which

    time the current tax year is well under way.

    3. The abuse of retroactive legislation.

    Retroactive finance legislation is not unknown. In 1974 the Chancellor Denis Healey introduced a

    tax on capital transfers in March, but it was not until the Autumn that the legislation was

    produced, even in draft form. During the intervening period, the taxpayer was subject to an

    unknown tax. In the nineteen twenties the Conservative government abolished Lloyd George's

    land value lax retrospectively (and refunded taxes already paid!).

    4. Failure to make rules understandable.

    This hardly bears comment. There are parts of the UK tax code which even the most emminent

    tax counsel do not understand, let alone the poor taxpayer.

    5. Contradictory rules.

    The UK tax code is full of provisions which seem to contradict each other, and which have to be

    reconciled by ingenious legal reasoning and extra-statutory concessions or practice directions.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    20/23

    6. Conduct beyond the powers of the taxpayer.

    While the UK tax code does not require any action which in theory is beyond the powers of the

    affected party, nevertheless strict adherence to them is in practice almost impossible (a good

    example is the extremely onerous VAT regime). Breaches (deliberate or inadvertent) are almost a

    daily occurrence - from failure to declare benefits-in-kind on your income tax return to omissions

    to charge VAT on certain minor transactions. In practice, the taxpayer has to rely heavily on the

    mercy of the Revenue, its concessions, discretions and occasional waivers.

    7. Disorientating frequency of changes.

    The tax rules in the UK are up for review every year and the Treasury and the Inland Revenue

    continuously review the existing legislation. Add to this the weekly, if not daily, barrage of tax

    cases, Revenue concessions and press releases, and VAT directives, and it is almost true to say

    that our tax law changes on a daily basis. How the taxpayer can ever orient his action by our tax

    law is a miracle. He is often reduced to a business philosophy of "hit and hope".

    8. Failure of congruence between the law and practice.

    In the UK, there is a whole book, about three inches thick, of Inland Revenue Extra-Statutory

    Concessions and Practice Directions. The Revenue has no constitutional power to issue these and

    it has been clarified that the taxpayer has no right to rely on these in any litigation before the

    courts. This is not to criticise the Revenue, but Parliament; for these Concessions and Directions

    attempt to harmonise a motley collection of ill-fitting and most disharmonious rules enacted by

    Parliament. In practice, the Revenue is doing Parliament's job for it, and there is in the UK a great

    deal of taxation without representation, by the executive branch of government.

    The UK is just one example. There are few countries that fare any better. The United States is a

    tax minefield, with city, state and federal taxes that often impose double if not triple taxation.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    21/23

    APPENDIX II

    ADAM SMITH'S FOUR MAXIMS OF TAXATION

    I. The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of the government, as nearly

    as possible, in proportion to their respective abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue which

    they respectively enjoy under the protection of the state.

    II. The tax which each individual is bound to pay ought to be certain, and not arbitrary. The time

    of payment, the manner of payment, the quantity to be paid, ought all to be clear and plain to thecontributor, and to every other person.

    III. Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in which it is most likely to be

    convenient for the contributor to pay it.

    IV. Every tax ought to be contrived as both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the people as little as possible over and above what it brings into the public treasury of the state.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    22/23

    APPENDIX III

    LAMBERT'S MODERN PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION

    1. Taxation must be simple.

    2. Taxation must be certain, both now and in the future.

    3. Taxation must be neutral to production, to consumer spending and to saving.

    4. The costs of determination and collection of taxation should be the lowest possible.

    5. Net tax beneficiaries should not pay tax; net taxpayers should not receive benefit

    payments from the government.

    6. There must be no double taxation.

    7. All taxation should be levied at source.

    8. Taxation should be legally levied on the persons by whom it is economically borne.

    9. Continuous variations in circumstances should not result in discontinuous variations in the

    amounts of tax levied.

    10. The points at which taxation ceases or starts to be payable should be drawn along borders

    of economic substance not legal form.

    11. The action by reference to which taxation is levied must correspond with reality.

    12. Taxation should be payable at times convenient to the taxpayers.

    13. The taxpayer should be entitled to free and unlimited advice on his tax position from and

    at the expense of the government.

    14. Since the government has neither the duty nor the power to be generous, no discretions

    should be vested in its revenue officials; likewise, taxation should be strictly enforced by

    the courts.

    15. Since the government has neither the duty nor the power, through taxation, to destroy

    anything, taxation must be distinguished from criminal fines and penalties.

  • 8/12/2019 Some Modern Principles of Taxation

    23/23

    16. Since there is no contractual basis for taxation, taxation should be based on the principle

    of restitution, and should therefore restore to the taxing community the value bestowed on

    the taxpayer by that community