the determinants of managerial ownership and the ownership

37
The determinants of managerial ownership and the ownership- performance relation Student name: Huib Raterink Administration number: 664727 Faculty: Economics and Management Department: Finance Supervisor: dr. A. Manconi Date: 18-12-2012

Upload: others

Post on 02-Jan-2022

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

The determinants of managerial ownership and the ownership-

performance relation

Student name: Huib Raterink Administration number: 664727 Faculty: Economics and Management Department: Finance Supervisor: dr. A. Manconi Date: 18-12-2012

1

2

Acknowledgements

This research could not have been realized without the help of others. I would especially like

to thank my thesis supervisor, dr. A. Manconi, for giving me valuable feedback week after

week and for staying positive at all times. I would also like to thank Marloes Coppoolse for

her never-ending optimism and support, and for putting up with me the past year. Lastly, I

would like to thank my parents and Max for helping me wherever they could.

3

Table of contents

1. Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 4

2. Hypothesis development ........................................................................................................ 6

2.1 Determinants of managerial ownership ............................................................................ 6

2.2 The ownership-performance relation ................................................................................ 7

3. Data and methodology ........................................................................................................... 9

3.1 Data ................................................................................................................................... 9

3.2 Econometric problem ..................................................................................................... 12

3.3 Methods .......................................................................................................................... 14

4. Empirical results ................................................................................................................... 18

4.1 Determinants of managerial ownership .......................................................................... 18

4.2.1 Determinants of firm performance: fixed effects estimation ....................................... 19

4.2.2 Determinants of firm performance: IV estimation ...................................................... 20

4.2.3 Determinants of firm performance: sample splits ....................................................... 21

5. Conclusion ............................................................................................................................ 22

6. References ............................................................................................................................ 24

7. Appendix .............................................................................................................................. 26

4

1. Introduction

Being the CEO of Apple from 2000 until 2011, the late Steve Jobs earned a yearly salary of

only $1.1 While that may seem strange, other CEOs have had $1 salaries as well. Some

examples include Google’s Eric Schmidt2, Facebook’s Mark Zuckerberg (as of 2013) and Mr.

Jobs’s successor at Apple Tim Cook. Obviously, these men are compensated in other ways.3

In their extensive study on CEO pay, Frydman and Jenter (2010) show that stock-based

compensation like restricted stock grants and option grants have become increasingly

important in the composition of CEO pay. Indeed, Mr. Cook was granted 1,000,000

Restricted Stock Units (RSUs) as a promotion and retention reward when he was appointed.4

A natural question, then, is: why not simply pay these executives with salary? The

answer lies in agency theory. Berle and Means (1932) were the first to note that the separation

of corporate ownership and control results in a conflict of interests between shareholders (the

principal) and managers (the agent). Unlike shareholders, managers do not necessarily want to

maximize firm value. Instead, they may want to engage in empire building, spend money on

pet projects that do not create value or consume corporate assets. Because shareholders cannot

perfectly observe the actions of managers, there is a need for incentive alignment in order to

reduce agency costs. A well known solution is to make managers themselves owners of the

firm by giving them an equity share. This is exactly the reasoning behind Mr. Job’s

compensation package as formulated by Apple:

“While Mr. Jobs served as CEO, the Company believed that

his level of stock ownership significantly aligned his interests

with shareholders’ interests; therefore, his total compensation

consisted of $1 per year.

- Apple’s 2012 Proxy Statement

While the theory described above may sound perfectly reasonable, in the end I am

interested in whether executive ownership really is effective in increasing firm performance.

This is the main topic my thesis. More specifically, I replicate and extend the research of

1 Source: Apple Inc. proxy statements. 2 Source: Google Inc. proxy statements. 3 For instance, Steve Jobs was granted options worth over 500 million USD in 2001 and restricted stock grants worth 75 million USD in 2003 (source: Compustat ExecuComp). 4 Based on the adjusted closing price of Apple stock on the day of his promotion (August 24, 2011), this reward was worth 374,920,000 USD.

5

Himmelberg, Hubbard and Palia (1999), hereafter referred to as HHP. My main research

question is as follows:

Is there an empirical link between managerial equity ownership and firm performance?

An impressive body of literature on the relationship between executive ownership and

firm performance already exists. The need for further examination stems from the fact that the

empirical evidence has not led to consensus on the matter. On the contrary, there is a wide

variety in observed ownership-performance relations. I rely on HHP’s methodology because

they point out a serious flaw in many other studies. According to HHP, ownership and

performance are partly determined by common characteristics. Failing to control for these

characteristics would result in spurious correlations. Addressing this endogeneity problem of

(unobserved) omitted variables is at the heart of their study.

Before I focus on the ownership-performance relation, I first examine the determinants

of executive ownership. Whereas Jensen and Meckling (1976) associate low levels of

ownership with suboptimal compensation design, HHP argue that ‘the compensation contracts

observed in the data are endogenously determined by the contracting environment, which

differs across firms in both observable and unobservable ways’. Put differently, the severity of

the moral hazard problem will differ across firms and as a result, some managers may need

less equity for incentive alignment. Apart from gaining insight into how equity compensation

is determined, the variation in ownership explained by unobservable, time-invariant factors

informs us on the possible endogeneity of ownership in regressions on firm performance.

As an extension to the HHP investigation, I try to identify an ownership-performance

relation by separating firms on the basis of share liquidity, agency costs and institutional

ownership. I hypothesize that the relationship is stronger for firms whose shares are relatively

liquid because managers will prefer liquid shares to illiquid ones. Agency costs give an

indication of the scope for moral hazard and could therefore weaken the relationship. Lastly,

institutional investors may want to actively monitor managers because of their large equity

holdings, thereby strengthening the relationship.

My findings are not in favor of using managerial equity as a mechanism for incentive

alignment. Like HHP, I find no convincing evidence for an ownership-performance relation,

after controlling for unobserved heterogeneity. The only evidence I find for a correlation is

tentative at best, and results from splitting the sample on the basis of share liquidity. This

finding suggests that managers may indeed be more motivated to maximize shareholder value

6

if they can easily sell their shares. Regarding the determinants of ownership, I reject HHP’s

statement that observable firm characteristics are strong predictors. However, I corroborate

that managerial equity stakes are largely determined by unobserved heterogeneity at the firm

level.

This thesis makes three contributions to the literature. First, it examines the

ownership-performance relation using a very extensive data set (22,463 firm-year

observations) consisting of recent data (2000-2010). Second, it shows that the variables used

by HHP to instrument executive ownership are actually not strong instruments. Third, it

documents how controlling for mediators such as liquidity can help uncover evidence of an

ownership-performance relation.

The remainder of this thesis is organized as follows. In section 2, I discuss the relevant

literature and develop my hypotheses. Section 3 describes our data, discusses the endogeneity

issue in an analytical framework, and describes the tests we run. In section 4, I present my

empirical results and interpret them. Section 5 concludes.

2. Hypothesis Development

2.1 Determinants of managerial ownership

While not directly investigating the determinants of managerial ownership, Demsetz and Lehn

(1985) show that firm risk has a significant and positive effect on the degree of ownership

concentration. According to them, ‘firms that transact in markets characterized by stable

prices, stable technology, stable market shares, and so forth are firms in which managerial

performance can be monitored at relatively low cost. In less predictable environments,

however, managerial behavior simultaneously figures more prominently in a firm’s fortunes

and becomes more difficult to monitor.’ Extending this argument to the determination of

executive ownership, the riskier the firm, the higher the equity stake that should be given to

managers (all else equal). However, there is also a potential offsetting incentive effect since

more equity means more idiosyncratic risk that cannot be diversified away. HHP seek to find

which of these effects prevails by controlling for other variables proxying for the scope for

moral hazard. These include firm size, capital intensity, R&D expenses, advertising expenses,

market power and investment rate. They find that idiosyncratic stock price risk is actually

associated with lower levels of managerial ownership. Moreover, observable firm

characteristics in the contracting environment strongly predict managerial equity levels and in

7

predicted ways, i.e. consistent with the principal-agent model. Using the same set of

explanatory variables as HHP, I test if these ‘logical’ relations still hold based on recent data

and therefore formulate the following hypothesis:

H1 Managerial ownership is determined by observable characteristics in the contracting

environment in ways that are consistent with the principal-agent model.

2.2 The ownership-performance relation

As mentioned in the Introduction, there is an impressive body of literature on this relation.

Mørck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988) consider a cross-section of fortune 500 firms and estimate

a piecewise-linear relation between board ownership and Tobin’s Q, the most commonly used

measure of firm valuation/performance. They do this because they suspect that managerial

ownership affects firm valuation differently dependent on the level of equity holdings. More

specifically, two effects are distinguished: the convergence-of-interests and the entrenchment

effect. The latter is explained as follows: ‘A manager who controls a substantial fraction of

the firm’s equity may have enough voting power or influence more generally to guarantee his

employment with the firm. […] With effective power, the manager may indulge his

preference for non-value maximizing behavior’. This theory is more or less supported by their

results, as the relation is increasing for ownership levels between 0% and 5%, decreasing

between 5% en 25% en increasing beyond 25%. The Mørck et al. study was later replicated

by McConnell and Servaes (1990), Cho (1998) and Holderness, Kroszner and Sheehan

(1999), providing mixed results.5 In addition, McConnell and Servaes (1990) use a quadratic

specification of ownership and find an inverted U-shaped relation. Their evidence suggests

that the entrenchment effect dominates the incentive alignment effect when managerial equity

stakes reach 40% to 50%.

An important caveat to the above findings is that ownership is treated as an exogenous

explanatory variable in regressions for firm performance. Jensen and Warner (1988, p. 11)

note that this assumption is likely to result in spurious correlations because executive

ownership and firm performance may be influenced by common characteristics. HHP give

some really intuitive examples. For instance, a firm that has access to a superior monitoring

technology will not need to give its managers high levels of ownership to align incentives. At

the same time, there is less scope for managers to engage in non-value maximizing activities, 5 The relation for the 0-5% range of ownership is corroborated by all, but not for the other ranges.

8

resulting in a higher valuation. Not accounting for this characteristic in the firm’s contracting

environment leads to a negative ownership-performance relation, which is obviously

misleading. Hence, many researchers claim that ownership should be treated as endogenous.

This is what Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) do and they also find a significant non-

monotonic relation. Other studies accounting for endogeneity (like Demsetz and Villalonga

(2001) and HHP), however, show that ownership fails to explain variations in firm

performance.

Clearly, the literature does not provide a common view on the ownership-performance

relation. Using Tobin’s Q as measure of firm performance and building on the theory of

Mørck et al., I test the following hypothesis:

H2 Managerial ownership affects firm performance in accordance with the theoretical

notions of incentive alignment and managerial entrenchment.

Because the literature shows that it is generally hard to even identify a relationship between

managerial equity ownership and firm performance, I formulate three hypotheses concerning

specific circumstances that may strengthen or weaken the relation. The first is related to the

liquidity of firms’ shares. Everything else equal, managers will prefer liquid shares to illiquid

shares as they know they can easily convert these into cash at going market prices. I therefore

expect liquid shares to provide managers with stronger incentive effects. Another reason why

liquidity may affect the ownership-performance relation is that firms whose shares are

relatively liquid are probably more transparent than others; traders know their information to

be reliable and trade accordingly. Being more transparent, managers will be more inclined to

pursue value maximization. I thus hypothesize:

H3 The more liquid a firm’s shares are, the more positive is the ownership-performance

relationship.

Besides share liquidity, agency costs may also affect the ownership-performance

relationship. High agency costs indicate a strong need for monitoring because there is a scope

for managers to use corporate assets for their own benefit. The greater this scope, the less

effective an equity stake in the firm is in aligning incentives with shareholders (all else equal).

9

My fourth hypothesis is thus:

H4 The lower a firm’s agency costs are, the more positive is the ownership-performance

relationship.

Most of the studies mentioned earlier in this section do not solely focus on managerial

ownership but on ownership structure as a whole. Some, like Demsetz and Villalonga (2001),

include the fraction of shares owned by a firm’s largest shareholders in their regressions for

firm performance because it may influence the relation we try to identify in this thesis. The

reasoning is straightforward: large shareholders have a greater incentive to monitor executives

compared to smaller investors (who typically also lack the required expertise). Since

institutional investors generally hold large amounts of shares, I hypothesize:

H5 The higher the concentration of institutional ownership is, the more positive is the

ownership-performance relationship.

On a final note, addressing another issue of endogeneity, reverse causality, is not within the

scope of this thesis. Studies like Kole (1996), Cho (1998) and Demsetz et al. (2001) claim that

their evidence suggests that firm performance actually causes managerial ownership, i.e.

executives are rewarded with shares of stock if they do well. While I do not ignore their

findings, there at least seems to be some room for interpretation as HHP point out so I leave

this issue for future research.

3. Data and methodology

3.1 Data

The sample used in this study consists of all Compustat ExeCucomp firms for which

additional information on firm characteristics (accounting information) is available in the

CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over the period 2000-2010. The ExecuComp data set

contains information on various types of executive compensation, including the percentage of

total shares owned by executives.6 It is from this figure that I construct my various ownership

variables. The CRSP/Compustat Merged data set contains information on balance sheet and

6 Excluding still to be exercised options.

10

income statement items, which I need for examining the determinants of managerial

ownership and as controls in regressions for firm performance. I retrieved holding period

returns and information on share liquidity from CRSP. Finally, Thomson Reuters provides me

with measures of institutional ownership that I use for a sample split. Table 1 in the Appendix

provides a detailed description of how I constructed each variable and where I retrieved the

(underlying) variables from.

When I merge all the data into one file, I end up with a sample that is, to my

knowledge, much larger than any sample previously used in studies on this particular topic. In

total, I have 22,463 firm-year observations on 2,559 firms over a period of 11 years. To put

this in perspective, HHP, Mørck et al. (1988) and Demsetz et al. (2001) examine 600, 500 and

223 firms, respectively. Moreover, these and several other studies only consider specific

subsets of firms. For example, HHP and Demsetz et al. (2001) require their sample to have no

missing observations on certain variables while Mørck et al. (1988) restrict themselves to

examining Fortune 500 firms. Since I do not impose any such restriction on my observations,

I would argue that besides being more extensive, my sample is also more random because the

sample selection bias is less severe. Lastly, the data I am using has a panel structure, i.e. it

contains repeated observations over the same units (in this case: firms). This allows me to

control for unobserved firm heterogeneity in our regressions with firm-fixed effects. Section

3.2 will elaborate on this.

To get a first impression of the relation between managerial ownership and firm

performance, the scatter plot in figure 1 displays all observed combinations of the fraction of

shares owned by managers and Tobin’s Q, a market-to-book ratio which proxies for firm

performance. Like all of my other variables, fraction of ownership and Tobin’s Q have been

censored at the 1st and 99th percentiles to prevent distortion of our estimates. Note that I

cannot make any inferences on the ownership-performance relationship based solely on figure

1 since both ownership and performance may be influenced by common characteristics (this is

related to the endogeneity problem described previously). Our models described in section 3.3

will try to control for these characteristics.

11

Figure 1: Scatter plot of Tobin’s Q on the fraction of shares owned by managers

Figure 1 does not show a clear correlation between managerial ownership and firm

performance. With a bit of imagination, one can discern a somewhat downward sloping

relation in the scatter plot. This observation would not correspond to the theory discussed in

section 2 since I expect managerial ownership to positively affect firm performance, at least at

lower levels of ownership. Then again, when looking at the lowest levels of firm performance

at a given level of managerial ownership, performance seems to be slightly increasing with

ownership. I rely on OLS and instrumental variables models to determine the exact

relationship (if there is one).

Table 2 in the Appendix reports means, medians, standard deviations, minima and

maxima of our dependent and independent variables. A comparison with HHP would be very

informative here but unfortunately, they do not report summary statistics in their study. In any

case, our average fraction of executive ownership of 2.74% is well below the averages found

in other studies. For example, Mørck et al. (1988) and McConnell and Servaes (1990) report

average ownership stakes of 10.6% and 11.84%, 7 respectively. It is unlikely that this

difference is attributable to the nature of our sample since McConnell and Servaes (1990) also

consider a large sample consisting of firms from various industries. A more logical

7 Average executive ownership for their 1986 sample.

05

10

15

Tob

in's

Q

0 .1 .2 .3 .4Fraction of shares owned by managers

12

explanation is that these studies are relatively old, dating back to the late 1980s/early 1990s,

and firms’ capital stocks have grown in size since then. In any case, the average fraction of

executive ownership has gone down percentagewise even though absolute values of

managerial ownership have risen over the years (Frydman and Jenter, 2010). Regarding

Tobin’s Q, my observed average of 1.82 is higher than those found in older studies. 8

However, these values are still within one standard deviation of my average � (1.13) so the

difference is not statistically significant.

3.2 Econometric problem

To get a better understanding of why I use the models described later in this section, I first

look at the endogeneity problem in an econometric way by considering the analytical

framework developed by HHP. This framework is based on the assumption that management

compensation contracts, designed by firm owners (shareholders), include shares of equity for

the purpose of aligning managers’ interests with those of the shareholders. I also assume that

other means by which agency costs can be reduced are exhausted so that managerial equity

stakes must address the residual agency costs. Now, let ��� be the fraction of shares owned by

the managers of firm � at time � and let ��� and �� be vectors of observable and unobservable

characteristics (unobserved firm heterogeneity) for firm � at time � . ��� is determined by

observable firm characteristics (���) such as the scope for moral hazard and firm risk but also

by unobservable firm characteristics (�� ) such as a firm’s monitoring technology and

intangible assets. Note that the unobservable firm characteristics are considered to be time-

invariant, i.e. they are relatively constant for each firm. This assumption allows me to use

fixed effects estimation which I will elaborate on later in this section. Putting the above in a

simple model yields:

��� ���� � ��� � ��� (1)

where ��� represents an error term which captures all unobserved factors that are not

correlated over time.

Once managers know what share of equity they are given, they set their effort level,

��� , accordingly. This effort level will also be influenced by the firm’s observable and 8 For example, Mørck et al. (1988) report an average � of 0.85 while Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) find an

average � of 1.13.

13

unobservable characteristics. For example, managers of firms with a superior monitoring

technology will put in more effort, everything else equal. Hence the following linear relation:

��� ���� � ���� � ��� � ��� (2)

where ��� is an error term. I now have the ingredients to construct a relation for firm

performance, which is captured by Tobin’s Q, a measure of firm value. I assume it depends on

managers’ level of effort and observed and unobserved firm characteristics. Hence:

��� ���� � ���� � ��� � ��� (3)

with ��� being the error term. Inserting equation (2) into (3) allows managerial ownership,

���, to be put back into the equation for firm performance:

��� ����� � ��� � ����� � �� � � ���� � ���� � ��� (4)

Simplifying equation (4) results in the regression specification used by Mørck et al. (1988) to

estimate the effect of ownership on performance with ordinary least squares (OLS):

��� �� � ����� � ����� � ��� (5)

where ��� is the simplified version of �� � � ���� � ���� � ���. The problem with equation

(5) is that the coefficients on managerial ownership and observed firm characteristics can only

be estimated consistently if the error term ��� is uncorrelated with both ��� and ���. Since the

choice of how much shares to give to managers is based partially on unobserved firm

characteristics, cov(���,���) ≠ 0 and thus equation (5) cannot be estimated consistently with

OLS.

In order to remedy the problem formulated above, I control for unobserved firm

heterogeneity by including a firm fixed effect for each firm. This is essentially a firm-specific

dummy that purges the effect of �� from the error term, thereby making OLS a suitable

estimator again.

14

3.3 Methods

I estimate equation (6) to test my first hypothesis (‘Managerial ownership is determined by

observable characteristics in the contracting environment in ways that are consistent with the

principal-agent model’):

ln � ���1 ���! " � �#�$��� � �#�$���

� � �#�%���� � &#�%��'������� ()�*+,�-���.�� � /)�*+,�-���.��� � 01�*2��34��*��� 56&'�� � 86&''������ � ��9+��*��:�;%��� ��9+��*��:�;%'������ � ��<;��:���;�6������ ��=��*'����� � �� � ���

(6)

where � and � represent firm and time, � is a firm fixed effect and � is an error term. The

fraction of managerial ownership � is captured in a logarithmic function to be able to express

changes in the explanatory variables into percentage changes in ownership. All of the

explanatory variables, except for #�%��, are proxies for the scope for discretionary spending

or, more generally, for the scope for moral hazard. Important to note here is that I cannot

assume the error term to be independently and identically distributed since a) there is a

potential for serial correlation because of the panel structure of my data (cov(���, ���) ≠ 0) and

b) the variance of the error term is likely to differ across firms (var ��� ≠ σ2, i.e.

heteroskedasticity). To deal with this problem, I use robust standard errors which are clustered

around firms (Peterson, 2009). Like all other regression models discussed in this section, save

the ones on sample splits, I also estimate equation (6) for specifications with pooled data and

industry fixed effects. This will tell us something about the extent to which managerial

ownership is endogenously determined by the contracting environment. I discuss the expected

relations between executive ownership and the explanatory variables, borrowed from HHP,

below.

The effects of #�$� and #�$��, measured as the natural log of sales and the natural log

of sales squared, on managerial ownership are unclear a priori. I include them nonetheless

because Kole (1995) claims that differences in firm size can account for disparities between

studies concerning the ownership-performance relation. HHP offer arguments in favor of a

positive as well as a negative relationship. Firm size could positively affect managerial stakes

because it is harder to monitor managers of large firms and because large firms are likely to

15

hire more skilled managers who demand a higher share of ownership. An argument in favor

of a negative relationship is that large firms enjoy economies of scale in monitoring managers.

I include #�$�� to allow for nonlinear relations.

The effect of firm-specific risk, captured by #�%��, on managerial stakes is also not

evident a priori. On the one hand, the riskier a firm, the easier it is for managers to engage in

non-value-maximizing activities while staying unnoticed, as argued by Demsetz and Lehn

(1985). HHP favor a second interpretation. They argue that the added risk to managers’

portfolios from owning volatile stocks is not easily hedged (firm-specific risk cannot even be

hedged at all). Therefore, the risk inherent to firm stock may not give managers the desired

incentive beyond a certain level of ownership. #�%��'���� is simply a dummy variable

that allows me to account for the possibility that firms for which #�%�� can be calculated

(#�%��'���� = 1)9 are inherently different from firms for which it cannot.

)�*+,�-���. and )�*+,�-���.�, the ratios of hard capital to sales and hard capital

to sales squared (to allow for nonlinear relations), represent a firm’s easier to monitor assets.

Hard capital is defined here as a firm’s property, plant and equipment. These are tangible,

long-term assets and thus easily monitored. One would therefore expect )�*+,�-���. to be

negatively related to managerial ownership.

I expect 1�*2��34��*, 6&' , 9+��*��:�;% and <;��:���;�6��� to be positively

related to managerial ownership. I measure a firm’s market power by using the ratio of

operating income to sales, the rationale being that firms with more market power are generally

more profitable. Managers of powerful firms will be less disciplined by market forces,

resulting in a greater need for incentive alignment. This need will also be present for firms

that spend relatively large amounts on research and development (R&D) and advertising since

both types of spending are vulnerable to managerial discretion. The dummy variables

6&''���� and 9+��*��:�;%'���� are included to distinguish between reporting and

non-reporting firms. My last measure for the scope for discretionary spending,

<;��:���;�6���, is given by the ratio of capital expenditures to hard capital. This ratio

proxies for the link between high growth and opportunities for discretionary projects.

9 A minimum of 20 daily returns on a yearly basis is used as a requirement to calculate a meaningful Sigma.

16

In addition to the dependent variable based on the fraction of managerial ownership �,

I also use the log of average equity holdings per manager, calculated as the value of common

shares outstanding times the fraction of shares owned by managers divided by the number of

managers, as dependent variable for examining the determinants of executive ownership:

ln����� " � ��� � �� � ��� (7)

where � is the shorthand notation for the observable explanatory variables in equation (6).

Equation (7) serves as an extra test for H1 since I expect to see roughly the same results. The

advantage of using average ownership over the fraction of ownership is that people are

ultimately motivated by money rather than by the fraction of shares they own. Moreover, �

takes into account the number of managers (typically 5 per firm) while � does not.

To test my second hypothesis (‘Managerial ownership affects firm performance in

accordance with the theoretical notions of incentive alignment and managerial

entrenchment’) I estimate the impact of managerial ownership on firm value, represented by

Tobin’s Q, in several ways. First, I use two specifications of managerial ownership in a

regression for Q while controlling for unobserved firm characteristics:

��� ���� � ����� � ���� � �� � ��� (8)

��� ��1�� � ��2�� � ��3�� � &��� � �� � ��� (9)

McConnel and Servaes (1990) use the quadratic specification in their study as in (8)

while Mørck et al. (1988) use the spline specification as in (9) to allow for different slope

coefficients for different regions of ownership levels (see table 1 in the Appendix for the

interpretation of �1, �2 and �3). These specifications may allow me to identify when, if at

all, the entrenchment effect dominates the incentive effect. I also estimate equations (8) and

(9) using only the managerial ownership variables and the non-investment set of observable

variables. Once again, I estimate all specifications for pooled data, industry effects and fixed

effects, resulting in a total of eighteen regressions.

An alternative approach to solving the endogeneity problem is instrumental variables

estimation. A good instrument of � and �� is correlated with these variables (the instrument

should be relevant) but not with the error term in the � regression and not with � itself (the

instrument should be exogenous). If the instrument does affect performance by itself, then it

17

should be included in the Q regression to prevent biasedness of the estimators. The idea here

is that the instrumental variable affects firm performance only through its effect on

managerial ownership, resulting in better estimates for � and ��. I use the same variables as

HHP to instrument the ownership variables, namely #�$� , #�$�� , #�%�� and

#�%��'���� 10 . Applying the two stage least squares (2SLS) method results in the

following model:

��� "� ��� � �� � ��� (10)

���� � ���� � �� � ��� (11)

��� A ��B �� ��B ��� � ��� � �� � $�� (12)

where ", and A are constants, � is the full set of control variables, � is the set of

control variables without #�$�, #�$��, #�%�� and #�%��'����, � is the firm fixed effect

and �, � and $ are error terms. Equation (10) and (11) make up the first stage of the 2SLS

method that provides me with the fitted values of the endogenous ownership variables needed

for the second stage, denoted by equation (12). A first-stage F-test will make clear whether

my instruments are weak or strong based on the variation they explain in � and �� while a

Hansen’s J-test informs me about the exogeneity of the instruments. Again, I also estimate the

IV model using pooled data and industry fixed effects.

Lastly, I try to identify an ownership-performance relation by splitting the sample

based on firm liquidity, agency costs and institutional ownership. Firm liquidity is proxied by

share turnover and two differently computed bid-ask spreads, agency costs are proxied by the

ratio of cash to assets and by the ratio of SG&A expenses to sales, and institutional ownership

is proxied by the fraction of shares held by institutional investors and by institutional

blockholders (see the table 1 in the Appendix for more details on these variables). To test H3,

H4 and H5, I run the same regression as in equation (8) on samples split at the median of the

variable of interest for each year and for the entire sample period. In addition, I also split the

samples into quantiles for each year and for the entire sample period. This makes for a total of

56 regressions (considering I only use firm fixed effects specifications here). Then I compare

the coefficients on ownership for the top and bottom 20% of the sample, expecting a greater

difference when comparing the top 50% against the bottom 50%. I formally test for the

difference between coefficients with a Chow test.

10 There are reasons to believe that these are correlated with ownership but not with performance nor with omitted variables (HHP, p. 379).

18

4. Empirical results

4.1 Determinants of ownership

Table 3A in the Appendix reports the estimated coefficients on the determinants of the

fraction of executive equity ownership.11 Turning first to the estimates of the pooled model in

column (1), I observe that only R&D expenditures have a significant (and unexpected) impact

on managerial stakes, apart from the coefficient on #�$�� which is only marginally

significant. This is quite a surprising result, considering that HHP mention that the fraction of

executive ownership is affected by nearly all regressors for pooled data. Moving to column

(2) where I control for unobserved industry heterogeneity by including industry fixed effects,

I observe that the coefficient on Size2 is no longer significant while the effect of R&D

expenses persists, although it is smaller. In terms of economic significance, a one-standard-

deviation increase in R&D expenses leads to an average decrease in ownership stakes of

2.81%,12 which is a modest effect. Moreover, the coefficient on <;��:���;�6��� has now

become marginally significant and, like the one on 6&', with a sign that runs counter to my

theoretical predictions. Finally, column (3) reports estimates for the specification that includes

firm fixed effects. Now, increases in R&D expenses no longer negatively affect ownership

stakes (suggesting a correlation with unobserved firm characteristics) while the effect of a

firm’s investment rate has become slightly more pronounced in terms of statistical

significance. The economic impact of a one-standard-deviation increase in <;��:���;�6���

is a decrease of 1.88% 13 in managerial stock holdings, a negligible effect. A possible

explanation for this negative relation is that capital expenditures are investments in fixed

assets and, as I have argued before, these are easily monitored. The estimates in Table 3A

provide little support for my first hypothesis.

Table 3B reports estimates for the determinants of managerial ownership when

ownership is measured as the log of average equity holdings per manager. Again, column (1)

reports the estimates of the pooled model while columns (2) and (3) control for industry and

firm fixed effects, respectively. Although columns (1) and (2) suggest that there is a

significant relationship between some observable characteristics and ownership, only the

effect of idiosyncratic firm risk represented by #�%�a survives the inclusion of firm fixed

11 Note that our dummy variables SigmaDummy, R&DDummy and AdvertisingDummy are omitted from all regressions because of collinearity. 12 1.2714 F 0.0945 J 4.2789 13 0.4044 F 0.1990 J 4.2789

19

effects. This again provides evidence for a correlation between the observed and unobserved

characteristics. Consequently, estimates of the model with firm dummies will be more reliable

than those of the other models. In terms of economic significance, a one-standard-deviation

increase in #�%�� will result in a decrease average managerial stock holdings of 26.07%14,

which is considerable but not implausibly high. This finding is in line with the interpretation

that rewarding managers with risky firm stock comes at the cost of less portfolio

diversification and therefore may not lead to the desired incentive effects.

Everything considered, the results presented in Table 3A and 3B do not support the

hypothesis that observable characteristics in firms’ contracting environments determine

executive ownership in ways that are consistent with the principal-agent model. In fact,

ownership is not even affected at all by nearly all variables. This contradicts the findings of

HHP. Because ownership is largely explained by unobserved factors, it is essential to control

for unobserved firm heterogeneity when regressing firm performance (�) on ownership (�).

4.2.1 Determinants of firm performance: fixed effects estimation

Moving on to the determinants of �, table 4A and 4B report, respectively, the estimated

coefficients for the quadratic and spline specifications of ownership. Turning first to column

(1) of table 4A, both � and �� have a statistically significant effect on � when neither

observable firm characteristics nor any fixed effects (except for year effects) are controlled

for. This finding corresponds to those of studies that fail to account for the endogeneity

problem. If the observed estimates for � and �� in column (1) were trustworthy, it would

imply an inverted U-shape relation between � and � with an inflection point at an ownership

level of 21.59%, 15 a finding that is perfectly in line with my second hypothesis (the

entrenchment effect supposedly dominates the incentive effect when the fraction of ownership

exceeds 21.59%). In terms of economic significance, a one-standard-deviation increase in �

would result in an average increase of 6.98%16 in �. However, introducing industry effects in

column (2) results in an � that is only marginally significant and its significance is lost

altogether when I control for unobserved firm heterogeneity in column (3). Controlling for the

full set of control variables (columns (4) to (6)) and for the non-investment set of control

variables (columns (7) to (9)) also yields ownership coefficients that are practically never

statistically different from zero. I conclude from Table 4A that ownership is indeed an

14 25.3101 F 100 F 0.0103 15 This is calculated by taking the first order derivative of � with respect to ��� and solving for ���. 16 �2.4347 F 0.0601 5.6385 F 0.0601�� J 1.8187

20

endogenous variable in regressions for firm performance and that � and � are actually not

related, even though studies based on cross-sectional data claim the opposite. To my support,

HHP find roughly the same significance pattern for the quadratic specification of �.

The reported estimates from the spline specification of ownership in Table 4B provide

even less evidence for an ownership-performance relation. Only �1 is statistically significant

in the pooled model without any other controls (column (1)). Its coefficient of 2.7106

indicates an increase of 2.73%17 in firm performance when ownership below a level of 5% is

raised by one standard deviation, an economic effect that can hardly be called significant. The

inclusion of industry effects, firm effects and observable contracting determinants in columns

(2) through (8) results in insignificant ownership coefficients, apart from the one on �2 in

column (7). Although it is not obvious why there is some significance here, I know this

estimate to be unreliable because it is not robust to the inclusion of industry and firm effects.

In conclusion, Table 4A and 4B cast serious doubt on empirical findings from studies

that fail to control for unobserved heterogeneity, be it at the industry level or at the firm level.

Both specifications of ownership are not even robust to the inclusion of only observable firm

characteristics. Something else worth mentioning is that practically all ownership variables

have the predicted signs, even though they are not statistically significant. For example,

nearly all estimations in Table 4A signal an inverted U-shaped pay-performance relation

(corroborating McConnell and Servaes (1990)) while the signs on �1, �2 and �3 in Table

4B suggest that increasing ownership up to a level of 25% increases performance and

decreases it thereafter.

4.2.2 Determinants of firm performance: IV estimation

Can I now safely conclude that managerial stakes do not influence performance? No, because

the panel data method used previously might not be the best method to estimate the real

population parameter on ownership. For instance, fixed effects estimation does not solve the

problem of time-varying omitted variables (Wooldridge, 2009). Table 5 reports instrumental

variable estimates for � and �� with #�$� , #�$�� , #�%�� and #�%��'���� 18 as

instruments. As usual, column (1) includes no fixed effects apart from year effects, column

(2) includes industry effects and column (3) includes firm effects. One immediately notices

the extremely high (and insignificant) estimates and corresponding standard errors on � and

17 2.7106 F 0.0183 J 1.8187 18 Which is again dropped in both stages of 2SLS because of being collinear to one of the other explanatory variables.

21

��. This is what happens when the instrumental variables explain only a small fraction of the

variation in the instrumented variables (Wooldridge, 2009, p. 511 and p. 515). Our first-stage

F-test statistics confirms the weak correlation between the instruments and the ownership

variables. According to Stock and Watson’s rule of thumb (Stock and Watson, 2011), this

statistic should be at least 10 in order to reject the hypothesis that the instruments are jointly

zero. Clearly, I cannot reject this hypothesis for any of the estimations reported in Table 5.

Moreover, one could have already predicted the above findings simply by looking at Table

3A: none of the instruments are significantly related to the fraction of executive equity

holdings. Even though I cannot reject the exogeneity of my instruments (the p-value of a

Hansen’s J-test is above 0.10 in each column), the ones used by HHP are certainly not

suitable for this particular sample. Because the other explanatory variables do not satisfy the

requirements for an instrumental variable either, IV estimation does not help identify the

effect of ownership on performance.

4.2.3 Determinants of firm performance: sample splits

Turning to the last possibility of detecting an ownership effect, Table 6 reports results from

splitting the sample on the basis of the liquidity of a firm’s shares. Three proxies for liquidity

are used: share turnover, a bid-ask spread based on end-of-month closing prices and a bid-ask

spread based on daily closing prices. Column (1) reports estimates for firms which have a

share turnover above the median share turnover, which is calculated for each sample year.

Column (2) reports estimates for firms which have a share turnover below the median share

turnover. Unobserved firm heterogeneity is controlled for in both columns, which is also true

for columns (3)-(6). The coefficient on � is marginally significant in both columns, with a

positive sign for firms that have a share turnover above the median and with a negative sign

for firms that belong to the below-median group. In line with our predictions, the observed

signs suggest that managers who are actually able to sell their shares at market prices are

more motivated to maximize shareholder value than managers who are rewarded with less

liquid stock. The negative coefficient in column (2) even indicates that compensation in the

form of illiquid firm stock has an adverse effect on firm performance. Columns (3) and (4),

which report estimates for firms that face below and above median end-of-month bid-ask

spreads, 19 respectively, support the previously mentioned findings. The coefficients on � and

�� imply an inverted U-shaped relation between managerial stock holdings and performance

19 Recall that low bid-ask spreads are associated with liquid shares.

22

with an inflection point at an ownership level of 17.53% for firms in the above-median group.

In addition, the impact of a one-standard-deviation increase in � results in a 7.70%20 change

in �, which is large enough to be economically significant. In columns (5) and (6), however,

the ownership coefficients are no longer significant and this is reflected by the p-value of the

Chow test. Whereas the ownership variables were statistically significantly different before

(p-values below or practically below 0.10), I cannot reject the hypothesis that the ownership

coefficients are different for columns (5) and (6). This also holds for all estimated coefficients

from regressions on samples split at the median of each liquidity variable calculated for the

entire sample period. The same is true when all previously described regressions are done for

the top and bottom 20% firms in terms of share liquidity. Although this casts some doubt on

the results reported in Table 6, 21 separating firms by share liquidity does seem to be a

potential starting point on the basis of which an ownership-performance relation can be

identified. I therefore do not accept, nor reject H3.

Regarding all regressions for samples split on the basis of variables proxying agency

costs and institutional ownership, I did not include any tables because I nowhere find

significant ownership coefficients. Therefore, there is no evidence that supports H4 and H5.

5. Conclusion

This thesis replicates and extends the study by Himmelberg, Hubbard and Palia

(1999), who found little evidence that executive equity holdings and firm performance are

related. Given that my research is based on recent data (2000-2010) and a very extensive data

set compared to other research in the field, I first show that managerial stakes are hardly

determined by observable factors in the contracting environment. As a result, I reject the

hypothesis that managerial ownership is determined by observable characteristics in ways

consistent with the principal-agent model. Instead, I find that the variation in ownership is

largely determined by unobserved factors at the firm level. This signals the need for

controlling for unobserved firm heterogeneity in the regression for firm performance

(represented by Tobin’s Q). Failing to do so would result in inconsistent estimates for the

explanatory variables. I also find that the effect of executive ownership on performance is not

20 �2.8138 F 0.0601 8.0263 F 0.0601��/1.8187 21 Since we expected that the difference between ownership coefficients would be more pronounced when comparing the top and bottom 20% firms.

23

robust to the inclusion of industry and firm dummies, thereby casting serious doubt on the

findings of studies that fail to account for unobserved heterogeneity.

As an alternative to fixed effects, I use instrumental variables to control for the

endogeneity of ownership in the � regression. My results show that the instruments used by

HHP are certainly not suitable for my sample. Again, I do not find evidence for a correlation

between the two variables of interest.

Extending the HHP study, I try to identify an ownership-performance relation by

separating firms on the basis of share liquidity, agency costs and institutional ownership.

Hypothesizing that the relation is stronger for firms with liquid shares, low agency costs and

high institutional ownership, I only find some tentative evidence for a correlation when our

sample is split on the basis of liquidity. This suggests that managers are more motivated and

thus perform better when they are rewarded with liquid stocks instead of illiquid stocks.

All in all, my results provide little evidence by which to reject the hypothesis that

managerial equity ownership and firm performance are unrelated. However, I do not ignore

the fact that certain aspects of my thesis are being questioned by other researchers (and maybe

rightly so). For example, Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) provide arguments against the use of

Tobin’s Q as a proxy for firm performance22 and point out that managers do not necessarily

share common interests. Zhou (2001) even devotes an entire article to the HHP study,

criticizing the use of within variation for resolving the issue at hand. Additionally, I noted

earlier that fixed effects estimation does not solve the problem of time-varying omitted

variables (Wooldridge, 2009). Lastly, my thesis does not address the possibility that

managerial ownership is actually determined by firm performance as argued by Kole (1996),

though HHP claim that their results allow for a different interpretation.

Future research could focus on a variety of issues pertaining to the ownership-

performance relation. Instrumental variable estimation still seems like a viable method for

identifying a relationship, the difficulty being finding proper instruments. One should look for

policy or regulatory changes that do not affect firm value but do affect ownership on a cross-

sectional level. Another avenue of inquiry is exploring other factors that strengthen or weaken

the relationship. For example, CEOs are more likely to influence firm value than COOs

(Chief Operations Officers) which may be reflected by different ownership coefficients.

Finally, stock options may be used as alternative mechanism for incentive alignment.

22 As well as against its most logical replacement, accounting profit.

24

6. References

Berle, A., Means, G., 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York:

Harcourt, Brace and World.

Cho, M. 1998. Ownership structure, investment, and the corporate value: an empirical

analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 47, pp. 103-121.

Demsetz, H., Lehn, K., 1985. The structure of corporate ownership: causes and consequences.

Journal of Political Economy, vol. 93, pp. 1155-1177.

Demsetz, H., Villalonga, B., 2001. Ownership structure and corporate performance. Journal

of Corporate Finance, vol. 7, pp. 209-233.

Frydman, C., Jenter, D., 2010. CEO Compensation. Annual Review of Financial Economics,

vol. 2, pp. 75-102.

Hermalin, B., Weisbach, M., 1991. The effects of board compensation and direct incentives

on firm performance. Financial Management, vol. 20, pp. 101-112.

Himmelberg, C.P., Hubbard, R.G., Palia, D., 1999. Understanding the determinants of

managerial ownership and the link between ownership and performance. Journal of

Financial Economics, vol. 53, pp. 353-384.

Holderness, C., Kroszner, R., Sheehan, D., 1999. Were the good old days that good?

Evolution of managerial stock ownership and corporate governance since the great

depression. Journal of Finance, vol. 54, pp. 435-469.

Jensen, M., Meckling, W., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and

ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3, pp. 305-360.

Jensen, M., Warner, J., 1988. The distribution of power among corporate managers,

shareholders, and directors. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 20, pp. 3-24.

Kole, S., 1996. Managerial ownership and firm performance: incentives or rewards? Advances

in Financial Economics, vol. 2, pp. 119-149.

McConnell, J., Servaes, H., 1990. Additional evidence on equity ownership and corporate

value. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 27, pp. 595-612.

Morck, R., Schleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1988. Management ownership and market valuation.

Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 20, pp. 293-315.

Petersen, M.A., 2009. Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: comparing

approaches. Review of Financial Studies, vol. 22, pp. 435-480.

Wooldridge, J.M., 2009. Introductory Economics. Fourth edition. South-Western.

Zhou, X., 2001. Understanding the determinants of managerial ownership and the link

25

between ownership and performance: comment. Journal of Financial Economics,

Vol. 62, No. 3, pp. 559-571.

26

7. Appendix

Table 1

Variable Descriptions

� Tobin’s Q, a measure of firm performance. It is a market-to-book ratio

defined as firm value divided by the replacement value of the firm’s assets. I

calculate firm value by multiplying share price at fiscal year-end with the

number of common shares outstanding and adding the book value of total

liabilities. The replacement value of a firm’s assets is equal to the book

value of total assets. I retrieved these variables from Compustat and their

variables names are PRCC_F, CSHO, LT and AT, respectively.

� The total fraction of a firm’s shares owned by its managers. It is constructed

by dividing the Compustat ExecuComp variable

SHROW_EXCL_OPTS_PCT by 100. Other variables that represent

managerial ownership are adaptations of �.

�� The total fraction of a firm’s shares owned by its managers squared.

�1 The fraction of a firm’s shares owned by its managers up to and including

0.05.

�2 The fraction of a firm’s shares owned by its managers beyond 0.05 up to and

including 0.25. For example, if �=0.25 for company X, then �1=0.05 and

�2=0.20.

�3 The fraction of a firm’s shares owned by its managers beyond 0.25.

� Average equity holdings per manager. It is calculated by multiplying share

price at fiscal year-end with the number of common shares outstanding

times the fraction of shares held by top managers (�) divided by the number

of top managers. � is expressed in millions of dollars.

#�$� The natural logarithm of a firm’s sales. Firms’ sales are retrieved from

Compustat, where the variable is named SALE. #�$� is expressed in

millions of dollars.

#�$�� The natural logarithm of a firm’s sales squared. #�$�� is expressed in

millions of dollars squared.

#�%�� Share price volatility resulting from firm-specific risk. It is constructed by

first estimating ‘normal’ daily returns for each firm-year combination using

the CAPM model and then taking the standard deviation of the residuals.

Daily returns and market returns used for constructing #�%�� are retrieved

from CRSP and the Fama-French website, respectively.

#�%��'���� A dummy variable that takes the value 1 if a firm reports the required

information to construct #�%�� and 0 otherwise (at least 20 daily returns on

27

a yearly basis are required to construct a meaningful #�%��).

)�*+,�-���. A capital-to-sales ratio calculated as a firm’s power, plant and equipment

(representing ‘hard’ capital) divided by its sales. Power, plant and

equipment and sales are retrieved from Compustat. Their variable names are

PPENT and SALE, respectively.

)�*+,�-���.� A firm’s hard capital-to-sales ratio squared.

1�*2��34��* Operating income-to-sales, a ratio that proxies for a firm’s market power. It

is a measure for the scope for discretionary spending. Operating income is

retrieved from Compustat, where it is named OIBDP.

6&' The ratio of R&D expenditures to hard capital, a proxy for the scope for

discretionary spending. R&D expenditures are named RDIP in Compustat.

6&''���� A dummy variable that takes the value 1 if a firm reports R&D expenses and

0 if it does not.

9+��*��:�;% The ratio of a firm’s advertising spending to hard capital. Like MarketPower

and R&D, it proxies for the scope for discretionary spending. Advertising

expenses are retrieved from Compustat. Its variable name is XAD.

9+��*��:�;%'���� A dummy variable that takes the value 1 if a firm reports any advertising

expenses and 0 if it does not.

<;��:���;�6��� The ratio of capital expenditures to hard capital, another measure for the

scope for discretionary spending. Capital expenditures are retrieved from

Compustat. Its variable name is CAPX.

Share turnover Share turnover is calculated as the number of shares traded during a firm’s

fiscal year divided by the number of shares outstanding in that year. Their

Compustat variable names are CSHTR_F and CSHO, respectively. Share

turnover is not included in any regression but it is used to split the sample on

the basis of a firm’s share liquidity.

Bid-ask spread A second measure for a firm’s share liquidity. Two differently calculated

bid-ask spreads are used throughout this paper. One is a bid-ask spread

based on end of month bid-ask spreads which are readily available from

CRSP. This monthly bid-ask spread variable is named Spread Between Bid

and Ask. The other is a bid-ask spread based on daily differences between

bid and ask prices. Both are expressed in dollars and are named Closing Bid

and Closing Ask in CRSP.

Cash/assets A ratio that proxies for agency costs. Like our proxies for a firm’s share

liquidity, this variable is used for splitting our sample into ‘high’ and ‘low’

groups. Cash and assets are retrieved from Compustat. Their variable names

are CH and AT.

SG&A/sales The ratio of selling, general and administrative expenses to sales, a second

proxy for agency costs. SG&A expenses are retrieved from Compustat,

where it is named XSGA.

28

Institutional ownership Institutional ownership represents the fraction of shares that is held by

institutional investors. Like the proxies for share liquidity and agency costs,

it is used for splitting the sample. Institutional ownership is retrieved from

the Thomson Reuters database, where it is named Total Institutional

Ownership.

Instituional block ownership A second measure of institutional ownership. This variable is similar to the

previous one, except for the fact that it only includes institutional ownership

beyond a considerable level. This level is not explicitly mentioned by

Thomson Reuters but if one relies on the description of a variable called

‘Number of >5% Institutional Block Ownerships’, it is 5% of a firm’s

shares. The Thomson Reuters variable name for institutional block

ownership is Total Ownership by Institutional BlockHolders.

29

Table 2

Summary statistics

The table below reports summary statistics on all dependent and independent variables. These are all described

in detail in table 1 of the Appendix. The sample consists of all firms from Compustat’s ExecuComp data set of

which additional information on firm characteristics is available in the CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over

the period 2000—2010. The top and bottom 1% of observations on �, � and variables underlying the other

reported variables have been dropped to prevent distortion of our estimates.

Variable Mean Median St. Dev. Min Max N. Obs.

Q 1.8187 1.4338 1.1261 0.5766 13.4921 21,950

m 0.0274 0.0038 0.0601 0.0000 0.4265 19,935

m2 0.0044 0.0000 0.0168 0.0000 0.1819 19,935

m1 0.0135 0.0038 0.0183 0.0000 0.0500 19,935

m2 0.0125 0.0000 0.0400 0.0000 0.2000 19,935

m3 0.0014 0.0000 0.0115 0.0000 0.1765 19,935

e 25.0304 0.7011 379.964 0.0000 21,262.0900 19,927

Size 7.0240 6.9362 1.5680 2.4650 11.4945 21,944

Size2 51.7957 48.1110 22.6631 6.0764 132.1227 21,944

Sigma 0.0217 0.0192 0.0103 0.0034 0.0754 22,390

SigmaDummy 0.9968 1.0000 0.0569 0.0000 1.0000 22,463

HardCapital 0.3911 0.1787 0.6905 0.0005 31.5207 20,747

HardCapital2 0.6297 0.0319 7.9362 0.0000 993.5573 20,747

MarketPower 0.1705 0.1496 0.2140 -7.0907 0.9678 20,871

R&D 0.0083 0.0000 0.0945 0.0000 4.1320 17,820

R&DDummy 0.8494 1.0000 0.3577 0.0000 1.0000 22,463

Advertising 0.3421 0.0821 1.1956 0.0000 29.7071 8,864

AdvertisingDummy 0.4019 0.0000 0.4901 0.0000 1.0000 22,463

InvestmentRate 0.2472 0.1987 0.1990 0.0000 9.3339 20,256

30

Table 3

(A) Determinants of total managerial ownership

The table below reports the estimated coefficients from regressing managerial ownership, defined as ln(�/(1-

�)), on a set of control variables. These variables are all described in detail in the Appendix. #�%��'����,

6&''���� and 9+��*��:�;%'���� are not reported because of collinearity. Industry fixed effects (3-digit

SIC code) are controlled for in column (2). Firm fixed effects are controlled for in column (3). Year fixed effects

are controlled for in columns (1)-(3). Intercept terms and year dummies are included for all regressions but not

reported. The same is true for fixed effects where appropriate. Standard errors are robust, clustered around firms

and reported in parentheses. The sample consists of all firms from Compustat’s ExecuComp data set of which

additional information on firm characteristics is available in the CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over the

period 2000—2010. For robustness, all underlying variables have been censored at the 1st and 99th percentiles.

The symbols *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

Variable (1) (2) (3)

Size 0.3605 -0.2437 0.4552 (0.3205) (0.3971) (0.5152) Size2 -0.0383* -0.0073 -0.0517 (0.0228) (0.0286) (0.0374) Sigma 2.1729 -1.9676 3.2985 (7.0600) (6.8083) (6.8164) HardCapital -0.1952 0.3033 0.1408 (0.4026) (0.5542) (0.6242) HardCapital2 0.1109 -0.2022 -0.1912 (0.1785) (0.1999) (0.2124) MarketPower -0.1210 0.2816 -0.0896 (0.2665) (0.2483) (0.2127) R&D -1.8512*** -1.2714*** -0.2289 (0.5308) (0.4239) (0.2968) Advertising -0.0003 0.0081 -0.0118 (0.0287) (0.0252) (0.0589) InvestmentRate -0.2937 -0.4245* -0.4044** (0.2607) (0.2549) (0.2015) Industry f.e. No Yes No Firm f.e. No No Yes Year f.e. Yes Yes Yes N. Obs. 19,935 19,935 19,935 R2 0.0415 0.2148 0.7712 St. Errors Cluster Firm Firm Firm

31

Table 3 – Continued

(B) Determinants of average equity ownership per manager

The table below reports the estimated coefficients from regressing average equity ownership per manager,

defined as ln(�) to allow for comparison with Himmelberg, Hubbard and Palia (1999), on a set of control

variables. These variables are all described in detail in the Appendix. #�%��'���� , 6&''���� and

9+��*��:�;%'���� are not reported because of collinearity. Industry fixed effects (3-digit SIC code) are

controlled for in column (2). Firm fixed effects are controlled for in column (3). Year fixed effects are controlled

for in columns (1)-(3). Intercept terms and year dummies are included for all regressions but not reported. The

same is true for fixed effects where appropriate. Standard errors are robust, clustered around firms and reported

in parentheses. The sample consists of all firms from Compustat’s ExecuComp data set of which additional

information on firm characteristics is available in the CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over the period 2000—

2010. For robustness, all underlying variables have been censored at the 1st and 99th percentiles. The symbols *,

** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

Variable (1) (2) (3)

Size -0.0055 -0.0495 0.6516 (0.3531) (0.4150) (0.5667) Size2 0.0329 0.0344 -0.0158 (0.0254) (0.0297) (0.0414) Sigma -52.7045*** -50.6563*** -25.3101*** (9.3972) (8.9869) (7.5880) HardCapital 0.4551 1.8469*** 0.7389 (0.4445) (0.5951) (0.7066) HardCapital2 -0.0953 -0.6583*** 0.3531 (0.1879) (0.2123) (0.2349) MarketPower 1.6281** 1.4479* 0.4257 (0.7410) (0.7508) (0.3948) R&D -0.8354*** -0.6792** 0.0201 (0.3060) (0.3285) (0.4169) Advertising -0.0025 0.0223 0.0010 (0.0364) (0.0329) (0.0693) InvestmentRate 1.3370*** 0.8156*** 0.1818 (0.2992) (0.2852) (0.2257) Industry f.e. No Yes No Firm f.e. No No Yes Year f.e. Yes Yes Yes N. Obs. 19,935 19,935 19,935 R2 0.1989 0.3481 0.8134 St. Errors Cluster Firm Firm Firm

32

Table 4

(A) Determinants of firm performance (Tobin’s Q), quadratic specification

The table below reports the estimated coefficients from regressing firm performance, � , on measures of

managerial ownership, � and ��, and a set of control variables. These variables are all described in detail in the

Appendix. #�%��'���� , 6&''���� and 9+��*��:�;%'���� are not reported because of collinearity.

Industry fixed effects (3-digit SIC code) are controlled for in columns (2), (5) and (8). Firm fixed effects are

controlled for in columns (3), (6) and (9). Year fixed effects are controlled for in columns (1)-(9). Intercept terms

and year dummies are included for all regressions but not reported. The same is true for fixed effects where

appropriate. Standard errors are robust, clustered around firms and reported in parentheses. The sample consists

of all firms from Compustat’s ExecuComp data set of which additional information on firm characteristics is

available in the CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over the period 2000—2010. The top and bottom 1% of

observations on � and variables underlying the independent variables have been dropped to prevent distortion of

our estimates. The symbols *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level,

respectively.

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

m 2.4347*** 1.0563* 0.7187 0.8301 1.6848* 0.9259 0.6875 0.4573 0.5850 (0.7170) (0.5920) (0.6432) (1.0214) (0.9619) (0.9882) (0.7163) (0.6109) (0.6547) m2 -5.6385** 2.6447 -2.4792 0.6451 -2.8260 -3.4325 -0.3467 -0.5475 -2.4737 (2.2831) (1.8994) (1.9544) (3.1377) (3.0052) (3.0070) (2.2343) (1.9138) (2.0195) Size - - - -

0.7658*** -

0.6362*** -0.7656** -

0.7547*** -

0.6302*** -0.7322***

(0.1505) (0.1661) (0.3309) (0.0994) (0.0944) (0.1844) Size2 - - - 0.0460*** 0.0425*** 0.0298 0.0456*** 0.0403*** 0.0320** (0.0100) (0.0108) (0.0231) (0.0066) (0.0062) (0.0130) Sigma - - - -11.4597* -0.7418 11.2422*** 6.1775** 4.6120* 17.6040*** (6.3174) (6.0578) (4.1438) (2.5927) (2.4949) (2.3230) HardCapital - - - -0.1311 -0.2222 -2.2074*** -

0.4463*** -

0.3093*** -0.4269***

(0.2283) (0.2781) (0.4658) (0.0543) (0.0754) (0.0774) HardCapital2 - - - -0.1463* -0.0595 0.6228*** 0.0437*** 0.0327** 0.0341*** (0.0852) (0.0985) (0.1509) (0.0136) (0.0160) (0.0114) MarketPower - - - 1.9168*** 1.7627** 0.9847 1.0315*** 1.2219*** 0.9176*** (0.7124) (0.7896) (0.7665) (0.2130) (0.2496) (0.2064) R&D - - - 0.3316 0.1317 0.2251 - - - (0.2701) (0.2719) (0.1790) Advertising - - - 0.0038 0.0118 -0.0153 - - - (0.0317) (0.0309) (0.0426) InvestmentRate - - - 1.1366*** 1.1176*** 0.6581*** - - - (0.3358) (0.3110) (0.2377) Industry f.e. No Yes No No Yes No No Yes No Firm f.e. No No Yes No No Yes No No Yes Year f.e. Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N. Obs. 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 R2 0.1989 0.3481 0.8134 0.1903 0.3489 0.7293 0.1033 0.3170 0.6878 St. Errors Cluster

Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm

33

Table 4 – Continued

(B) Determinants of firm performance (Tobin’s Q), spline specification

The table below reports the estimated coefficients from regressing firm performance, � , on measures of

managerial ownership, �1, �2 and �3, and a set of control variables. These variables are all described in detail

in the Appendix. #�%��'���� , 6&''���� and 9+��*��:�;%'���� are not reported because of

collinearity. Industry fixed effects (3-digit SIC code) are controlled for in columns (2), (5) and (8). Firm fixed

effects are controlled for in columns (3), (6) and (9). Year fixed effects are controlled for in columns (1)-(9).

Intercept terms and year dummies are included for all regressions but not reported. The same is true for fixed

effects where appropriate. Standard errors are robust, clustered around firms and reported in parentheses. The

sample consists of all firms from Compustat’s ExecuComp data set of which additional information on firm

characteristics is available in the CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over the period 2000—2010. The top and

bottom 1% of observations on � and variables underlying the independent variables have been dropped to

prevent distortion of our estimates. The symbols *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%

and 1% level, respectively.

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

m1 2.7106** 1.1320 0.6733 0.6639 2.4993 0.8507 -0.8847 0.1194 0.4096 (1.1932) (0.9704) (1.0228) (1.7895) (1.6824) (1.6402) (1.2474) (1.0326) (1.0373) m2 0.8782 0.4496 0.1383 0.8913 0.7057 0.0089 1.6104** 0.6514 0.0903 (0.7068) (0.5918) (0.5205) (1.0409) (0.9009) (0.7996) (0.7027) (0.6024) (0.5361) m3 -1.7669 -1.4220 -1.2986 -0.5508 0.4612 -1.4136 -1.9351 -1.0404 -1.5977 (1.4348) (1.2451) 1.0453 (1.9947) (1.8487) (1.6833) (1.3727) (1.2437) (1.1198) Size - - - -

0.7653*** -

0.6317*** -0.7654** -

0.7576*** -

0.6305*** -0.7321***

(0.1505) (0.1663) (0.3308) (0.0994) (0.0945) (0.1846) Size2 - - - 0.0459*** 0.0423*** 0.0298 0.0456*** 0.0403*** 0.0320** (0.0100) (0.0108) (0.0231) (0.0065) (0.0062) (0.0130) Sigma - - - -11.4130* -0.7168 11.2436*** 6.3346** 4.6378* 17.6271*** (6.3119) (6.0524) (4.1313) (2.5983) (2.500) (2.3169) HardCapital - - - -0.1304 -0.2248 -2.2052*** -

0.4483*** -

0.3100*** -0.4273***

(0.2283) (0.2780) (0.4652) (0.0545) (0.0754) (0.0773) HardCapital2 - - - -0.1463* -0.0581 0.6214*** 0.0439*** 0.0327** 0.0341*** (0.0852) (0.0987) (0.1503) (0.0137) (0.0160) (0.0114) MarketPower - - - 1.9161*** 1.7606** 0.9842 1.0330*** 1.2212*** 0.9172*** (0.7124) (0.7894) (0.7666) (0.2128) (0.2495) (0.2063) R&D - - - 0.3320 0.1355 0.2252 - - - (0.2703) (0.2725) (1.1790) Advertising - - - 0.0040 0.0118 -0.0152 - - - (0.0318) (0.0309) (0.0425) InvestmentRate - - - 1.1344*** 1.1178*** 0.6586*** - - - (0.3355) (0.3105) (0.2382) Industry f.e. No Yes No No Yes No No Yes No Firm f.e. No No Yes No No Yes No No Yes Year f.e. Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N. Obs. 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 R2 0.0367 0.2941 0.6722 0.1905 0.3493 0.7293 0.1040 0.3172 0.6878 St. Errors Cluster

Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm

34

Table 5

Ownership-performance model with instrumental variables

The table below reports the estimated coefficients from regressing firm performance, � , on measures of

managerial ownership, � and �� , and a set of control variables. #�$�, #�$��, #�%�� and #�%��'���� are

used as instruments for � and ��. All these variables are described in detail in the Appendix. 6&''���� and

9+��*��:�;%'���� are not reported because of collinearity. Industry fixed effects (3-digit SIC code) are

controlled for in column (2). Firm fixed effects are controlled for in column (3). Year fixed effects are controlled

for in columns (1)-(3). Intercept terms and year dummies are included for all regressions but not reported. The

same is true for fixed effects where appropriate. Standard errors are robust, clustered around firms and reported

in parentheses. The sample consists of all firms from Compustat’s ExecuComp data set of which additional

information on firm characteristics is available in the CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over the period 2000—

2010. The top and bottom 1% of observations on � and variables underlying the independent variables have

been dropped to prevent distortion of our estimates. First-stage F reports the first-stage F statistic for tests of

under- and weak identification of the instruments. Hansen and pHansen report, respectively, the Hansen J

statistic and associated p-value for a test of overidentification of the instruments. The symbols *, ** and ***

indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

Variable (1) (2) (3)

m 102.8004 69.9304 -420.0164 (92.1357) (44.9864) (713.6528) m2 -479.3124 -332.9519 1607.408 (450.9528) (211.1995) (2550.8060) HardCapital 0.09098 -0.2252 1.0911 (0.8881) (0.6572) (5.9288) HardCapital2 0.1001 -0.1336 0.1827 (0.5370) (0.3045) (1.4209) MarketPower 2.1177** 1.7800** 0.4416 (0.8699) (0.8216) (1.2046) R&D 0.3745 0.0816 0.2686 (0.4768) (0.3208) (0.5856) Advertising 0.0216 0.0137 -0.2422 (0.0571 (0.0512) (0.5064) InvestmentRate 0.4064 0.6336 0.7246 (0.8053) (0.4199) (1.8517) Industry f.e. No Yes No Firm f.e. No No Yes Year f.e. Yes Yes Yes N. Obs. 21,950 21,950 21,950 St. Errors Cluster Firm Firm Firm First-stage F on instruments of m

8.06 8.54 4.21

First-stage F on instruments of m2 5.61 5.35 3.93

Hansen 1.6550 0.0240 0.0650 pHansen 0.1983 0.8759 0.7993

35

Table 6

Ownership-performance model with sample splits

The table below reports the estimated coefficients from regressing firm performance, � , on measures of managerial

ownership, � and �� , and a set of control variables. All these variables are described in detail in the Appendix.

6&''���� and 9+��*��:�;%'���� are not reported because of collinearity. Columns (1) and (2) report coefficients on

the sample split at the median share turnover which is computed for each sample year. Column (1) reports coefficients for

firms which have a share turnover above the median share turnover. Column (2) reports coefficients for firms which have a

share turnover below the median share turnover. Columns (3) and (4) report coefficients on the sample split at the median

bid-ask spread which is computed for each sample year. The bid-ask spread is calculated by averaging end of month bid-ask

spreads that are readily available from CRSP. Column (3) reports coefficients for firms which face bid-ask spreads below the

median bid-ask spread. Column (4) reports coefficients for firms which face bid-ask spreads above the median bid-ask spread

(and whose shares are thus more illiquid). Columns (5) and (6) are similar to (3) and (4), except now the split is done at the

median bid-ask spread that is constructed from daily differences between bid and ask prices. Firm fixed effects and year fixed

effects are controlled for in columns (1)-(6). Intercept terms and year dummies are included for all regressions but not

reported. The same is true for fixed effects where appropriate. Standard errors are robust, clustered around firms and reported

in parentheses. The sample consists of all firms from Compustat’s ExecuComp data set of which additional information on

firm characteristics is available in the CRSP/Compustat Merged data set over the period 2000—2010. The top and bottom

1% of observations on � and variables underlying the independent variables have been dropped to prevent distortion of our

estimates. pChow reports the p-value of a Chow test that tests for the difference between the managerial ownership variables.

The symbols *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

m 2.6021* -1.7582* 2.8138** -0.3719 1.9826 0.3891 (1.5547) (1.0055) (1.3445) (1.2717) (1.2576) (1.3034) m2 -6.9101 4.7170 -8.0263** 0.5970 -4.7941 -2.1111 (4.6846) (3.0212) (3.9501) (3.9367) (3.6238) (3.8739) Size -1.5551*** -0.2254 -1.1576** -0.3603 -1.2586*** -0.4079 (0.4713) (0.4877) (0.4571) (0.4854) (0.4563) (0.4943) Size2 0.0752** 0.0067 0.0408 0.0176 0.0500 0.0143 (0.0325) (0.0328) (0.0327) (0.0311) (0.0336) (0.0325) Sigma 14.9161*** 12.0239*** 11.9756*** 6.0953 14.5259*** 12.6071*** (4.0527) (4.0483) (4.3100) (3.7881) (3.9130) (3.8669) HardCapital -2.0992*** -1.5460*** -2.4249*** -1.8386*** -2.1528*** -1.8456*** (0.5491) (0.5588) (0.5914) (0.5796) (0.5748) (0.5729) HardCapital2 0.5990*** 0.4192** 0.8002*** 0.4513*** 0.7033*** 0.4809*** (0.1973) (0.1674) (0.2251) (0.1753) (0.2397) (0.1737) MarketPower 2.1390*** 2.4610*** 2.3875*** 0.1507 2.2329*** 3.8398*** (0.5703) (0.6900) (0.4345) (0.7190) (0.4065) (0.7545) R&D 0.2713 -1.1720* 0.2909 -0.1307 0.3060 0.0627 (0.1806) (0.6317) (0.2555) (0.1328) (0.2397) (0.3705) Advertising 0.0184 -0.0569 -0.0436 0.0336 0.0009 -0.0296 (0.0561) (0.0668) (0.0487) (0.0918) (0.0524) (0.0857) InvestmentRate 0.6415** 0.2660 0.9513*** 0.2017 1.0885*** 0.0178 (0.3111) (0.2281) (0.3006) (0.1670) (0.2449) (0.1733) Firm f.e. Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year f.e. Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N. Obs. 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 21,950 St. Err. Cluster Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm Firm pChow on m 0.0182 0.0740 0.3731 pChow on m2 0.0355 0.1112 0.6128

36