the economic e ects of a borrower bailout: …...maulik chauhan and avichal mahajan provided...

49
The Economic Effects of a Borrower Bailout: Evidence from an Emerging Market * Xavier Gin´ e Martin Kanz Abstract We study the credit market implications and real effects of one the largest borrower bailout programs in history, enacted by the government of India against the backdrop of the 2008–2009 financial crisis. We find that the stimulus program had no effect on productivity, wages or consumption, but led to significant changes in credit allocation and an increase in defaults. Post-program loan performance declines faster in districts with greater exposure to the program, an effect that is not driven by greater risk-taking of banks. Loan defaults become significantly more sensitive to the electoral cycle after the program, suggesting the anticipation of future credit market interventions as an important channel through which moral hazard in loan repayment is intensified. Preliminary. Please do not cite without permission. JEL: G21, G28, O16, O23 Keywords: bailout, economic stimulus, crisis resolution, moral hazard * We thank the Reserve Bank of India and the various State Level Bankers’ Committees for sharing data used in this paper. We thank Patrick Bolton, Shawn Cole, Dina Pomeranz, Rui Silva and numerous seminar and conference participants for helpful comments and suggestions. Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support Budget is gratefully acknowledged. The opinions expressed do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. The World Bank, Development Research Group, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Email: [email protected] The World Bank, Development Research Group, Email: [email protected]

Upload: others

Post on 06-Jul-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

The Economic Effects of a Borrower Bailout:Evidence from an Emerging Market∗

Xavier Gine† Martin Kanz‡

Abstract

We study the credit market implications and real effects of one the largest borrower

bailout programs in history, enacted by the government of India against the backdrop

of the 2008–2009 financial crisis. We find that the stimulus program had no effect on

productivity, wages or consumption, but led to significant changes in credit allocation

and an increase in defaults. Post-program loan performance declines faster in districts

with greater exposure to the program, an effect that is not driven by greater risk-taking

of banks. Loan defaults become significantly more sensitive to the electoral cycle after

the program, suggesting the anticipation of future credit market interventions as an

important channel through which moral hazard in loan repayment is intensified.

Preliminary. Please do not cite without permission.

JEL: G21, G28, O16, O23Keywords: bailout, economic stimulus, crisis resolution, moral hazard

∗We thank the Reserve Bank of India and the various State Level Bankers’ Committees for sharing data used in this

paper. We thank Patrick Bolton, Shawn Cole, Dina Pomeranz, Rui Silva and numerous seminar and conference participants for

helpful comments and suggestions. Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial

assistance from the World Bank Research Support Budget is gratefully acknowledged. The opinions expressed do not necessarily

represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.

† The World Bank, Development Research Group, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Email: [email protected]

‡ The World Bank, Development Research Group, Email: [email protected]

Page 2: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

1 Introduction

In the United States and the world over economic stimulus programs are ubiquitous in times

of economic crisis. In their simplest form, such programs provide direct subsidies or income

support to households through the tax code. In many cases, however, economic stimulus

programs operate through the credit market, typically in the form of debt restructuring and

debt relief programs designed to support investment and consumption during exceptionally

harsh economic circumstances.

Stimulus programs that operate through the credit market remain controversial among

economists and policymakers for at least two reasons. First, as in the case of fiscal stim-

ulus programs more generally, critics question whether ex-post credit market interventions

can affect real economic activity (Agarwal et al. [2005], Mian et al. [2010]) Second, while

proponents argue that stimulus programs through the credit market may prevent excessive

deadweight losses in times of economic crisis (Bolton and Rosenthal [2002]), opponents argue

that credit market interventions are a particularly harmful way of implementing a stimulus,

as they change the contracting environment and may generate significant bank and bor-

rower moral hazard. Although credit market-led stimulus programs are common, there is

surprisingly little evidence on how they affect credit market outcomes and the real economy.

We address these questions by evaluating one of the largest borrower bailout programs

in history, enacted by the government of India against the backdrop of the global financial

crisis of 2008–2009. The program, known as the ‘Agricultural Debt Waiver and Debt Relief

Scheme’ (Adwdrs), consisted of unconditional debt relief for more than 60 million rural

households across India, amounting to a volume of more than US$ 16 billion (approximately

1.7% of GDP). We exploit a natural experiment arising from the Adwdrs program eligibility

criteria and use detailed geographically disaggregated data on bailout exposure, to estimate

the effect of the bailout on credit allocation, loan performance and real economic activity.

1

Page 3: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

The key challenge in identifying the causal effect of the bailout is the difficulty of con-

structing a meaningful counterfactual. Because cross-sectional exposure to the debt relief

is a function of loan delinquencies prior to the program, one might worry that estimates of

program impact are endogenous to pre-existing economic trends. To address this concern,

our identification strategy –which essentially relies on a differences-in-differences approach–

exploits a plausibly exogenous cross-sectional variation in program exposure generated by the

Adwdrs eligibility rules. We additionally validate our credit market estimates using bank-

district data, which allows us to use within-district variation to explicitly control for local

shocks to credit demand, and identify the credit supply shock (Khwaja and Mian [2008]).

We find that the bailout had a significant and economically large effect on post program

credit allocation and loan performance. A one standard deviation increase in bailout ex-

posure led to a 4–6% decline in the number of loans and a 13–16% decline in the amount

of credit outstanding. The results also reveal significant reallocation of credit away from

districts with high exposure to the bailout. While districts with high (above median) pro-

gram exposure received 4 cents of new lending for every 1 dollar of credit written off under

Adwdrs, districts with low (below median) program exposure received 4 dollars for every 1

dollar of debt relief. Despite this reallocation of new bank lending to observably “less risky”

districts, we document a significant decline in loan performance in districts with high bailout

exposure, concentrated among borrowers that had previously been in good standing.

In the second part of our analysis, we examine the effect of debt relief on the real economy.

Supporters of Adwdrs, including India’s government at the time, cited debt overhang and

investment constraints as one of the key motivations for the program and argued that debt

relief could not only provide immediate relief to households, but also improve agricultural

investment, with positive implications for rural productivity, wages and consumption. We

use detailed, regionally disaggregated data to test for the effect of the bailout on rural

productivity, wages and employment. Our results identify a precise zero for each of these

2

Page 4: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

outcomes, implying a low spending multiplier of debt relief and suggesting that debt relief

did not achieve the efficiency gains claimed by its proponents.

There are several reasons that make India’s bailout for rural households an attractive

setting to explore the impact of a credit market-led stimulus program. First, Adwdrs is

representative of a wide range of stimulus programs executed through interventions into the

credit market. In the United States, federal and state governments have frequently intervened

into debt contracts, with some of the largest credit market interventions occurring in the

aftermath of the Great Depression (Rucker and Alston [1987]). More recent credit market

interventions include programs for mortgage renegotiation in response to foreclosure crisis

of 2008 (Agarwal et al. [2013], Guiso et al. [2013]). Stimulus programs enacted through

the credit market have been more frequent in developing countries, where debt relief and

restructuring programs have often targeted the economically and politically influential rural

sector. Recent examples include a US$ 2.9 billion bailout for farmers in Thailand and the

restructuring of more than US$10 billion of household debt in Brazil.

Second, unlike many other political interventions in the credit market, India’s Adwdrs

program was a one-off initiative that left the institutional environment unchanged, thus

allowing us to isolate the effect of debt relief. Beneficiaries were identified, settlements were

made and lenders were refinanced through the banking system in a way that modified the

terms of existing loans but did not affect the rules and regulations governing new lending.

Third, unlike any previous debt relief initiative in India, eligibility for the program de-

pended on the amount of land pledged at the time of loan origination, typically many years

prior to the program. This rule, applied retrospectively, implies that the share of credit that

could qualify for the program is a function of the historically determined land distribution

in a given district. This provides a source of quasi-exogenous variation in program exposure,

which we exploit to provide causal estimates of the impact of debt relief.

To the best of our knowledge, the paper provides the first empirical evidence on the

3

Page 5: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

effects of large-scale debt relief programs on credit market outcomes and the real economy

and thus contributes to several strands of the finance literature. Most closely related to

our study, Agarwal et al. [2013] study subsidized mortgage renegotiations under the Home

Affordability Modification Program (Hamp) in the wake of the foreclosure crisis in the United

States. They find that the program led to a modest reduction in foreclosures but had no

effect on durable and non-durable consumption. Alston [1983], Alston [1984] and Rucker

and Alston [1987] study debt moratoria in the United States in the aftermath of the Great

Depression. Their results suggest that the short-term benefits of this policy may have come

at the cost of credit rationing in the longer run. In this paper, we study the impact of debt

relief in a setting that provides the unique opportunity to quantify both the moral hazard

costs of a bailout and potentially offsetting effects on the real economy.

Our results are also complementary to, but distinct from, a growing literature on the

effects of economic stimulus programs more broadly. Mian and Sufi [2012] study the impact

of the “Cash for Clunkers” stimulus program in the Unites States, which offered consumers

direct subsidies for new car purchases. They find that the stimulus shifted the timing of new

car purchases but did not affect employment, or default rates in cities with higher exposure to

the stimulus. Chodorow-Reich et al. [2014] study the American Recovery and Reinvestment

Act (Arra) and find positive employment effects of the program. These studies relate to

the literature on government spending and Ricardian Equivalence (Barro [1989], Agarwal et

al. [2007], Nakamura and Steinsson [2014]). While our analysis differs from this literature

by focusing specifically on the impact of a credit market-led stimulus program, our results

suggest a low spending multiplier from debt relief. This is consistent with the arguments

and evidence presented in Mian et al. [2011], who link high levels of pre-crisis leverage in the

United States to slow post-crisis consumption growth and economic recovery.

Because the bailout affected not only borrowers but was also tied to a recapitalization of

banks, which were refinanced by the Reserve Bank of India, our results are also related to a

4

Page 6: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

large literature on the transmission of financial shocks to the real economy (Peek and Rosen-

gren [2000], Khwaja and Mian [2008], Paravisini [2008], Schnabl [2012], Lin and Paravisini

[2013]), as well as more recent work on bank recapitalizations (Philippon and Schnabl [2013]

and Gianetti and Simonov [2013]). In line with this literature, we find evidence of important

changes in bank lending and credit allocation as a result of the program.

There is much reason to believe that prior to Adwdrs, Indian banks faced significant

incentives for “evergreening” de facto non-performing loans. Reflecting a long history of

directed lending (see Burgess and Pande [2005], and Banerjee and Duflo [2014]), all banks

in India are required to allocate 40% of their net credit to “priority sectors”, which include

agriculture and small scale industry. Although this mandate forced the allocation of a

significant share of credit to high-risk borrowers, local branch managers face sanctions for

realizing losses. This creates a significant incentive to keep lending to borrowers close to

default. The introduction of Adwdrs removed this incentive distortion. Consistent with

the “evergreening” hypothesis (Peek and Rosengren [2005]), we find evidence of a shift in

post-program bank lending away from districts with a high-share of total credit waived under

the bailout. Importantly, this also suggests that the bailout did not encourage greater risk-

taking by banks and thus enables us to distinguish the effect of Adwdrs on bank risk-taking

from its impact on borrower behavior.

Finally, we contribute to the literature on the political economy of credit in emerging

markets (Dinc [2005], Cole [2009b], Agarwal et al. [2012]). We find that loan performance

is responsive to the electoral cycle, and that this effect is magnified in the period after the

bailout is enacted. This finding underscores the concern that stimulus programs may lead

to severe moral hazard in loan repayment, fueled by the anticipation of future credit market

interventions –especially so in economies with a long history of political intervention and

significant state ownership of banks, such as the one we study in this paper.

The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we provide an overview

5

Page 7: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

over the eligibility rules and timing of India’s bailout program for rural households. Section

3 provides details about the data used and provides summary statistics. In Section 4 we

discuss the effect of the bailout on credit supply and loan performance. In Section 5 we

explore the real effects of the program. Section 7 concludes.

2 India’s Bailout Program for Rural Households

We study the credit market implications and real effects of a credit market led stimulus pro-

gram, using a natural experiment generated by the eligibility criteria for India’s ‘Agricultural

Debt Waiver and Debt Relief Scheme for Small and Marginal Farmers’. In this section, we

describe the main features and eligibility rules of the program.

The intention of the Adwdrs program was twofold. First, owing to a long history

of directed lending to the rural sector, Indian banks had accumulated significant amounts

of non-performing loans. Under the bailout, these debts were cancelled and banks were

refinanced through the central bank. Second, this reduction in household debt was intended

to to alleviate debt overhang problems and act as a direct stimulus for investment and

consumption among rural households. Introduced a year ahead of national elections, the

program also represented a significant transfer from urban to rural voters.

The rules for program eligibility were kept deliberately simple to allow for the swift

processing of claims, and to minimize opportunities for leakage and corruption at local

bank branches tasked with identifying eligible borrowers. In contrast to earlier debt relief

initiatives, eligibility for the program at the individual level depended on the amount of

land pledged as collateral at the time a loan was originated, typically several years before

the program. Small borrowers who had pledged less than two hectares of land were eligible

for full debt relief, while borrowers that had pledged more than two hectares of collateral

qualified for 25% conditional debt relief if they were able to repay the remaining balance.

6

Page 8: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Loans qualified for debt relief if they had been originated between December 31, 1997

and December 31, 2007, were 90+ days past due as of December 31, 2007 and remained in

default until February 28, 2008. Importantly, the eligibility rules, including the collateral

cutoff, were announced retrospectively, so that there was no scope for manipulation around

program dates. In addition, Adwdrs was the first debt relief program in India’s history for

which eligibility was based on landholdings (rather than the amount of credit) and thus the

rules were unanticipated.

Implementation of the program began in June 2008. Every bank branch in the country

was asked to identify all loans and borrowers on its books that met the bailout eligibility

criteria. As a transparency measure, branches were required to publicly post these beneficiary

lists, including the identity of the borrower, the details of the qualifying loan and collateral

pledged at the time of loan origination. Borrower lists underwent independent audits at

the branch and bank level, and an appeals process was put in place by the regulator to

allow borrowers to rectify errors in published beneficiary lists. Banks were refinanced by the

central government through the Reserve Bank of India, for the full amount of credit written

off under the program.

Unconditional debt relief, which accounted for approximately 81% of claims, was pro-

cessed immediately so that virtually all claims had been settled by the end of June 2008.

The deadline for settling claims under the partial debt relief scheme for loans with collateral

of more than two hectares of land was extended several times because of slow take-up –first

to December 2009, and subsequently to December 2010. To ensure that we accurately cap-

ture the total amount of debt relief granted in a district, our analysis relies on data collected

in December 2011, when the program was closed and all claims had been settled.

As one of the largest economic stimulus programs in history, the Adwdrs program

received significant media attention and was at the center of an intense political debate.

Proponents of the program, including members of India’s governing alliance, heralded the

7

Page 9: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

program as a cure for endemic problems of debt overhang in the rural sector. In a speech

describing the program and its expected benefits to the rural sector, the Indian finance

minister stated “We are discharging a debt that we owe to our farmers.”1 Responses to the

program from the financial sector were much more cautious and warned, in particular, about

the potentially detrimental effects of the bailout for credit discipline and future access to

credit among borrowers benefiting from the bailout. As The Economist noted “Some fear the

government’s largesse will do lasting damage to a culture of prudent borrowing, productive

investment and prompt repayment.”2

This paper provides the first quantitative evidence to evaluate these opposing claims.

We use a natural experiment that generates quasi-random variation in program exposure

to provide causal evidence on the impact of one of the largest economic stimulus programs

in history. Using a rich dataset on credit market outcomes and real economic activity, this

allows us to trace the impact of the program on lending and loan performance, as well as

any potentially offsetting effects on real economic activity.

3 Data and Descriptive Statistics

We examine the effect of the Adwdrs bailout using a panel of 502 of 5933 Indian census

districts observed annually for the years 2001 to 2012. The dataset combines information

on lending and loan performance with information on productivity, wages and consumption.

The dataset contains three main types of information, which we describe in this section.

First, we measure the cross-sectional intensity of program exposure, as the share of

1“Text of Finance Minister’s Statement on the Agricultural Debt Waiver and Debt Relief Scheme.” Min-istry of Finance of the Republic of India, March 23, 2008. Available at http://pib.nic.in.

2“Waiving, not drowning: India writes off farm loans. Has it also written off the rural credit culture?”The Economist. June 3, 2008.

3Between 2001 and 2012, 47 new districts were created, typically by bifurcating existing ones. In ouranalysis, we aggregate all data to the level of India’s 2001 census districts.

8

Page 10: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

agricultural credit written off in each district under the program.

Second, the dataset contains credit market outcomes including the amount of total lend-

ing and new loans made in each district. We augment the district level information on credit

with a new dataset of lending and loan performance at the bank-district level, constructed

from proprietary data from India’s largest commercial banks.

Third, we use data from the Indian National Sample Survey (NSS) and the Indian Agri-

cultural Statistics Database to construct a panel of agricultural productivity, rural wages and

per capita consumption. We aggregate all data to the level of a district, an administrative

unit roughly comparable to a U.S. county. In the base year 2001, India had 593 districts

with an average population of 1,731,897 inhabitants. In that year, the districts in our sample

account for approximately 95% of the Indian population and 89% of bank credit.

3.1 Measuring Program Exposure

To measure a district’s exposure to the bailout, we collected data on the amount of debt

relief granted under the program from each state’s State Level Bankers’ Committee (Slbc),

the administrative body responsible for collecting and reporting data on publicly supported

credit market programs at the state level. We were able to obtain this information for all

districts in 23 of India’s 28 states including all states of mainland India, which account for

the vast majority of India’s population, agricultural production and total credit.4 For each

district, we observe the amount of credit eligible for the bailout, as well as the amount of

debt relief actually disbursed. This amount includes principal and accumulated interest of

all non-performing loans that had been originated prior to December 31, 2007, and remained

90+ days past due as of February 28, 2008.

Based on these data, we construct our measure of program exposure, measuring the share

4Data were not available for the Northeastern states Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Meghalaya, Nagalandand Mizoram. In the base year, these states account for less than 10% of total credit outstanding.

9

Page 11: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

of credit eligible for debt relief under the Adwdrs program in each district in our sample.

Specifically, letting creditit denote the total amount of outstanding agricultural credit in

district i at the time of the program deadline t = 2008, with superscript S denoting the

share of debt owed by households below the two hectare eligibility cutoff and superscript L

denoting debt owed by households above the cutoff. Letting φ denote the share of credit

that was current at the program deadline (and hence unaffected by the bailout), the program

exposure of district i can be written as

Bailout shareit =(1− φ)

[creditS

it + .25κicreditLit

]creditS

it + creditLit

(3.1)

where κi denotes the fraction of loans settled under the partial debt relief option for house-

holds above the two hectare cutoff. Because settlement was optional for households above

the two hectare collateral threshold, our baseline estimates assume κi = 1 (full compliance

among households above the cutoff), which is equivalent to estimating the intent-to-treat

(Itt) effect for households with more than two hectares of land pledged as collateral.

Table I reports summary statistics for the share of credit written off under the program

and highlights significant geographical variation in program exposure. For the median district

in our sample, 28.4% of outstanding credit was waived under the program (s.d.=22.4%). Fig-

ure 1 plots the geographical distribution of program exposure and illustrates the significant

cross-sectional variation in program exposure, which is key to our identification strategy.5

3.2 Lending and Loan Performace

We use two main data sources to capture credit market outcomes at the district and bank-

district level. In particular, our credit market dataset combines district level information on

5It is also worth noting that bailout exposure does not appear to correlate with state boundaries. Thissuggests that program exposure is driven primarily by local variation in economic shocks, rather than insti-tutional factors.

10

Page 12: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

lending by all commercial banks in India with novel data on lending and loan performance

for India’s largest commercial banks at the bank-district level, which allow for a more robust

identification of the credit market impact of the program.

District-level. Our first source of credit market data is the Reserve Bank of India’s Basic

Statistical Returns of Commercial Banks in India (BSR) dataset, which provides compre-

hensive, regionally disaggregated, information on bank lending. The BSR data are based on

information collected annually by the regulator and covers lending activities at the branches

of all commercial banks in India.6 This annual ‘census’ of outstanding credit includes details

on total loans, loan amounts, and the sectoral allocation of credit as of March 31st, the end

of the Indian fiscal year.

We use the BSR data to construct a panel of credit outstanding, number of loans out-

standing and loan sizes for the years 2001 to 2012. Unless otherwise indicated, we focus

on agricultural credit, the type of credit that was most directly affected by the Adwdrs

program. In the base year 2001, the median district had a total of 27,834 agricultural loans

outstanding with a an average loan size of Rs 234,000 (US$ 3,842). Summary statistics for

the district-level credit variables are reported in Table II, Panel A.

Bank-district level. Our second data source contain information on lending and loan

performance at the bank-district level. Because data at this level of disaggregation is not

made available by the regulator, we construct a new dataset based on proprietary data from

India’s four largest commercial banks. This dataset contains information on lending and loan

performance for 1,783 bank-district pairs observed annually between 2006 to 2012. In the

base year, the bank-district data cover 27,678 bank branches, accounting for approximately

40% of India’s branch network and 62% of total credit.

Because data on loan performance at the sub-national level is not disclosed by the Reserve

Bank of India, the bank-district panel is our main source of information on loan performance.

6In the base year 2001, the dataset covers 67,929 bank branches in all states and union territories of India.

11

Page 13: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

The data reveal significant variation in loan performance. In the pre-program period, the

median branch recorded a non-performing loan share of 13.6% (s.d.=12.3). This share de-

clines to 6.25% (s.d.=7.3) in the first year after Adwdrs. Figure ?? plots the year by year

share of non-performing loans. Interestingly, there is a surge in non-performing loans in 2008,

possibly because banks responded to the program by converting previously evergreened loans

into default. Table II, Panel B, reports summary statistics for the bank-district dataset.

One might be concerned that using data from a subset of banks could induce selection

problems. We believe this not to be a major concern in our setting because data on loan

performance comes from the largest banks in the country, all of which are “public sector”

banks (publicly listed entities with majority ownership by the Government of India). Since

the nationalization of banks in India in 1969, these institutions have been subject to stringent

bank branching regulations, which mandated multiple branches to be opened in unbanked

locations for every new branch opened in a banked location (Burgess and Pande [2005],

Banerjee and Duflo [2014]). Given their nationwide presence, this mitigates concerns that

branch location is biased towards better performing districts.

3.3 Productivity, Wages and Employment

We focus on three main outcomes to trace the effect of the bailout on the real economic

activity: agricultural productivity, unskilled wages and household consumption. Data on

agricultural productivity come from the Indian Agricultural Statistics Database, which con-

tains district-level information on crop yields and area planted for the 25 most common crops

grown in India. We combine this data with commodity prices from Indiastat to construct

the value of real agricultural production per hectare in each district and year in the dataset.7

7 We report additional details on the construction of the productivity measure in Appendix D.

12

Page 14: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

The Indian Agricultural Database also provides district-wise wages for unskilled rural

labor. Wages are reported seasonally, for every district in India and a range of occupations.

To capture changes in agricultural wages, we focus on unskilled daily wages for field and

non-field agricultural labor. We calculate a district’s rural wage as the average of these

two wage groups over all crop seasons for which data are available, to account for seasonal

variation in labor demand and rural wages.

Data on household consumption are calculated from the Indian National Sample Survey

(NSS). The NSS is conducted annually as a repeated cross-sectional survey of approximately

75,000 rural and 45,000 urban households. We use the 2004–2005, 2006–2007, 2009–2010

and 2011–2012 rounds of the NSS and focus on monthly per capita consumption expendi-

ture (Mpce). This measure of household consumption is collected consistently across NSS

rounds and widely used in practice, for example in the calculation of poverty lines.

3.4 Additional Variables

Our dataset contains a number of additional variables, which we use as controls and to con-

struct the instrumental variable described below. Specifically, we measure weather shocks

using local variation in monsoon rainfall. Rainfall data are taken from the Indian Meteo-

rological Department’s and measure total monthly precipitation at the district level. The

rainfall variable we use in our analysis is total monsoon rainfall between July and September

for the previous year as a fraction of the district’s long-run rainfall average over the same

period. Based on this dataset, we also construct a dummy variable indicating years in which

a district was exposed to a drought shock. This variable takes on a value of one for any year

in which a district’s total monsoon precipitation between the months of July and September

was below 75% of the district’s long run precipitation average, measured over the same time

period. This definition matches the threshold used by Indian state and local authorities to

13

Page 15: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

declare a district as ‘drought affected’.

Previous work has shown that lending of state banks in India tracks the electoral cycle.8

Hence, we control for a district’s temporal distance to the next scheduled state election to

account for the resulting fluctuations in credit supply. Electoral data come from the Election

Commission of India’s publicly available election statistics database. Finally, we use data on

district characteristics from the Census of India and the Indian Agriculture Census. These

data include the population and and land distribution of each district.

4 The Credit Market Effects of the Bailout

Estimating the credit market consequences of the bailout poses two main identification chal-

lenges. First, the level of program exposure is a function of loan defaults ahead of the

program, and therefore potentially endogenous to pre-existing economic trends at the dis-

trict level. Second, estimating the effect of the program requires us to distinguish changes

in credit supply from contemporaneous changes in credit demand.

We address this identification problem in two steps. First, we estimate the credit market

impact of the bailout at the district level, using a difference-in-differences specification, in

which we instrument for program exposure. Since we observe both program exposure and

real outcomes at the district level, we use this approach as our benchmark identification

strategy. Second, we verify the robustness of our credit market results by using data at the

bank-district level. This allows us to isolate the impact of the bailout on credit supply from

contemporaneous shocks to credit demand using a fixed effects strategy similar to Khwaja

and Mian [2008].9 We show that both identification strategies yield similar point estimates.

8Cole [2009b] shows that agricultural lending by state-owned banks in India increases by 5-10 percentagepoints in an election year.

9Similar identification strategies have been used in a number of studies that identify the transmission ofcredit shocks through the bank lending channel, such as Schnabl [2012], Paravisini et al. [2014] and others.

14

Page 16: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

We begin by estimating the impact of the bailout on credit market outcomes at the

district level, using differences-in-differences specifications of the form:

ln(Cit) = αt · αr + βi + γExposureit + ζ ′Xit + εit (4.1)

where Cit is a credit market outcome for district i and year t, αt are time fixed effects,

which we allow to vary across the Reserve Bank of India’s four administrative regions to

account for variation in local business cycles, and βi are district fixed effects that con-

trol for time-invariant heterogeneity in credit market conditions. We additionally control

for a matrix of time-varying controls Xit, which includes observable determinants of credit

market conditions, such as monsoon rainfall and electoral cycle dummies.10 The variable

Exposureit = Bailout sharei ∗ Postt measures a district’s exposure to the bailout.

We construct an instrument for program exposure based on the program eligibility cri-

teria. Specifically, we exploit the rule that a loan had to be both in default and backed by

land collateral of less than two hectares to qualify for full and unconditional debt relief. This

allows us to use two exogenous sources of variation to instrument for program exposure. The

first source of variation is the time series of weather shocks11 experienced by a district prior

to the program, which is a strong predictor of loan defaults. The second source of variation

is a district’s land distribution, which determines the fraction of households that fall below

the two hectare collateral cutoff and could have been eligible for unconditional debt relief.

It is worth noting that even if one of these two plausibly exogenous sources of variation

were to affect outcomes through a channel other than program exposure, the interaction

between weather shocks and the collateral cutoff should become relevant only as a result of

the program.12 We therefore use the number of drought years, wit, experienced by a district

10See Cole [2009b] for evidence that lending by Indian state banks co-moves with the electoral cycle.11We use years in which total monsoon rain between June and September was below 75% of the district’s

long-run average rainfall as our definition of weather shocks. This definition is consistent with the thresholdused by the Indian state and local authorities to declare a district as ‘drought affected’.

12We verify empirically that this is the case and provide additional robustness checks in Appendix B.

15

Page 17: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

prior to the program, interacted with the share of households below the eligibility cutoff, Li,

to obtain a cross-sectional predictor of the share of credit bailed out in each district:13

Zi =t∑t

wit · Li (4.2)

We then interact this variable with an indicator that marks the beginning of the program,

to construct a time-varying instrument for program exposure:

Zit =

(t∑

t=1

wit · Li

)∗ Postt (4.3)

Table III presents estimates of the first stage and demonstrates that the instrument is

a relevant predictor of program exposure. The first stage coefficient on the instrument is

positive and statistically significant at the 1% level throughout, indicating that districts with

greater exposure to pre-program weather shocks and a greater share of households below the

eligibility cutoff saw a higher share of credit waived as a result of the program. An F -

Statistic of 20.6 in the first stage regression that matches our preferred specification (Table

III, Column [4]) implies a strong first stage. While the exclusion restriction Cov(Zit, εit) = 0

cannot be tested directly, Appendix B presents several tests to assess its plausibility. The

results provide strong support for our identification assumptions.

Second, we verify our district level results and provide additional evidence on the pro-

gram’s impact on credit allocation, using an alternative identification strategy based on

bank-district level data. We derive the empirical specification for our analysis at the bank-

district level from a simple model of credit supply and demand.

In the model, which we describe in greater detail in Appendix C, bank j lending in

district i experience a shock to its equity as a result of the bailout. Similarly, at any time t,

13The present day land distribution of India’s districts is largely the result of land reforms enacted underBritish colonial rule (see Banerjee and Iyer [2005] for a discussion) and therefore plausibly exogenous toeconomic trends over the comparatively short time period we study.

16

Page 18: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

district i may face idiosyncratic shocks to credit demand. In order to trace the redistributive

impact of the program, we relax the assumption that shocks to bank’s equity are passed on

uniformly to all borrowers. This allows us to derive a simple empirical equation that can be

estimated directly, using bank-district level data on credit market outcomes

ln(Cijt) = αit + γEEjt + γBBijt + εijt (4.4)

where αit are district-time fixed effects, Ejt denotes the equity shock received by bank j as

a result of the bailout and Bijt denotes the program exposure (share of total credit written

off under the program) at all branches of bank j in district i.

This specification has several advantages. First, the inclusion of district-time fixed effects

allows us to isolate the effect of the bailout from any concurrent shocks to credit demand.

Second, we can identify the aggregate bank lending channel separately from the effect that

the bailout has on credit allocation across districts with differential program exposure.

The model underlying our estimating equation makes several testable predictions. First,

banks experiencing a larger equity shock as a result of greater overall exposure to the bailout

should increase lending (γE > 0). At the same time, banks should redistribute lending away

from districts with greater program exposure, as the program allows them to clean troubled

assets from their books and thus reduces incentives that may have existed to “evergreen”

loans close to default prior to the program (γB < 0). This can be tested against the alterna-

tive hypothesis that the program encouraged banks to engage in riskier lending. If this were

the case, then one would expect γE > 0 and γB > 0.14

4.1 Effects on Credit Allocation

Table IV reports the impact of the bailout on the intensive and extensive margin of bank

14See, for example, Gianetti and Simonov [2013] and Philippon and Schnabl [2013].

17

Page 19: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

lending using the specification in equation (4.2). The dependent variable in columns (1) to

(4) is the log number of new loans, while in columns (5) to (8) it is the log amount of credit.

For each dependent variable, the first two columns report OLS estimates while the later two

present results from instrumental variables regressions. Since 2SLS estimates are unbiased, a

comparison of OLS and 2SLS estimates reveals the sign of the correlation between Exposureit

and εit and thus the nature of the OLS bias. Within each set of estimates, the first column

controls for country and district fixed effects as well as time varying controls. The second

column additionally controls for each district’s linear time trend prior to the program.

We find that bank lending becomes more conservative in the post-program period, as

banks reduce lending in districts with greater program exposure. Estimates from our pre-

ferred specification in columns (4) indicate that a one standard deviation increase in the

share of credit covered by the program leads to a 3.7% decrease in new loans made in the

post-program period. The shift of bank lending away from high bailout districts is both

larger and more precisely estimated when the amount of credit is used instead. Specifically,

our results indicate that a one standard deviation increase in program exposure leads to

a 13.2% decrease in new lending in the post-program period (column 8). This suggests

that the capital injection resulting from the bailout was large enough to solve the banks’

debt overhang problem, thus reducing incentives for “evergreening” and giving rise to more

conservative lending and credit allocation in the post-program period. In addition, OLS

estimates tend to be consistently smaller than 2SLS suggesting a negative correlation be-

tween Exposureit and εit. In other words, districts with greater program exposure had either

lower pre-existing trends or were subject to lower demand shocks that were not captured by

district trends or region and year fixed effects.

The results suggest a reallocation of bailout funds from high to low bailout districts. We

thus estimate a modified version of our baseline model in equation (4.2), in which we use

the total amount of credit as the outcome of interest and replace our measure of program

18

Page 20: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

exposure by the total amount of credit eligible for the program in a given district. This

allows us to interpret the DD estimate γ as the amount of post-program lending per rupee

of bailout exposure.

Table A.I in Appendix A presents the results dividing the sample in districts above and

below the median of bailout exposure. We find strong evidence of reallocation of credit

away from districts with poorer loan performance in the pre-program period. While districts

with high exposure receive 0.21-0.36 rupees per rupee of bailout exposure, districts with

low bailout exposure receive an average of 2.2-4.2 rupees of new lending for every rupee

of bailout exposure in the post-program period. Taken together, these results suggest that

banks reduced their exposure to observably riskier districts in response to the program.

Table VI implements the specification in equation (4.5). Similarly to Table IV column

1 reports the Log of the number of accounts and column 2 reports the Log of credit. Con-

sistent with the econometric model, γE > 0 and γB < 0 for both outcomes. Given that

the district and year fixed effects absorb all time-varying district-specific factors, including

district-specific credit demand shocks, the coefficient γB captures the bank lending channel,

and the results suggest that it is large. An increase of one standard deviation in the bailout

share that the bank received almost doubles the number of accounts and increases lending

by 72.5%. More importantly, as already evidenced in IV the coefficient γE > 0 is negative

and significant both both outcomes, confirming that lenders redistribute credit away from

districts with higher levels of exposure. In particular, an increase of one standard deviation

in the amount of bailout that the bank received in the district reduces the number of ac-

counts by 14.2% and disbursements by 21% in that district.

4.2 Effects on Loan Performance

Table V estimates the effect of the bailout on ex-post loan performance using district-

19

Page 21: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

level data. The dependent variable columns (1) to (4) is the share of non-performing loans

in a given district, while in columns (5) to (8) is the share of non-performing credit. We

find evidence of a strong negative effect of the bailout on loan performance. Specifically, the

coefficient estimates indicate that a one standard deviation in bailout exposure increases the

share of non-performing loans by 3–7%.

Similarly, columns 3 and 4 of Table VI also show a deterioration in loan performance.

An increase of one standard deviation in the bailout share received by the bank increases the

number of non-performing accounts by 2.7% and the share of non-performing assets by 0.9%.

This suggests that banks that received more bailout funds overall experienced on average

more defaults, perhaps due to poorer management or a larger exposure to agriculture. But

more importantly, an increase of one standard deviation in the share of bailout that the bank

received in a given district also increases the number of non-performing accounts by 1.6%

and the share of non-performing credit by 2.4%.

Taken together, the results on credit allocation and loan performance allow us to distin-

guish between bank and borrower moral hazard. As we show in Tables IV and VI, banks

continue to expand their lending but reallocate credit towards observably less risky districts.

At the same time, we show that the same districts experience a significant decrease in loan

performance in the post program period.

These results have two important implications. First, the fact that the number of ac-

counts declines in higher bailout districts suggests that there is no new lending, and therefore

the deterioration in loan performance must be due to defaults among borrowers who were

previously in good standing (and not covered by the bailout). Second, given that bank lend-

ing becomes more conservative after the bailout, the decline in loan performance in districts

with high program exposure must be driven by borrower, rather than bank moral hazard.

20

Page 22: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

5 Real Effects of the Bailout

An important aim of economic stimulus programs is to stabilize output, and to prevent dis-

tortions in investment and consumption during economic downturns. In the case of India’s

debt relief program, proponents of the program argued that the bailout could serve to allevi-

ate “debt overhang” problems among rural households and stimulate productive investment.

In this section, we test for the effect of the bailout on real economic outcomes, using data on

district level agricultural productivity, real wages and household consumption. To do this,

we estimate the equation:

ln(Rit) = αt · αr + βi + ηRExposureit + ζ ′Xit + εit (5.1)

where Rit is an outcome of interest for district i observed at time t, Exposureit measures

the district’s exposure to the bailout and Xit is a vector of time varying controls. The

coefficient of interest in this equation is ηR, which measures the elasticity of real outcomes

with respect to program exposure. We do not control for district-year fixed effects because

real outcomes are observed at the district, rather than the bank-district level. Hence, we

cannot use district-year fixed effects to separately identify exposure to the bailout from

time-varying demand shocks, as in equation 4.4. Equation 5.1 therefore requires the stronger

identification assumption that changes in credit demand at the district level are uncorrelated

with program exposure. To ensure that this condition is met, we first instrument bailout

exposure using the interaction between the number of drought years prior to the bailout and

the share of households below the Adwdrs collateral threshold as in the previous section.

Second, we control for any observable time-varying determinants of credit market conditions,

such as the regional business cycle (αt · αr), and the timing of state elections.

We first explore the effect of debt relief on agricultural productivity. To do this, we take

advantage of a district level panel on crop yields and commodity prices from the Indian

21

Page 23: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Department of Agriculture. The dataset, which we describe in Section 3 and Appendix D,

contains detailed information on agricultural revenue and area cultivated so that we can

construct time series of agricultural productivity over the time period 2001-2011 for 387

districts in our sample. Table VII, Panel A estimates the impact of the stimulus program

on agricultural productivity. The results show that the program had no discernible effect

on agricultural productivity . Using our preferred specification, the estimated effect is a

precise zero (γ=-0.003, s.e.=0.014), suggesting that the stimulus did not create investment

incentives of a magnitude sufficient to affect agricultural productivity.

Second, in VII, Columns [5] to [8] we investigate the effect of the debt relief program on

rural employment. Unskilled labor is an important input to agricultural production. Hence,

if the bailout had a positive impact on households’ ability to invest in productive inputs,

one might expect to find this effect reflected in rural employment. To test for this channel,

we use data on rural employment from the 2007-2008 and 2011-2012 rounds of the Indian

National Sample Survey and construct a variable measuring total rural employment as a

share of a district’s labor force. We test for an impact of the bailout on this measure of

employment using the same regression specifications as in Columns [1] to [4], and do not

find a discernible effect of the bailout on rural employment. This result remains unchanged

when we exclude metropolitan areas and limit the sample to districts with a rural population

share of 70 percent and above.

Finally, Table VII, Columns [9] to [12], we turn to the effect of the bailout on real wages,

as an additional test for potential labor maket impact of the bailout. To do this, we con-

struct a panel of real wages for the period 2006-2011, based on the Agricultural Wages in

India (AWI) dataset. The data capture monthly wages for unskilled agricultural labor in a

sample of 327 districts, which we average for all agricultural occupations and crop seasons

to acocunt for seasonal fluctuations. We estimate the effect of the bailout on agricultural

wages in Table VII, Columns [9] to [12], and find that the bailout had no measurable impact

22

Page 24: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

on real wages.

6 Extensions and Robustness

6.1 Mechanisms: Moral Hazard

The results so far document that the Adwdrs bailout had a strong negative effect on loan

performance, which does not appear to be driven by greater bank risk-taking. In this section,

we shed light on the mechanism behind this result, by isolating changes in loan performance

that occur for economic reasons from defaults that correlate with the electoral cycle and can

be regarded as pure moral hazard. We find that the Adwdrs bailout magnified political

cycles in loan defaults. This suggests that the anticipation of lenient enforcement and future

credit market interventions acts as an important channel through which moral hazard in

loan repayment is intensified.

Our test makes the following argument. There are two potential channels that can

lead to a decline in loan performance ahead of election years. First, electoral cycles in

default can arise from changes in credit market conditions, such as increased credit supply,

reduced screening and monitoring standards and a change in loan sizes around elections.15

Second, electoral cycles in default can arise from strategic behavior and pure moral hazard

among borrowers who expect credit enforcement to be more lenient in election years. If the

bailout indeed induced moral hazard by heightening expectations of future credit market

interventions, we would expect the magnitude of political cycles in default to increase after

the bailout, even when we condition on credit market conditions and the local business cycle.

To test for this channel explicitly, we exploit the exogenous timing of Indian state elec-

tions. Each of India’s 28 states holds state assembly elections on a 5-year cycle. These

15See Cole [2009b] and Cole [2009a]for evidence on politically motivated lending in India and politicalcycles in agricultural lending.

23

Page 25: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

elections are staggered in time, with an average of 4–6 states holding elections in a given

calendar year. We use this exogenous source of variation in Table VIII, where we regress

the share of non-performing loans on an interaction between a post-program dummy and

an indicator equal to one in the two years preceding a state election. Because state govern-

ments have the power to call early elections, we define this variable with reference to the

time remaining to the next scheduled state election.

We find that electoral cycles in loan defaults are magnified in the post-program period.

On average, defaults in pre-election years increase by an additional 1–2 percentage points

(over the post-program sample mean of 7.25%) after the bailout. In unreported results, we

verify that the greater loan delinquencies around election times are not driven by concurrent

changes in loan sizes that might affect the average debt burden and repayment capacity of

borrowers. We find no evidence of a systematic change in average loan sizes around elections

prior to the bailout or as a result of Adwdrs.

These results are consistent with the concern that the cost of politically motivated credit

market interventions arises, to a significant extent, from their effect on borrower expecta-

tions. While our data do not allow us to test this hypothesis explicitly, one might expect

this adverse effect of credit market-led stimulus programs on borrower behavior to be partic-

ularly pronounced in credit markets with significant state ownership of banks and a history

of politically motivated credit market interventions, such as the one we study.

6.2 Falsification Tests

The difference-in-differences strategy underlying our empirical strategy relies on the identifi-

cation assumption that outcomes for the treatment and control groups –in our case districts

with different levels of bailout exposure– did not follow differential trends in the pre-program

period. We test this assumption in three different ways.

24

Page 26: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

In Figures ?? to ??, we first present descriptive graphical tests of the parallel trends

assumption for the main outcomes of interest, and compare outcomes for districts above

and below the median program exposure. There is no indication that the parallel trends

assumption is violated for any of our main outcomes in the period prior to the Adwdrs

bailout.

Second, we control for linear district-specific time trends in all estimates in Tables IV to

VIII. These estimates are reported as the second specification for each group of regressions,

and we show that none of our main results are affected by the inclusion of unit specific time

trends in our baseline regression.

Third, we perform two placebo experiments to rule out the possibility that our estimates

are biased as a result of divergent non-linear trends. In Table X, Columns [1] to [5], we

restrict our sample to the pre-bailout period and move the program date from 2008 to 2005.

The coefficients are close to zero and, in several cases have the opposite sign. Table X,

Columns [6] to [10], reports treatment coefficients from a second placebo experiment, in

which we randomly reassign treatment levels among the districts in our sample. We do this

using a bootstrap procedure, in which we draw 1,000 random assignments of our treatment

variable and estimate treatment coefficients using our preferred specification, and report the

bootstrap coefficients and standard errors. Again, we find that the estimated treatment

coefficients are close to zero and statistically insignificant. These results make it unlikely

that our findings are explained by differential time trends.

7 Conclusion

Around the world, governments have routinely intervened in credit markets in an effort

to stimulate economic activity. Although it is often hypothesized that such interventions

have severe repercussions for credit discipline and borrower expectations, surprisingly little

25

Page 27: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

robust evidence exists to evaluate these claims. In this paper, we use a natural experiment

surrounding one of the largest borrower bailouts in history to estimate the effect of a large

economic stimulus program on productivity and loan repayment.

We find that the program generated no measurable productivity gains, but led to sig-

nificant moral hazard in loan repayment. The annual post-program increase in the share of

non-performing loans grows up to 5 annual percentage points faster in districts in the highest

quintile of the debt relief distribution. Importantly, our findings also suggest a mechanism

for the amplification of moral hazard in loan repayment arising from economic stimulus en-

acted through the credit market. We show that the relationship between defaults and the

electoral cycle documented by earlier studies is magnified by the bailout program. This sug-

gests that the adverse effects of the bailout become more persistent as the stimulus generates

expectations of future politically motivated interventions in the credit market.

Taken together, these results provide some of the first evidence on the moral hazard gen-

erated by large government stimulus programs operating through the credit market. While

such programs have received much attention in the aftermath of the recent global financial

crisis, it is worth noting that programs of this kind, often more frequent and larger in scale,

have been carried out in many developing countries. Understanding the moral hazard conse-

quences of these large-scale economic stimulus programs is essential to weighing their costs

and benefits, particularly in an environment where weak institutions make such programs

susceptible to political capture and manipulation. The results in this paper are a first step

in this broader research agenda.

References

Agarwal, Sumit, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas Souleles, “The Reaction of ConsumerSpending and Debt to Tax Rebates: Evidence from Consumer Credit Card Data,” Journalof Political Economy, 2007, 115 (4), 986–1019.

26

Page 28: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

, G. Amromin, I. Ben David, and Serdar Dinc, “The Legislative Process and Fore-closures,” Working Paper, 2012.

, G., I. Ben David, S. Chomsisengphet, T. Piskorski, and A. Seru, “PolicyIntervention in Debt Renegotiation: Evidence from the Home Affordability ModificationProgram,” Working Paper, 2013.

, S.Chomsisenghpet, and O. Hassler, “The Impact of the 2001 Financial Crisis andthe Economic Policy Response on the Argentine Mortgage Market,” Journal of HousingEconomics, 2005, 14 (3), 242–270.

Alston, Lee, “Farm Foreclosures in the United States During the Interwar Period,” Journalof Economic History, 1983, 43 (4), 885–903.

, “Farm Foreclosure Moratorium Legislation: A Lesson From the Past,” American Eco-nomic Review, 1984, 74 (2), 445–457.

Banerjee, Abhijit and Esther Duflo, “Do Firms Want to Borrow More? Evidence froma Directed Lending Program,” Review of Economic Studies, 2014, 81 (1).

and Lakshmi Iyer, “History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacyof Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India,” American Economic Review, 2005, 95 (4),1190–1213.

Barro, Robert J., “The Ricardian Approach to Budget Deficits,” Journal of EconomicPerspectives, 1989, 3 (2), 37–54.

Bolton, Patrick and H. Rosenthal, “Political Intervention in Debt Contracts,” Journalof Political Economy, 2002, 110 (5), 1103–1134.

Burgess, Robin and Rohini Pande, “Do Rural Banks Matter? Evidence from the IndianSocial Banking Experiment,” The American Economic Review, 2005, 95 (3), 780–795.

Chodorow-Reich, Gabriel, Laura Feiveson, Zachary Liscow, and William Wool-ston, “Does State Fiscal Relief During Recessions Increase Employment? Evidence fromthe American Recovery and Reinvestment Act,” American Economic Journal: EconomicPolicy, 2014, 4 (3), 118–145.

Cole, Shawn A., “Financial Development, Bank Ownership, and Growth. Or, Does Quan-tity Imply Quality?,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 2009, 91 (1), 33–51.

, “Fixing Market Failures or Fixing Elections? Elections, Banks and Agricultural Lendingin India,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2009, 1 (1), 219–250.

Dinc, Serdar, “Politicians and Banks: Political Influences on Government-Owned Banksin Emerging Markets,” Journal of Financial Economics, 2005, 77 (1), 453–479.

27

Page 29: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Gianetti, Mariassunta and Andrei Simonov, “On the Real Effects of Bank Bailouts:Micro Evidence from Japan,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2013, 5 (1),135–167.

Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales, “The Determinants of Attitudestoward Strategic Default on Mortgages,” Journal of Finance, 2013, 68 (4), 1473 – 1515.

Khwaja, Asim and Atif Mian, “Tracing the Impact of Bank Liquidity Shocks: Evidencefrom an Emerging Market,” American Economic Review, 2008, 98 (1), 1413–1442.

Lin, Huidan and Daniel Paravisini, “The Effect of Financiang Constraints on Risk,”Review of Finance, 2013, 17 (1), 229–259.

Mian, Atif, Amir Sufi, and Francesco Trebbi, “Foreclosures, House Prices and theReal Economy,” American Economic Review, 2010, 100 (5), 1967–1998.

and , “The Effects of Fiscal Stimulus: Evidence from the 2009 Cash for ClunkersProgram,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2012, 127 (3), 1107–1142.

, Kamalesh Rao, and Amir Sufi, “Household Balance Sheets, Consumption and theEconomic Slump,” Chicago Booth Working Paper, 2011.

Nakamura, Emi and Jon Steinsson, “Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union: Evidencefrom U.S. Regions,” American Economic Review, 2014, 104 (3), 753–792.

Paravisini, Daniel, “Local Bank Financial Constraints and Access to External Finance,”Journal of Finance, 2008, 63 (5).

, Veronica Rappoport, Philipp Schnabl, and Daniel Wolfenzon, “Dissecting theEffect of Credit Supply on Trade: Evidence from Matched Credit-Export Data,” WorkingPaper, 2014.

Peek, Joseph and Eric Rosengren, “Collateral Damage: Effects of the Japanese BankCrisis on Real Activity in the United States,” American Economic Review, 2000, 90 (1),30–45.

and Eric S. Rosengren, “Unnatural Selection: Perverse Incentives and the Misalloca-tion of Credit in Japan,” American Economic Review, September 2005, 95 (4), 1144–1166.

Philippon, Thomas and P. Schnabl, “Efficient Recapitalization,” Journal of Finance,2013, 68 (1), pp. 1–42.

Rucker, Randal and L. Alston, “Farm Failures and Government Intervention: A CaseStudy of the 1930s,” The American Economic Review, 1987, 77, 724–730.

Schnabl, Philipp, “The International Transmission of Bank Liquidity Shocks: Evidencefrom an Emerging Market,” Journal of Finance, 2012, 67 (3), 897–932.

28

Page 30: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Data Sources

Table A.I Description of Variables

Variable Description SourcesTotal credit, accounts Total number of agricultural loans outstanding. (a) District-level data are

constructed from the Reserve Bank of India’s Basic Statistical Returns ofcommercial Banks in India (BSR) dataset, and include all agricultural loansmade by private, public, cooperative and regional rural banks. We use datafor the years 2001-2012 (b) At the bank-district level, this variable isconstructed from proprietary data on agricultural lending at all branches ofIndia’s four largest commercial banks. The dataset covers the period2006-2012 and contains district level aggregates of approximately 27,678branches in all states and Union Territories of India (Reserve Bank of India,A Profile of Banks, 2012).

Reserve Bank of India,Basic StatisticalReturns of ScheduledCommercial Banks inIndia, (2001 -2012);proprietary bank data.

Total credit, amount The natural logarithm of outstanding agricultural credit in units of Rs100,000 for each district of India. (a) The district-level data are constructedfrom the Reserve Bank of India’s BSR dataset, and cover all agriculturalloans made by private, public, cooperative and regional rural banks for theyears 2001-2012. (b) The bank-district level data are taken from proprietarydata on agricultural lending at all branches of India’s four largestcommercial banks and covers the years 2006-2012.

Reserve Bank of India,Basic StatisticalReturns of ScheduledCommercial Banks inIndia, (2001 -2012);proprietary bank data.

Non-performing loans,accounts

This information is not publicly available. We have calculated it fromproprietary data obtained from four of India’s four largest commercialbanks. (a) At the bank-district level, the data cover the years 2006-2012 andconsist of annual information on the number of outstanding agriculturalloans and the number of loans in default, defined as 90+ days past due (b)At the district level, our measure of loan performance is the arithmeticmean of loan performance for all banks with branches in the district. Toensure consistency with the credit data, we exclude districts for which wehave no information on program exposure.

Proprietary bank data.

Non-performing loans,amount

This information is not publicly available. We have calculated it fromproprietary data obtained from four of India’s four largest commercialbanks. (a) At the bank-district level, the data consist of annual informationon the amount of outstanding rural credit and the amount of rural NPAs(both denominated in units of Rs 100,000) and cover the years 2006-2012.(b) At the district level, our measure of loan performance is the arithmeticmean of loan performance for all banks with branches in the district. Toensure consistency with the credit data, we exclude districts for which wehave no information on program exposure.

Proprietary bank data.

Rainfall Total monsoon rainfall as a share of the 50 year district-level average.Monsoon rainfall is defined as total rainfall between June and September.Long-run normals are taken from India Meteorological Department LongRun Averages of Climatological Normals, CD-ROM.

India MeteorologicalDepartment (IMD)

Electoral cycle Five dummy variables indicating the temporal distance to the nextscheduled state assembly election. State assembly elections are scheduledevery five years and are staggered over time.

Election Commissionof India, available athttp://eci.nic.in.

Total agriculturalproductivity

Revenue per hectare derived from the sale of 32 main crops. Data onagricultural yields is available from the Indian Ministry of Agriculture,revenues are calculated using constant 2001 commodity prices. Data areavailable for the years 2001-2011.

Indian Ministry ofAgriculture, Indiastat

Rural wage Real unskilled wage for all agricultural occupations, measured at the end ofthe main crop season each year. Data are available for the years 2001-2011.

Indian Ministry ofAgriculture

Householdconsumption

Mean per capita household expenditure (MPCE), calculated fromhousehold-level data of the Indian National Sample Survey.

India National SampleSurvey (various years)

29

Page 31: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table A.I: Description of Variables (cont’d)

Variable Description SourcesLand distribution Share of landholdings in the district that are smaller than two hectares

(approximately 5 acres) in size.India AgricultureCensus, DistrictTables (2001)

Drought years The number of ’drought years’ experienced by a district prior to theprogram. A drought year is defined as a year in which total monsoonrainfall between June and September was below 75 percent of a district’s50-year average. The variable counts the number of drought years in thepre-program period between the years 2001 and 2007. Rainfall data comesfrom the Indian Meteorological Department (IMD), Long-run normals aretaken from India Meteorological Department Long Run Averages ofClimatological Normals, CD-ROM.

India MeteorologicalDepartment (IMD)

30

Page 32: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Tables and Figures

Table IProgram Exposure

This table reports summary statistics for the variable Bailout share,our main measure of program exposure. The variable measures thetotal amount of credit eligible for the bailout as a share of totaloutstanding agricultural credit on March 31, 2008, the date whenthe bailout program was enacted. To facilitate the interpretationof our estimates, the variable is normalized to have mean zero andstandard deviation one in all subsequent tables.

Bailout share

(N =501)

Mean .326

Median .284

StDev .224

Min .002

Max .991

31

Page 33: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table IISummary Statistics

This table presents summary statistics for the datasets used in the analysis. Panel [A] summarizes thedistrict-level dataset, containing information for 501 districts and the years 2001 to 2012. Total credit is thelog amount of total agricultural lending (in Rs million). Total loans is the log number of total agriculturalloans outstanding. Loan performance at the district level is aggregated from the bank-district datasetdescribed in Panel B. Population is the log of a district’s total population. Rural share is the share of adistricts population living in rural areas. Productivity per hectare is the total revenue from all crops producedin a district at 2001 prices, divided by the total area planted. Rural wage is the log of the average daily wagefor agricultural labor. Per capita consumption is the log of monthly per capita household consumption. Landholdings below 2 ha measures the share of total recorded landholdings in a district that are smaller thantwo hectares. Monsoon rain is the average precipitation recorded in a district between June and Septemberas a share of the district’s 50-year rain average over the same period. Drought years is the number ofyears between 2001 and the 2007, in which a district experienced a drought, defined as a year in whichmonsoon rainfall was less than 75 percent its long-run average. Time to election measures the number ofyears remaining until the next scheduled state election. Panel [B] summarizes the bank-district level dataset.All variables in this dataset are based on proprietary data from India’s four largest banks, available for apanel of 569 districts for the years 2005 to 2012. Total credit is the log of total agricultural lending at thesebanks, and Total loans is the log number of agricultural loans. All monetary values are in nominal IndianRupees. Table A.I and Appendix D provide additional details on data sources and the definition of variables.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Obs Mean Median StdDev Min Max

Panel A: District-level data

I. Lending and loan performance

Total credit 6,952 9.20 9.46 1.80 1.75 14.52

Total loans 6,952 10.10 10.36 1.52 2.08 14.71

Non-performing loans, share of ag credit 6,574 0.14 0.06 0.20 0.00 1.00

Non-performing loans, share of accounts 6,437 0.18 0.10 0.22 0.00 1.00

II. District characteristics

Total population 7,553 14.00 14.21 1.02 10.35 16.08

Rural share 7,553 0.78 0.82 0.17 0.00 1.00

III. Real outcomes

Productivity per hectare 5,840 0.17 0.14 0.10 0.00 0.74

Rural wage 1,031 4.36 4.32 0.43 3.29 5.75

Per capita consumption 2,478 11.96 11.85 0.53 10.59 13.43

IV. Additional controls

Land holdings below 2ha 6,669 0.53 0.56 0.24 0.00 .99

Monsoon rain, % of 50-year mean 6,094 97.05 88.46 50.71 8.36 1062

Drought years 7,008 0.87 0.00 1.48 0 7

Time to election 7,540 2.01 2.00 1.41 0 4

Panel B: Bank-district level data

I. Lending and loan performance

Total credit 15,003 6.44 6.88 2.80 -4.61 12.75

Total loans 10,170 6.13 6.48 2.74 0.00 12.56

Non-performing loans, share of ag credit 14,987 0.11 0.04 0.17 0.00 1.00

Non-performing loans, share of ag accts 10,763 0.15 0.08 0.20 0.00 1.0032

Page 34: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table IIIFirst Stage – Weather Shocks and Program Exposure

The regressions in this table estimate the first stage relationship between weather shocks andprogram exposure. The coefficient of interest measures how the interaction between the numberof drought years experienced by a district in the period between 2001 and 2007 and the shareof households below the two hectare eligibility cutoff affects program exposure. The dependentvariable in all regressions is the share of credit eligible for the program. We define a ‘drought year’as any year in which total precipitation during the monsoon months of June to September wasless than 75 percent of a district’s long-run average. All regressions control for lagged monsoonrain, and a set of dummy variables indicating the number of years until the next schduled stateelection. Estimates in columns [2] to [4] add interactions between time and region fixed effectsto control for heterogeneity in business cycles across regions and between urban and rural areas.Coefficient estimates on these controls are not reported to save space. Standard errors, in brackets,are calculated using the Huber-White correction for arbitrary heteroskedasticity and clustered atthe district level. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Dependent variable Program exposure

Drought years*Below cutoff 0.192*** 0.194*** 0.202*** 0.133***

[0.037] [0.024] [0.023] [0.015]

Observations 4,592 4,592 4,592 4,592

R-squared 0.057 0.032 0.108 0.735

Joint F -Statistic 5.21 7.95 8.73 20.60

Region*Year FE No Yes Yes Yes

District FE No No Yes Yes

District trends No No No Yes

Clustered SE district district district district

33

Page 35: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table IVCredit Supply – Effect on Post-Program Lending (District)

The regressions in this table estimate the impact of debt relief on post-program credit supply. Within a panel, each columnrepresents results from a separate regression. The first two columns in each panel report OLS estimates, the second twocolumns report instrumental variables regressions using the first stage relationship reported in Table III. The dependentvariable in columns [1] to [4] is the log number of loans outstanding. The dependent variable in columns [5] to [8] is the logamount of credit outstanding. In addition to the fixed effects reported in the table, all regressions control for the deviation oflagged monsoon rainfall from its long run average, a full set of electoral cycle dummies indicating the number of years untilthe next scheduled state election. Standard errors, in brackets, are heteroskedasticity robust and clustered at the districtlevel. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Dependent variable Log(# loans) Log(amount credit)

OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS

Bailout share*post -0.025* -0.056** -0.015 -0.037 -0.177*** -0.156** -0.030** -0.132***

[0.014] [0.027] [0.042] [0.068] [0.051] [0.077] [0.012] [0.023]

observations 5,131 5,131 4,592 4,592 5,131 5,131 4,592 4,592

# clusters 501 501 441 441 501 501 441 441

R-squared 0.678 0.748 0.727 0.735 0.924 0.941 0.914 0.940

Region*Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District trends No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes

Clustered SE district district district district district district district district

34

Page 36: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table VMoral Hazard – Effect on Post-Program Loan Performance (District)

The regressions in this table estimate the effect of debt relief on loan performance. Within a panel, each column representsresults from a separate regression. The first two columns of each panel report OLS estimates. The second two columnsreport instrumental variables regressions, using the first stage relationship reported in Table III. The dependent variablein columns [1] to [4] is a dummy variable equal to one if a district experienced an increase in the share of non-performingloans. The dependent variable in columns [5] to [8] is a dummy variable equal to one if a district experienced an increasein the share of non-performing credit. In addition to the fixed effects indicated in the table, all regressions contain the fullset of controls described in Table IV. Standard errors, reported in brackets, are heteroskedasticity robust and clustered atthe district level. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Dependent variable Non-performing loans (# accounts) Non-performing loans (share of credit)

OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS

Bailout share*post 0.093*** 0.022 0.442*** 0.720** 0.068*** 0.058 0.468*** 0.740**

[0.021] [0.058] [0.167] [0.344] [0.022] [0.058] [0.177] [0.368]

observations 2,801 2,801 2,514 2,514 2,801 2,801 2,473 2,473

# clusters 472 472 420 420 472 472 420 420

R-squared 0.264 0.513 0.232 0.460 0.282 0.470 0.189 0.413

Region*Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District trends No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes

Clustered SE district district district district district district district district

35

Page 37: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table VIEffects on Credit Supply and Loan Performance (Bank-District)

The regressions in this table estimate the impact of debt relief on credit supply and loan performance,using panel data at the bank-district level. The dataset is based on proprietary data from India’s fourlargest commercial banks and covers agricultural lending and loan performance at 27,678 bank branches,located in 569 districts between 2006 and 2012. The first two columns examine the effect of the bailout oncredit supply. The dependent variable in column [1] is the log number of agricultural loans outstanding.The dependent variable in column [2] is the log amount of agricultural credit outstanding. The secondtwo columns explore the effect of the bailout on loan performance. The dependent variable in column[3] is the share of non-performing agricultural loans. The dependent variable in column [4] is the shareof non-performing agricultural credit. The variable Bailout shareij is a district’s exposure to the bailoutprogram. Bailout sharej measures the mean bailout exposure of each bank across all districts in whichit is present. The variable To account for time-varying credit demand shocks, all regressions control fordistrict-time fixed effects. Standard errors, in brackets, are calculated using the Huber-White correctionfor arbitrary heteroskedasticity and clustered at the district-year level. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Dependent variable Lending Loan performance

Log(credit) Log(# accounts) NPL(share credit) NPL(accounts)

Bailout shareij*post -0.210*** -0.142*** 0.024*** 0.016***

[0.033] [0.045] [0.003] [0.003]

Bailout sharej*post 0.725*** 1.913*** 0.009*** 0.027***

[0.024] [0.078] [0.001] [0.004]

observations 12,479 7,840 12,469 7,840

# districts 569 533 569 533

# clusters 4,051 3,858 4,051 3,858

R-squared 0.470 0.667 0.415 0.587

District*Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

Clustered SE district-year district-year district-year district-year

36

Page 38: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table VIIReal Effects of the Bailout – Productivity, Wages and Employment

The regressions in this table estimates of the effect of debt relief on real outcomes, using a district-level data for the years 2006 to 2012. Within apanel, each column represents results from a separate regression. The first two columns of each panel show OLS estimates, the second two columnsshow instrumental variables estimates based on the first stage regressions in Table III. The dependent variable in columns [1] to [4] is district levelproductivity, calculated as agricultural revenue per hectare at constant 2001 commodity prices. The dependent variable in columns [5] to [8] is thedistrict level real wage for unskilled agricultural occupations. The dependent variabe in columns [9] to [12] is the district level average of monthlyper capita consumption expenditure (Mpce), calculated from Indian National Sample Survey (NSS) microdata. Details on data sources and theconstruction of these variables are available in Table A.I and Appendix D. In addition to the fixed effects reported in the table, all regressions controlfor the deviation of lagged monsoon rainfall from its long run average, electoral cycle dummies indicating the number of years until the next scheduledstate election. All regressions additionally control for time*region and time*metro fixed effects to account for business and credit cycle heterogeneityacross regions as well as across rural versus urban areas. Standard errors, in brackets, are calculated using the Huber-White correction for arbitraryheteroskedasticity and clustered at the district level. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Dependent variable Log(Productivity) Log(Real wage) Log(Consumption)

OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS

Bailout share*post 0.002 0.000 0.009 -0.004 0.022 0.034 -0.025 0.005 0.000 0.011 -0.053 -0.256**

[0.002] [0.004] [0.009] [0.014] [0.014] [0.033] [0.061] [0.147] [0.008] [0.008] [0.075] [0.104]

observations 2,029 2,029 1,916 1,916 915 915 844 844 1,928 1,928 1,727 1,727

R-squared 0.166 0.667 0.157 0.667 0.144 0.598 0.138 0.602 0.916 0.927 0.911 0.846

Region*Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District trends No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes

Clustered SE district district district district district district district district district district district district

37

Page 39: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table VIIIMechanism – Defaults and the Electoral Cycle

This table explores the mechanism underlying the program’s effect on loan performance.The dependent variable in columns [1] and [2] is a dummy variable equal to one if a districtexperienced an increase in the share of non-performing loans [3] and [4] is a dummy variableequal to one if a district experienced an increase in the overall share of non-performingcredit. The coefficient of interest is the diff-in-diff coefficient on the interaction betweenthe program and a dummy variable equal to one for all years in which a district is lessthan two years away from the next scheduled state election. In addition to the fixed effectsreported in the table, all regressions control for the deviation of lagged monsoon rainfallfrom its long run average, as well as year*region and year*metro fixed effects. Standarderrors, reported in brackets, are heteroskedasticity robust and clustered at the districtlevel. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Dependent variable NPL (accounts) NPL (credit)

OLS OLS OLS OLS

Close to election*post 0.064* 0.081 0.132*** 0.131*

[0.039] [0.073] [0.048] [0.076]

observations 3,096 3,096 3,096 3,096

R-squared 0.270 0.461 0.27 0.462

Region*Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

District trends No Yes No Yes

Clustered SE district district district district

38

Page 40: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table IXRobustness – Placebo Program Date

This table reports the results of a placebo test. Panel A displays the estimated effects of the bailout on lending and loan performance, estimatedusing the district panel (columns [1] to [4]) and the bank-district panel (columns [5] to [8]). Panel B reports the results of robustness checksthat test for bias in the difference-in-differences estimates due to unobserved non-linear time trends. To perform the test, we generate placebotreatment vectors containing randomly reassigned values of the treatment variable and use these vectors to estimate counterfactual programeffects. Panel B reports the sample mean and standard deviations for 1,000 counterfactual treatment effect estimates, as well as two-samplet-tests for the equality of estimated program effects in Panel A and the placebo estimates in Panel B. The reported estimates are obtainedfrom regressions using the same set of controls listed in tables IV and VI. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Dependent variable Log(accts) Log(credit) NPL(credit) NPL(accts) Log(accts) Log(credit) NPL(credit) NPL(accts)

2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS

Panel A: Treatment effect estimates

Bailout sharei*post -0.037 -0.132*** 0.720** 0.740**

[0.068] [0.023] [0.344] [0.368]

Bailout shareij*post -0.188*** -0.231*** 0.016*** 0.025***

[0.048] [0.035] [0.004] [0.003]

Panel B: Placebo [post=1(t≥2007)]

Bailout sharePlaceboi *post 0.067 0.04 -0.108* -0.031

[0.056] [0.065] [0.056] [0.055]

Bailout sharePlaceboij *post 0.067 0.04 -0.108* -0.031

[0.056] [0.065] [0.056] [0.055]

95% Confidence interval [-0.043 [-0.089 [-0.218 [-0.138

0.175] 0.168] 0.002] 0.076]

|γ − γPlacebo| [-0.043 [-0.089 [-0.218 [-0.138

Test: P(γ = γPlacebo) 0.175] 0.168] 0.002] 0.076]

Region*Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District trends Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Clustered SE district district district district district-year district-year district-year district-year

39

Page 41: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Table XRobustness – Reassigned Treatment Levels

This table reports the results of a placebo test. In Panel A, we restrict the sample to the pre-program period 2001-2007 and estimate treatmenteffects for a hypothetical program date in 2005. In Panel B, we randomly reassign treatment levels to the districts in our sample and estimatetreatment effects for the actual program date using the entire sample. All outcome variables are as previously defined. In addition to the fixedeffects noted at the foot of the table, all regressions control for time*region and time*metro fixed effects to account for business and creditcycle heterogeneity across regions as well as across rural versus urban areas. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors, reported in brackets,are clustered at the district level. * p<0.10 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Dependent variable Log(accts) Log(credit) NPL(credit) NPL(accts) Log(accts) Log(credit) NPL(credit) NPL(accts)

2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS

Panel A: Treatment effect estimates

Bailout sharei*post -0.037 -0.132*** 0.720** 0.740**

[0.068] [0.023] [0.344] [0.368]

Bailout shareij*post -0.188*** -0.231*** 0.016*** 0.025***

[0.048] [0.035] [0.004] [0.003]

Panel B: Placebo [reassigned treatment]

Bailout sharePlaceboi *post -0.010 -0.026 0.029 0.010

[0.035] [0.057] [0.015] [0.009]

Bailout sharePlaceboij *post -0.001 -0.002 0.000 0.000

[0.002] [0.001] [0.000] [0.000]

95% Confidence interval [-0.079 [-0.138 [-0.001 [-0.008 [-0.005 [-0.005 [-0.000 [-0.000

0.059] 0.086] 0.056] 0.028] 0.0024] 0.0003] 0.0002] 0.0002]

|γ − γPlacebo| 0.027 0.106 0.691 0.730 0.187 0.229 0.016 0.025

Test: P(γ = γPlacebo) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

Region*Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

District trends Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Clustered SE district district district district district-year district-year district-year district-year

40

Page 42: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Figure 1: Program Exposure

(a) Per capita credit outstanding [pre-program]

q4

q3

q2

q1

No data

(b) Program exposure [share of total ag credit]

q4

q3

q2

q1

No data

Notes: The figure plots rural credit per capita on March 31, 2008 the date of the program announcement in Panel (a) against district levelexposure to the bailout, measured as the share of credit outstanding eligible for debt relief under the program in Panel (b). Both variables areplotted as quartiles, darker colors indicate higher amounts of credit per capita and bailout exposure, respectively. The share of credit writtenoff under the program is identical to the treatment variable described in Table I, and available for 501 of India’s 593 (2001) census districts. Inthe base year 2001, the districts in the sample account for approximately 95% of India’s population and 89% of total bank credit outstanding.

41

Page 43: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Figure 2: Parallel Trends – Credit Supply

(a) Number of Loans [2001=100]

��

���

���

���

���

���

���

��

���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ��� ��� ���� ���� ����

�� ��������� �����������

(b) Total Credit [2001=100]

����

���

���

���

���

���

����

���

���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ��� ��� ���� ���� ����

�� ��������� �����������

Notes: The figure plots the time series of the number of agricultural loans outstanding in panel(a) and the amount of agricultural credit outstanding in panel (b) for districts with “high” and“low” program exposure. Districts are classified into “high” and “low” program exposure relativeto the median of the treatment variable. The vertical line indicates the beginning of the program.

42

Page 44: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Figure 3: Parallel Trends – Loan Performance

(a) Non-performing loans [accounts]

����

����

����

����

����

����

����

���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ����

��� ����� ���� �����

(b) Non-performing loans [amount]

����

����

����

����

����

����

����

���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ����

��� ����� ���� �����

Notes: The figure shows the time series of loan performance at the district level, measuredas the share of non-performing agricultural loans in panel (a) and the share of non-performingagricultural credit in panel (b) for districts with “high” and “low” program exposure, respectively.Districts are classified into “high” and “low” program exposure relative to the median of thetreatment variable. The vertical line marks the beginning of the program.

43

Page 45: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Figure 4: Parallel Trends –Real Effects

(a) Rural wage [2006=100]

���

��

���

���

���

���

���

���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ����

��� ����� ���� �����

(b) Productivity [2001=100]

���

��

���

���

���

���

���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ���� ��� ��� ���� ����

�� ��������� �����������

Notes: The figure plots the time series of rural unskilled wages (a) and agricultural productivity,measured as revenue per hectare at constant 2001 commodity prices (b) for districts with “high”and “low” program exposure. Districts are classified into “high” and “low” exposure relative tothe median of the treatment variable. The vertical line indicates the beginning of the program.

44

Page 46: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

Supplemental Appendix

‘The Economic Effects of a Borrower Bailout: Evidence froman Emerging Market’

Xavier Gine† Martin Kanz‡

A Post-Program Credit Supply: How much Reallocation?

Expanding on the finding that districts with greater exposure to the bailout experienced adecline in post-program lending, this section tests to what extent this result is driven bythe reallocation of credit away from ‘high-bailout’ to ‘low-bailout’ districts. To do this, weestimate a difference-in-differences model similar equation [1], but replace our measure oftreatment intensity by the total amount of credit eligible for the bailout in a given district.We then estimate the effect of this variable on the net amount of post-program credit, sothat our coefficient estimates can be interpreted as the amount of new lending per rupee ofbailout received. To test for reallocation in the post-program period, we split the sample indistricts above (high-bailout) and below (low-bailout) the median of program exposure. Theresults in Table A.I indicate that 1 rupee of bailout is associated with 2.2 - 4.3 rupees ofnew lending in low-bailout districts, but only .21 - .36 rupees of new lending in high-bailoutdistricts. This provides strong evidence to suggest that banks actively reallocated creditaway from districts with poorer loan performance in the pre-program period.

Table A.I Effect of the Bailout on Credit Supply – Reallocation

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Amount credit

High-bailout district Low-bailout district

Eligible amount*post 0.213* 0.360 2.198*** 4.259***

[0.125] [0.222] [0.255] [0.430]

observations 2,498 2,498 2,505 2,505

R-squared 0.729 0.811 0.772 0.846

District FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

District trends No Yes No Yes

Clustered SE district district district district

† The World Bank, Development Research Group, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Email: [email protected]

‡ The World Bank, Development Research Group, Email: [email protected]

45

Page 47: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

B Pre-program Outcomes and District Characteristics

This appendix presents additional tests to assess the validity of our exclusion restriction. Weaddress two main concerns that might pose a challenge to our identification strategy.

First, one might be concerned that our instrument –the interaction between the programcutoff and the number of pre-program drought years in a given district– affects outcomesnot only through its effect on program exposure, but also directly. While the identificationassumption that the instrument affects outcomes only through its effect on program exposurecannot be tested directly, we can assess its plausibility by testing for a conditional correlationbetween the instrument and outcomes of interest in the pre-program period. We performthis test in Table B.II and find no correlation between the first stage and any of the mainoutcomes of interest in the period prior to the bailout.

A second potential challenge our identification strategy is that that variation in bailoutexposure induced by the program rules correlates systematically with district characteristicsin 2008 that may have put districts with greater bailout exposure on a different growth pathin the post-program period. We address this challenge by testing for a direct relationshipbetween our first stage and a set of district characteristics at the time of the programannouncement. These tests are presented in Table B.III, and again find no effect.

Table B.II Test – Effects on Pre-program Outcomes

(1) (2)

Coefficient p-value

Dependent variable Drought years*cutoff (H0: No conditional correlation)

Log(# loans) -0.014 [0.024] 0.566

Log(amt credit) 0.004 [0.027] 0.879

Non-performing loans -0.069*[0.040] 0.084

Log(productivity) -0.002 [0.004] 0.547

Log(rural wage) -0.002 [0.004] 0.547

Log(consumption)

Table B.III Test – Effects on District Characteristics in 2008

(1) (2)

Coefficient p-value

Dependent variable Drought years*cutoff (H0: No conditional correlation)

Log(Population) -0.129 [0.132] 0.329

Share rural population 0.006 [0.017] 0.713

Log(Total ag credit) -0.064 [0.134] 0.633

Log(Productivity) -0.012 [0.011] 0.282

46

Page 48: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

C Derivation of Bank-District Level Regression Equation

This appendix presents a simple model of the credit market, from which we derive theestimating equation for credit market outcomes at the bank-district level.

Consider an economy in which j ∈ 1...J banks provide credit to borrowers in i ∈ 1...Ndistricts, so that the lending of bank j in district i can be written as Cijt. We assume bankscan raise deposits at the marginal cost θDDijt, and that loans are financed by either depositsor equity, so that each bank’s lending must be consistent with the identity

Cjt ≡ Djt + Ejt. (C.1)

In each period, banks may experience supply shocks ejt = et + ejt that determine thelevel of equity available to each bank. For the average district, the effect of this supply shockcan be written as Eijt = (et + ejt)/N , where N denotes the number of districts.

On the demand side, we assume that in any given period, a district may experience ademand shock δit = δt + δit with an economy-wide and a district-specific component. Hence,the marginal return of a loan Lijt is given by δt + δit − θCCijt − θBBijt, where Bijt is theamount of non-performing assets of bank j in district i. We assume that θC and θB ∈ [0, 1),so that the marginal return of an additional unit of credit to district i is declining in theamount of credit outstanding as well as the district’s stock of non-performing loans.

Equating marginal cost and marginal return, we obtain the condition θDDijt = δt + δit−θCCijt− θBBijt. Combining this expression with the identity in equation (4.3), we can solvefor the credit market equilibrium

Cijt =δt + 1

NθDet

θD + θL+

1NθD

θD + θLejt −

θBθD + θL

Bijt +1

θD + θLδit (C.2)

The first term in this equation is an economy-wide time-varying constant that includesdemand and supply shocks. The last term is a district-specific time-varying constant. Bothcan be combined into a time-varying district fixed effect αit. The second and third termscontain the main coefficients of interest. We can then rewrite equation (4.3) as follows

ln(Cijt) = αit + γEejt + γBBijt + νijt (C.3)

This equation can be estimated directly, using credit data at the bank-district level, andallows us to isolate the impact of the bailout on credit supply by controlling for demandshocks using a simple fixed effects strategy. The model underlying our estimating equationpredicts that γE > 0 and γB < 0. That is, banks experiencing a larger equity shock (greaterbailout exposure) should increase lending. At the same time, banks should redistributelending away from districts with greater program exposure, as the program allows them toclean troubled assets from their books and thus reduces incentives that may have existedto “evergreen” loans close to default prior to the program (Peek and Rosengren [2005]).This can be tested against the alternative hypothesis that the program encouraged banks to

47

Page 49: The Economic E ects of a Borrower Bailout: …...Maulik Chauhan and Avichal Mahajan provided outstanding research assistance. Financial assistance from the World Bank Research Support

engage in riskier lending. If this were the case, then one would expect γE > 0 and γB > 0.

D Measuring Real Economic Activity

This section describes the construction of outcome variables used to analyze the effect of thebailout on real economic activity in Table VII.

Productivity: To construct a measure of agricultural productivity at the districtlevel, we use data on crop yields from the Indian Department of Agriculture database onAgricultural Prices in India. The dataset is an unbalanced panel which reports the (i) areacultivated and (ii) total harvest in tons for each the 25 most common crops in India for alldistricts of India over the time period 2000/01–2010/11. We first aggregate these data tothe district as defined in the 2001 census, our unit of analysis throughout the paper. The foreach year and crop we aggregate total area planted and crop output for two crop seasons,Kharif and Rabih. To measure productivity in monetary terms, we obtained commodityprices for the base year 2001 from the Indiastat17 for all crops in the dataset as of January2001. Letting acdy denote the area planted with crop c ∈ {1...C} in district d and year y,letting rcdy denote the total production of crop c in district d and year y, and letting pc′01

denote the price of commodity c in the base year 2001, we calculate productivity per hectare

in district d and year y as Productivitydy =∑C

c=1{rcdy ·pc‘01}∑C

c=1 acdy

. We use constant prices for the

base year 2001 to construct a productivity measure that is unaffected by commodity priceshocks and allows us to isolate the component of productivity that can be affected by bailoutbeneficiaries.

Wages: Rural wages are calculated from the Indian Department of Agriculture’s Agri-cultural Wages in India (AWI) dataset. The dataset contains wages for several unskilledprofessions by district and month. We measure the wage for unskilled labor as the averagewage of agricultural field labor. Data are available for an unbalanced panel of 264 districtsbetween the years 2006–2012.

Consumption: We measure household consumption using round of the Indian Na-tional Sample Survey (NSS). We use the 2004–2005, 2006–2007, 2009–2010 and 2011–2012rounds of the NSS and focus on monthly household consumption expenditure, measuredannually in schedule 1 of the NSS. To ensure that our measure of household consumption isconsistent across different NSS rounds, we use monthly per capita expenditure (Mpce). Thiskey indicator of household consumption is available for all survey rounds and widely used inthe calculation of poverty measures at the national and sub-national level. We calculate thearithmetic mean of repeated cross-sectional survey rounds at the district-level, and obtain apanel of monthly per capita consumption for 238 districts.

17“District-wise farm harvest prices of principal agricultural crops in India”, available at http://www.indiastat.com/agriculture

48