the joint use of formal and informal job search methods in ... · table 5. four ideal types of...

174
The Joint Use of Formal and Informal Job Search Methods in China: Institutional Constraints, Working Mechanisms, and Advantages by Jing Shen A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Sociology University of Toronto © Copyright by Jing Shen 2013

Upload: others

Post on 20-Jun-2020

35 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

The Joint Use of Formal and Informal Job Search Methods in China: Institutional Constraints, Working

Mechanisms, and Advantages

by

Jing Shen

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

Department of Sociology University of Toronto

© Copyright by Jing Shen 2013

ii

The Joint Use of Formal and Informal Job Search Methods in

China: Institutional Constraints, Working Mechanisms, and

Advantages

Jing Shen

Doctor of Philosophy

Department of Sociology University of Toronto

2013

Abstract

Using data drawn from in-depth interviews collected in three Chinese cities and the

countrywide China General Social Survey, this dissertation examined how people found jobs

during the historic period of China’s employment system change. This dissertation is written

in the format of three publishable papers. The first paper revisited China’s employment

system change, by focusing on individual reactions towards the changing employment

policies. Perceiving the persistent political authority, individuals pursued higher education,

accumulated political advantages, and mobilized network resources, to get state-assigned

jobs. Individual job-seeking strategies, in turn, boosted the state’s hiring criteria, as well as

facilitated the growth of the market principle. Consequently, state power and market strength

have been co-developed in this process.

Following my analysis of institutional constraints, in the second paper, I addressed the

question of how individual job seekers and job positions are matched together. I examined

how contact use matches individual qualifications to the employer’s hiring expectations,

iii

from an innovative perspective of the certifiability of job requirements. I demonstrated that

informal methods facilitate job-person matching success when used in combination with

formal methods, rather than being used alone.

My third dissertation paper provides strong empirical evidence of the advantages of the joint

use of formal and informal methods. I found that individuals who used formal and informal

job search methods jointly tend to obtain more job information and thus apply for more

positions. They are also more likely to exit job search successfully within a three-month time

period. Using the Endogenous Switching Regression (ESR) model, I found that the joint

channel itself is more likely to lead one to late-stage career success, as indicated by one’s

recent income.

Above all, my dissertation systematically investigated the use of contacts in the labor market

of post-socialist China, regarding its institutional constraints, working mechanisms, and

advantages.

iv

Acknowledgments

The completion of this doctoral dissertation has been a long, challenging, but also fruitful

journey. Over the years, what I have learned is not only how to produce high-quality

scholarly works, but more importantly, also a whole new understanding about life. Looking

back at the moment, I know the completion of this dissertation would not have been possible

had I not been fortunate enough to get amazing support and help from a lot of people.

I would like to express my deepest appreciation to my doctoral thesis supervisor, Professor

Bonnie Erickson. Thank you for being always encouraging, since the first day I entered this

program. Thank you for reading through hundreds of drafts of my papers and providing

thorough and constructive comments on each of them. Thank you for being amazingly

supportive not only academically, but also in other aspects of my life. Your great mentorship

not only helps me complete a dissertation I desire to achieve, but also guides me to become

the scholar I want to be. My gratitude towards you is more than just a simple “thank you.”

My heartfelt thanks go to Professor Eric Fong and Professor Alexandra Marin, who have

been extremely helpful doctoral committee members, guiding me in every step of my

dissertation progress in the past a few years. Thank you, Professor Fong, for being a great

mentor on my dissertation as well as career development. I would have taken a longer time in

this program, if it were not your close guidance and cogent advice. Thank you, Professor

Marin, for always giving me valuable and helpful feedback on my dissertation drafts so

promptly. I have also learned a lot from both of your excellent scholarship by working

together with you as a Research Assistant.

I sincerely thank Professor Robert Andersen and Professor Deborah Davis for kindly being

the internal and external examiners in my committee. Thank you both so much for taking

your precious time to read through my dissertation. Your insightful comments and advice

will surely help me further improve my dissertation for potential publications in the near

future.

v

I am indebted to Professor Charles Jones, whose genuine and constant support is one of the

reasons that I felt being blessed even when going through the most difficult time. Thank you,

Professor Jones, for being such a kind TA/ RA supervisor and a good friend.

My Master’s thesis supervisor, Professor Yanjie Bian has been amazingly supportive to me

throughout all these years. Thank you, Professor Bian, for making it possible for me to access

a great dataset – the 2003 China General Social Survey. I also thank you for your strong

support for my academic career development.

I will be forever thankful to two of my greatest comrades in this program, Naoko S. Hawkins

and Sarah Knudson. Not only has their wisdom helped me navigate through my program as

smoothly as possible, but also their amazing company has made a supposedly challenging

Ph.D. experience so much more enjoyable.

I also want to say thank you to all the great people in the sociology department. Professors

Zaheer Baber, Monica Boyd, Hae Yeon Choo, Philip Goodman, John Myles, Erik

Schneiderhan, Barry Wellman, and Weiguo Zhang have been greatly supportive in various

aspects of my academic career development over the years. My current and former

classmates, Sarah Cappeliez, Phillipa Chong, Vincent Chua, Rochelle Cote, Kim DeLaat,

Omar Faruque, Loretta Ho, Lida Kaida, Scott Milligan, Guang Ying Mo, Siyue Tian, Burin

Yildiztekin, and Tony Zhang are great sources to seek academic support from, as well as

lovely company after work. Staff members, such as Carmela Versace, Jeremy Nichols, and

John Richard Manalo, were a great help, which has made my student life in the department a

lot easier.

I thank my friends outside the sociology department, Siniša Colic, Mée Hiroki, Ji Ke,

Gelareh Namdar, Ian Pang, Maira Perotto, and Bryce Sharman, for consistently reminding

me of remaining a life-work balance. It is you all who have made my life in Toronto

meaningful.

To my parents, Tailin Shen and Shanghui Ye. I feel guilty that the days I have spent with you

are countable in the past nearly seven years. I deeply appreciate that you have never said a

vi

single word to complain, and all what you wish for is my success and happiness. Your

unconditional love and support is the source of my strength to overcome obstacles in my life.

Finally, to my husband, Matthew Mackay. I cannot count how many times you cheered me

up when I was considering giving up, how many times you cooked for me, and how many

times you proofread my dissertation drafts. Half of my degree is yours. I love you more every

minute since the day we met.

vii

Table of Contents

Acknowledgments.......................................................................................................................... iv

List of Tables ...................................................................................................................................x

List of Figures ............................................................................................................................... xii

List of Appendices ....................................................................................................................... xiii

Chapter 1 Introduction .....................................................................................................................1

1.1. Two Issues in Existing Job Search Studies ..........................................................................1

1.2. Taking Individuals into Account: An Interplay Perspective ................................................3

1.3. The Context of the Transitional Economy in China ............................................................4

1.4. Data Used in This Dissertation ............................................................................................6

1.5. Structure of the Dissertation ................................................................................................8

References .................................................................................................................................11

Chapter 2 How Have Individual Behaviors Shaped China’s Employment System Change until 2003? .................................................................................................................................15

2.1. Introduction ........................................................................................................................15

2.2. Theoretical Development of China’s Socioeconomic Transition ......................................17

2.3. Historical Constraints: China’s Employment System Change by 2003 ............................19

2.4. State Policy Changes and Individual Reactions .................................................................25

2.4.1. Increasing Investment in Education: Response to the State’s Changing Emphasis ................................................................................................................27

2.4.2. Joining the Party: Response to the Increasing Competition for Assigned Jobs ........................................................................................................................32

2.4.3. Guanxi Manipulation: Response to the Persistence of State Power ......................34

2.5. Consequences of the Interplay: Concentration of the Social Elite and Their Resources ...........................................................................................................................37

2.5.1. Why Is a Quantitative Verification Legitimate? ....................................................37

viii

2.5.2. Hypotheses: Three Types of Successful Job Seekers and the Resource Distribution among Them ......................................................................................39

2.5.3. Data and Measurements .........................................................................................41

2.5.4. Descriptive Analysis ..............................................................................................45

2.5.5. Distribution of Human Capital among Three Types of Successful Job Seekers ...................................................................................................................47

2.5.6. Distribution of Political Capital among Three Types of Successful Job Seekers ...................................................................................................................49

2.5.7. Distribution of Family Ties among Three Types of Successful Job Seekers ........50

2.6. Conclusion and Discussion ................................................................................................54

References .................................................................................................................................57

Chapter 3 The Value of Mixed Methods: How Does Certifiability of Job Requirements Determine the Channels of Job-Person Matching? ...................................................................60

3.1. Introduction ........................................................................................................................60

3.2. The Effectiveness of Contact Use from the Job Seeker’s Perspective ..............................61

3.3. Linking Individual Search Behaviors to Employers’ Hiring Expectations .......................62

3.4. Typology of Job-Person Matching Patterns: Four Basic Types and Their Illustrations ........................................................................................................................64

3.5. Extensions of the Job-Person Matching Typology towards a Realistic Model .................67

3.6. Overview of the Qualitative Data ......................................................................................68

3.7. Formal Channels Only versus Informal Channels Only: A Perspective of Certifiability .......................................................................................................................72

3.8. Illustration of the Type III Scenario ...................................................................................73

3.9. Joint Use of Formal and Informal Strategies in Both Recruitment and Selection .............75

3.10. How Does the Certifiability of Qualifications Determine One’s Search Behaviors?..........................................................................................................................78

3.10.1. Data and Measurements .........................................................................................79

3.10.2. Results ....................................................................................................................80

ix

3.11. Conclusion and Discussion ....................................................................................83

References .................................................................................................................................86

Chapter 4 When Does Contact Use Matter? The Joint Use of Formal and Informal Channels and Job Search Success .............................................................................................89

4.1. Introduction ........................................................................................................................89

4.2. Formal versus Informal Job Search: The Mismatch between Theoretical Dichotomization and Empirical Non-Separation ...............................................................91

4.3. Hypotheses: Advantages of Formal-Informal-Joint Job Search Channels ........................92

4.4. Data, Measurements, and Methods ....................................................................................96

4.4.1. Generation of Three Job Search Channels .............................................................96

4.4.2. Dependent Variables and Other Independent Variables ........................................97

4.4.3. Methods................................................................................................................101

4.5. Advantages of the Use of the Joint Channel during Job Search ......................................106

4.6. Advantages of the Use of the Joint Channel on Recent Income ......................................110

4.6.1. OLS Estimations and Implications ......................................................................110

4.6.2. The Joint Channel versus the Formal Channel Only ...........................................114

4.6.3. The Joint Channel versus the Informal Channel Only .........................................118

4.7. Conclusion and Discussion ..............................................................................................122

References ...............................................................................................................................126

Chapter 5 Conclusion and Discussion .........................................................................................130

5.1. Overview of the Dissertation ...........................................................................................130

5.2. Contributions in the Area of Social Stratification and Inequality ....................................132

5.3. Contributions in the Area of Social Capital .....................................................................132

5.4. Directions of Future Research .........................................................................................134

References ...............................................................................................................................136

Appendices ...................................................................................................................................137

x

List of Tables

Chapter 2

Table 1. The Generation of Three Types of Successful Job Seekers 43

Table 2. Frequency Distribution of Respondents with and without Above-High-School Education by Era of Job Entry, CGSS 2003, Urban Section

46

Table 3. Frequency Distribution of Party Membership by Era of Job Entry, CGSS 2003, Urban Section

47

Table 4.Multinomial Estimates on the Likelihood of the Three Types of Successful Job Seekers, CGSS Urban Section, 2003

52

Chapter 3

Table 5. Four Ideal Types of Job-Person Matching Patterns 65

Table 6. The Expanded Typology of Job-Person Matching Channels in a Two-Stage Hiring Process

68

Table 7. Types of Job-Person Matching Patterns among Twenty-Eight Interviewees 70

Table 8. Multinomial Logistic Regression on Job Applicants’ Search Behaviors, CGSS Urban Section, 2003

83

Chapter 4

Table 9. Descriptive Statistics of Dependent and Independent Variables Used in Chapter 4, CGSS 2003, Urban Section

100

Table 10. Zero-Inflated Negative Binomial Regression of the Number of Positions One Applied for Prior to Job Entry

108

Table 11. Binary Logit Regression of Job Entry within a Three-Month Job Search Duration

110

Table 12. OLS Regression of Logged Annual Income in 2002, Urban China 113

Table 13. Endogenous Switching Regression of Logged Annual Income in 2002 between the Joint Channel and the Formal Channel Only

117

Table 14. Decomposition of Expected Logged Income between the Use of the Joint Channel and the Formal Channel Only, Predicted Based on Table 13

118

xi

Table 15. Endogenous Switching Regression of Logged Annual Income in 2002 between Joint-Channel Users and Informal-Channel-Only Users

121

Table 16. Decomposition of Expected Logged Income between the Use of the Joint Channel and the Informal Channel Only, Predicted Based on Table 15

122

xii

List of Figures

Chapter 2

Figure 1. Sector Composition of Urban Employees in China, 1978-2002 23

xiii

List of Appendices

Appendix A. Descriptive Statistics of the Qualitative Data 137

Appendix B. Distribution of the Year of Job Entry, CGSS 2003, Urban Section 138

Appendix C. Descriptive Statistics for Variables Used in the Quantitative Study

139

Appendix D. Decomposition of Group Differences in ESR Estimations 140

Appendix E. In-Depth Interview Guide 141

Appendix F. China General Social Survey (2003 Urban Questionnaire) 143

1

Chapter 1 Introduction

1.1. Two Issues in Existing Job Search Studies

Since Granovetter’s (1974) seminal study, scholarly interests in the roles that social relations

play in economic activities, such as job search, have continuously grown. The social-capital

enterprise provides an alternative job-search theory beyond the dominant human capital

explanation. A perspective of social capital also illuminates the importance of social relations

as one of the determinants of individuals’ mobility within a stratified social structure. Despite

those achievements, job search studies from the perspective of social capital have been faced

with challenges derived from two issues.

The first issue lies in the wide variation of the effects of contact use across institutional

contexts. According to Mayorova’s (2008) review, compared to the American labor market,

contact use in job search is seen less frequently in West Germany and the Netherlands (De

Graaf and Flap 1988), as well as in Sweden (Korpi 2001). The labor markets in China and

Japan show percentages of contact use as high as that in the United States. However, while

weak ties facilitate one’s job search success in the United States (Granovetter 1973, 1974;

Lin and Dumin 1986; Lin, Vaughn, and Ensel 1981), strong ties were observed to play a

positive role in leading individuals to jobs in China (Bian 1997) and Japan (Watanabe 1987).

When it comes to job search outcomes, the effects of contact use are found to vary even more

widely across (and within) societies. Using survey data in Tianjin, Bian (1997) argued that

individuals who mobilized strongly-tied contacts tended to land in more prestigious positions

than their counterparts who used weak ties, under the pre-reform job assignment system in

China. Based on a countrywide survey in Hungary, Bartus (2001) found that contacting a

high status person is as important as having two to four years of additional vocational

education, because high-status contacts inform job seekers about information that is

associated with better income opportunities. However, studies carried out in the Netherlands,

West Germany, and the former German Democratic Republic did not show significant effects

of contact use on income attainment (Habich 1984; De Graaf and Flap 1988; Volker and Flap

2

1999). Based on the 1970 Detroit Area Study, Marsden and Hurlbert (1988) reached a similar

conclusion. In Singapore, Chua (2010) found a non-significant effect of contact use on job

search outcomes, due to the meritocratic social institution of the Singaporean society. The

variation of contact use and its consequences across institutional contexts has become a

challenging topic facing scholars who are interested in the use of contacts during job search.

Despite Granovetter’s (1995) insight about the institutional constraint imposed on

individuals' job search behaviors, there has not yet been a single study that specifically

addresses how individuals strategize in job search, corresponding to the institutional

constraint. Focusing on an individual perspective, this dissertation thus aims to provide new

understanding about how individuals’ job search behaviors are constrained by, and at the

same time, shape the labor market institution. By doing so, I by no means deny the important

role social institutions play in shaping individual job search behaviors; but instead, I aim to

take a close look at why social institutions matters in job search studies through a focus on

individuals’ perceptions of and reactions towards the social institution.

The second issue is the “homophily” principle – “the tendency of people in friendship pairs

to be similar” (McPherson and Smith-Lovin 1987: 370). Based on both longitudinal and

cross-sectional survey datasets, Mouw (2003) argued that the causality between contact use

and positive job search outcomes is spurious, because individuals who tend to succeed in the

labor market also tend to make friends with those possessing similar characteristics. Thus,

“much of the effect of social capital in the existing literature reflects the tendency for similar

people to become friends rather than a causal effect of friends’ characteristics on labor

market outcomes.” (Mouw 2003: 868) Despite that, Mouw (2003) admitted that “it would be

naïve to argue that contacts do not matter.” (2003: 891) Otherwise, it would be impossible to

explain the empirical fact that a significant portion of job seekers rely on social contacts in

job search in the majority of human societies (Bian 1997; Bian and Ang 1997; Boxman,

DeGraaf, and Flap 1991; Fevre 1989; Granovetter 1974; Marsden and Campbell 1990;

Watanabe 1987). The subsequent challenge is thus to reveal how contact use functions, with

the homophily principle taken into account.

3

1.2. Taking Individuals into Account: An Interplay Perspective

Existing studies have not yet made satisfactory progress in terms of addressing the above two

issues. In terms of institutional constraints, by linking outcomes of contact use to

stratification consequences within a particular social structure, scholars failed to generalize a

social-capital theory across social contexts. For example, although Granovetter (1995)

admitted that institutional contexts must be considered to understand the roles of social

capital, it is not shown why and how institutional contexts should be studied. In his social-

resource theory, Lin (1999, 2001) made a more significant attempt to generalize the

application of social capital in job search. However, the theory seems to explain individual

job search behaviors better in the American context than in other societies, because weak ties

that are pervasively used in the American society function as a bridge between individuals

and desirable resources embedded in higher status positions. In Eastern Asian societies, such

as China (Bian 1997) and Japan (Watanabe 1987), the situation seems to be different,

because strong ties, rather than weak ties, play a more important role in facilitating one’s job

search success.

In terms of the homophily issue, although pro-social-capital scholars (Fernandez 2012; Lin

2001; Lin and Ao 2008) posited that the positive effects of contact use is due to the

homophily characteristic of social capital, their arguments fail to directly address the

causality concern raised by critics, such as Mouw (2003). Namely, if a highly qualified job

seeker can access both high-status social contacts and high-quality job positions, how can

researchers demonstrate that the relationship between contact use and job search success is

causal, rather than a mere association caused by the job seeker’s qualifications? The solution

currently adopted by scholars is to examine one’s social capital prior to job attainment, to

validate the causal chain between contact use and job search outcomes (Fernandez 2012; Lin

and Ao 2008). This solution is not entirely satisfactory, because using Mouw’s (2003) logic,

one’s current job search success is caused by his or her formal credentials or qualifications

prior to job attainment; thus, good contacts prior to job attainment can also be considered a

byproduct of one’s formal qualifications.

4

In this dissertation, I thus argue to address the two challenges existing in the previous

literature from an individual perspective, derived from new institutionalism (Nee 1998). By

embedding individual behaviors into the massive social change, new institutionalists

emphasize the formation process, instead of consequences, of a social institution. As North

put it, institutions “evolve and are altered by human beings; hence our theory must begin

with the individual. At the same time, the constraints that institutions impose on individual

choices are pervasive. Integrating individual choices with the constraints institutions impose

on choice sets is a major step toward unifying social science research.” (North 2007[1990]:5)

By doing so, this approach successfully bridges social structure and social actors after a long-

term divergence between structuralism and individualism derived from Emile Durkheim

(1951) and Max Weber (1949) (Nee 1998). Representative research in this regard includes

Granovetter’s (1985) seminal paper on the ‘embeddedness’ problem, DiMaggio and Powell’s

(1991) study on organizational innovation, Uzzi’s (1996) finding about the network effect on

organizational performance, Sanders and Nee’s (1996) research on immigrant self-

employment, and a body of literature in economic sociology (refer to Granovetter and

Swedberg 1992; Smelser and Swedberg 1994).

The new institutionalist perspective with a focus on individuals is also of great importance to

the area of job search studies. From this perspective, contact use is not viewed as a result

simply predicted by structural and individual factors, but as a decision that individuals make

based on their perceptions of the structural constraints and their own characteristics. By

interpreting the use of social contacts and its consequences by focusing on the interaction

between structural (or institutional) constraints and individual behaviors, in this dissertation I

make a preliminary attempt to construct a universal theory about contact use in job search.

1.3. The Context of the Transitional Economy in China

Every empirical study is confined within a certain social context. For this dissertation, the

investigation of employment activities was conducted within the context of the transitional

economy of China. Since the end of the 1970s, China has undergone a transition from a “neo-

traditional authoritarian” (Walder 1988) economy controlled by state power to a market-

dominant economy. Using the term “enterprise-based society”, Hebel (1996) pointed out that

5

the state-owned enterprises were a fundamental social institution in pre-reform urban

Chinese society. This institution was well known as the “danwei” (work unit) system, which

characterized labor participation not only as a matter of employment, but also of security,

social participation, social status, and other social opportunities of individuals (Hebel 1996).

A free labor market was not legal; the so-called “labor bureaus” were put in charge of

planned allocation of workers to state-owned work organizations. As a result, this state-

controlled job assignment system integrated workers into their work units in an all

encompassing way: All labor forces were assigned to different work units by administrative

means. No work unit could hire employees or fire an assigned employee by itself.

Employees’ salaries, bonuses, and other benefits were rated and distributed by the state, and

work units were only responsible for executing the state’s commands. Meanwhile,

individuals had little freedom to choose job positions or work units by themselves. Once

entering an assigned work unit, they were required to stay for life, excluding job shifts

commanded by the state. Thus, being affiliated with a work unit meant permanent

employment and lifelong security in a material and a social sense, at the cost being in the

state’s absolute control (Hebel 1996; Zhang 2000).

Over the decades, this job assignment system, in which employment was a right for every

urban Chinese citizen in the pre-reform egalitarian society, has been gradually been replaced

by a competition-based free labor market. To get jobs, individuals need to be equipped with

as desirable qualifications as possible, and must mobilize as many job search channels as

possible. The process, from looking into hiring advertisements from newspapers, the Internet,

schools, and companies, and attending job fairs, to circulating CVs, to experiencing job

interviews, and finally to getting job offers has gradually become the dominant way for urban

Chinese citizens to get jobs. Since 2003, for individuals who enter the labor market for the

first time, the state-controlled job assignment system has become a part of history, and the

hiring procedures in the Chinese labor market do not differ significantly from those in

western labor markets.

This gradual change is usually attributed to the party-state’s power, the ultimate purpose of

which is to prevent its regime from being devastated by rapid social change (Christiansen

6

1996; Harvey 2005). This explanation may only tell one side of the story. As far as the

employment institution is concerned, at least, the state would prefer to shake off the heavy

burden of being responsible for all urban residents’ employment sooner, rather than later. It

was urban residents’ resistance to the free job market that urged the state to push the

institutional change of employment slowly. Therefore, simply considering the reform as

“state-initiated and state-led” (Cao and Nee 2000; Nee 1996; Walder 1996, 2003; Zhou 2000)

disguises the negotiation or interaction process between the state power and individual social

actors. As North (2007[1990]) pointed out, the occurrence of institutional change must

concern all participants within the existing institutional framework. That is to say, without

individuals’ active responses to the state’s changing policies, the shift of the employment

institution would not have taken place. For this reason, the case of employment activities in

transitional China provides a real-world laboratory for one to observe the constructive

process of institutional change. During this process, individual job search behaviors are, on

one hand, constrained by the changing employment policies; however, on the other hand,

they are also one of the essential components that have shaped the employment institution as

it is now. Considering individual behaviors a constructive force in the formation of social

institutions makes it possible to theorize the roles social capital plays in job search

independent from institutional contexts. Subsequently, considering individual job search

behaviors endogenous – rather than exogenous – to one’s perception of contextual constraints

and personal characteristics makes it possible to theorize the working mechanisms of social

capital with the homophily issue taken into account. Only from this theoretical approach can

a theory about the use of social capital and its consequences in job search be understood.

1.4. Data Used in This Dissertation

In this dissertation, I combined qualitative data collected in three representative Chinese

cities – Beijing, Shenzhen, and Jiangyou in 2009, and quantitative data drawn from the 2003

China General Social Survey. The use of mixed research methods has gained increasing

popularity since the start of this century. It has been called the “third methodological

movement” (Tashakkori and Teddlie 2003a: 5), the “third research paradigm” (Johnson and

Onwuegbuzie 2004:15), and “a new star in the social science sky” (Mayring 2007). While

7

quantitative research makes up for qualitative research’s weakness in terms of the enduring

bias and absence of generalization resulting from the use of qualitative research methods,

qualitative research also makes up for quantitative research’s weakness in terms of the

absence of individuals’ voices and the context (Creswell and Plano Clark 2007). The

adoption of the mixed research methods adds unique strengths to my dissertation. While the

analysis of the qualitative data generates in-depth findings, the analysis of the quantitative

data can verify if those findings can be generalized at the population level.

Regarding the area of contact use in job search, specifically, the current challenge is to

understand how exactly social institutions shape individuals’ job search behaviors, as

aforementioned. This brings the importance of the qualitative approach to the forefront. By

combining quantitative and qualitative methods together, in this dissertation I attempt to

achieve both the breadth and depth of understanding about individuals’ institution-confined

job search behaviors. By taking a qualitative approach, I will interpret how individuals

perceive the social institution, and subsequently strategize in their job searches. This will

offer a deeper understanding about the job search patterns in China’s emerging labor market

discovered by analyzing the quantitative data. On the other hand, the quantitative data

validate qualitative findings by making generalization possible at the population level. Thus,

the combination of the qualitative and quantitative analysis is an essential step to embed job

search behaviors into the institutional context and disclose the interplay of institutional

constraints and individual behaviors.

I want to emphasize that my study in the first paper (Chapter Two) has a specific time frame,

by focusing on the employment system change until 2003. Although university graduates

were pushed to look for jobs in the labor market starting in the late 1990s, it was not until

early this century that assigned jobs basically disappeared from all universities throughout

the country1. Also, despite the launch of the entrance exam for entry-level governmental jobs

in the mid 1990s, those positions have become accessible for regular job seekers only in this

1 Exceptions are government-initiated volunteer programs starting early this century. Through them, university

graduates are mobilized to support economic development in remote, rural areas. After the volunteer program is over, the volunteer may be re-assigned to a better position.

8

century. Thus, a time frame from the end of 1970s to 2003 captures the whole process in

which the previously dominant job assignment system was gradually replaced by a free labor

market. For this reason, interview cases described in this dissertation are limited to those with

the year of job entry no later than 2003, though the interview data also include cases with the

year of job entry up to 2009.

I also want to point out that the 2003 CGSS data cover exclusively urban Chinese citizens

with the registered residency (hukou) status. For this reason, rural migrants who worked in

the urban area were excluded. It is undeniable that rural migrant workers have become a

significant part of the urban labor force. The existing literature (Han, Huang, Han, 2011; Lu

and Pun, 2010; Qin and Huang, 2010) focusing on rural migrant workers’ employment in the

urban area has provided essential understanding, regarding the positive role that rural

migrants’ participation in the urban labor force plays in accelerating the marketization

process in urban China. However, in this dissertation, I will focus on the urban workforce

with hukou status only. This is because the institutional context I focused on in this study is

the employment system change. Since only urban citizens with hukou status could benefit

from the pre-reform job assignment system, it is reasonable to limit the research object to this

population, so as to show the impacts of the abolishment of the job assignment system and

emergence of the labor market on the same social group. Bringing rural migrant workers into

this study may be not only unnecessary, but also faulty, considering it would make the

focused population inconsistent before and after the abolishment of the job assignment

system. Corresponding to the quantitative data, interview cases were only focused on urban

residents with hukou status as well.

1.5. Structure of the Dissertation

Using three publishable papers, this dissertation articulates the use of different types of job

search methods, particularly social contacts, by focusing on its institutional constraints,

working mechanisms, and advantages. My first paper explains the institutional context of the

newly-emerged employment patterns. I analyzed the process of the employment system

change as the interplay between the state and individuals, revolving around three types of

resources that are essential for employment in post-socialist China, namely, education, party

9

membership, and family ties. My qualitative analysis shows that individuals, driven by their

perception of the persistent political authority, pursued higher education, accumulated

political advantages, and mobilized family ties for the purpose of obtaining declining state-

assigned job opportunities. These job-seeking strategies continuously intensified competition

for assigned jobs as the available job opportunities further declined. I emphasize that it is this

interplay of the changing employment qualifications for assigned jobs and individual

responses towards this trend, rather than either the market or the state by itself, that formed

the concentration of the social elite and their resources in the state-controlled system.

Meanwhile, individuals’ responses to the changing employment policies have equipped

individuals with market rationality and resources for market competition. My constructive

interpretation of the employment system change thus provides a sound answer to the

unsolved puzzle in the existing transition literature; namely, what has driven the co-

development of state power and market strength.

Under this institutional constraint, I shifted my focus to explaining how individuals were

matched up with job positions through different types of channels in the second paper. I

innovatively put forth an approach of examining job-person matching from the perspective of

the certifiability of job requirements. On the employer’s side, the employers’ interests in

certifiable qualifications correspond to formal hiring strategies, while their interests in

uncertifiable qualifications correspond to informal hiring strategies. Because employers often

shift their focuses between certifiable and uncertifiable qualification assessment across two

stages, as well as within each stage of a hiring process (namely, recruitment and selection),

informal channels are often jointly used with formal channels, instead of functioning alone.

On the job applicant’s side, qualifications an individual possesses also vary in the

certifiability spectrum. A successful job-person match would occur only when an

individual’s certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications match up with the targeted employer’s

hiring expectations. Because the majority of job positions require both certifiable and

uncertifiable qualifications, the joint use of formal and informal channels would lead to

successful job-person matching more often than the use of either formal or informal channels

alone.

10

In my third dissertation paper, I further elaborated on the advantages of the joint use of

formal and informal channels from the job seeker’s perspective. My analysis shows that

contact use exerts positive effects on job search in combination with formal job search

methods, instead of alone. During job search, individuals who used formal and informal job

search methods jointly tend to obtain more job information and thus apply for more

positions. They are also more likely to exit job search successfully within a three-month time

period, compared to their counterparts who used either formal or informal job search

methods only. In terms of post-search outcomes, I used individuals’ recent income as the

indicator of later-stage career success. Findings from the Endogenous Switching Regression

(ESR) model show that the use of the joint channel itself is associated with higher recent

income than that of the either type of the single channels. However, there exists a significant

self-selection effect against the use of the joint channel, probably because individuals’ cost-

benefit calculation is only focused on the job-search stage, so that individuals fail to predict

the long-term benefits of using the joint channel. Regardless of the reason, the existence of

this self-selection effect causes an under-estimation of the effect of the joint channel in

conventional methods (such as the Ordinary Least Squares model). I thus advocate that the

examination of the effects of job search methods should be separated from the effects caused

by individual job seekers.

In my concluding chapter, I restate the theoretical significance of examining the employment

system change from a constructive perspective, constructing the model of the joint use of

formal and informal job-person matching by focusing on certifiability of job requirements,

and re-evaluating the advantages of contact use in combination with formal channels by

taking into account endogeneity of social capital. I focused my discussion on how a universal

theory about the application of social capital in job search can be generalized beyond the

Chinese context.

11

References

Bartus, Tam-s. 2001. Social Capital and Earnings Inequalities. Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of Groningen, Groningen, The Netherlands: (www.ub.rug.nl/eldoc/dis/ppsw/t.bartus).

Bian, Yanjie. 1997. Bringing Strong Ties Back In: Indirect Connection, Bridges, and Job Search in China, American Sociological Review. 62: 266-85.

Bian, Yanjie and Soon Ang. 1997. “Guanxi Networks and Job Mobility in China and Singapore.” Social Forces. 75:981-1006.

Bian, Yanijie, Ronald Breiger, Deborah Davis, and Joseph Galaskiewicz. 2005. "Occupation, Class, and Social Networks in Urban China." Social Forces 83:1443-68.

Boxman, Ed A. W., De Graaf Paul M., and Flap Hendrik D. 1991. “The Impact of Social and Human Capital on the Income Attainment of Dutch Managers.” Social Networks 13: 51-73.

Campbell, Karen, and Rachel Rosenfeld. 1985. “Job Search and Job Mobility: Sex and Race Differences.” Research in the Sociology of Work 3: 147-74.

Cao, Yang, and Victor G. Nee. 2000. “Comment: Controversies and Evidence in the Market Transition Debate.” The American Journal of Sociology 105(4):1175-89.

Christiansen, Flemming. 1996. “Chinese Labour in Transition 1978-91: A Case of Institutional Evolution.” Pp. 179-204 in The Institutional Approach to Labour and Development, edited by Gerry Rodgers, Klara Foti, and Laurids Lauridsen. London: Frank Cass.

Chua, Vincent. 2010. Social Capital and Inequality in Singapore. Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of Toronto, Toronto, Canada.

Creswell, John W., and Vicki L. Plano Clark. 2007. Designing and Conducting Mixed Methods Research. Sage Publications.

De Graaf, Nan Dirk, and Hendrik D. Flap. 1988. “’With a Little Help from My Friends’: Social Capital as an Explanation of Occupational Status and Income in the Netherlands, the United States and West Germany.” Social Forces 67:452-72.

DiMaggio, Paul, and Walter Powell. 1983. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” American Sociological Review 48 (2): 147-60.

Durkheim, Emile. 1951. Suicide: A Study in Sociology. Translated by John A. Spaulding and George Simpson, edited with an introduction by George Simpson. Glencoe, Ill: Free Press.

12

Fernandez, Roberto. 2012. “The Causal Status of Social Capital in Labor Markets.” Presented in the American Sociological Association annual meeting, Denver, Colorado.

Fevre, R. 1989. “Informal Practices, Flexible Firms and Private Labour Markets.” Sociology, 23(1), 91-109.

Granovetter, Mark S. 1973. “The Strength of Weak Ties.” American of Journal of Sociology 78: 1360-80.

——. 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

——. 1985. "Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness." American Journal of Sociology 91(3):481-510.

——. 1995. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers, 2nd ed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Granovetter, Mark, and Richard Swedberg, eds. 1992. The Sociology of Economic Life. Boulder CO: Westview Press.

Habich, R. 1984. “Berufliche Plazierung.” Pp. 343-65 in Lebensqualitat in der Bunderepublik, ed. by W. Glatzer and W. Zapf. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag.

Han, K. Q., Huang C. C. & Han W. J. (2011). Social Mobility of Migrant Peasant Workers in China. Sociology Mind, 1(4), 206-11.

Harvey, David. 2005. A Brief History of Neoliberalism. New York: Oxford University Press Inc.

Hebel, Jutta. 1996. “Institutional Change in Enterprise-based Society and its Impact on Labour: The Case of the People’s Republic of China.” Pp. 161-78 in The Institutional Approach to Labour and Development, edited by Gerry Rodgers, Klara Foti, and Laurids Lauridsen. London: Frank Cass.

Johnson, R. B., A. J. Onwuegbuzie, and L. A. Turner. 2007. “Toward a Definition of Mixed Methods Research.” Journal of Mixed Methods Research 1(2): 112–133.

Lin, Nan. 1982. “Social Resources and Instrumental Action.” Pp. 131-45 in Social Structure and Network Analysis, edited by Peter V. Marsden and Nan Lin. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.

Lin, Nan. 1999. “Social Networks and Status Attainment.” Annual Review of Sociology 25: 467-87.

——. 2001. Social Capital: A Theory of Social Structure and Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.

13

Lin, Nan and Dan Ao. 2008. “The Invisible Hand of Social Capital: An Exploratory Study.” Pp. 107-132 in Social Capital: An International Research Program, edited by Nan Lin and Bonnie H. Erickson. New York: Oxford University Press.

Lin, Nan and Mary Dumin. 1986. “Access to Occupations through Social Ties.” Social Networks 8:365-85.

Lin, Nan, John C. Vaughn, and Walter Ensel. 1981. “Social Resources and Occupational Status Attainment.” Social Forces 59:1163-81.

Lu, H. & Pun N. (2010). Unfinished Proletarianization: Self, Anger, and Class Action among the Second Generation of Peasant-workers in Present-day China. Modern China, 36(5), 493-519.

Marsden, P. V. & Campbell K. E. (1990). Recruitment and Selection Processes: The Organizational Side of Job Searches. In R. L. Breiger (Ed.), Social Mobility and Social Structure (pp.59-79). Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

Marsden, Peter V. and Jeanne S. Hurlbert. 1988. “Social Resources and Mobility Outcomes: A Replication and Extension.” Social Forces 66(4):1038-59.

Mayorova, Olga V. 2008. Social capital and institutional transition: Regional context for network use in job search in Russia, 1985—2001. Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of Arizona, Arizona, the United State. Available at: http://books.google.ca/books?id=inyajhduFXAC&pg=PA190&lpg=PA8&ots=muQpcxcn4K&dq=Social+capital+and+institutional+transition:+Regional+context+for+network+use+in+job+search+in+Russia,+1985--2001.

Mayring, P. 2007. “Introduction: Arguments for Mixed Methodology.” Pp. 1-4 in Mixed Methodology in Psycho-Logical Research, edited by P. Mayring, G. L. Huber, L. Gurtler, and M. Kiegelmann. Rotterdam/ Taipei: Sense Publishers.

Mouw, Ted. 2003. “Social Capital and Finding a Job: Do Contacts Matter?” American Sociological Review 68, 6: 868-98.

Nee, Victor. 1998. “Sources of New Institutionalism.” Pp. 1-16 in The New Institutionalism in Sociology, edited by Mary C. Brinton and Victor Nee. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.

North, Douglass C. 2007[1990]. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Korpi, Tomas. 2001. “Good Friends in Bad Times? Social Networks and Job Search among the Unemployed in Sweden.” Acta Sociologica 44 (2), pp: 157-70.

Qin, H. & Huang, P. (2010). A General Description of Research on New Migrants in Urban China. Chinese Sociology and Anthropology, 43(1), 6-22.

14

Sanders, Jimy, and Victor Nee. 1996. “Immigrant Self-Employment: The Family as Social Capital and the Value of Human Capital.” American Sociological Review 61(2): 231-49.

Smelser, Neil J., and Richard Swedberg, eds. 1994. The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Tashakkori, A., and C. Teddlie (Eds). 2003. The Handbook of Mixed Methods in the Social and Behavioral Sciences. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

Uzzi, Brian. 1996. “The Sources and Consequences of Embeddedness for the Economic Performance of Organizations: The Network Effect.” American Journal of Sociology 61:674-698.

Volker, Beate and Henk Flap. 1999. “Getting Ahead in the GDR: Social Capital and Status Attainment under Communism.” Acta Sociologica 42(1):17-34.

Walder, Andrew G. 1988. Communist Neo-Traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese Industry. University of California Press.

——. 1996. “Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Toward Testable Theories.” American Journal of Sociology 101(4):1060-73.

——. 2003. “Elite Opportunity in Transitional Economics.” American Sociological Review 68(6):899-916.

Watanabe, Shin. 1987. Job-Searching: A Comparative Study of Male Employment Relations in the United States and Japan. Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of California at Los Angeles, Los Angeles, CA.

Weber, Max. 1949 (1st ed). Max Weber on the methodology of the social sciences: Weber, Max, 1864-1920. Glencoe, Ill., Free Press.

Zhang, Minglong. 2000. “A Historic Review of Five-decade Changes of the Employment System of China,” Tianfu Xinlun 1:11-16.

Zhou, Xueguang. 2000. “Economic Transformation and Income Inequality in Urban China.” American Journal of Sociology 105 (4):1135-74.

15

Chapter 2 How Have Individual Behaviors Shaped China’s Employment

System Change until 2003?

2.1. Introduction

Sociological scrutiny in social institutions and their changes is often aimed at the structural

level. From the structural perspective, studies about China’s massive social change since the

end of the 1970s are often focused on the stratified social structure indicated by political

power (Bian & Logan 1996; Parish & Michelson 1996; Rona-Tas 1994), income (Xie &

Hannum 1996), or nonmonetary benefits (Oberschall 1996; Zhou, Tuma, & Moen, 1997).

Although this approach provides a bird’s-eye view of the changing stratification mechanisms

and their impacts on social structure, scholars (Wu & Xie 2003; Zhou 2000) have

increasingly realized its insufficiency to explain the process of a large-scale social change.

Understanding the process of institutional change is of great significance, particularly in

China’s case, because a focus only on stratification outcomes cannot solve the long-lasting

debate centered on the driving force of the transition (Bian & Logan 1996; Nee 1989, 1991,

& 1996; Xie & Hannum 1996; Walder, Li, & Treiman 2000; Zhou 2000), as I will articulate

in the following sections.

Drawing inspiration from the recent development of new institutionalism— which explains

social change by focusing on the interaction between institutions and individual behaviors,

this study will be individual-centered, rather than social-structure-centered. As North put it,

institutions “evolve and are altered by human beings; hence our theory must begin with the

individual.” (North 2007[1990]:5) By revisiting one of the crucial historic periods in China,

from the end of the 1970s to 2003, in this study I will innovatively interpret a massive social

change from the individual perspective. My focus is centered on China’s employment system

change, during which a free labor market was gradually substituted for the traditional state-

controlled job assignment system.

My study is distinctive from previous transition studies, which were focused on transitional

outcomes, and thus failed to explain the formation of the co-existence of two seemingly

contradictory forces – state power and market strength. In my study, I describe China’s

16

employment system change as a process shaped by individuals’ perceptions of and reactions

towards the changing state employment policies. I do not deny the state’s leading role in the

employment system changing process, as argued in the existing literature. However,

attributing the social change path solely to state power cannot completely explain the reality.

For example, despite the fact that the state would rather relieve itself of the heavy burden of

providing permanent, full employment to all urban citizens sooner rather than later, the

employment system change did not occur overnight. As Hebel (1996) pointed out, the

previous job assignment system was not just a result of direct control, and political

intervention and/or repression; it was individuals’ acceptance that legitimized the mechanism

of status and income distribution (see Hebel 1996: 167). By the same token, the change of

this system also needs to be accepted by individuals. Thus, the interpretation from the

individual perspective is indispensable in a comprehensive understanding of the employment

system change.

For this reason, this study aims to highlight the role individuals play in a massive social

change. To do so, I portray state power (represented by the state-controlled job assignment

system) and market strength (represented by the employment mechanism in the labor market)

not as pre-determined, exogenous constraints, but as endogenous social configurations that

are ceaselessly shaped by individual behavior. While the state gradually withdrew from being

responsible for all urban citizens’ employment and pushed them into the labor market,

individuals clearly perceived the persistence of the political authority that had the ultimate

control over the distribution of social wealth. As a result, an individual’s response was to

seek the gradually decreasing assigned job opportunities and stay under the protection of the

state-controlled system as long as possible. To access the declining state-assigned job

opportunities, thus, individuals actively pursued higher education, accumulated political

capital, and mobilized family ties. These job-seeking strategies have concentrated the social

elite and their resources in the state-controlled system, and consequently solidified state

power. Meanwhile, individuals’ calculation and maneuvering in job searches has also

constructed market rationality, while individuals’ strategies for obtaining assigned jobs

equipped them with high qualifications for market competition. At the later transitional stage,

when the elite dabbled in the free market, they gained a market premium by taking advantage

17

of resources they accumulated in the state-controlled system. Their participation in the

private sector has undoubtedly hastened the growth of the market mechanism. In short, while

the previous literature emphasizes the state’s leading role in China’s socioeconomic changes,

this paper draws scholarly attention to individuals’ responses to the macro social change. I

argue that the formation of the co-existence of state power and market strength can be

understood from a micro perspective; namely, individuals’ job seeking strategies driven by

their pursuits of maximum security and of maximum benefits under the changing

employment institution nourish state power and market strength simultaneously. This study is

thus a pioneering sociological attempt to explain the process of a massive social change from

an individual perspective.

In the following sections, I will first review how China’s socioeconomic transition was

analyzed from a structural perspective in the previous stratification literature. To introduce

the historic context, I will also briefly review the employment change in China’s employment

system from the end of the 1970s to 2003. The main purpose of my study is to show how

individuals perceived and reacted to the changing employment policies, and consequently

how labor market inequality was shaped not only by the changing policies, but also by

individual coping strategies towards the institutional change. This will be based on my

qualitative analysis of twenty-eight in-depth interviews conducted in three representative

Chinese cities. I will then verify my qualitative interpretations by testing the distribution of

individuals and their resources using data from the countrywide 2003 China General Social

Survey, because my argument from the individual perspective of the employment system

change is a necessary and sufficient condition of the transitional consequence – the unequal

distribution of resources. To conclude, I will restate the necessity of examining individual

behaviors as an inseparable component of a large-scale social change.

2.2. Theoretical Development of China’s Socioeconomic Transition

Despite the variation in theoretical approaches, previous studies of China’s socioeconomic

transition mainly focused on structural changes; it is unclear about what role social actors

played during this massive changing process. For example, challenging the traditional state-

18

centered approach in the earliest literature about the socioeconomic transition of state

socialism, Nee and his collaborator (Nee 1989; Nee & Matthews 1996) put forth a new

institutionalist perspective by emphasizing the market as a crucial non-state player in

reshaping and re-stratifying the social structure. Despite its innovative attempt to examine the

market as a competing stratification force versus state power, Nee’s market transition theory

(Nee 1989, 1998; Nee & Mathews 1996) simplified “non-state actors” as the market. This

thus led to the prediction of a linear path, through which the formerly communist economy

would be converted to a purely capitalist economy. Consequently, a state-vs.-market

dichotomy was set up, which scholars followed, wittingly or not, during the long-lasting

market transition debate. Namely, Nee’s opponents criticized his theory mainly by

emphasizing the state “end” of the state-vs.-market dichotomy. One approach of this

literature, known as the technocratic-continuity hypothesis (Cao & Nee 2000), argues that

former cadres can rely on their administrative expertise acquired under state socialism to

maintain high socioeconomic status in the post-socialist era (Bian & Logan 1996; see also

Cao & Nee’s 2000 review: 1179; Rona-Tas 1994). Another approach, the power-conversion

hypothesis (Cao & Nee 2000), argues that political power and capital possessed by cadres

can be translated into various forms of economic advantages when a market economy is

created (Parish & Michelson 1996; Walder 2004; Zhou 2000; Zhou et al. 1997).

With an assumption of an opposing relationship between state power and the market, Nee

and his opponents have each grasped one facet of the complex social change. Based on both,

Zhou (2000) put forth a “coevolution between politics and markets” model. As Zhou stated,

“state-initiated reforms and emerging markets have been two major sources of economic

transformation. Both interest politics and markets coevolve in interactions with each other…

[N]either one can be understood without a careful and substantive understanding of the

other.” (Zhou 2000:1140) Despite being theoretically enlightening, Zhou’s (2000) study did

not offer an explanation about what drives the co-evolution of “politics and markets.”

Following Zhou, Wu and Xie (2003) proposed treating workers as “dynamic social actors

who are not simply affected by the market, but rather respond to it by actively situating

themselves in the labor market. (Wu & Xie 2003: 429)” By categorizing individuals into four

19

groups based on their work history in the public and market sectors, Wu and Xie (2003)

found that the public and market sectors do not differ from each other in terms of economic

returns to human capital. Although Wu and Xie (2003) did not directly explain the co-

evolution process of the state and market, the emphasis on individuals’ active reactions in the

labor market is undoubtedly an inspiration.

Previous scholarly contributions clearly show the necessity of incorporating individuals to

understand the process of social change in which strong state power and a booming market

co-exist. To demonstrate this point, I will use China’s employment system change from the

end of 1970s to 2003 as a case study. As employment scholars argued, “the employment

activities an individual displays are based on the complex interplay of employment motives

and goals; personal, emotional, and social tendencies; and unique personal and situational

conditions.” (Kanfer, Wanberg, & Kantrowitz 2001:838) Thus, the change in the

employment system provides a perfect scenario for one to observe the interplay between

macro institutional constraints and micro individual reactions. To understand the process,

some background knowledge about the historic change in China’s employment system is

necessary.

2.3. Historical Constraints: China’s Employment System Change by 2003

The pre-reform employment system in China was well known as a state-controlled job

assignment system, in which the so-called “labor bureaus” were responsible for planned

allocation of urban citizens to state-owned work organizations. Using the term “enterprise-

based society”, Hebel (1996) pointed out that state-owned enterprises (SOEs hereafter) were

a fundamental social institution in the pre-reform urban Chinese society. This institution was

well known as the danwei (work unit) system, which characterized labor participation not

only as a matter of employment, but also of security, social participation, social status, and

other social opportunities of individuals (Hebel 1996). A free labor market was not legal; the

so-called “labor bureaus” were put in charge of planned allocation of workers to state-owned

work organizations. This job assignment system integrated workers into their work units in

an all-encompassing way: On one hand, all labor forces were assigned to different work units

20

by administrative means. No work unit could hire employees or fire an assigned employee by

itself. Employees’ salaries, bonuses, and other benefits were rated and distributed by the

state, and work units were only responsible for executing the state’s commands. On the other

hand, individuals had little freedom to choose job positions or work units by themselves.

Upon entering an assigned work unit, they must stay for life, excluding job shifts abiding by

the state’s commands. Thus, being affiliated with a work unit meant permanent employment

and lifelong security in a material and a social sense, at the cost of absolute state control of

one’s socioeconomic behaviors (Hebel 1996; Zhang 2000).

By using the state’s plan to allocate workers into work units, this totalitarian job assignment

system, in principle, made it possible to save on recruitment costs and achieve advances more

efficiently. The reality, however, did not unfold as the planners expected. Because of its

comprehensive coverage on not only employment, but also social security, social status, and

all resources for one’s basic needs, this labor system created entitlement to employment for

both state employees and their offspring2 who came of age. Consequently, the gate-keeper

function of the labor bureau could not be sustained because of the rapid growth of the urban

population3 by the end of 1970s. Labor bureaus were forced to deal with increasing

overstaffing. Conservative estimates indicate that between 15 and 30 million workers in

urban state-owned enterprises were superfluous in the mid 1980s (Christiansen 1996).

Furthermore, the employment pressure intensified when the policy of sending urban youths

to the countryside was stopped. Those youths still in the countryside were gradually allowed

back to cities4 near the end of 1970s and early 1980s (Christiansen 1996).

The state was therefore forced to adapt its “full-employment” job assignment system to the

unprecedentedly severe employment pressure. Changes have since occurred, both inside and

2 Claimed as the greatest advantage of the socialist system relative to the capitalist system, a state-owned work

organization was responsible for all needs of its employees, including employment of their offspring. 3 In the early 1980s, the urban population had reached 206.5 million (Demographic Yearbook of China 2001).

4 During the Cultural Revolution, urban youth were sent to the countryside, in order to relieve the employment pressure in urban areas. This policy was abolished in 1979, and those sent to the countryside were allowed to go back to their home cities. Consequently, employment became an extremely severe socioeconomic issue in urban areas. According to Zhang (2000), there were 17 million urban residents who needed jobs in the end of 1970s and early 1980s.

21

outside the state-controlled workplaces. Inside the state-owned work organizations, firstly, a

labor contract system5 was officially enacted throughout the country in 19866. For the first

time, labor contracts could be given to workers upon their first entry into state-run work units

(Hebel 1996). Despite its legal validity on paper, in reality this labor contract system was

hardly practiced in the 1980s. Under the dominant socialist ideology, managers were not able

to lay off workers, even when bad conduct and performance were obvious. “[T]o avoid

conflicts, managers gave the same treatment to contract workers and the working conditions

of contract workers approached those of permanent workers.” (Hebel 1996: 168) Despite

this, a real change was seen in the job assignment system itself. Instead of an individual’s

absolute obedience to the state’s assignment, job allocation in this era was based on “mutual

selection”7 between the work unit and the individual.

Since 1992, new efforts were made to implement labor reform. For one, a policy entitled ‘All

Staff Labor Contract System’ was put on the agenda8. “The goal of this system was that all

staff members and workers should sign a contract with an enterprise of their choice. This new

contract system was thought of as an instrument for managers to employ the right staff and

workers in order to meet market conditions better. It was also said that workers should gain a

greater choice in their jobs and enterprises.” (Hebel 1996: 168) In the same year, the central

government also issued ‘Regulations on Changing State-owned Industrial Enterprises’

Management Systems,’9 which stated that the state-controlled job assignment system should

be replaced by a competition-based hiring mechanism in SOEs. As of the end of 1992, 25.4

million staff and workers, namely, 17.2% of employees in state-owned workplaces reported

5 Tentative Regulations about the Implementation of a Labor Contract System in State-owned Enterprises,

enacted on October 1st, 1986. The full text is available at: http://wenku.baidu.com/view/bd030ef79e31433239689376.html 6 Some experiments had been carried out earlier.

7 See “A Brief Review on the Employment of University Graduates in China.” The full text is available at:

http://12945294.blog.hexun.com/38691637_d.html 8 An Announcement about Proposed Solutions on Issues Related to the Tentative Implementation of All Staff

Labor Contract System from the Ministry of Labor, enacted on September 12th, 1992. The full text is available at: http://www.law-lib.com/law/law_view.asp?id=55194 9Quanmin Suoyouzhi Gongye Qiye Zhuanhuan Jingying Jizhi Tiaoli, available at http://www.whhd.gov.cn/news/oldnews/103855435885586200.html.

22

that they had signed a labor contract (Hebel 1996; data source: China Statistical Yearbook

1993). Starting from the mid 1990s, the reform in SOEs had reached a new stage. While

superfluous workers were starting to be laid off, youths who came of age gradually stopped

being assigned into job positions. From 1997 onwards, graduates from general10 universities

were, in principle, not covered by the state-controlled job assignment system any more. By

2003, the job assignment system was basically abolished in all remaining universities.

Meanwhile, the National Entrance Exam for Governmental Officials was substituted for job

assignment as the primary hiring channel for entry-level positions in all governmental

organizations. Ever since, the job market has replaced the state-controlled job assignment

system, and has become the primary channel for one to get a job in China.

Outside the state-controlled system, the elements of a free market were never eradicated,

even during Mao’s era. Collective enterprises11 had always played an important role in

providing some outlets for the urban unemployed. “These enterprises were operating outside

the state plan, and formed a structural precursor for labor service enterprises, and also

established the background for other non-plan economic activities.” (Christiansen 1996: 181)

Typical examples were the widespread “labor service companies12” founded by large-scaled

SOEs. Meanwhile, the state also (re)legitimized jobs in the private sector in the early 1980s.

Figure 1 shows changes in the sector composition of the urban employees from 1978 to 2002.

During the first decade of the reform, most employees that were not under the coverage of

the state-controlled job assignment system were hired in collective enterprises: the

10 Universities subordinate to the Ministry of Education are general, and abide by all polices issued by the ministry. Those policies do not necessarily affect universities subordinate to other ministries, such as the Ministry of Defence and Ministry of Justice. 11 The major function of collective enterprises was initially to relieve social burdens of a local society, for example by providing employment opportunities to SOE employees’ spouses and offspring, and local residents who were once sent to the countryside. A hiring decision in a collective enterprise was made at the local level rather than through the state’s plan. Therefore, positions in collective enterprises were not covered by the state job assignment system. 12 The labor service companies (LSCs hereafter) were collective enterprises with no fixed wages and only profit sharing. “In this way, part of the staff would be placed outside the state plan, and the costs could be kept lower… Other LSCs were set up with large investment in highly competitive sectors, including transport, catering, the tourist industry, and even manufacturing. Operating outside the state plan and with less commitment to social overheads, LSCs were effective and contributed to the development of a ‘market’ outside the state plan.” (Christiansen 1996 183)

23

percentage of employees working in collective enterprises stayed around 28%. The

proportion of people employed in the private sector reached only 3.8% of the total employed

population in 1985, and displayed a setback in the end of 1980s and early 1990s. It is only

after Deng’s famous talk during his South China tour in 199213 that the number of employees

in the private sector started to soar. The percentage of employees in the state sector has

decreased sharply since the 1990s. I need to reemphasize that among those employed in the

state sector, contract jobs had started to replace assigned jobs that endowed SOE workers

with permanent employment, though the exact numbers were not recorded. As shown in

Figure 1, by 2002 half of the employed population was hired in the private sector. While the

percentage of workers in the state sector was down to less than 50%, a much smaller portion

of them had state assigned jobs.

Figure 1. Sector Composition of Urban Employees in China, 1978-2002

Sources: Statistical Yearbook of China 1992 and 2003; Zhang, Minglong. 2000. “A Historic Review of Five-decade Changes of the Employment System of China,” Tianfu Xinlun, Vol. 1, 11-16.

In short, from the end of the 1970s to 2003, China’s employment institution had changed

from a state monopoly over all job opportunities, to a reformed state-controlled system in

which market elements (i.e., contracts) started to grow, and finally to an increasingly mature

13 Deng Xiaoping, who initiated the socioeconomic reform in China in 1979, stated that China should build up its socialist market economy during his tour to South China in 1992. This symbolizes that the socioeconomic transition of China has entered a second stage.

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

1978 1985 1991 2002

Party, governmental, and

public insitutions, and

SOEs

Collective

Hybrid and private

24

labor market that dominates not only the private sector, but also the state sector. Currently,

job assignment may only occur after one enters a state-owned organization, or in certain

politically-oriented recruitments14.

This gradual change is usually attributed to the party-state’s power, which aimed to maintain

the socialist system to the greatest extent (Christiansen 1996; Harvey 2005). This explanation

may only concern one side of the story. As far as the employment institution is concerned, at

least, the state would prefer to relieve itself of the heavy burden of being responsible for all

urban residents’ employment sooner, rather than later. It was urban residents’ resistance

towards the free job market that forced the state to push the change slowly. Therefore, simply

considering the reform as “state-initiated and state-led” (Cao and Nee 2000; Nee 1996;

Walder 1996, 2003; Zhou 2000) disguises the negotiation or interaction process between

state power and individual actors. As Hebel pointed out, the stability of the danwei system in

China “was not only a result of direct control, political intervention and/or repression, but it

was built into the accepted and legitimizing mechanism of status and income distribution.”

(Hebel 1996: 167) Namely, it is not the unilateral state’s control, but the mutual agreement

between the state and urban residents that founded the stability of the danwei system. That is,

the gradual institutional change in China’s employment system has to be explained by taking

into account individuals’ perceptions of and responses to this state-led reform. By focusing

on how individuals understood and responded to the changing employment institution in the

following qualitative section, I will explain why China’s employment system change

followed the path it took in the last three decades.

14 “University Volunteers Serving the West,” initiated by the central government, has operated since 2003. Under this project, every year a certain amount of university graduates are recruited to work in poor counties or rural areas of the western region. Another similar project was launched in 2006. After their tenure is due, a volunteer graduate would be assigned to a better position in the government. See “A Brief Review of the Employment System Reform about University Graduates in China” (Woguo Daxue Biyesheng Jiuye Zhidu Gaige Jianyao Huigu), available at http://12945294.blog.hexun.com/38691637 d.html.

25

2.4. State Policy Changes and Individual Reactions

In this section of my qualitative analysis, I will elaborate on the changing employment

system by focusing on individuals’ responses towards the changing state policies. I collected

qualitative data in three Chinese cities, Beijing, Shenzhen, and Jiangyou, in the summer of

2009. The three selected urban locations are representative examples of North China, where

the central government has the strongest influence, South China, where the market economy

started earliest and developed fastest, and West China, where the central government’s

control and market strength are both relatively weak, respectively. By adopting the snowball

sampling method, I composed a sample frame with up to 50 individuals in each city.

However, to match up with the quantitative analysis in this study, I only selected interview

cases in which the informants were urban residents with the local hukou status and got into

their current workplaces no later than 2003. I also excluded self-employed cases from this

study. As a result, twenty-eight cases were used in this study, including ten cases in Beijing,

and nine cases in Shenzhen and Jiangyou, respectively. Descriptions of interviewees’

characteristics are provided in Appendix A.

In order to conduct the study in Chapter 3, I oversampled individuals who entered their

current workplaces around the year of 200315. This is because the influence of the state-

controlled job assignment system under the socialist regime did not completely fade away

until early this century. Although studies (Bian 1997, 2001, 2002) have shown that guanxi

(social relations) might have been mobilized for a better assigned job, it was not uncommon

for one to get a job without active search under the job assignment system. Particularly, the

older the respondent is, the more likely it is for his or her case to fall into the “no search”

category. However, this would not be a concern for individuals who entered the labor market

from 2000 onwards, by which time even job positions in the public sector became

competition-based, instead of need-based. Oversampling the younger generation gives rise to

significantly greater proportions of respondents with university degrees and of respondents

15

Cases in which informants entered their current workplaces after 2003 were excluded in the analysis, to match up with the analysis of the 2003 CGSS data.

26

who entered their current jobs after 1992, which serves the purpose of the study in Chapter 3,

by increasing the variation of job-person matching patterns. As a result, my twenty-eight

informants consisted of 58% males and 42% females. 43% of informants were below thirty

years old, 30% of them were between thirty and forty years old, and 27% of them were above

forty years old. 64% of the informants had some higher education; in fact, 48% of them had

graduate degrees. 48.5% of the informants were party members. While 73% of the

informants entered their current workplaces after 1992, 15% and 12% of them entered their

current workplaces before 1979 and between 1979 and 1991, respectively. I do not intend to

generalize my qualitative findings solely based on the twenty-eight in-depth interviews.

Instead, the purpose of the qualitative part of my study is to delineate a macro social change

from the individual perspective, by focusing on how individuals understand and respond to

the state’s changing employment policies. Hypotheses derived from my qualitative findings

will be tested using the representative countrywide survey data.

According to my interview data, the majority of the interviewees emphasized the political

context, when talking about their job attainment stories. Certain phrases frequently appeared,

including “under the background of the CCP (Chinese Communist Party),” “in the political

context of China,” “China’s unique politics,” “the leadership of the Communist Party,” and

so on. The emergence of the labor market was not perceived as a sign of the declination of

the state’s totalitarian authority. “No matter how this society changes, the governance of the

CCP wouldn’t change, at least as far as I can see,” Mr. Jian Fang16, a 56-year-old

departmental chief in a large-scale SOE made the above comment. This perception directly

led to individuals’ persistent preference towards assigned jobs. In the following analysis, I

will demonstrate this point by analyzing individuals’ coping strategies towards the changing

employment environment in three dimensions, human capital, political capital, and social

capital. Arguably, these three types of resources are the most valuable— if not exclusive—

resources under the state socialist employment institution. Focusing on these three types of

pre-hiring resources, I will show that it is qualifications for entering the state-controlled job

16 All interviewee names appearing in this study are pseudonyms, for the reason of confidentiality.

27

assignment system, rather than the labor market, that orientate individuals’ job seeking

behaviors, at least for those who seek jobs for the first time. Meanwhile, individuals’

persistent pursuit of assigned jobs also impacted macro policy changes, by raising the entry

bar for state-controlled jobs, as well as speeding up the development of the market economy.

2.4.1. Increasing Investment in Education: Response to the State’s Changing Emphasis

Recent studies have shown that economic returns to human capital do not differ between the

state and market sectors (Wu & Xie 2003; Xie & Hannum 1996). Unlike the prediction of the

market-transition theory (Nee 1989), the market economy is not necessarily more

meritocratic than the job-assignment system. In fact, since the late 1970s it has become

vitally important for the party-state to recruit talented people from all social classes for its

“pursuit of a technocratic economic growth policy” (Gabriel, Powell, & Mundt 1996).

Individuals now preferred by the party-state are those having “the skills desired by party

leaders to accomplish their new policy agenda (Bruce 2000)”. As Townsend and Womack

commented, “in general, post-Mao recruitment has reverted to the pattern of the mid-1950,

except that recruitment now is less class-oriented and even more committed to including

intellectuals.” (1986: 299)

The revival of the university entrance exam system in 1978 was a clear sign of the state’s

inclination towards higher education. Perceiving the state’s (re)emphasis on education,

individuals started to invest in education in order to find a “good” assigned job. The

aforementioned informant, Jian, is a typical case in this regard. Jian was initially recruited

into a large-scale SOE, the Great Wall Steel Manufacture, as a manual worker in 1972. Being

good at calligraphy, however, Jian was quickly promoted to be an associate office head in a

sub-branch of the enterprise. Despite a promising career prospect, Jian decided to take a

continuing-education program in 1984. As he explained:

“When I first got my job, a junior high graduate appeared to be a knowledgeable

person already. At that time (in the early 1980s), I felt like the situation changed. The

state needs intellectuals now. I must be left behind if I still had only a junior high

28

diploma. I felt that I needed recharge, learning more stuff, so as not to be kicked out

by the society.”

Clearly, Jian’s motivation for pursing higher education was based on the fact that “the state

needs intellectuals now.” Responding to the state’s new policy and obtaining higher

education thus directly led individuals to better jobs. Although Jian suspended his work to

study in a college program for two years, he was promoted to office head in the central

department of Great Wall Steel immediately after he received the degree. When the supply of

university graduates fell short of the state’s demand for intellectual employees, individuals’

investment in higher education paid off in the state sector in the 1980s. In another case, a 45-

year-old high school principal, Mr. Gu Huo recalled that when he graduated from a

prestigious university in the local region in 1987, each graduate could bargain with the labor

bureau for an ideal assigned job. Gu himself refused the first assigned job because of his

dissatisfaction with the geographical location, before getting a second assignment that finally

met his expectations.

Simply put, in correspondence with the state’s changing policies, with an emphasis on

education, individuals started to invest in higher education to get ahead in the state-controlled

job assignment system. That is, individuals’ pursuit of education cannot be attributed to the

meritocratic principle of the market at this stage. As the existing literature (Davis 1999; Wu

& Xie 2003) shows, most private entrepreneurs and individual business owners (getihu) in

the first decade of the reform were migrant peasants, unemployed youth, dismissed workers,

former criminals released from prisons, and retirees. The influx of the urban unemployed and

migrant peasant workers made the private sector unattractive to the mainstream, by bringing

in a stigmatized label of “lower class.” University graduates, among other social elite, who

could easily access high-status jobs through the state’s job assignment, would not feel

motivated to dabble in the private sector, at least in the first stage of the employment system

change.

While state policy stimulated individuals’ pursuit of higher education, this individual reaction

also retroacted to the state’s hiring criteria. As the supply of university graduates rapidly

caught up with and exceeded the state’s demand, university graduates’ advantages in

29

obtaining good assigned jobs faded away. The case of Mr. Lei Yang confirms that a

university degree started to lose its privilege to access desirable assigned jobs in the 1990s.

When graduating from the Wuhan Water Conservancy College in 1992, Lei was assigned to

a state-owned oceangoing company in his home province, although his grades were good

enough to enable him to choose his ideal work unit— Shanghai Maritime Bureau. Lei

appealed for a re-assignment, but unfortunately got rejected. Lei recalled:

“The employment pressure (for university graduates) had emerged. Huge competition

for (getting into) good danwei (work units). My department forced me to go back (to

my home province); I had no choice. If I had insisted, I might have ended up getting

nothing.”

While the number of university graduates has multiplied, the job assignment system

continuously declined. Faced with this irreversible trend, individuals did not choose to

embrace jobs in the market sector immediately, but instead, strategically pursued higher

educational degrees. Lei’s remarks explicate the rationale behind this behavior:

“If I had not accepted the assignment, I must go looking for jobs on my own. I was

just a poor young student, having zero work experience, (and) knowing nobody…

There is a saying that ’a camel that died of hunger is still bigger than a horse.’ After

all, you got assigned into a SOE, which made your choices open. (If) [y]ou like it, you

stay; (if you) don’t like it, well, you could always choose to leave later on. The

reverse way would be very hard: Don’t dream about getting into a SOE if you didn’t

choose it in the beginning.”

On one hand, an individual entering the labor market for the first time lacked resources to

succeed in market competition. On the other hand, the state assignment channel provided

more flexibility than the labor market for one’s future career development. Perceiving these

two points, people’s preference towards the state job assignment system did not disappear

with the withdrawal of the system, but rather, became stronger. From the 1990s onwards, to

access the shrinking number of job assignment opportunities, individuals chose either to

advance their education further, or to focus on particular majors and universities for which

30

state-assigned jobs would still be accessible. My interview data show that starting from the

mid 1990s’, a Bachelor’s degree could no longer secure an assigned job. Individuals chose

either to pursue a Master’s or even a Ph.D. degree, or to select universities strategically.

“During the later stage of my undergraduate, I sensed I needed a Master’s degree. You see, I

finished my undergraduate in 2000, by which year most graduates had to be on the market.

You must know how competitive the job market has been…” said Mr. Gang Hu, a 32-year-

old Master’s graduate who entered the central government in 2003. In another case, a 29-

year-old customs officer who got his current job through the governmental official entrance

exam in 2002, Mr. Jun Ye, purposely chose to attend a university that is directly subject to

the Ministry of Justice of China. Due to this university’s association with the ministry,

various governmental departments throughout the country come to this university to hire new

graduates directly. As Jun commented on his job search experience, “it doesn’t seem to be so

hard for graduates from our university to get jobs.”

In short, to release itself from the heavy burden of a full, permanent employment system, the

state initiated the first move by prioritizing university graduates’ employment opportunities,

though less-educated urban citizens could still have access to assigned jobs in the 1980s. As

individuals actively responded to this shift in the state’s hiring preference, the supply of

university graduates rapidly exceeded the state’s demand. While higher education was only

an asset for one to get ahead in the job assignment system in the 1980s, it became a required

qualification for one to even access an assigned job in the 1990s. Clearly, although it was the

state that made the first move in restoring the importance of human capital in the hiring

process, the continuously increasing educational entry bar was due to the “push” factor—

individual job seekers’ increasing investment in education. In other words, individuals’

reactions (pursuit of higher education) to the initial policy change (reemphasis on education)

accelerated the meritocratic trend of the job assignment system, and consequently reinforced

the state’s preference for hiring intellectuals. Thus, I must restate that an education-driven

employment system occurring in China’s post-transition labor market is not due to the

emergence of the market mechanism. Instead, the continuous increase in required educational

qualifications is constructed in the process, in which individual job seekers consistently

31

invested in education to gain advantages in securing assigned jobs while the state

consistently cut down the number of available assigned jobs.

One may disagree on the above argument by pointing out the fact that an increasing number

of the highly-educated have dabbled in the market, as the employment system change

continued. For example, in the wave of “xiahai” (jumping into the sea) in the 1990s,

numerous intellectuals and former communist cadres shifted their jobs from the public sector

to market sector. However, as Hebel (1996) found, individuals would seek opportunities

more actively in the private sector after they held assigned positions as their primary jobs. As

he said, during the 1990s it was a common trend to take a second job in the market, while

holding one’s assigned job in the state sector. Particularly, highly-educated employees, such

as professors, teachers, technicians, and researchers were the leading cohorts among two-job

holders. Even for those who completely shifted from the public to market sector, resignation

rarely took place. A typical way to “jump into the sea” was to get a permit from the original

workplace for “leave without pay.” Namely, although one does not work for, nor get paid by

the original state-owned workplace, one could pay the workplace a certain amount of annual

fees to keep one’s affiliation to this workplace for years. In this way, one could come back to

the original workplace if the attempt of “jumping into the sea” failed. A second piece of

counterevidence one may have is that highly-educated job seekers indeed started to look for

their primary jobs in the labor market after the mid 1990s, as shown in Wu and Xie’s 2003

study. However, my in-depth interview data reveal that highly-educated individuals chose to

seek employment primarily through the labor market only when their ideal assigned jobs

were not accessible. With similar economic returns and career development opportunities

provided, one would still prefer an assigned job over a job available in the free market,

particularly when entering the labor market for the first time.

As Lei commented above, “a camel that died of hunger is still bigger than a horse.” An

assigned job functions as a safety net. Even with a relatively low economic return, being

assigned into the state sector means lifetime security and benefits, which makes assigned jobs

ultimately superior to jobs in the market. An assigned job also functions as a spring board, by

allowing one to access and take advantage of rich resources in the state sector for further

32

career development, most often in the market sector. Particularly, highly-educated

individuals’ participation in the free market is not contradictory to my argument that

attributes the overall increase in education in the post-socialist era to individuals’ preference

towards state-controlled jobs. In fact, it is the highly-educated who were more likely to gain

market premium by taking advantage of resources they accumulated within the system at the

later transitional stage (Wu & Xie 2003).

2.4.2. Joining the Party: Response to the Increasing Competition for Assigned Jobs

As shown above, a direct impact of individuals’ vast investment in education is the rising

educational entry bar of assigned jobs. When increasing educational qualifications could not

preclude as many job seekers as the state expected, the importance of political qualifications

was emphasized in the job assignment system. As Walder et al. (2000) pointed out, political

credential still plays a crucial role, particularly when it comes to positions that exercise

decision-making authority. The state’s continuous emphasis on political qualifications

directly led to individuals’ participation in the CCP. In his study on the Party’s recruitment of

college students in the last several decades, Guo (2005) showed that the changing trend in the

number of student party members corresponds to that of the employment situation. The ratio

of social demand to the supply of college graduates was 3 to 1 in 1986, which evidenced

ample employment opportunities for highly-educated individuals in the 1980s.

Correspondingly, the proportion of college students who joined the Party declined

dramatically from 11% (in 1979) to less than 1% in 1989 (Guo 2005:375). However, when it

turned to the 1990s, the number of college students has consistently increased during the

whole decade, and increased even faster since 1999, when the state decided to significantly

expand college enrolment. According to Guo (2005), undergraduate party members increased

from 16,000 to 209,000, or from 0.81% to 3.83% of the total undergraduate population from

1990 to 2000. It is thus reasonable to say that one’s participation in the CCP was, to a

significant degree, driven by the increasingly intensified competition for assigned jobs. As

Guo (2005) pointed out, nowadays the majority of students strive to join the Party out of a

personal pragmatic concern for their job searches and career advancement, rather than for an

33

ideological reason. When asked about his motivation for joining the Party, a 26-year-old

salesman who entered his company, Lenovo Ltd. in 2002, Mr. Wei Cao said:

“You’d definitely want to have as many advantages as possible to be ready for the job

market, especially when you didn’t know what kind of job you’d end up in. After all,

SOEs still prefer party members, if candidates’ academic performances are the same.

On the other hand, being a party member wouldn’t be a disadvantage in private

firms, if it’s not an advantage. So, I can’t see why not (to get party membership).”

Wei’s remarks clearly represent individuals’ rational calculation in terms of joining the Party.

Party membership is seen as a safe investment that, under the CCP regime, has no negative

consequences, but only potential benefits. Ms. Yun Zhen, a 30-year-old associate

departmental chief in a state-owned bank explained why being a party member would benefit

one’s job search. “Indeed, some excellent graduates don’t want to join the Party; but if you

are not good enough, you definitely cannot get in (the Party). So, being a party member more

or less proves your merits.”17 This supports Guo’s (2005) argument that party membership

connotes desirable qualities in a job seeker, such as organizational and communication skills,

team spirit, and the capability to get things done.

Take Gang’s case as an example. Gang got into the top management school of the country

with outstanding grades on the entrance exam. When Gang realized that he could not be as

successful as before in academic competition, for his rivals were all top students from

different places throughout the country, he decided to “work the other way around”. Gang

applied for the CCP’s membership actively, and became a party member at the early stage of

his undergraduate period. Beyond this, Gang also actively participated in party events, and

was eventually appointed to be the highest-rank student leader in the party branch of the

university. As Gang said, political performances are “like a bumper… I need to bump up my

qualifications, ‘cause you know, if (the committee) only looked at academic performances, I

17 Party members are claimed as pioneers whose mission is to lead the masses in achieving collective and individual well-being under the socialist regime. Therefore, in principle, only the “best” individuals in every field can be recruited into the communist party. However, the definition of “best” changes over time.

34

couldn’t be ranked high enough.” Because of his outstanding political performance in the

party branch of the university, Gang was successfully recommended to enter the Master’s

program. Three years later, Gang successfully entered the central government. Although he

entered his job by taking the entrance exam, Gang pointed out that his political performance

weighed significantly in his successful job search.

In short, human capital had outweighed political capital in the job assignment system in the

first decade after a free labor market was legitimized. As the market mechanism further

matured, political capital seemed to regain its popularity, particularly among university

graduates. This phenomenon, again, cannot be attributed to the growth of the market.

Moreover, focusing only on the persistence of state power, one cannot explain the “down and

up” trend of the importance of political capital, either. By contrast, considering joining the

party as the complement to one’s educational credentials, I explained that the increasing

trend of joining the party is driven by the increasing competition for state assigned jobs.

Under the condition in which a university degree could no longer secure an assigned job,

individuals perceived party membership as a supplemental advantage that may increase one’s

chance for getting an assigned job. On the surface, the increasing number of student party

members shows that the state’s control over employment has not been weakened, but

solidified. At the deeper level, however, this pragmatic behavior with an instrumental

purpose of job search matched the market rationality very well. It seems reasonable to say

that individuals’ strategies for getting assigned have also paved the way for the advent of a

market-economy era.

2.4.3. Guanxi Manipulation: Response to the Persistence of State Power

Social capital is a third component that constructs the changing employment system.

Although the importance of social capital in labor markets has been well demonstrated

(Granovetter 1973, 1995; see also Lin’s 1999 review), scholars found that the role social

capital plays varies with the institutional context (Granovetter 1995). The term ‘guanxi’

(relations in Chinese term) in China is used to describe a kind of patron-client relationship,

which is considered to be an inseparable part of the Chinese economy (Bian, Breiger,

35

Galaskiewicz, and Davis 2005; Bian, Davis, and Wang 2006; Christiansen 1996; Oi 1989).

This is not only because guanxi is culturally embedded in every aspect of the Chinese’s lives

(Fei [1949]1992; Gold 1985), but also due to its’ pragmatic function in distributing resources

within a certain boundary (Yang 1994). In his study about the use of ‘guanxi’ for getting a

job in pre-reform China, Bian distinguished two major functions of social capital in the

process of job attainment: influence imposition and information flow. As he pointed out,

under the job assignment system in pre-reform China, the mobilization of guanxi benefits job

seekers by imposing influence on the employer side and bonding the job seeker and the

employer, so that a job assignment would be made through guanxi (Bian 1997).

Although guanxi was never the state’s official hiring criterion, its usage was pervasive during

the command economy era. Under the rigid state-controlled system, as Oberschall (1996)

argued, individuals, as well as families, cliques, subunits, and work units, cultivated and

modified informal networks that penetrated vertical boundaries and compartments, “to

escape the rigidities and controls of the party-state and danwei, and to get ahead of others.”

(Oberschall 1996: 1031) This collective behavior was thus institutionalized, by “creating and

forever changing a parallel, informal system of social organization that constituted a kind of

no man’s land in which conformity and deviance were blurred and could be manipulated to

advantage.” (Oberschall 1996: 1031) The case of Mrs. Yi Li, a 52-year-old division chief in

the Urban Planning Department, supports this argument. As Yi said, the reason that she could

get a job in the government in 1976, instead of being sent to the countryside, was because of

her father who was the head of the Military Department in the local city18. “My father knew

someone in the labor bureau. It’s not difficult for him to get me an assigned job,” said Yi. Yi

thought that “it’s no big deal” to get a job using her father’s influence, because “everybody

did that.”

Therefore, the interaction of the rigid job assignment system and individuals’ attempts to get

around the system caused the pervasiveness of guanxi manipulation in the pre-reform era.

Although unofficial, guanxi manipulation was “institutionalized” and created an “informal

18 The name of city is not identified here, for the reason of confidentiality.

36

rule” that no one could escape under the communist regime. Presumably, this informal

employment institution should have changed in the process of the substitution of the labor

market for the job assignment system. In reality, however, individuals’ competition for the

declining state-controlled job opportunities has reinforced, rather than reduced, the use of

guanxi.

Mr. Liang Wang, a 30-year-old governmental official who got his job in the Economic

Development Council of his home city in 2001, described his “job search” experience as

follows:

“I had wanted to go outside (of my hometown). However, I couldn’t find a job

outside. My college is a local college, which doesn’t have a countrywide reputation.

Then, I tried to take a Master’s program somewhere else, but failed the entrance

exam…There happened to be some temporary positions open in my dad’s workplace,

and he asked me to take one.”

After a year of probation, Liang was smoothly promoted to an official position. Liang

admitted that the reason for getting his job was due to his father, who was the associate chief

in that council. In two working papers I have discussed the mechanism and consequences of

guanxi manipulation in details. Based on a comparison of the above two cases, here I want to

emphasize that guanxi manipulation did not change significantly during the transitional

process. My interview data show that the advantaged group in the state-controlled system

saw maintaining their offspring’s advantaged status within the system as a top priority,

instead of transferring this advantage into the market sector. The higher one’s family status

origin, the higher the quality of guanxi resources one could mobilize through family ties, and

thus the better one’s chance was to get an assigned job with guanxi assistance. Therefore, the

interplay of employment policies (downsizing assigned jobs) and individual reactions

(mobilizing family ties) has further strengthened the trend of elitism in the state-controlled

system, by maintaining the elite group’s advantages across generations. As a side effect, this

individual strategy has, to some degree, also coincided with the function of social capital in

the market economy, and thus facilitated individuals’ adaptation into the newly-emerged

labor market.

37

Above all, while the state’s leading role in China’s transitional process has been well

explained in the existing literature, my qualitative analysis articulates the formation of the

trajectory of the employment system change by focusing on individuals’ corresponding

strategies towards the state’s changing employment policies. In the process of the shift from

a state-controlled job assignment system to a free labor market, individuals viewed

maintaining an advantaged status in the state-controlled system as their goal. They

consistently strived to obtain an assigned job by pursuing higher educational degrees, joining

the party, and mobilizing guanxi resources, particularly family ties. These strategies further

raised the bar of entry for assigned jobs, which in turn, exacerbated competition for assigned

jobs. Therefore, I argue that the path of China’s employment system change is not solely

decided by the state, regardless of its ultimate power. It is reasonable to consider it an

interplay process, in which individual responses to state policies have played a significant

role in shaping the trajectory of the employment system change.

2.5. Consequences of the Interplay: Concentration of the Social Elite and Their Resources

2.5.1. Why Is a Quantitative Verification Legitimate?

A common critique of qualitative analysis lies in its difficulties of verification and

generalization. However, an indirect way to verify and generalize qualitative findings is

possible. Regarding my argument about the interplay process of the employment system

change, my strategy is thus to test the consequences derived from this argument, since the

interplay process is not directly verifiable. This strategy is legitimate only when the targeted

argument is a necessary and sufficient condition of the hypotheses that are directly tested. I

also want to reemphasize that my study is focused only on the time period of the abolishment

of the job assignment system. A discussion about the well-established labor market after

2003 is thus beyond the scope of this paper. Keeping these two points in mind, I develop my

hypotheses as follows.

In my qualitative analysis, I have articulated how individuals’ responses to the initial policy

change have re-shaped the changing path of state policies, which in turn stimulated

38

individuals’ further reactions. First, in terms of education, my qualitative analysis shows that

highly-educated job seekers preferred assigned jobs over jobs in the market, and

subsequently the investment in education increased over time because of the competition for

assigned jobs. Second, by joining the party, an individual tends to gain additional advantages

to access an assigned job. Third, a comparison between the last two cases in my qualitative

analysis suggested that the pervasiveness of mobilizing family ties in the state-controlled

system remained, despite the institutional change. These above three hypotheses are derived

directly from my qualitative analysis. In other words, my argument about the interplay of the

employment policies and individual reactions is the sufficient condition of the three

hypotheses.

On the other hand, the formation of labor market stratification and inequality as a

consequence of institutional change has been discussed in depth in the existing

socioeconomic-transition literature. However, as aforementioned, what remains puzzling is

the driving force of this consequence. Three explanations are available in the market-

transition debate, namely, the emergence of the market, the persistence of political power,

and the “co-evolution” of political power and the market. As my qualitative analysis reveals,

the change in the employment system cannot be solely explained by the emergence of the

market, because individuals invested in higher education with a direct goal of getting an

assigned job, instead of participating in labor market competition. This employment system

change cannot solely be attributed to the persistence of political power either, because,

clearly, individuals’ interest in accumulating political credentials increased only after the

competition for assigned jobs intensified. The only remaining explanation is thus the co-

existence of political power and market strength, as Zhou’s (2000) “co-evolution” model

stated. However, there has not yet been a single study that explains the working mechanism

of the “co-evolution” model. While state power and the market are regarded as competing

forces by economists19, my qualitative analysis from the individual perspective has explained

19 Classic economists advocated a self-regulating market free of any intervention (Smith 1903[1723-1790]; Ricardo; Malthus), and strongly oppose the state’s interference into economic life. Even for Keynesian economists (Keynes 2007[1936]), the market still plays a predominant role, though government intervention is allowable through adjusting monetary policies during recessions.

39

how the boundary between the state and market is blurred at the individual level. To

individuals, only benefits matter; to maximize benefits, individuals actively adapt their job-

seeking behaviors so as to make good use of advantages from both the state-controlled

system and the market. State power and market strength have thus been reinforced

simultaneously as the underlying forces that have co-shaped the path of the employment

system change. To summarize, here I have discussed all possible theoretical explanations of

the formation mechanism of the institutional change. Focusing on either the emergence of the

market or persistence of state power has been shown to be an incomplete explanation in my

qualitative analysis. The explanation of the co-existence of the state and market holds its

ground, only under the condition that one understands the institutional change as the

interplay of state policies and corresponding individual responses. This means that the

“interplay” explanation of the institutional change is the necessary condition of the

hypothesized stratification consequences.

Given the premise that the “interplay” argument is the necessary and sufficient condition of

the derived stratification consequences, the verification of those consequences is equivalent

to the verification of the “interplay” argument.

2.5.2. Hypotheses: Three Types of Successful Job Seekers and the Resource Distribution among Them

In the following quantitative analysis, I test the consequences of the employment system

change by focusing on the differentiation of qualifications among individual job seekers.

Differences among individual qualifications were minimized when the job assignment

system was the only legal employment channel open to all urban citizens, and then became

increasingly noticeable as the number of assigned jobs declined. Before the job assignment

system was completely abolished, there would be three types of job seekers. I call the first

type “job-assignment system winners,” including individuals who got jobs exclusively

through the job assignment system. The second type is “job-assignment system

referring to those who tried multiple job search channels, but eventually got jobs through the

job assignment system. The final type is called “job-assignment system outsiders,” referring

40

to individuals who eventually got jobs in the labor market, rather than in the job assignment

system.

My qualitative analysis suggests an unequal distribution of resources or qualifications among

‘job-assignment system winners,’ ‘job-assignment system opportunists,’ and ‘job-assignment

system outsiders.’ These groups will be called ‘system winners,’ ‘system opportunists,’ and

‘system outsiders,’ respectively, in the following parts of the paper. If individuals’

preferences towards assigned jobs persist and the declining trend of the job assignment

system intensifies the job competition, it is reasonable to hypothesize that ‘system winners’

should possess resources or qualifications that are the most desirable by the state, followed

by ‘system outsiders,’ and then by ‘system outsiders.’ Corresponding to the three types of

resources discussed in the qualitative section, I develop my hypothesis from three aspects.

First, with respect to education I hypothesize that:

Hypothesis 1a: Other characteristics being equal, highly-educated individuals are more

likely to be ‘system winners,’ whereas lowly-educated individuals are more likely to be

‘system outsiders.’

Market-transition scholars might want to argue that the emergence of the market mechanism

had bumped up the overall educational qualification for employment, so it was not surprising

to observe the significant effect of education on successful job search. However, this sole

“market mechanism” argument cannot explain why human capital was concentrated among

‘system winners,’ rather than ‘system outsiders.’ More importantly, in my qualitative

analysis I have clearly shown that individuals’ increasing investment in education primarily

for securing assigned jobs had raised the educational entry bar for assigned jobs, though the

job assignment system itself declined. Namely,

Hypothesis 1b: As the employment system change proceeds, the educational requirement for

being ‘system winners’ does not decrease, but instead, increases.

Regarding political capital, it is reasonable to hypothesize its concentration within the

instead of outside the system. Using party membership as an indicator of political capital, I

thus hypothesize that:

41

Hypothesis 2a: Other characteristics being equal, party members are more likely to be

‘system winners’ and ‘system opportunists,’ whereas non-party members are more likely to

be ‘system outsiders.’

By contrast with the “persistence of political power” argument, my qualitative analysis

shows that the importance of political capital was emphasized only when individuals could

not secure assigned jobs by only relying on human capital. Namely,

Hypothesis 2b: Other characteristics being equal, party members are more likely to be

‘system winners’ only in the later stage of the employment system change.

In terms of social capital, my qualitative analysis shows that the pervasiveness of mobilizing

guanxi resources for getting into the state-controlled system did not change with time.

Moreover, in the Chinese context, the guanxi resources seem, to a great extent, to be

embedded in family ties. It is thus reasonable to propose that those who could successfully

access the declining assigned job opportunities with assistance of guanxi resources were

usually from high-status family background. Namely,

Hypothesis 3a: The higher one’s status origin, the higher quality of family ties one can

mobilize, and thus the greater the chance there is for one to get an assigned job.

Moreover, since the employment system change does not seem to impact the role family ties

play in one’s job attainment in the state-controlled system, as shown in my qualitative

analysis, I hypothesize that:

Hypothesis 3b: The importance of family ties remains constant at different stages of the

employment system change.

2.5.3. Data and Measurements

Data used to verify the above hypotheses are drawn from the 2003 China General Social

Survey (CGSS) – the urban section, a four-stage stratified probability sampling survey on the

Chinese urban population. The sample consists of 5,894 adults, aged 18 to 69 years old, who

were randomly selected from 30 provincial-level locations. Because it is hard to define one’s

42

first ever job20, I focus on how one got the first job at his or her current workplace (or last

workplace for retired respondents). As mentioned in the Introduction chapter, the 2003 CGSS

data cover exclusively urban Chinese citizens with the registered residency (hukou) status. It

is undeniable that rural migrant workers have become a significant part of the urban labor

force. The existing literature (Han, Huang, Han, 2011; Lu and Pun, 2010; Qin and Huang, 2010)

focusing on rural migrant workers’ employment in the urban area has provided essential

understanding, regarding the positive role that rural migrants’ participation in the urban labor

force plays in accelerating the marketization process in urban China. However, in this

dissertation, I will focus on the urban workforce with hukou status only. This is because the

institutional context I focused on in this study is the employment system change. Since only

urban citizens with hukou status could benefit from the pre-reform job assignment system, it

is reasonable to limit the research object to this population, so as to show the impacts of the

abolishment of the job assignment system and emergence of the labor market on the same

social group. Bringing rural migrant workers into this study may be not only unnecessary, but

also faulty, considering it would make the focused population inconsistent before and after

the abolishment of the job assignment system.

The dependent variable is “types of successful job seekers,” which as I articulated before, can

be categorized into three groups— system winners, system opportunists, and system

outsiders. This variable was generated based on all jobs search methods one tried AND the

determinant method that led to one’s job search success. First, the respondent was required to

report all the channels he or she tried in the entire job search process. In addition to seven

options that were provided in the questionnaire, another three options were reported by the

respondents themselves. Among the total ten options, only ‘assigned by the government or

arranged by a governmental organization’ and ‘internal recruitment in a state-owned

organization’ were coded as job-assignment channels. All other channels were considered

outside-system channels, which could further be divided into two categories. Methods, such

as ‘replacing parent(s)/relatives’, ‘recommendation from others’, and ‘others offering a job

20 My qualitative interviews show that respondents usually had difficulty defining their first jobs. Some started to work while at school, some returned to school from work and then re-entered a career afterwards, and some claimed that their first jobs after school could not be considered “official” jobs.

43

without asking’, were coded as guanxi channels; while others, such as direct application,

employment services in the market, human resources exchange center, self-employed, and

job entry exams, were regarded as new, formal channels emerging with the labor market.

Second, the respondent was asked to report only ONE method that played a determinant role

in his or her job attainment. Although it is possible that sometimes each of the multiple

channels one used contributed equally into one’s job search success, asking the respondent to

decide which one was ultimately important is still meaningful. This is because when the

respondent could not decide on the most important job search channel, the common response

would be to follow the social expectation and provide the answer that one thought was the

“common sense”. Thus, this kind of responses did not bias, but on the contrary, reflected the

typical situation within the corresponding context. Three types of job search channels are

presented in the following Table 1.

Table 1. The Categorization of Three Types of Job Search Channels

Three types of successful job seekers were thus generated as follows:

Job-assignment system winners – In this group, respondents reported only the job-assignment

channel in the question for all of the used job search methods. They also chose the job-

assignment channel as the determinant method for their job attainment.

44

Job-assignment system opportunists – In this group, the job-assignment channel was

combined with either of the guanxi or market channel, or both of them in responses about all

of the used job search methods. However, respondents chose the job-assignment channel as

the determinant method for their successful job attainment.

Job-assignment system outsiders – In this group, responses for all of the used job search

methods might or might not include the job-assignment channel. More importantly, the job-

assignment channel was not reported as the crucial method for the respondent’s job

attainment.

Information in the 2003 CGSS was collected retrospectively, which allows researchers to

sequence each respondent’s life events in chronological order. By sequencing one’s

educational history, work history, and participation in the Party, I generated individual

characteristics before job entry. I used years of education to measure human capital, and

party membership to indicate political capital. The quality of family ties is closely associated

with one’s family background, which in this study was measured by the father’s highest

education and party membership, because of the lack of direct measures of the father’s

occupational status in the original questionnaire. However, arguably, those two indicators are

positively associated with the father’s occupational status, and can thus reflect one’s family

background to a great extent. Based on the information of the year of one’s entry into the

current workplace, the variable “era of job entry” was generated, corresponding to three

stages of the employment system change; namely, job entry before 1979, job entry between

1979 and 1991, and job entry between 1992 and 2003. Approximately one third of the total

sample fell in each historic period. (The distribution of the year of job entry is shown in

Appendix B.) I need to point out that to reveal the impacts of the temporal change in the

employment system, this study focused only on changes in the time dimension. Certainly,

changes have also occurred in the spatial dimension, which has been addressed in a separate

study about labor market inequality resulting from the differences of individuals’ job search

behaviors across geographic locations (Shen 2013).

Control variables, such as age, age square, and gender were included. I must point out that

based on the assumption that the obtained job is the best option one can achieve under the

45

limitation of one’s resources, controlling over the status or quality of the obtained job is not

only unnecessary, but also misleading. What matters in this study is not which job search

channel leads to the best job; but instead, how an individual positions him- or herself,

strategically utilizing the resources he or she possesses in order to achieve the best result for

this particular individual. A descriptive analysis on all variables used is presented in

Appendix C.

2.5.4. Descriptive Analysis

Corresponding to the qualitative analysis, Table 2 shows the frequency distribution of

respondents with and without above-high-school education by era of job entry. As Table 2

shows, among 5,894 respondents, only 640 of them (12% of the total sample size) attended

school for more than 12 years. Considering only 6% of the total labor force attended school

for more than 12 years throughout the country (with the rural area taken into account) by the

end of 200221, the percentage of 12% in the 2003 CGSS is in line with that of the total labor

force with above-high-school education in urban China22. The frequency distribution shows

that less than 6% of respondents who entered their jobs before 1979 attended school for more

than 12 years. This percentage increased to about 9% among respondents who entered their

jobs between 1979 and 1991, and sharply increased to almost 20% among those who entered

their jobs between 1992 and 2003. This corresponds to my qualitative analysis about the

increase in individuals’ investment in education, as the employment system change went on.

21

See Table 1-39 Educational Attainment Composition of Employment by Region. Pp. 48 in China Labour Statistical Year Book 2003, compiled by Department of Population, Social, Science, and Technology Statistics, National Bureau of Statistics, P. R. China. China Statistics Press. 22

The average educational level is significantly higher in the urban area than in the rural area.

46

Table 2. Frequency Distribution of Respondents with and without Above-High-School Education by Era of Job Entry, CGSS 2003, Urban Section

Era of Job Entry Education Before 1979 1979-91 1992-2003 Total High School or below 1,343 1,644 1,616 4,603 94.25% 91.13% 80.24% 87.79% Beyond high school 82 160 398 640 5.75% 8.87% 19.76% 12.21% Total 1,425 1,804 2,014 5,243

100.00% 100.00% 100.00% 100.00%

Table 3 shows the frequency distribution of party members in the urban labor force by the era

of job entry. The average percentage of 10.55% of party members in the 2003 CGSS

corresponds to that of 9%23 of party members in the total labor force throughout the country

by the end of 2002. The proportion of party members is only slightly higher in the first stage

of the reform than that in the pre-reform stage. The slow increase in the proportion of party

members in the urban labor force between 1979 and 1991 is correlated with the

aforementioned decreasing trend of college party members during this period found by Guo

(2005). The percentage of party members increased significantly from 9.9% at the first stage

of the reform to 12.5% at the second stage. This table supports my statement that individuals’

participation in the Party is motivated by individuals’ interest in getting assigned jobs as the

competition intensified. Otherwise, one cannot explain the increasing trend of the proportion

of party members, as the market principle – which is supposedly centered on human capital –

gradually replaced the job assignment system, where party membership plays a significant

role.

23

The percentage was derived from two sources: Sun Yingshuai. 2009. “The Change and Development Trend in the Membership Composition of the Chinese Communist Party.” The Newsletter of the China National School of Administration vol. 5. Available at http://myy.cass.cn/news/482499.htm. And Table 1-1 Main Indicators of National Labour Statistics. Pp. 3 in China Labour Statistical Year Book 2003, compiled by Department of Population, Social, Science, and Technology Statistics, National Bureau of Statistics, P. R. China. China Statistics Press.

47

Table 3. Frequency Distribution of Party Membership by Era of Job Entry, CGSS 2003, Urban Section

Era of Job Entry Party membership Before 1979 1979-91 1992-2003 Total Non-party member Freq. 1,277 1,602 1,717 4,596 % 91.34 90.10 87.51 89.45 Party member Freq. 121 176 245 542 % 8.66 9.90 12.49 10.55 Total Freq. 1,398 1,778 1,962 5,138 % 100.00 100.00 100 100

As shown in Tables 2 and 3, despite the increasing trends, both the percentage of respondents

with above-high-school education and that of party members are small, up to 2003. This is

because attending higher education and joining the Party are both merit-based. While

individuals need to pass a highly competitive entrance exam to get into post-secondary

educational institutions, they also need to go through a very strict, multi-stage procedure for

joining the Party. Because only a small portion of individuals can be selected for attending

higher education and/ or joining the Party, those with educational degrees or diplomas

beyond high school, those with party membership, and those who have both are considered

members of the social elite group. Although the preference towards assigned jobs is common

among urban Chinese citizens, my following analysis will show that only the social elite who

possess desirable educational and political resources, as well as high-status family

background, can obtain assigned jobs during the substitution of the labor market for the job

assignment system.

2.5.5. Distribution of Human Capital among Three Types of Successful Job Seekers

Results are shown in Table 4. All possible comparisons are all presented, for the purpose of

showing the differences between three types of successful job seekers directly. The baseline

model (Model 1) shows that, other covariates being equal, every one-year increase in

education improves: 1). the likelihood of being ‘system winners’ relative to ‘system

outsiders’ by 16% (=1/(e-0.149)-1); 2). the likelihood of being ‘system winners’ relative to

‘system opportunists’ by 6% (=1/(e-0.062)-1); and 3). the likelihood of being ‘system

opportunists’ relative to ‘system outsiders’ by 9% (=(e0.087)-1). Namely, individuals who

48

have the highest level of education are most likely to concentrate in the group of ‘system

winners,’ whereas those who have the lowest level of education are most likely to be ‘system

outsiders.’ Hypotheses 1a is thus substantiated.

With the interaction between education and era of job entry taken into account, Model 2

demonstrates the increasing educational qualification for being “system winners.” On one

hand, era of job entry shows significant effects in favor of the likelihood of being ‘system

outsiders,’ relative to the likelihoods of being either ‘system winners’ or ‘system

opportunists.’ This finding confirms the aforementioned employment system changing

process, in which the labor market had matured, accompanied by the declination of state-

assigned job opportunities. However, this macro changing trend did not prevent human

capital from flowing into the state-controlled system. Other covariates being equal, every

one-year increase in education itself improves the likelihood of being ‘system winners’

versus ‘system outsiders’ by 11% (=1/(e-0.102)-1). In addition, compared to individuals who

found jobs before 1979, every one-year increase in education brings a 7% (=1/(e-0.069)-1)

higher possibility of being ‘winners’ (relative to ‘outsiders’) for those who entered their jobs

between 1979 and 1992, and a 8% (=1/(e-0.08)-1) higher possibility of this odds ratio for those

who entered their jobs after 1992, other covariates being equal. The increase of educational

qualification among ‘system winners’ becomes even more obvious, compared to educational

qualification changes in the other two types of successful job seekers. Regarding the

likelihood of being ‘system opportunists’ versus ‘system winners,’ as shown in the Model 2

column in the center block of Table 4, education itself shows a significant effect in favor of

the odds of being ‘winners’ (coef.= -0.092), other covariates being equal. Although

coefficients of the interaction terms between education and each of the two job-entry stages

are not significant, the directions of coefficients indicate that the educational gap between

‘winners’ and ‘opportunists’ might have widened, when comparing job seekers who entered

their jobs from 1979 to 1992 to their counterparts who found jobs from 1992 to 2003. I then

turn to the odds ratio of being ‘system opportunists’ relative to ‘system outsiders,’ presented

in the Model 2 column in the right block of Table 4. It is clear that, with other characteristics

controlled, ‘opportunists’ have significant advantages in education (relative to ‘outsiders’)

only for those who got employed at the early stage of the employment system change, shown

49

as the significant coefficient of interaction for education and job entry between 1979 and

1992 (coef.= 0.142). The educational gap between ‘opportunists’ and ‘outsiders’ has

disappeared for those who got jobs between 1992 and 2003. Thus, the overall trend shows

that as the employment system change proceeded, the educational gap narrowed between

‘system opportunists’ and ‘system outsiders,’ whereas widened for the ‘system winner’ group

relative to the other two types. Hypothesis 1b is demonstrated. This finding confirms my

qualitative analysis. Namely, the increasing educational entry bar for the assigned jobs

should not be attributed to the emergence of the market, but to individuals’ active responses

to the changing employment system.

2.5.6. Distribution of Political Capital among Three Types of Successful Job Seekers

Model 1 shows that ‘system winners’ and ‘system opportunists’ possess significantly

political advantages over ‘system outsiders.’ Other covariate being equal, the likelihood for

party members being ‘system winners’ is 3.07(=1/(e-1.122)) times as high as for non-party

members, and the likelihood for party members being ‘system opportunists’ is 4.13(=e1.418)

times as high as for non-party members. This finding shows that political capital is

concentrated within the state-controlled system. Hypothesis 2a is thus confirmed.

Model 3 of Table 4 show interesting trends about the change in the importance of party

membership over time. First, there is a distinctive line between party members and non-party

members to become ‘system winners’ and ‘system outsiders’, and this distinction does not

change over time. As shown in the ‘system outsiders vs. system winners’ panel of Model 3,

other covariates being equal, the likelihood for party members becoming system winners

(versus being system outsiders) is 2.63 (=exp(-(-0.966))) times as high as that of non-party

members. Turning to the interaction between party membership and era of job entry, the non-

significant coefficients suggest that party members’ advantage relative to non-party members

in terms of the likelihood of being system winners is consistent over time. Second, there

seems to be a tendency, in which party membership becomes increasingly important for

one’s chance of becoming the ‘system winner’ (relative to ‘system outsiders’) over time.

Other covariates being equal, party members who entered their jobs between 1979 and 1992

50

seemed to be more likely to become ‘system opportunists’ (relative to ‘system winners’),

whereas their counterparts who entered their jobs between 1992 and 2003 presented a

tendency of being more likely to become ‘system winners’. On the other hand, the political

advantage of ‘system opportunists’ relative to ‘system outsiders’ is marginally significant for

those who entered their jobs between 1979 and 1992, but not for those who entered jobs after

1992. Those findings suggest that while political capital is always concentrated within the

state-controlled system, this concentration might have even been intensified at the later stage

of the institutional change, as the gap of political capital seemed to have widened between

‘system winners’ and ‘system opportunists,’ while narrowing between ‘system opportunists’

and ‘system outsiders’. This supports the increasing importance of party membership for

one’s chance of getting a job solely through the job assignment, as the number of assigned

jobs declined. Hypothesis 2b is confirmed.

2.5.7. Distribution of Family Ties among Three Types of Successful Job Seekers

Turning to the effect of family background, a striking finding is that the father’s education

has a significantly positive effect on the likelihood of being ‘system opportunists’ relative to

both ‘system winners’ and ‘system outsiders.’ Model 1 shows that every one-year increase in

the father’s education increases one’s chance of being a ‘system opportunist,’ relative to

being either a ‘system winner’ or ‘system outsider’ by 6% (=e0.056-1; e0.057-1), with other

covariates controlled. The father’s party membership also shows a marginally positive effect

(coef.= 0.29, α=0.1) for one’s chance of being a ‘system opportunist’ versus ‘system

outsider,’ other covariates being equal. These findings suggest that the father’s human capital

and political capital can be transformed to social capital that the corresponding individual can

mobilize to secure a job in the state-controlled system. Model 4 only includes the interactions

between the father’s education and eras of job entry, because an insignificant interaction

involving the father’s party membership is predicted, due to the weak contribution of this

variable. In Model 4, the interaction terms between the father’s education and two eras of job

entry do not show significant effects, which means that the influence of one’s family

background on one’s job search did not change with the employment system change. Thus,

similar to the job assignment system before the reform, the changing employment system

51

from 1979 to 2003 was accompanied with the influence of family ties on one’s successful job

attainment in the state-controlled system. Moreover, this trend remained consistent

throughout the whole period. Hypotheses 3a and 3b are thus demonstrated.

52

Table 4.Multinomial Estimates on the Likelihood of the Three Types of Successful Job Seekers, CGSS Urban Section, 2003

53

54

2.6. Conclusion and Discussion

By using China’s employment system change from the 1970s’ to 2003 as a case study, I

illustrate how an institutional change can be understood as a process co-constructed by

macro-level policies and micro-level individual responses. My focus on the individual level

shows that while the state had initiated the employment system change in urban China, the

trajectory of this institutional change was not solely determined by state policies. Perceiving

the persistence of the political authority, individuals saw state-assigned jobs as a safety net

and/or spring board, and thus made assigned jobs their primary job choices, at least when

entering jobs for the first time. They strategized in their job search schemes to create the best

chance to obtain assigned jobs.

My qualitative analysis shows that individuals pursued education actively upon the new

meritocratic requirements in the job assignment system. This corresponds to the rapid

increase in the proportion of the above-high-school respondents as the employment system

change advanced, shown in my quantitative analysis. This increase cannot be explained by

the market growth, because as Table 4 shows, the educational gap presented a widening trend

between ‘system winners’ and the other two types, while it had narrowed between ‘system

opportunists’ and ‘system outsiders.’

The increasingly intensified competition for the declining assigned jobs also pushed the

increase of individuals’ investment in political capital. Otherwise, one cannot explain the fact

that the proportion of party members did not decrease, but instead increase more rapidly at

the second stage of the reform, when the market economy was significantly strengthened.

Party members are indeed more likely to get assigned jobs by being either ‘system winners’

or ‘system opportunists,’ while non-party members are more likely to become ‘system

outsiders.’

What remains consistent during the institutional change is the mobilization of family ties for

obtaining an assigned job. The father’s human capital and political capital can be transformed

to guanxi resources that provide a shortcut for one’s access to an assigned job. Both of my

qualitative and quantitative analyses show that the better the family background, the greater

55

the chance is for one to become a ‘system opportunist’— achieving an assigned job not by

merely relying on job-assignment channels, but with assistance of other methods, i.e., the

father’s influence.

Putting my qualitative and quantitative analyses together, this study delineates the

employment system change from the individual perspective, through which individuals’

responses to the changing employment policies were brought to the front stage. Individuals’

interest in assigned job opportunities did not decrease, but had increased with the declination

of the job assignment system. Driven by their persistent preference towards assigned jobs,

individuals continuously invested in education, strategically accumulated political

credentials, and actively mobilized family ties in their job search processes.

Understandably, despite the common attempts, not everyone could successfully achieve those

resources. Those who managed to stay in the state-controlled system are only the social elite

who possess one or more types of desirable resources in terms of education, political capital,

and family guanxi resources. Although the existing literature (i.e., Wu and Xie 2003) has

clearly shown that market inequality increased exponentially, after the social elite started to

take advantage of the resources they accumulated in the state-controlled system to pursue

market benefits, there has not been a single study that specifically examined the role

individuals played during the formation process of social inequality. The absence of an

explanation at the individual level makes it difficult for one to understand how state power

and the market, as two seemingly contradictory driving forces of social stratification, have

co-developed during China’s transition.

This study shows that at the individual level the distinction between state power and market

strength gets blurred, as individuals make use of all possible means to optimize their job

search outcomes. What drives the stratification among individual job seekers during this

process is not simply the state’s changing policies per se; but instead, individuals’

perceptions of and responses towards those policies – motivated by their persistent interest in

the state-controlled job opportunities. The direct consequence of individuals’ responses is the

formation of the concentration of the social elite with desirable resources in the state-

controlled system before the job assignment system disappeared. This very small group of

56

social elite has thus gained the market premium, when they dabbled into the market with

advantages they further accumulated within the state-controlled system. Social inequality is

consequently intensified while both state power and the market economy are developed in

this process. Future studies are needed to further understand the co-development of the state

and market from the individual perspective.

Needless to say, the Chinese society has been going through another wave of fundamental

changes since 2003. What is presented in this study may not be in line with the latest trends,

particularly because of the occurrence of the latest series of reforms in the higher educational

system, the change in the Communist Party leadership, the rapid diffusion of the Internet, and

China’s unavoidable participation in globalization. However, the constructive perspective

with a focus on individuals exemplified by this study can be used in any historic and societal

context. As much as this perspective provides a new understanding of the formation of the

stratified social structure and the underlying mechanism of the co-development of state

power and the market in post-socialist China, it also has great potential to improve scholarly

understanding of social changes in China as well as around the globe in the new century.

57

References

Bian, Y. J. 1997. “Bringing Strong Ties Back In: Indirect Connection, Bridges, and Job Search in China.” American Sociological Review 62(3): 266-285.

Bian, Y. J., R. Breiger, J. Galaskiewicz, and D. Davis. 2005. “Occupation, Class, and Networks in Urban China.” Social Forces 83(4): 1443-68.

Bian, Y. J., D. Davis, and S Wang. 2006. “Family Social Capital in Urban China: A Social Network Approach.” In Wenfang Tang and Burkart Holzne (Eds.), Social Change in Contemporary China (pp. 219-32). University of Pittsburgh Press.

Bian, Y. J., & Logan, J. R. 1996. “Market Transition and the Persistence of Power: The Changing Stratification System in Urban China.” American Sociological Review 61(5): 739-758.

Bruce, J. Dickson. 2000. “Cooptation and Corporation in China: The Logic of Party Adaptation.” Political Science Quarterly 115(4): 517-540.

Cao, Y., and Nee, V. G. 2000. “Comment: Controversies and Evidence in the Market Transition Debate.” The American Journal of Sociology 105(4): 1175-1189.

Christiansen, F. 1996. “Chinese Labour in Transition 1978-91: A Case of Institutional Evolution.” In G. Rodgers, K. Foti, & L. Lauridsen (Eds.), The Institutional Approach to Labour and Development (pp.179-204). London: Frank Cass.

Davis, D. 1999. “Self-employment in Shanghai: A Research Note.” China Quarterly 157: 22–43.

Fei, X.T. 1992[1949]. From the Soil, the Foundations of Chinese Society: A Translation of Fei Xiaotong’s Xiangtu Zhongguo. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

Gabriel, A. A., Powell G. B., & Mundt, R. J. 1996. Comparative Politics: A Theoretical Framework. New York: Harper Collins Colleges Publishers.

Gold, T. 1985. “After Comradeship: Personal Relations in China since the Cultural Revolution.” China Quarterly 104: 657-675.

Granovetter, M. S. 1973. “The Strength of Weak Ties.” American of Journal of Sociology 78(6): 1360-1380.

——. 1995. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers, 2nd ed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Guo, G. 2005. “Party Recruitment of College Students in China.” Journal of Contemporary China 14(43): 371-393.

58

Han, K. Q., Huang C. C. & Han W. J. (2011). Social Mobility of Migrant Peasant Workers in China. Sociology Mind, 1(4), 206-11.

Hebel, J. 1996. “Institutional Change in Enterprise-based Society and its Impact on Labour: The Case of the People’s Republic of China.” In G. Rodgers, K. Foti, & L. Lauridsen (Eds), The Institutional Approach to Labour and Development (161-178). London: Frank Cass.

Lin, N. 1999. “Social Networks and Status Attainment.” Annual Review of Sociology 25: 467- 87.

Lu, H. & Pun N. (2010). Unfinished Proletarianization: Self, Anger, and Class Action among the Second Generation of Peasant-workers in Present-day China. Modern China, 36(5), 493-519.

Kanfer, R., Wanberg, C. R., & Kantrowitz, T. M. 2001. “Job Search and Employment: A Personality-Motivational Analysis and Meta-Analytic Review.” Journal of Applied Psychology 86(5): 837-55.

Keynes, J. M. 2007[1936]. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan.

Malthus, T. 1949[1766-1834]. An Investigation of the Cause of the Present High Price of Provisions. With an Introduction by Harry G. Johnson. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

North, D. C. 2007[1990]. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Nee, V. 1989. “A Theory of Market Transition: From Redistribution to Markets in State Socialism.” American Sociological Review 54(5): 663-81.

——. 1998. “Sources of New Institutionalism.” In M. C. Brinton & V. Nee (Eds), The New Institutionalism in Sociology (pp. 1-16). New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.

Nee, V., & Matthews, R. 1996. “Market Transition and Societal Transformation in Reforming State Socialism.” Annual Review of Sociology 22: 401-35.

Oberschall, A. 1996. “The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and sociology Exit Socialism into the Market.” American Journey of Sociology 101(4): 1028-41.

Oi, J. C. 1989. State and Peasant in Contemporary China: The Political Economy of Village Government. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Qin, H. & Huang, P. (2010). A General Description of Research on New Migrants in Urban China. Chinese Sociology and Anthropology, 43(1), 6-22.

59

Parish, W. L., and E. Michelson. 1996. “Politics and Markets: Dual Transformations.” American Journal of Sociology 101(4): 1042-59.

Ricardo, D. 1917[1772-1823]. The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London, Dent.

Rona-Tas, A. 1994. “The First Shall Be the Last? Entrepreneurship and Communist Cadres in the Transition from Socialism.” American Journal of Sociology 100(1): 40-69.

Shen, Jing. 2013. “How Can One Get Ahead in the Contemporary Labor Market of China? – Examining the Changing Stratification Mechanisms through Job-Attainment Patterns.” Journal of Management and Sustainability vol. 3(2): 132-44.

Smith, A. 1903[1723-1790]. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Routledge.

Townsend, J. R., & Womack, B. 1986. Politics in China. The Scott, Foresman/Little, Brown Series in Comparative Politics. A Country Study Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresman and Company.

Walder, A. G. 2004. “The Party Elite and China’s Trajectory of Change.” China: An International Journal 2(2): 189-209.

Walder, A. G., Li, B. B., & Treiman, D. J. 2000. “Politics and Life Chances in a State Socialist Regime: Dual Career Paths into the Urban Chinese Elite, 1949 to 1996.” American Sociological Review 65(2): 191-209.

Wu, X. G., & Xie, Y. 2003. “Does the Market Pay Off? Earnings Returns to Education in Urban China.” American Sociological Review 68(3): 425-42.

Xie, Y., & Hannum, E. 1996. “Regional Variation in Earnings Inequality in Reform-Era China.” American Journal of Sociology 101(4): 950-92.

Yang, M. 1994. Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

Zhang, M. L. 2000. “A Historic Review of Five-decade Changes of the Employment System of China.” Tianfu Xinlun 1: 11-16.

Zhou, X. G. 2000. “Economic Transformation and Income Inequality in Urban China.” American Journal of Sociology 105 (4): 1135-74.

Zhou, X. G., Tuma, N. B., & Moen, P. 1997. “Institutional Change and Job-shift patterns in Urban China, 1949 to 1994.” American Sociological Review 62(3): 339-65.

60

Chapter 3 The Value of Mixed Methods: How Does Certifiability of

Job Requirements Determine the Channels of Job-Person Matching?

3.1. Introduction

Since Granovetter’s (1973, 1974) seminal study about why personal ties are efficient

channels for matching employers and job seekers, informal job-person matching methods

have been widely studied in different societies. Although the advantages of the use of

informal channels have been well documented from both the employer’s and the job seeker’s

perspectives, the question “how do informal channels work?” still puzzles scholars. For

example, why do organizations seldom use informal channels alone in a hiring process,

despite the widely-acknowledged advantages of informal job-person matching (Marsden

1994a, 1994b)? From the job seeker’s side, why do the disadvantaged rely on informal

channels more heavily than highly skilled job seekers (Lin 1999)? Still, if the use of informal

channels does not necessarily have a causal effect on job search success (Mouw 2003), why

are informal channels so often used in many societies?

The reason that the existing literature fails to provide answers to the above questions can be

attributed to a common approach used in previous studies. Researchers treat informal and

formal job-person matching channels as mutually excluding alternatives, while employers

and job seekers often combine the two types of methods in reality. “[T]he formal and

informal routes to jobs, which we keep distinct in our statistics, get blurred in actual daily

practice.” (Granovetter, 1995:168) Thus, to understand the working mechanism of social

capital in reality, it is necessary to take into account the informal-formal-combined channel,

independent from the use of either the formal or informal channel alone.

This study makes an innovative attempt to theorize a typology of the use of job-person

matching methods, by focusing on the certifiability of the employer’s hiring requirements.

“Certifiability” means the extent to which a required qualification can be explicated,

quantified, and proven by an authorized third party. Some requirements (such as basic

knowledge for fulfilling the job) are certifiable by diplomas, degrees, certificates, or licenses,

while the others— such as loyalty, work ethics, career ambition, enthusiasm, and

61

personality— cannot be certified easily. Formal procedures are often used if certifiable

qualifications are the focus of the job, while informal procedures tend to be more effective

and efficient when uncertifiable qualifications are the focus of the job. If a job position

requires both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications, then both formal and informal hiring

procedures are needed. Following Marsden’s (1994a, 1994b) studies on organizational hiring

practices among American establishments, I divide an employer’s hiring process into two

stages – recruitment and selection. Because employers often shift their focuses between

certifiable and uncertifiable qualification assessment across two stages, as well as within

each stage of a hiring process, informal channels are often jointly used with formal channels,

instead of functioning alone.

I will illustrate the job-person matching theory in two steps. First, using case studies drawn

from my interview data collected in three representative Chinese cities, I will demonstrate

different types of successful job-person matching scenarios, in which job seekers perceive

employers’ hiring expectations differently. Second, under the assumption that a job seeker

always tries to match his or her qualifications to the employer’s expectations during a hiring

process, the job seeker’s certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications predict their choice of job

search methods. In the second step, I will use quantitative data from the 2003 China General

Social Survey to demonstrate a positive association between the certifiability of one’s

qualifications and one’s chosen job search channels. The survey results will show that the

patterns found in the qualitative analysis can be generalized to the population level.

3.2. The Effectiveness of Contact Use from the Job Seeker’s Perspective

Job seekers in various labor markets often use informal channels to find jobs, for example,

getting job information from acquaintances, mobilizing internal referrals, or relying on

external recommendations. Granovetter’s (1974) study of professional and managerial men

in Newton found that 55.7% of the respondents used contacts during job search, while

Marsden and Campbell’s (1990) study of a 1982 sample in the Indianapolis area found that

51.4% of respondents got their jobs through friends and relatives. According to Granovetter’s

(1995) review, the percentage of individuals who used contacts for job search varied between

30 and 40% in Britain in the 1980s, and this percentage reached 70 to 75% in Japan in the

62

same period. In China, a survey conducted in Tianjin showed that 45% of the respondents

used informal channels to get their jobs (Bian 1997). A parallel study conducted in Singapore

shows that around 60% of respondents changed their jobs with the help of contacts (Bian and

Ang 1997).

Although job seekers often use informal routes to jobs, it is not yet clear when and how they

benefit from using contacts. On one hand, studies have shown positive effects of contact use

on: 1) facilitating information flow (Granovetter 1973, 1974; Lin and Dumin 1986), 2)

exerting influence on an organizational agent’s decision (Bian 1997; Bian and Ang 1997), 3)

providing social credentials to an individual (Fernandez and Weinberg 1996; Wegener 1991),

and 4) reinforcing the individual identifying and recognizing him/herself as a member of the

work organization (Erickson 2001, 2004). On the other hand, Mouw (2003) challenged the

causal relationship between contact use and one’s career success. According to Mouw

(2003), more qualified job candidates tend to have higher status friends, because people in

general make friends with others similar to themselves (the homophily principle). Thus,

although the qualified job seekers are able to access good contacts, their job search success is

due to their own strong qualifications. This homophily argument may explain why the

positive effects of contact use are not consistent in all studies. Studies found no significant

difference in job search outcomes between formal and informal channels in the Netherlands

and Germany (De Graaf and Flap 1988; Habich 1984; Volker and Flap 1999) and in Detroit

(Marsden and Hurlbert 1988). Using the 1981 Chicago Survey, Bridges and Villemez (1986)

found no effect of search method on income after controlling exogenous variables, such as

race, gender, and human capital, are taken into account. Given studies both showing and not

showing positive effects of using contacts, scholars no longer ask whether informal channels

are useful or not. Instead, “we should ask when social capital matters, how it matters, and

under what conditions.” (McDonald and Elder 2006: 522)

3.3. Linking Individual Search Behaviors to Employers’ Hiring Expectations

Since employers control job allocation, their hiring procedures determine which job search

methods are most likely to succeed. Thus, I begin with examining the hiring expectations on

the employer’s side. As Marsden and Campbell pointed out, “[w]hat search method will be

63

effective for an individual is very much contingent on the methods of recruitment used by

potential employers.” (1990: 59) An employer’s goal is to hire a candidate who suits the

requirements of the job position the best. Following Marsden’s (1994a, 1994b) studies on the

wave of the National Organizations Study (NOS) in the early 1990s, I divide a hiring process

into two stages: recruitment (or extensive search) and selection (intensive search) (see also

Rees 1966; Barron and Bishop 1985). At the recruitment stage an employer’s goal is to

“publicize the availability of openings to qualified applicants and assemble modest

information about a pool of eligible persons.” (Marsden 1994b: 288) After a candidate pool

is generated, the employer would then evaluate all applicants by a variety of means, in order

to single out the candidate who matches requirements of the vacant position the best.

Eventually, “the staffing process ends with the negotiation of agreements between

organizations and employees.” (Marsden 1994b: 288)

Because a job position requires multiple qualifications, an employer often needs to use

multiple strategies in one or both stages. At the recruitment stage, formal channels— such as

advertisements and employment agencies— can be used to reach out to potential employees

who possess desirable certifiable qualifications. However, informal channels— such as

informal referrals from co-workers or business/professional colleagues— would be adopted,

if the employer prefers hiring candidates with certain uncertifiable characteristics. At the

selection stage, while formal procedures (such as screening, testing, and interviewing) are

used to evaluate candidates’ certifiable qualifications, informal methods (usually involving

reference-checking) are the most reliable way to gauge candidates’ uncertifiable

qualifications.

As Marsden (1994a, 1994b) observed based on the NOS data, although informal methods,

such as referrals from employees and reference-checking, are used most frequently, they are

more often used together with formal approaches rather than alone. Employee referrals are

the cheapest method of obtaining labor (Fernandez, Castilla, and Moore 2000; Fernandez and

Weinberg 1997; Rees 1966). However, a candidate pool generated through internal referrals

is usually small, since referrals are very likely to reach out to only a few potential candidates

who share similarities with themselves. This means that if the employer intends to hire a

candidate with the best certifiable qualifications, formal recruitment methods must be used to

“pump up” (Fevre 1989: 98) the size of the candidate pool so as to increase the possibility of

64

recruiting the best qualified candidate. At the selection stage, reference-checking is often

used when a candidate with desirable qualifications is selected. References provide reliable

information about a job applicant’s uncertifiable qualifications (Fevre 1989; Grieco 1987).

Particularly, the use of internal referral increases the new employee’s loyalty to the employer

and reduces the turnover rate, by tying the new worker’s performance to the interests and

reputation of his or her sponsor (Jenkins 1984; Jewson and Mason 1986; Petersen, Saporta,

and Seidel 2000).

In other words, the employer’s hiring strategies are determined by the extent to which a

certain desirable qualification is certifiable in recruitment and in selection. Under the premise

that the job seeker’s search success is determined by the employer’s hiring strategies, I can

thus theorize successful job-person matching patterns, on the axes of certifiability of job

requirements and hiring stage.

3.4. Typology of Job-Person Matching Patterns: Four Basic Types and Their Illustrations

Despite the existence of infinite combination possibilities for job-person matching methods, I

will start with a two-by-two simple categorization based on two hiring stages and two ends of

the certifiability spectrum. Here, I borrowed Max Weber’s (2001[1949]) concept “ideal type”

to construct the job-person matching typology. As Weber (2001[1949]) pointed out, the word

“ideal” does not mean perfection; instead, it stresses certain elements common to most cases

of the given phenomena. An “ideal type” is not a perfect type, but represents a social

category with certain distinctive characteristics. As the two-dimensional typology (Table 5)

shows, in an ideal hiring process, in which stages of recruitment and selection are clearly

divided and the employer considers either only certifiable or only uncertifiable qualifications

at each stage, job-person matching must fall into one of the four scenarios, namely:

certifiable qualifications are desired at both recruitment and selection stages (Type I),

certifiable qualifications are required in recruitment with uncertifiable qualifications required

in selection (Type II), uncertifiable qualifications are preferred in recruitment with certifiable

qualifications referred in selection (Type III), and uncertifiable qualifications are desired at

both recruitment and selection stages (Type IV). Assume that the employer adopts formal

methods to evaluate applicants’ certifiable qualifications, and informal methods to evaluate

65

uncertifiable qualifications in an ideal hiring process, and that job seekers are most likely to

succeed if they use methods matching the employer’s hiring strategies. Under these

conditions, job seekers use only formal channels in Type I, formal channels in recruitment

with informal channels in selection in Type II, informal channels in recruitment with formal

channels in selection in Type III, and only informal channels in Type IV.

Table 5. Four Ideal Types of Job-Person Matching Patterns

The Type I scenario is consistent with economists’ and educationalists’ explanation of labor

market success from the perspective of human capital. Studies conducted in the United States

(Alon and Tienda 2007) and United Kingdom (Goodman et al. 1997; Machin 1999; Themelis

2008) show that the impact of education on career success has remained positive and

moreover, this positive impact has become increasingly strong over time. “The shifting

meritocracy in higher education” (Alon and Tienda 2007) suggests that formal credentials—

particularly in higher education and highly-skilled fields— have become more important than

ever before. Under this approach, job-person matching is a process in which the job seeker’s

certifiable qualifications match up with the employer’s hiring expectations through formal

recruitment and selection procedures.

The Type II scenario can be illustrated by a case study about manufacturing workers’

employment in South Wales during the 1950s and 60s (Fevre 1989). Fevre (1989) found that

employers publicized job information using posts and newspaper advertisements only when

the labor supply was not sufficient. After a proper size of candidate pool was generated

through formal recruitment methods, however, employers made final hiring decisions

through informal channels. Those who had family members or relatives working in the same

factory were more likely to be hired. This is because employers aimed to attract as many as

possible qualified applicants in order to relieve the shortage of labor supply at the recruitment

66

stage. However, once employers reached a large pool of candidates, their focus turned to

applicants’ uncertifiable qualifications, such as values of hard work and loyalty to the

employer, and subsequently changed to select employees through informal channels. In this

case, employers’ continuous “use of informal methods depended on occasional use of formal

methods to prime the recruitment pump” (Fevre 1989:98).

The Type III scenario often occurs when the employer is a small, private company, according

to Marsden’s (1994a) study on the organizational hiring behaviors. Small, private

organizations are likely to prefer a relatively small pool of candidates with certain

similarities, which are often uncertifiable. However, to single out the best qualified

candidate, the selection procedure would still be formal.

Finally, the Type IV scenario can be illustrated by Grieco’s (1987) case study on how

unemployed Scottish workers got jobs at steel factories in Central England through the

recruitment of state-run employment agencies. In this case, the employers’ hiring strategy—

relying on state-run employment agencies— was supposedly formal. However, instead of

publicizing job information broadly so as to attract potentially qualified candidates as many

as possible in the recruitment stage, the agencies chose to minimize the amount of

information available on the market. “[T]he kin-and-friends channel through the importance

of internal notification procedures and word-of-mouth spread of information” (Grieco

1987:121) became the major channel in the recruitment process. At the following selection

stage, those who had relatives or friends working in the factories were more likely to get

hired. The reason for this hiring strategy is that the employers’ top concern was whether or

not employees were hard working and willing to stay in the job. To reach job candidates with

the uncertifiable qualifications, the employers preferred a certain type of laborer from the

same location. In this case, the employer’s concern about employees’ work ethics and

willingness to stay in the jobs are uncertifiable. Those uncertifiable qualifications were

consistently considered in both recruitment and selection. This determines that kinship and

friendship ties – informal methods – were not only the major recruitment sources, but also

the main selection criteria.

Among the above four scenarios, job-person matching presents a completely formal pattern

when certifiable qualifications dominate the whole hiring process (Type I), while it presents a

67

completely informal pattern when uncertifiable qualifications concern the employer

throughout hiring (Type IV). Type II and Type III – 50% of the job-person matching patterns

in an ideal hiring process – show that channels of job-person matching could differ at

different stages of a hiring process, depending on whether certifiable or uncertifiable

qualifications are dominant at each hiring stage. In short, the typology under the assumption

of an ideal hiring process indicates that not only does the joint use of formal and informal

job-person matching legitimately exist, but also its existence may be more pervasive than

scholars have realized.

3.5. Extensions of the Job-Person Matching Typology towards a Realistic Model

The reality is certainly more complicated than an ideal hiring process. On one hand,

recruitment and selection may not be distinctive in every hiring process; on the other hand,

the employer may not focus on only one type of qualifications at each hiring stage. Freeing

the first assumption simplifies the aforementioned typology, and thus does not require

additional discussion. Freeing the second assumption means that certifiable and uncertifiable

qualifications co-exist in either recruitment, or selection, or both. Thus, the four basic types

need to be extended accordingly.

Table 6 presents the extensions of Table 5, by allowing transferability between certifiable

and uncertifiable qualifications in each of the stages. Namely, it is entirely possible that both

certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications are evaluated in recruitment, or selection, or both

stages. The corresponding hiring strategy would subsequently display as a type of

combination of formal and informal channels. This, in turn, determines that job seekers need

to use formal and informal methods jointly in order to meet an employer’s hiring

expectations. This would consequently lead the “joint use of formal and informal job-person

matching” model to the second level; namely, formal-informal-joint matching within the

recruitment stage, or the selection stage, or both. In other words, the extended model means

that formal and informal job-person matching methods can be jointly used, not only across

hiring stages, but more importantly, also within each hiring stage.

68

Table 6. The Expanded Typology of Job-Person Matching Channels in a Two-Stage Hiring Process

Recruitment Selection Single channel across two stages Formal Formal

Informal Informal Joint channel between two stages Formal Informal

Informal Formal Joint channel within two stages Formal + Informal Formal

Formal + Informal Informal Formal Formal + Informal Informal Formal + Informal Formal + Informal Formal + Informal

In the following section, I will illustrate this extended typology using empirical cases

observed in the labor market of post-socialist China. The context of China’s labor market

allows testing of the model across types of sectors and job tenure. China’s socialist market

economy includes a strong state sector and booming private sector (Oi and Walder 1999;

Zhou 2000). The co-existence of a state-controlled economy and a free market has also

diversified types of job tenure. In contrast with lifetime, permanent employment in the

communist era, a variety of contract forms can be found in the context of the transitional

economy. Using qualitative case studies, I will reflect on the theoretical model by discussing

corresponding typical cases across types of sectors and jobs. Following my case studies,

which aim to exemplify how the theoretical model really works in job-person matching

practices, I will then explore the generalizability of the model using representative

countrywide survey data.

3.6. Overview of the Qualitative Data

I conducted my field work in three Chinese cities, Beijing, Shenzhen, and Jiangyou, in the

summer of 2009. The three selected urban locations are representative examples of North

China, where the central government has the strongest influence, South China, where the

market economy started earliest and developed fastest, and West China, where the central

government’s control and market strength are both relatively weak, respectively24. By

24 More detailed descriptions about location-selection rationales are available upon request.

69

adopting the snowball sampling method, I composed a sample frame with up to 50

individuals in each city. However, to match up with the quantitative analysis in this study, I

only selected interview cases in which the informants were urban residents with the local

hukou status and got into their current workplaces no later than 2003. I also excluded self-

employed cases from this study. As a result, twenty-eight cases were used in this study,

including ten cases in Beijing, and nine cases in Shenzhen and Jiangyou, respectively.

Descriptions of interviewees’ characteristics are provided in Appendix A.

As Appendix A shows, the youngest cohort (aged 30 and under) was oversampled. This is

because the influence of the state-controlled job assignment system under the socialist regime

did not completely fade away until early this century. Although studies (Bian 1997, 2001,

2002) have shown that guanxi (social relations) might have been mobilized for a better

assigned job, it was not uncommon for one to get a job without active search under the job

assignment system. Particularly, the older the respondent is, the more likely it is for his or her

case to fall into the “no search” category. By contrast, this would not be a concern for

individuals who entered the labor market from 2000 onwards, by which time even job

positions in the public sector became competition-based, instead of need-based.

Oversampling the youngest cohort gives rise to significantly greater proportions of

respondents with university degrees and of respondents who entered their current jobs after

1992, which serves the purpose of this study by increasing the variation of job-person

matching patterns. As a result, my informants consisted of 58% males and 42% females. 43%

of informants were below thirty years old, 30% of them were between thirty and forty years

old, and 27% of them were above forty years old. 64% of the informants had some higher

education; in fact, 48% of them had graduate degrees. 48.5% of the informants were party

members.

Among the twenty eight cases, twelve cases (43%) reported using formal and informal search

behaviors jointly in their searches, including: two cases (7%) of using informal channels in

recruitment with formal channels in selection, seven cases (25%) of using both formal and

informal channels in recruitment with only formal channels in selection, and the three others

(11%) using formal-informal-joint channels in both recruitment and selection. Fourteen

(50%) respondents reported using only formal channels throughout their searches, consisting

of five cases (18%) getting assigned jobs through the state-controlled system and the

70

remaining nine (32%) competing for publicly available jobs in the market. Only two

respondents (7%) reported solely relying on informal channels for getting their current jobs,

among which one of them first found internships in the government before they got current

permanent jobs, while the other one found a job in the private sector. The distribution results

are presented in Table 7.

Table 7. Types of Job-Person Matching Patterns among Twenty-Eight Interviewees

Recruitment Selection Freq. (%)

Sub-types Freq. (%)

Single channel across two stages Formal Formal

14 (50%)

Assigned jobs from the state

5 (18%)

Jobs obtained from the market

9 (32%)

Informal Informal 2 (7%)

Joint channel between two stages Informal Formal 2 (7%)

Joint channel within two stages

Formal+ Informal

Formal 7 (25%)

Formal+ Informal

Formal+ Informal

3 (11%)

Total 28 (100%)

Despite a modest number of interview cases, Table 7 suggests an interesting trend. Namely,

individuals who solely relied on formal job search channels are the majority (50%), while

those who got jobs completely through informal channels constitute the smallest portion of

active job searchers (7%). The more common use of informal channels is seen in certain

combinations with formal channels. The most popular combination is to use formal and

informal channels jointly only in recruitment, constituting 25% of the total cases. Using joint

channels in both recruitment and selection make up 11% of the total cases. There are also

two cases (7%) reporting using informal channels in recruitment while formal channels only

in selection.

It is noticeable that the job-person matching patterns presented in my qualitative data reflect

three out of four basic types in the original typology. The Type II scenario – formal methods

in recruitment with informal methods in selection – is not found in my case studies. In the

aforementioned example of manufacturing workers in South Wales (Fevre 1989),

71

uncertifiable, instead of certifiable, qualifications were the employers’ major concern; formal

recruitment methods were used only when labor supply was insufficient, for the purpose of

attracting as many as possible applicants with minimum certifiable qualifications.

Employment in the current labor market of China is a completely different story, however.

The unemployment rate in China has never gone below 4%25 in the last decade, according to

the official record. Not just the poorly-educated struggle to become employed; university

graduates are also faced with difficulties in getting jobs. According to a report (Cai and

Wang 2009) issued by the government-controlled media, the first-time employment rate

among university graduates was 72.6% in 2005, and has further deteriorated since then. In

2009, the estimated number of unemployed university graduates reached two million

throughout the country. Within the context of labor oversupply – especially the oversupply of

the highly-educated labor force, certifiable qualifications can hardly be completely

overlooked in selection, particularly when certifiable qualifications are essential at the

recruitment stage.

Despite the absence of the Type II scenario from the Chinese context, a fiercely competitive

labor market urges individuals to maximize their job search efforts to meet the employer’s

hiring requirements. Thus, it provides an ideal context to observe how individuals strategize

in job searches, by using formal and informal methods jointly. In the following analysis, I

will analyze the job-person matching process from the job seeker’s perspective; namely, how

they perceived and interpreted the employer’s hiring requirements, and how they strategized

in their job search so as to obtain jobs successfully. I will start with the scenarios of Type I

and Type IV, in which either formal or informal methods are used throughout the hiring

process. My elaboration on the joint use of formal and informal job-person matching

methods will be based on the Type III scenario and its extensions in real hiring practices.

25

Data can be retrieved from the China Labour Statistical Yearbook – 2003-2012. Available at: http://www.molss.gov.cn/gb/zwxx/node_5435.htm

72

3.7. Formal Channels Only versus Informal Channels Only: A Perspective of Certifiability

The case of Ms. Hua Lu26, a 33-year-old assistant professor, who entered her current

educational institution27 in 2003, shows that when certifiable qualifications dominate the

employer’s concern, formal methods dominate in the matching process. The academy, as a

state-controlled institution responsible for training high-rank governmental officials and

cultivating the future leadership of the Communist Party, is concentrated with political

power. Hiring in this organization is presumably highly exclusive and is only open to

applicants who have recommendations from internal referrals. Indeed, the hiring process for

Hua’s position was full of guanxi’s (social relations’) influence. As Hua said,

“I guess our department head needed someone to do real work. If he had hired some

people through guanxi, he couldn’t get the work done. He said to me once that hiring

me was not easy and that he actually bore some pressure (in order to hire me).”

Guanxi provides a reliable channel for the employer to scrutinize an applicant’s uncertifiable

qualifications. However, in this case an applicant’s certifiable qualifications are far more

important than uncertifiable ones. Hua graduated with a Ph.D. degree from the best program

within the country, which made her stand out of the candidate pool with a competitive

academic background. Moreover, during a multiple-stage screening process, Hua was ranked

at the first place not only among the applicants for the position she applied for, but also

among all applicants for all positions offered by the academy in that year. Between one

candidate with excellent certifiable qualifications and others with powerful guanxi, the

employer chose the former and turned down guanxi. In short, when the employer aims to hire

a candidate with the best certifiable qualifications, job seekers’ sole reliance on formal

methods would be appropriate.

The case of Mr. Jie Wang, a 23-year-old leader of the security team in a prestigious gated

community in Shenzhen, presents an opposite story. After dropping out of school at grade 9,

26

All names used in this study are pseudonyms to protect interviewees’ confidentiality. 27

The name of the city is omitted to protect the interviewee’s confidentiality.

73

Jie had a difficult time to find a job. In 2003, Jie’s brother knew a former classmate working

as the head of the repair team in the property management office of this gated community.

Through his help, Jie was introduced to the former head of the security team. Jie was then

hired as a security guard upon the team leader’s approval, and worked his way up since then.

Despite its low socioeconomic status, Jie’s position could still be very attractive to rural

migrant workers who would have worked in sweatshops otherwise, for its relatively higher

salary and nice working environment. It is not hard to imagine that the number of applicants

would be enormous if the company had publicized the job vacancy. However, the employer

had no interest to do so. First, a security guard position does not need highly certifiable

qualifications. Also, the employer’s expectations of applicants’ uncertifiable qualifications,

such as trustworthiness, sense of responsibility, and willingness to help home owners, are

very high. Under this condition, formal recruitment would not bring in the right candidates.

Instead, informal recommendation, particularly through a relatively high-status internal

reference, is strongly preferred.

The above two cases show that formal job-person matching occurs when certifiable

qualifications dominate the employer’s hiring requirements, while informal job-person

matching would be successful when certifiable qualifications are relatively irrelevant. Most

often, however, both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications are expected for a job

position, which requires a certain combination of formal and informal matching channels.

3.8. Illustration of the Type III Scenario

As shown in the above Table 7, two out of twenty eight job-person matching cases fit the

Type III scenario exactly, where the individual reached the employer through informal

recommendation, and then was hired through a formal selection process. Using the case of

Mr. Lei Yang, a forty-year-old departmental manager, one can clearly see how the

certifiability of job requirements determines the channels by which the employer and job

seeker come together. Lei currently manages a research team in a booming foreign-invested

company, YICT, which operates the largest-scale container terminals in the local harbor.

Prior to his current job, Lei had multiple years of work experience, and also went back to

school to obtain a Master’s degree in his field. Driven by his career ambition, Lei set up a

goal to get a managerial position in YICT, the leading company in his field, though there was

74

no such position open in the company at that time. What Lei did was to ask a senior

schoolmate, Mr. Zhao, who was a senior manager in a related company, to call up Mr. Wang,

the manager of the R&D department in YICT, asking if they were hiring. Upon Zhao’s

recommendation, Wang said, “OK, then, let me check him out. If he’s qualified, I can open a

position for him.” Subsequently, Lei had an interview with Wang, who was impressed with

his knowledge in the shipping field. Wang then took Lei to see his supervisor, Mr. Zhang –

the administrative deputy general manager, who found that what Lei could do was actually

very important for the company. With Zhang’s permission, Wang opened a new position for

Lei. Lei then started to work as an associate manager in the R&D department of YICT in

2001.

Unlike jobs that only require entry-level certifiable qualifications, the R&D managerial

position in YICT needs outstanding, highly specialized knowledge, which allows the

manager to think ‘from the big picture’ and design creative development strategies. This

requirement is beyond certifiable qualifications measured by an educational degree or the

number of years of work experience. For this reason, generating a large pool of applicants

through formal recruitment channels would not necessarily bring in a right candidate.

However, through a third party’s recommendation, the employer can reach a promising

candidate directly.

The point one must bear in mind is that not all recommendations from the third party would

be equally effective. What types of references the employer relies on is determined by what

types of uncertifiable qualifications the employer is looking for. If the employer aims to find

new employees sharing similarities with the current employees, internal referrals would be

the most suitable way, as illustrated by the aforementioned cases of Scottish migrant workers

in Central England (Grieco 1987) and manufacturing workers in South Wales (Fevre 1989).

If the required uncertifiable qualifications are related to reliability or trustworthiness, a

recommendation from a reliable reference is needed. This corresponds to Jie’s case, in which

the security-guard leader extended his trust on his colleague – the repair team leader – to Jie,

the job applicant who was recommended by the repairmen leader. In Lei’s case, uncertifiable

qualifications desired by the employer are clearly focused on a candidate’s productivity and

creativity, which are not shown on the resume. Only because of this does a recommendation

from an expert in the same field matter.

75

Although an informal recommendation secured the first interview opportunity for Lei, it is

his own outstanding expertise, as shown in the screening process, which eventually won the

position for him. In this hiring process, informal recruitment and formal selection

complement each other, so that the right candidate can be singled out in the most efficient

way. On one hand, an informal recommendation reduces the employer’s recruitment costs to

a minimum. To achieve the same goal, a public, formal recruitment method, often involved

with disseminating a job post, generating a candidate pool, and then singling out potential

employees from the pool, would be far more expensive. On the other hand, a formal

interviewing process, which is focused on evaluating one’s certifiable qualifications, can also

verify the person’s uncertifiable qualifications recommended by an expert contact. As

aforementioned, in Lei’s case, uncertifiable qualifications – potential working abilities – are

built upon certifiable ones, so that it is reasonable to say that Lei’s uncertifiable

qualifications are the extension of his certifiable qualifications. Because of the inherent

correlation between uncertifiable and certifiable qualifications required by the employer,

informal and formal channels can serve a common goal, though they are used at separate

hiring stages.

3.9. Joint Use of Formal and Informal Strategies in Both Recruitment and Selection

Not all uncertifiable and certifiable qualifications are closely linked together, as they are in

Lei’s case. Very often, the employer needs to consider both types of qualifications in each of

the hiring stages. When it happens, the joint use of formal and informal job-person matching

methods takes place. In this section, I will use a case study to illustrate the most complicated

scenario in which formal and informal channels are jointly used in both hiring stages.

Mrs. Yun Chen, a 30-year-old office head working in a branch of Bank of China (BOC

hereafter) admitted that without informal help, she could not have entered the BOC in 2002.

Through a good friend’s husband, Yun managed to connect with a high-rank manager who

was affiliated with the hiring BOC branch. According to Yun, only because the high-ranking

contact put in a word for her could her application get attention from the recruiters. As she

said:

76

“There are so many applicants. Everyone holds a Bachelor’s or Master’s degree in

economics, finance, or other disciplines (that the bank would be interested in)… If

you want to make your resume stand out, you must have someone (important to the

bank) put in a word for you.”

Yun’s remarks have two implications. First, every applicant needs to hold “a Bachelor’s or

Master’s degree in economics, finance, or other disciplines,” in order to be eligible to apply

for the position in the bank. Second, holding a required degree does not necessarily mean that

the applicant fits the bank employer’s hiring expectations, since a reference’s

recommendation plays a crucial role for one to get through the first-round screening. This

implies that the bank employer considers both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications at

the recruitment stage. Certifiable qualifications – an educational degree in this case –

certainly determines whether or not one is eligible to apply for this position at BOC. Under

the premise that everyone who applied possesses certifiable qualifications desired by the

bank, the recruiters tried to narrow the candidate pool by using informal channels to screen

applicants’ uncertifiable qualifications. When asked why a reference was important for her

successful job application at the bank, Yun said:

“People (job seekers) have to understand that it’s not like if you are the best

candidate, you must be hired. Doesn’t work that way… It also depends on if you are

suitable for this position.”

In Yun’s opinion, a good contact provides rich information about an applicant’s suitability

for the job position, because a good contact knows what qualities the employer desires.

“I was told (by my reference) that the bank wouldn’t hire those who like to stand out,

because a bank doesn’t need this type of people. The work at a bank is not necessarily

challenging. So, he (my reference) recommended me as a good employee who is down

to earth and willing to do tedious work.”

Work in a bank is often “tedious” and not “challenging.” For this reason, a bank employer’s

ultimate concern is not an applicant’s meritocratic achievements, but his or her “down-to-

earth” work ethics and willingness to do long-term, tedious work. Those qualifications are

uncertifiable, and can hardly be evaluated reliably by formal means. A reference’s

77

recommendation thus becomes a relatively more effective way. Working closely with the

bank, Yun’s reference knew exactly what kind of recommendation he should put for Yun.

Furthermore, his high status made his recommendation reliable. It is reasonable for the

recruiters to believe that the applicant recommended by this prestigious internal reference is

well connected to the bank, and thus would be more committed to working there in a long

run.

After the recruitment stage, it took Yun one round of written test and two rounds of

interviews with different levels of bank mangers to get her job offer. However, Yun pointed

out that a reference also plays a role in the screening process.

“The whole process of interview and examination is very objective. The bank also

fears to recruit some very useless people, (who) would be very troublesome. After the

objective evaluation, they (the bank) would evaluate your guanxi [relations in

Chinese term] with the bank, by scaling your reference’s relationship (with the bank),

and the relationship between you and your reference. If you are far below the

qualifications, and your guanxi is just so-so, you must be screened out. If you yourself

are at the medium level (in terms of personal qualities), and your guanxi is strong –

for example, your parent or your direct relative works at the managerial level in one

of our branches – you must be screened in.”

Namely, the selection process in the bank is also a combination of formal and informal

strategies. While the written test and interview are direct evaluations of the candidate’s

professional knowledge – certifiable qualifications, the evaluation about the candidate’s

reference shows the importance of a candidate’s uncertifiable qualifications in the bank’s

hiring. The bank employer evaluates each candidate’s uncertifiable qualifications by ranking

the reference’s “guanxi” with the bank and the candidate’s “guanxi” with the reference. The

higher the reference’s status within the bank system, the stronger the guanxi between the

reference and the bank, and thus the more reliable the recommendation is about the

candidate’s uncertifiable qualifications. Meanwhile, the closer the guanxi between the

applicant and the reference, the better the reference knows the applicant, and thus the more

detailed information the internal recommendation contains about the candidate’s

uncertifiable qualifications. A hiring decision is eventually made based on an integrative

78

calculation of an applicant’s certifiable qualifications (shown through the objective score

during formal recruitment) and uncertifiable qualifications (evaluated through a guanxi-based

screening system).

Above all, my qualitative analysis demonstrates that the variation of job-person matching

patterns can be explained by the certifiability of job requirements that the employer is

focused on at the stages of recruitment and selection, respectively. My analysis shows that

the employers’ sole focus on certifiable qualifications will lead to the use of formal channels,

while their sole focus on uncertifiable qualification will lead to the use of informal channels,

throughout recruitment and selection stages. If both certifiable and uncertifiable

qualifications are expected in recruitment and/or selection, the joint use of formal and

informal hiring channels would occur in the corresponding stage. However, this is only a half

of the story. A job-person matching process involves both the employer’s hiring strategies

and the job seeker’s search behaviors. To verify the theoretical “job-person matching” model,

it is necessary to examine whether the certifiability of qualifications can also explain job

seeker’s search behaviors. Using the countrywide survey data, in the following section, I will

thus shift my focus from certifiability of qualifications expected by the employer to

certifiability of qualifications possessed by the job seeker.

3.10. How Does the Certifiability of Qualifications Determine One’s Search Behaviors?

Individual certifiable qualifications commonly include educational degrees, transcripts,

expertise certificates, and occupational licenses. For Chinese job seekers, however, an

additional type of certifiable qualification is membership in the Communist Party. Joining the

Party was once the symbol of one’s merits in the communist era. Although the ideological

importance of being a party member has faded since the socioeconomic transition started, the

importance of political credentials remains, particularly when it comes to positions that

exercise decision-making authority (Walder, Li, and Treiman 2000). Thus, party membership

still connotes desirable qualities in a job seeker, such as organizational and communication

skills, team spirit, and the capability to get things done, as Guo (2005) argued in his study on

the Party’s recruitment of college students in the last several decades. As for individual

79

uncertifiable qualifications, as shown in the above qualitative analysis, getting help from a

right contact enables the individual to demonstrate his or her suitability for the job position.

Based on the association between certifiability of qualifications and the use of job-person

matching channels shown as above, I hypothesize that:

An individual with high certifiable qualifications leans towards using formal job search

channels, while one with high uncertifiable qualifications leans towards using informal job

search channels. For those who possess both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications,

formal and informal job search channels are expected to be used jointly.

3.10.1. Data and Measurements

To demonstrate the above hypothesis, I used data drawn from the 2003 China General Social

Survey (CGSS) — the urban section, a four-stage stratified probability sampling survey on

the Chinese urban population. The sample consists of 5,894 adults, aged 18 to 69 years old,

who were randomly selected from 30 provincial-level locations. The dataset suits this study

well, because it includes retrospective information about how one got into his or her current

workplace and measures of one’s certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications at job entry.

Descriptive analysis of the quantitative data is shown in Appendix C.

Each respondent was asked to report all job search methods used. The options ‘replacing

parents(s)/ relatives,’ ‘recommendation from others,’ and ‘others offered a job without

asking’ were coded as informal channels, while all other options were coded as formal

channels, including: methods under the pre-reform job assignment system, such as ‘assigned

by the government or arranged by some official organization,’ and ‘internal recruitment in a

state-owned organization’; and methods used in the newly emerged labor market, such as

‘direct application,’ ‘employment services in the market,’ ‘human resources exchange

centre,’ ‘self-employed,’ and ‘job entry examination’. Based on all reported methods,

respondents’ job search behaviors were coded into three categories, namely, formal-informal-

joint channels, formal channels only, and informal channels only. To verify the information,

each respondent was also asked how they collected job information, and whether or not they

received help from someone else in the process of getting their current job. If a respondent

did not report any informal job search method in the first question, but reported using

80

informal connections for collecting job information and/or getting help from someone else

for job acquirement, this case would be recoded from “formal channels only” to “formal-

informal-joint channels.”

Certifiable qualifications, as aforementioned, include education (measured by years) and

party membership (with party members coded 1 and non-party members coded 0). As for

uncertifiable qualifications, I use the family status origin as the measure for two reasons.

Firstly, one’s personality, values, and habits, which are direct indicators of uncertifiable

qualifications, are determined by parental influence, to a great degree. On the other hand, the

quality of social resources one can access through family ties also varies with one’s status

origin. If one’s uncertifiable qualifications are explicated to the employer mainly through

informal channels, job seekers from low-status family backgrounds would bear more

challenges in meeting the employer’s expectations for uncertifiable qualifications, due to the

lack of high-quality contacts. This is particularly the case for individuals who entered the

labor market for the first time. Considering the patriarchal culture in the Chinese context, I

thus use the father’s education and party membership to measure one’s family status origin,

due to the absence of the father’s occupational status in the survey data. Another crucial

indicator of qualifications is one’s work experience. Under the assumption that an individual

accumulates both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications at work, I argue that one’s years

of work experience is the indicator of both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications. In

addition, gender, age, age square, and era of job entry are controlled.

3.10.2. Results

Results from multinomial regression models are shown in Table 8, with all possible

comparisons between the three types of job search methods presented. First, individuals who

possess the highest degree of certifiable qualifications are more likely to only use formal

channels. Years of education increase the likelihood of the use of “formal channels only”,

relative to “informal channels only” and the joint channel category. It also has a significantly

positive effect on the likelihood of using the joint channel category, relative to “informal

channels only”. Namely, as one’s education decreases, one’s preference of job search

methods moves from “formal channels only,” to “joints channels,” and then to “informal

channels only.” Similar to the effects of education, being a party member increases the

81

likelihood of the use of “formal channels only”, relative to “informal channels only.”

Although its effect is only marginally significant, party membership displays an impact in

favor of the joint channels versus “informal channels only”. Namely, for a party member, the

most preferred job search channels are “formal channels only,” followed by “joint channels,”

and then by “informal channels only.”

Second, “years of work experience” exerts significantly positive impacts on “informal

channels only” and “joint channels,” relative to “formal channels only.” However, one’s

work experience does not make a difference between one’s possibilities of using joint

channels and informal channels only. This finding suggests that individuals accumulate both

certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications at work, but work experience seems to benefit the

growth of uncertifiable qualifications more than that of certifiable ones. Consequently, work

experience leads one towards relying on informal channels more than formal channels in

one’s later job searches.

Third, one’s family status origin, closely associated with one’s uncertifiable qualifications,

presents a tendency of increasing the likelihood of the use of joint channels. Other covariates

being equal, every one-year increase in the father’s education increases one’s possibility of

using joint search channels by 21% (coef.=0.021; p=0.041), relative to that of using formal

channels only. Although marginally significant, the father’s party membership shows a

tendency of facilitating the use of joint channels, relative to using informal channels only

(coef.=0.214; p=0.087). Interestingly, one’s family status origin, the indicator of one’s

uncertifiable qualifications, does not show a positive impact on the likelihood of using

informal channels only, relative to formal channels only, since neither the father’s education

or the father’s party membership shows a significant coefficient in the first column of Table

8. Thus, the impacts of one’s family status origin support my argument. Namely, the positive

effect of social capital does not show when the informal channel is used alone, but shows in

the joint channel in which informal search methods are combined with formal search

methods.

In short, the above results show that: 1). certifiable qualifications indeed increase one’s

reliance on formal channels; 2). uncertifiable qualifications facilitate the use of informal

channels in the form of joint use, rather than the use of informal channels alone. As a result,

82

individuals with the highest degree of certifiable but low uncertifiable qualifications tend to

use formal channels only. Individuals with both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications

tend to use formal and informal channels jointly. Those with low certifiable qualifications

tend to use informal channels solely. However, this does not mean that they have a high level

of uncertifiable qualifications, because uncertifiable qualifications do not increase the

likelihood of using informal channels only, but that of using informal channels in a

combination with formal channels. This finding explains the existing literature in social

capital and job search. As Lin (1999) pointed out, the disadvantaged in the labor market are

observed to use informal job search the most, though they do not possess high-quality social

capital.

83

Table 8. Multinomial Logistic Regression on Job Applicants’ Search Behaviors, CGSS Urban Section, 2003

3.11. Conclusion and Discussion

From the perspective of certifiability of qualifications at the stages of recruitment and

selection, in this paper I first theorized four basic types of job-person matching patterns.

Namely, if the job requirements only involve certifiable qualifications, formal channels

would be solely used throughout the hiring process; on the contrary, for a position that only

requires uncertifiable qualifications, only informal channels would be used in a hiring

process. When both types of qualifications are required, formal and informal channels would

84

then be used jointly. I further extended the four basic types to a more realistic model, in

which certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications may co-exist within each hiring stage. Data

collected in the labor market of post-socialist China show that from either the employer’s

side or the job seeker’s side, formal and informal job-person matching channels can indeed

be used separately, but what occurs more frequently is the joint use of formal and informal

channels.

Returning to the questions raised at the beginning of this paper, my qualitative data show that

the employers seldom use informal hiring channels alone despite their advantages, because

for the majority of job positions, a certain degree of certifiable qualifications are always

required, which makes formal hiring channels unavoidable. On the other hand, my

quantitative data from the job seeker’s side confirm that uncertifiable qualifications facilitate

the use of informal job search channels in a joint form, rather than being used alone. This

explains why the disadvantaged in the labor market are observed to rely on informal channels

more than their competitive counterparts do. That is, their reliance on informal channels does

not necessarily imply high-quality contacts, but simply means that they have limited choices

for job search methods due to their disadvantages in certifiable qualifications.

Unlike the conventional measure of jobs in a socioeconomic sense, certifiability of

qualifications adopted in this study does not measure one’s job search success by salaries or

social status. Presumably, everyone chooses the best job that is available to them, which

means every acceptance of a job offer is the best outcome for this particular individual. By

using the measure of certifiability, this study evaluates job-person matching channels only by

matching success. This perspective is particularly important to address the long-lasting

causality issue in social capital studies. While it is practically infeasible to decouple the

effects of job search methods on job-attainment outcomes from those of individual

characteristics, it is effective to evaluate the likelihood of matching success that each job

search channel brings, as exemplified in this study. Thus, while the causal effects of contact

use on job search success is challenged by the “homophily” principle (Mouw 2003), a

perspective of job-person matching in terms of certifiability of qualifications provides solid

evidence of the positive impacts of contact use on matching success. Because certifiable and

uncertifiable qualifications are both required for the majority of job positions, job seekers

whose qualifications enable them to activate both search channels should have a better

85

chance to succeed. Indeed, their certifiable qualifications may not be at the top level, but are

sufficient to meet the employer’s requirements for the job position. Meanwhile, they are also

able to demonstrate their uncertifiable qualifications through informal channels. Therefore,

the use of contacts indeed plays a positive role in job-person matching, but very often in a

combination with the use of formal channels, instead of functioning alone. This study thus

sheds light on a new approach to address the causal effect of contact use on instrumental

activities, such as job search.

A caveat is that, as aforementioned, the labor market in the present Chinese society is

characterized by labor oversupply, especially the oversupply of university graduates. Under

this particular context, competition with respect to certifiable qualifications may be more

intense than that in a market where job positions outnumber applicants. This may be the

fundamental cause of the absence of a case in the Type II scenario— where only formal

channels are used in recruitment whereas only informal channels are used in selection— in

my qualitative analysis. Also, this fact may be related to the finding that uncertifiable

qualifications increases the likelihood of the use of joint channels, rather than using informal

channels alone, as shown in my quantitative analysis.

Despite that, the innovative perspective – certifiability of job requirements adopted in this

study has theoretical implications in the literature of job search studies. As I mentioned

before, the question facing current scholars is not “whether or not there is a causal effect of

contact use on labor market activities,” but “how the causal effect of contact use functions in

the empirical world.” The perspective of the certifiability of job requirements provides an

effective angle to address the “how” question. Driven by the certifiability of job

requirements, individuals mobilize either formal, or informal, or both job search channels to

match their qualifications to the employer’s expectations. To what extent contact use is

effective depends on the extent to which the employer values uncertifiable qualifications.

The fact that the employer often considers both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications for

a job position implies that informal channels should exert positive functions when used

jointly with formal channels, rather than being used alone. This study thus provides a new

approach to examine the causal effects of contact use on job search success, which I will

further explore in Chapter 4.

86

References

Alon, S. and Tienda, M. 2007. “Diversity, Opportunity, and the Shifting Meritocracy in Higher Education.” American Sociological Review 72(4): 487-511.

Bian, Y. 1997. “Bringing Strong Ties Back In: Indirect Connection, Bridges, and Job Search in China.” American Sociological Review 62(3): 266-85.

——. 2001. “Guanxi Capital and Social Eating: Theoretical Models and Empirical Analyses.” In N. Lin, K. Cook, and R. Burt (Eds.), Social Capital: Theory and Research (pp. 275-95). New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

——. 2002. “Institutional Holes and Job Mobility Processes in the PRC: Guanxi Mechanisms in Emergent Labor Markets.” In T. Gold, D. Guthrie, and D. Wank (Eds.), Social Connections in China: Institutions, Culture, and the Changing Nature of Guanxi (pp. 117-36). New York: Cambridge University Press.

Bian, Y. and S. Ang. 1997. “Guanxi Networks and Job Mobility in China and Singapore.” Social Forces 75 (3): 981-1005.

Bridges, W. P. and W. J. Villemez. 1986. “Informal Hiring and Income in the Labor market.” American Sociological Review 51:574-82.

Cai, F. and M. Wang. 2009. “Overview of the Unemployment Issue in China.” China Net. Retrieved from: http://www.china.com.cn/news/zhuanti/09rkld/2009-12/21/content_19105554.htm

De Graaf, N. D. & H. D. Flap. 1988. “’With a Little Help from My Friends’: Social Capital as an Explanation of Occupational Status and Income in the Netherlands, the United States and West Germany.” Social Forces 67(2): 452-72.

Erickson, B. H. 2001. “Good Networks and Good Jobs: The Value of Social Capital to Employers and Employees.” In N. Lin, R. S. Burt, & K. Cook (Eds.), Social Capital: Theory and Research (pp. 127-57). New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

——. 2004. “The Distribution of Gendered Social Capital in Canada.” In H. Flap & B. Volker (Eds.), Creation and Returns of Social Capital: A New Research Program (pp. 19-37). New York, NY: Routledge.

Fernandez, R. M., Castilla E., & Moore P. 2000. “Social Capital at Work: Networks and Employment at a Phone Center.” American Journal of Sociology 105: 1288-356.

Fernandez, R.M. & Weinberg N. 1997. “Sifting and Sorting: Personal Contacts and Hiring in a Retail Bank.” American Sociological Review 60(6): 883-902.

Fevre, R. 1989. “Informal Practices, Flexible Firms and Private Labour Markets.” Sociology 23(1): 91-109.

87

Flap, H. & E. Boxman. 1999. “Getting a Job as a Manager.” In T. Roger, A. J. Leenders & S. M. Gabbay (Eds.), Corporate Social Capital and Liability (pp.161-79). Boston: Kluwer.

Goodman, A., Blundell, R., Dearden, L., and Reed, H. 1997. Higher Education, Employment and Earnings in Britain. London: London Institute for Fiscal Studies.

Granovetter, M. S. 1973. “The Strength of Weak Ties.” American of Journal of Sociology 78(6): 1360-80.

——. 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

——. 1995. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers (2nd ed). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Grieco, M. 1987. Keeping It in the Family: Social Networks and Employment Chance. London and New York: Tavistock Publications.

Guo, G. 2005. “Party Recruitment of College Students in China.” Journal of Contemporary China 14(43): 371-93.

Habich, R. 1984. “Berufliche Plazierung.” In W. Glatzer and W. Zapf (Eds.), Lebensqualitat in der Bunderepublik (pp. 343-65). Frankfurt: Campus Verlag.

Jenkins, R. 1984. “Acceptability, Suitability, and the Search for the Habituated Worker: How Ethnic Minorities and Women Lose Out.” International Journal of Social Economics 11(7): 64-76.

Jewson, N. & Mason, D. 1986. “Modes of Discrimination in the Recruitment Process: formalisation, Fairness and Efficiency.” Sociology 20(1): 43-63.

Lin, N. 1999. “Social Networks and Status Attainment.” Annual Review of Sociology 25: 467-87.

Lin, N. & Dumin M. 1986. “Access to Occupations through Social Ties.” Social Networks 8: 365-86.

Machin, S. 1999. “Wage Inequality in the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s.” In R. Dickens, P. Gregg, and J. Wadsworth (Eds.), The Labour Market under New Labour (pp. 185-205). Manchester: Manchester University Press.

Maguire, M. 1986. “Recruiting as a Means of Control.” In K. Purcell (Ed.), The Changing Experience of Employment: Restructuring and Recession (pp. 58-78). London: Macmillan.

Manwaring, T. 1984. “The Extended Internal Labour Market.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 8: 161-87.

Marsden, P. V. 1994a. “The Hiring Process: Recruitment Methods.” The American Behavioral Scientist 37(7): 979-91.

88

——. 1994b. “Selection Methods in US Establishments.” Acta Sociologica 51: 281-301.

Marsden, P. V. & Campbell K. E. 1990. “Recruitment and Selection Processes: The Organizational Side of Job Searches.” In R. L. Breiger (Ed.), Social Mobility and Social Structure (pp.59-79). Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

Marsden, P. V. and J. S. Hurlbert. 1988. “Social Resources and Mobility Outcomes: A Replication and Extension.” Social Forces 66(4):1038-59.

Marsden, P. V. and Hurlbert J. S. 1988. “Social Resources and Mobility Outcomes: A Replication and Extension.” Social Forces 66(4): 1038-59.

McDonald, S. and G. H. Elder. 2006. “When Does Social Capital Matter? Non-Searching for Jobs Across the Life Course.” Social Forces 85 (1): 521-49.

Mincer, J. 1958. “Investment in Human Capital and Personal Income Distribution.” Journal of Political Economy 66: 281-302.

Mouw, T. 2003. “Social Capital and Finding a Job: Do Contacts Matter?” American Sociological Review 68(6): 868-98.

Oi, J. C. & Walder A. (Eds.) 1999. Property Rights and Economic Reform in China. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

Petersen, T., Saporta, I. & Seidel, M. L. 2000. “Offering a Job: Meritocracy and Social Networks.” American Journal of Sociology 106(3): 763-816.

Rees, A. 1966. “Information Networks in Labor Markets.” American Economic Review 56(2): 559-66.

Themelis, S. 2008. “Meritocracy through Education and Social Mobility in Post-war Britain: A Critical Examination.” British Journal of Sociology of Education 29(5): 427-38.

Volker, B. & Flap, H. 1999. “Getting Ahead in the GDR: Social Capital and Status Attainment under Communism.” Acta Sociologica 42(1): 17-34.

Walder, A. G., Li, B. & Treiman D. 2000. “Politics and Life Chances in a State Socialist Regime: Dual Career Paths into the Urban Chinese Elite, 1949 to 1996.” American Sociological Review 65(2): 191-209.

Weber, Max. (2011[1949]). Methodology of Social Sciences. Translated and edited by Edward A. Shils and Heny A. Finch. With a new introduction by Robert J. Antonio and Alan Sica. Rutgers: The State University of New Jersey, New Jersey.

Wegener, B. 1991. “Job Mobility and Social Ties: Social Resources, Prior Job, and Status Attainment.” American Sociological Review 56(1): 60-71.

Zhou, X. 2000. “Economic Transformation and Income Inequality in Urban China.” American Journal of Sociology 105 (4): 1135-74.

89

Chapter 4 When Does Contact Use Matter? The Joint Use of Formal and Informal Channels and Job Search Success

4.1. Introduction

An ongoing debate, centered on the roles the use of social contacts plays in job search

success, has stimulated studies at two opposite sides. On one hand, following Granovetter’s

(1973, 1974) pioneering study on how information flows through weak ties during a job

search process, scholars further extended their investigations about the advantages of contact

use to job search outcomes. Positive effects of contact use are thus shown on successful job

attainment and subsequent outcomes, such as income and occupational prestige (Bian 1997;

Erickson 2001, 2004; Lin 1982; Lin and Dumin 1986; Lin, Vaughn, and Ensel 1981;

Marsden and Hurlbert 1988). On the other hand, those positive effects of contact use are

found to be inconsistent, particularly when other factors, such as gender, race, and education,

are taken into account (Bridges and Villemez 1986; Corcoran, Datcher, and Duncan 1980;

Holzer 1987; Korenman and Turner 1996; Marsden and Gorman 2001; Staiger 1990).

Faced with this dilemma, in Chapter 3 of this dissertation, I pointed out that the positive

effects of contact use may be contingent on the employer’s hiring expectations. From the

perspective of the certifiability of job requirements, I articulated that employers’ hiring

expectations vary from certifiable qualifications (such as diplomas, degrees, certificates, or

licenses) to uncertifiable qualifications (such as loyalty, work ethics, career ambition,

enthusiasm, and personality). While formal procedures are often used if certifiable

qualifications are the focus of the job, informal procedures tend to be more effective and

efficient when uncertifiable qualifications are the focus of the job. Because the majority of

job positions require both certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications, the employer often

combines formal and informal methods in a hiring process. Consequently, job seekers who

can mobilize both formal and informal channels to match the employer’s hiring strategies are

more likely to succeed in their job searches. For most jobs, successful candidates’ “certifiable

qualifications may not be at the top level, but are sufficient to meet the employer’s

requirements for the job position. Meanwhile, they are also able to demonstrate their

uncertifiable qualifications through informal channels.” (see Chapter 3: 90)

90

If individuals who mobilize both formal and informal job search channels, rather than who

rely on either formal or informal channels only, are more likely to succeed in job search, a

naturally derived proposition from the use-of-joint-channel argument would be: the joint use

of formal and informal job search channels is more advantageous than the use of either

formal or informal channels alone.

Using data drawn from the 2003 China General Social Survey (CGSS hereafter), this current

chapter thus aims to empirically demonstrate the proposition about the advantages of using

formal and informal job search channels jointly. The context of the newly emerged labor

market of China provides an excellent setting for this study. As I articulated in Chapter 2,

state power and market strength have been co-strengthened during the gradual process in

which China’s employment system shifted from a state-controlled job assignment program to

a free labor market. Corresponding to this institutional change, individuals not only pursued

certifiable qualifications (such as education and political credentials), but also continuously

mobilized informal ties to demonstrate uncertifiable qualifications. Formal and informal job

search behaviors seem to be combined together naturally in the transitional context of China.

In the following parts of this chapter, I will first point out the necessity of examining the

effects of contact use in combination with formal job search methods. I will then hypothesize

advantages of the joint use of formal and informal channels in the context of China’s labor

market. I will categorize all observed job search methods into three channels, namely, the

joint channel, formal channel only, and informal channel only. The purpose of this chapter is

to demonstrate that the optimal job search outcome is achieved through the joint use of

formal and informal job search methods, instead of using either the formal or informal

channel alone. I will compare outcomes led by three types of job search channels both during

the job search process and after job attainment. Although my argument, to some extent, may

be due to the characteristics of the Chinese labor market, my study shows the necessity of

understanding the roles that contact use plays beyond a conventional formal-vs.-informal job

search dichotomy.

91

4.2. Formal versus Informal Job Search: The Mismatch between Theoretical Dichotomization and Empirical Non-Separation

Granovetter’s (1973) seminal study on the “strength of weak ties” stimulated sociologists’

long-lasting interest in job-person matching, a topic that was traditionally studied only by

economists. Since then, numerous studies (Bian 1997; Bian and Ang 1997; Bridges and

Villemez 1986; De Graaf and Flap 1988; Fernandez, Castilla, and Moore 2000; Fernandez

and Weinberg 1997; Lin et al. 1981; Marsden and Hurlbert 1988; Marsden and Gorman

2001; Wegener 1991) have contributed in highlighting the significant roles social relations

play in economic activities, by contrasting informal job search methods with formal methods.

However, strong counterevidence on the positive effects of contact use on job search cannot

be denied, either (Bridges and Villemez 1986; Corcoran, Datcher, and Duncan 1980; Holzer

1987; Korenman and Turner 1996; Marsden and Gorman 2001; Mouw 2003; Staiger 1990).

By taking a close look at the existing literature, I found a within-group difference among

contact users. For example, De Graaf and Flap’s (1988) comparative study about West

Germany, the Netherlands, and the United States, and Volker and Flap’s (1999) follow-up

study on job search behaviors in the German Democratic Republic both found that formal

and informal job search methods do not show significant differences in influence on prestige

of obtained jobs. The use of high-status contacts has a significant effect on job prestige only

when the comparison is made among job seekers who all used informal methods. In other

words, a significant difference does not exist between job seekers who used and who did not

use contacts, but among those who all used contacts to some degree.

Indeed, most scholars who confirmed positive effects of contact use on job search outcomes

did not base their conclusions on a comparison between respondents who used informal job

search methods and their counterparts who used formal methods. A common strategy is to

distinguish the strengths of ties used in job search. Focusing on the respondents who found

jobs through family members, relatives, friends, acquaintances, and any other types of

informal relations, Lin and Dumin (1986) reported that getting help from a contact with

higher social status (normally accessed through weak relations) leads a job seeker to a better

job than getting help from strongly-tied contacts, such as family members and relatives. In

92

his study on the German labor market, Wegerner (1991) considered the interaction effect of

social status and tie strength only within the group in which respondents all used informal

contacts. His finding— weak ties are more effective for lower-status individuals to “reach

up,” while people in the upper class would rely on strong ties to exclude themselves from the

rest of the society— did not concern the advantages of contact use relative to other formal

job search methods, either. Similarly, using data drawn from a survey in Tianjin, Bian (1997)

argued for a positive influence of using strong ties on obtained job prestige. It is noticeable

that instead of using the whole sample, Bian (1997) used 45% of the sample, in which

respondents all used some kind of contacts during job search. In short, instead of

demonstrating the advantages of contact use over formal job search methods, the existing

studies convincingly demonstrate that there is a within-group variation among contact users

in terms of the impact of contact use on job search outcomes.

The within-group differences among contact users may be understood from the essential

characteristic of social capital – homophily. The principle of homophily, also known as the

‘like-me’ hypothesis, means that social interactions tend to take place among individuals

with similar socioeconomic characteristics, implying a positive relationship between

individuals with similar socioeconomic statuses and the amount of interactions they have

(Lin 2001:40). Because of this, “it is not the use of contacts per se, but the quality and

quantity of the social resources that are accessed through using contacts that matters.”

(Mouw 2003: 869; see also Lin 1999: 481) If the quality of contact use is positively

associated with one’s own characteristics, it is reasonable to infer that contact use may be

effective only for those who possess desirable formal (or certifiable) qualifications, as Lin

(2001) stated in his social-resource theory. For this reason, it is not only possible, but also

necessary to consider the positive effects of contact use in combination with formal job

search methods, rather than from a formal-vs.-informal-search dichotomous approach.

4.3. Hypotheses: Advantages of Formal-Informal-Joint Job Search Channels

Due to the existence of a within-group difference among contact users, in this section I will

hypothesize that this difference is between individuals who use formal and informal job

search methods jointly and their counterparts who rely exclusively on informal channels.

93

According to Lin’s (1999:31) summary, the use of social contacts exerts positive impacts on

one’s job search, in terms of: 1). facilitating the flow of information (Granovetter 1973,

1974; Lin and Dumin 1986; Marsden and Hurlbert 1988); 2). exerting influence on the

employer’s decision-making process (Bian 1997; Bian and Ang 1997; Volker and Flap

1999); 3). providing social credentials to an individual (Fernandez, Castilla, and Moore 2000;

Fernandez and Weinberg 1997); and 4). reinforcing the individual identifying and

recognizing him- or herself as a member of the work organization (Fernandez et al. 2000).

While the first two advantages occur during a job search process, the other two happen after

one gets a job.

By distinguishing individuals who use formal and informal channels jointly from those who

rely solely on informal methods, I argue that the existing notions about the advantages of

contact use can be altered by adding one condition; namely, the use of contacts in

combination with formal job search methods. In terms of the role of contact use in facilitating

information flow (Granovetter 1973, 1974), I thus hypothesize that:

Hypothesis 1: The joint use of formal and informal channels broadens one’s search

coverage. Namely, other characteristics being equal, individuals who jointly use formal and

informal job search methods are likely to access more job information, and thus apply for

more job positions than their counterparts who use only formal or informal methods during

job search.

In Chapter 2, I have pointed out that while urban Chinese citizens continuously sought state-

assigned job opportunities, they have unintentionally become market-oriented. Namely, a

rational job seeker would not limit him- or herself only to the job assignment system, but

instead, maximize his or her employment chance by looking for jobs broadly. My hypothesis

emphasizes that job seekers who use formal and informal methods jointly have a significant

advantage in accessing job information. The verification of this hypothesis will demonstrate

that Granovetter’s (1973, 1974) argument about the role of contact use as a conveyor of

information is valid not only in a developed market economy (such as the United States), but

also in a transitional economy (such as China).

Certainly, searching broadly does not necessarily mean an advantage, unless a broad search

enhances one’s search efficiency by matching a job with one’s reservation wage in a

94

reasonable time period. This relates another advantage of contact use in terms of influencing

the employer’s decision-making process. If job seekers who use formal and informal search

channels jointly are more likely to influence the employer’s decision-making process

positively, I hypothesize that:

Hypothesis 2: The joint use of formal and informal channels shortens one’s search duration.

Namely, other characteristics being equal, individuals who use formal and informal channels

jointly are more likely to successfully exit job search in a reasonable time period than their

counterparts who use only formal or informal methods during job search.

Whether or not one finds a job within a certain time period has commonly been used as one

of the essential measures of job search success (Brasher and Chen 1999; Rosenfeld 1975).

“Typically, a somewhat arbitrary cut-off time for finding a job is chosen, such as one month

after being laid off another job (e.g. Kanfer and Hulin 1985) or whether students have found

a job by graduation.” (Brasher and Chen 1999: 58) Within the context of the dominance of

the state-controlled job assignment system in China till 2003, however, in this study I used a

three-month time span as the threshold, based on the average time length required for getting

a state-assigned job28. Namely, my hypothesis about job search duration is that: Other

characteristics being equal, individuals who use formal and informal channels jointly are

more likely to succeed in job search within a three-month time period than their counterparts

who use either formal or informal methods only.

As for the advantages of contact use after job attainment, although Lin (1999) did not include

income into his aforementioned summary about functions of contact use, existing studies

usually focus on income, since it is the most straightforward indicator of how well a job

seeker matches with a position. The majority of studies reviewed by Granovetter (1995),

Marsden and Gorman (2001), and Mouw (2003) do not show significant effects of contact

use on wages (Bridges and Villemez 1986; Campbell and Rosenfeld 1985; De Graf and Flap

1988; Elliot 1999; Marsden and Hurlbert 1988; Volker and Flap 1999). One possible

explanation is that entry-level wages used in those studies might not reflect economic returns

28 Getting an assigned job was usually slower than finding a job through the labor market. Normally, the bureaucratic procedure would take about three months (Chan, Ngok, and Phillips 2008).

95

to the job search channel entirely, because not only the absolute amount but also the growth

rate of entry-level wages matters (Corcoran et al. 1980; Simon and Warner 1992). For this

reason, the most recent wage should be a better indicator than the entry-level wage to capture

individuals’ career success. If the joint use of formal and informal job search methods leads

to a better job-person match, I hypothesize that:

Hypothesis 3: Other characteristics being equal, the joint use of formal and informal job

search methods leads to a better economic return at the recent stage than the use of either

formal or informal job search methods alone.

This is because one’s job entry casts a time-lagged effect on late-stage career success, which

cannot be seen from entry-level income (Brown et al. 2006; Warren et al. 2002). This is

particularly true in the Chinese context. Drawing data from an urban household survey in

1999, Knight and Yueh (2004) found that while mobility among rural-urban migrants was

extraordinarily high, mobility among urban Chinese workers was negligible. At least before

2000, the majority of urban workers “had lifetime employment with their work unit so that

any improvements in the matching of workers and jobs occurred only within the work unit.”

(Knight and Yueh 2004:658) Job entry thus plays a determinant role in one’s career success.

However, as Zhou, Tuma, and Moen (1997) specifically pointed out in their study on job

shift patterns in urban China from 1949 to 1994, the entry-level income could not reflect

economic gains embedded in a job position, especially in the state sector. Only after latent

benefits in the state sector (such as housing and health care29) were marketized and counted

into one’s income from 1999 onwards, has income become comparable between the state and

private sectors. Thus, at least for the 2003 CGSS data that cover job entries from the 1940s to

2003, income in the year of 200230 provides more reliable information to compare career

success across sectors, relative to entry-level income collected across decades in the last

29 A significant reform of the housing policy is represented by the issue of “Regulations on the Management of the Housing Provident Fund” in 1999 (available via http://www.people.com.cn/GB/shizheng/19/20020328/697118.html). Since then, public housing has officially begun to be marketized and the Housing Provident Fund is included as part of state employees’ annual income. The significant step of marketizing health care took place early this century (see Song’s 2010 review).

30 Cases of job entries in 2003 were dropped from corresponding analyses due to the lack of income information.

96

century. In addition, by using income in the most recent year available in the dataset, one can

avoid adjusting for differences caused by over-time inflation and policy changes.

4.4. Data, Measurements, and Methods

4.4.1. Generation of Three Job Search Channels

As aforementioned, to demonstrate the above hypotheses, I used data drawn from the 2003

CGSS. The dataset serves this study well, because it includes retrospective information about

respondents’ career paths up to the most recent year. Each respondent was asked to report all

methods he or she tried in order to get into the current workplace. The options “replacing

parents(s)/ relatives,” “recommendation from others,” and “others offered a job without

asking” were coded as informal channels, while the others were coded as formal channels,

including “assigned by the government or arranged by some official organization,” “internal

recruitment in a state-owned organization,” “direct application,” “employment services in the

market,” “human resources exchange centre,” “self-employed,” and “job entry

examination.”31 I need to point out that in order to draw a boundary between “informal” and

”formal” methods, in this study I do not further distinguish different formal methods. Thus,

both the state-controlled hiring system and regular methods used in the labor market are

categorized into the “formal job search” channel.

Based on all methods reported by each respondent, three job search channels were generated.

If all reported methods belong to the formal channel, this corresponding respondent would

fall into the “formal channels only” category. Likewise, the category of “informal channels

only” refers to respondents who only used informal job search methods. If the reported

options include both formal and informal job search methods, this corresponding respondent

would be coded as a “formal-informal-joint-channel” user. To verify the information, each

respondent was asked again in the later part of the questionnaire about how they collected job

information, and whether or not they received help from someone else in the process of

getting their current jobs. If a respondent did not report any informal job search method in

31

Formal channels include the state-controlled job assignment system and regular hiring procedures in the labor market. More detailed information about the differences between those two can be seen in Chapter Two about China’s employment system change from the 1970s to 2003.

97

the earlier questions, but later reported using informal connections for collecting job

information and/or getting help from someone else for job acquirement, this case would be

recoded from “formal channels only” to “formal-informal joint channels.” As Table 9

presents, 21% of the respondents reported using formal and informal channels jointly in their

job searches, while 62% and 17% of the respondents reported using formal and informal

channels only, respectively. This distribution shows that while 62% of the respondents only

used some kind of formal job search channels, the other 38% more or less relied on informal

channels to get into their current workplaces. This distribution is in line with the fact that the

majority of urban Chinese citizens got jobs exclusively through the state-assignment system

before 2003, as demonstrated in Chapter Two about China’s employment system from the

end of the 1970s to early this century.

4.4.2. Dependent Variables and Other Independent Variables

The first dependent variable is the number of jobs one actively applied for before obtaining

an offer from the current workplace (0= did not apply for any job; 1=1 job; 2= 2 jobs; 3= 3

jobs; and 4= 4 jobs or more). Table 5 shows that 84.66% of the respondents did not apply for

jobs, but instead got assigned jobs. 6.26% of the sample applied for one job, 3.89% applied

for two jobs, 2.52% applied for three jobs, and 2.67% applied for four jobs or more. I must

emphasize that respondents applying for zero jobs might still have mobilized job search

strategies. As Bian (1997) pointed out in his study about job search behaviors within the job

assignment system, individuals did not just passively wait for assigned jobs; very often, they

mobilized all kind of informal ties in order to be assigned in good positions. In other words,

applying for zero jobs does not indicate the absence of a job search strategy. I also want to

point out that the generally non-intensive job search phenomenon needs to be understood

within the context of China’s employment system change from the 1970s to 2003, during

which the state-controlled job assignment never lost its popularity. Urban Chinese citizens’

persistent preference towards state-assigned jobs prevented them from actively searching for

jobs in the labor market in the last century. As I pointed out in Chapter 2, however,

individuals had to increase job search intensity due to the increasingly scarce assigned jobs.

In other words, an individual’s job search intensity is not entirely determined by his or her

own willingness, but, to a great extent, is determined by the historic stage in which a job-

person matching process occurs. It would be impossible before the 1980s and unlikely in the

98

1980s for an individual to get a “good,” legal job outside the job assignment system. It

became necessary for an individual to actively search for jobs in the 1990s, and since then

job search intensity has continuously increased. Because of this, the zero-inflated negative

binominal regression was adopted to address the excessive zero issue of the sample

distribution. I will elaborate on this reason in the methods section.

The second dependent variable is job search duration (1= got a job within a three-month

duration; 0= did not get a job within a three-month duration). 43% of the respondents got into

their current workplaces within three months, while 57% failed to do so. The last dependent

variable is logged annual income in the year of 2002. After a logarithmic transformation, the

distribution of logged annual income in 2002 is approximately normal with a mean value of

7.73 and standard deviation of 3.19.

In addition to the three types of job search channels, other independent variables are coded as

follows. Education was coded by years. In addition to education, for Chinese job seekers, an

additional source of formal resources lies in membership in the Communist Party. Joining the

Party was once the symbol of one’s merits in the communist era; and still connotes desirable

qualities in a job seeker in the post-communist era, such as organizational and

communication skills, team spirit, and the capability to get things done (Guo 2005). Finally,

family status origin was measured by the father’s highest education and party membership32.

Control variables include: age (coded by years) and its squared form, gender (1= female;

0=male), and era of job entry (1= entered the current workplace before 1979; 2= entered the

current workplace between 1979 and 1992; and 3= entered the current workplace after

199233). In addition, for models about the job search process, I controlled over one’s work

32 Father’s socioeconomic status is supposedly the ideal measure of one’s family background in a patriarchal society. However, information about the father’s occupational characteristics is ambiguous in the original questionnaire. The only available information about the type of the father’s workplace (state sector vs. private sector) cannot be used, unfortunately, due to a large portion of missing values. Information about the father’s education and party membership is much more reliable. Moreover, these two variables are directly associated with one’s socioeconomic status under the pre-reform communist regime. It is thus justifiable to use the father’s education and party membership characteristics as measures of one’s family background. 33 The rationale of this categorization is in line with three stages of the socioeconomic transformation in China. Usually, the year of 1979 is considered the beginning of the reform, while the year of 1992 indicates that the reform reached a new stage, where the socialist system had begun a fundamental change. More details can be seen in Chapter 2 of this dissertation.

99

experience prior to entering the current workplace (coded by years) and its squared form. For

models on the recent income attainment, I instead controlled over the type34 of one’s

workplace (0= state-owned enterprises (SOEs hereafter); 1= governmental, public, and party

organizations; 2= collective organizations; 3= private firms; and 4= others), one’s current

position (1= managerial position; 0= worker position), and one’s total years of work

experience up to 2002 and its squared form. Descriptive analyses of the above variables are

presented in Table 9.

Other independent variables include education (coded by years), party membership (1= party

members; 0=non-party members), family background (measured by the father’s highest

education and party membership), era of job entry (1= entered the current workplace before

1979; 2= entered the current workplace between 1979 and 1992; and 3= entered the current

workplace after 199235), female (1= female; 0=male), age (coded by years) and the square of

age. In addition, for models about the job search process, I controlled over one’s work

experience prior to entering the current workplace (coded by years) and its squared form. For

models on income, I instead controlled over the type of one’s workplace (0= state-owned

enterprises (SOEs); 1= governmental, public, and party organizations; 2= collective

organizations; 3= private firms; and 4= others), one’s current position (1= managerial

position; 0= worker position), and one’s total work experience up to 2002 (coded by years)

and its squared form. Descriptive analyses of the above variables are presented in Table 5.

34 Due to the co-existence of state power and the market economy, there have been distinctively different types of workplaces in the Chinese labor market. State-owned enterprises include those work organizations in manufacturing, processing and other production firms, and those in service sectors that are directly owned by the central or various levels of local governments. The category of governmental, public and party organizations includes not only ministries, commissions, bureaus and offices at various levels of the Communist Party and central and local governments, but also nonprofit organizations in the public domain. Collective enterprises are often sponsored by local governments (such as district/county government or residential offices). Despite its public ownership, this type of organization has the least redistributive benefits, so is also less regulated by the government than state-owned enterprises. The type of private firms includes private entrepreneurs, firms with mixed property rights, and foreign investment firms. 35 The rationale of this categorization is in line with three stages of the socioeconomic transformation in China. Usually, the year of 1979 is considered the beginning of the reform, while the year of 1992 indicates that the reform reached a new stage, where the socialist system had begun a fundamental change. More details can be seen in my paper (2012b) on China’s employment system change up to 2003.

100

Table 9. Descriptive Statistics of Dependent and Independent Variables Used in Chapter 4, CGSS 2003, Urban Section

101

4.4.3. Methods

Zero-inflated Negative Binomial Regression was adopted to estimate the likelihood of the

number of positions one applied for prior to job entry. As aforementioned, an excessive zero

– almost 85% of the respondents did not apply for any job – is not because available jobs

outnumber applicants so that job search is not necessary; instead, this is mainly due to the

institutional constraint within the job assignment system. Namely, non-search behavior is

inflated by the historic stages of the job assignment system. In Table 6, I thus used the

variable “era of job entry” to indicate the institutional constraint that inflates the proportion

of applying for zero jobs. Following the convention in previous studies, Binary Logistic

Regression was used to estimate one’s likelihood of getting a job within a three-month time

period. Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) and Endogenous Switching Regression (ESR) models

were used to estimate one’s long-term career success, indicated by the most recent income. In

the following part of this section, I will explain the use of the ESR model in detail.

As aforementioned, based on the homophily characteristic of social capital, I inferred that

contact use exerts positive effects in combination with formal job search methods, instead of

being used alone. However, this by no means implies that an individual with an advantageous

status, equipped with both formal and informal resources, must use formal and informal

channels jointly for job search. An individual’s decision on which job search channel to use

102

is based on what career path he or she desires and how intensively he or she searches for

jobs. It is entirely possible that one who is able to use the joint channel actively chooses to

use a type of single channel, if one perceives using a type of single channel as a less costly

way for achieving one’s desired career path. When an individual who is capable of using the

joint channel chooses to use a type of single channel, the returns to his or her job search

behavior are expected to be different from the average returns to this kind of job search

behavior, because he or she possesses qualities essentially different from the typical qualities

attached to this kind of job search behavior. In this case, one’s job search outcomes are not

equivalent to the effects of the job search channel, but reflect the interaction between one’s

qualities and this job search channel. When this interaction occurs, the estimation of the

effect of the job search channel based on the observed job search outcome would be

confounded by the effect of the individual’s qualities. In other words, one’s selection on the

use of the job search channel, namely, the selection effect, could bias the estimation of the

effect of the job search channel, based on the observed job search outcome.

Therefore, I must emphasize the distinction between effects caused by job search channels

per se from those caused by individuals who used different types of job search channels. In

an ideal36 situation, three types of job search channels are used by three distinctive groups of

job seekers, respectively; and each of the group of job seekers uses only one type of job

search channel. Each ideal type of the job search channel is not equivalent to the

corresponding group observed in the empirical data, since the “ideal” type is predicted across

the population without the disturbance of a self-selection effect. For example, ideal joint-

channel users are not equivalent to respondents who reported using joint channels in the

dataset; instead, they refer to part of the population with typical characteristics of joint-

channel users. This group may not be observed in the data, because it is a predicted outcome

at the population level under the assumption of random selection. The same interpretation is

also applied to the ideal formal-channel-only users and ideal informal-channel-only users.

The observed differences in job search outcomes reflect the disparities among different types

of job search channels, only when three observed groups of job seekers are equivalent to

36 The explanation about “ideal” can be seen in Chapter 3.

103

three ideal groups, respectively. However, this is not always the case. The fact that ideal

joint-channel users share characteristics with both ideal contact users and formal-channel

users implies that their job search choices are full of self selection. In other words, while

some individuals who possess both formal and informal resources indeed use the joint

channel, it is completely possible for some others with both types of resources to use either

the formal channel or the informal channel only, since they are able to do so. When

individuals who are ideal joint-channel users actively choose to use a type of single job

search channel, the observed search outcome would not be caused only by the effect of the

job search channel, but by a co-determination of job seekers’ characteristics and the chosen

type of job search channel.

To reveal the effect caused by a type of job search channel itself, thus, it is necessary to

decouple the difference caused by the use of the type of job search channel from that caused

by job seekers’ characteristics. The ESR model thus provides a powerful solution in this

regard. According to Gamoran and Mare (1989), Gerber (2000), and Mare and Winship

(1988), the rationale of the ESR model is to estimate the pure effect of a dichotomous

variable – often called treatment variable – by controlling over the difference due to

individuals’ active selection. In this study, the treatment variable is whether or not a job

seeker uses the joint job search channel, if one considers “using the joint channel” one

outcome and “not using the joint channel” the other. “Not using the joint channel” means the

use of either of the two types of the single channel – the formal channel only or the informal

channel only. Presumably, the “formal channel only” and the “informal channel only” are

two ends of the spectrum of individual job search behaviors, meaning that individuals who

only use the formal channel possess characteristics complementary to those of individuals

who only use the informal channel. For this reason, the ideal formal-channel-only users

would not have a possibility to fall into the category of the “informal channel only,” because

they do not possess any characteristic of being ideal “informal-channel-only” users. Vice

versa, the ideal informal-channel-only users would not have a possibility to fall into the

category of the “formal channel only,” either. Therefore, it is theoretically incorrect to

assume that an individual’s selection could vary between the “formal channel only” and the

“informal channel only” options. In addition, because two possibilities – the “formal channel

only” and the “informal channel only” – cannot occur simultaneously, the choices facing

104

ideal joint-channel users consist of two sets of options; namely, using the joint channel

relative to using the formal channel only, or using the joint channel relative to using the

informal channel only. Therefore, it is also theoretically incorrect to assume that an ideal

joint-channel user would be faced with three options simultaneously.

Based on the above theoretical concerns, I modeled the ideal joint-channel users’ potential

choices between the joint channel and the “formal channel only,” and between the joint

channel and the “informal channel only,” separately. I also excluded the possibility of the

interchange between the “formal channel only” and the “informal channel only.” To estimate

the ideal joint-channel users’ selection between the joint channel and either type of the single

channels, the ESR model consists of three equations – two outcome equations and one

selection equation. Assuming the sampled respondents were selected from two separate

populations – ideal joint-channel users (population 1) and ideal formal (or informal)-channel

users (population 2), job-attainment outcome, i.e., income, can be estimated using the

following outcome equations:

��� = ∑ ������� + �� (1)

��� = ∑ ������� + �� (2)

For each individual i, the estimated income (��) is composed of the intercept (���), all effects

of this individual’s measurable characteristics (��� �� + ��� ���+ ⋯ + ��� ��), and the error

term (�). In different populations, the same measurable characteristic � exerts its impact

differently; namely, ��� differs from ���. Within each population, with each measurable

characteristic is fixed to its average value �, the average effect of each type of job search

channel on the outcome variable is:

�� = ∑ ������ + � (3)

�� = ∑ ������ + � (4)

By calculating �� − ��, one can thus see the real difference caused by using different types of

job search channels, under the assumption that equation (3) only captures individuals in

population 1 while equation (4) only captures individuals in population 2. This is the

105

assumption when OLS regression is used to predict the effects of job search channels.

However, this assumption does not always hold, because the boundary between joint-channel

users and single-channel users is not necessarily clear. For individuals who possess both

formal and informal resources, they could choose either to use or not to use the joint channel.

One can assume that there is a latent score, z, which reflects both the effects of measurable

factors and an individual’s calculation about potential economic return to each type of job

search channel.

�� = ∑ �� �� + ����� + ����� + ��� (5)

For an ideal joint-channel user �, if �� > 0, then this individual would use the joint channel

(�� = 1); if �� < 0, then he or she would choose to one type of single channel (�� = 2). By

plugging in equations (1) and (2), one can simplify equation (5) as:

�� = ∑ �� �� + �� (6)

where �� = ��"+ ����#

+ $� and %= ���%

+ ���%+ ��.

Based on the above selection equation, if an individual who possesses both formal and

informal resources perceives achieving the optimal job search outcome in using one type of

single channel, he or she would be more likely to choose a type of single channel over the

joint channel. In this case, this individual would be observed in the group of single-channel

users, though he or she possesses typical characteristics of joint-channel users; namely, a

self-selection effect occurs. With the existence of self selection, the effects of types of job

search channels cannot be simply calculated in equations (3) and (4), because ��� can only

be used for individuals who possess typical characteristics in population 1, while ��� can

only be used for those who possess typical characteristics in population 2. Using the

mathematic language, a self-selection effect means that the error term ( ) in the selection

equation (equation 6) is endogenous to the error terms (�and�) in the outcome equations;

namely, &'()�, + = ,� ≠ 0, and/or &'()�, + = ,� ≠ 0.

A more straightforward understanding of ,� and ,� is based on estimations on the outcome

variable. For example, in an ESR model using a treatment variable with two options – the

106

joint channel and the formal channel only, one can consider the ESR model estimating the

outcome variable – income – twice for each of the two options. One estimation is based on

the observed data, while the other is based on a predicted population consisting of ideal joint-

channel users who only use the joint channel and ideal formal-channel users who only use

the formal channel. A significant self-selection effect occurs when two estimations are

significantly different. In an ESR model, Ρ37 is used to denote: 1) whether or not there is a

significant self-selection effect in each group; 2) the degree and direction of the self selection

at the population level, if it does exist. The “+” sign indicates a positive selection effect in ρ1,

while it indicates a negative selection effect in ρ2. In the example of the ideal joint-channel

users in population 1 and the ideal formal-channel-only users in population 2, a significantly

positive ρ1 means that part of the observed advantage of using the joint channel is caused by

individual characteristics, so the effect of the joint channel is overestimated. A significantly

positive ρ2 would then mean that the observed advantage of using the joint channel shows

only a part of the effect resulting from the ideal joint channel, so the effect of the ideal joint

channel is underestimated. On the contrary, the “-” sign indicates a negative selection effect

in ρ1, while it indicates a positive selection effect in ρ2. Still, in the example of the ideal joint-

channel users in population 1, and the ideal formal-channel-only users in population 2, a

significantly negative ρ1 means that the observed advantage of using the joint channel is only

a part of the advantage caused by the ideal joint channel, so the effect of the ideal joint

channel is underestimated. A significantly negative ρ2 means that part of the observed

advantage of using the joint channel is caused by individual characteristics, so the effect of

the joint channel is overestimated. More explanations about ρ1 and ρ2 can be seen in

Gamoran and Mare’s (1989) study on the track effects on college students’ school

performance.

4.5. Advantages of the Use of the Joint Channel during Job Search

I started my analysis with the advantages of the joint channel during job search. As indicated

by the number of positions one applied for, the amount of job information conveyed by

37 To make the interpretation convenient, the correlations between σ13 and σ1, and between σ23 and σ2, rather than σ13 and σ23 themselves, are reported. namely, ρ1=σ13/σ1, and ρ2=σ23/σ2.

107

different types of job search channels is estimated in Table 10. Other characteristics being

equal, individuals who only used the formal channel on average applied for jobs 65% (=(1-e-

1.055)*100%) less than their counterparts who used formal and informal channels jointly. The

coefficient of the ‘informal only channel’ is negative, suggesting the trend of one applying

for less jobs in this channel relative to the joint channel, though this trend is not statistically

significant. Also, noticeably, one’s education and the father’s education exert positive

impacts on the number of jobs one applied for, whereas one’s party membership and the

father’s party membership play negative roles in the number of jobs one applied for, with

other covariates controlled. I want to emphasize that era of job entry indeed causes an

inflated zero. As the ‘inflate’ column shows, compared to the pre-reform stage, the first stage

of the reform decreases the probability of an inflated zero by 38% (=(1-e-0.48)*100%), while

the second stage of the reform decreases the probability of an inflated zero by 81% (=(1-e-

1.64)*100%). Namely, as the substitution of the labor market for the job assignment system

proceeded, applying for zero jobs is increasingly less likely because one did not need to

search for jobs. With the issue of an excessive zero taken into account, among three types of

channels, the use of the formal channel leads to significantly less job information than that of

either the joint channel or informal channel. This is because the majority of respondents who

used formal search methods only in the 2003 CGSS are those who solely relied on the state’s

assignment. They usually got only one assigned option at one time. Under the “mutual

selection” principle, theoretically, one could have got a second assignment if the first

assigned job did not match one’s expectations. As the number of assigned positions kept

decreasing, however, one might accept whichever job was assigned to him or her, because a

second round of assignment would be unlikely.

108

Table 10. Zero-Inflated Negative Binomial Regression of the Number of Positions One Applied for Prior to Job Entry

Coef. Inflate Job search channels (ref: Joint channel) Formal channel only -1.055 ***

(0.097) Informal channel only -0.030

(0.081) Age 0.034

(0.035) Age square -0.001

(0.001) Female -0.075

(0.064) Education (in years) 0.057 ***

(0.013) Party membership -0.299 *

(0.129) Father's highest education 0.028 ***

(0.009) Father’s party membership -0.131 +

(0.072) Previous work experience 0.000

(0.015) Previous work experience square 0.000

(0.001) Job entry era (ref: before 1979) The first reforming stage (between 1979 and 1992) -0.480 **

(0.153) The second reforming stage (after 1992) -1.644 ***

(0.147) Constant -0.439 1.910 ***

(0.468) (0.152) Observations 4,847 lnalpha -2.154 ** N_zero 4106 vuong 6.345 *** Chi2 test of alpha=0 2.91 * Log likelihood -2860.455

Note: Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.001, ** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

I then turned to the effects of three types of job search channels on job search duration. Using

a three-month time span as the threshold, Table 11 shows that the use of the joint channel is

more likely to help one successfully exit job search within three months. Other characteristics

being equal, the chance for an individual who used the “formal channel only” to successfully

109

get a job within three months is equal to 20% (=e-1.609) of the likelihood of one who used the

joint channel. If one only used the informal channel, his or her chance of getting a job within

three months is 47% (=e-0.76) of that of an individual who used the joint channel. Namely,

individuals who used the joint channel are most likely to successfully exit job search within

three months, followed by those who used the informal channel only, and then by those who

used the formal channel only38.

Above all, I examined two aspects of a job search process. In terms of the number of

positions one applied for prior to job entry, individuals using the formal channel only applied

for significantly less positions than their counterparts using either the joint channel or the

informal channel only, because most of the formal-channel-only user relied on the job

assignment system and did not actively apply for jobs. In terms of the search duration,

significant differences exist between the three types of channels. Individuals who used the

formal channel only are least likely to exit job search successfully within three months, while

those who used the joint channel are most likely to do so. Putting results from Tables 10 and

11 together, the use of the joint channel has an advantage over the use of the formal channel

in term of job information, and an advantage over both the use of the formal channel and the

informal channel regarding job search duration. Thus, during a job search process, the joint

use of formal and informal search channel is the most efficient among three types of job

search channels, since it leads to both more job information and shorter search duration.

38 The difference between “formal channels only” and “informal channels only” is also significant (coef.= -0.712; p=0.000).

110

4.6. Advantages of the Use of the Joint Channel on Recent Income

4.6.1. OLS Estimations and Implications

I first estimated one’s economic gains in the year of 2002 using the OLS method. The results

presented in Table 8 do not show a significantly positive effect of the use of the joint channel

on income. First, the Baseline model shows that individuals who got jobs only through the

informal channel indeed earn significantly less than their counterparts who got jobs through

Table 11.

111

the formal-informal-joint channel, other characteristics being equal. However, there is no

significant difference detected in income between individuals who used the formal channel

only and those who used the joint channel, shown as the non-significant coefficient for the

group of the “formal channel only” (relative to the reference group of the “joint channel”).

Second, in the Interaction model, I controlled over the interaction between type of job search

channel and type of workplace. This is because, as aforementioned, the job-assignment

system pervasive in the state sector in the last century is completely different from job search

methods usually used in the free labor market. Which type of workplace one desires to enter

may thus influence which type of job search channel one decides to use. The Interaction

model shows that after the interaction effects were controlled, the type of job search channel

does not show any significant effect by itself. However, the significant interaction terms

show that other covariates being equal: 1) The logged income of individuals who entered

governmental, public, and party organizations only through the informal channel is 0.833

units lower than that of individuals who entered state-owned enterprises through the joint

channel, and 0.167 (=0.666-0.833) units lower than that of their counterparts who entered

governmental, public, and party organizations through the joint channel. Also, 2) individuals

who entered private firms only through the informal channel earn significantly less (coef.= -

0.826) than those who used the joint channel to enter either state-owned enterprises or private

firms.

The OLS results in Table 12 do not show robust evidence of significant effects of different

types of job search channels on recent income. However, the Interaction model shows that

the economic return to a type of job search channel varies with the type of workplace. Thus,

if an individual desires to enter a certain type of workplace, he or she may use the type of job

search channel that can lead to the best economic return in the corresponding type of

workplace, though this person’s characteristics may match another type of job-search-

channel user well. This Interaction model thus suggests the possibility of the existence of job

seekers’ self selection.

By using the term ‘self selection’, I refer to the phenomenon in which an individual’s

behavior is not in line with the statistical estimation based on a randomized sample with

characteristics identical to this individual’s. This concept is particularly useful in job search

studies, because one’s job search strategies are not only predicted by one’s measurable

112

characteristics, but are also determined by less obvious factors, such as one’s career

ambition, or perception of his or her ideal job. For example, an individual who could have

used both the formal and informal search methods to obtain a high-pay job in the market may

choose to solely pursue a state assigned job, due to the social values in favor of the job

assignment system over the labor market. It is also possible for this individual to choose to

solely rely on the informal channel, if he or she desires a “relaxing” rather than high-pay job,

and thus perceives that relying on the informal channel is an easy way out.

I must point out that, by exploring the interaction between type of job search channel and

type of workplace, I by no means imply that the type of workplace is the only possible reason

for self selection to occur, though job seekers’ preferences towards certain types of

workplaces indeed shape their search behaviors to a great extent, shown in Chapter Two of

this dissertation. In this analysis, however, my purpose is not to exhaust the reasons of the

occurrence of self selection, but to reveal the real effect of the job search channel without the

disturbance of a self-selection effect.

As aforementioned, using the ESR model, I mainly tested if there is a significant tendency

for ideal joint-channel users to actively select using either the formal channel only or the

informal channel only, since ideal joint-channel users presumably have the capacity to use

either of the two types of single channels. I excluded the possibility about the interchange

between two types of single job search channels. This is because the ideal formal-channel-

only users do not possess characteristics that enable them to use the informal channel only;

and vice versa, the ideal informal-channel-only users do not possess characteristics that

enable them to use the formal channel only.

113

Table 12. OLS Regression of Logged Annual Income in 2002, Urban China

114

4.6.2. The Joint Channel versus the Formal Channel Only

I first tested the potential interchange between the joint channel and the formal channel only.

According to the ESR formulas presented in the “Methods” section, one’s selection on the

type of job search channel is co-influenced by one’s measurable characteristics and

perception of the optimal job search outcome. An individual who possesses qualities of using

the joint channel may not necessarily use the joint channel, if he or she does not desire the

search outcomes obtained by using the joint channel. A selection effect would occur, when

individuals with the characteristics of the joint-channel users actively choose not to use the

joint channel. To detect this selection effect, I constructed the ESR model as follows. First,

assuming that one’s obtained job-related characteristics reflect one’s desired career path, I

used all job-related characteristics as both the factors of one’s recent income attainment and

proxies of one’s perception of the optimal job search outcome. Namely, job-related

characteristics were included not only in outcome equations, but also in the selection

equation. Second, family status origin has a direct impact on one’s choice of the type of job

search channel, but has only an indirect impact on one’s recent income attainment, as

demonstrated by Blau and Duncan’s (1967) study on the American occupational structure.

Thus, family background was only included in the selection equation, but not in the outcome

equations. Finally, one’s measureable characteristics influence both the choice of the type of

job search channel and recent income, and thus were included in both the selection equation

and two outcome equations.

With the above variables taken into account, Table 13 estimates if the income difference

between observed joint-channel users and formal-channel-only users is only caused by the

use of different types of job search channels. In Table 9, a significantly negative ρ1 indicates

115

a negative self selection effect existing in the population of ideal joint-channel users,

meaning that there is a significant tendency for individuals with typical characteristics of

joint-channel users to purposely choose to use the formal channel only during job search. On

the other hand, a non-significant ρ2 suggests that individuals with typical characteristics of

formal-channel-only users did indeed choose to only use the formal channel for job search.

This confirms my aforementioned inference; that is, the ideal formal-channel-only users do

not possess characteristics for them to switch into another type of job search channel.

Because of the existence of a significant self-selection effect among ideal joint-channel users,

the observed income difference between two categories of the treatment variable is not equal

to the difference between the effect of using the joint channel and that of using the formal

channel only. The significant self-selection effect occurring among ideal joint-channel users

must be singled out, so as to reveal the real difference caused by the use of different types of

job search channels per se. To do so, I followed the decomposition method used by Gamoran

and Mare (1989) and Gerber (2000). The key formulas are presented in the Appendix D, and

more details about decomposition of group differences in ESR estimations are explained in

details by Gamoran and Mare (1989: 1178-80).

Table 14 presents the decomposition of the expected logged income based on estimations in

Table 9. As Panel A – “difference caused by the type of job search channel” shows, the

predicted income is significantly higher in the joint-channel group, relative to that of using

the formal channel only (13.01 vs. 8.29), when the self-selection effect is excluded. This is

the income gap caused by the use of different types of job search channels. It supports my

argument that the use of the joint channel leads to higher income return than the use of the

formal channel only.

Panel B shows “selection effects.” Predictions based on non-significant σ23 were italicized to

indicate non-significant selection effects. Predictions based on significant σ13 show that the

average logged recent income among observed joint-channel users is 5.04 units lower than

what is expected in the population of ideal joint-channel users, when individuals who possess

typical characteristics of joint-channel users had all used the joint channel (5.04= 13.01-

7.97). This means that there is a significant tendency for job seekers who possess typical

characteristics of joint-channel users to actively select themselves out of the group of the

116

joint channel, and instead choose to use the formal channel only. Thus, when the observed

group of formal-channel-only users was hypothetically switched into the opposite position –

using the joint channel, the estimated average logged income is 6.4 units higher than what is

expected for ideal formal-channel-only users in a hypothetical scenario of using the joint

channel (6.4=14.69-8.29).

Panel C shows the “total expected logged income.” The income difference between observed

joint-channel users and formal-channel-only users is 7.97 vs. 8.41, though the latter was

predicted based on non-significant σ23. This explains the OLS results in Table 12, where the

coefficients of “formal channel only” (versus the “joint channel”) are positive but non-

significant in both the Baseline and Interaction models.

In short, under the random-assignment condition, in which the predicted outcome difference

between joint-channel users and formal-channel-only users can be completely attributed to

the difference between the use of the joint channel and the formal channel only, the use of the

joint channel itself indeed leads to significantly higher income than that of the formal channel

only, as shown in Panel A of Table 14. In reality, however, there is a significant trend, which

is that individuals who possess characteristics of typical joint-channel users actively chose to

use the formal channel only to find jobs. As a result, the estimation based on the empirical

data is significantly different from the estimation based on the same data under the

randomization condition. Because of the significant selection effect in favor of only using the

formal channel among individuals with typical characteristics of joint-channel users, the

predicted income, based on the empirical data, is significantly lower in the joint-channel

group while significantly higher in the formal-channel-only group, compared to the predicted

income in the corresponding group, based on the same data under the randomization

condition. The advantage of using the joint channel in income attainment is thus shown only

after the significant self-selection effect among individuals with typical characteristics of

joint-channel users is taken into account.

117

Table 13. Endogenous Switching Regression of Logged Annual Income in 2002 between the Joint Channel and the Formal Channel Only

118

Table 14. Decomposition of Expected Logged Income between the Use of the Joint Channel and the Formal Channel Only, Predicted Based on Table 13

4.6.3. The Joint Channel versus the Informal Channel Only

I subsequently examined if there is also a possibility to switch between the use of the joint

channel and the informal channel only. Unlike the previous model, where I used the “formal

channel only” as the baseline group, in this model I used the group of the “joint channel” as

the baseline group, as shown in Table 15, to exclude the possibility that the significant

existence of the self-selection effect is caused by the positions of two types of job search

channels in model estimation. Using the “joint channel” as the baseline group, Table 15

shows that ρ2 is significantly positive, which again indicates the existence of a negative self-

selection in the population of ideal joint-channel users. Namely, there is indeed a significant

119

tendency for ideal joint-channel users to actively select themselves out of the joint channel,

and instead choose to use the informal channel only.

Table 16 presents the decomposition of the expected logged income based on estimations in

Table 15. Panel A – “difference caused by the type of job search channel” clearly shows that

the use of the joint channel leads to significantly higher income than that of the “informal

channel only” (10.35 vs. 7.49). In Panel B – “selection effects,” predictions based on non-

significant σ13 were italicized to indicate non-significant select effects. Predictions based on

significant σ23 show that the observed average logged income among joint-channel users

(with the occurrence of self selection) is 2.47 units lower than what is expected in the

population of ideal joint-channel users, when individuals who possess typical characteristics

of joint-channel users had all used the joint channel (2.47= 10.35-7.88). This means that there

is a significant tendency for ideal joint-channel users to actively choose to use the informal

channel only. Thus, when the observed group of informal-channel-only users was

hypothetically switched into the opposite position – using the joint channel, the estimated

average logged income is 5.38 units higher than what is expected for ideal informal-channel-

only users in a hypothetical scenario of using the joint channel (5.38=12.87-7.49). In Panel C

– “total expected logged income,” the observed difference in income attainment between

informal-channel-only users and joint-channel users is 7.38 vs. 7.88, though the former was

predicted based on non-significant σ13. This explains the OLS results in Table 12, where the

coefficients of the “informal channel only” (versus “joint channel”) are negative in both the

Baseline and Interaction models.

Again, under the random-assignment condition, in which the predicted outcome difference

between joint-channel users and informal-channel-only users can be completely attributed to

the difference between the use of the joint channel and the informal channel only, the use of

the joint channel itself indeed leads to significantly higher income, as shown in Panel A of

Table 15. However, a significant selection effect means that individuals who possess

characteristics of typical joint-channel users actively chose to use the informal channel only

to find jobs. Because of this, the predicted income, based on the empirical data, is

significantly lower in the joint-channel group while significantly higher in the formal-

channel-only group, compared to the predicted income in the corresponding group based on

the same data under the randomization condition. By controlling the significant self-selection

120

effect among individuals with typical characteristics of joint-channel users, the use of the

joint channel is indeed more advantageous regarding recent income attainment, compared to

the use of the informal channel only.

By putting together results from Tables 9 to 12, Hypothesis 3 – the use of the joint channel

leads to higher recent income than the use of either the “formal channel only” or “informal

channel only” – is supported. The reason that the advantage of using the joint channel cannot

be observed in OLS models (as shown in Table 12) is because individuals who are typical

joint-channel users have a tendency to actively choose to use either the formal or informal

channel only. This causes an underestimation of the effect of the use of the joint channel.

With the self-selection effect excluded – meaning that individuals possessing typical

characteristics of joint-channel users indeed use the joint channel to get jobs, the use of the

joint channel displays a significantly higher income return than that of either the formal or

informal channel only.

121

Table 15. Endogenous Switching Regression of Logged Annual Income in 2002 between Joint-Channel Users and Informal-Channel-Only Users

122

Table 16. Decomposition of Expected Logged Income between the Use of the Joint Channel and the Informal Channel Only, Predicted Based on Table 15

4.7. Conclusion and Discussion

In Chapter 3, I have demonstrated that a combination of formal and informal methods is

adopted most frequently in a job-person matching process, from both the employer’s and the

job seeker’s perspective. An argument naturally derived from this framework of the

“combined use of formal and informal job-person matching methods” is that the combined

use of formal and informal methods is more advantageous than the use of either the formal or

informal methods alone.

This current chapter thus aims to demonstrate the advantages of the joint use of formal and

informal methods from the job seeker’s side. My analyses based on the 2003 CGSS data

show that individuals who used formal and informal search methods jointly indeed tend to

obtain more job information and apply for more jobs than their counterparts who only used

the formal channel. The joint channel users are also more likely to exit job search

123

successfully within three months, compared to both formal-channel-only and informal-

channel-only users. Overall, thus, the joint channel is the most advantageous among three

types of job search channels during a job search process, since it allows job seekers to access

more job information and at the same time exit job search successfully within a reasonable

duration.

I also examined the effect of the joint channel on one’s late-state career success, indicated by

the most recent income. The OLS results failed to reveal the economic advantages of the use

of the joint channel over the other two types of single channels. However, after controlling

over significant self-selection effects among individuals with typical characteristics of joint-

channel users, the ESR models show that the use of the joint channel indeed leads to

significantly higher income than the use of either the formal or informal channel only. This

advantage is underestimated in OLS models, because individuals with typical joint-channel-

user characteristics tend to actively choose to use either of the two types of single channels.

This seemingly ironic phenomenon may be understood from two aspects. First, one needs to

keep in mind that the focus in this study is long-term, rather than short-term, career success.

Mobilizing both formal and informal resources to search jobs in the joint channel is more

costly than using a single type of channel, for which only one type of resources is mobilized.

One would be motivated to use the joint channel only when its use generates greater returns

than the use of a type of single channel does. However, at the entry level, tangible returns

tend to be similar across different types of job search channels (as shown in existing studies

about the non-significant effect of contact use on entry-level wages), which may mislead an

individual to choose a relatively less costly type of job search channel if one fails to foresee

the long-term benefits of using the joint channel. Second, the co-development of state power

and a market economy in China’s transitional context may also shape individuals’ job search

behaviors. Particularly, driven by their persistent preference towards state-assigned jobs,

individuals may choose to get an assigned job through the formal channel only, instead of

mobilizing multiple job search methods to seek a job with the highest pay in the market.

Consequently, the observed income cannot be solely predicted by which job search channel

was used, because to what extent the use of a certain job search channel pays off depends on

who uses it. With the significant self-selection effect excluded, decomposition results based

124

on the ESR estimations show that the expected average income resulting from the joint

channel itself is significantly higher than that in either the formal or informal channel alone.

Overall, thus, considering both the job search process and long-term career development, the

use of the formal-and-informal joint channel – instead of either the formal or informal

channel only – pays off. This study provides a theoretical alternative corresponding to the

currently unsolved debate on the causal effects of contact use on one’s job search. While the

use of social contacts is demonstrated to play positive roles in facilitating one’s job search

success, critiques questioned the causal chain between contact use and job search outcomes

based on the homophily characteristic of social capital. My study shows that because of the

homophily principle, the positive effects of contact use should be seen in combination with

formal job search methods, rather than when social contacts are used alone. My analysis,

focused on the measures during a job search process as well as after job attainment, clearly

shows that the use of the informal channel alone does not benefit one’s job search. Instead,

one achieves the optimal job-search outcomes when contact use is jointly used with formal

job search methods. It may be safe to say that social capital exerts positive effects, not

despite its homophily characteristic, but exactly because of the homophily principle. My

argument of the joint use of the formal and informal job search methods thus provides a new

perspective to further explore the causal effects of social capital in future studies.

A caveat that one needs to bear in mind is that effects of different types of job search

channels may vary with institutional contexts, as Granovetter (1995) pointed out. The

Chinese labor market has long been characterized as a labor-oversupply market. Particularly,

the oversupply of highly-educated job seekers might have raised the formal-qualification

entry bar for the majority of job positions, which I have discussed in details in Chapter 2.

Although the phenomenon of the joint use of the formal and informal job search methods

may be, to some extent, attributed to the contextual characteristic of the Chinese labor

market, this study has a general theoretical implication by illustrating an alternative

perspective to understand how social capital functions in instrumental activities, such as job

search. Namely, contact use pays off not through the informal channel alone, but by

embedding the use of social contacts in the process of mobilizing formal job search methods.

By distinguishing individuals who use contacts jointly with formal job search methods from

those who only rely on contact use, this study inspires future research to examine

125

“homophily” as the theoretical foundation, rather than the counterevidence, of the causal

effects of contact use on instrumental activities.

126

References

Alon, S. and Tienda, M. 2007. “Diversity, Opportunity, and the Shifting Meritocracy in Higher Education.” American Sociological Review, 72(4), 487-511.

Bandura, A. 2001. “Social Cognitive Theory: An Agentic Perspective.” Annual Review of Psychology 52: 1–26.

Barron, John M., Mark C. Berger, and Dan A. Black. 1997. “How Well Do We Measure Training?” Journal of Labor Economics 15(3): 507-28.

Bartus, Tam-s. 2001. “Social Capital and Earnings Inequalities.” Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of Groningen, Groningen, The Netherlands: (www.ub.rug.nl/eldoc/dis/ppsw/t.bartus).

Bell, N. E. and B. M. Staw. 1989. “People as Sculptors versus Sculpture: The Role of Personality and Personal Control in Organizations.” Pp. 232-51 in The Handbook of Career Theory, ed. by M. B. Arthur, D. T. Hall, and B. S. Lawrence. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

Bian, Yanjie. 1997. Bringing Strong Ties Back In: Indirect Connection, Bridges, and Job Search in China, American Sociological Review. 62: 266-85.

Bian, Yanjie and Soon Ang. 1997. “Guanxi Networks and Job Mobility in China and Singapore.” Social Forces. 75:981-1006.

Blau, Peter M., and Otis Dudley Duncan (with the collaboration of Andrea Tyree). 1967. The American Occupational Structure. New York Wiley.

Brown, Douglas J., Richard T. Cober, Kevin Kane, Paul E. Levy, and Jarrett Shalhoop. 2006. “Proactive Personality and the Successful Job Search: A Field Investigation with College Graduates.” Journal of Applied Psychology 91(3): 717-26.

Boxman, Ed A. W., De Graaf Paul M., and Flap Hendrik D. 1991. “The Impact of Social and Human Capital on the Income Attainment of Dutch Managers.” Social Networks 13: 51-73.

Brasher, Eric E., and Peter Y. Chen. 1999. “Evaluation of Success Criteria in Job Search: A Process Perspective.” Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology 72: 57-70.

Bridges, William P., and Wayne J. Villemez. 1986. “Informal Hiring and Income in the Labor market.” American Sociological Review 51:574-82.

Campbell, Karen, and Rachel Rosenfeld. 1985. “Job Search and Job Mobility: Sex and Race Differences.” Research in the Sociology of Work 3: 147-74.

Corcoran, M., L. Datcher and G. J. Duncan. 1980. “Information and Influence Networks in Labor Markets.” Pp. 1-37 in Five Thousand American Families—Patterns of Economic Progress, Vol VIII, ed. by G. J. Duncan and J. N. Morgan. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

127

De Graaf, Nan Dirk, and Hendrik D. Flap. 1988. “’With a Little Help from My Friends’: Social Capital as an Explanation of Occupational Status and Income in the Netherlands, the United States and West Germany.” Social Forces 67:452-72.

Devine, Theresa and Nicholas Kiefer. 1991. Empirical Labor Economics: The Search Approach. New York: Oxford University Press.

Elliot, James. 1999. “Social Isolation and Labor Market Insulation: Network and Neighborhood Effects on Less-Educated Urban Workers.” Sociological Quarterly 40: 199-216.

Erickson, Bonnie. 2001. “Good Networks and Good Jobs: The Value of Social Capital to Employers and Employees.” Pp. 127-57 in Social Capital: Theory and Research, (eds.) Nan Lin, Ronald S. Burt, and Karen Cook. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

——. 2004. “The Distribution of Gendered Social Capital in Canada.” Pp. 27-50 in Creation and Returns of Social Capital, (eds.) Henk Flap and Beate Volker. London and New York: Routledge.

Gamoran, Adam and Robert D. Mare. 1989. “Secondary School Tracking and Educational Inequality: Compensation, Reinforcement, or Neutrality?” The American Journal of Sociology 94(5): 1146-83.

Gerber, Theodore P. 2000. “Membership Benefits or Selection Effects? Why Former Communist Party Members Do Better in Post-Soviet Russia.” Social Science Research 29:25-50.

Granovetter, Mark S. 1973. “The Strength of Weak Ties.” American of Journal of Sociology 78: 1360-80.

——. 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

——. 1995. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers, 2nd ed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Holzer, Harry J. 1987. “Hiring Procedures in the Firm: Their Economic Determinants and Outcomes.” Pp. 243-72 in Human Resources and Firm Performance. Madison, WI: Industrial Relations Research Association.

Judge, T. A. R. D. Bretz, D. J. Kennedy, and M. C. Bloom. 1996. “People as Sculptors vs. Sculpture: Test of a Dispositional Model of Career Success.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Academy of Management, Cincinnati, OH.

Kaas, Leo, and Stefan Zink. 2011. “Human Capital Investment with Competitive Labor Search.” European Economic Review Vol. 55 (4): 520-34.

Kanfer, Ruth, and Charles L. Hulin. 1985. “Individual Differences in Successful Job Searches Following Lay-Off.” Personnel Psychology 38(4): 835-47.

128

Knight, John, and Linda Yueh. 2004. “Job Mobility of Residents and Migrants in Urban China.” Journal of Comparative Economics 32: 637-60.

Korenman, Sanders and Susan C. Turner. 1996. “Employment Contacts and Minority-White Wage differences.” Industrial Relations 35: 106-22.

Lin, Nan. 1982. “Social Resources and Instrumental Action.” Pp. 131-45 in Social Structure and Network Analysis, edited by Peter V. Marsden and Nan Lin. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.

Lin, Nan. 1999. “Social Networks and Status Attainment.” Annual Review of Sociology 25: 467-87.

——. 2001. Social Capital: A Theory of Social Structure and Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Lin, Nan and Dan Ao. 2008. “The Invisible Hand of Social Capital: An Exploratory Study.” Pp. 107-132 in Social Capital: An International Research Program, edited by Nan Lin and Bonnie H. Erickson. New York: Oxford University Press.

Lin, Nan and Mary Dumin. 1986. “Access to Occupations Through Social Ties.” Social Networks 8:365-85.

Lin, Nan, John C. Vaughn, and Walter Ensel. 1981. “Social Resources and Occupational Status Attainment.” Social Forces 59:1163-81.

Mare, R. D., and Winship, C.. 1988. “Endogenous Switching Regression Models for the Causes and Effects of Discrete Variables.” Pp. 132-60 in Common Problems/Proper Solutions: Avoiding Error in Quantitative Research, ed. by J. S. Long. Sage: Newbury Park.

Marsden, Peter V., and Elizabeth H. Gorman. 2001. “Social Networks, Job Changes and Recruitment.” Pp. 467-502 in Sourcebook of Labor Markets: Evolving Structures and Processes, edited by Ivar Berg and Arne L. Kalleberg. New York: Plenum Press.

Marsden, Peter V. and Jeanne S. Hurlbert. 1988. “Social Resources and Mobility Outcomes: A Replication and Extension.” Social Forces 66(4):1038-59.

McDonald, S. and G. H. Elder. 2006. “When Does Social Capital Matter? Non-Searching for Jobs Across the Life Course.” Social Forces Vol. 85 (1), 521-49.

Mouw, Ted. 2003. “Social Capital and Finding a Job: Do Contacts Matter?” American Sociological Review 68, 6: 868-98.

Rosenfeld, Carl. 1975. “Jobseeking Methods Used by American Workers.” Monthly Labor Review (pre-1986) 98:39-42.

Simon, C. J., and J. T. Warner. 1992. “Matchmaker, Matchmaker: The Effect of Old Boy Networks on Job Match Quality, Earnings, and Tenure.” Journal of Labor Economics 10:306-29.

129

Song, Xiaowu. 2010. “A Historic Review on the Construction and Development of the Health Care System in China.” Review of China’s Health Care Reform, January 20. Available via: http://www.chinareform.net/2010/0225/12911.html.

Staiger, Doug. 1990. The Effect of Connections on the Wages and Mobility of Young Workers. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

The author. 2012. “Individuals Matter: A Constructive Interpretation of China’s Employment System Change until 2003.” Working paper.

Volker, Beate and Henk Flap. 1999. “Getting Ahead in the GDR: Social Capital and Status Attainment under Communism.” Acta Sociologica 42(1):17-34.

Warren, John Robert, Jennifer T. Sheridan, and Robert M. Hauser. 2002. “Occupational Stratification across the Life Course: Evidence from the Wisconsin Longitudinal Study.” American Sociological Review 67(3): 432-55.

Wegener, B. 1991. “Job Mobility and Social Ties: Social Resources, Prior Job, and Status Attainment.” American Sociological Review 56(1): 60-71.

Zhou, Xueguang, Nancy Brandon Tuma, and Phyllis Moen. 1997. “Institutional Change and Job-shift patterns in Urban China, 1949 to 1994.” American Sociological Review 62(3):339-365.

130

Chapter 5 Conclusion and Discussion

5.1. Overview of the Dissertation

Within the context of China’s employment system change until 2003, this dissertation

systematically investigated the application of social capital in employment activities, by

focusing on its institutional constraints, working mechanisms, and advantages.

I first explained the pervasive existence of contact use in urban China by tracing its

institutional origin. By understanding institutional change from the constructive perspective,

individuals’ job search behaviors are not just directed by the state’s changing employment

policies, but are one of the driving forces that have impacted the trajectory of China’s

employment system change. In the first paper, I discussed individual coping strategies for job

search success from three aspects. As I demonstrated, guanxi manipulation (mainly through

family ties) persists across pre- and post-reform eras. However, since the start of the

employment system change, the mobilization of guanxi has increasingly been accompanied

by one’s formal qualifications. Corresponding to new meritocratic requirements in the job

assignment system, individuals pursued education actively. When educational degree itself is

not sufficient to get an assigned job due to the declination of the job assignment system,

individuals sought party membership to supplement their educational qualifications. The fact

that individuals’ reliance on contact use is accompanied by their active investment in

education and political resources lends legitimacy to my following studies, in which I

examined the use of contacts in combination with formal channels to employment.

From the perspective of certifiability of qualifications at the stages of recruitment and

selection, in the second paper I theorized a new approach to examining the use of social

capital in employment activities. Based on the variation of certifiability of required

qualifications for a job position, I categorized four basic types of job-person matching

patterns and their extensions. I found that certifiable and uncertifiable qualifications are both

required by the majority of job positions. For this reason, the employer’s hiring strategies

often display as a certain combination of formal and informal channels. Consequently, at the

job applicant’s side, those who are able to mobilize both formal and informal job search

methods to match up with the employer’s hiring expectations are presumably more likely to

succeed in the labor market. An essential message from this paper is that contact use indeed

131

plays a positive role in job-person matching, but very often in combination with the use of

formal channels, instead of functioning alone.

In the third paper, I examined the causal effects of contact use with the homophily

characteristic taken into account. Indeed, contact use is endogenous to other types of

resources (i.e., human capital and political credentials) one possesses. Although pro-social-

capital scholars (Fernandez 2012; Lin 2001; Lin and Ao 2008) argue that homophily is the

reason that social capital can exert positive effects on labor market outcomes, it is unclear

why this is the case. My answer to this question is that contact use is not exogenous, but

endogenous to individual formal (or certifiable) qualifications. The use of contacts exerts

positive effects only when it is combined with one’s formal qualifications. Thus, I verified

the causal effects of social capital on job search by comparing the joint use of formal and

informal search methods with the use of either formal or informal methods only. This is

different from the conventional approach, by which the dichotomy between contact use and

formal job search channels is assumed. Findings show that during a search process,

individuals who used the formal-informal joint channel tend to obtain more job information

and apply for more jobs, compared to their counterparts who used either the formal or

informal channel only. This type of job seeker is also more likely find a job within three

months. With respect to late-stage career development (indicated by recent income), the ESR

results show that the use of the joint channel itself indeed exerts a positive effect. However,

the positive effect of the joint channel is likely to be underestimated, because individuals

who possess typical characteristics of using the joint channel may actively choose to use

either type of the single channels. This is possible, because individuals’ perception of “good”

jobs is shaped by the co-development of state power and market strength in China’s

transitional economy. Also, failing to predict long-term benefits of the use of the joint

channel may also contribute into individuals’ decision-making in favor of using a less costly

single channel. Once the self-selection effect is taken into account, however, the causal effect

of the use of the joint channel is strongly supported. The third paper demonstrated the

existence of the casual effects of contact use on job search success, not despite homophily,

but exactly due to the homophily principle.

Putting these three papers together, this dissertation has contributed to the literature in two

areas: social stratification and inequality, and social capital.

132

5.2. Contributions in the Area of Social Stratification and Inequality

As one of the foremost transitional economies, the case of China’s socioeconomic transition

has provided an excellent real-world laboratory for scholars to test a variety of theories that

aim to explain massive social changes. Despite the differences in theories (Bian and Logan

1996; Nee 1989, 1991; Parish and Michelson 1996; Rona-Tas 1994; Walder 2004; Zhou

2000; Zhou et al. 1997), scholars have investigated the empirical evidence from the same

approach— focusing on the impacts of the stratified social structure on individuals’

socioeconomic statuses. However, this structural approach solely focused on stratification

outcomes does not explain the origin of social stratification. The direct consequence of this

shortcoming is that studies about China’s transitional economy fail to explicate why two

seemingly contradictory social forces – state power and the market strength – have co-

developed in China’s case.

In this dissertation, I demonstrated that this theoretical defect can be corrected by adopting a

constructive perspective. Focusing on the process of the transition, my dissertation delineates

how the co-development of the state and the market can be explained as a ceaseless

interaction between state policies and individual coping strategies towards them.

Beyond the contextual concern, I want to emphasize that a constructive perspective, which is

focused on the interaction process between structural factors and individual behaviors, should

be a powerful theoretical tool that can be used to understand any type of large-scale social

change. My dissertation has exemplified that understanding the formation process of a social

institution is of great importance to understand the foundation of the stratified social structure

and its consequences.

5.3. Contributions in the Area of Social Capital

An on-going debate in social capital studies lies in the challenge of homophily against the

causal effects of contact use. In my dissertation, I pointed out that the conventional

dichotomy between using and not using social contacts in employment activities is

problematic. Since social capital is endogenous to other types of “formal” resources, i.e.,

human capital (as well as political credentials in China’s case), according to the homophily

133

explanation, the positive effects of social capital should be seen when social capital is

combined with other types of resources, rather than used alone. This proposition is

theoretically legitimate as well as empirically effective. Theoretically, focused on

certifiability of qualifications required for a job position, my dissertation demonstrated that

the joint use of formal and informal job-person matching channels is more common than the

use of either formal or informal channels alone. Since most job positions require both

certifiable and uncertifiable qualification, individuals who often succeed in the labor market

are not those who possess the best certifiable qualifications but poor quality social contacts.

Instead, an individual’s certifiable qualifications only need to be sufficient to meet the

employer’s hiring expectations. Under the condition that an individual’s certifiable

qualifications match the corresponding job requirements, the employer would turn to value

this individual’s uncertifiable qualifications conveyed through social contacts, rather than

more certifiable qualifications. In my third dissertation paper, the joint use of formal and

informal job search methods was found to have significant advantages during job search as

well as after job search, relative to the use of either type of single channels.

In short, the innovative way to study roles social capital play in job search in my dissertation

is to distinguish those who can mobilize social contacts and formal job search channels

jointly from those who rely solely on either contact use or formal job search methods. The

strong evidence of my argument may have a certain association with the Chinese context. As

I mentioned before, one must bear in mind that the labor market of post-socialist China is

characterized as a labor-oversupply market. Especially, the oversupply of highly-educated

job seekers may lift up the average requirement for formal qualifications. This may lead to

the fact that formal or certifiable qualifications are required by default, even for positions that

mainly concern uncertifiable qualifications.

Despite that, the theoretical approach of distinguishing individuals who use contacts jointly

with formal search methods from those who have no other options but to only rely on

contacts can be considered a universal way to address the homophily issue. Depending on the

institutional context, individual characteristics may vary among job seekers who use the joint

job search channel, who only use the formal channel, and who only use the informal channel;

so do the consequences of three scenarios.

134

5.4. Directions of Future Research

Future research extended from this dissertation will be conducted beyond the Chinese

context. Despite the use of the empirical evidence in China’s transitional economy, my

doctoral research aims to elaborate on a universal theory of contact use by focusing on the

interaction between institutional constraints and individual behaviors. To test this theoretical

perspective, I will first compare different transitional economies, such as China, Vietnam,

Russia, and Eastern European countries. It would be interesting to find out if the differences

in labor market institutions among those countries can be explained not only by the

differences in macro-level policies, but more importantly, by the differences caused by

individuals’ active reactions towards those policies.

Furthermore, this theoretical perspective should also have explanatory power for institutional

change in a relatively stable economy. For example, scholars’ (Granovetter 1974; Lin et al.

1981; Marsden and Campbell 1990; Marsden and Hurlbert 1988) findings about the

dominant use of weak ties in the American labor market can be explained by the constructive

perspective. Responding to the institutional constraint— segregation of the labor market in

the dimensions of race, ethnicity, immigration status, gender, and so on, individuals may

choose to mobilize weak ties. Traversing network boundaries means that one can access

better employment opportunities in sectors of the labor market that one might have been

segregated from due to one’s individual characteristics.

Comparative studies are also required in terms of testing the theory of the “joint use of

formal and informal employment channels.” My central argument in this respect is that the

homophily issue can universally be addressed by making a distinction between individuals

who use formal and informal search channels jointly and those who can only rely on informal

channels. If so, I expect the differences in effects of contact use across societies do not

contradict, but support the argument that the positive effects of social capital on job search

shows in the joint use of formal and informal channels in a variety of societal contexts.

Overall, although this dissertation specifically investigated employment activities in the

context of China’s transitional economy, theories derived from this dissertation can be

generalized beyond a certain social context. Focusing on meso-level social relations, studies

on social capital have a unique strength to link the macro social structure and individuals at

135

the micro level. Understanding this linkage not only sheds light on the question of how social

capital functions in a particular social context, but also provides inspiration in terms of the

origin of social stratification and inequality. This constructive perspective consequently

brings to the fore the necessity of addressing the homophily issue in social capital studies.

My solution to facing the challenge of homophily is to differentiate individuals who use

formal and informal job search methods jointly from those who rely solely on contact use.

Comparative studies are needed to confirm if the approach of singling out the joint use of

formal and informal channels can also offer proper explanations to effects of contact use in

other social contexts.

136

References

Bian, Yanjie, and John R. Logan. 1996. “Market Transition and the Persistence of Power: The Changing Stratification System in Urban China.” American Sociological Review 61(5): 739-58.

Fernandez, Roberto. 2012. “The Causal Status of Social Capital in Labor Markets.” Presented in the American Sociological Association annual meeting, Denver, Colorado.

Granovetter, Mark. 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

——. 2001. Social Capital: A Theory of Social Structure and Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Lin, Nan and Dan Ao. 2008. “The Invisible Hand of Social Capital: An Exploratory Study.” Pp. 107-132 in Social Capital: An International Research Program, edited by Nan Lin and Bonnie H. Erickson. New York: Oxford University Press.

Lin, Nan, John C. Vaughn, and Walter Ensel. 1981. “Social Resources and Occupational Status Attainment.” Social Forces 59:1163-81.

Marsden, P. V. & Campbell K. E. (1990). Recruitment and Selection Processes: The Organizational Side of Job Searches. In R. L. Breiger (Ed.), Social Mobility and Social Structure (pp.59-79). Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

Marsden, Peter V., and Jeanne S. Hurlbert. 1988. “Social Resources and Mobility Outcomes: A Replication and Extension.” Social Forces 66(4):1038-59.

Nee, Victor. 1989. “A Theory of Market Transition: From Redistribution to Markets in State Socialism.” American Sociological Review 54(5):663-81.

——. 1991. “Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China.” American Sociological Review 56(3):267-82.

Parish, William L., and Ethan Michelson. “Politics and Markets: Dual Transformations.” American Journal of Sociology 101(4):1042-59.

Rona-Tas, Akos. 1994. “The First Shall Be the Last? Entrepreneurship and Communist Cadres in the Transition from Socialism.” American Journal of Sociology 100(1):40-69.

Walder, Andrew G. 2004. “The Party Elite and China’s Trajectory of Change.” China: An International Journal 2(2):189-209.

Zhou, Xueguang. 2000. “Economic Transformation and Income Inequality in Urban China.” American Journal of Sociology 105 (4):1135-74.

Zhou, Xueguang, Nancy Brandon Tuma, and Phyllis Moen. 1997. “Institutional Change and Job-shift patterns in Urban China, 1949 to 1994.” American Sociological Review 62(3):339-365.

137

Appendices

Appendix A.

Descriptive Statistics of the Qualitative Data

Variables Values Percentage Gender Male 57.6 Female 42.4 Age Below 30 42.4 30-40 30.3 Above 40 27.3 Party Membership Party members 48.5 Non-party members 51.5 Years of education Less than 6 years 15.2 6-12 years 21.2 13-16 years 15.2 Above 16 years 48.4 Father's party membership

Party members 48.5

Non-party members 51.5 Father's education Less than 6 years 36.4 6-12 years 33.3 13-16 years 18.2 Above 16 years 12.1 Era of job entry <1979 15.2 1979-1992 12.1 >1992 72.7 Location Beijing 36 Shenzhen 32 Jiangyou 32

138

Appendix B. Distribution of the Year of Job Entry, CGSS 2003, Urban Section

Year of job entry Freq. Percent Cum.

Year of job entry Freq. Percent Cum.

1944 1 0.02 0.02 1984 116 2.21 43.2 1945 2 0.04 0.06 1985 141 2.69 45.89 1946 1 0.02 0.08 1986 161 3.07 48.96 1947 2 0.04 0.11 1987 149 2.84 51.8 1948 1 0.02 0.13 1988 108 2.06 53.86 1949 3 0.06 0.19 1989 120 2.29 56.15 1950 9 0.17 0.36 1990 159 3.03 59.18 1951 1 0.02 0.38 1991 126 2.4 61.59 1952 10 0.19 0.57 1992 158 3.01 64.6 1953 15 0.29 0.86 1993 158 3.01 67.61 1954 16 0.31 1.16 1994 130 2.48 70.09 1955 7 0.13 1.3 1995 151 2.88 72.97 1956 39 0.74 2.04 1996 136 2.59 75.57 1957 24 0.46 2.5 1997 150 2.86 78.43 1958 75 1.43 3.93 1998 173 3.3 81.73 1959 44 0.84 4.77 1999 163 3.11 84.84 1960 42 0.8 5.57 2000 204 3.89 88.73 1961 30 0.57 6.14 2001 172 3.28 92.01 1962 42 0.8 6.94 2002 255 4.86 96.87 1963 35 0.67 7.61 2003 164 3.13 100 1964 48 0.92 8.53 Total 5,243 100 1965 48 0.92 9.44 1966 47 0.9 10.34 1967 31 0.59 10.93 1968 59 1.13 12.05 1969 55 1.05 13.1 1970 102 1.95 15.05 1971 71 1.35 16.4 1972 69 1.32 17.72 1973 52 0.99 18.71 1974 64 1.22 19.93 1975 97 1.85 21.78 1976 106 2.02 23.8 1977 62 1.18 24.99 1978 115 2.19 27.18 1979 177 3.38 30.56 1980 161 3.07 33.63 1981 126 2.4 36.03 1982 137 2.61 38.64 1983 123 2.35 40.99

139

Appendix C.

Descriptive Statistics for Variables Used in the Quantitative Study

140

Appendix D.

Decomposition of Group Differences in ESR Estimations

(Formulas are quoted from Gerber 2000: 37 and 44. Gerber, Theodore P. 2000. “Membership Benefits or Selection Effects? Why Former Communist Party Members Do Better in Post-Soviet Russia.” Social Science Research 29:25-50.)

In an ESR model, every case is estimated twice— one is when this case is in its actual group,

and the other is when this case is hypothetically switched to the opposite group. Thus, four

scenarios are estimated in an ESR model. For two observed groups, the expected outcome is

formulated as follows:

)]}(/[)](){[/()0|( 31311 iikik

kii ZZXZYE))

Φ+=> ∑ φσσβ (7)

and

)]}(1/[)](){[/()0|( 32322 iikik

kii ZZXZYE))

Φ−−=< ∑ φσσβ

where βkXk denotes effects of measurable characteristics, σ13 and σ23 denote the covariance

of the disturbances ε1 and ε2 with ε3, φ denotes the normal probability density function, and

Φ denotes the cumulative normal probability function. In Tables 6 and 8, while ƩβkXk

indicates differences caused by the types of job search channels (shown in Panels A), the

second half of the decomposition equation indicates the self-selection effects (shown in

Panels B). The final result derived from each equation indicates the total logged income

(shown in Panels C).

The expected outcome in two hypothetical scenarios, in which the case is switched to the

opposite group, can be formulated as follows:

)]}(/[)](){[/()0|( 32322 iikik

kii ZZXZYE))

Φ+=> ∑ φσσβ (9)

and

)]}(1/[)](){[/()0|( 31311 iikik

kii ZZXZYE))

Φ−−=< ∑ φσσβ (10)

(8) (8)

141

Appendix E.

In-Depth Interview Guide Part I. Ask the interviewee to introduce the current workplace and job position.

1. First of all, I want to know about your current workplace. Could you please give me a brief introduction about your current workplace?

2. I also want to know what you usually do at work. Could you please tell me what your current job is like?

3. How long have you been in this workplace? 4. Compared to your co-workers who entered the workplace in the same year with you,

how do you feel about your career progress?

Part II. The processes of job searches 5. I am interested in how you entered this workplace. Could you tell me your story about

how you entered this workplace? 1) Before the application

i. What was your experience before applying for this job? ii. How did you know there was a position opening in the workplace? iii. What made you decide to apply for that position?

2) During the application (If interviewees accepted the job without applying, skip

this step). i. OK, you decided to apply for that job position. I’m interested in what

happened next. Could you tell me what you did to get the job? ii. Your job-search story is very interesting. When you look back now, what

step(s) would you think was/were crucial for you to get the job in this workplace? Can you tell me the reason?

iii. Yes, I can see how important this step was for you, but what do you think about other step(s)/ job-search efforts you did?

3) Decision making: Why did you accept the job offer? i. How many job offers did you have when you received the one from this

workplace? How many potential job offers did you have at that moment – that is, jobs for which you were still waiting for the final decision from the employers?

ii(1). For interviewees who had more than one job offer, including potential job offers: a) What were your other job offers or potential job offers? b) What made you choose the offer from this workplace, among all the

offers you got or would have a chance to get? c) To what extent do you think the job offer met your expectations at that

moment? d) If you could go back, would you still choose to accept the offer? Why

or why not? ii(2). For interviewees who had only one job offer:

e) What directly led you to accept the job offer?

142

f) To what extent do you think the job offer met your expectation at that moment?

g) If you could go back, would you still choose to accept the offer? Why or why not?

Part III: Background information 6. Gender and age 7. Educational experience 8. Re-confirmation of party membership 9. Family background

143

Appendix F.

144

145

146

147

148

149

150

151

152

153

154

155

156

157

158

159

160

161