the political economy of oil and gas in southeast asia

36
The Pacific Review, Vol. 23 No. 2 May 2010: 225–259 The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia: heading towards the natural resource curse? Benjamin K. Sovacool Abstract The notion of the resource curse suggests that countries with large caches of natural resources often perform worse in terms of economic growth, social devel- opment, and good governance than other countries with fewer resources. The theory posits that countries depending on oil or other extractive industries for their liveli- hood are among the most economically troubled, socially unstable, authoritarian, and conflict-ridden in the world. This article explores whether the resource curse is occurring in relation to oil and gas production in Southeast Asia, where invest- ments in oil and gas infrastructure are expected to increase significantly. The article begins by conceptualizing the resource curse before explaining the factors believed to cause it. It then proposes metrics that can be used to identify the presence of the resource curse before testing these metrics on the five Southeast Asian countries with the largest rates of oil and gas production and reserves – Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, Myanmar, and Thailand – from 1987 to 2007. The article compares the performance of these Southeast Asian countries with the five largest producers in the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries as well as Brazil, China, India, the Russian Federation, and South Africa. The article concludes that the resource curse is not occurring in any of these countries, and that the theory may be too sim- plistic and deterministic to fully explain why some countries appear to be ‘cursed’ with resources while others are ‘blessed’. Keywords Resource curse; crude oil; natural gas; energy security. 1. Introduction Emil Salim, the President of the Extractive Industries Review, an attempt by the World Bank to improve transparency and accountability in the Dr Benjamin K. Sovacool is Assistant Professor at the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy at the National University of Singapore. He is also a Research Fellow in the Energy Gover- nance Program at the Centre on Asia and Globalization. Address: 469C Bukit Timah Road, Singapore, 259772. E-mail: [email protected] The Pacific Review ISSN 0951-2748 print/ISSN 1470-1332 online C 2010 Taylor & Francis http://www.informaworld.com/journals DOI: 10.1080/09512741003624484

Upload: others

Post on 28-Oct-2021

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

The Pacific Review, Vol. 23 No. 2 May 2010: 225–259

The political economy of oil and gasin Southeast Asia: heading towardsthe natural resource curse?

Benjamin K. Sovacool

Abstract The notion of the resource curse suggests that countries with large cachesof natural resources often perform worse in terms of economic growth, social devel-opment, and good governance than other countries with fewer resources. The theoryposits that countries depending on oil or other extractive industries for their liveli-hood are among the most economically troubled, socially unstable, authoritarian,and conflict-ridden in the world. This article explores whether the resource curseis occurring in relation to oil and gas production in Southeast Asia, where invest-ments in oil and gas infrastructure are expected to increase significantly. The articlebegins by conceptualizing the resource curse before explaining the factors believedto cause it. It then proposes metrics that can be used to identify the presence of theresource curse before testing these metrics on the five Southeast Asian countrieswith the largest rates of oil and gas production and reserves – Brunei, Indonesia,Malaysia, Myanmar, and Thailand – from 1987 to 2007. The article compares theperformance of these Southeast Asian countries with the five largest producers inthe Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries as well as Brazil, China, India,the Russian Federation, and South Africa. The article concludes that the resourcecurse is not occurring in any of these countries, and that the theory may be too sim-plistic and deterministic to fully explain why some countries appear to be ‘cursed’with resources while others are ‘blessed’.

Keywords Resource curse; crude oil; natural gas; energy security.

1. Introduction

Emil Salim, the President of the Extractive Industries Review, an attemptby the World Bank to improve transparency and accountability in the

Dr Benjamin K. Sovacool is Assistant Professor at the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policyat the National University of Singapore. He is also a Research Fellow in the Energy Gover-nance Program at the Centre on Asia and Globalization.

Address: 469C Bukit Timah Road, Singapore, 259772. E-mail: [email protected]

The Pacific ReviewISSN 0951-2748 print/ISSN 1470-1332 online C© 2010 Taylor & Francis

http://www.informaworld.com/journalsDOI: 10.1080/09512741003624484

Page 2: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

226 The Pacific Review

mining and energy sectors, once began a conference on governance with thefollowing statement. ‘Not only have the oil, gas, and mining industries nothelped the poorest people in developing countries, they have often madethem worse off’ (Steiner 2007: 2). Juan Pablo Perez Alfonzo, one of thefounders of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC),went even further and called oil ‘the devil’s excrement’ (Karl 2005: 21).Both statements imply that for many countries with relatively rich endow-ments of natural resources ranging from gems and copper to gas and crudeoil, those very commodities can become ‘curses’ to the government and itscitizens.

Indeed, a long line of political economists and theorists have stated dif-ferent variants of the ‘resource curse’ argument, which explains that nat-ural resource endowments can incite, prolong, and intensify governmentfailure and violent conflict. Stevens (2004) argues that large windfall rev-enues from oil or gas production can change government behavior, dam-age economic growth, and imperil development. Karl (1998, 2005) postu-lates that the consolidation and extraction of natural resources can createand solidify asymmetries in wealth that then contribute to rising incomegaps between the rich and poor, institutionalize corruption, and enable op-pressive regimes to maintain their political power. De Soysa (2000) notesthat civil strife and social instability are strongly associated with natural re-source abundance, particularly with mineral, gas, and oil exports. Silberfein(2004) states that resource based conflicts can become some of the mostintractable because participants often benefit from unstable conditions,which can facilitate access to resources, smuggling, and covert trade. Ben-eficiaries not only grow in their power but also become reluctant to ter-minate bloody conflagrations. Le Billon (2004) suggests that resources canbe used to finance conflicts (such as the civil war in Sierra Leone over di-amonds), or can be a motive for other countries to go to war (such as theIraqi invasion of Kuwait in 1990). Omorogbe (2006) expresses that a ma-jority of resource-rich countries have performed well below expectationsand capability and with little to show after decades of resource extraction.Esanov et al. (2006) comment that Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Turkmenistan,and Uzbekistan have performed worse than other countries in the CaspianSea and Central Asia because their energy resources have been appropri-ated by elites and stunted economic development.

For confirmation of the resource curse thesis, consider that in Saudi Ara-bia, proven crude oil reserves are the greatest in the world but per capitaincome has plunged from $28,600 in 1981 to $6,800 in 2001 (Baer 2003). InNigeria and Venezuela, also rich in crude oil and natural gas, real per capitaincome has regressed to levels of the 1960s. Algeria, Angola, the Congo,Ecuador, Gabon, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Libya, Qatar, and Trinidad and To-bago, countries with substantial endowments of minerals, gold, timber, anddiamonds, have seen real per capita income fall back to levels of the 1970sand 1980s as the extraction of these resources has increased. In late 1980s

Page 3: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 227

Afghanistan, Ahmad Shah Massoud was able to earn $50 million annuallyfor his ‘United Front’ campaign against the Russians by selling locally har-vested emeralds and lapis lazuli, and the civil wars in Zaire and the Congowere directly exacerbated by gold and diamond mining. These examples arenot anecdotal, and O’Lear (2004) has identified 10 serious civil wars andconflicts from 1990 to 1999 directly fueled by natural resources: copper fa-cilitated a secessionist revolt in Bougainville, Papa New Guinea; oil fundedfive separate civil wars in Angola, East Timor/Indonesia, the Kurkuk regionof Iraq, Southern Sudan, and the Xinjiang province of China; natural gas en-abled a conflict in Aceh, Indonesia; nickel a secessionist movement in NewCaledonia, France; gold financed a war in West Papua, Indonesia; andphosphates contributed to conflict in the Western Sahara and Morocco.Controlling for ‘structural attributes’, Humphreys et al. (2007) estimatethat resource-rich countries as a whole have shown less economic devel-opment than resource-poor countries from 1975 to 2000. Auty (2006) com-pared the economic performance of developing countries ‘rich in resources’with those ‘poor in resources’ and found that resource rich countries had amedian gross domestic product (GDP) per capita of about $200 less thanresource poor ones.

The theory of the resource curse is worrisome and alarming for South-east Asia for at least two reasons. First, resource extraction is anticipated toincrease dramatically throughout the region. Southeast Asia is where signif-icant investments in oil and natural gas are being called for to satisfy robustregional economic growth, diversify oil and gas supply outside of the Mid-dle East, and satisfy demand for imported fuel in China, Japan, and SouthKorea. Regulators have rushed to invest in oil and gas, and by 2030 some an-alysts expect that Southeast Asia will become ‘the Persian Gulf of Gas’ andbe responsible for one-quarter of the world’s gas production (Tan 2008).The International Energy Agency (2008) anticipates the need to invest tril-lions of dollars in electricity and energy supply in Southeast Asia by 2030,and the Asian Development Bank and World Bank expect to spend morethan $50 billion in infrastructure lending between 2005 and 2015 (Bapna2006).

Second, corruption and poor governance are prevalent in Southeast Asia.One World Bank survey recently detailed that large-scale infrastructureprojects in Southeast Asia, because of their capital intensive nature, practi-cally invite corruption. The survey documented that in Indonesia, a physicalaudit of roads built under the oversight of village heads uncovered missingmaterials worth 24 per cent of total expenditures; in Cambodia and Laos,up to one-third of electricity generated was stolen; and that an average firmworking in Asia expects to lose 11 per cent of its budget for infrastructureprojects on bribes (Kenny 2007).

If rapid resource extraction threatens to fundamentally alter the politicaland economic structure of exporting countries, and investments in oil andgas infrastructure will only accelerate resource depletion and increase

Page 4: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

228 The Pacific Review

corruption, then it is essential to explore the dynamics of the resource cursein Southeast Asia. This article begins by conceptualizing the resource cursebefore explaining the factors believed to cause it. It then proposes metricsthat can be used to identify the presence of the resource curse beforetesting these metrics on the five Southeast Asian countries with the largestrates of oil and gas production and reserves – Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia,Myanmar, and Thailand – from 1987 to 2007. The article then comparesthe performance of these Southeast Asian countries with the five largestproducers in the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries as wellas Brazil, China, India, the Russian Federation, and South Africa. Suchan investigation adds important depth to discussions of the resource cursebecause so far exemplars of scholarship have mostly ignored SoutheastAsia (with the exception of Malaysia and Indonesia) and instead focusedon Africa and the Middle East. Moreover, most debates about the resourcecurse frame it in somewhat abstract terms that make it difficult to com-prehend and even more challenging to measure. One value to this articleis that it proposes ways of defining and quantifying the presence of theresource curse (or lack of it) that may be useful to policy-makers and otherscholars studying extractive industries around the world. The article alsoprovides a way of concretely testing the validity of the resource curse asa concept 30 years after its inception for the performance of 15 countriesfrom 1987 to 2007.

2. Conceptualizing the natural resource curse

Put simply, the resource curse suggests that countries with large caches ofnatural resources often perform worse in terms of economic growth, so-cial development, and good governance than other countries with fewer re-sources (Humphreys et al. 2007). The theory posits that countries dependingon oil or other extractive industries for their livelihood are among the mosteconomically troubled, socially unstable, authoritarian, and conflict-riddenin the world (Karl 2005). These resource-rich but practically-poor countrieshave slower than average economic growth and little industrial diversifica-tion. The ‘curse’ or mismanagement of their resources expands outside theextractive industries sector and slowly degrades social welfare. Resourcecursed countries also display rising levels of poverty and inequality, de-teriorating environmental quality, institutionalized corruption, and an in-creased frequency of conflict and war (Karl 2005). Ross (1999) elaboratesthat three separate strands of the resource curse theorem exist. The ‘cog-nitive’ strand implies that windfalls from resource extraction produce my-opic disorders among policy-makers. The ‘social’ strand suggests that wind-falls empower recipients that then favor growth-stunting and self-servingpolicies. The ‘statist’ strand argues that windfalls weaken the state institu-tions necessary for long-term economic development. Many investigations

Page 5: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 229

weave all three strands together. The inverse of the resource curse also ap-pears justifiable: lack of natural resources has not prevented Hong Kong,Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan from achieving booming export in-dustries based on solid manufacturing sectors and rapid economic growth(Humphreys et al. 2007).

The problem, in essence, is that many of the most valuable resources suchas diamonds, gold, oil, and gas are worth so much money that their extrac-tion can be severely mismanaged but still create profits for companies andgovernments (Maassarani et al. 2007: 139). Resource cursed governmentstend to manage natural resources opportunistically rather than strategically.That is, government officials view them as a mechanism to create immedi-ate wealth rather than a long-term but depletable asset that should be care-fully managed over time. Resource depletion therefore tends not to servethe public interest, and instead consolidates wealth among a very narrowclass of bureaucrats and managers. Moreover, the immense value of thoseresources can mask mismanagement and inequity. As one high ranking ex-ecutive for a large transnational oil company told the author, ‘high prices[for natural resources] cover a multitude of sins.’

The easiest resources to control – the ones most germane to the resourcecurse – are ‘point’ resources, resources spatially concentrated in small ar-eas, relatively easy to monitor, and extracted through capital intensive tech-nologies. ‘Point’ resources contrast ‘diffuse’ resources, which are spatiallydistributed and therefore more ‘lootable’, exploited by less capital inten-sive measures, and more difficult to consolidate (Le Billon 2004; O’Lear2004). Point and diffuse resources can contribute to different patterns ofcapital ownership and distribution of resource benefits. While both can becorrupted, or rapidly extracted or pillaged to serve limited ends or means,point resources are more prone to the resource curse.

Because of their spatially concentrated nature, point resources are wellattuned to highly centralized control. Ruling elites can extract them by con-trolling small geographic areas, and the revenues generated by even mod-els levels of extraction can be significant. Karl (2005) argues that point re-sources are ‘easily’ the worst managed, for they can be extracted from anarrow geographic or economic base and have the strongest correlationwith poor growth. Diffuse resources such as coal, charcoal, wood, diamonds,gems, cobalt, gold, silver, sapphires, rubies, and other small, strategic, orvaluable metals are more difficult to track and govern due to their dis-tributed nature. While sapphires and rubies provided the Khmer Rouge inCambodia and Karen in Burma with significant revenues during 1990s, theirextraction could only occur by controlling vast amounts of land through al-most complete authoritarian control.

Five distinct and interrelated conditions appear to explain the struc-tural social, political, and economic factors behind the resource curse(Humphreys et al. 2007; Bapna 2006; Stiglitz 2005; Karl 2005; Stevens 2004;Sachs and Warner 1999; Karl 1998).

Page 6: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

230 The Pacific Review

Figure 1 Real and nominal global crude oil prices, 1980–2009 (in US dollars perbarrel). Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration (2008a).

First, those countries most susceptible to the resource curse haveeconomies that are not diversified and remain heavily dependent on a fewextractive industries. When the price of these few commodities fluctuateswidely, the sudden price gyrations and boom and bust cycles erode bud-getary discipline, decrease expenditures for public sector investment, andcomplicate efforts at state planning. Oil prices, for example, have been in-credibly volatile from 1980 to 2008 (see Figure 1). Mikesell (1997) calcu-lated that between 1972 and 1992, regions with high primary mineral andoil exports experienced periods of trade volatility two to three times greaterthan average industrialized economies over the same period. The volatilityof any mineral commodity is exacerbated by banks and financial institu-tions. When commodity prices fall or interest rates rise, lenders are quickto call in their loans (a general maxim of bankers is that they always preferto lend to those that do not need their money). When prices fall, resource-dependent countries also need more money, but this is usually when bankswant their money back. Capital flows and the decline of oil prices, for exam-ple, tend to be pro-cyclical, worsening the fluctuations brought about by theinitial fall in the price of oil. Falling prices also tend to incentivize increasedamounts of resource production to maintain stable levels of revenue, pre-cipitating greater environmental damage, economic concentration, and de-pletion of the resource. When prices are high, leaders face expectations thatthey should increase spending, embark on capital intensive projects, and re-ward productive components of the economy with subsidies (Tsalik 2003).

Page 7: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 231

Second, mineral and commodity exports can cause economic consolida-tion and the ‘Dutch disease’, or rapid inflation and increases in the exchangerate of local currency, rendering other exports less competitive (Corden andNeary 1982). (Economists and historians call this the ‘Dutch disease’ afterNorth Sea oil and gas production had rapid negative effects on the exchangerate and inflation in the Netherlands in the 1960s). In essence, the primaryresource being exported then crowds out other sectors of the economy,causing even more economic concentration. In response, regulators oftenadopt policies that protect that very sector to a greater degree, reinforcingdependence on the resource and worsening the cycle. The risk of economicconsolidation becomes greater the more valuable the natural resource, forunlike other sources of wealth and manufactured goods, lucrative mineralsneed only be extracted rather than produced to attain revenue. This creates‘enclaved’ spheres of economic activity without major linkages to other sec-tors and can take place without large-scale participation of the labor force.

Third, most extractive industries rely on sophisticated technology notowned or licensed by the host countries. Oil and gas production and mining,for instance, are very capital- and technology-intensive, meaning they cre-ate fewer jobs per dollar invested and require unique skills not well suitedfor other areas of economic activity. Resource-rich countries often sendhighly skilled labor abroad to train, and foreign workers are typically sentin to do the local extracting, minimizing the chance that exporting coun-tries will ‘learn by doing’ or own the intellectual property and technologyassociated with extraction.

Fourth, since most extractive industries and technologies are large-scale,capital intensive and foreign owned, few productive links exist between re-source extraction and the rest of the economy. Generally, the revenues flowdirectly to the government in the form of royalties, taxes, and profits. Thisconsolidates revenue among the existing political parties, worsens the gapbetween rich and poor, and also breaks the link between taxation, repre-sentation, and accountability, since most resource-rich regimes do not needto tax their own people. It also increases the changes of regulatory captureand rent seeking, since only a small number of officials need to be ‘cap-tured’ to facilitate large transfers of wealth. The concentration of wealthfrom resource revenues sometimes enables rulers to spend their money onsubsidies to friends, family, and political supporters. Karl (2000), for exam-ple, estimates that from 1974 to 2000 OPEC states spent 65 to 75 per centof their income in this manner.

Fifth and finally, large extractive projects frequently fail to benefit mi-norities and poor communities because these stakeholders have not partic-ipated in project selection and financing. The decision making processesin resource cursed countries tend to lack transparency and accountabil-ity, so vested interests determine what gets built and who benefits. Localcommunities and indigenous populations must then contend with the dam-ages from resource extraction while the political and corporate elite reap

Page 8: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

232 The Pacific Review

the benefits. Moreover, when cost benefit analyses are conducted by thosein power, benefits are usually overestimated publicly while costs underes-timated. In the absence of effective oversight and regulation, companieslower their social and environmental standards to reduce costs and maxi-mize short-term returns. In the hazardous extractive industries sector, theconsequence of poor oversight can be severe and include acute and catas-trophic spills, explosions, accidents, and disasters along with chronic andgradually deleterious exposure to noxious emissions, noise, degraded habi-tat, and food and water contamination (Steiner 2007; Sovacool 2008).

Perhaps the extraction of oil and gas resources in Angola, Columbia,Nigeria, Saudi Arabia, and OPEC states as a whole bests exemplifies howthe resource curse can occur at multiple scales of governance, in many de-grees, and to a collection of different countries.

In Angola, which has extracted some of the world’s largest oil and gasreserves for 40 years, average life expectancy has plunged to 36.8 years in2006, the infant mortality rate has risen to 19 per cent, the country importsmost of its food, and almost three-quarters of the population live belowthe poverty line (Omorogbe 2006: 45). Proceeds from oil and gas produc-tion have nourished oppressive tendencies within the state. Oil revenueshave enabled elites to capture virtually all economic enterprises, and en-couraged violent contests for political power from a dissatisfied population.The United Nations has accused Angola of using state used oil revenuesto fund blood diamond operations, and the state has admitted to using oilrevenues to fund illegal cocaine operations throughout the Andean region(Auty 2004).

In Columbia, oil and gas profits have contributed to acts of terrorismand intensified military conflict. Guerilla groups reap an oil ‘war tax’ andearn $140 million per year from oil-related extortion and kidnappings. TheNational Liberation Army (ELN) and Revolutionary Armed Forces ofColumbia (FARC), the two largest rebel groups, have extracted war taxesfrom oil companies and local contractors through threatened sabotage andmurders, extortions, and bombings. When their threats have not gottenthem the leverage they desire, ELN and FARC guerillas have dynamitedstate oil and gas pipelines more than 1,000 times in 13 years, spilling 2.9 bil-lion barrels of crude oil and greatly damaging ecosystems and local waterresources. The economic losses alone from explosions on the Cano Limon-Covenas pipeline amounted to $1 billion from 1990 to 1995, or seven percent of Columbia’s entire export revenue over the same period. Paramil-itary groups have also built a cottage industry by stealing natural gas andgasoline by drilling holes in pipelines. Ecopetrol, one state oil company, es-timates they lose $5 million per month. Finally, oil and gas revenues providethe Columbian Army with significant income needed to purchase weaponsand train soldiers. A military tax of roughly $1 per barrel (or $12 to $30 mil-lion per year) allows the army to increase their troop presence and prolongtheir struggle against the rebels (Dunning and Wirpsa 2004).

Page 9: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 233

In Nigeria, the thirteenth largest producer of petroleum in the world, oiland gas accounts for 80 per cent of all government revenues, 95 per centof exports, and 90 per cent of foreign exchange earnings. Oil productionhas generated billions of dollars in government revenues, but the country’saverage GDP in the past decade was less than its GDP in the 1960s andthe poverty rate increased from 27 per cent in 1980 to 70 per cent in 1999(Omorogbe 2006: 44). Rather than bringing peace and stability, oil pro-duction has exacerbated political flashpoints. A collection of smaller NigerDelta states have attempted to expand their access and control over oil andgas resources, struggling with minority groups clamoring for sovereignty.Militant youth movements have grown from the resulting insecurity andpromote intensified campaigns of interethnic violence (Watts 2004).

Saudi Arabia is heavily dependent on oil production, and derives 85 percent of its total export revenue from the oil industry, so much that everydollar increase in the price of a barrel of oil means a gain of about $3 bil-lion to the Saudi treasury. The Saudis have used their oil wealth not toimprove social welfare, however, and have instead consolidated it amonga very few number of families. Five extended families in the Middle Eastown about 60 per cent of the world’s oil, and the House of Saud controlsmore than a third of that amount. Per capita income in Saudi Arabia hasfallen significantly from 1981 to 2001, and seven out of 10 jobs in the coun-try are filled by foreigners (and close to nine out of every 10 private sectorjobs). The disparity in income between the rich and poor has generatedsignificant resentment towards the royal family, a resentment sharpenedby the belief that the Saudis have failed to protect Muslims in Palestineand elsewhere and have been corrupted by their money. Adding to the so-cial instability, Saudi Arabia has one of the highest birth rates in the world(37.25 births for every 1,000 citizens, compared to 14.5 in the United States),half the population is under 18 and another half is unemployed (Baer2003).

Finally, Karl (1998) analyzed the impact of oil production on the politicaleconomies of Venezuela, Nigeria, Mexico, Iran, Algeria, and Norway andfound that in only one, Norway, did oil extraction correlate with positive de-velopment. In each of the other OPEC countries, bottlenecks in production,declines in other economic activity (especially in the agricultural and indus-trial sectors), capital flight, double digit hyperinflation, and sudden declinesin living standards occurred. Karl hypothesizes that these countries havebecome ‘addicted’ to oil, creating lavish subsidies for oil companies andpursuing oil profits over the public good. She concludes that productionand dependence on oil has changed the entire political economy of eachcountry. The per capita GDP for all OPEC members from 1965 to 1998,for instance, decreased by an average of 1.3 per cent each year whereas percapita GDP for all other developing countries that did not rely on oil ex-ports as a whole grew by an average of 2.2 per cent over the same period(Karl 2005: 23).

Page 10: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

234 The Pacific Review

While these examples may be convincing, the resource curse is by nomeans inevitable. Australia, Canada, Chile, and the United States are allworld leaders in mineral economies and manufacturing and have steadilyimproved per capita gross national product and living standards (Karl2005). Sierra Leone and Botswana are both rich in diamonds, but the lat-ter has had an average growth rate of 5.2 per cent between 1974 and 2002while the former has plunged into civil war and negative growth (Stiglitz2005: 13). In 1973, Indonesia and Nigeria had comparable per capita in-comes, and both were dependent on oil revenues, but by 2002 Indonesia’sper capita income was four times that of Nigeria’s (Nigerian per capita in-come actually fell from $302.75 in 1973 to $254.26 in 2002) (Stiglitz 2005:13).

Clearly, political economy and governance play a role in how susceptiblecountries are to the resource curse. Bevan et al. (1999) explain that Indone-sia fared much better than Nigeria in developing its resources and success-fully minimized the resource curse because of three political and economicfactors. Indonesian President Sukarno’s articulation of a clear vision ofsocial cohesion and fighting poverty in the 1950s and 1960s engenderedexpectations among the Indonesian population. This created a politicalenvironment where poverty alleviation could not be ignored, yet nosuch expectations took root in Nigeria. The occurrence of hyperinflationin the 1960s also made avoiding inflation an important social issue forIndonesians but not in Nigeria, and the rapid economic growth in theAsian region precipitated greater trade and investment for Indonesia whileNigeria’s neighbors struggled economically. Moreover, the presence of fiveinterrelated factors – volatility, inflation, knowledge transfer, economicconcentration, and lack of participation – illustrate that the resource cursecannot be reduced to institutional structure, politics, distribution of naturalresources, or standards of living. A combination of each plays a role,meaning the presence of the resource curse seems to be highly contingentand contextualized (Rosser 2006).

3. Measuring the resource curse in Southeast Asia

Given its complex and contextual roots, how can the resource curse be mea-sured? And is it occurring among Southeast Asian countries that have thelargest oil and gas reserves and rates of production?

The resource curse, according to the logic presented above, is ultimatelyconnected to geologic factors such as a country’s resource endowment; po-litical factors such as transparency, participation, and corruption; economicfactors such as diversification and wealth consolidation; and social factorssuch as life expectancy and standards of living. Countries suffering fromthe resource curse would be blessed with certain mineral resources, tendto have less transparency, more corruption, a less diversified economy andmore concentration of wealth, and undergo deteriorating social indicators

Page 11: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 235

Table 1 Oil reserves for Southeast Asia

CountryTotal proven reserves

(billion barrels)Per capita reserves

(barrels)

Cambodia 0 0Brunei 1.2 3209Indonesia 4.37 20Laos 0 0Malaysia 5.36 212Myanmar 0.20 4Philippines 0.14 2Singapore 0 0Thailand 0.46 7Vietnam 0.6 7Total/Average 12.33 22

Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration (2007). Per capita reserves calculated by di-viding total proven reserves by the total population listed in World Bank (2008).

including higher rates of malnutrition, child mortality, and poor educationalperformance.

In the case of Southeast Asia, the five countries with the largest endow-ment of combined oil and natural gas reserves (both per capita reserves andabsolute reserves) and production are Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, Myan-mar, and Thailand (see Tables 1 and 2). Thirteen metrics can be used todetermine the extent that these countries’ resources have ‘cursed’ themby measuring three political dimensions (transparency, authorized levelsof oil and gas production), six economic dimensions (composition of ex-ports, composition of GDP, government revenues, per capita income, ratesof poverty, and rates of inflation), and four social dimensions (education,infant mortality, food security, and life expectancy) (see Table 3). For thesecountries to be suffering from the resource curse, we would expect trans-parency to decrease and corruption to increase from 1987 to 2007. Theamount of oil and gas as a percentage of exports would also increase, alongwith overall oil and gas production (which would be harvested at faster ratesto increase royalties, taxes, and profits). Oil and gas would be anticipated tocontribute to more GDP as economic activity becomes concentrated, gov-ernment revenues from the oil and gas sector would increase along withinflation and poverty, and per capita income would decrease. Finally, wewould predict that social indicators such as literacy and life expectancywould deteriorate, while infant mortality and undernourishment would rise.

Contrary to what the resource curse posits, none of the five countries ex-amined exhibited deteriorating trends in most of these metrics. While nat-ural gas and crude production did increase for all five countries, crude oilproduction remained almost flat in Brunei and exports actually remained

Page 12: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

236 The Pacific Review

Tab

le2

Nat

ural

gas

rese

rves

for

Sout

heas

tAsi

a

Pro

ven

rese

rves

Pos

sibl

ere

serv

esP

roba

ble

rese

rves

Tot

al(t

rilli

onP

erca

pita

tota

lres

erve

sC

ount

ry(t

rilli

oncu

bic

feet

)(t

rilli

oncu

bic

feet

)(t

rilli

oncu

bic

feet

)cu

bic

feet

)(m

illio

ncu

bic

feet

)

Cam

bodi

a0

00

00

Bru

nei

84

012

32.1

Indo

nesi

a90

4234

166

0.8

Lao

s0

00

00

Mal

aysi

a58

280

863.

4M

yanm

ar21

1710

480.

9P

hilip

pine

s3

11

50

Sing

apor

e0

00

00

Tha

iland

129

1132

0.5

Vie

tnam

511

925

0.3

Tot

al/A

vera

ge19

711

265

374

0.7

Sour

ce:U

.S.E

nerg

yIn

form

atio

nA

dmin

istr

atio

n(2

007)

.Per

capi

tare

serv

esca

lcul

ated

bydi

vidi

ngto

tal(

trill

ion

cubi

cfe

et)

byth

eto

talp

opul

atio

nlis

ted

inW

orld

Ban

k(2

008)

.

Page 13: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 237

Tab

le3

Met

rics

for

mea

suri

ngth

ere

sour

cecu

rse

Dim

ensi

onM

etri

cE

xpla

nati

on

Pol

itic

alT

rans

pare

ncy

Inte

rnat

iona

lR

atin

gM

easu

res

the

amou

ntof

corr

upti

onw

ithi

na

give

nco

untr

y.T

here

sour

cecu

rse

posi

tsth

atco

rrup

tion

will

incr

ease

alon

gw

ith

reso

urce

extr

acti

onov

erti

me

Pol

itic

alN

atur

alga

spr

oduc

tion

Mea

sure

sth

eam

ount

ofdo

mes

tic

natu

ralg

aspr

oduc

tion

inbi

llion

cubi

cfe

et.T

here

sour

cecu

rse

pred

icts

that

gas

prod

ucti

onw

illin

crea

seov

erti

me

sogo

vern

men

tsca

nex

trac

tmor

ere

nts

Pol

itic

alO

ilpr

oduc

tion

Mea

sure

sth

eam

ount

ofdo

mes

tic

oilp

rodu

ctio

nin

thou

sand

barr

els

per

day.

The

reso

urce

curs

epr

edic

tsth

atoi

lpro

duct

ion

will

also

incr

ease

over

tim

eso

gove

rnm

ents

can

extr

actm

ore

reve

nue

Eco

nom

icF

uels

as%

ofal

lexp

orts

Mea

sure

sth

epe

rcen

tage

ofoi

land

gas

inov

eral

lexp

orts

.The

reso

urce

curs

esu

gges

tsth

atoi

land

gas

will

grow

toco

nsti

tute

grea

ter

expo

rts

over

tim

eE

cono

mic

%G

DP

inoi

land

gas

Mea

sure

sth

eex

tent

that

oila

ndga

sco

ntri

bute

togr

oss

dom

esti

cpr

oduc

t.T

here

sour

cecu

rse

impl

ies

that

oila

ndga

sw

illcr

owd

outo

ther

area

sof

econ

omic

acti

vity

Eco

nom

icO

ilan

dga

sas

%of

gove

rnm

entr

even

ues

Mea

sure

sth

epe

rcen

tage

ofgo

vern

men

trev

enue

sat

trib

utab

leto

oila

ndga

sta

xes,

roya

ltie

s,an

dst

ate-

owne

dpr

oduc

tion

.The

reso

urce

curs

epo

sits

that

gove

rnm

ents

will

beco

me

mor

ede

pend

ento

noi

land

gas

reve

nues

over

tim

eE

cono

mic

GN

P/G

NI

per

capi

taM

easu

res

the

amou

ntof

gros

sna

tion

alpr

oduc

tor

gros

sna

tion

alin

com

edi

stri

bute

dto

each

pers

onof

the

coun

try

per

year

.The

reso

urce

curs

efo

rete

llsa

low

erin

gof

GN

P/G

NI

per

capi

taE

cono

mic

%po

pula

tion

belo

w$2

ada

yM

easu

res

the

amou

ntof

peop

leliv

ing

inpo

vert

y(o

rle

ssth

anU

S$2

per

day)

.The

reso

urce

curs

ew

ould

expe

ctpo

vert

yto

incr

ease

askn

owle

dge

and

labo

rbe

com

eco

ncen

trat

edin

the

oila

ndga

sse

ctor

Eco

nom

icA

vera

gean

nual

rate

ofin

flati

onM

easu

res

the

rate

ofin

flati

onfo

rea

chye

ar.T

he‘D

utch

dise

ase’

aspe

ctof

the

reso

urce

curs

ear

gues

that

infla

tion

will

incr

ease

over

tim

e(C

ontin

ued

onne

xtpa

ge)

Page 14: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

238 The Pacific Review

Tab

le3

Met

rics

for

mea

suri

ngth

ere

sour

cecu

rse

(Con

tinue

d)

Dim

ensi

onM

etri

cE

xpla

nati

on

Soci

alA

dult

liter

acy

rate

Pro

vide

sa

crud

em

easu

rem

ento

fthe

gove

rnm

ent’

sab

ility

topr

ovid

eed

ucat

ion.

The

reso

urce

curs

epo

sits

that

gove

rnm

ents

will

beco

me

less

able

topr

ovid

eba

sic

serv

ices

such

ased

ucat

ion

over

tim

eSo

cial

Infa

ntm

orta

lity

(per

thou

sand

live

birt

hs)

Off

ers

aro

ugh

mea

sure

men

tofh

ealt

hca

re,w

hich

wou

ldal

sobe

expe

cted

tode

clin

ein

qual

ity

asgo

vern

men

tsbe

com

ere

sour

cecu

rsed

Soci

alP

reva

lenc

eof

unde

rnou

rish

men

t(%

popu

lati

on)

Indi

cate

sa

gene

ralm

easu

rem

ento

fthe

avai

labi

lity

offo

odw

ithi

na

coun

try.

The

reso

urce

curs

esu

gges

tsth

atun

dern

ouri

shm

entw

illin

crea

seas

gove

rnm

ents

beco

me

corr

upta

ndle

ssco

mpe

tent

Soci

alL

ife

expe

ctan

cy(a

ge/y

rs)

Per

haps

the

mos

tgen

eral

ofal

lind

icat

ors,

itm

easu

res

the

over

allq

ualit

yof

life

bytr

acki

ngho

wlo

ngpe

ople

live.

The

reso

urce

curs

esu

gges

tsth

atlif

eex

pect

ancy

will

dete

rior

ate

Page 15: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 239

Figure 2 Bruneian natural gas and crude oil production and exports,1980/1992–2007.

roughly constant or fell from 1987 to 2007 for Indonesia and Thailand (seeFigures 2–6). The 13 metrics, furthermore, quite clearly show that most po-litical, economic, and social indicators improved for all five countries overthe same period (see Table 4). While Myanmar performed the worst of allfive countries analyzed, for it was most reliant on oil and gas revenues andthe least diversified, even it displayed improvements in education, life ex-pectancy, and per capita GDP. When given a score for how well the groupof five Southeast Asian countries performed according to each metric, witha −1 indicating a deteriorating metric and a +1 signifying an improvement,they collectively showed progress in 47 indicators and regressed in only 17(data for two metrics did not exist).

However, the resource curse is not only about whether resource-richcountries will perform poorly in absolute terms, but also how well they do

Page 16: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

240 The Pacific Review

Figure 3 Indonesian natural gas and crude oil production and exports, 1980/1990–2005/2007.

compared to other countries, both ‘resource rich’ and ‘average’. To typify‘resource rich’ countries, Table 5 presents data relating to the same politi-cal, economic, and social metrics for the five largest oil producers of OPEC:Saudi Arabia, Iran, Venezuela, Kuwait, and United Arab Emirates from1987 to 2007. These five countries produced about 70 per cent of OPEC’sdaily output of crude oil in 2007, and they also represented 43 per cent ofthe world’s total daily output. To exemplify ‘average’ developing countries,Table 6 presents equivalent data for five countries that are still ‘developing’but also relatively industrialized: Brazil, China, India, Russia, and SouthAfrica. These countries are often grouped together as ‘newly industrializ-ing’ and framed as definitively ‘developing’ (Bozyk 2006).

Interestingly, relying on the same scoring technique, the five OPEC coun-tries as a whole progressed in 43 metrics and regressed in 17 (data for

Page 17: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 241

Figure 4 Malaysian natural gas and crude oil production and exports, 1980/1990–2005/2007.

five metrics was not available), and the group of developing countries pro-gressed in 56 metrics and regressed in only nine (see Figures 7 and 8). Whenmetrics are compared between groups of countries, a few trends emerge:

• In terms of transparency and political openness, Southeast Asian coun-tries performed better than both OPEC countries and developing coun-tries, scoring the highest average as a group on Transparency Interna-tional’s corruptions perception index;

• Southeast Asian average production of crude oil remained relativelyflat (slightly less than 420,000 barrels per day in both 1987 and 1997)compared to massive increases in production among OPEC members(a jump of more than 1.7 million barrels per day over the same pe-riod), yet natural gas production remained comparable to OPEC’s (off

Page 18: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

242 The Pacific Review

Figure 5 Myanmari natural gas and crude oil production and exports, 1980/1992–2005/2007.

by only about 200 billion cubic feet per day for two decades) and bothwere dwarfed by production from the developing countries, mostly dueto Russia, which produced more natural gas than the OPEC and South-east Asian countries combined;

• A significant amount of GDP and government revenues among South-east Asian countries came from the oil and gas sectors, making themsimilar to OPEC countries (both sets of countries average more thanone-quarter of GDP and revenues from oil and gas) but unlike the de-veloping countries (which received less than 10 per cent);

• The most remarkable gains in gross national product (GNP) per capita,fighting poverty, and keeping annual interest rates low occurred in theOPEC countries, which saw incomes rise over the period by $8,844

Page 19: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 243

Figure 6 Thai natural gas and crude oil production and exports, 1980/1990–2005/2007.

compared to $3,660 for Southeast Asian countries and only $2,746 forthe developing countries;

• All three groups of countries made progress on social indicators butthe developing countries had higher rates of child mortality (one-thirdhigher than the combined rates for Southeast Asia and OPEC) andlower life expectancy (9 per cent lower).

While this type of scoring is admittedly crude, it suggests that SoutheastAsian countries performed slightly better than the OPEC countries butslightly worse than the developing countries in the metrics related to theresource curse, although each group of countries made significant stridestowards improving various political, economic, and social metrics.

Page 20: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

244 The Pacific ReviewT

able

4R

esou

rce

curs

ein

dica

tors

for

Bru

nei,

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

,Ind

ones

ia,M

alay

sia,

and

Tha

iland

,198

7–20

07

Con

firm

reso

urce

1987

1997

2007

curs

e?(Y

/N)

Ave

rage

tran

spar

ency

rati

ng57

/85

108/

180

NB

rune

i—

——

—B

urm

a/M

yanm

ar—

—17

8/18

0—

Indo

nesi

a—

80/8

512

6/18

0N

Mal

aysi

a—

29/8

547

/180

NT

haila

nd—

61/8

580

/180

NA

vera

gefu

els

as%

ofal

lexp

orts

34%

29%

35%

NB

rune

i97

%88

%96

%N

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

3%0%

36%

YIn

done

sia

49%

39%

28%

NM

alay

sia

18%

17%

13%

NT

haila

nd3%

1%4%

NA

vera

gena

tura

lgas

prod

ucti

on(b

illio

ncu

bic

feet

)45

694

213

38Y

Bru

nei

308

324

487

YB

urm

a/M

yanm

ar40

4847

0Y

Indo

nesi

a1,

300

2,40

02,

600

YM

alay

sia

520

1,40

02,

250

YT

haila

nd11

054

088

5Y

Ave

rage

oilp

rodu

ctio

n(t

hous

and

barr

els

per

day)

418

485

417

NB

rune

i13

916

014

3N

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

128

21N

Indo

nesi

a1,

400

1,50

01,

100

NM

alay

sia

500

700

610

NT

haila

nd38

5520

9Y

Page 21: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 245A

vera

ge%

GD

Pin

oila

ndga

s27

%21

%26

%N

Bru

nei

80%

34%

40%

NB

urm

a/M

yanm

ar10

%15

%19

%Y

Indo

nesi

a8%

8.6%

10.8

%Y

Mal

aysi

a31

%39

%51

%Y

Tha

iland

4%6%

11%

YA

vera

geoi

land

gas

as%

ofgo

vern

men

trev

enue

s—

30%

44%

YB

rune

i95

%75

%94

%N

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

—37

%54

%Y

Indo

nesi

a56

%20

%25

%N

Mal

aysi

a—

10%

35%

YT

haila

nd—

10%

11%

NA

vera

geG

NP

/GN

Ipe

rca

pita

3,70

25,

564

7,36

2N

Bru

nei

$12,

170

$16,

310

$26,

740

NB

urm

a/M

yanm

ar$4

85$4

51$6

16N

Indo

nesi

a$7

62$1

,429

$1,3

49N

Mal

aysi

a$3

,359

$6,0

25$5

,237

NT

haila

nd$1

,732

$3,6

05$2

,866

NA

vera

ge%

popu

lati

onbe

low

$2a

day

—38

%36

%Y

Bru

nei

—2%

1%N

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

—30

%91

%Y

Indo

nesi

a—

59%

52%

NM

alay

sia

—27

%9%

NT

haila

nd—

24%

25%

NA

vera

gean

nual

rate

ofin

flati

on8%

10%

15%

YB

rune

i11

%9%

1%N

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

13.8

%25

%54

%Y

Indo

nesi

a8.

5%11

%13

%Y

Mal

aysi

a1.

3%2.

7%2.

3%N

Tha

iland

3.1%

4%2.

3%N

(Con

tinue

don

next

page

)

Page 22: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

246 The Pacific ReviewT

able

4R

esou

rce

curs

ein

dica

tors

for

Bru

nei,

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

,Ind

ones

ia,M

alay

sia,

and

Tha

iland

,198

7–20

07.(

Con

tinue

d)

Con

firm

reso

urce

1987

1997

2007

curs

e?(Y

/N)

Ave

rage

adul

tlit

erac

yra

te72

%88

%92

%N

Bru

nei

73%

91%

95%

NB

urm

a/M

yanm

ar49

%83

%90

%N

Indo

nesi

a74

%84

%91

%N

Mal

aysi

a73

%84

%89

%N

Tha

iland

91%

94%

93%

NA

vera

gech

ildm

orta

lity

(per

thou

sand

life

birt

hs)

6546

32N

Bru

nei

2211

9N

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

122

117

103

NIn

done

sia

109

6631

NM

alay

sia

3117

11N

Tha

iland

4220

7N

Ave

rage

prev

alen

ceof

unde

rnou

rish

men

t(%

popu

lati

on)

—11

%8%

NB

rune

i10

%4%

4%N

Bur

ma/

Mya

nmar

—10

%5%

NIn

done

sia

—9%

6%N

Mal

aysi

a—

3%3%

NT

haila

nd—

30%

22%

NA

vera

gelif

eex

pect

ancy

(age

/yrs

)66

6870

NB

rune

i73

7677

NB

urm

a/M

yanm

ar60

6061

NIn

done

sia

6165

68N

Mal

aysi

a70

7274

NT

haila

nd65

6971

N

Sour

ce:W

orld

Ban

k(1

990)

;Wor

ldB

ank

(199

9);I

nter

nati

onal

Mon

etar

yF

und

(200

6);W

orld

Ban

k(2

008)

;Tra

nspa

renc

yIn

tern

atio

nal(

2008

);U

.S.E

nerg

yIn

form

atio

nA

dmin

istr

atio

n(2

008b

).A

llm

onet

ary

figur

esha

vebe

enup

date

dto

$200

7.‘A

vera

ge’c

olum

nco

mpu

ted

asth

em

ean

ofth

efiv

enu

mbe

rsfo

rea

chco

lum

n.

Page 23: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 247T

able

5R

esou

rce

curs

ein

dica

tors

for

five

OP

EC

coun

trie

s,19

87–2

007

Con

firm

reso

urce

1987

1997

2007

curs

e?(Y

/N)

Ave

rage

tran

spar

ency

rati

ng—

—93

/180

—Sa

udiA

rabi

a—

—79

/180

—Ir

an—

—13

1/18

0—

Ven

ezue

la—

77/8

516

2/18

0N

Kuw

ait

——

60/1

80—

Uni

ted

Ara

bE

mir

ates

——

34/1

80—

Ave

rage

fuel

sas

%of

alle

xpor

ts78

%78

%83

%Y

Saud

iAra

bia

81%

89%

88%

NIr

an90

%86

%85

%N

Ven

ezue

la60

%80

%91

%Y

Kuw

ait

88%

89%

95%

YU

nite

dA

rab

Em

irat

es73

%45

%58

%N

Ave

rage

natu

ralg

aspr

oduc

tion

(bill

ion

cubi

cfe

et)

607

1,17

31,

946

YSa

udiA

rabi

a94

61,

601

2,68

0Y

Iran

565

1,66

03,

952

YV

enez

uela

657

994

936

NK

uwai

t18

732

744

1Y

Uni

ted

Ara

bE

mir

ates

682

1,28

21,

723

YA

vera

geoi

lpro

duct

ion

(tho

usan

dba

rrel

spe

rda

y)2,

288

3,92

64,

027

YSa

udiA

rabi

a4,

265

8,36

28,

722

YIr

an2,

298

3,66

43,

912

YV

enez

uela

1,75

23,

280

2,43

3N

Kuw

ait

1,58

52,

007

2,46

4Y

Uni

ted

Ara

bE

mir

ates

1,54

12,

316

2,60

3Y

(Con

tinue

don

next

page

)

Page 24: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

248 The Pacific ReviewT

able

5R

esou

rce

curs

ein

dica

tors

for

five

OP

EC

coun

trie

s,19

87–2

007

(Con

tinue

d)

Con

firm

reso

urce

1987

1997

2007

curs

e?(Y

/N)

Ave

rage

%G

DP

inoi

land

gas

33%

32%

34%

NSa

udiA

rabi

a60

%41

%32

%N

Iran

8%20

%33

%Y

Ven

ezue

la18

%22

%30

%Y

Kuw

ait

42%

45%

50%

YU

nite

dA

rab

Em

irat

es36

%33

%25

%N

Ave

rage

oila

ndga

sas

%of

gove

rnm

entr

even

ues

65%

69%

67%

NSa

udiA

rabi

a90

%81

%75

%N

Iran

70%

65%

58%

NV

enez

uela

45%

47%

52%

YK

uwai

t43

%75

%80

%Y

Uni

ted

Ara

bE

mir

ates

76%

75%

70%

NA

vera

geG

NP

/GN

Ipe

rca

pita

9,40

610

,436

18,2

50N

Saud

iAra

bia

$7,6

70$8

,410

$15,

470

NIr

an$3

,320

$1,7

70$3

,540

YV

enez

uela

$3,1

60$3

,370

$7,5

50N

Kuw

ait

$16,

000

$18,

560

$38,

420

NU

nite

dA

rab

Em

irat

es$1

6,88

0$2

0,07

0$2

6,27

0N

Ave

rage

%po

pula

tion

belo

w$2

ada

y16

%19

%13

%N

Saud

iAra

bia

15%

8%7%

NIr

an7%

3%8%

NV

enez

uela

30%

61%

31%

NK

uwai

t3%

1%1%

NU

nite

dA

rab

Em

irat

es25

%22

%19

.5%

NA

vera

gean

nual

rate

ofin

flati

on15

%10

%14

%N

Saud

iAra

bia

4%2%

4%N

Iran

23%

14%

20%

N

Page 25: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 249V

enez

uela

33%

38%

14%

NK

uwai

t11

%−5

%18

%N

Uni

ted

Ara

bE

mir

ates

3%0%

12%

NA

vera

gead

ultl

iter

acy

rate

72%

81%

89%

NSa

udiA

rabi

a79

%80

%83

%N

Iran

51%

76%

85%

NV

enez

uela

87%

92%

96%

NK

uwai

t70

%79

%93

%N

Uni

ted

Ara

bE

mir

ates

71%

79%

89%

NA

vera

gech

ildm

orta

lity

(per

thou

sand

life

birt

hs)

4828

19N

Saud

iAra

bia

6334

25N

Iran

9555

33N

Ven

ezue

la38

2819

NK

uwai

t23

1211

NU

nite

dA

rab

Em

irat

es21

128

NA

vera

gepr

eval

ence

ofun

dern

ouri

shm

ent(

%po

pula

tion

)10

%6%

7%N

Saud

iAra

bia

3%4%

4%N

Iran

7%3%

4%N

Ven

ezue

la11

%15

%18

%Y

Kuw

ait

24%

5%5%

NU

nite

dA

rab

Em

irat

es4%

3%3%

NA

vera

gelif

eex

pect

ancy

(age

/yrs

)69

7375

NSa

udiA

rabi

a67

7173

NIr

an63

6871

NV

enez

uela

7173

74N

Kuw

ait

7476

78N

Uni

ted

Ara

bE

mir

ates

7277

79N

Sour

ce:W

orld

Ban

k(1

990)

;Wor

ldB

ank

(199

9);I

nter

nati

onal

Mon

etar

yF

und

(200

6);W

orld

Ban

k(2

008)

;Tra

nspa

renc

yIn

tern

atio

nal(

2008

);U

.S.E

nerg

yIn

form

atio

nA

dmin

istr

atio

n(2

008b

).A

llm

onet

ary

figur

esha

vebe

enup

date

dto

$200

7.‘A

vera

ge’c

olum

nco

mpu

ted

asth

em

ean

ofth

efiv

enu

mbe

rsfo

rea

chco

lum

n.

Page 26: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

250 The Pacific ReviewT

able

6R

esou

rce

curs

ein

dica

tors

for

five

‘ave

rage

’dev

elop

ing

coun

trie

s,19

87–2

007

Con

firm

reso

urce

1987

1997

2007

curs

e?(Y

/N)

Ave

rage

tran

spar

ency

rati

ng—

54/8

580

/180

NB

razi

l—

46/8

572

/180

NC

hina

—52

/85

72/1

80N

Indi

a—

66/8

572

/180

NR

ussi

a—

76/8

514

3/18

0N

Sout

hA

fric

a—

32/8

543

/180

NA

vera

gefu

els

as%

ofal

lexp

orts

7.3%

8.4%

12.8

%N

Bra

zil

NC

hina

3%<

1%N

Indi

a<

1%N

Rus

sia

33.5

%42

%64

%Y

Sout

hA

fric

a<

1%N

Ave

rage

natu

ralg

aspr

oduc

tion

(bill

ion

cubi

cfe

et)

4,48

64,

376

5,41

6N

Bra

zil

105

195

346

YC

hina

494

801

2,44

6Y

Indi

a22

771

71,

119

YR

ussi

a21

,604

20,1

6823

,064

NSo

uth

Afr

ica

00

103

NA

vera

geoi

lpro

duct

ion

(tho

usan

dba

rrel

spe

rda

y)2,

318

2,16

43,

212

NB

razi

l56

684

11,

748

YC

hina

2,69

03,

200

3,72

9Y

Indi

a60

967

569

8Y

Rus

sia

7,72

46,

102

9,87

4N

Sout

hA

fric

a0

016

N

Page 27: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 251A

vera

ge%

GD

Pin

oila

ndga

s5%

4%4%

NB

razi

l<

1%N

Chi

na4%

<1%

NIn

dia

<1%

NR

ussi

a20

%22

%20

%N

Sout

hA

fric

a<

1%N

Ave

rage

oila

ndga

sas

%of

gove

rnm

entr

even

ues

5%5%

8%N

Bra

zil

<1%

NC

hina

2%<

1%N

Indi

a<

1%N

Rus

sia

21%

25%

40%

YSo

uth

Afr

ica

<1%

NA

vera

geG

NP

/GN

Ipe

rca

pita

$1,7

40$2

,514

$4,4

86N

Bra

zil

$2,0

40$5

,060

$5,8

60N

Chi

na$3

20$7

50$2

,370

NIn

dia

$360

$420

$950

NR

ussi

a$3

,310

$2,6

60$7

,530

NSo

uth

Afr

ica

$2,6

70$3

,680

$5,7

20N

Ave

rage

%po

pula

tion

belo

w$2

ada

y62

%43

%31

%N

Bra

zil

45%

23%

18%

NC

hina

68%

47%

18%

NIn

dia

81%

75%

73%

NR

ussi

a53

%25

%12

%N

Sout

hA

fric

a61

%45

%34

%N

Ave

rage

annu

alra

teof

infla

tion

49%

8%8%

NB

razi

l20

4%8%

4%N

Chi

na5%

2%7%

NIn

dia

9%6%

5%N

Rus

sia

14%

15%

14%

NSo

uth

Afr

ica

14%

8%9%

N(C

ontin

ued

onne

xtpa

ge)

Page 28: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

252 The Pacific ReviewT

able

6R

esou

rce

curs

ein

dica

tors

for

five

‘ave

rage

’dev

elop

ing

coun

trie

s,19

87–2

007

(Con

tinue

d)

Con

firm

reso

urce

1987

1997

2007

curs

e?(Y

/N)

Ave

rage

adul

tlit

erac

yra

te77

%81

%87

%N

Bra

zil

80%

85%

90%

NC

hina

81%

83%

91%

NIn

dia

48%

54%

66%

NR

ussi

a96

%99

%10

0%N

Sout

hA

fric

a79

%84

%88

%N

Ave

rage

child

mor

talit

y(p

erth

ousa

ndlif

ebi

rths

)72

5538

NB

razi

l74

4022

NC

hina

4642

22N

Indi

a13

710

272

NR

ussi

a30

2714

NSo

uth

Afr

ica

7164

59N

Ave

rage

prev

alen

ceof

unde

rnou

rish

men

t(%

popu

lati

on)

16%

11%

9%N

Bra

zil

11%

10%

6%N

Chi

na15

%12

%9%

NIn

dia

44%

24%

21%

NR

ussi

a5%

5%4%

NSo

uth

Afr

ica

5%5%

5%N

Ave

rage

life

expe

ctan

cy(a

ge/y

rs)

6466

66N

Bra

zil

6569

72N

Chi

na67

7073

NIn

dia

5962

65N

Rus

sia

6967

68N

Sout

hA

fric

a61

6050

Y

Sour

ce:W

orld

Ban

k(1

990)

;Wor

ldB

ank

(199

9);I

nter

nati

onal

Mon

etar

yF

und

(200

6);W

orld

Ban

k(2

008)

;Tra

nspa

renc

yIn

tern

atio

nal(

2008

);U

.S.E

nerg

yIn

form

atio

nA

dmin

istr

atio

n(2

008b

).A

llm

onet

ary

figur

esha

vebe

enup

date

dto

$200

7.‘A

vera

ge’c

olum

nco

mpu

ted

asth

em

ean

ofth

efiv

enu

mbe

rsfo

rea

chco

lum

n.

Page 29: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 253

Figure 7 Performance evaluation of average resource curse metrics for SoutheastAsian, OPEC, and developing countries.Notes: SEA = Brunei, Burma, Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand; OPEC = SaudiArabia, Iran, Venezuela, Kuwait and UAE; DEV = Brazil, China, India, Russiaand South Africa.

4. Explaining Southeast Asian performance

The factors underpinning the success of the key Southeast Asian coun-tries do imply that certain social and political variables shape economicdevelopment and welfare outcomes. With this in mind, the following sectionsuggests that three factors, some unique to Southeast Asia, may explain whythey have avoided the resource curse so far: diffusion of resources, politicalinstitutions, and cooperative production.

First, point resources such as oil fields tend to be easily dominated byoligarchs and elites, but in Southeast Asia oil and gas reserves are morediffused over a broader geographic area than in other regions. Indonesia’soil and gas fields, for example, are spread across Riau province in CentralSumatra, the Java Sea, parts of the western Pacific Ocean, East Kalimantan,and Natuna, reserves that occupy more than 433,000 square kilometers ofonshore and offshore land. Other oil and gas fields, like those in the Gulf ofThailand, are jointly extracted by Malaysia and Thailand. The exceptions

Page 30: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

254 The Pacific Review

Fig

ure

8A

vera

gere

sour

cecu

rse

met

rics

com

pare

dbe

twee

nSo

uthe

astA

sian

,OP

EC

,and

deve

lopi

ngco

untr

ies.

Sour

ce:F

igur

esta

ken

from

Tab

les

1,2,

and

3.N

otes

:Tra

nspa

renc

yra

ting

isou

tof8

5co

untr

ies

for

1997

and

185

coun

trie

sin

2007

(the

high

erth

era

nkin

gth

epo

orer

the

scor

e).N

atur

alga

spr

oduc

tion

isin

billi

oncu

bic

feet

.Cru

deoi

lpro

duct

ion

isin

thou

sand

barr

els

per

day.

GN

I/G

NP

per

capi

taha

sbe

enup

date

dto

$200

7.P

over

tyra

teis

defin

edas

the

perc

enta

geof

peop

leliv

ing

onle

ssth

an$2

per

day.

Chi

ldm

orta

lity

refe

rsto

num

ber

ofch

ildre

nun

der

the

age

of5

that

die

ever

yye

arou

tof1

,000

.

Page 31: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 255

are obviously Brunei and Myanmar, two countries within Southeast Asiathat performed worse according to the resource curse metrics.

Second, political institutions and the openness of the political system canplay a determining factor in whether the benefits from natural resourcesare equitably distributed. Bulte et al. (2005) and Ross (1999) have notedthat political regimes that enforce property rights and exhibit a predictablejudicial system tend to avoid the resource curse. Sandbu (2006) theorizesthat a strong system of taxation can improve natural resource management,and Andersen and Aslaksen (2008) think that resource abundance is lessdamaging in parliamentary democracies. Robinson et al. (2006) hypothe-size that the overall impact of resource booms depends critically on thepresence of political institutions that are accountable, rational, and merito-cratic. The major oil and gas producing Southeast Asian countries, with theexception of Myanmar, are all relatively democratic and transparent, haverobust property rights, and respect rule of law, with moderate to strongcivil society groups and informed constituents. While certainly not uniform,these countries also all tended to focus intently on import substitution, in-dustrialization, economic diversification, and social betterment in the 1980sand 1990s.

Third, in their investigation of the resource curse Mehlum et al. (2006a,2006b) identify ‘producer friendly’ countries where rent-seeking occurs butis complementary to resource production, and ‘grabber friendly’ countrieswhere rent-seeking competes with production. Producer friendly nationsare those where governments enroll entrepreneurs and private actors intothe production process; grabber friendly ones are those that try to excludethem and keep resources to themselves, resulting in specialization but alsoconcentration, corruption, and personal enrichment. The presence of co-operative production, where extraction of a resource is a partnership, en-sures that revenues are distributed to a greater number of actors. Foreignmultinational firms can also serve as buffers against export instability (Ross1999).

Southeast Asian countries, even Myanmar, adhere to a model of co-operative oil and gas production. Rather than resist industrialization andcooperation with international firms, these countries have formed activepartnerships with major oil and gas companies to assist with exploration,production, and distribution. The single largest producer of oil in Indone-sia, for example, is not the state-owned energy company Pertamina but themultinational Chevron, followed by the corporations of British Petroleum,ConocoPhillips, ExxonMobil, and Total. The China National Offshore OilCorporation and PetroChina have strong roles in Indonesia, and American,Chinese, French, Indian, South Korea, and Vietnamese firms own substan-tial amounts of oil and natural gas in Myanmar. Indeed, as of early 2009, atleast 10 multinational companies and more than 70 subsidiaries were oper-ating in each of the five Southeast Asian countries selected here, implying

Page 32: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

256 The Pacific Review

that each has attuned their oil and gas sectors to a cooperative rather thancompetitive or ‘grabber friendly’ model.

Clearly, the presence of diffuse resources, strong political institutions,and complementary production may be insufficient alone to militate againstthe resource curse, and a more comprehensive theoretical justification be-hind why Southeast Asian countries appear to have avoided it would makefor enticing research. It should be emphasized that the explanation pre-sented here is a preliminary one, in need of refinement and further scrutiny.Research exploring why the five OPEC countries selected for comparisonappear to be improving in their resource curse metrics would also make forfruitful scholarship.

5. Conclusion

First, the prevalence of the resource curse can be reasonably reduced to anumber of measurable factors. Countries suffering from the resource cursedisplay higher rates and levels of corruption, resource extraction, economicconcentration, government dependency, inflation, poverty, infant mortal-ity, and undernourishment; and exhibit lower rates of transparency andaccountability, per capita income, literacy, and life expectancy over time.Understood in this context, the resource curse serves as a useful frameworkfor highlighting how a relative abundance of natural resources is insufficientalone to promote economic development and explains why many resource-rich countries such as Algeria, Angola, the Congo, Columbia, Ecuador,Gabon, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Libya, Mexico, Nigeria, Qatar, Saudi Arabia,Sierra Leone, Trinidad and Tobago, and Venezuela have performed poorlyat various points in time.

Second, however, the resource curse does not account for the eco-nomic success of Australia, Botswana, Canada, Chile, Hong Kong, Norway,Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, and the United States, countries that haveharnessed natural resources to improve economic diversification, raise stan-dards of living, and increase economic growth. The resource curse, further-more, does not match the political, economic, and social reality in the fiveSoutheast Asian countries with the highest rates of oil and gas extractionand production. The resource curse is too crude and deterministic a methodto adequately explain the political economy of oil and gas production inBrunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, Myanmar, and Thailand from 1987 to 2007.In each of these countries, including Myanmar, economies have becomemore diversified, per capita incomes have risen, and life expectancies andliving standards improved. Political transparency and accountability haveremained constant in Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand, and oil and gashave contributed less to government revenues over time in Indonesia andThailand. When compared to the performance of five OPEC countries(Saudi Arabia, Iran, Venezuela, Kuwait, and United Arab Emirates) and

Page 33: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 257

a set of five developing countries (Brazil, China, India, the Russian Fed-eration, and South Africa), Southeast Asian countries have tended to per-form slightly better than OPEC but worse than the developing countries,although each group of countries has made remarkable progress at improv-ing political, economic, and social indicators. Ultimately, the situation infive Southeast Asian countries, five OPEC countries, and five developingcountries suggests that extractive resources themselves are neither a cursenor a blessing.

References

Andersen, J. J. and Aslaksen, S. (2008) ‘Constitutions and the resource curse?’,Journal of Development Economics 87(2): 227–46.

Auty, R. M. (2004) ‘Natural resources and civil strife: a two-stage process,’ Geopol-itics 9(1): 29–48.

Auty, R. M. (2006) ‘Transition to mid-income democracies or to failed states?’, inR. M. Auty and I. de Soysa (eds) Energy, Wealth, and Governance in the Cau-casus and Central Asia: Lessons Not Learned, London: Routledge, pp. 3–16.

Baer, R. (2003) ‘The fall of the house of Saud’, Atlantic Monthly, May, pp. 34–48.Bapna, M. (2006) ‘Infrastructure, poverty, and the role of the MDBs’, Testimony

Before the Senate Committee on Foreign Relations, 12 July; accessed at http://foreign.senate.gov/testimony/2006/BapnaTestimony060712.pdf, 10 January2009.

Bevan, D., Collier, P. and Gunning, J. W. (1999) The Political Economy of Poverty,Equity, and Growth: Nigeria and Indonesia, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Bozyk, P. (2006) Globalization and the Transformation of Foreign Economic Policy,London: Ashgate.

Bulte, E. H., Damania, R. and Deacon, R T. (2005) ‘Resource intensity, institutions,and development’, World Development 33(7): 1029–44.

Corden, W. M. and Neary, J. P. (1982) ‘Booming sector and Dutch disease eco-nomics’, The Economic Journal 92(368): 825–48.

De Soysa, I. (2000) ‘The resource curse: are civil wars driven by rapacity orpaucity?’, in M. Berdal and D. M. Malone (eds) Greed and Grievance: Eco-nomic Agendas in Civil Wars, London: Lynne Reinner, pp. 113–35.

Dunning, T. and Wirpsa, L. (2004) ‘Oil and the political economy of conflict inColumbia and beyond: a linkages approach’, Geopolitics 9(1): 81–92.

Esanov, A., Raiser, M. and Buiter, W. (2006) ‘Nature’s blessing or nature’s curse?’,in R. M. Auty and I. de Soysa (eds) Energy, Wealth, and Governance inthe Caucasus and Central Asia: Lessons Not Learned, London: Routledge,pp. 39–56.

Humphreys, M., Sachs, J. D. and Stiglitz, J. E. (2007) ‘What is the problem withnatural resource wealth?’, in M. Humphreys, J. D. Sachs and J. E. Stiglitz(eds) Escaping the Resource Curse, New York: Columbia University Press,pp. 1–21.

International Energy Agency (2008) World Energy Outlook 2008, Paris: OECD.International Monetary Fund (2006) World Economic Outlook Database, April; ac-

cessed at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2006/01/data/dbcselm.cfm?G=2001, 15 February 2009.

Karl, T. L. (1998) ‘State building and petro revenues’, in M. Garcelon, E. W. Walker,A. Patten-Wood and A. Radovich (eds) The Geopolitics of Oil, Gas, and Ecol-ogy in the Caucasus and Caspian Sea Basin, Berkeley: Berkeley Institute ofSlavic, East European, and Eurasian Studies, pp. 3–14.

Page 34: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

258 The Pacific Review

Karl, T. L. (2000) ‘Crude calculations: OPEC lessons for the Caspian region’, in R.Ebel and R. Menon (eds) Energy and Conflict in Central Asia and the Cauca-sus, New York: Rowman & Littlefield, pp. 29–54.

Karl, T. L. (2005) ‘Understanding the resource curse’, in S. Tsalik and A. Schiffrin(eds) Covering Oil: A Reporter’s Guide to Energy and Development, NewYork: Open Society Institute, pp. 21–7.

Kenny, C. (2007) Infrastructure Governance and Corruption: Where Next, Washing-ton, DC: The World Bank Sustainable Development Network.

Le Billon, P. (2004) ‘Geopolitical economy of resource wars’, Geopolitics 9(1): 1–28.Maassarani, T. F., Drakos, M. T. and Pajkowska, J. (2007) ‘Extracting corporate re-

sponsibility: towards a human rights impact assessment’, Cornell InternationalLaw Journal 40(1): 136–69.

Mehlum, H., Moene, K. and Torvik, R. (2006a) ‘Institutions and the resource curse’,Economic Journal 116(508): 1–20.

Mehlum, H., Moene, K. and Torvik, R. (2006b) ‘Cursed by resources or institu-tions?’ The World Economy 29(8): 1117–31.

Mikesell, R. (1997) ‘Explaining the resource curse, with special reference tomineral-exporting countries’, Resources Policy 23(4): 191–7.

O’Lear, S. (2004) ‘Resources and conflict in the Caspian Sea’, Geopolitics 9(1):161–75.

Omorogbe, Y. O. (2006) ‘Alternative regulation and governance reform in resource-rich developing countries of Africa’, in B. Barton, L. Barrera-Hernandez, A.Lucas and A. Ronne (eds) Regulating Energy and Natural Resources, Oxford:Oxford University Press, pp. 39–65.

Robinson, J. A., Torvik, R. and Verdier, T. (2006) ‘Political foundations of the re-source curse’, Journal of Development Economics 79(2): 447–68.

Ross, M. L. (1999) ‘The political economy of the resource curse’, World Politics51(2): 297–322.

Rosser, A. (2006) ‘Escaping the resource curse’, New Political Economy 11(4):557–70.

Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (1999) ‘The big push, natural resource booms andgrowth’, Journal of Development Economics 59(1): 43–76.

Sandbu, M. E. (2006) ‘Natural wealth accounts: a proposal for alleviating the naturalresource curse’, World Development 34(7): 1153–70.

Silberfein, M. (2004) ‘The geopolitics of conflict and diamonds in Sierra Leone’,Geopolitics 9(1): 213–41.

Sovacool, B. K. (2008) ‘The costs of failure: a preliminary assessment of major en-ergy accidents, 1907 to 2007’, Energy Policy 36(5): 1802–20.

Steiner, R. (2007) ‘Public oversight of extractive industries in developing countries’,Paper Presented at the Revenue Watch Institute Public Oversight of Extrac-tive Industries Conference, Baku, Azerbaijan, September.

Stevens, P. (2004) ‘Resource curse and investment in energy industries’, in C. Cleve-land (ed.) Encyclopedia of Energy 5, pp. 451–9.

Stiglitz, J. E. (2005) ‘Making natural resources into a blessing rather than a curse’,in S. Tsalik and A. Schiffrin (eds) Covering Oil: A Reporter’s Guide to Energyand Development, New York: Open Society Institute, pp. 13–20.

Tan, A. T. H. (2008) ‘The security of the ASEAN energy supply chain’, Seminar onSustainable Development and Energy Security, Institute of Southeast AsianStudies, Singapore, 22–23 April 2008,

Transparency International (2008) TI Corruption Perceptions Index; accessed athttp://www.transparency.org/policy research/surveys indices/cpi, 22 January2009.

Page 35: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

B. K. Sovacool: Political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia 259

Tsalik, S. (2003) ‘The hazards of petroleum wealth’, in R. Ebel (ed.) Caspian OilWindfalls: Who Will Benefit?, Washington, DC: Open Society Institute, pp.1–15.

U.S. Energy Information Administration (2007) World Proved Reserves of Oil andNatural Gas, Most Recent Estimates, Washington, DC: U.S. Department ofEnergy.

U.S. Energy Information Administration (2008a) Historical Oil Prices; accessedat http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/steo/pub/fsheets/real prices.html, 4 February2009.

U.S. Energy Information Administration (2008b) Country Energy Profiles, Wash-ington, DC: U.S. Department of Energy.

Watts, M. (2004) ‘Resource curse? Governmentality, oil, and power in the NigerDelta, Nigeria’, Geopolitics 9(1): 50–69.

World Bank (1990) World Development Repot 1990: World Development Indicators,Oxford: Oxford University Press.

World Bank (1999) World Development Report 1998/1999: Knowledge for Develop-ment, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

World Bank (2008) World Development Indicators, Washington, DC: The WorldBank.

Page 36: The political economy of oil and gas in Southeast Asia

Copyright of Pacific Review is the property of Routledge and its content may not be copied or emailed to

multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users

may print, download, or email articles for individual use.