standardizing financial reporting regulation

27
Mario Einaudi Center for International Studies Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation: What Implications for Varieties of Capitalism? Vera Palea, University of Torino March 2015 Mario Einaudi Center for International Studies www.einaudi.cornell.edu 170 Uris Hall, Cornell University, Ithaca NY 14853, t. 607-255-6370, f.607-4-50 No. 1-15 Working Paper Series

Upload: truongcong

Post on 16-Jan-2017

225 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

Mario Einaudi

Center for

International

Studies

Standardizing Financial

Reporting Regulation:

What Implications for

Varieties of Capitalism?

Vera Palea, University of Torino

March 2015

M a r i o E i n a u d i C e n t e r f o r I n t e r n a t i o n a l S t u d i e s

w w w . e i n a u d i . c o r n e l l . e d u

1 7 0 U r i s H a l l , C o r n e l l U n i v e r s i t y , I t h a c a N Y 1 4 8 5 3 , t . 6 0 7 - 2 5 5 - 6 3 7 0 , f . 6 0 7 - 4 - 5 0 0 0

No.1-15

Wo

rkin

g P

ap

er

Se

rie

s

Page 2: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation
Page 3: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

STANDARDIZING FINANCIAL REPORTING REGULATION:

WHAT IMPLICATIONS FOR VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM?

Vera Palea, University of Torino

ABSTRACT

Financial reporting is a powerful practice that shapes social and economic processes. This

paper argues that there are fundamental reasons against current attempts to establish a single

set of global financial reporting standards, moreover tailored to the needs of stock market-

based capitalism. Evidence shows that there exists more than one way of doing business.

Social market economy, for instance, is one of the founding principles of the European Union.

Standardizing financial reporting onto a single economic model could therefore harm

alternative forms of capitalism. It is at time of great uncertainty and change that the

advantages of variety can be appreciated. Consistent with this view, this paper claims that the

optimal design of financial reporting regulation should depend on the specific institutional

characteristics of the economic and political systems.

KEYWORDS: Financial Reporting, Varieties of Capitalism, European Union; JEL

CLASSIFICATION: M4o, P00, K00

About the Author

Vera Palea is tenured Researcher and Adjunct Professor in Financial Reporting and Analysis

at the University of Torino where she is currently teaching financial reporting and regulation.

Her research focuses on the adoption of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) in

the European Union. She has recently published several papers on the adoption of fair value

measurement by banks and the role of fair value reporting in the recent financial market crisis.

She has widely investigated financial regulations adopting IFRS in the European Union in the

light of the Lisbon Treaty. She holds a Ph.D. in Finance and Accounting from Bocconi

University.

Contact Information

Vera Palea, University of Torino, Department of Economics and Statistics “Cognetti de

Martiis”, Campus Luigi Einaudi, Lungo Dora Siena 100/A, 10100 Torino, Italy. E-mail:

[email protected]

Page 4: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

1

1. INTRODUCTION

The recent economic crisis has given rise to a wide criticism on stock market-based

globalization. Along these same lines, this paper argues that there are fundamental reasons

against the wisdom of current attempts to establish a single set of financial reporting standards

suitable for all the world. In doing this, it focuses on the European Union and sets the

discussion within the framework of the Lisbon Treaty (also 'Treaty' hereafter).

The Lisbon Treaty defines the constitutional setting of the European Union, establishing its

founding principles and objectives. According to the Treaty, the European Union shall work

for a sustainable development based on a highly competitive social market economy aiming at

full employment and social progress.

Social market economy represents the economic and social model on which the European

Union has decided to build and shape its own future, and proves that there exists more than

one way of doing business.

This paper discusses in detail the potentially destabilizing effects of IFRS adoption on

social market economies. It shows that IFRS in general and, more specifically, fair value

reporting can have detrimental effects on long-term investments, which have been crucial for

gaining and maintaining competitive advantages in many social market economies in the

European Union. Fair value reporting is also supposed to exacerbate contagion effects among

banks, which are core to the European financial system, and to amplify procyclicality and

credit crunch, with relevant consequences on real economy.

Current attempts to establish a single set of global financial reporting standards,

accommodated to the needs of liberal stock market economies, therefore are not neutral and

risk doing harm to alternative forms of capitalism.

The Lisbon Treaty also provides a political construct of the European Union based on

federalism. Federalism grounds on a pluralist conception and is conceived as a way to unify

different peoples for important but limited purposes, not as a way to destroy their political

identities. Prior to IFRS adoption in the European Union, financial reporting for listed

companies was regulated by directives. The directives guaranteed the harmonization of

financial disclosure, but also allowed European countries to take into accounts the specific

characteristics of their socio-economic settings. As a result, the directives were able to

conjugate unity and diversity, which is a basic principle in federalism.

Page 5: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

2

According to this paper, the European Union should go back to such an approach in

regulating financial reporting issues, and should also promote it at an international level.

Rather than accepting European economies to standardize onto a single economic model, the

European Union should pursue every effort to target its objective of realizing a social market

economy, as it is set out by the Treaty. Consistent with Bertrand Russell (1919), ideals are

defined by politics and come first, actions must follow accordingly.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the main attempts

to establish a single set of global financial reporting standards tailored on the needs of liberal

stock market-based economies. Section 3 discusses the main characteristics of social market

economy, which has been set out in the Lisbon Treaty as a founding principle of the European

Union. Section 4 raises several issues that call into question the consistency of IFRS with

social market economies. Section 5 discusses the sovereignty paradox of the standards-setting

process, while Section 6 provides some conclusions and policy recommendations for the

future.

2. THE WISDOM OF A SINGLE SET OF INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL

REPORTING STANDARDS FOR ALL THE WORLD

On January 2005, all listed companies in the European Union started using IFRS set out by

the International Accounting Standard Board (IASB). IFRS were introduced in the European

Union by the European Parliament and Council Regulation No. 1606, 19 July 2002, which

mandates IFRS for consolidated financial statements of listed companies, with a member state

option to apply IFRS to other reporting entities. A certain number of states - such as Italy,

Belgium and Portugal - have extended IFRS to unlisted banks, insurance and supervised

financial institutions, while others - such as Cyprus and Slovakia - require IFRS for all firms.

Some other states - including Italy, Cyprus and Slovenia - have also extended IFRS to

separate financial statements of certain types of firms. There is also a clear intent on the part

of the IASB to push to extend IFRS to all unlisted firms, with the purpose of avoiding

inconsistency within the accounting practices of individual countries (IASB, 2009).

One of the purposes of mandating IFRS was to standardize accounting language at a

European level and to introduce a single set of high-quality global accounting standards that

could be recognized in international financial markets.

Page 6: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

3

Regulation 1606/2002 is very much focused on capital markets. According to Regulation

1606/2002, adopting IFRS should ensure a high degree of transparency in financial

statements, which should - in turn - lead to more effective and efficient functioning of capital

markets. The same holds for the IASB, which is very focused on equity investors, who are

considered to be those most in need of information from financial reports. Moreover, the

IASB assumes that, as investors provide risk capital to firms, the financial statements that

meet their needs also meet most of the needs of other users (IASB, 2010 BC 1.16).

The IASB’s approach to financial reporting is very close to the Financial Accounting

Standards Board’s (FASB) one1

. Indeed, the IASB and the FASB have several joint projects

aimed at promoting financial reporting’s convergence at the international level.

The wide use of fair value accounting under IFRS must be considered in this perspective.

Fair value accounting is one of the most important innovations in financial reporting in the

European Union, and represents the main difference between IFRS and the former European

regulation. Fair value is supposed to provide investors with better information to predict the

capacity of firms to generate cash flow from the existing resource base, thereby improving the

quality of information for decision usefulness (e.g. Barth et al. 2001). Both the IASB and the

FASB have made clear their view that fair value is likely to become the primary basis for

financial reporting in the future (Jordan et al. 2013). Along these lines, in 2009 the IASB

issued IFRS 9, Financial Instruments, which extends the use of fair value for financial

instruments. In 2011, the IASB issued IFRS 13, Fair Value Measurement, which provides a

single framework for measuring fair value. IFRS 13 is the result of a joint project conducted

by the IASB together with the FASB, which however resulted in a passive alignment fair

value definition, measurement and disclosure to the US FAS 157.

By adopting IFRS, the European Union, which is the second largest capital market in the

world, has delegated standards-setting to a private body, the IASB, over which it has no

control (Sinclair, 1994; Cutler et al., 1999; Hall and Biersteker, 2002). To address this issue,

Regulation 1606/2002 contains an endorsement mechanism that should guarantee that, among

different conditions, IFRS are conducive to the European public good, which – however – has

never been defined clearly. The endorsement process involves many institutions at a European

level. One of these is the European Financial Reporting Advisory Group (EFRAG), which is a

1The FASB is the organization responsible for setting accounting standards for public companies in the

United States.

Page 7: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

4

technical advisor group that assists the European Commission in this process. So far, the

EFRAG has always given positive advice on IFRS, recommending their adoption in the

European Union (Maystadt, 2013). As will be discussed, this paper raises several concerns

over the appropriateness of the current standards-setting and endorsement processes.

3. SOCIAL MARKET ECONOMY AS A FOUNDING PRINCIPLE OF THE

EUROPEAN UNION

This paper argues that since financial reporting is one of the competences of the European

Union, financial reporting regulation must be examined within the constitutional framework

of the European Union.

The constitutional setting of the Union is provided by the Lisbon Treaty, which defines the

inspiring values and founding principles on which the Union has decided to build and shape

its future. The Lisbon Treaty also provides the key conception of “European public good”, on

which the EFRAG reports.

The Lisbon Treaty came into force on 1 December 2009. It was the outcome of a long and

lively debate on the future of the European Union, which started in 2001 at the Laeken

European Council and was focused on what kind of economic and social model the European

Union would pursue.

The Lisbon Treaty goes beyond the Maastricht architecture of a simple economic and

monetary union, establishing the basis for a new economic, political and social governance.

For instance, it enshrined a Charter of Fundamental Rights into the European Union’s

constitutional order for the first time.

According to the Treaty, social market economy is one of the founding principles of the

European Union. In fact, the European Union “shall work for the sustainable development of

Europe based on balanced economic growth and price stability, a highly competitive social

market economy, aiming at full employment and social progress” (art. 3 TEU2). Moreover, “it

shall combat social exclusion and discrimination, and shall promote social justice and

protection” (art. 3 TEU).

There is general agreement that the Lisbon Treaty looked to the Rhenish variety of

capitalism in setting the social market economy as a guiding principle for the European Union

(Glossner 2014). The Rhenish variety of capitalism refers to coordinated market economics

2 TEU is the acronym for “Treaty on the European Union”.

Page 8: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

5

(Hall and Soskice, 2001), whereas the Anglo-Saxon variety refers to liberal market

economics. These two models have been developed on the basis of United States and western

Europe, while further models are necessary for other economies.

According to the literature, the defining characteristics of the Rhenish model typical of

Germany and the Scandinavian Countries are the consensual - for the most part - relationship

between labour and capital, the supporting role of the state, and the availability of patient

capital provided by the bank system or internally generated funds. These characteristics have

been key in developing a long-term perspective on economic decision-making, high skilled

labour and quality products based on incremental innovation, each at the basis of post Second

World War Germany’s economic success (Albert, 1993; Hall and Soskice 2001; Fiss and

Zajac, 2004; Perry and Nölke, 2006).

The Anglo-Saxon variety of capitalism, instead, is characterized by comparatively short-

term employment, the predominance of financial markets for capital provision, an active

market for corporate control, and more adversarial management-labour relations. Given these

characteristics, the Anglo-Saxon business model is also called stock-market based capitalism.

Specifically, the term 'social market economy' originates from the post-World War II

period, when the shape of the 'New' Germany was being discussed. Social market economy

theory was developed by the Freiburg School of economic thought, which was founded in the

1930s at the University of Freiburg, and received major contributions from scholars such as

Eucken (1951, 1990), Röpke (1941, 1944, 1946, 1969) and Rüstow (1932, 1960).

In the definition of Müller-Armack (1966), a social market economy seeks to combine

market freedom with equitable social development. Social market economics shares with

classical market liberalism the firm conviction that markets represent the best way to allocate

scarce resources efficiently, while it shares with socialism the concern that markets do not

necessarily create equal societies (Marktanner, 2014).

As highlighted by Glossner (2014), a social market economy is not a dogmatic, but a

pragmatic concept that implies that conscious and measured state intervention is contingent

on economic and social circumstances.

According to social market economics, a free market and private property are the most

efficient means of economic coordination and of assuring a high dose of political freedom.

However, as a free market does not always work properly, it should be monitored by public

authorities who should act and intervene whenever the market provides negative outcomes for

Page 9: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

6

society. The social dimension is essential not only for society as a whole, but also for the

market to work well. Market efficiency and social justice do not represent a contradiction in

terms, as is proven by Germany’s post-World War II economic miracle (Spicka, 2007;

Pöttering, 2014).

In a social market economy, public authorities must set out the rules and the framework,

acting as the referees that enforce the rules. A strong public authority does not assume a lot of

tasks, but a power that keeps it independent from lobbies, for the sake of general interest (Gil-

Robles, 2014).

Consistently with this view, the Lisbon Treaty contains a 'social clause' requiring the

European Union, in conducting its policy, to observe the principle of equality of its citizens,

who shall receive equal attention from its institutions, bodies, offices and agencies. In order to

promote good governance and ensure the participation of civil society, decisions shall be

taken as openly and as closely as possible to citizens (art. 15 TFEU3). This should prevent the

European institutions from being influenced by special interest groups. The Treaty also

highlights the importance of social dialogue, which is one important pillar of social market

economy (art. 152 TFEU). In fact, social dialogue has proved to be a valuable asset in the

recent crisis: it is no mere coincidence that the best performing member states in terms of

economic growth and job creation, such as Germany and Sweden, enjoy strong and

institutionalized social dialogue between businesses and trade unions (Andor, 2011).

4. FINANCIAL REPORTING AND VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM: DO IFRS FIT

FOR SOCIAL MARKET ECONOMIES?

Of course, a single set of global accounting standards would address the needs of

international investors who incur costs and time in translating financial statements. Financial

reporting, however, is not just a matter of investors. It serves as a basis for determining a

number of rights, which affects a great variety of constituencies: not only market actors such

as firms, investors, bankers and auditors, but also ordinary citizens, employees and states.

Financial statements, for instance, represent the basis to elaborate public budget and for tax

purposes. As a result, financial reporting must be considered with a broader perspective,

which takes into account its effects on real economy and society.

3 TFEU is the acronym for “Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union”.

Page 10: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

7

A thorough review of different research streams provides several warning signs with

regard to the disruptive effects of reporting under IFRS on social market economy.

As mentioned above, IFRS are very much focused on capital market and therefore

optimised for stock market-based capitalism. Fair value reporting as well is considered to be

essential for tailoring financial reporting to the information needs of financial markets.

As a matter of fact, in the last 40 years worldwide economies have undergone profound

transformations. The role of government has diminished, while that of the markets has

increased. Economic transactions between countries have risen substantially, and domestic

and international financial transactions have expanded at an exponential rate. In short,

neoliberalism, globalization and financialization have been the key features of this changing

landscape (Epstein, 2005).

Indeed, financial motives, financial markets, financial actors and financial institutions have

played an increasingly prominent role over time in the operation of economies. Accordingly,

shareholder value maximization has become a central feature of the corporate governance

ideology, which spread across the whole private-sector (Froud et al., 2000; Lazonick and

O’Sullivan, 2000).

As highlighted by MacKenzie (2008), financial economic theories have been intrinsic parts

of this process. Modigliani and Miller (1958), for instance, looked at the corporation from the

perspective of the investors and financial markets, and considered corporate’s market

maximization as the main priority of management. Agency theory (Jensen and Meckling,

1976) also provided an academic source of legitimacy for a greatly increased proportion of

corporate executives’ rewards in the form of stocks and stock options, with the specific

purpose of aligning the interests of shareholders and managers. In this financial conception of

the firm, corporate efficiency was redefined as the ability to maximize dividends and keep

stock prices high, thus legitimating a far-reaching redistribution of wealth and power among

shareholders, managers and workers (Fligstein, 1990).

There is no reason to think that financial economists saw themselves as acting politically in

emphasizing shareholder value. However, as highlighted by Van der Zwan (2014), financial

economic theories became the cultural frame for economic actors and intrinsic parts of the

economic processes (Fligstein and Markowitz, 1993).

Page 11: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

8

The key question is now whether IFRS fit for all the varieties of capitalism or whether the

world would rather be better served by allowing alternative forms of capitalism to develop

accounting standards tailored to their needs.

By adopting and extending fair value accounting as much as possible, IFRS institutionalize

and spread the shareholder value paradigm in the form of financial reporting practices (e.g.

Jürgens et al., 2000; Börsch, 2004; Nölke and Perry, 2007; Widmer, 2011), and reinforce the

financialization process by shifting power from managers to markets. For instance, the

definition of fair value as a spot market price provided by IFRS 13 reduces the enterprise’s

voice in favor of that of the market, making reporting of assets, liabilities and income

independent of the manager’s influence (Barlev and Haddad 2003). When analyzing financial

statements under IFRS, readers are now exposed to the 'market’s voice'.

In this context, managers are forced to consider the firm as a portfolio of assets that must

constantly be reconfigured and rationalized in order to maximize shareholder value and to

demand that every corporate asset is put to its most profitable use as judged by market

benchmarks. Since capital markets tend to take a more short-term perspective on profit,

shareholder value orientation is likely to discourage long-term industrial strategies and to

threaten economic growth (e.g. Lazonick and O’Sullivan, 2000; Crotty, 2005; Nölke and

Perry, 2007; Milberg, 2008; Baud and Durand, 2012).

Along the same lines, financial reporting no more considers the value of the employment

of assets within the firm and, as a result, does not reflect the future cash flows that the assets

may in fact generate. Focusing on financial institutions, Allen and Carletti (2008) show that as

a consequence of fair value reporting, when liquidity plays an important role, as occurs in

financial crises, asset prices on the balance sheets reflect the amount of liquidity available,

rather than the actual assets’ future cash-flows. As a result, bank assets may fall below their

liabilities so that banks become insolvent, despite their capability to fully cover their

commitments if they were allowed to continue until the assets matured. This can start the

march into insolvency of institutions that would otherwise be solvent, and the insolvency or

near insolvency of the institutions that are forced to write down their assets gives rise to write-

downs in connected institutions with relevant contagion effects.

Page 12: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

9

Banks play a crucial role in European social market economies. Financial system in the

Continental Europe has always been highly bank-oriented (Bank of Italy, 2013)4, mainly

because the backbone of these economies is composed of small- and medium-sized

manufacturing firms, which encounter greater difficulties in accessing bond markets than big

corporates.

Given this crucial role, financial reporting for the banking system has particularly significant

consequences on real economy. The European Central Bank (2004), the Banque de France

(2008) and the International Monetary Fund (2009) have in fact raised several concerns on the

procyclical effects caused by fair value reporting on firms’ financing.

There is general agreement that during the recent financial turmoil, fair value reporting

caused a downward spiral in financial markets, which made the crisis more severe, amplifying

the credit-crunch (e.g. Persaud, 2008; Plantin et al., 2008; Allen and Carletti, 2012; Ronen,

2012). William Isaac (2010), former Chairman of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

(FDIC), considers fair value reporting the primary cause of the recent financial crisis. Plantin

et al. (2008) provide evidence that mark-to-market accounting injects an artificial volatility

into financial statements, which, rather than reflecting underlying fundamentals, is purely a

consequence of the accounting norms and distorts real decisions. Damage done by fair value

reporting is particularly severe for assets that are long-lived, illiquid and senior, which are

exactly the attributes of the key balance sheet items of banks and insurance companies.

Stockhammer (2012) also reports that excessive volatility in asset prices heightens systemic

risk and makes the economy prone to recurring crises. These results are in line with Cifuentes

et al. (2005), Khan (2009) and Bowen et al. (2010).

Freixas and Tsomocos (2004) show that fair value reporting worsens the role of banks as

institutions that smooth inter-temporal shocks. The weakening of bank balance sheets also

heightens concerns over the future courses of some markets, the health of banks and, more

broadly, the financial system, which results in several runs on banks (Gorton, 2008; Allen et

al., 2009b).

Given the key role of banks in the economy, financial distress in the banking system exert

disruptive effects on real economy and employment. With this respect, Dell’Ariccia et al.

(2008) report a correlation between bank distress and a decline in credit and GDP. Due to the

4 In 2012 bank debts represented 31.4% of liabilities in the Euro-zone, in contrast to 14.2% in the US

(Bank of Italy, 2013).

Page 13: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

10

financial system crisis in 2007-2009, economic activity declined significantly in the European

Union and unemployment rose dramatically. All in all, the recent crisis has been the worst

since the Great Depression (Allen et al., 2009b).

The choice of full historical accounting made by national regulators for domestic GAAP

prior to IFRS was consistent with the socio-economic context in the Continental Europe,

where banks were primarily concerned with ensuring the securities of their long-term loans to

enterprises, and therefore took a relatively cautious view of the future, acknowledging its

inherent uncertainty (Fiss and Zajac, 2004; Perry and Nölke, 2006). A prudent valuation of

assets reassured bankers that there was sufficient collateral to support their loans, and

employees that the firm was solvent and stable over time.

Evidence shows that rather conservative accounting standards based on the European

directives combined with stakeholder corporate governance and bank financing have allowed

companies in these countries to follow long-term strategies, such as investing heavily in

human resource development. This has been crucial for gaining and maintaining a competitive

advantage based on using highly skilled labor to produce high-quality, and often specialized,

products (e.g. Sally, 1995; Froud et al., 2000; Lazonick and O’Sullivan, 2000; Perry and

Nölke, 2006). Long-term strategies require stewardship, defined as accountability to all

stakeholders, to be a primary objective of financial reporting and historical cost to be the

relevant measurement basis (Whittington, 2008).

Conversely, IFRS in general and, more specifically, fair value reporting increase pressure

from short-termism, namely from the shareholders’ focus on quarterly results and short-range

returns on investment (Sally, 1995). Different research streams suggest that short-termism is

likely to have destabilizing effects on the social market economies in the long run (Perry and

Nölke, 2006). Stockhammer (2004) shows that short-termism accompanied by an excessive

focus on shareholder value reduce the rate of capital accumulation in the long term and

undermine economic growth. Under the pressure of shareholder value, firms tend not to

reinvest gains in their productive assets, but to distribute them to shareholders through

dividend payouts and share buy-back (Lazonick and O’ Sullivan, 2000; Crotty, 2005;

Milberg, 2008; Baud and Durand, 2012).

Short-termism also leads to more conflictual relationships between enterprise managers,

employees and other stakeholders. The IASB emphasizes the role of financial reporting in

Page 14: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

11

serving investors in capital markets. Investors in capital markets, however, are not the only

stakeholders of a firm (e.g. Holthausen and Watts, 2001; Whittington, 2008).

In many countries in Europe where a social market economy applies, shareholder wealth

maximization has never been the only – or even the primary – goal of the board of directors.

In Germany, for instance, firms are legally required to pursue the interests of parties beyond

the shareholders through a system of co-determination in which employees and shareholders

in large corporations sit together on the supervisory board of the company (Rieckers and

Spindler, 2004; Schmidt, 2004). Austria, Denmark, Sweden, France, and Luxembourg also

have systems of governance that require some kind of co-determination (Wymeersch, 1998;

Ginglinger et al., 2009). While the specific systems of governance in these countries vary

widely, the inclusion of parties beyond shareholders is a common concern. As a result,

workers play a prominent role and are regarded as important stakeholders in firms. For this

reason, it is common to refer to the Rhenish variety of capitalism also as 'stakeholder

capitalism'.

However, it is not just the legal systems in these countries that require firms to take

stakeholder concerns into account, but social convention as well. Yoshimori (1995), for

instance, documents that an overwhelming majority of managers in France and Germany feel

that a company exists for the interest of all stakeholders, whereas shareholder interest is the

priority for managers in the US and the UK.

In the Rhenish variety of capitalism, companies have been able to develop thanks to

consensual corporate governance arrangements. With this respect, research now reports

evidence of an unequivocal negative impact of shareholder value policies and short termism

on industrial relations (Van der Zwan 2014). Evidence also documents that the shareholder

value principle tends to make shareholders and managers rich to the detriment of workers

(Lazonick and O’Sullivan, 2000; Fligstein and Shin, 2004; Lin and Tomaskovic-Devey,

2013). Take as a whole, recent research presents a dramatic picture in which the pursuit of

shareholder value is directly linked to a decline in working conditions and a rise in social

inequality for large segments of the population (Van der Zwan, 2014).

Page 15: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

12

5. THE SOVEREIGNTY PARADOX

By adopting IFRS, the European Union, which is the second largest capital market in the

world, has delegated decisions on financial reporting regulation to a private body, the IASB,

on which it has no control (Sinclair, 1994; Cutler et al., 1999; Hall and Biersteker, 2002).

Indeed, the IASB represents one of the most fascinating cases of private authority in

international affairs. The IASB is a private, independent, British law organization, strongly

affected by the structural power of the private financial sector. If one looks at the IASB’s

composition, this is largely limited to members from the financial industry, as well as from

big auditing firms (Perry and Nölke, 2005; Chiapello and Medjad, 2009; Nöel et al., 2010;

Crawford et al., 2014).

Consistent with Gramsci’s notion of organic intellectuals (1971), expert knowledge is

always political because it is acquired in a particular social context, and it reflects the

political-economic structure and social relations that generate and reproduce that context. This

is also true, of course, for the IASB’s members. In fact, research provides specific evidence of

a close link between the increasing adoption of the fair value reporting and the financial

backgrounds of standards setters, who can use this body as a vehicle for institutionalizing its

own perspective on what value is, and how to measure it, within IFRS (Thistlethwaite, 2011;

Ramanna, 2013).

Furthermore, the IASB is dominated by representatives from Anglo-Saxon countries and

from international organizations whose priorities conform to stock-market based capitalism

(IASB, 2013). Many, for instance, highlight the pivotal role played by the SEC, operating

through the IOSCO (Crawford et al., 2014; see also Arnold, 2005; Martinez-Diaz, 2005;

Nölke and Perry, 2007; Botzem, 2008; Botzem and Quack, 2009; Nöel et al., 2010). IFRS 13,

which is virtually identical to its US counterpart SFAS 157, actually exemplifies how a US

discourse pervades the IASB and the accounting standards-setting agenda. As mentioned,

IFRS 13 is the result of a joint project conducted by the IASB together with the FASB with

the specific purpose of harmonizing US GAAP and IFRS, which however resulted in a

passive alignment of fair value definition, measurement and disclosure to FAS 157. This is a

key issue, given the potential economic and distributional consequences produced by financial

reporting.

Page 16: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

13

The same holds for EFRAG, which is a technical expert committee that provides advice to

the European Commission on whether IFRS meet the criteria for their endorsement in the

European Union. The EFRAG as well is a privately held and managed organization, which

operates in a manner very similar to the IASB, and is represented predominately by the

financial sector and big auditing firms (Perry and Nölke, 2005; Chiapello and Medjad, 2009;

Nöel et al., 2010; Crawford et al., 2014).

As a result, the European Union has no say in how things are done in both the standards-

setting and endorsement processes (Maystadt, 2013). As accounting serves not only to inform

investors, but also to set the limit for distributable profits, to elaborate public budgets and for

tax purposes, this is of course a key issue. There are different perspectives, such as the public

interest, which are key at the European level and should be more seriously considered also

with regard to financial reporting policies.

6. CONCLUDING REMARKS AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS

Proudhon (1846) used to say that "the accountant is the true economist" to highlight that

financial reporting is not a neutral, mechanical and objective process that simply measures the

economic facts pertaining to a firm. It is rather a powerful calculative practice that is

embedded in an institutional context and shapes social and economic processes.

Of course, a single set of global accounting standards would address the needs of

international investors who incur costs and time in translating financial statements. However,

financial reporting is not just a matter of investors, but a powerful practice that shapes social

and economic processes. It serves as a basis for determining a number of rights and therefore

affects a great variety of constituencies.

With this respect, academic research reports wide evidence that IFRS in general and, more

specifically, fair value reporting are likely to destabilize social market economies.

Social market economy is one of the founding principles of the European Union set out in

the Lisbon Treaty. There is a general agreement that the Treaty, in establishing social market

economy as a core value of the European Union, looked to the Germany and Scandinavian

Countries’ experience (Glossner 2014). In these countries, a consensual relationship between

labour and capital, a supporting role of the state, and the availability of patient capital

provided by the bank system or internally generated funds have been key in developing long-

Page 17: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

14

term perspective on economic decision-making, high skilled labour and quality products

based on incremental innovation, each at the basis of their economic successes.

As mentioned above, the choice of full historical accounting made by national regulators in

Continental Europe prior to IFRS adoption was consistent with this kind of environment,

where banks were primarily concerned with ensuring the securities of their long-term loans to

enterprises, and therefore took a relatively cautious view of the future, acknowledging its

inherent uncertainty (Fiss and Zajac, 2004; Perry and Nölke, 2006). Conservative accounting

standards based on the European directives combined with stakeholder corporate governance

and bank financing have also allowed companies to follow long-term strategies, such as

investing heavily in human resource development. This has been crucial for gaining and

maintaining a competitive advantage based on using highly skilled labor to produce high-

quality, and often specialized, products (e.g. Sally, 1995; Froud et al., 2000; Lazonick and

O’Sullivan, 2000; Perry and Nölke, 2006).

Mandating IFRS in the European Union goes in exactly the opposite direction. As outlined

previously, IFRS institutionalize and spread the shareholder value paradigm in the form of

financial reporting practices (e.g. Jürgens et al., 2000; Börsch, 2004; Nölke and Perry, 2007;

Widmer, 2011), and reinforce the financialization process by shifting power from managers to

markets. Fundamental reasons therefore question the consistency of Regulation 1606/2002,

mandating IFRS in the European Union, with the Lisbon Treaty. At the time the IFRS

Regulation was issued, the Lisbon Treaty had not yet been signed. Now, thanks to the Treaty,

we have a constitutional framework with which to analyse financial reporting policies.

Consistent with this view, this paper argues that some corrective actions should take place

in the standards-setting process. First of all, the European Union should restore the legitimacy

of the standards-setting process by bringing it back to democratic rules that guarantee the

representation of all the stakeholders involved in the economy and a strong role for the

European Parliament. While increasing privatization was the general trend in recent years in

international accounting standards setting, it is now time for this trend to be reversed and,

therefore, for a necessary backing of public actors (e.g. Kerwer 2007, Botzem 2008,

Bengstsson 2011).

By setting social market economy as a founding principle of the European Union, the Lisbon

Treaty shows that there is more than one way of doing business. Mandating a single set of

international financial reporting standards, designed to accommodate the needs of liberal

Page 18: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

15

stock market economies, for all the world is not neutral with respect to alternative forms of

capitalism, and risks doing harm to these varieties. Financial reporting is not a neutral,

mechanical and objective process that simply measures the economic facts pertaining to a

firm. It is rather a powerful calculative practice that is embedded in an institutional context

and shapes social and economic processes. As Miller and O’Leary (1987) note, accounting

normalizes and abstracts a "system of socio-political management".

The adoption of IFRS, which are shaped on stock market-based capitalism, runs the risk of

severely harming social market economies. In addition, recent events have raised several

doubts about unregulated free stock market capitalism being necessarily the best way to run

economy. The worldwide recession caused by the financial market crisis and excessive credit

expansion has indeed shown the fragility of stock market-based capitalism as an economic

and political process, highlighting the need for alternative way of doing business.

It is at time of great uncertainty and change that the advantages of variety can be

appreciated. Financial reporting should therefore be large enough to accommodate different

forms of capitalism and to let them compete on a level playing field. The optimal design of

financial reporting regulation should depend on the institutional characteristics of the political

and economic systems. The European directives, which regulated financial reporting for listed

companies prior to IFRS adoption, have been successful in this respect. The European

directives provided the same basic principles and a set of minimum accounting rules, but left

open to member states some options that could be implemented in national law according to

their diverse national historical and economic backgrounds, cultures and legislation. Given

such flexibility, the implementation of the accounting directives into national law differed

from country to country. For instance, countries could choose between historical cost and fair

value for evaluating certain assets. Countries from the Continental European Union required

full historical cost accounting, while the United Kingdom, which is closer to stock market-

based capitalism, allowed the use of fair value for some items.

The Lisbon Treaty provides a political construct of the European Union based on a

federalist approach to integration. Federalism grounds on a pluralist conception and is

conceived as a way to unify different peoples for important but limited purposes, not as a way

to destroy their political identities.

The European directives have been able to conjugate unity and diversity effectively,

guaranteeing the harmonization of financial disclosure, yet allowing countries to take into

Page 19: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

16

accounts the specific characteristics of their socio-economic settings. A single set of global

financial reporting standards, moreover tailored on the needs of stock market-based

capitalism, instead represents a significant monopoly power that harms exiting variety of

capitalism and prevents alternative forms from evolving. According to the Lisbon Treaty, the

European Union must work in order to pursue its objective of realizing a social market

economy. The European Union must therefore exert every effort and use all the available

means to reach this goal, including financial reporting regulation.

Page 20: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

17

REFERENCES

Albert M. Capitalism against capitalism. London: Whurr; 1993

Allen F, Carletti E. Should financial institutions mark to market? Banque de France, Financial

Stability Review 2008; 12: 1-6.

Allen F, Carletti E, Marquez R. Stakeholder capitalism, corporate governance and firm value.

Working Paper Wharton Financial Institutions Center; 2009(a).

Allen F, Carletti E, Babus A. Financial crises: theory and evidence. Annual Review of Financial

Economics 2009(b); 1: 97-116.

Andor L. Building a social market economy in the European Union. Press Releases Database

Speech/11/965; 2011.

Arnold P. Disciplining domestic regulation: the world trade organization and the market for

professional services. Accounting Organizations and Society 2005; 30 (4): 299–330.

Banque de France. Financial Stability Review 2008. https://www.banque-

france.fr/en/publications/financial-stability-review.html.

Bank of Italy. Annual Report 2013. www.bancaditalia.it.

Barlev B, Haddad JR. Fair value accounting and the management of the firm. Critical

Perspectives on Accounting 2003; 14(4): 383-415.

Barth ME, Beaver WH, Landsman WR. The relevance of the value relevance literature for

financial accounting standard setting: another view. Journal of Accounting and Economics

2001; 31(1): 77-104.

Baud C, Durand C. Financialization, globalization and the making of profits by leading retailers.

Socio-Economic Review 2012; 10 (2): 241–266.

Bengtsson E. Repoliticalization of accounting standard setting—The IASB, the EU and the

global financial crisis. Critical Perspectives on Accounting 2011; 22(6): 567– 580.

Börsch A. Globalisation, shareholder value, restructuring: the (non)-transformation of Siemens.

New Political Economy 2004; 9(3): 365-387.

Botzem S. Transnational expert-driven standardisation – accountancy governance from a

professional point of view. In Graz JC, Nölke A (Eds.) Transnational private governance and

its limits. London: Routledge; 2008.

Botzem S, Quack S. (No) Limits to Anglo-American accounting? Reconstructing the history of

the International Accounting Standards Committee: a review article. Accounting,

Organizations and Society 2009; 34(8): 988–998.

Page 21: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

18

Bowen RM, Khan U, Rajgopal S. The economic consequences of relaxing fair value accounting

and impairment rules on banks during the financial crisis of 2008-2009. Working paper; 2010

[13 September].

Chiapello E, Medjad K. An unprecedented privatisation of mandatory standard-setting: the case

of European accounting policy. Critical Perspectives on Accounting 2009; 20 (4): 448-468.

Cifuentes R, Hyun SS, Ferrucci G. Liquidity risk and contagion. Journal of the European

Economic Association 2005; 3(2-3): 556-566.

Crawford L, Ferguson J, Helliar CV, Power DM. Control over accounting standards within the

European Union: the political controversy surrounding the adoption of IFRS 8. Critical

Perspectives on Accounting 2014; 25(4-5): 304-318.

Crotty J. The neoliberal paradox: the impact of destructive product market competition and

‘modern’ financial markets on nonfinancial corporation performance in the neoliberal era. In

Epstein G (Ed.) Financialization and the World Economy. London: Edward Elgar Publishing;

2005.

Cutler AC, Haufler V, Porter T. Private authority and international affairs. In Cutler AC, Haufler

V, Porter T (Eds.) Private authority and international affairs. Albany, NY: State University of

New York Press; 1999.

Dell'Ariccia G, Detragiache E, Rajan R. The real effect of banking crises. Journal of Financial

Intermediation 2008; 17(1): 89-112.

Drezner D. All politics is global: explaining international regulatory regimes. Princeton

University Press; 2007.

Epstein GA. Financialization and the world economy. Cheltenham Glos, UK: Edward Elgar;

2005.

Eucken W. Unser zeitalter der Misserfolge. Tübingen; 1951.

Eucken W. Grundsätze der wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen; 1990.

Eucken W. 1952/2004. Grundasetze der wirtschaftspolitik. 7th edition. Tübingen.

European Central Bank. The impact of fair value accounting on the European banking sector.

Monthly Bullettin 2004; February: 70-81.

European Commission. Financial reporting obligations for limited liability companies

(Accounting Directive). Memo/13/540 2013(a) [12 June].

Page 22: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

19

European Commission. Commissioner Barnier welcomes European Parliament vote on the

Accounting and Transparency Directives (including country by country reporting).

Memo/13/546 2013(b) [12 June].

Fiss P, Zajac E. The diffusion of ideas over contested terrain: the (non) adoption of a shareholder

value orientation among German firms. Administrative Science Quarterly 2004; 49(4): 501-

534.

Fligstein N. The transformation of corporate control. Cambridge: Harvard University Press;

1990.

Fligstein N, Markowitz L. Financial reorganization of American corporations in the 1980s. In

Wilson WJ (Ed.) Sociology and the public agenda. Newbury Park: Sage; 1993.

Fligstein N, Shin T. The shareholder value society: changes in working conditions and inequality

in the U.S., 1975–2000. In Neckerman K (Ed.) Social Inequality. New York: Russell Sage

Foundation; 2004.

Freixas X, Tsomocos D. Book vs. Fair value accounting in banking and intertemporal

smoothing. Working paper Pompeu Fabra University and Oxford University; 2004.

Froud J, Haslam C, Sukhdev J, Williams K. Shareholder value and financialization: consultancy

promises, management moves. Economy and Society 2000; 29(1): 80-110.

Gil-Robles JM. The need for a social market economy. The Euro Atlantic Union Review 2014;

1(0): 13-18.

Ginglinger E, Megginson W, Waxin T. Employee ownership, board representation, and

corporate financial policies. Working paper University of Oklahoma; 2009.

Glossner CL. The social market economy. Incipiency and topicality of an economic and social

policy for a European community. The Euro Atlantic Union Review 2014; 1(0): 53-62.

Gorton G. The Panic of 2007. Jackson Hole Conference Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of

Kansas City; 2008.

Gramsci A. The intellectuals. Selections from the Prison Notebooks. New York: International

Publisher; 1971.

Hall PA, Soskice D. Varieties of capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2001.

Hall RB, Biersteker TJ. The emergence of private authority in global governance. Cambridge

University Press; 2002.

Holthausen RW, Watts RL. The relevance of the value-relevance literature for financial

accounting standard setting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 2001; 31(1): 3-75.

Page 23: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

20

IASB. IFRS for SMEs; 2009.

IASB. Conceptual framework for financial reporting; 2010.

IFRS Foundation. www.ifrs.org; 2013.

Isaac WM. Why SEC accounting rules need more oversight.

http//www.forbes.com/2010/05/10/bob-corker-sec-accounting-rlues-amendment-opinions-

contributors-william-isaac.html?partner+email; 2010.

International Monetary Fund. Procyclicality and fair value accounting. Working Paper Series;

2009: 39.

Jensen MC, Meckling WH. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and

ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 1976; 3(4): 305-360.

Jordan CE, Clark SJ, and Pate GR. The debate over fair value reporting: Fact or fiction? using

Benford's Law to find answers. CPA Journal 2013; 83 (2): 46-51.

Jürgens J, Naumann K, Rupp J. Shareholder value in an adverse environment: the German case.

Economy & Society 2000; 29(1):54-79.

Kerwer D. How accountable is the ‘International Accounting Standards Board’? In paper

prepared for the 6th SGIR Pan-European Conference in International Relations; 2007.

Khan U. Does fair value accounting contribute to systemic risk in the banking industry? Working

paper Columbia University; 2009.

Lazonick W, O’Sullivan M. Maximizing shareholder value: a new ideology for corporate

governance. Economy and Society 2000; 29(1): 13-35.

Lin K-H, Tomaskovic-Devey D. Financialization and U.S. income inequality, 1970–2008.

American Journal of Sociology 2013; 118(5): 1284–1329.

MacKenzie D. An engine, not a camera. How financial models shape markets. Cambridge: MIT

Press; 2008.

Marktanner M. The social market economy – Assembled in Germany, not made in Germany!

The Euro Atlantic Union Review 2014; 1(0): 77-113.

Martinez-Diaz L. Strategic experts and improvising regulators: explaining the IASC's rise to

global influence, 1973-2001. Business and Politics 2005; 7(3): 1-28.

Maystadt P. Should IFRS standards be more “European”? Mission to reinforce the EU’s

contribution to the development of international accounting standards. Report to the European

Commission; 2013.

Page 24: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

21

Milberg W. Shifting sources and uses of profits: sustainingUS financialization with global value

chains. Economy and Society 2008; 37(3): 420–451.

Miller T, O’Leary T. Accounting and the construction of the governable person. Accounting,

Organizations and Society 1987; 12(3): 235–265.

Modigliani F, Miller MH. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment.

American Economic Review 1958; 48(3): 261-297.

Müller-Armack A. Wirtschaftsordnung und wirtschaftspolitik. Studien und konzepte zur sozialen

marktwirtschaft und zur europäischen integration. Beiträge zur Wirtschaftspolitik 1966; 4.

Noël C, Ayayi AG, Blum V. The European Union’s accounting policy analyzed from an ethical

perspective: the case of petroleum resources, prospecting and evaluation. Critical Perspectives

on Accounting 2010; 21(4): 329–341.

Nölke A, Perry J. The power of transnational private governance: financialization and the IASB.

Business and Politics 2007; 9(3): 1-25.

Perry J, Nölke A. International Accounting Standards setting: a network approach. Business and

Politics 2005; 7(3): 1-34.

Perry J, Nölke A. The political economy of International Accounting Standards. Review of

International Political Economy 2006; 13(4): 559-586.

Persaud AD. Regulation, valuation and systemic liquidity. Banque de France, Financial Stability

Review 2008; 12: 75-83.

Plantin G, Sapra H, Hyun SS. Marking-to-market: panacea or Pandora’s box. Journal of

Accounting Research 2008; 46(2): 435-460.

Pöttering H-G. A stable economic system for Europe. The Euro Atlantic Union Review 2014;

1(0): 19-22.

Proudhon PJ. Système des contradictions économiques ou Philosophie de la misère. Paris:

Guillaumin et cie; 1846.

Ramanna K. Why “Fair value” is the rule. Harvard Business Review 2013; 91(3): 99-101.

Rieckers O, Spindler G. Corporate governance: legal aspects. In Krahnen J, Schmidt R (Eds.)

The German financial system. Oxford University Press; 2004.

Ronen J. What do FAS 157 ‘Fair values’ really measure: value or risk? Accounting

Perspectives 2012; 11(3): 149-164.

Röpke W. Grundfragen rationeller Wirtschaftspolitik. Zeitschrift für schweizer statistik &

volkswirtschaft 1941; 1: 112.

Page 25: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

22

Röpke W. Civitas Humana – Grundfragen der Gesellschafts-und Wirtschaftsordnung. Erlenbach-

Zurich; 1944.

Röpke W. The german question. London; 1946.

Röpke W. The intellectuals and “Capitalism”. In Röpke W (Ed.) Against the tide. Chicago; 1969.

Available at http://library.mises.org/books/Wilhelm%20Ropke/Against%20the%20Tide.pdf

(april 14, 2013).

Russell B. Introduction to mathematical philosophy. London: George Allen & Unwin; 1919.

Reprinted New York: Dover; 1993.

Rüstow A. 1932. Liberal intervention. In Stuetzel W, Watrin C, Willgerodt H, Hohmann K,

Wuensche HF (Eds.) Standard texts on the social market economy, two centuries of

discussion. Stuttgart; 1982.

Rüstow A. Wirtscheft als dienerin der menschlichkeit. Was wichtiger ist als wirtschaft, vorträge

auf der fünfzehnten tagung der aktionsgemeinschaft soziale marktwirtschaft am 29 Juni 1960

in Bad Godesberg (Aktionsgemeinschaft Soziale Marktwirtschaft Tagungsprotokoll; 15).

Ludwigsburg: 1960: 7–16.

Sally R. States and firms: multinational enterprises in institutional competition. London:

Routledge; 1995.

Schmidt R. Corporate governance in Germany: an economic perspective. In Krahnen J, Schmidt

R (Ed.) The German financial system. Oxford University Press; 2004.

Simmons B. The international politics of harmonization: the case of capital market regulation.

International Organization 2001; 55(3): 589–620.

Sinclair TJ. Between state and market: hegemony and institutions of collective action under

condition of international capital mobility. Policy sciences 1994; 27(4): 447-466.

Spicka M. Selling the economic miracle: reconstruction and politics in West Germany. Berghahn

Books; 2007.

Stockhammer E. Financialization and the slowdown of accumulation. Cambridge Journal of

Economics 2004; 28(5): 719-741.

Stockhammer E. Financialization, income distribution and the crisis’, Investigacion Economica

2012; LXXI (279): 39–70.

Thistlethwaite J. Counting the environment: the environmental implications of International

Accounting Standards. Global Environmental Politics 2011; 11(2): 75-97.

Page 26: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

23

Van der Zwan N. Making sense of financialization. Socio-Economic Review 2014; 12(1): 99-

129.

Whittington G. Fair value and the IASB/FASB conceptual framework project: a different view.

Abacus 2008; 44(2): 139-16.

Widmer F. Institutional investors, corporate elites and the building of a market for corporate

control. Socio-Economic Review 2011; 9(4): 671-697.

Wymeersch E. A status report on corporate governance rules and practices in some continental

European states. In Hopt K, Kanda H, Roe M, Wymeersch E, Prigge S (Eds.) Comparative

corporate governance: the state of the art and emerging research. Oxford: Clarendon Press;

1998.

Yoshimori M. Whose company is it? The concept of the corporation in Japan and the West.

Long Range Planning 1995; 28(4): 33-44.

Page 27: Standardizing Financial Reporting Regulation

Mario Einaudi Center for International Studies 170 Uris Hall Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853-7601

Phone: 607-255-6370 Fax: 607-254-5000 [email protected] www.einaudi.cornell.edu