the economics of social housing

76
[email protected] Arcwell Ltd Slide 1 Economics of Social Housing Version 1 Jan 2009 The Economics of Social Housing

Upload: walker

Post on 14-Jan-2016

46 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

The Economics of Social Housing. Learning objectives. The aim of this session is to equip you with a basic understanding of the economic factors driving affordable housing – supply and demand - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 1

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1 Jan 2009

The Economics of Social Housing

Page 2: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 2

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Learning objectives

• The aim of this session is to equip you with a basic understanding of the economic factors driving affordable housing – supply and demand

• We will survey the history of the UK housing market in general and then focus on the recent history of UK social housing

• We will then outline the economic mechanisms that drive social housing with special attention to S106

• And we will assess how well S106 has performed

• Finally we will explain how and why the credit crunch happened and what its impact has been on UK affordable housing

Page 3: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 3

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Contents

1. Executive summary2. The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply and demand trends

• Or why the need for social housing is driven by macroeconomics – restricted supply relative to demand

3. The macroeconomics of social housing: supply and demand trends4. The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

• Or how affordable housing has been provided as a tax on developers and as a means of avoiding grants

5. Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing• Or how well S106 addresses the economic issues of affordable housing

6. UK affordable housing in the credit crunch7. The credit crunch and its economic impact UK housing

• What happened, why, and what it means

Page 4: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 4

Key findings

• The UK does not build enough houses to keep up with demand especially in the south east – we need around 155,000 new houses annually to cope with household growth

• Affordable housing has changed its role from being a chosen form of housing to being primarily a safety net for the very poorest in society

• Planning (S106) does not give the UK enough affordable homes

• Government spending on affordable housing is broadly the static– but the money goes on demand (rent) not on supply (house building)

• The HCA aims to transform UK housing by significant house building in smart, “joined-up” ways. The credit crunch could compromise its ambitions if private house building does not participate

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Page 5: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 5

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Executive summary (1)

• The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply trends

The UK’s overall supply of housing has grown in every period since 1939

National housing supply does not respond to increasing prices and rising demand

UK house building is less responsive than other countries

Housing is in short supply in the south but in surplus in the north

Land supply has declined especially in the south due to planning

Restricted supply has driven up house prices and reduced affordability in cycles

• The macroeconomics of housing overall: demand trends

Mortgages are more affordable, so demand for housing has increased

But first time buyers are worse off because the cost of deposits has risen

Housing demand will be driven by changing types of household

Planning constraints deliver national preferences, but imperfectly

• The macroeconomics of social housing: supply

The overall net supply of social housing has declined since 1979

Most of the stock of social housing are existing units

Local Authority spending on maintenance and management has risen

Subsidies for housing are little reduced but have shifted to the demand side

• The macroeconomics of social housing: demand

Underlying drivers of social housing have improved, but affordability is still an issue

The role of social housing is now to provide a safety net for the poorest

Far fewer social tenants are now employed compared to previous decades

Overcrowding is still an issue, driving the need for social housing

Social tenants enjoy less space per person, and are more dissatisfied

The real value to tenants of social housing is significant

Social housing’s real value to tenants varies across the country

Page 6: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 6

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Executive summary (2)

• The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

Planning policy has forced developers to create social housing

S106-driven affordable housing is a stable component of housing completions

S106 has grown as affordable housing additions has declined

Regional supply of affordable housing matches demand, but not due to S106

• Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing

Affordable housing via S106 may not increase the total supply of housing

S106 does deliver affordable housing but is not necessarily fair

S106 house building still needs public money and developers get a good deal

Local authorities lack commercial skills to make S106 fully effective

• The impact of the credit crunch What happened

Began when banks lent too much on risks they didn’t understand

Liquidity and banks’ confidence destroyed Trust and therefore credit evaporated

Why it happened Roots are in US affordable housing Innovations in finance created the crunch The world gorged on credit The whole system was incentivised to exploit

credit through securitisation Subprime lending went wrong because it was

risky, hidden – and predatory Scale of securitisation and CDOs created a

chain reaction The whole finance system into shock Banking crises often happen, but innovations

made this one worse than usual How it affects the UK

Securitisation was the lifeblood of the UK mortgage market but it has collapsed

Overall housing market decimated Threatens all house building Changes the game for affordable housing Much depends on the HCA

Page 7: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 7

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Key Sources

• Stephens, Whitehead, and Munro: Lessons From the Past, Challenges for the Future for Housing Policy: Evaluation of English Housing Policy 1975–2000, ODPM, 2005

• Hills: Ends And Means: The Future Roles Of Social Housing In England, ESRC Research Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion / Department of Communities and Local Government, 2007

• Monk: The Provision Of Affordable Housing Through Section 106, Royal Institute of Chartered Surveyors, 2007

Page 8: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 8

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Contents

1. Executive summary2. The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply and demand trends

• Or why the need for social housing is driven by macroeconomics – restricted supply relative to demand

3. The macroeconomics of social housing: supply and demand trends4. The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

• Or how affordable housing has been provided as a tax on developers and as a means of avoiding grants

5. Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing• Or how well S106 addresses the economic issues of affordable housing

6. UK affordable housing in the credit crunch7. The credit crunch and its economic impact UK housing

• What happened, why, and what it means

Page 9: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 9

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The UK’s overall supply of housing has grown in every period since 1939

• Changing housing stock composition since 1939

• UK Housing stock has doubled since WW2 UK housing stock doubled to 22 million units

since 1939 Owner occupation has grown

continuously, other tenures have varied over time.

Private rentals fell from the 1940s until the late 1980s, but grew to 11% of stock by 2004.

The Right to Buy and less new building reduced social housing to only 18.5% of the stock by 2004.

Source: Hills 2007

Page 10: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 10

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

National housing supply does not respond to increasing prices and rising demand

• House building has declined and price elasticity of supply has been near zero since 1990

Supply of new houses reduced significantly after 1980, as shown in Figure 2.1 from Stephens et al 2005, which looks at trends in new build completions since the end of WW2

Public/social sector output was high until the late 1970s. The private sector has not replaced public sector supply of new housing

Private output rose in response to house increases in the boom of the late 1980s

But private output did not increase in response to booming prices in the boom late 1990s-early 2000s. Supply elasticity was low, but is now virtually zero

• Supply has been low in both north and south, despite growing demand in the south

Declining supply of houses since 1975 is shown in Figure 2.2 from Stephens et al which looks at new building in the ‘North’ (including the midlands) and ‘South’ (including London).

The decline was steeper in the early part of the period, when public sector output declined from its previously high levels.

Again, despite booming house prices, house supply has declined, due to falling private sector output.

Output has declined in both the north and the south, despite the much stronger demand in the south.

Source: Stephens et al 2005

Page 11: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 11

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

UK house building is less responsive than other countries

• The UK is less responsive than other countries to changes in prices

• UK house building is only half as responsive as the French, a third as responsive as the US and only a quarter as responsive as German house building.

• Over the last 10-15 years, UK supply has become almost totally unresponsive, so as prices have risen, the supply of houses has not increased at all.

• Planning has been a constraint on the supply of new houses in the UK

• Housing targets define how much land local authorities allow for development.

• But regional and local housing targets do not respond to housing demand - the UK's supply of new housing responds relatively little, compared to other countries, to changes in house prices.

• House building is politically contentious • Local costs of development can be high and

those already housed have a much stronger voice than those in need of housing.

• Land is often unsuitable• Much undeveloped land is either in areas of low

demand, or does not possess required infrastructure.

• Brownfield land has high development costs

• House building is a structurally inflexible industry

• The house building industry market and planning risks mean the industry which is reluctant to invest for the long term and employ direct labour, which may hold back production rates.

Source: Barker 2004

Page 12: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 12

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Housing is in short supply in the south but in surplus in the north

• Surplus housing stocks have declined in most areas

• Figure 2.3 from Stephens et al shows the balance between households and dwellings, expressed as the percentage surplus dwellings over households.

• Housing surpluses rose in most areas before 1980 and were substantial in the South East, due to public sector house building.

• After 1980, surplus declined in all regions, as public sector supply was cut back.

• In the 1990s, housing surplus shrank in London and the South East, while low demand in the North East led to growing surpluses.

• Surpluses vary across regions, with surplus stocks in the north and shortages in the south

• Figure 2.4 shows the annual rate of dwelling growth minus the annual rate of household growth for five-year periods from 1975 to 2001, distinguishing the north from the south.

• Surpluses of houses over households grew in the late 1970s but fell back in the early 1980s. Between 1985 and 1996, household and dwelling growth were reasonably in step.

• Since 1996, dwelling growth ran ahead of households in the north while falling short in the south. There is increasing shortage in the south and increasing surplus in the north.

Source: Stephens et al 2005

Page 13: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 13

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Land supply has declined especially in the south due to planning

• Land supply is constrained in urban regions

• Figure 2.5 from Stephens shows the stock of outstanding planning permissions for private housing, per thousand resident households.

• Supply was more generous in the relatively rural East Midlands, East of England and South West.

• The stock supply was more limited in the more urban regions, both north and south.

• Stock supply rose slightly between 1988 and 1994 reflecting the 1980s boom and recession cycle.

• Stock supply fell in most regions up to 1997. The fall was modest in the three northern regions, substantial elsewhere, and very high in the South East.

• Planning permissions have declined since 1990

• Figure 2.6 from Stephens looks at a measure of the flow supply of new planning permissions.

• Supply rose in the late 1980s boom period, but has since fallen more or less continuously. The fall was proportionately greater in the south.

• London has always had a low supply and dropped further in the late 1990s.

• In the south, supply has fallen to about half its peak rate of 1988.

Source: Stephens et al 2005

Page 14: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 14

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Restricted supply has driven up house prices and reduced affordability in cycles

• Regional housing and land price show that planning restrictions pushes up house prices

• Economic theory says that if planning cuts the number of houses which can be built below the volume demanded by the market then house prices will increase.

• Real house prices have been in a cycle of booms and busts since 1969. Each boom ends at a higher level of (real) pricing.

• This cycle of boom and bust shows that Britain has a low elasticity of supply of new housing. I.e. housing supply is static, but long term demand is rising. This is partly because of planning constraints

• In the long term prices have risen significantly (3.3% pa in real terms over this whole 35 year period for UK, or 2.1% since the cyclically comparable year of 1973).

• Both cycles and growth are stronger in some regions than others. In London prices in 2005 were over 3.5 times their level in 1969, whilst for the North they have only slightly more than doubled.

• Regional affordability ratios indicate that planning restrictions drive up prices

• The same cyclical pattern exists in terms of affordability – the ratio of house prices to incomes. Figure 2.10 shows the ratio of average house price to average disposable household income for the same regions, for the period since 1984.

• The latest boom is not ‘worse’, in terms of driving higher ratios, than the previous one, though the real price rises in 2002 and 2003 have pushed these ratios to higher levels.

• Houses are more expensive, but people were still as likely on average to be able to afford them as in previous periods, at least up till 2001. Very low interest rates since the mid 1990s make a given ratio of income to house price more affordable than they were in 1989.

• Changes in the distribution of income may, of course, have made affordability worse for some groups. Source: Stephens et al 2005

Page 15: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 15

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Mortgages are more affordable, so demand for housing has increased

• Interest payments are low

• Total interest payments are now 8.9% of disposable income compared with a high of over 15% in 1990 (Chart 2.2)

• Repossessions have been at a fraction of their peak in 1991 when over 70,000 properties were taken into possession (Chart 2.3).

• Mortgage rates are low

• Mortgage rates have been at their lowest for forty years – average building society rates were 5.2% in May, compared with 11% between 1979 and 1997.

• Over the last 50 years the proportion of households that own their own home has increased substantially – to over 70% in 2003 (Chart 2.4).

• Nine out of ten households would prefer to own their own home if they could.

Source: Barker 2004

Page 16: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 16

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

But first time buyers are worse off because the cost of deposits has risen

• One of the costs of long-term under supply is higher house prices and a lack of market affordability.

• Higher house prices make it harder for younger, less well-off households to buy their own home.

• Rising prices mean higher deposit costs so it is harder for first time buyers to enter the housing market. They often need help from relatives: in London over a third of first time buyers between 1995 and 2001 used gifts, family loans, inheritances or windfalls to fund deposits

• In contrast, in many European countries the ratio of house prices to incomes is lower than it was 30 years ago.

Source: Barker 2004

Page 17: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 17

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Housing demand will be driven by changing types of household

• Volumes of households are increasing because of social changes

Households are rising at around 155,000 a year from 1996 to 2021.

Many are single parent or single person households.

• Household increases are greatest in the south

Increase in households is concentrated in London and the South East – where there is already the most demand for housing.

London and the South East are expected to see 80,000 extra households each year to 2021.Source: Barker 2004

Page 18: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 18

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Planning constraints deliver national preferences, but imperfectly

• Planning constraints on housing supply fulfils policy aims and reflects national preferences The housing market expresses national preferences for land use, where the UK wants to

preserve land. This protects the countryside and addresses urban decline. The UK overall is a relatively densely populated country (242 persons per sq. km), on a par

with Germany (230 persons per sq. km). It is significantly less dense than Belgium (337 per sq. km) or the Netherlands (390 per sq.

km). But England is much more dense at 380 persons per sq. km. Constrained supply creates problems of affordability and constraints on economic

growth – these are the price of urban regeneration and preservation of green belt and rural landscape.

• But planning may constrain supply unnecessarily Some development would have a high cost to society (such as urban parks and fields with

rights of way). But some argue planning stops building on land with a lower social value. Planning is an insider-outsider problem: house owners inside the housing market have

more power over decisions than those outside and their decisions reflect their own interests rather than those of the wider community.

• Only increased housing supply can enhance affordability Greater affordability for all cannot be achieved by increasing government subsidy to home

ownership. It can help some groups (e.g. “key workers”). But if subsidies increase demand and supply is held constant, then prices will rise. If some households do not receive a subsidy they might be squeezed out of the market. Wider affordability can only be sustainable by increasing the supply of housing Source: Barker 2004

Page 19: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 19

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Contents

1. Executive summary2. The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply and demand trends

• Or why the need for social housing is driven by macroeconomics – restricted supply relative to demand

3. The macroeconomics of social housing: supply and demand trends4. The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

• Or how affordable housing has been provided as a tax on developers and as a means of avoiding grants

5. Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing• Or how well S106 addresses the economic issues of affordable housing

6. The credit crunch and its impact on affordable housing provision• What happened, why, and what it means for affordable house building

Page 20: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 20

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The macroeconomics of social housing: supply

Page 21: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 21

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The overall net supply of social housing has declined since 1979

• Changing housing stock since 1939

• Social rented stock peaked in 1979 Social housing grew rapidly after WW2, to

31% of stock in 1979, dominated by local authority housing.

The Right to Buy and less new building reduced social housing to only 18.5% by 2004.

New building is by housing associations – who took stock from councils. In 2004 housing associations had almost as many units (1.8M) as local authorities (2.2M).

• Changing social housing stock since 1991

• The net supply of new-build social rented dwellings has fallen since 1991

Less social housing was built. Many social houses were bought under Right to

Buy - sales peaked in 2003-04 and 2004-05. People bought council houses before maximum discounts reduced. Net housing stocks shrank by more than 60,000 in 2003-04 and 2004-05.

The pace of reduction has slowed. Source: Hills 2007

Page 22: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 22

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Most of the stock of social housing are existing units

• Social housing stock is dominated by existing units

The diagram compares the structure of social housing in 1996 and 2005.

It shows that 93% of the 4 million social rented units in 2005 were already within the sector nine years earlier.

Existing stock is more significant than newly-built stock. Even if 40,000 new units were added each year from 2006 to 2016, 90% of the UK’s 2016 social rented stock would have been in existence in 2006

• Local authority stock has been replaced by housing association stock

The local authority sector has reduced through demolitions, sales and transfers to housing associations

The housing association sector has grown through those transfers, new building, and acquisitions of existing properties.

• Stock quality is improving overall Social homes failing to reach the Decent

Homes standard has almost halved from 2.3 million to 1.2 million

Source: Hills 2007

Page 23: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 23

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Local Authority spending on maintenance and management has risen

• Councils spend more on maintenance, and rent income matches spending

Local authority maintenance spending was constant until 2002-03, but grew since then.

Council properties get an average of £34 per week for supervision, management and repair, plus £11 per week for major repairs, and £10 per week for interest on borrowing.

£52 per week is collected in gross rents Council house spending is sustainable

– a holding pattern – because rent almost covers costs (there is a small government subsidy).

Building many new houses would increase cost vastly

• Housing associations spend about the same on maintenance

Housing associations spent £40 per week for each property, compared to £56 per week collected in rents

These figures are not strictly comparable with those for local authorities, but suggest that rental income was slightly higher and current spending on management, maintenance and provision for major repair slightly lower per dwelling.

Social Housing Expenditure 1997-2006

OtherCapital

expenditure

Debt charges

Management and

maintenance

£0

£500

£1,000

£1,500

£2,000

£2,500

£3,000

£3,500

1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06

An

nu

al E

xpen

dit

ure

Per

D

wel

lin

g (

2005

-6 p

rice

s)

Other Capital expenditure Debt charges2 Management and maintenance

Source: Hills 2007

Page 24: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 24

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Subsidies for housing are little reduced but have shifted to the demand side

• Total public support to housing is little lower in real terms now than in the mid-1970s

But there has been a decisive shift from supply-side to demand-side subsidy.

• Supply subsidies that allow producers to supply housing at lower cost have fallen

Capital subsidies (grants to housing associations to build new dwellings) fell rapidly in the second half of the 1970s, and again after the early 1990s, before rising after 1999-00.

• Demand subsidies have grown Demand subsidies allow consumers to

spend more than they would otherwise. Housing Benefit grew to around between

£10-12 billion since 1993-94 Reducing benefits for private sector

renters was offset by growth in benefit for social tenants

Housing Subsidy 1975 - 2004

Capital (Supply)

LA Revenue (Supply)

Rent rebate (Demand)

Rent allowance (Demand)

Mortgage interest relief (Demand)

Income Support Mortgage Interest

(Demand)

0

5

10

15

20

25

1975-76 1980-81 1985-86 1992-93 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04

Year

Co

st,

£b

illi

on

(2

00

3-4

pri

ce

s)

Income Support Mortgage Interest (Demand)

Mortgage interest relief (Demand)

Rent allowance (Demand)

Rent rebate (Demand)

LA Revenue (Supply)

Capital (Supply)

Source: Hills 2007

Page 25: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 25

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The macroeconomics of social housing: demand

Page 26: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 26

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Underlying drivers of social housing have improved, but affordability is still an issue

• Many indicators of housing market stress have improved as overall housing conditions have improved

Mortgage arrears and repossessions are a fraction of the peaks of the early 1990s.

Annual mortgage repossessions were 0.1% per year, a seventh of the rate in the early 1990s, until 2009.

Literal homelessness – sleeping rough –fell between 1998 and 2001, since when it has been stable.

Households placed in “bed and breakfasts” by local authorities has fallen since 2002, back to the levels of the mid 1990s – but use of temporary accommodation has doubled

“Concealed households” (households that could form separately) fell from 165,000 in 1991 to 140,000 in 2000 and have fallen slightly since then

Separate households sharing dwellings (couples or lone parents living within another household) fell from 390,000 in 1996 to 207,000 in 2006 (up from a low point in 2004). Numbers seem down significantly over the last decade.

• These indicators have not disappeared and much is still to be done

• But affordability is the key driver of social housing Source: Hills 2007

Page 27: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 27

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Social housing waiting lists are worse now than in 2002

• Geography of social housing waiting lists

• Council waiting lists are up 53% on 2002 Immigration and ageing populations

have driven demand for council housing

Many of the growing number of people in temporary rented housing form lengthening queues for social housing

House building has not kept up

Source: The Times, 12-09-2008

Page 28: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 28

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The role of social housing is now to provide a safety net for the poorest

• Over the last quarter century the role of social housing has changed. The social housing sector has become much smaller as a proportion of the total, although nearly 4

million households still live within it. In the past many people chose to live in social housing. Post-War provision was aimed at

households on a range of incomes. With rising real incomes and the Right to Buy, many of those social renters bought their own council houses or bought other houses, many of them ex-rental.

Demand for social housing is now driven by need where in the past it was a matter of choice.

• Since the 1980s provision has become more tightly constrained and new lettings focussed on those in greatest need.

Most people have been able to afford to buy houses despite rising prices and constrained supply, as real incomes rose and interest rates dropped

But people who could not afford to participate in the housing market often had severe needs for affordable housing.

• Social tenants are now much more likely to have low incomes and not to be in employment than in the past, and to be “stuck” in social housing.

Social tenants in paid employment fell from 47% to 32% between 1981 and 2006. 70% of social tenants have incomes within the poorest 40% of the overall income distribution Tenants have high rates of disability, are more likely than others to be lone parents or single

people, and to be aged over 60. 27% of all black or minority ethnic householders are social tenants (including around half of Bangladeshi and 43% of black Caribbean and black African householders), compared to 17% of white householders.

More than 80% of those living in social housing today were also within the sector ten years ago

Page 29: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 29

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Social tenants are now consistently poorer, compared to previous decades

• Social tenants have increasingly concentrated in the lowest income groups since the 1980s

• This is a major change from the position in the 1960s and 1970s.

In 1979, 20% of the richest tenth lived in social housing.

Now hardly any of those in the top fifth of earners have social housing.

Better-off tenants purchased under the Right to Buy, or paid to move elsewhere.

• By 2004-05 a third of people living in social

housing had incomes in the poorest fifth of the income distribution. 70% were in the poorest two-fifths. (Hills, p87). This was driven by changes in employment status.

Social tenants in employment has fallen from 47% to 32%; full-time employment from 43% to 22%.

In contrast employed private renters have risen from 58% to 69%; employed house owners are stable, falling from 70 to 68% (with increasing retirees).

Part time work rose rapidly, to just under 50% in 2005, driven by increasing numbers of lone parents.

“Unemployed” social tenants have fallen but many are “other inactive” (63% are lone parents) and in the “permanently sick or disabled”, to nearly one quarter of all those of working age.

Source: Hills 2007

Page 30: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 30

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Overcrowding is still an issue, driving the need for social housing

• Overcrowding is a consistent issue for social renters and a growing issue for private renters

• For most of the last decade, about 500,000 households have been in dwellings failing the “bedroom standard”, with little clear trend, although in the private rented sector the number has risen from 63,000 to 110,000 (Figure 4.7). The rate of overcrowding against this standard is higher in the social rented sector than in owner occupation.

• It is also higher in London than elsewhere, at 11% of social housing households. This rate rises to 28 and 29% for black African and Bangladeshi householders.

• Overcrowding in London has increased since 1998-99, mostly in the private rented sector, doubling from 25,000 to over 50,000 by 2005-06.

• The “bedroom standard” of number of bedrooms needed for their household size and composition allows one bedroom for each couple or person over 21 in a household, plus bedrooms for children on the assumption that two of the same sex can share, as can two children of different sex aged under 10. Source: Hills 2007

Page 31: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 31

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Social tenants enjoy less space per person, and are more dissatisfied

• Space drives satisfaction with homes For any given level of space social tenants

are far more likely to be dissatisfied 30% of social tenants with the least space

are dissatisfied, compared to 10% of owners.

Overcrowded social tenants have fewer options to move and will be affected longer

Largely unemployed social tenants are affected for more of their time each day.

Owners choose a trade-off between space and price; social tenants have not.

• Social tenants have a quarter less space per person than owner-occupiers

28% of both private and social tenant households are in the most crowded fifth overall, but only 17% of owners, although density varies across all tenures.

The most crowded tenth has 15.4 m2 per person

The least crowded tenth 91.5 square metres, six times as much.

• Higher income may not mean more space

In all tenures, more income means more space per person.

Owner-occupiers’ space per household rises with income. But tenants' space varies little by income.

Source: Hills 2007

Page 32: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 32

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The real value to tenants of social housing is significant

• The advantage to tenants of rents that generate a sub-economic return is in the hundreds of billions.

• The “economic subsidy” (the difference between actual rents and those giving an economic return) reached £6.6 billion in England in 2004, higher in real terms than in 1996.

Three-fifths of this total went to social tenants in London, the South East and South West. In Northern regions and the Midlands, actual social rents were £10-20 per week below those that would give a comparable return on housing capital values to those in the private sector, but in the East and South East the difference was £40-50, and in London about £70-80. (Source: Communities and Local Government analysis, HCA.)

• London’s higher capital values mean economic rent would be £138 per week for local authority properties, or £150 per week for housing associations.

Actual social rents do not vary much across the country, so there are much higher levels of subsidy in London than in lower cost regions – averaging £71 per week for local authorities and £80 per week for housing associations.

The net present value of a subsidy at this level to tenants who stay for 15 or 20 years is around £32,000 across the country and more than £65,000 in London.

• With a national average value for social rented dwellings of £105,000 in 2004 the overall housing stock is worth £400 billion.

Net of management, maintenance and repair, rents were yielding around 1% on this capital value (0.9% for local authorities, 1.2% for associations), well below an economic rate of return

Page 33: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 33

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Social housing’s real value to tenants varies across the country

Capital value (£)

Economic rent (£/w)

Actual rent (£/w)

Subsidy (£/w) Net present value, 15 yrs

Net present value, 20 yrs

(a) Local authorities

North East 58,600 55 43 11 9,000 11,500

North West 65,100 65 47 17 15,400 19,100

Yorkshire & the Humber 62,200 65 44 20 16,700 20,600

East Midlands 77,700 67 46 21 17,200 21,200

West Midlands 73,900 67 49 17 15,400 19,000

East of England 128,200 101 55 46 36,700 44,400

London 165,200 138 67 71 55,400 66,700

South East 128,000 98 59 38 32,100 39,000

South West 100,800 76 50 26 22,700 27,700

England 100,700 87 53 34 28,000 34,100

(b) Housing associations

North East 59,600 55 49 6 7,300 9,500

North West 65,500 65 52 13 14,600 18,200

Yorkshire & the Humber 66,010 67 50 17 18,200 22,400

East Midlands 85,400 70 53 18 17,000 21,200

West Midlands 87,300 73 52 20 18,100 22,400

East of England 119,200 96 60 35 29,800 36,300

London 189,100 150 70 80 60,500 72,800

South East 142,400 105 67 38 34,200 41,700

South West 117,000 83 58 25 24,300 29,800

England 111,400 93 61 31 29,400 35,900Source: Hills 2007

Page 34: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 34

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Contents

1. Executive summary2. The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply and demand trends

• Or why the need for social housing is driven by macroeconomics – restricted supply relative to demand

3. The macroeconomics of social housing: supply and demand trends4. The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

• Or how affordable housing has been provided as a tax on developers and as a means of avoiding grants

5. Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing• Or how well S106 addresses the economic issues of affordable housing

6. UK affordable housing in the credit crunch7. The credit crunch and its economic impact UK housing

• What happened, why, and what it means

Page 35: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 35

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Planning policy has forced developers to create social housing

• Since the 1990s local authorities have used planning powers to promote the provision of affordable housing.

• The aim is to make developers (or landowners) pay for affordable housing.

Local authorities negotiate with developers for the inclusion of an element of ‘affordable housing’ within general housing sites. The policy covers both social rented housing and Low Cost Home Ownership (LCHO)

• Developed at the end of the 1980s, the aim was to address the needs of lower income households

Poorer people were being priced out of local housing markets during the boom

Then in the slump in the housing market, repossessions by mortgage lenders added to the housing burden.

Neither Local authorities nor the Housing Corporation could provide enough affordable housing. The Right to Buy (1980) meant local authorities were losing their stock and Local Authorities could not afford to replace it.

• The policy operates through Section 106 of the Town and Country Planning Act 1990 (S106)

• S106 agreements mitigate against the impact of development by providing additional infrastructure, or – increasingly – to require the inclusion of affordable housing requirements at the cost of the developer.

• The policy affects the supply side, complementing the public focus on demand side subsidy

Although often the whole site may be built out by the builder, the houses are transferred to the RSL at a price which reflects the reduced land value.

In some cases, the houses may be transferred at less than construction cost, entailing a cross-subsidy from the market part of the site

Page 36: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 36

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

S106-driven affordable housing is a stable component of housing completions

• S106-driven completions are increasing

• S106 is vital in London, less so in the north

• S106 is more important in London and the South East than in northern regions. This is as would be predicted, on the basis of development land values.

Source: Stephens et al 2005

Page 37: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 37

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

S106 has grown as affordable housing additions has declined

• S106 is half of affordable house building

• S106 output has risen by fast since 1999-2000

S106 rose from 5% to 12% of total private completions from 1999 to 2007.

S106 drove 21% of all affordable housing completions in 1999-2000, rising to 55% in 2004-05 – but falling back to 50% in 2005/6

• Most S106 starts are in major residential developments

26% of large developments had S106 housing in 1997-98; 40% in 2003-04.

• S106 housing is substantial in value £1.15 billion in England in 2003-04 (Barker

2006).

• But affordable housing volumes do not grow as a result of S106

The volume of affordable dwellings built depends on Government grants and overall house building

In the late 1990s both declined so fewer affordable homes were built.

Affordable housing delivery therefore fell 30% between 2000-01 and 2001-02, a fall of over one third.

From 2001 both funding and house building rose - but slowly

Growth in affordable housing has been slow. Output levels are only 75% of 1999 levels

S106 succeeds in delivering affordable housing without public subsidy.

Only when the government starts to increase finance do output levels rise. Crook et al demonstrate this by looking in more detail at S106 completions.

Source: RICS

Page 38: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 38

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Contents

1. Executive summary2. The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply and demand trends

• Or why the need for social housing is driven by macroeconomics – restricted supply relative to demand

3. The macroeconomics of social housing: supply and demand trends4. The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

• Or how affordable housing has been provided as a tax on developers and as a means of avoiding grants

5. Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing• Or how well S106 addresses the economic issues of affordable housing

6. UK affordable housing in the credit crunch7. The credit crunch and its economic impact UK housing

• What happened, why, and what it means

Page 39: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 39

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Affordable housing via S106 may not increase the total supply of housing

• S106 does generate some new social housing without the need for grant According to Stephens 30% of affordable housing provided on S106 sites is provided without Social

Housing Grant. This part of the output is ‘additional’. The other 70% of S106 schemes that get grants have some additionality because they “stretch” SHG

to create more homes – but these schemes tend to be on more expensive sites.

• S106 does not offset the decline in publicly-subsidised house building. S106 completions are not enough to substitute for the decline in affordable homes built in the

traditional way with government grant to housing associations – S106 completions rose by 30% but the total rose by only 15%.

At the turn of the century total output was 45,000 units. Total output was 33,000 in 2004-05.

• The Housing Corporation still built 50% or more of public housing in 2005/6 Since 1974 the Housing Corporation has been the major provider of capital finance for RSLs, using the

Approved Development Programme (ADP). ADP accounted for the funding of 50% of affordable housing in 2005/6.

The amount delivered with no support increased from 18% in 2004/5 to 25% in 2005/6. The remainder is funded through a mixture of subsidy and developer contribution.

• The policy remains disappointing in terms of the amount of ‘additional’ provision and cross-subsidy from development gains actually achieved.

The policy has changed the geography of new social housing, and it is achieving the new aim of promoting mixed communities.

However, developer contributions as a proportion of overall development values on mixed sites remains low, in the range of 2-12%.

Therefore, the policy could achieve more, if there were better land supply, and consistent policy. But there are limits to the development gain which can be tapped given other demands for

infrastructure and brownfield land remediation.

Page 40: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 40

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

S106 does deliver affordable housing but is not necessarily fair

• S106 provides affordable housing on sites that RSLs cannot afford to buy

• S106 changed the geography of affordable housing

RSLs can now access high value sites Mixed developments are more common S106 increased take-up of brown-field

land.

• In areas where land supply is completely tied up in the private sector, S106 is the only way RSLs can develop.

RSLs used to have access to ex-local government owned land, or public sector land (e.g. NHS Trusts) but often this has run out.

• S106 agreements are usually fully implemented

• S106 is accepted by developers Local Authorities report that in the vast

majority of cases S106 agreements are implemented in full (RICS and Stephens quoting Monk et al 2006).

• Both developers and Local Authorities would like S106 agreements to be better specified but both sides have learnt a great deal

• S106 is effectively a tax on larger residential developments

• S106 is a tax, but developers do not know what the tax rate will be before development

Developers are uncertain about how this tax is applied – and the lack of clarity is a little unfair

House builders do not offer S106 as philanthropy. It is a coercive system. Affordable housing is the price paid for planning permission. It is part of the cost of development, a cross-subsidy from development value to affordable housing

Developers and LA s agree that greater consistency and clarity are required.

• S106 delays developments • 45% of S106 development agreements

(11,500 cases) take more than six months to complete

• 11% (around 3,700 developments) take over a year to negotiate (Barker 2006).

• S106 agreements can cause delay and frustration.

Source: RICSSource: Stephens, RICS

Page 41: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 41

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

S106 house building still needs public money and developers get a good deal

• S106 housing is usually funded by public bodies as well as developers

• Local authorities help fund most S106-based social housing by providing land at lower cost

Average SHG rates were typically 40-60% of scheme costs but could be higher in the South.

Grant rates for shared ownership were roughly 20% to 30%.

Costs per unit including land range from below £30,000 for a small rural exception site used for shared ownership up to £135,000 for rented flats in a central London luxury development.

In the majority of cases the land was given free or heavily discounted.

Costs excluding land were typically around £50,000 but rising to £60,000 – £70,000 in the South East and up to £80,000 in London.

Costs for shared ownership were considerably lower.

• Developer contributions are large absolutely, but not relatively

• Local authorities are good at using S106 to gain land and money from developers

In 2005/6 developer contributions of discounted or free land went up to 2,519 hectares from 40 Ha in 2004/5.

But most of this was in the South West (up from only 8 hectares in 2004/5 to 2475 hectares in 2005/6).

Financial contributions increased from £40M in 2004/5 to £142M in 2005/6.

Most of this was in the South East (£103M in 2005/6, compared to £11M)

• Developers’ contributions are only a small percentage of scheme development values

RICS surveys of developers and LAs found that developers contribute 2-12% of scheme value

Since land values are 40%+ of total value, S106-based developer contributions are relatively low

E.g. a 25% developer contribution (by area) turned out to be only 6% of the whole scheme value.

Page 42: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 42

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Local authorities lack commercial skills to make S106 fully effective

• Local authorities have not always understood S106• The aim of getting developers/landowners to contribute to affordable housing is implicitly clear enough

to expert observers• But the policy has been criticised for its lack of practical clarity right from the start• Additional guidance has been issued and PPG3 has been revised twice.

• Local authorities do not fully understand the legal limits to their negotiating power• LAs still complain that it is not clear whether they should be maximising the developer contribution, or

simply asking for a ‘reasonable’ amount – and they do not know what might be reasonable.

• Planners lack the skills to negotiate effectively• Planners as a profession are uneasy of their right to impose social housing development on developers• Planners are not necessarily trained for financial assessment and negotiation• Planners biggest problem is when developers claim that providing the affordable housing desired by the

LA renders their scheme uneconomic. LA’s planning, housing and legal departments need skills in development economics, to assess site viability issues.

• Best practice is emerging• The best councils have clearly identified which staff take responsibility for S06 and can specify the type,

tenure mix, and even size and location of the housing. Some have model S106 agreements to try and standardise the process

Page 43: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 43

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Contents

1. Executive summary2. The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply and demand trends

• Or why the need for social housing is driven by macroeconomics – restricted supply relative to demand

3. The macroeconomics of social housing: supply and demand trends4. The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

• Or how affordable housing has been provided as a tax on developers and as a means of avoiding grants

5. Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing• Or how well S106 addresses the economic issues of affordable housing

6. UK affordable housing in the credit crunch7. The credit crunch and its economic impact UK housing

• What happened, why, and what it means

Page 44: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 44

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch has decimated the overall housing market

• Prices in the UK housing market are being “corrected” – they are falling dramatically Property prices were probably

“overvalued” anyway. UK housing bubble one of the worst in the world. UK households are the most indebted in G7.

Global financial market stresses have destroyed the capital available for lending on UK mortgage markets

Weaker economic growth means less money around, so less demand for houses

• Prices down at the fastest annual rate since the early 1970s Further price falls ahead – only

about half way through? Capital Economics forecast a crash

and expect 12% price drops in 2009, 10% in 2010.

• The Mortgage market will be disrupted for a long time There is no revival of securitisation

imminent, so no new supply of mortgage lending. Virtual closure of the securitisation market has disproportionately big effect on UK mortgage finance. Mortgage market has plummeted to unprecedented depths

Unemployment and repossessions on the rise

Buy-to-let market is at risk

• Average length of housing cycles is around a decade Some economists (Oxford Economics)

forecast a price rise from late 2010 Long-term demographic and

economic factors will drive up real incomes and house prices - eventually

But real (inflation-adjusted) prices will regain their 2007 peak only in 2017.

Page 45: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 45

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch threatens all house building

• Achievement of the Government’s house building targets are threatened Housing Green Paper, Homes for the future targets 2 million new homes by 2016, 3

million 2020, higher environmental standards and commitments. Public investment of £8 billion over 2008-11 in affordable housing . These targets are under significant threat. Market house building stalled - developers face falling demand from customers and

pressure on asset values and business models. Affordable housing under pressure - programmes were reliant on cross subsidy from

shared ownership and open market sale properties.

• Starts are down and continuing to fall NHBC's September 2008 numbers show 23,185 applications to start new homes in

the combined private and public sectors in the three months to the end of September - 54% lower y-o-y. private sector (i.e. excluding housing associations) down even faster - 13,358, down 67% on 2007).

New home starts in England during Q3 2008 fell 50% year-on-year to 20,239.

• Completions are also down Completions fell 20% in Q3 2008 - 33,299

Page 46: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 46

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch changes the game for affordable housing

• Shared ownership market is dwindling Banks are not liquid so there few lenders

for shared ownership, hence buyers cannot borrow. Lenders property valuations are dropping fast

Shared ownership flats often cannot be sold on

Shared ownership buyers treated as sub-prime - Low income with potential default

Location is now vital – there is a glut of apartments in Northern towns

RSL’s shared ownership properties are now in competition with developers who are desperate to get anything for their flats

• S106’s have benefited in the short term but may decline in medium term

There has been a slowdown in S106 development – as house builders hold back on new starts, S106 opportunities have reduced.

But developers are renegotiating s106 deals to increase proportions of affordable housing

Housing associations are seen as less risky buyers than owner-occupiers or property investors

The benefit to affordable housing was unexpected, is small in overall scale, and may not last long.

• This could be the end for S106 in the medium term

When property prices are in freefall, S106 may not be the best way to capture planning gains.

• Surviving developers want to do affordable housing

Commercial developers are now shifting more of their work into affordable housing

Only the government has cash / can borrow so RSLs LAs are now premium clients

• Land price opportunities Residential land values will decline to the

end of 2009 – probably more than property values (as occurred in previous residential property downturns), since banks are unwilling to provide finance

This creates opportunities for housing associations and public sector to buy land more cheaply and increase supply

• Mortgage rescue and support for mortgage interest could stop the rise in waiting lists

The government will support up to 6,000 of the most vulnerable homeowners facing repossession through a £200m mortgage rescue scheme

The DWP aims to provide more income support for mortgage interest to keep unemployed house owners in their homes

Page 47: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 47

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The HCA comes into existence at an interesting time

• The HCA combines pre-existing government bodies in one strengthened entity Functions and assets of English Partnerships Investment functions of the Housing Corporation Delivery programmes from Communities and Local Government The Academy for Sustainable Communities.

• The HCA aims to do economic regeneration, house building and community development in a “joined up” way The HCA aims to cover all housing and regeneration issues in a local area, helping

local bodies with cash, knowledge of best practice, and cross-departmental working / problem solving

The HCA works across central and local government, housing associations, private sector builders and developers, the voluntary and community sectors, Regional Development Agencies and industry bodies

• The HCA has significant power A wide brief from government “do anything … for the purposes of its objects or for

purposes incidental to those purposes”. The HCA can build/ organise housing and infrastructure, give money, form

companies, do training and offer advice It has compulsory purchase powers

Page 48: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 48

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

As private and S106 house building declines, the HCA will be key

• The HCA is now the primary investor in affordable housing No-one else has any money to invest… the HCA claims it has an annual budget of

£5bn, making it the biggest regeneration and development agency in Europe Funding for 2008-11 is £17.3bn, with £8.4bn in the National Affordable Housing

Programme The HCA is the Housing Corporation (funds social housing) and national regeneration

agency, English Partnerships, plus delivery functions from the Department of Communities and Local Government (DCLG).

Takes on the government target of 3m new homes in England by 2020, as well as improving social housing, tackling homelessness and regenerating cities.

“Local government’s best delivery partner” – Bob Kerslake

• The HCA’s scope is to support the UK’s housing and community development: Improvement of the supply and quality of housing in England Regeneration or development of land or infrastructure in England Support regeneration and development of communities (“or their continued well-

being”) Support sustainable development and good design that meets people’s needs Co-operation with the Tenant Services Authority (TSA), the new social housing

regulator on social housing.

Page 49: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 49

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

In theory, the National Affordable Housing Programme addresses key issues

• The HCA will build affordable homes with private house builders

The aim is to deliver 155,000 additional new homes a year.

The aim is to increase the supply of new housing and address wider issues of affordability by increasing supply relative to demand.

Some – but not all – homes are for low cost home ownership and social rent. The aim is to Increase social rented homes by 50%, to 45,000 in 2010-11, with 25,000 affordable homes a year and 240,000 new homes by 2016.

• The HCA’s funding mechanisms are varied

House builders must bid for the work. 143 firms have “Investment Partner” accreditation.

£200M extra per year for housebuilding around London.

The HCA has fairly wide financial scope – projects up to £10M don’t need Departmental approval.

Private sector partners as well as housing associations – and for the first time, local authorities – council housing is back.

• S106 is being both tightened up and loosened

Developers who want grant have to make their case using “recognised economic tools” i.e. it is harder for developers to wriggle out of making their full contribution.

Developers taking grants have to meet design and quality standards.

But if developers don’t want grant, they don’t have to meet the same standards of quality and design as grant-takers do.

• The HCA claims to have an opportunity to address known, deep seated issues

The aim is to build houses sensibly – with access to infrastructure and jobs.

Mixed tenure is encouraged – developments that are more than 25 social rented homes with no other types of tenure will rarely be funded.

All homes to be built affordable homes to be more spacious than previously.

Investment in housing renewal and repair.

• Relationship between registered social landlords and councils may change

HCA hopes to be avenue for closer cooperation between central government and local authorities

Government hopes to build more homes without increasing grant.

Page 50: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 50

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The HCA is shifting strategy fast to deal with the collapse in house building

• The HCA may only take up slack left by private developers

The HCA’s target of 155,000 new homes a year is about the same as current new house builds (completions for England in the 12 months to June 2008 were 161,100).

If housebuilders stop building then the HCA will not succeed

• The HCA planned to rely on private developers via Public Private Partnerships

£1 of HCA money is joined by £5 of developer money

“The leverage is often five to one, so their investment, their willingness to take risks and participate in delivery capacity is crucial to the agency.” – Bob Kerslake, The Times, 12-09-08

• But the HCA is putting in more government money instead

Grants for housing association developments will rise

The Government will put more equity into social homes, funded by bringing forward money from 2010-11

Bob Kerslake, The Times, 12-12-08.

• The desire to build mixed developments may be overcome by the collapse in house buying

Private sector housing development has largely stopped, jeopardising S106 low-cost homes

The HCA claims that housing associations already have 10,000 homes for private sale or shared ownership that they can’t sell because of the credit crunch.

• The aim seems to be a small-scale move back to “traditional” council housing with mixed-class tenants

A third of the homes on an estate will be social rented homes at very low rates

The rest will be at subsidised “intermediate rents” – about 80 per cent of market rates – for those earning less than £60,000.

Housing association homes that cannot be sold will be rented to those on council waiting lists, people on low incomes, and key workers and would-be first-time buyers. This could bail out housing associations which are under threat if they cannot sell units.

Page 51: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 51

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The crunch is forcing the HCA to deal with prickly problems

• There is a concern that the new social housing will be “sink estates” If government rushes to build social housing then “zones of 100 per cent social

tenure may be created... Embedding… social problems and poverty of council estates.” - Tony Travers, London School of Economics

“We are not going to go back to the mono-tenure estates of the past. Half of our housing developments are small, with ten to twenty homes, which could be scattered next to existing private homes. We are all aware of the dangers of building mono-estates of just social housing.” - David Orr, National Housing Federation Trust

• The HCA counters this by saying the move away from mixed owner-occupation is temporary, and by offering cash Once the recession is over many of the homes will be shared ownership RSLs may be given “tailored packages” and higher grants – RSLs usually get 40%

grant, raising 60% from banks or developers. The HCA may even buy homes from RSLs and sell them later (at a profit)

• But the HCA won’t offer free money to distressed RSLs RSLs that run out of private / developer finance in the middle of projects will find the

HCA will demand equity stakes in return for cash

Page 52: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 52

Key findings

• The UK does not build enough houses to keep up with demand especially in the south east – we need around 155,000 new houses annually to cope with household growth

• Affordable housing has changed its role from being a chosen form of housing to being primarily a safety net for the very poorest in society

• Planning (S106) does not give the UK enough affordable homes

• Government spending on affordable housing is broadly the same – but the money goes on demand (rent) not on supply (house building)

• The HCA aims to transform UK housing by significant house building in smart, “joined-up” ways. The credit crunch could compromise its ambitions if private house building does not participate

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Page 53: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 53

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Contents

1. Executive summary2. The macroeconomics of housing overall: supply and demand trends

• Or why the need for social housing is driven by macroeconomics – restricted supply relative to demand

3. The macroeconomics of social housing: supply and demand trends4. The economics of planning policy to deliver affordable housing

• Or how affordable housing has been provided as a tax on developers and as a means of avoiding grants

5. Economic assessment of planning-driven provision of affordable housing• Or how well S106 addresses the economic issues of affordable housing

6. UK affordable housing in the credit crunch7. The credit crunch and its economic impact UK housing

• What happened, why, and what it means

Page 54: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 54

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Glossary

• ‘Subprime’ A financial term used to identify borrowers who don’t qualify for a ‘prime’ loan because there is a

greater risk of them not repaying the loan – so the borrower pays a higher interest rate. This is why poor people can be more profitable for banks.

• Securitization Bundling mortgages (prime and sub-prime) together and selling them as bonds (i.e. debt – a

“mortgage-backed security”). It enables financial institutions to loan money to high-risk borrowers get those loans off their balance sheets by selling them to someone else.

• “Collateralized Debt Obligations” An insurance policy to protect investors from suffering too great a loss if a debtor defaults,

especially for securitised assets. These become complex “bets” on the ability of borrowers to repay. (Everyone bet, and everyone lost!)

• Leverage Borrowing money so that you lend / invest more.

• Liquidity ratio The ratio of a bank’s cash to its lending.

• Fanny Mae FNMA – Federal National Mortgage Association.

• Freddie Mac FHLMC – Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation.

• GSE Government sponsored enterprise.

• Balance sheet A snapshot of a company's financial condition at a particular point in time. When banks make a

loan, they acquire assets (in the form of repayments) which increase their balance sheet.

Page 55: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 55

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch: what happened

Page 56: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 56

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch began when banks lent too much on risks they didn’t understand

• Sub prime was a result of easy credit and financial innovation. Other asset classes have similar characteristics

• Financial markets were slow to react to bad news. US housing slowdown started in 2006, sub prime meltdown didn’t start in earnest until Spring 2007

• It’s been worse than expected. A financial event has become an economic problem

• Downside risks have emerged simultaneously. Record oil prices, the lagged effect of past rate hikes, financial stress

Source: Deloitte 2007

Page 57: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 57

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Liquidity evaporated in H2 2007

Source: Deloitte 2007

Page 58: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 58

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch destroyed banks’ confidence after September 15th 2007

• The impact of the credit crunch was devastating Overnight, banks stopped trusting each other – in fact, they stopped trusting money itself, because they

no longer believed that liquidity was real “Credit” literally means belief. After September 2007, the banking world ran out of belief. Since

then, the rest of the world has run out of belief as well.

• Overnight Indexed Swaps, 2005-2008

• The Overnight Indexed Swap (OIS) market shows how happy banks are to lend to one another

Swap spreads reflect expectations of credit risks and of interbank lending risksSource: Cambridge Econometrics

Page 59: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 59

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Trust and therefore credit evaporated

• Trust underlies our use of money Banks have the role of creating money

(we trust banks to create money responsibly, not recklessly)

We trust governments to regulate the banks and to guard against “regulatory capture”, i.e. when the private banks subvert regulation to further their self-interest

• Private banks have lost some of our trust The banks do not trust each other

(evidence: LIBOR/OIS spread shows that this trust has been eroded since 2007)

Different branches within the same bank do not trust each other (evidence: at the run-up to bankruptcy, the head-office of Lehman Brothers in NY appear to have transferred London assets to NY)

• No trust = no banking Evidence: UK “Run on the Rock”

• No banking means no bank loans for real investment (or consumption) Banks lend less to restore their

balance sheets All private banks with substantial

exposure to bad money are threatened with bankruptcy

Banks’ own investment is reduced

• The Big Crunch is a global financial catastrophe Non-linear event with extreme

outcomes Unprecedented in economic history

in its scale (UK-US private banking linking with all stock exchanges)

Unlike the 17C tulip mania or South Sea Bubble, it originates in banks creating money not speculation

The crisis is continuing (accelerating?): inertia in expectations slows the rate of “melt-down”

Page 60: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 60

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch: why it happened

Page 61: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 61

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch’s roots are partly in US affordable housing

• “Fanny Mae” and “Freddie Mac” deliver the US’ aim of supporting low income home ownership

Since the 1970s the US has tried to expand affordable housing by making it easier for banks to lend to low income households

Increasing home ownership was a goal of the Clinton and Bush administrations.

So Government Supported Enterprises “Fanny Mae” and “Freddie Mac” (the GSE) provided wholesale funds for mortgage lending

• The USA’s affordable housing policy legitimised and relied on securitisation

Fannie Mae underwrites home mortgages – it does not lend money directly but buys loans on the secondary market

By expanding the type of loans that it will buy, Fannie Mae spurred banks to make more loans to people with poor credit ratings.

• The US government persuaded the mortgage industry, including Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (the GSE), to lower lending standards.

In 1995, the government incentivised the GSE to buy mortgage backed securities including subprime market. Between 1994 and 2003, the volume of subprime mortgages in rose ten-fold; Fannie and Freddie bought less risky subprimes, but they encouraged the entire subprime market

• From 1996 the Department of Housing and Urban Development told the GSE to fuel sub-prime lending

Target set of 40% of lending to very low income

Target rose to 50% in 2000 and 52% in 2005.

From 2002 to 2006 GSE subprime securities purchases rose from $38 billion to around $175 billion per year

The total market rose from $172 billion to nearly $500 billion; affordable housing drove securitisation and sub-prime lending

• When securitisation went wrong, the GSE went bust and had to be bailed out

The GSE were highly leveraged, net worth on 30 June 2008 was just US$114 billion

By 2008, the GSE owned, either directly or through mortgage pools they sponsored, $5.1 trillion in residential mortgages, about half the amount outstanding

In September 2008, the US government effectively nationalized them

• Affordable housing is not entirely to blame

The policy drove securitisation But securitisation went wrong because of

failed risk management, regulatory failure and greed if not fraud – not because of affordable housing

Page 62: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 62

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

‘New’ modelTraditional model

Bank checks

‘Independent’ checks

a simplification

Banking innovations diluted the relationship between lenders and borrowers

• Traditional vs. ‘new’ banking model

Source: Kim Kaivanto, Leeds University Management School, November 2008

CDOs

Page 63: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 63

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Innovations in finance underpinned the credit crunch

• Securitisation Securitisation turns the

cash-flow from loan repayments into financial products to be bought and sold

Made possible by technology that gathers and analyzes credit information. It should have enabled better risk management

It increased the flow of mortgage funds, created liquidity (buying and selling of loans), and reduced risk – or seemed to

• New sources of credit Deregulation of financial

markets exploded the supply of credit

Lenders used to hold mortgages on their books until the loans were repaid, but lenders could now sell mortgage funds wholesale to brokers, who lent to actual borrowers

Financial firms combined the cashflows from repayments into assets, and sold them to investors as “structured securities”.

This “securitization” gave lenders access to capital while passing risk to investors – which works well if there is sufficient transparency

Source: Kim Kaivanto, Leeds University Management School, November 2008

• New lenders Mortgage lending

moved outside the traditional financial institutions

Banks and S&Ls competed with “non-depository” financial entities who wanted to make loans.

Homebuilders sold financing to buyers, using wholesale funds from FIs.

Lots of companies turned into a “bank” that made loans to people

Page 64: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 64

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

(a) ‘Other’ includes car, credit card and student loan ABS.(b) Commercial mortgage-backed securities.(c) Residential mortgage-backed securities.Source: Dealogic / Bank of England.

Innovations in liquidity let the world gorge on credit

• Asset-backed securities grew fast, but collapsed in 2008

• Liquidity / credit bubbles were the ammunition for securitisation

There has been an extended global credit boom since 2002. Banks / FIs expanded balance sheets – i.e. lent more by using securitisation

Everyone made money – and got complacent about risk. There was a massive appetite for CDOs, because this asset class appeared to be delivering high returns (but with high risk)

This was a “shadow” banking system responsible for 50% of US mortgage lending 2005−2007.

• US and UK fed markets with cheap money US Fed pursued loose monetary policy (low

interest rates) from 2001 Massive US government spending on war

destroyed the budget surplus so needed cash UK also cut interest rates (and spent on war)

• Fast growing far east nations fed markets with investment funds

“Tiger economies” of Asia bought US assets / stocks and US government debt after Asian crisis

Much money was invested in CDOs and much of government bonds backed Fanny Mae and Freddy Mac, who securitised mortgage debt

Capital outflows from Asian manufacturing nations, with surplus US$, seeking.

• US tax cuts; low US saving rate fed demand Many more “bad risk” borrowers could afford

low savings rates – especially introductory deals

Page 65: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 65

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Banks exploited credit by borrowing – “leveraging” – and took on vast risk

• Deregulated banks’ could borrow more Reduced capitalisation requirements from early 90s meant banks could borrow more, and lend more,

without the need to keep so much “real cash” on hand Banks literally have a license to print money

• Banks’s leverage created much more risk than they imagined Magnifies gains, but also magnifies losses The banks have been creating new forms of money that have an uncertain worth: they created bad

money, unfounded liquidity. The crisis came when banks ceased to trust one another, Banks failed to value assets properly, and may in effect have indulged in creative accounting

• Banks borrowed money in the form of “repos” which made them very vulnerable From 2000 onward, investment banks were financed with short-term collateralised lending – lending

against the cashflows of repayments from their debtors – called repurchase agreements or ‘repos’. In 2007 banks had to “roll over” 25% of their balance sheet daily to keep operating / investing. This

meant that any disturbance in the repo market immediately affects investment bank balance sheets. So investment banks were much more vulnerable than they thought: As soon as repo markets had

issues with ‘liquidity’ (i.e. willingness to buy and sell short term bank debt) the “house of cards started to collapse.

• Leverage amplified the risks exponentially Banks such as Bear Stearns were leveraged 35:1 on balance sheet – they had borrowed 35 times as

much as the assets they could sell for cash. If these banks bought CDOs by borrowing money at a ratio of 10:1 – which was common – then their

total leverage is 350:1 ($350 backed by $1 equity). So a 0.3% fall in the value of the mortgage assets underlying the CDO wipes out ALL the bank’s

capital.

Page 66: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 66

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The whole system was incentivised to exploit credit through securitisation

• Securitisation makes banking much more profitable, but much more risky Banks bundled their high risk mortgages into bonds and sold them onto unwary investors. In return, banks received cash that allowed them to issue more mortgages. This recycling of loans created unprecedented levels of credit and fuelled the extraordinary

run up in house prices. Securitised products (CDOs, CMOs, CLOs, SIVs) take mortgages/loans off the bank’s

balance sheet. This means that banks can “cheat” on capital charge regulations – they don’t have to set aside as much money to cover borrowers going bust

• Auditors and credit rating agencies made much more profit because of the complexity At every ‘link’ in the mortgage market chain, specialised firms received transactions-based

fees. The rating agencies were making between 8 and 11 basis points on every CMO structure

rated. This equated to $ 250,000−$300,000+ each - in the heyday, at 20 ratings per month ≥ $5million per month. These structures would work only if the bulk of the tranches received AAA

Rating agencies had massive conflict of interest between ‘rating’ and ‘advisory’ functions

• Securitisation removed the incentive for sub-prime lenders to monitor credit quality. Up to 2004, insurers and investors ‘disciplined’ the market, pricing sub-prime-based

products conservatively. After 2004, issuers of CDOs did much more buying and selling of sub-prime credit risk and

therefore did much more − but they didn’t have specific sub-prime expertise. No-one with expertise scrutinized risks or questioned agencies’ credit ratings.

As a result, sub-prime lending exploded and credit quality fell. Lending was unsustainably risky from late 2005 to 2007.

There was a “winner’s curse”: both experts and non-experts found there was a market for lemons

Page 67: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 67

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Subprime lending went wrong because it was risky, hidden – and predatory

• The sub prime market exploded as a result of securitisation – but it was hidden According to the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, there was $10 trillion in

outstanding mortgage debt at the end of 2006. Of this amount, subprime mortgage loans accounted for $1.4 trillion. Of the subprime amount, $1.08 trillion was securitized But subprime risk exposure was wide and unclear - on the balance sheets of hedge

funds, mutual funds, insurance companies, pension funds … everyone was a lender, everyone took bets on the lending, no-one fully understood the risk

• But selling to sub-prime was more risky than securitisation innovations indicated Delinquencies increased. Many couldn’t afford higher payments when rates changed

– and many sub prime mortgages were set up so that rates increased automatically. Sub-prime borrowers rarely understood this – or were counting on refinancing at a

lower rate, but couldn’t, as housing prices fell because lacked equity in homes to qualify for refinancing

• And new players were predatory and under-regulated Predatory mortgage sales, loose underwriting standards Fraudulent sales practices including false or incomplete loan documentation,

misrepresentations in the lending process, inflated appraisals (“predatory lending”) Because loans were packaged and sold on the secondary market, lenders and

brokers thought they were insulated from default – so just wanted to sell loans

Page 68: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 68

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

When subprime failed, the scale of securitisation and CDOs created a chain reaction

• Bets made on whether loans would be repaid were more than the loans themselves!

• Banks found that lending was risky Falls in US house prices led to rising arrears

on sub-prime debt Because so much bank assets were based on

mortgage-backed securities, banks couldn’t lend on them

Some asset-backed securities (ABS) markets seized up – suddenly no-one would buy these assets or lend money on them

• CDOs multiplied the impact and created “financial contagion”

CDOs were special securities that were like insurance contracts to reduce risk but they used to bet on whether debts would be repaid.

They mixed subprime debt with lots of other debt

This vastly magnified the risk and the losses: if subprime went “bad”, most debt went “bad”

Securitisation and CDOs were everywhere. Small falls in prices of securitised assets made all CDOs decline

Much credit / lending was based on the flow of money from securitisation and CDOs but this dried up as prices for securities dropped and risk suddenly seemed much worse

Any one element of credit seizure could be managed – but everything was linked, and everything dried up

Page 69: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 69

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The chain reaction of CDOs sent the whole finance system into shock

• Nobody really understood CDOs and nobody knew how far they spread financial contagion Mortgage payments were the assets underlying CDOs These assets were bundled into a pool, securitised, and put into a CDO Bits of that CDO was then plugged into the next CDO… repeatedly. A typical CDO

might receive income from several hundred sources. A lawyer’s paradise, with baffling complexity – and impossible to sensibly assess for

risk

• When mortgage defaults began to increase after 2-year teaser rates ended CDOs began defaulting. First, flight to quality in the repo market, then closure of repo market. Inter-bank unsecured lending dried up. Asset-Backed Commercial Paper market dried up.

• Banks were quickly caught up in “Loss Spirals” As asset values fall, banks cannot borrow as much and have to sell asset sales to

cover their loans Lots of selling makes asset prices fall, which reduces borrowing capacity even

more…. Marking-to-market feeds the loss spiral. Margin Spirals − increased ‘margin calls’ force ‘deleveraging’, which lowers the price,

which forces more sales, which causes margins to be increased, and so on. Margin Spirals and Loss Spirals reinforce each other.

Page 70: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 70

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The credit crunch: how it affected the UK

Page 71: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 71

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Securitisation was the lifeblood of the UK mortgage market but it has collapsed

• Mortgage backed securities have disappeared

• Without securitisation, banks can no longer fund mortgage lending

Page 72: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 72

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

Mortgage lending has collapsed

• Without securitisation funds, mortgage approvals have collapsed

• Unemployment is rising as the credit crunch bites

• Without mortgage lending to feed demand, house prices have dropped

• Repossessions are rising

Page 73: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 73

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

House prices are dropping now, but will go up again in a few years

• The fall in house prices is real but house valuations are still high Economists call house price falls “full-

blown” because prices will fall for several years

But house prices in real terms are still far higher than 1990

• The falls in prices are similar to those of the early 1970s and early 1990s Real house prices fell 35% 1973-

1977, retaining their peak only in 1987

Real house prices fell 28% 1989-1995, retained their peak 2000

Oxford Economics expects house prices to drop 17% from their 2007 peak by 2010, a real terms fall of 23%

• Economists expect real house prices to rise from late 2010 There is a long term supply-demand

imbalance due to demographics and planning controls, and limited house building

Real incomes will continue to grow – and income rises of 1% drive house price rises of 2.5%

Page 74: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 74

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

30 years of banking crises have not created fundamental problems

Financial Instability is built-in: Over long periods of growth, capitalist economies tend to move from a financial structure dominated by stable finance to one ruled by speculative finance (unstable). Greed and fear overcome each other sequentially. Irregular cycles result from this dynamic

Source: Cambridge Econometrics

Page 75: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 75

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

The current crisis includes most of the features of previous crises

• Financial History 1929 to present

The current crisis includes speculation, asset price bubbles, easy credit, poor regulation, management hubris, financial innovations… a “perfect storm” that is very hard to fix

Source: Cambridge Econometrics

Page 76: The Economics of Social Housing

[email protected] Ltd Slide 76

Economics of Social HousingVersion 1.0

ENDS