supply-side reforms to oil and gas production on federal …supply-side reforms to oil and gas...

72
Supply-Side Reforms to Oil and Gas Production on Federal Lands Modeling the Implications for Climate Emissions, Revenues, and Production Shifts Brian Prest Working Paper 20-16 September 2020

Upload: others

Post on 18-Feb-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Supply-Side Reforms to Oil and Gas Production on Federal LandsModeling the Implications for Climate Emissions, Revenues, and Production Shifts

    Brian Prest

    Working Paper 20-16 September 2020

  • Resources for the Future i

    About the Author Brian Prest is a fellow at Resources for the Future specializing in climate change, electricity markets, and oil and gas economics. Prest uses economic theory and econometric models to improve energy and environmental policies by assessing their impacts on markets and pollution outcomes. His recent work includes evaluating the impacts of federal tax credits for coal use. He is also working to establish an empirical basis for determining discount rates used in the social cost of carbon. His past work includes econometric analysis of the US oil and gas industry, understanding the economic effects of rising temperatures, modeling the market dynamics of climate change policy under policy uncertainty, and assessing household responses to time-varying electricity pricing. His work has appeared in the Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, Energy Economics, and The Energy Journal.

    Prior to joining RFF, Prest earned his PhD at Duke University and previously worked in both the public and private sectors. At the Congressional Budget Office, he developed economic models of various energy sectors to analyze the effects of proposed legislation, including the 2009 Waxman-Markey cap-and-trade bill and related Clean Electricity Standards. At NERA Economic Consulting, he conducted electricity market modeling, project valuation, and discounted cash flow analysis of various infrastructure investments in the United States, Latin America, Europe, Africa, and Southeast Asia, with a focus on the power sector.

  • Insert title here on Master A ii

    About RFFResources for the Future (RFF) is an independent, nonprofit research institution in Washington, DC. Its mission is to improve environmental, energy, and natural resource decisions through impartial economic research and policy engagement. RFF is committed to being the most widely trusted source of research insights and policy solutions leading to a healthy environment and a thriving economy.

    The views expressed here are those of the individual authors and may differ from those of other RFF experts, its officers, or its directors.

    Sharing Our WorkOur work is available for sharing and adaptation under an Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0) license. You can copy and redistribute our material in any medium or format; you must give appropriate credit, provide a link to the license, and indicate if changes were made, and you may not apply additional restrictions. You may do so in any reasonable manner, but not in any way that suggests the licensor endorses you or your use. You may not use the material for commercial purposes. If you remix, transform, or build upon the material, you may not distribute the modified material. For more information, visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/.

    https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/

  • Supply-Side Reforms to Oil and Gas Production on

    Federal Lands: Modeling the Implications for Climate

    Emissions, Revenues, and Production Shifts

    Brian C. Prest ∗

    September 13, 2020

    ∗Resources for the Future, 1616 P St NW, Washington, DC 20036. [email protected]. I am grateful to

    The Wilderness Society for financial support and Enverus for the data used in this study. I have no

    relevant or material financial interests related to the research described in this paper.

    mailto:[email protected]

  • Supply-Side Reforms to Oil and Gas Production on Federal

    Lands: Modeling the Implications for Climate Emissions,

    Revenues, and Production Shifts

    Abstract

    Over the last decade, 25 percent of US fossil fuel production came from lands

    and waters directly managed by the federal government, and the resulting emis-

    sions are equivalent to nearly a quarter of all US greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.

    Policy reforms targeting oil and gas production on federal lands have increasingly

    attracted attention as an option to reduce emissions. Yet such policies are con-

    troversial, in part due to concerns of “leakage,” in which reduced oil and gas pro-

    duction on federal lands shifts to other producers. Accordingly, this paper models

    the effects of three proposed policy reforms for federal oil and gas production:

    raising royalty rates, carbon “adders” (fees) that internalize GHG externalities,

    and a moratorium on new leasing. The model, which accounts for unprecedented

    declines in oil prices associated with COVID-19, shows that raising royalty rates

    has negligible effects on emissions but could raise an additional $1–$3 billion an-

    nually. A moratorium reduces emissions from federal lands by an estimated 314

    million metric tons of carbon dioxide equivalent (MMTCO2e) per year on aver-

    age from 2020–2050 but also reduces royalty revenues by $5–$6 billion annually.

    A carbon adder achieves two-thirds of the emissions reductions of a moratorium

    (216 MMTCO2e annually from federal lands) and also raises $7 billion annually.

    Although those emissions reductions are substantial, production shifts are also

    large, implying smaller net emissions reductions of 85 to 147 MMTCO2e and 58

    to 100 MMTCO2e annually for a moratorium and carbon adder, respectively. De-

    spite sizable reductions, none of these policies would achieve the goal of net-zero

    emissions from oil and gas on federal lands by 2040, as endorsed in the June 2020

    report from the House Select Committee on the Climate Crisis. Achieving that

    ambitious goal would therefore require modifying existing leases and/or additional

    investments in carbon sequestration and renewable energy on federal lands.

    Keywords: oil, gas, public lands, public finance, climate policy, emissions, leakage,

    instrument choice

  • 1 Introduction

    Over the last decade, 25 percent of US fossil fuel production came from lands and waters

    directly managed by the federal government, and the resulting emissions are equivalent

    to nearly a quarter of all US greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Policy reforms target-

    ing oil and gas production on federal lands have increasingly attracted attention as an

    option to reduce emissions. However, disagreement remains, even among supporters

    of climate policy, about the effectiveness of such policies. Critics argue that they are

    undermined by emissions “leakage”—in which reduced fossil fuel production (and hence

    emissions) in one region is offset by increased production and emissions in other regions.

    Proponents argue that although leakage may reduce the efficacy of a policy, the net

    effect is unlikely to be zero and that alternative, demand-side approaches can similarly

    lead to leakage. Further, proponents argue, supply-side policies are simply more feasi-

    ble to implement than demand-side policies for various political or institutional reasons

    (Green and Denniss 2018). Indeed, federal coal and offshore oil and gas leasing was tem-

    porarily suspended by the Obama administration, and a permanent suspension has been

    endorsed by 2020 Democratic presidential candidate Joe Biden. Although such policies

    are not first best from an economic perspective, economists are increasingly receptive

    to incorporating political feasibility constraints into their assessments of second-best

    policies (Goulder 2020).

    Historically, the US government has leased federal lands1 to private firms that then

    extract and sell federally owned resources. In exchange for the right to extract those

    resources, firms pay the federal government royalties (a share of gross revenues, typically

    12.5 to 18.75 percent), along with other payments, including bonus bids and rental pay-

    ments. These revenues are shared between the states and the federal government. The

    1Henceforth, I use the term “federal lands” as shorthand for both lands and waters where the mineralrights are owned by the federal government. This does not include Native American lands because therevenues from mineral extraction on those lands accrue to the relevant tribes and not to the federalgovernment.

    1

  • federal share is used both as an unrestricted revenue stream and to fund land and water

    conservation and water reclamation projects. Because the US federal government owns

    large swaths of resource-rich land, fossil fuel production on federal land is a significant

    contributor to greenhouse gas emissions. In particular, carbon emissions associated with

    fossil fuels produced from federal lands represent 24 percent of US CO2 emissions (Mer-

    rill et al. 2018), making it a large target for policymakers seeking to reduce emissions.

    Further, the executive branch has broad authority under existing law to expand or re-

    strict leasing for fossil fuel development on federal lands, without the need for legislative

    action (Leshy 2019; Beaudreau, Schneider and Marnitz 2019).

    Recent policy proposals that would reduce oil and gas development on federal lands

    include increased royalty rates, carbon adders to internalize climate externalities, and a

    leasing moratorium. Each policy was previously considered in context of the coal leasing

    program during the Obama administration (CEA 2016; Gillingham et al. 2016; Krupnick

    et al. 2016; Gillingham and Stock 2016). Ultimately, in 2016, the Obama administration

    ordered a temporary moratorium on coal leasing while the program underwent a review.

    The Trump administration revoked this moratorium and terminated the review.

    In the years since, the US coal industry has been in decline, shifting the portfolio of

    fossil fuel production on federal lands away from coal and toward oil and gas. According

    to data from the Department of the Interior, although federal coal production has fallen

    by nearly 30 percent from 2014 to 2019, federal oil production has actually risen by

    about 40 percent.2 As a result, greenhouse gas emissions associated with oil and gas

    produced on federal lands now exceed those associated with coal from those lands.3

    This decline of coal and rise of oil and gas on federal lands has drawn attention to

    reforming the federal oil and gas leasing program. For example, the majority staff of

    the US House of Representatives’ Select Committee on the Climate Crisis (HSCCC)

    2At the same time, federal natural gas production has declined by a relatively modest 10 percent.These data can be found at https://revenuedata.doi.gov/downloads/production-by-month/.

    3This is based on the same data from the Department of the Interior, applying the emissions factorsdiscussed in section 2.2.6 for oil and gas and an emissions factor of 1.87 tCO2e per short ton for coal.

    2

    https://revenuedata.doi.gov/downloads/production-by-month/

  • released a report (HSCCC 2020) that proposed a series of policies that aim to reach net-

    zero greenhouse gas emissions on federal lands by 2040, including higher royalty rates and

    a moratorium. Several pieces of legislation have been introduced that would implement

    these proposals (H.R. 4364, S. 3330, H.R. 5186, S. 2906, and H.R. 5435). Many of

    these changes could also be implemented through unilateral executive action by a future

    administration. Indeed, every 2020 Democratic presidential candidate endorsed some

    form of restrictions on federal oil and gas leasing, including a moratorium.

    The HSCCC report also expresses more policy goals than simply reducing emissions.

    On the one hand, the report frames these public lands policies as part of a broader climate

    policy effort to reduce emissions, in this case by directly reducing oil and gas production.4

    On the other hand, the report expresses a desire to raise additional royalty revenues for

    the communities most affected by a reduction in fossil fuel extraction. That revenue

    could also be used for other purposes, such as investing in research and development of

    clean energy or reducing distortionary taxes. These dual goals of reducing emissions and

    raising revenues create a tension that affects policy design. For example, a moratorium

    may substantially reduce emissions, but it will also reduce revenues as production falls.

    Although there is renewed interest in supply-side restrictions on federal oil and gas

    production, there is a dearth of economic research that speaks to how effective these

    policies would be. Gerarden, Reeder and Stock (2020) suggest that reducing federal coal

    production by charging carbon adders—fees based on the marginal damages of carbon

    emissions—could be effective at reducing emissions. But this result for the coal industry

    4Although a key focus of these policies is greenhouse gas emissions, reducing oil and gas developmenton federal lands also has other important environmental and social benefits. This includes opening uppublic lands to alternative uses, such as conservation, preservation of biodiversity, renewable energydevelopment, and/or recreation. Although precluding oil and gas development also has economic costs,alternative land uses also yield economic benefits, such as for industries associated with recreation ortourism. For example, Walls, Lee and Ashenfarb (2020) find that designating public lands as nationalmonuments increased the growth of local business establishments. However, because reducing emissionsis the primary stated environmental goal for these policies, I focus on that as a measure of a policy’senvironmental effects. Because the emissions effects of these policies are strongly linked to the land useeffects, the size of the emissions impacts is also an approximate indicator for the size of these otherbenefits. However, I do not estimate the magnitude of these other benefits, nor do I estimate theeconomic costs of the proposed policies.

    3

  • does not necessarily extend to oil and gas. The economics of oil and gas are simply very

    different from that of coal. For one, oil and gas are less carbon intensive than coal. For

    another, oil markets are much more globally linked than coal, largely due to relatively

    low transportation costs. The market for US-produced gas is also increasingly global,

    with the recent rapid construction of liquefied natural gas export facilities. Another

    difference is that a much smaller share of US oil and gas production comes from federal

    land (22 percent of oil and 12 percent of gas in 2019) compared to coal (about 40

    percent). This distinction is only growing with the rise of oil and gas production from

    shale formations, which are predominantly located on state and private land. Finally,

    oil and gas production from shale is more price responsive than conventional production

    (Newell, Prest and Vissing 2019; Newell and Prest 2019). All of these factors suggest

    strong potential for leakage of production from federal lands to state, private, and tribal

    lands, in addition to foreign producers.

    One recent study (Erickson and Lazarus 2018) estimated the impacts of ending new

    federal leasing of oil and coal (but not gas) in a static constant-elasticity model drawing

    on supply elasticity estimates from the gray literature. That study estimated that a

    moratorium on all new federal fossil fuel leasing could reduce global CO2 emissions by

    280 million tons per year by 2030. However, most of this reduction was estimated to come

    from reduced coal consumption, with only about 14 percent (39 million tons) estimated

    to come from oil. This estimate may understate long-run effects however because it is

    based on a static model for the year 2030. But the effects of changing federal leasing

    policies generally occur more than a decade into the future, suggesting larger effects

    beyond 2030. Federal oil and gas leases typically have a duration of 10 years, and oil

    and gas firms typically do not develop these leases until the eighth, ninth, or tenth year,

    that is, just prior to expiration (CBO 2016). Further, once a well is drilled, standard

    leasing provisions extend the duration indefinitely so long as the well is producing oil

    or gas. This means that wells drilled on federal leases continue to produce for decades

    4

  • after the initial 10 year term. As a result, changes in federal leasing policy today (say

    in 2020) primarily affect production more than a decade into the future (after 2030),

    meaning their impacts are likely to be much larger beyond a 10 year period. For the

    same reason, CBO estimated minor revenue effects from leasing reform but emphasized

    that their small estimates primarily reflected their use of CBO’s standard 10 year budget

    window and noted that the effects could be substantially larger after that point (CBO

    2016).

    These aforementioned two studies represent the two main efforts in the literature

    to estimate the effects of reforming federal oil and gas leasing policies on greenhouse

    gas emissions (Erickson and Lazarus 2018) or revenues (CBO 2016), highlighting the

    extremely limited literature on the topic.5

    This paper fills that gap in the literature by building on and extending the econo-

    metric oil and gas supply methods developed in Newell, Prest and Vissing (2019) and

    Newell and Prest (2019) to model the effects of several proposals that would reform leas-

    ing policy regarding oil and gas production from US federal lands. I consider the three

    key policy approaches that have recently attracted attention: (1) raising federal royalty

    rates by 6.25 to 12.5 percentage points (from their current levels of 12.5 percent onshore

    and typically 18.75 percent offshore6), (2) charging carbon adders equal to the social

    cost of carbon of about $50 per ton of CO2 to internalize the externalities of greenhouse

    gas emissions, or (3) establishing a complete moratorium on all new oil and gas leasing.

    I focus on these three policies because they have each attracted attention for potential

    reform. The Department of the Interior already charges royalty rates and has clear au-

    thority to change them. Further, proponents of this approach argue that federal onshore

    5U.S. Government Accountability Office (2017) also cites a draft paper (Enegis, LLC 2011) studyingthe effects of raising royalty rates on revenues, but it does not appear to be publicly available anywhere.

    6Royalty rates on offshore wells depend on water depth. In recent years, offshore oil and gas de-velopment has increasingly focused on deepwater reservoirs, where the royalty rate is 18.75 percent.Although the statutory rates are typically 12.5 and 18.75 percent, these rates are often subject to al-lowances, deductions, and waivers that, under the current system, can reduce effective rates below thestatutory ones. See U.S. Government Accountability Office (2017).

    5

  • royalty rates are very low (12.5 percent) relative to market rates typically charged on

    state and private lands (often 18.75 to 25 percent). Raising royalty rates would ensure

    that taxpayers receive returns on public resources commensurate with market rates. I

    model a carbon adder for two reasons: first, it is an economically appealing approach

    that approximates Pigouvian-style taxation for covered producers, and second, it dif-

    ferentially disincentivizes oil versus gas production (in accordance with their different

    carbon intensities), in contrast to royalty rates, which disincentivize oil and gas equally.

    The carbon adder is set based on the social cost of carbon (SCC) as estimated by the

    Interagency Working Group in 2016, which equals approximately $50 per ton in 2020

    and rises at 2 percent annually in real terms.7 Finally, I model a moratorium because

    this approach has been used repeatedly in recent decades on a temporary basis and

    because policymakers are now considering a permanent one. For example, Joe Biden’s

    2020 presidential campaign proposed some form of each of these policies, including “ban-

    ning new oil and gas permitting on public lands and waters [and] modifying royalties

    to account for climate costs.”8 I also model different variants and combinations of these

    policies (e.g., increasing the royalty rate and charging carbon adders) to illustrate their

    potential interactions.

    First, I econometrically estimate how US drilling activity responds to oil and gas

    prices, allowing for heterogeneous responses by type of well (e.g., oil-directed versus gas-

    directed drilling, wells on federal versus nonfederal land). Then, I use these estimates to

    simulate how drilling activity translates into oil and gas production over time, based on

    the path of oil and gas prices (net of royalties and carbon charges). The model accounts

    for key structural features of oil and gas markets, including both own-price and cross-

    price responses (e.g., natural gas production depends on both gas prices and oil prices),

    complementarities in production (such as so-called “associated gas” that is produced

    7This reflects the estimate from the Interagency Working Group on the Social Cost of Carbon (IWG2016), after adjusting for inflation to 2020 dollars. The SCC values estimated by the IWG rise atapproximately 2 percent per year.

    8See https://joebiden.com/climate-plan/, last accessed September 8, 2020.

    6

    https://joebiden.com/climate-plan/

  • alongside oil in oil-directed wells; see, e.g., Gilbert and Roberts 2020), and leakage (e.g.,

    substitution from federal to nonfederal production).

    Unlike work from the literature on the topic, the model extends beyond 2030. This

    captures the long time lags between federal policy changes and realized production im-

    pacts. This lag occurs because oil and gas wells drilled prior to a change in leasing policy

    are unaffected by the policy but nonetheless may produce for many decades to come.

    The model accurately reflects that, once drilled, a well may produce indefinitely so long

    as it is capable of yielding oil or gas. The model also reflects that even after a change

    in policy regarding new leases (including a moratorium), some wells may continue to be

    drilled on leases that were issued before the policy change but had not yet been drilled.

    After the primary terms of that stock of existing leases expire (say, after 10 years, as-

    suming no extensions), policy changes to newly issued leases affect all new wells. Before

    that point, only a fraction of newly drilled federal wells are covered by changes in lease

    terms.9

    Finally, the model is calibrated using data that include the recent shale boom that

    has increased the price responsiveness of oil and gas supply. I estimate key model

    parameters using a large well-level dataset on more than one million individual oil and

    gas wells in the United States, representing nearly all operating wells in the country. The

    estimated model is then used to simulate the effects of different sets of federal leasing

    policies on oil and gas prices, production, emissions, and revenues from royalties and

    carbon adders. The model accounts for endogenous production responses from non-US

    foreign suppliers through a reduced form relationship based on modeling results from the

    International Energy Agency. Importantly, and unlike other studies, the model accounts

    9As described in more detail in section 2.2.6, I assume that the fraction of newly drilled federalwells that is covered by each policy phases in linearly over a 10-year period, where 10 years is thetypical statutory length of federal leases. This simplifying assumption is analogous to the assumptionin Gerarden, Reeder and Stock (2020). This implicitly assumes that no lease extensions are grantedand that existing lease sales are scheduled to expire in a uniform fashion over the next 10 years. Theresults are not very sensitive to this assumption, as discussed in section 2.2.6, affecting cumulativefederal emissions by about ±8 percent at the most.

    7

  • for the dramatic decline in oil prices in 2020 associated with the COVID-19 pandemic

    and the Russia-Saudi price war.

    Figure 1: Policy Impacts on Emissions and Revenues, Annual Average 2020–2050, byDemand Elasticity Assumption

    Note: “Nonfederal” includes both domestic and foreign producers.

    The results demonstrate stark differences in the effects of the three policies on the

    key outcomes of emissions and revenues. Figure 1 summarizes the results for three key

    policies: a 25 percent royalty rate, a $50 carbon adder, and a moratorium. Raising

    royalty rates at the levels commonly proposed would have little effect on federal oil

    and gas production and hence relatively small effects on emissions associated with that

    production, around 37 million tons of CO2e (MMTCO2e) annually on average from

    federal lands,10 but could raise as much as $3 billion in additional royalty revenues per

    10The emissions “from federal lands” refers to the CO2e emissions “embodied” in the oil and gasproduced—that is, these ultimately result from the combustion of the oil and gas produced on federallands. This is consistent with the terminology used in Merrill et al. (2018). These emissions technically

    8

  • year.11 At the other extreme, a moratorium would lead to substantial reductions in

    emissions from federal oil and gas production (an estimated 314 MMTCO2e annually on

    average from federal lands) but at the loss of $5–$6 billion of royalty revenues per year.

    A “middle ground” policy of carbon adders (which would internalize the externalities

    of greenhouse gas emissions for federal production) would achieve about two-thirds of

    the emissions reductions of a moratorium (216 versus 314 MMTCO2e annually) but also

    raise, rather than lose, about $7 billion in additional royalty and carbon revenues per

    year on average. Adding a royalty rate increase on top of a carbon adder (not shown

    in Figure 1) is estimated to produce only slightly more emissions reductions (about 10

    percent more) but also actually raises less revenue (about 10 percent less) than a carbon

    adder alone because layering on this charge further reduces federal production.

    Although those estimated emissions reductions from production on federal lands can

    be large, leakage rates are also substantial, ranging between 53 and 74 percent, depending

    on oil and gas demand elasticity assumptions, as indicated in Figure 1. This means that,

    for example, the federal reductions of 314 MMTCO2e from a moratorium translate into

    only 85 to 147 MMTCO2e worth of reductions in net global emissions. This leakage is in

    part due to offsetting supply responses from production on state and private lands not

    subject to federal restrictions and in part due to leakage to foreign producers. Leakage

    to US producers on state and private lands constitutes about one-third of the total

    leakage effect, despite the fact that those sources historically represented less than 15

    percent of global oil and gas supply (in barrels of oil equivalent). This disproportionate

    contribution to leakage is due to the projected rise in the nonfederal US share of global

    occur at the point of combustion and not at the production site on the federal lands themselves.Nonetheless, for brevity, throughout this paper, the reported emissions reductions by supply source(such as “emissions reductions from federal lands”) correspond to this “embodied” CO2e measure.

    11All revenue estimates represent the effects on gross royalty and carbon adder revenues collectedby the federal government (excluding revenues from tribal lands). Historically, federal royalty revenueshave been split approximately equally between the states and the federal government. I do not attemptto calculate the federal versus state shares of these incremental revenues raised under higher ratesbecause this would be a policy choice, but a 50/50 split would be a reasonable estimate.

    9

  • oil and gas supply and the larger supply elasticities of nonfederal US supply (relative to

    foreign producers), both of which can be attributed to the shale boom.

    Despite the significant potential for emissions leakage, the results suggest that federal

    oil and gas leasing policies can have larger effects on global emissions than previous

    estimates indicate. However, even the most aggressive policy considered—a moratorium

    on all new federal oil and gas leasing—would not drive oil and gas emissions from federal

    lands to zero because production from wells on existing leases would remain unrestricted

    (see Figure 2). Achieving the HSCCC report’s target of net-zero emissions on federal

    lands by 2040 therefore would require modifying existing federal leases and/or a larger

    role for carbon sequestration and renewable energy development on federal lands.

    −10

    0−

    80−

    60−

    40−

    200

    Year

    Per

    cent

    Red

    uctio

    n in

    Ann

    ual F

    eder

    al O

    il an

    d G

    as E

    mis

    sion

    s

    2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050

    18.75% Onshore RR25% RR, Onshore Only25% RR, Onshore &Offshore

    $50 Carbon Adder (2%)

    $50 Carbon Adder (2%)& 25% RR

    Moratorium

    Figure 2: Federal Emissions Reductions by Policy and Year, as a Percent of Baseline

    Notes: RR = royalty rate. Figure only shows emissions reductions from oil and gas produced onfederal lands. Values are presented as a percent of oil and gas emissions from federal lands in eachyear, not including emissions from other sources, such as coal.

    10

  • 2 Model and Results

    The approach in this paper builds upon and extends the methods developed in Newell,

    Prest and Vissing (2019) and Newell and Prest (2019). Each of those papers separately

    models the three key stages of the oil and gas production process: (1) drilling wells,

    (2) completing them (which may include hydraulically fracturing them) to bring them

    online for production, and (3) production over time once the wells are online. Those

    papers then combine the models of each of the three stages to simulate the change in

    oil or gas production resulting from an exogenous change in prices. Those simulations

    were somewhat stylized steady-state models designed to demonstrate estimated price

    responses simply, whereas this paper extends them to incorporate key features relevant

    to changing federal oil and gas leasing policies. This includes the potential for supply

    substitutions across well types (including federal versus nonfederal wells) and a more

    nuanced treatment of well-level production declines over time (which are important

    to modeling the effects of a moratorium on new federal drilling and understanding the

    feasibility of achieving the goal of net-zero emissions). Another extension is to endogenize

    the price to policy changes, which is key to understanding the potential for policy leakage

    and hence net emissions impacts.

    2.1 Simulation Overview

    The simulation model is depicted in a flowchart in Figure 3. I start with a given path

    of projected oil and gas prices and assumptions about policies (royalty rates, carbon

    adders, or a moratorium) over time (box 1). For example, oil and gas price paths in the

    baseline scenario are based on observed futures prices, and royalty rates are assumed to

    be unchanged from current levels (12.5 percent onshore, 18.75 percent offshore). These

    price and policy paths are fed into the drilling module (box 2), which predicts future

    drilling activity for each month into the future based on these price paths (adjusted for

    11

  • royalty rates or carbon adders), separately for each of the eight well types. The drilling

    module is based on the econometric model discussed in detail in the next section.

    Figure 3: Simulation Model Overview

    The resulting trajectory of newly drilled wells gradually translates into new wells

    coming online for production (box 3) based on the empirical distribution of time from

    the initiation of drilling to first production (again, separately by well type). Then, newly

    operating wells produce oil and gas (box 4a) based on empirically estimated production

    profiles over time (also known as “type curves”). Finally, existing wells that have already

    been drilled will also continue to produce oil and gas for many years to come. These

    production levels are estimated using the standard “Arps curve” approach (box 4b).

    Production from new and existing wells is added together to arrive at total US oil and

    gas production. Finally, the US results are combined with a rest-of-world (ROW) module

    (box 5) to account for ROW supply responses to changes in US production, capturing

    potential leakage effects. The methodology underlying each box in Figure 3 is explained

    in detail in the next section.

    12

  • The model begins in equilibrium under current projections of oil and gas supply,

    demand, and prices.12 Then, to model the impacts of policy changes, I change the

    relevant policy assumptions (federal royalty rates, carbon adders, or a moratorium) in

    box 1 and simulate the remaining components of the model (boxes 2–5) under this

    new policy assumption. Any of the three policy levers reduces total quantity supplied,

    pushing the market out of equilibrium (quantity supplied less than quantity demanded)

    under the baseline price paths for oil and gas. I then numerically solve for the rise

    in oil and gas prices necessary to return the market to equilibrium, which yields the

    equilibrium outcomes under the new policy scenario. The effects of the policy on various

    outcomes, such as prices or emissions, are then calculated as the differences between the

    two scenarios (baseline versus policy case).

    2.2 Model Estimation and Calibration

    In this section, I explain the estimation and calibration of the key components of the

    simulation—that is, the estimation of the models in boxes 2, 3, 4a, and 4b in Figure

    3. Research has demonstrated (Anderson, Kellogg and Salant 2018; Newell, Prest and

    Vissing 2019; Newell and Prest 2019) that drilling is the key driver of long-run supply

    responses to oil and gas prices, so this stage merits the most attention. The other

    stages (time to production and production from existing wells) tend not to be very

    responsive to price.13 Most drilling costs are up-front and fixed, whereas the marginal

    cost of producing from an existing well is very low. This implies that it is almost always

    rational for a firm to produce a well at its maximum flow capacity, suggesting little

    adjustment of production from existing wells in response to price changes (Anderson,

    Kellogg and Salant 2018). Rather, oil and gas producers respond to price increases and

    12Oil and gas prices were based on futures prices as of June 25, 2020.13Further, even if these two stages were price responsive, this would primarily affect the timing of

    production rather than the total amount of production realized in response to a price shock.

    13

  • decreases by drilling more or fewer wells, respectively. For these reasons and more,14 I

    focus on modeling the first stage as a function of oil and gas prices, while treating the

    remaining stages as exogenous to prices.15

    In the coming sections, I explain the estimation of the price response of drilling

    activity, or “drilling elasticities” for short. Then I explain the estimations of the amount

    of time it takes for a drilled well to begin production (the second stage) and how much

    oil and gas each well produces in each month of its life (the third stage). Finally, I

    explain how these three stages are combined to simulate the effects of changes in US

    federal leasing policies on federal and nonfederal oil and gas production.

    Because the estimation relies on several key features of the data, I provide an overview

    of the data used in this study before moving on to discuss the estimation and simulation.

    2.2.1 Data

    The key data source is a well-level dataset from Enverus (formerly Drillinginfo) on more

    than one million oil and gas wells in the United States. This data source has been widely

    used in the economics literature (e.g., see Allcott and Keniston 2017; Feyrer, Mansur and

    Sacerdote 2017; Bartik et al. 2019) because it is both highly detailed (e.g., well-level pro-

    duction time series) and nationally comprehensive. The dataset I use includes all wells

    in Enverus’s data that began production between January 1990 and February 2019.16

    The dataset includes rich information on each well, including its latitude and longitude,

    when it was drilled, completed, and began production, whether it is oil directed or gas

    directed, and a monthly time series of its oil and gas production over time.

    14In addition, most proposed changes to federal oil and gas leasing policies would only apply to newlydrilled wells (and only ones on new leases at that) and not to any existing wells, again suggestingfocusing on the development of newly drilled wells.

    15Regression analyses of the second and third stages nonetheless confirm the findings of the previousliterature that these stages are not very price responsive.

    16The Enverus data were downloaded in April 2020, but due to reporting lags, they are only generallycomplete with a one-year lag. Therefore, I end the sample period on February 2019, as the wells in thedata after this date likely represent a biased and incomplete sample.

    14

  • This well-month panel dataset includes 121 million monthly observations on 1,044,817

    wells, accounting for nearly all oil and gas production in the United States. For 2018,

    the last full year of data, the total oil produced by the wells in the sample accounted for

    93 and 97 percent of US oil and gas production, respectively, according to data reported

    by the Energy Information Administration (EIA).17

    In all econometric analyses and simulations, I calculate values separately by well

    type. Specifically, I distinguish between wells along the following three dimensions:

    1. Federal versus nonfederal

    2. Oil-directed versus gas-directed

    3. Onshore versus offshore

    These three binary dimensions lead to 23 = 8 well types. The first dimension is

    natural because the focus of this study is a set of policies that would directly affect

    wells on federal land (and lead to indirect effects on nonfederal wells).18 I further dis-

    tinguish between oil-directed and gas-directed wells because past literature has shown

    that each type of well responds differently to oil versus gas prices. As would be ex-

    pected, oil-directed drilling responds more to oil prices, whereas gas-directed drilling

    responds more to gas prices (see Newell, Prest and Vissing 2019; Newell and Prest 2019;

    Gilbert and Roberts 2020). Pooling well types in an econometric analysis would ignore

    this heterogeneity and also reduce econometric precision. Finally, I also distinguish be-

    tween onshore and offshore wells because the economics, engineering, and geology of

    onshore and offshore drilling are quite distinct. This is also important because one of

    the proposed policy changes would only affect the treatment of onshore federal wells.19

    17These discrepancies owe to wells not in the sample, as Enverus is not a perfect census of every well.In my simulations, I account for these differences by scaling up oil and gas production projections byfactors of 10.93 and

    10.97 respectively.

    18I treat wells on Native American lands as nonfederal because the proposed policy changes wouldnot affect leases on those lands.

    19This policy would raise the onshore federal royalty rate from 12.5 to 18.75 percent, which is therate already typically charged for offshore wells.

    15

  • The Enverus data do not always indicate whether a well is on federal land or when

    it is offshore, so I overlay GIS shapefiles representing federal land20 and the ocean21 to

    geotag wells as federal versus nonfederal and onshore versus offshore. The identification

    of a well as oil directed or gas directed is primarily based on the production type variable

    in the Enverus data.22

    Figure 4 shows the location of the wells in the data by type. Onshore federal wells

    tend to be concentrated in the mountain west, where federal wells are predominantly

    gas directed (in dark blue). However, the map illustrates the signs of the recent rise

    in onshore oil drilling (in red) on federal lands in pockets of southeastern New Mexico

    (overlaying the Permian basin), eastern Colorado and Wyoming (overlaying the Nio-

    brara formation), and western North Dakota (overlaying the Bakken). Nevertheless,

    most of the shale boom has occurred on private lands, which is particularly evident for

    oil-directed drilling (in yellow) in west Texas and gas-directed drilling (light blue) in

    Pennsylvania, Ohio, and West Virginia. Although federal onshore oil production is on

    20I use a GIS shapefile representing federal surface ownership (available at https://www.arcgis.com/home/item.html?id=26c2a38f94c54ad880ff877f884ff931), but this is not necessarily the sameas the owner of the subsurface mineral rights. Unfortunately, no comprehensive nationwide GIS shapefileexists on federal mineral rights ownership, so this is an approximation. However, I checked the accuracyof the geotagging approach by comparing the total production from wells geotagged as “federal” toofficial production statistics reported by the Department of the Interior’s Office of Natural ResourcesRevenue (ONRR). The aggregated production based on the geotagged Enverus data very closely matchesONRR data. For example, in 2018, based on the geotagged aggregation, oil production in 2018 (thelast full year of data) averaged 2.39 million barrels per day (mb/d), compared to 2.41 mb/d reportedby ONRR, a difference of less than one percent. The difference is larger for natural gas production,where the geotagged aggregation is about eight percent smaller than ONRR’s official statistics. Aninvestigation into this difference suggests it is likely due to some very old federal onshore gas wellsthat were drilled before 1990 that do not appear in the dataset. Such wells would not have a materialeffect on the paper’s results. First, they would not be useful in informing the identification of drillingresponses to prices during the sample period. Second, they would not affect the simulated effects ofleasing policy changes, which would apply to newly drilled wells.

    21The ocean shapefile is available at https://www.naturalearthdata.com/downloads/10m-physical-vectors/10m-ocean/. The Enverus data indicate whether wells are on federalwaters, meaning the ocean shapefile is only necessary to identify offshore nonfederal wells.

    22Nearly all (92 percent) of wells are indicated as oil or gas wells in the raw data. The remaining wellshad more ambiguous values for production type, primarily labelled as “O&G.” These wells were labelledas gas directed if their gas-to-oil ratio is higher than the 90th percentile of the observed gas-to-oil ratioof oil wells; all other wells with ambiguous type were labelled as oil directed.

    16

    https://www.arcgis.com/home/item.html?id=26c2a38f94c54ad880ff877f884ff931https://www.arcgis.com/home/item.html?id=26c2a38f94c54ad880ff877f884ff931https://www.naturalearthdata.com/downloads/10m-physical-vectors/10m-ocean/https://www.naturalearthdata.com/downloads/10m-physical-vectors/10m-ocean/

  • Figure 4: Location of Wells in Data by Well Type and Federal Lands

    Sources: Well locations are from Enverus. The federal lands locations are based on the ArcGIS federallands shapefile available athttps://www.arcgis.com/home/item.html?id=26c2a38f94c54ad880ff877f884ff931. Datasetincludes Alaska, which is omitted from the map for space.

    the rise, it remains small relative to oil production on state and private lands, and most

    federal oil production still comes from offshore wells, primarily the Gulf of Mexico.

    Not all well types are equally important in driving total US oil and gas production. To

    illustrate the relative importance of each well type, Figure 5 shows historical production

    of oil (top panel) and gas (bottom) by well type. Beginning around 2009, the sharp rise in

    oil production from the shale boom is evident in the graph (see yellow line representing

    nonfederal oil drilling, as the shale boom primarily took place on nonfederal lands).

    The stall in production following the temporary crash in oil prices in 2014–2015 is also

    17

    https://www.arcgis.com/home/item.html?id=26c2a38f94c54ad880ff877f884ff931

  • evident. Onshore federal oil-directed drilling has also risen (solid red line in top panel),

    which includes the New Mexico side of the Permian basin.

    Nonetheless, offshore oil-directed production has historically been dominant on fed-

    eral lands (dashed red line, top panel). The other categories of offshore wells have

    contributed relatively little to US oil and gas production in recent years. Federal gas

    production is dominated by onshore gas wells (bottom panel, solid dark blue line). In

    general, US gas production is dominated by onshore nonfederal wells (light blue line)

    and associated gas production from onshore nonfederal oil wells (yellow line in bottom

    panel).

    Although I model all eight well types to comprehensively account for all production

    sources, Figure 5 illustrates that the key types driving long-run production are onshore

    nonfederal oil wells (yellow solid line), onshore nonfederal gas wells (light blue solid),

    offshore federal oil wells (red dashed), and onshore federal gas wells (dark blue solid).

    Although historically relatively small, production from onshore federal oil wells (e.g.,

    in the New Mexico portion of the Permian basin) is also expected to be important in

    the future due to its recent rapid growth. Hence, in the subsequent analysis, the key

    estimates meriting attention are those for these well types.

    18

  • 02

    46

    8

    Oil

    Pro

    duct

    ion

    (mb/

    d)

    2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    OnshoreOffshore

    010

    2030

    4050

    6070

    Gas

    Pro

    duct

    ion

    (bcf

    /d)

    2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    OnshoreOffshore

    Figure 5: Historical Production of Oil (top) and Gas (bottom), by Well Type, 2000–2019

    Notes: The sample includes wells drilled in 1990 or later.

    In addition to the Enverus data, I also use data from the Federal Reserve Economic

    Database (FRED) for historical oil (WTI) and gas (Henry Hub) prices and inflation

    indexes.23 For the simulation, I also use futures prices for West Texas Intermediate

    (WTI), Brent, and Henry Hub from CME Group as the market’s best-guess forecasts

    23I also use copper prices as an instrument in the econometric analysis. The specific series used areDCOILWTICO, PNGASUSUSDM, PCOPPUSDM, and CPIAUCSL.

    19

    https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DCOILWTICOhttps://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/PNGASUSUSDMhttps://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/PCOPPUSDMhttps://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/CPIAUCSL

  • of future commodity prices24 and projections from the International Energy Agency’s

    2019 World Energy Outlook (IEA 2019) for global oil and gas demand, ROW supply,

    and international gas price spreads.

    2.2.2 Econometric Estimation of Drilling Response (Box 2)

    The drilling estimation uses standard time series methods as in Newell, Prest and Vissing

    (2019) and Newell and Prest (2019). Namely, for each well type j, I estimate how the

    number of wells drilled in month t responds to variation in contemporaneous and lagged

    oil and gas prices. The estimating equation for each well type j is

    ∆ log(Wells Drilledj,t) =12∑`=0

    ηoilj,`∆ log(WTIt−`) + ηgasj,` ∆ log(Henry Hubt−`) + λmoy + εj,t,

    (1)

    where WTI is the West Texas Intermediate crude oil price, Henry Hub is the natural gas

    price, and λmoy represents month of year fixed effects to capture seasonality in drilling

    activity. The time series of the variables in equation (1) are shown in Figure 6. The

    graph suggests a slightly lagged response of drilling activity to prices. This is most likely

    due to lag times, due to planning and logistics, between when drilling decisions are made

    by firms and when drilling rigs are brought to the well site. Twelve months of lagged

    prices are included, as in Newell, Prest and Vissing (2019) and Newell and Prest (2019),

    but the results are robust to including more lags.

    24These futures are available here: WTI, Brent, and Henry Hub. The prices used reflect the closingprice on June 25th, 2020.

    20

    https://www.cmegroup.com/trading/energy/crude-oil/light-sweet-crude_quotes_globex.htmlhttps://www.cmegroup.com/trading/energy/crude-oil/brent-crude-oil-last-day.htmlhttps://www.cmegroup.com/trading/energy/natural-gas/natural-gas-last-day.html

  • 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020

    050

    010

    0015

    0020

    0025

    0030

    00

    Month

    Num

    ber

    of W

    ells

    Dril

    led

    050

    100

    150

    Oil and G

    as Price

    (2020$ per barrel of oil equivalent)

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    WTI Oil PriceHenry Hub Gas Price

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020

    020

    4060

    8010

    012

    0

    Month

    Num

    ber

    of W

    ells

    Dril

    led

    050

    100

    150

    Oil and G

    as Price

    (2020$ per barrel of oil equivalent)

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    WTI Oil PriceHenry Hub Gas Price

    Figure 6: Wells Drilled per Month, by Well Type, Onshore (top panel) and Offshore(bottom panel)

    21

  • The ηoilj,` and ηoilj,` parameters in equation (1) are short-run drilling elasticities for a

    well of type j (i.e., the effect of a change in log prices on log drilling activity with a

    lag of ` months). The long-run, or cumulative, drilling elasticity with respect to the oil

    price is simply the sum of the contemporaneous and lagged coefficients ηoilj =∑12

    `=0 ηoilj,`.

    The long-run drilling elasticity with respect to gas prices is defined analogously.

    Endogeneity is not typically a major problem when estimating US drilling elasticities

    (see e.g., Prest 2018) because the country has historically been considered a relatively

    small producer, particularly for the oil market, and because surprise shocks to drilling

    activity are only weakly related to contemporaneous changes in production, which arise

    with a significant lag. As a result, drilling activity shocks tend to have little contempo-

    raneous effect on oil and gas prices. This argument may be weaker in recent years with

    the shale boom, which has arguably allowed US supply to have a larger influence on oil

    prices in particular. Therefore, I instrument for the potential endogeneity of oil and gas

    prices to drilling activity using approaches from the literature.25

    Drilling Estimation Results

    Each regression specification in equation (1) has 26 elasticity estimates (13 for oil and

    13 for gas prices).26 With a separate regression for each of the eight types of wells, this

    25The instrument for the oil price is the market price of copper, which acts as a proxy for globalcommodity demand, as used in Hamilton (2014); Prest (2018) and Newell, Prest and Vissing (2019).The instrument for natural gas prices is the twice-lagged level of log Henry Hub prices, based on one ofthe strongest instruments considered in Hausman and Kellogg (2015). Unfortunately, in this context,most standard instruments for natural gas prices, including those used in the literature, turn out tobe weak (e.g., see Hausman and Kellogg 2015, which faced a similar difficulty). After considering alengthy list of alternative natural gas instruments (average temperature, heating degree days, coolingdegree days, natural gas inventories, and their lags), the twice-lagged Henry Hub price turned out tobe the strongest and most conceptually defensible instrument. I use this price because it would beinappropriate to use the first lag, because the potentially endogenous variable (the first difference of logHenry Hub prices) is mechanically a function of the first lag.

    26Each regression uses 325 monthly observations: Feb. 1992 to Feb. 2019. The Henry Hub priceseries begins in Jan. 1991, so with 12 lagged first differences in prices, the complete time series beginsin Feb. 1992. Each model is estimated by two-stage least squares (2SLS). The first stage is the same foreach regression; the first-stage F-test for the copper price instrument is 14.8, which is strong, whereasthe F-test for the lagged Henry Hub instrument is 5.1. The latter F-test for natural gas prices is similarin magnitude to the results from Hausman and Kellogg (2015). When using ordinary least squares(OLS) instead of 2SLS, the long-run elasticities are generally somewhat smaller in magnitude for allkey well types, but the differences in magnitudes are not large. The most important effect of the IVapproach is for the oil price elasticity for offshore oil wells, where the IV elasticity is positive (0.48)

    22

  • leads to 26×8 = 208 coefficient estimates representing the time profile of drilling elastic-

    ities. Because the long-run drilling response depends only on the cumulative elasticities

    (i.e., the sum of the contemporaneous and lagged price coefficients), for the purposes of

    exposition, I present the results more concisely by showing only these cumulative esti-

    mates.27 This nonetheless leads to 16 cumulative elasticity estimates—one for oil prices

    and one for gas prices, for each of the eight well types. These are shown in Figure 7 for

    onshore wells and Figure 8 for offshore wells.

    Before discussing the results, it is worth noting the expected signs of the elasticities.

    Although “own-price” elasticities (e.g., oil prices on oil-directed drilling) should be pos-

    itive, “cross-price” elasticities (e.g., gas prices on oil-directed drilling) could be positive,

    negative, or even zero. For example, to the extent that associated gas coproduced by

    oil-directed wells is valuable, higher gas prices could support oil-directed drilling, imply-

    ing a positive elasticity. On the other hand, if rising gas prices lead to competition for

    drilling rigs that increase (unobserved) costs for oil-directed drilling, rising gas prices

    could lead to reduced oil drilling, implying a negative “cross-price” elasticity.

    Within each figure, the own-price elasticities are found in the top left (oil prices on

    oil wells) and bottom right (gas prices on gas wells) panels. The cross-price elasticities

    are in the top right (gas prices on oil wells) and bottom left (oil prices on gas wells)

    panels. The largest source of US oil production is onshore nonfederal oil wells, which are

    estimated to have a long-run drilling elasticity of 1.04 with respect to oil prices (yellow

    bar in the top left panel of Figure 7), which is also the most precisely estimated elasticity,

    with a standard error of 0.30. The corresponding elasticity for federal onshore oil wells

    is 0.93, slightly smaller but not statistically different from their nonfederal counterparts.

    These own-price elasticity estimates for onshore gas wells (bottom right panel) are 0.7

    for nonfederal and 1.2 for federal wells, although they are less precisely estimated. The

    but not significant (standard error of 0.61) but the OLS elasticity is close to zero (-0.08, again notsignificant). All statistical inference uses Newey West covariance matrices.

    27The full regression results are presented in appendix section A.

    23

  • cross-price elasticities are all positive but small and statistically insignificant. Although

    the literature has not typically estimated federal versus nonfederal drilling elasticities

    specifically, these estimates are comparable in magnitude to the most appropriate ana-

    logues in the literature (Hausman and Kellogg 2015; Anderson, Kellogg and Salant 2018;

    Newell, Prest and Vissing 2019; Newell and Prest 2019; Gilbert and Roberts 2020).

    Despite the substantial literature on onshore drilling elasticities, I am aware of no

    recent literature estimating offshore drilling elasticities. This is perhaps due to the

    small number of offshore wells drilled each year, leading to small sample sizes and hence

    noisy estimates. Indeed, the standard errors on the offshore drilling elasticities are

    wide. Although four offshore well types (federal versus nonfederal and oil versus gas)

    are presented in Figure 8, the vast majority of offshore wells are federal. The own-price

    elasticity estimate for this group is 0.5, with a standard error of 0.6, and the cross-price

    elasticity is 0.2, also with a standard error of 0.6. Because the other types of offshore

    wells are so few in number, their estimated elasticities matter very little to the simulation

    results.

    These large standard errors imply considerable uncertainty in the offshore drilling

    elasticity; indeed, I cannot reject that it is zero. However, the implications for the

    simulation modeling of leasing policies are smaller than may otherwise appear, because

    simulating most policies of interest does not depend strongly on the offshore oil price

    elasticity. The proposed increase in royalty rates to 18.75 percent would have no appre-

    ciable effect for offshore wells (for which the rate is typically already 18.75 percent), and

    the proposed moratorium is not a price-based instrument and therefore is not mediated

    by an elasticity estimate.

    24

  • Nonfederal Federal

    Oil Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Oil

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −1

    01

    23

    −1

    01

    23

    Nonfederal Federal

    Oil Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Gas

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −1

    01

    23

    −1

    01

    23

    Nonfederal Federal

    Gas Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Oil

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −1

    01

    23

    −1

    01

    23

    Nonfederal Federal

    Gas Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Gas

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −1

    01

    23

    −1

    01

    23

    Figure 7: Onshore Long-Run Drilling Elasticities with Respect to Oil Prices (left column)and Gas Prices (right)

    Notes: Error bars represent 90 percent confidence intervals

    25

  • Nonfederal Federal

    Oil Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Oil

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −1

    01

    23

    −1

    01

    23

    Nonfederal Federal

    Oil Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Gas

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −1

    01

    23

    −1

    01

    23

    Nonfederal Federal

    Gas Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Oil

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −2

    −1

    01

    23

    −2

    −1

    01

    23

    Nonfederal Federal

    Gas Wells

    Cum

    ulat

    ive

    Gas

    Pric

    e E

    last

    icity

    −1

    01

    23

    −1

    01

    23

    Figure 8: Offshore Long-Run Drilling Elasticities with Respect to Oil Prices (left column)and Gas Prices (right)

    Notes: Error bars represent 90 percent confidence intervals. Bottom left panel has a different scale.

    26

  • 2.2.3 Time from Drilling to First Production (Box 3)

    Once a well is drilled, it must be completed (and potentially hydraulically fractured)

    before it is ready to produce. Newell, Prest and Vissing (2019) and Newell and Prest

    (2019) found that the completion time (or more specifically, the time in months between

    the “spud date”—the date drilling began—to the first production date) did not strongly

    depend on prices. This time lag does affect the timing of production responses, however

    because it creates a lag between a rise in drilling activity and the realization of incre-

    mental oil and gas production. The simulation accounts for this time lag by converting

    changes in drilling activity to new wells coming online (box 3 in Figure 3) according

    to the empirically estimated distribution of completion time. These distributions are

    shown in Figure 9.28 Both onshore and offshore, the distributions of spud to first pro-

    duction time is similar across oil, gas, federal, and nonfederal wells. Offshore wells tend

    to take longer to come online (nearly two years, compared to four months on average

    for onshore, although the offshore average is in part driven by the skewed distribution

    with the long right tail).

    28These estimated distributions do not include wells with completion times that appear to be dataerrors, such as wells that were reported to begin production before they were drilled or took longer toenter production than is reasonable (two years after drilling for onshore wells or 10 years for offshorewells), based on the length of a typical lease’s primary term. Wells included in this calculation repre-sent approximately 90 percent of oil and gas production, suggesting that the impact of excluding theremainder is minor.

    27

  • 0.00

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.10

    Months from Spud to Production

    Den

    sity

    0 6 12 18 24

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    0 20 40 60 80 100 120

    0.00

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.10

    Months from Spud to Production

    Den

    sity

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    Figure 9: Density Plot of Time from Drilling (“Spud”) to First Production, by WellType, Onshore (top panel) and Offshore (bottom panel)

    28

  • 2.2.4 Oil and Gas Production from New Wells, Over Time (Box 4a)

    Once wells are online, they produce years or decades to come. Converting newly operat-

    ing wells to oil and gas production requires modeling the profile of such production over

    time (also called a “type curve”) for each well type. As research has shown, production

    from existing wells is almost perfectly inelastic to oil and gas prices.29 A panel regression

    of monthly well-level production on prices confirms this in this data as well.30 For this

    reason, I model the average production profile per well as exogenous based on the av-

    erage production profile, by well type, scaled to the average observed initial production

    (IP) in 2019 (the first year of the simulation), also by well type.

    More specifically, I calculate the average production profile by age of well in months

    for wells beginning production in 2009 or later. This year coincides with the beginning

    of the shale boom, is sufficiently recent that it captures the trends toward sharper

    decline curves due to the growing focus on the development of shale formations, and is

    sufficiently long ago to ensure an adequate number of wells in the data with a long enough

    observed history to reliably estimate production profiles. These profiles are converted to

    a percentage of IP and projected out to 30 years (the length of the simulation) using an

    Arps curve fit on the first five years of the average production profile.31 The estimation

    of Arps curves is discussed in more detail in the next section. These fitted curves (as a

    29Although well shut-ins happen on rare occasions, this primarily affects the timing, rather than thelevel, of production.

    30Results available on request.31I use the first five years to avoid noise that would be introduced by using data from a small number

    of wells that contribute to the production profile in the final years of the sample. Namely, the only wellsfor which we observe the 120th month of production in December 2018 are those drilled in exactly themonth of January 2009. Using that small sample would lead to noisy estimates, composition bias in thefinal months of the production profile, and potentially divergent production projections. Nonetheless,the majority of a well’s cumulative oil and gas production is realized in the first five years (Figure 10).

    29

  • percentage of IP) are then scaled to average IP values observed in the first year of the

    simulation.32 The resulting production profiles, by well type, are shown in Figure 10.0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    700

    Months Since Initial Production

    Oil

    Pro

    duce

    d P

    er D

    ay (

    barr

    els

    per

    day)

    0 60 120 180 240 300 360

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    020

    0040

    0060

    0080

    00

    Months Since Initial Production

    Gas

    Pro

    duce

    d P

    er D

    ay (

    mcf

    per

    day

    )

    0 60 120 180 240 300 360360

    050

    010

    0015

    0020

    0025

    0030

    00

    Months Since Initial Production

    Oil

    Pro

    duce

    d P

    er D

    ay (

    barr

    els

    per

    day)

    0 60 120 180 240 300 360

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    010

    0020

    0030

    0040

    0050

    00

    Months Since Initial Production

    Gas

    Pro

    duce

    d P

    er D

    ay (

    mcf

    per

    day

    )

    0 60 120 180 240 300 360360

    Figure 10: Estimated Production Profiles, by Well Type, Oil Production (left panels)and Gas Production (right panels), Onshore (top) and Offshore (bottom)

    32I assume that IP values by well type remain constant over time. Although IPs are unlikely toremain constant over time in reality, it is not clear whether they will rise or fall in the long run. On theone hand, technological innovation has driven large increases in IP in recent years, and it is possible thistrend could continue. On the other hand, IPs could decline as the most productive wells are exhausted.

    30

  • 2.2.5 Oil and Gas Production from Existing Wells, Over Time (Box 4b)

    For a given price path and set of policies, the previous modules of the model (boxes 1-

    4a) combined produce projections of oil and gas production over time from newly drilled

    wells. Because the typical well produces oil and gas for decades after it is drilled, a

    nontrivial share of total production at any given time is from existing (i.e., previously

    drilled) wells. I calculate production from wells drilled before the beginning of the

    simulation (2019) using well-specific Arps curve projections.

    The Arps curve is the standard method used by petroleum engineers to forecast an

    individual well’s future production. This approach involves estimating the following

    nonlinear equation by nonlinear least squares:

    qτ =q0

    (1 + bd0τ)1b

    + �τ , (2)

    where qτ is a well’s oil or gas production in month τ = 0, 1, 2, . . . of a well’s productive

    life. The q0 term is the well’s IP rate, and the Arps parameters are d0 (which represents

    the initial decline rate) and b (which represents how much the decline rate slows over

    time).33 I estimate separate Arps curves for each well still producing as of the end of

    2018 and use the fitted Arps curve to project production to 2050. I estimate two Arps

    curves for each well—one each for oil and gas. For each well type, production is summed

    across wells by calendar month to generate total projected oil and gas production from

    existing wells. These projections are shown in Figure 11.

    33The special case of b = 0 corresponds to constant exponential decline, qτ = q0e−d0τ , but it is

    common for production to decline slower than exponentially (b > 0).

    31

  • 02

    46

    8

    Oil

    Pro

    duct

    ion

    (mb/

    d)

    2019 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    OnshoreOffshore

    010

    2030

    4050

    6070

    Gas

    Pro

    duct

    ion

    (bcf

    /d)

    2019 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050

    Oil Wells, NonfederalOil Wells, FederalGas Wells, NonfederalGas Wells, Federal

    OnshoreOffshore

    Figure 11: Projected Production of Oil (top) and Gas (bottom) from Existing Wells asof 2018

    32

  • 2.2.6 Simulating US Oil and Gas Supply in Each Scenario (Boxes 1–4)

    With each stage of the US supply process modeled, I combine them as in Newell, Prest

    and Vissing (2019) and Newell and Prest (2019) to simulate future US oil and gas

    production for a given price path and set of federal leasing policies. I begin the simulation

    at the start of 2019 (following the last full year of complete data). The oil (WTI) and

    gas (Henry Hub) price paths are set equal to historical observed monthly average values

    for 2019 and the first half of 2020, after which prices are set equal to the futures prices

    for delivery in each future month (as of June 25, 2020).34 Those futures strips extend

    through 2031–2032, and I extrapolate to 2050, accounting for seasonality.35 Baseline

    federal royalty rates are set to 12.5 percent for onshore wells and 18.75 percent for

    offshore wells.36

    In addition to a baseline “business as usual” scenario, I simulate scenarios featuring

    different combinations of federal leasing policy changes that take effect in 2020. Each

    scenario reflects a different application of one or more of the three policy levers: raising

    federal royalty rates, charging carbon adders, and a moratorium.

    34It is common to use futures prices as proxies for expected future spot prices, based on the conceptthat arbitrage will ensure that futures reflect the market’s best guess of future spot prices. This ideaeffectively assumes that oil futures prices do not carry a risk premium. As documented by Baumeisterand Kilian (2016), such a risk premium can be positive or negative. Accounting for it would addconsiderable additional complexity, so I set it aside for simplicity. Given the broader uncertainty aboutthe outlook for oil prices in 2020, the potential bias from ignoring the risk premium is likely swampedby other uncertainties. Further, because this potential bias would be present in both the baseline andpolicy scenarios, it is unlikely to strongly affect the modeling results that reflect their difference.

    35Futures prices were downloaded from the CME group reflecting closing prices on June 25, 2020,when futures prices were available for oil and gas for delivery through 2031 (WTI) and 2032 (HenryHub). I extrapolate the final point on each futures strip beyond 2030 based on a regression of the logdifference of futures prices on month of year indicators, which account for price seasonality for naturalgas. The procedure yields prices that rise at average annual growth rates after 2030 of of 2.0 and 2.5percent for WTI and Henry Hub, respectively. Figure A.2 depicts these baseline price projections.

    36Nonfederal royalty rates are assumed to be unchanged over the simulation. Since only changeswould affect nonfederal drilling through equation (1), the precise assumption about nonfederal royaltyrates is immaterial. Nonetheless, I apply an 18 percent royalty rate, in the middle of the range ofnonfederal rates reported in U.S. Government Accountability Office (2017). For example, state ratesin Colorado, New Mexico, Utah, and Wyoming range from 12.5 to 20 percent, whereas rates in Texasare set at 25 percent. See also https://westernpriorities.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/06/Royalties-Report_update.pdf.

    33

    https://westernpriorities.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/06/Royalties-Report_update.pdfhttps://westernpriorities.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/06/Royalties-Report_update.pdf

  • I model the first two policies as affecting the net price of oil and gas received on

    production from new federal wells. For example, raising the onshore royalty rate from

    12.5 percent to 18.75 percent amounts to an (approximately) 6.25 percentage point drop

    in the net price of oil and gas received, which is fed into the estimated model of drilling

    elasticities in equation (1). Similarly, carbon adders are translated into oil- and gas-price

    equivalent values. For example, a $50/tCO2 carbon adder translates into a $21.50 per

    barrel charge, assuming an emissions rate of 0.43 tCO2 per barrel of oil combusted. The

    corresponding charge for natural gas is $3.30 per mcf.37 Note that these carbon charges

    are quite large relative to market value, suggesting that carbon adders are likely to lead

    to large reductions in federal production, particularly for natural gas.38 The simulation

    results demonstrate this effect.

    For all well types, I use the applicable paths of net oil and gas prices (after ap-

    propriately deducting royalties and carbon adders)39 to calculate the predicted values

    of monthly log-changes in drilling activity from equation (1), in both the baseline and

    policy cases, and convert this to predicted levels of wells drilled by month.

    A moratorium on new federal oil and gas leasing is simpler to model because it is a

    quantity instrument rather than a price instrument. After instituting a moratorium, new

    leasing ends, meaning eventually new federal drilling activity must go to zero. Operators

    may still have existing federal leases on which they have yet to drill. These leases last

    up to 10 years, assuming no extensions. For this reason, I model the moratorium as a

    gradual, linear 10-year decline in federal drilling activity that the model would otherwise

    predict, and no new drilling is permitted after that time. That is, 0 percent of new federal

    37The emissions rate for natural gas is 0.066 tCO2e per mcf. This is based on a 177 lbs of CO2 per mcffrom direct gas combustion, plus 28.55 lbs of CO2e from methane leakages, which is based on the 2.3percent methane leakage estimate from Alvarez et al. (2018) and a 100-year global warming potential.Together, this implies an emissions rate of (117 + 28.55 lbs CO2)× 1 metric ton2204.62 lbs = 0.066 tCO2e per mcf.

    38To ensure simulated net prices never go negative, which would preclude the use of logged prices inequation (1), I impose a floor on the net oil and gas prices equal to $1 per barrel of oil equivalent.

    39Naturally, for nonfederal wells, royalty rates are held constant and no carbon adders are charged.Nonfederal wells are nonetheless affected by the endogenous oil and gas prices calculated in box 5, asexplained in the next section. This accounts for policy leakage.

    34

  • drilling is assumed to be covered by the moratorium in year 1 of the policy change, 10

    percent covered in year 2, and so on until 100 percent is covered in year 10.

    Ten years is the standard statutory length of federal oil and gas leases.40 The linear

    phase-in assumption effectively assumes that no existing-but-undrilled leases would be

    renewed beyond their 10-year primary term. The royalty rate increase and carbon adder

    policies are also modeled as being phased in linearly over 10 years for the same reason.

    As in Gerarden, Reeder and Stock (2020), I assume a linear phase-in of royalty rates

    and carbon adders that apply to all wells because explicitly modeling which subsets of

    wells would face which royalty rates would add an unnecessary degree of complexity.

    The results are not sensitive to this assumption because only about 15 percent of

    business-as-usual federal emissions over the 30-year simulation horizon are from newly

    drilled wells during this 10-year window. The linear phase-in effectively implies that

    about half of this 15 percent of federal emissions (about 8 percent) are covered by the

    policy. Alternative extreme assumptions that either none of these wells are covered or

    all of them are would change the share of covered federal emissions by ∼ ±8 percent.

    2.2.7 Rest of World Supply and Demand (Box 5)

    The previous sections explain how US oil and gas supply is simulated for any given price

    path and set of policies. However, because the United States is not a closed economy,

    incorporating the potential for emissions leakage requires also modeling the responses of

    foreign supply and demand. To account for these trade effects, I incorporate an ROW

    model based on supply and demand projections from the International Energy Agency

    (IEA)’s 2019 World Energy Outlook (WEO) (IEA 2019). I use the WEO’s central

    “Stated Policies” scenario for global oil and gas demand and ROW supply, interpolated

    to the monthly level to correspond with the time step in the US supply model.

    40Ten years is the standard length of onshore leases and Alaskan and deepwater offshore leases (CBO2016). Although some offshore leases in shallow water have shorter lease terms (such as eight years),these account for relatively little of offshore oil and gas development.

    35

  • Some technical adjustments to these projections must be made to render the US

    supply model comparable to the values reported in the WEO. For example, the US

    supply model simulates gross gas withdrawals, whereas the WEO projections are for

    marketed gas production, which is a subset of gross withdrawals. In addition, I make

    some adjustments to the WEO demand and ROW supply projections to be consistent

    with the much lower oil and gas prices observed in 2020 relative to those assumed in the

    WEO projections in 2019. These are discussed in appendix section C.

    I model ROW supply as endogenous using the ROW supply elasticities implied by

    the WEO projections. I infer these supply elasticities by comparing ROW oil and gas

    production in the WEO’s base “Stated Policies” scenario to its “Current Policies” sce-

    nario, which corresponds to a case with somewhat higher oil and gas demand. These

    elasticities start at about +0.2 in the short run (2020) for both oil and gas supply and

    rise gradually in the long run (2050) to +0.9 for oil and +1.2 for gas, owing to the rising

    implied elasticities over time embedded in the WEO. On average, the ROW oil and gas

    supply elasticities are +0.4 for oil and +0.5 for gas over the simulation horizon.41

    For global oil and gas demand, I apply standard demand elasticities from the liter-

    ature. In the main results, I use elasticities of -0.2 for both oil and gas demand, based

    on the central case in Erickson and Lazarus (2018) for oil (which was in turn based

    on literature reviews by Hamilton 2009 and Bordoff and Houser 2015) and empirical

    estimates from Arora (2014) and Auffhammer and Rubin (2018) for gas. I also conduct

    a “high-elasticity” sensitivity case where the elasticities are set to -0.51 for oil and -0.42

    for gas. The gas demand elasticity is from Metcalf (2018), which in turn is based on

    estimates in Hausman and Kellogg (2015). The oil demand elasticity is based on the

    mean estimate from Balke and Brown (2018), but it also is very close to the value of

    -0.50 used in Metcalf 2018 based on the findings of Allaire and Brown (2012).

    41This is similar to the estimated long-run oil supply elasticity of 0.55 found in Balke and Brown(2018) from an empirically calibrated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model. That paper didnot estimate a gas supply elasticity.

    36

  • 2.2.8 Solving for New Equilibrium Prices

    When simulating a change in federal leasing policies that reduces federal oil and gas

    production, I solve for the new oil and gas prices that clear the markets for both oil and

    gas. The equilibrium concept I use is based on a standard no-arbitrage condition that

    implies that changes in expected future commodity prices are immediately capitalized

    into contemporaneous commodity prices.

    This equilibrium concept is perhaps most easily understood as an application of the

    result of the standard Hotelling model of nonrenewable resource extraction (Hotelling

    1931), although it is not restricted to that model. In the Hotelling model, current and

    (discounted) future oil prices in equilibrium are inseparably linked due to a no-arbitrage

    condition, implying that the price in a future year is a fixed multiple of current prices.

    This implies that an x% increase in the equilibrium price of oil due in the future to a

    supply shock must also coincide with an equivalent x% increase today. More generally,

    this inseparable, intertemporal link between prices over time is the result of no-arbitrage

    condition for any storable asset (see, e.g., Fama and French 1987, 1988).42

    Based on this result, I assume that the percentage change in the price of oil is

    the same across all periods in the simulation horizon, and similarly so for the price of

    gas. This theoretically inspired equilibrium mechanism also greatly simplifies solving for

    new market-clearing prices because it only requires a two-dimensional optimization. A

    key, desirable consequence of this assumption is that the expected effects of announced

    policies are immediately capitalized into market prices, even before the policy has an

    42The equilibrium price of a futures contract, Ft for a storable asset equals its spot price, S, grossedup by the discount factor, (1 +Rt), plus the marginal warehousing cost net of the marginal convenienceyield of holding the asset, Wt − Ct: Ft = S(1 + Rt) + Wt − Ct. With risk-neutral traders, the futuresprice should also reflect the expected future spot price. This demonstrates the link. The assumptionthat supply shocks have an equal percentage effect on current and future prices requires either thatthe marginal warehousing cost less the marginal convenience yield, Wt − Ct, is zero or that it scalesin proportion to the price. This is a reasonable approximation the purposes of this model. Finally,this equation is only valid in the presence of an interior solution for inventories, which ensures the no-arbitrage condition holds. Therefore, I track inventories in the model to ensure that they never becomenegative (which is impossible) or exceed physical limits. For the small policy changes (in the contextof global supply) that I consider, these constraints never become binding.

    37

  • appreciable effect on realized production. As a result, the model includes a kind of

    “green paradox” effect (Sinn 2008), whereby an anticipated tightening of policy in the

    future leads to immediately higher prices and hence somewhat accelerated oil and gas

    production.

    3 Results

    3.1 Simulation Results

    I model the following six policy scenarios, including variants of policies previously con-

    sidered for coal leasing reform in Krupnick et al. (2016) and Gerarden, Reeder and Stock

    (2020) and those by HSCCC (2020).

    1. A raise in onshore royalty rates to 18.75 percent (matching the current 18.75 rate

    typically charged offshore);

    2. A raise in onshore royalty rates to 25 percent (matching the high end of rates on

    state and private lands);

    3. A raise in onshore and offshore royalty rates to 25 percent;

    4. A $50/tCO2e carbon adder, rising at 2 percent annually, both onshore and offshore;

    5. A $50/tCO2e carbon adder and a 25 percent royalty rate, both onshore and off-

    shore; and

    6. A moratorium on new leasing, onshore and offshore.

    Consistent with statutory lease terms, I assume the primary terms of existing, undrilled

    leases expire on schedule (i.e., after 10 years). That is, I assume no extensions on

    undrilled leases, but once drilled, those wells may continue to produce indefinitely, also

    consistent with existing law.

    38

  • Table 1 shows the impacts of each policy scenario on equilibrium oil and gas prices,

    emissions by source (US federal, US nonfederal, ROW, and global), emissions leakage

    rates, and changes in royalty and carbon adder revenues. All values shown are annual

    averages over the full 2020–2050 window.43 Further, the table presents results using

    both “base-case” demand elasticities and the “high-elasticity” sensitivity case.

    Because US federal oil and gas production is a relatively small fraction of global oil

    and gas supply (about 2 and 3 percent for oil and gas, respectively, in 2018), the price

    impacts are small. Raising federal royalty rates would increase oil (WTI) and gas (Henry

    Hub) prices by 0.1–0.3 percent, depending on the size of the rate increase. Federal oil

    and gas production declines somewhat, albeit with a bit of lag due to the delay between

    leasing policy changes and changes in realized production. On average, this leads to a

    direct reduction in federal emissions of 16–37 MMTCO2e per year on average during

    the 2020–2050 window (see column 3). However, this is offset by an increase of 3–9

    MMTCO2e associated with production on nonfederal US lands (column 4) and another

    6–18 MMTCO2e increase in emissions from foreign production (column 5). In other

    words, about one-third of the leakage arises from US production from nonfederal lands

    and the other two-thirds from foreign (ROW) supply.

    43I focus on averages here and in Table 1 for simplicity and to reflect cumulative emissions effec