the role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

Upload: jlevans2012

Post on 05-Apr-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    1/46

    The role of labor markets in business cycle

    statistics

    Jennifer Evans* and Irina Stanga

    June 14, 2012

    Supervisor: Stefano Gnocchi

    Abstract

    This paper investigates cross-country heterogeneity in business cycle moments

    over the past 30 years to assess whether recent developments are global phenom-

    ena, or limited to the case of United States. Furthermore, we consider if labor mar-

    ket flexibility, a proposed driver of these developments, is relevant for other OECD

    countries. While there is a substantial degree of heterogeneity across countries, we

    find a number of statistical similarities between Italy and the United States. We

    profile the labor market in each country, and cast doubt on the ability of the labor

    market to account for the correlation of productivity with unemployment. How-

    ever, our analysis finds evidence that the labor market can explain the vanishing

    procyclicality of productivity.

    JEL: E24, E32

    Keywords: Great Moderation, macroeconomic volatility, labor market

    Barcelona GSE, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona

    1

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    2/46

    Contents

    1 Introduction 1

    2 Literature Review 3

    3 Data and Methodology 6

    4 Results 7

    4.1 Comparisons across countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

    4.1.1 Country groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

    4.2 Labor markets profiles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

    4.2.1 Temporary workers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

    4.2.2 Decline of unionization rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

    4.2.3 Sectoral shift from manufacturing to services . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

    4.2.4 Labor market conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

    4.3 Additional business cycle moments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

    5 Conclusion 16

    6 Appendix 20

    6.1 Robustness check . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

    6.2 Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

    2

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    3/46

    1 Introduction

    Business cycle statistics in the United States have changed considerably over the past 30

    years. Three developments in particular have captured the attention of the economics

    profession: (i) a sign shift in the unconditional correlation between productivity and

    unemployment, (ii) a decrease in the procyclicality of productivity and (iii) an increase

    in the volatility of employment and hours relative to output, and the decline in volatility

    of other macroeconomic series, known as the Great Moderation.

    While separate theories have been proposed to explain these shifts, structural changes

    in the labor market are a common theme. For example, Gali and van Rens (2010) point

    to authors who argue that the Great Moderation may have been driven at least in part

    by increased wage flexibility.1 Both Gali and van Rens (2010) and Barnichon (2010) find

    that the shifts in correlation and procyclicality can be explained in part by a reduction in

    labor market frictions. Gali and van Rens (2010) find a common thread in their paper by

    using a structural model to show how a reduction in labor market frictions can increasewage flexibility, finding evidence to link all three developments to the labor market.

    However, these business cycle developments have been documented for US only.

    The scope of this paper is to investigate the cross-country heterogeneity in these busi-

    ness cycle moments in order to assess whether the facts emphasized by Gali and van

    Rens (2010) and Barnichon (2010) are global phenomena, or limited to the case of US. We

    focus on the unconditional sample moments for the cyclical component of key macroe-

    conomic variables across 10 OECD countries (including the United States, for compari-

    son purposes). Furthermore, we consider if the theories proposed to explain these facts,

    which fit well with developments in the US economy, are relevant for other OECD coun-

    tries. More specifically, in the first part of the analysis we assess the evolution of the

    1See Gourio (2007), Champagne and Kurmann (2010), Nucci and Riggi (2009)

    1

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    4/46

    correlation between productivity and unemployment in order to uncover any similari-

    ties across countries and form groups. Thereafter, we focus on the group that includes

    US and consider whether the explanations based on labor market flexibility are sup-

    ported by empirical evidence, i.e. whether countries that belong to the same group had

    similar developments related to the degree of labor market rigidities. Finally, we ana-

    lyze additional business cycle statistics, such as the cyclicality of labor productivity and

    the volatilities of macroeconomic series, in order to determine whether the three devel-

    opments listed above are consistent and reflect the characteristics of the labor market

    within our group of interest.

    Our paper finds a substantial degree of heterogeneity in the patters of correlations

    between labor productivity and unemployment across OECD economies. A few coun-

    tries, such as Canada and Finland, display unique patterns, while the others can be

    grouped according to the sign of the correlation or the timing of the sign switch. Sur-

    prisingly, we find that the countries most comparable to the US are Italy and Norway.

    By profiling the labor markets of the United States and Italy, we cast doubt on the ability

    of the labor market to account for the correlation of productivity with unemployment

    and output, but find evidence that the evolutions on the labor markets are consistent

    with the vanishing procyclicality of productivity.

    First we place our paper in the literature, and discuss the outcomes of previous stud-

    ies into the Great Moderation and additional business cycle developments. Thereafter

    we present the data and our methodology. We then focus on our results and a discus-

    sion of labor market characteristics in the United States and Italy from the 1970s. Finally,

    we conclude.

    2

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    5/46

    2 Literature Review

    The studies that document the three business cycle developments considered above

    point towards two main explanations. The first one is related to a change in the relative

    importance between technology shocks and non-technology shocks and the second one

    is represented by the decrease in the rigidities on the labor market. We further discuss

    in detail the theories presented in the literature and the basic mechanisms that account

    for these changes.

    Barnichon (2010) documents a sign switch of the correlation between unemployment

    and productivity in the mid 80s and estimates a VAR in order to trace the impact of a

    technology and non-technology shock on these two variables. Based on the empirical

    evidence, he points towards two main explanations for the sign switch. First, since a

    positive technology shock leads to a positive correlation between the variables, while a

    non-technology shock generates a negative one, the sign shift could be explained by a

    change in the relative size of the shocks. Second, the evidence indicates a decrease inthe pro-cyclicality of productivity after the mid 80s based on structural changes in the

    labor market.

    Barnichon (2010) provides a structural interpretation using a New-Keynesian model

    with sticky prices, search and matching frictions and variable labor effort. In this con-

    text, a non-technology shock is interpreted as an aggregate demand shock that deter-

    mines firms to raise the labor input in order to be able to satisfy the increase in demand.

    Since employment cannot be adjusted immediately due to hiring costs, firms increase

    hours and effort leading to a rise in productivity. However, the use of the intensive mar-

    gin is limited because the disutility of workers increases in hours and effort, therefore

    firms will start to post vacancies and unemployment will decrease. This is the mecha-

    nism through which a positive non-technology shock leads to a negative productivity-

    3

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    6/46

    unemployment correlation.

    In contrast, a positive technology shock generates an increase in productivity, which

    leads firms to lower hours and effort initially, because employment is subject to fric-

    tions and hence they face firing costs. This reduction leads to a decrease in the value

    of a marginal worker and therefore firms will post fewer vacancies and unemployment

    will increase. As a consequence, a technology shock leads to a positive productivity-

    unemployment correlation.

    In line with this evidence, the two events that explain the correlation sign switch

    are an increase in the size of technology shocks relative to other types of shocks and

    a decline in the response of productivity to non-technology shocks after the mid 80s.

    In the model, the declining procyclicality of productivity is explained through a more

    flexible labor market due to smaller hiring frictions and an increased elasticity of hours

    per worker. The empirical evidence that could support these developments consists of a

    rising share of temporary workers, a decline in the unionization rate and the emergence

    of online recruitment sites in the last two decades.

    The results of the model indicate that about 40% of the increase in the correlation is

    due to changes in the sizes of the shocks and approximately 60% can be associated with

    the structural changes. Our purpose is to analyze whether these facts are valid for all

    the countries where the switch in the sign of the correlation took place and therefore

    determine whether they provide a comprehensive explanation or the evidence can be

    extended by considering other factors.

    Gali and Gambetti (2008) estimate a structural time varying VAR on output, hours

    and labor productivity and find evidence for a decline in the cyclical response of la-

    bor productivity to non-technology shocks. Furthermore, the authors document a drop

    in the correlation between total hours worked and productivity conditional on non-

    technology shocks.

    4

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    7/46

    The potential explanation for these findings could be related to the variations in ef-

    fort that take place due to the high adjustments costs in employment. Since it is costly

    to hire or fire new people when faced with fluctuations in demand, variations in effort

    represent a tool for the firms to easily adjust effective labor input. In this context, the

    measured hours fluctuate less than their effective counterpart and therefore labor pro-

    ductivity will tend to be procyclical. An increase in the flexibility of the labor markets

    leads to a decrease in the variations in effort and would therefore explain a decline in

    the procyclicality of labor productivity following an aggregate demand shock.

    These changes in conditional moments are synchronized with the decline in output

    volatility from the early 1980s, however it has not been established whether they share

    a common explanation based on structural modifications in the labor market.

    On the basis of a similar explanation related to a reduction in hiring costs, Gali and

    van Rens (2010) also find evidence for a vanishing procyclicality of labor productivity

    and a relative increase in the volatility of employment and the real wage with respect

    to output. The mechanism is illustrated through a model with labor market frictions,

    variable effort, and endogenous wage rigidities in which effort is considered as a factor

    input which is not subject to rigidities and can partly substitute labor. Since frictions

    on the labor market create difficulties in adjusting employment, a reduction in frictions

    leads to a drop in the volatility of this input and an increase in the one of employment

    relative to output. Hence, the procyclicality of productivity is influenced by variations

    in effort.

    The present study focuses on providing empirical evidence for the explanation based

    on an increased flexibility in the labor markets and we leave for future research the con-

    sideration of the relative importance of the technology and aggregate demand shocks.

    5

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    8/46

    3 Data and Methodology

    Our analysis is based on the following macroeconomic time series at the individual

    country level: real GDP, average hours per worker, employment, unemployment and

    productivity. We consider quarterly, seasonally-adjusted data for the period 1970Q1-

    2011Q42 for Australia, Canada, Finland, France, Italy, Japan, Norway, Sweden, United

    Kingdom and the United States. There is extensive research related to business cycle

    developments in the United States, and we include it as a benchmark with which to

    compare other OECD countries. The main data source is the OECD, although some

    OECD series were extracted from the FRED database of the St. Louis Federal Reserve

    Bank.

    To profile the labor markets in our countries of interest, we focus explicitly on tem-

    porary workers, unionization rates and sectoral shifts from manufacturing to services.

    The main source of this indicators is the CEP-OECD Institutions Data Set (See Nickell

    (2006)).Following Barnichon (2010), all series were de-trended with the HP-filter and a

    smoothing parameter of 16003 and our calculations are performed on the deviations

    of each series from its trend. Labor productivity is based on our own calculations, and

    is computed as real GDP divided by the total hours worked. The correlation of produc-

    tivity with unemployment and with output, and the volatilities of relevant times series

    are computed as 10 year rolling windows over the sample.

    2Exceptions: Finland 1970:Q1-2010:Q4; UK 1972:Q1-2011:Q43Our results are robust when data is transformed with the fourth-difference operator used in Stock

    and Watson (2002). See the Appendix, section 6.1

    6

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    9/46

    4 Results

    In the first part of the analysis we present our results regarding the patterns of correla-

    tions between unemployment and labor productivity for each country. Thereafter we

    propose a grouping based on similarities regarding the signs and breaks. In the second

    part of the analysis we zoom in on the group of countries that includes US in order to

    make a a brief and qualitative assessment of whether explanations based on the labor

    market, as cited in Barnichon (2010) and Gali and van Rens (2010), are consistent with

    the empirical facts in each country. Furthermore, we enrich our analysis by examin-

    ing the volatility of employment and hours relative to output and the procyclicality of

    productivity for the selected group of countries.

    4.1 Comparisons across countries

    The most striking result from our analysis is the parallel sign shifts experienced by the

    United States and Italy (See figures 3,6-7 in the Appendix, section 6.2). The first signif-

    icant break in the data occurs for both countries in the mid-1980s, when the correlation

    became significantly positive. After 1993, both countries display a second break, and

    the correlation becomes zero for the United States and significantly negative for Italy.

    Norway experiences a significant sign shift slightly later than the US and Italy. It

    breaks from a zero correlation in the beginning of the sample to significantly positive

    starting in the late 1980s.

    New Zealand, Sweden, UK and Australia display a switch in correlation in the late

    70s. Previously, the correlation for New Zealand and Sweden was negative, while in the

    UK and Australia the correlation was not significantly different from zero. In the late

    70s, the correlations become positive for New Zealand, Sweden and Australia, but the

    positive correlation is not significant over the full length of the sample. The correlation

    7

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    10/46

    became negative for the UK in the late 90s, although not significantly different from

    zero.

    The correlations for France and Japan are significantly negative after the 1980s and

    do not display any switch in the sign (figure 8). In both countries there are brief periods

    in which the correlation is not significantly different from zero.

    Canada is the only country for which the switch in correlation is from positive to

    negative (See figure 1). The date of this change is in the first quarter of 1983 and is

    characterized by a trend instead of a sharp break. The correlation for Finland is not

    statistically different from zero along the entire sample (figure 9).

    Italy, Norway and the US are the only countries that exhibit sharp breaks over the

    sample period. In the case of Australia, Canada, Finland, France, Japan, New Zealand,

    Sweden and the UK, the correlation is relatively smooth.

    The evolution of the correlation in each individual country can be seen in figures 1-6

    in the Appendix, section 6.2.

    4.1.1 Country groups

    While some countries display similar traits to the United States over the period of in-

    vestigation, we also find significant heterogeneity in both the sign of the correlation and

    the approximate date of the shift. Furthermore, some countries displayed a sharp break,

    and for others the sign shift was characterized by a trend instead of a sharp break. We

    classify the countries according to i) the presence of a sign shift, ii) the approximate date

    of the shift and iii) the shape of correlation over time.

    1) United States, Italy and Norway

    2) UK, Sweden, New Zealand, Australia

    3) France and Japan

    8

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    11/46

    4) Canada and Finland4

    In the next section, we will focus on the empirical evidence regarding the labor mar-

    ket and additional business cycle moments in the United States and Italy. We are in-

    terested in these two countries in particular because their correlations have a similar

    shape, exhibit the same sign shift and break at the same date. In addition, there are no

    immediately apparent reasons why the correlation should be so similar between these

    countries. They do not share a common labor market or currency union and have dif-

    ferent political systems.

    4.2 Labor markets profiles

    To explain the sign switch in the correlation between productivity and unemployment,

    the literature has offered up a number of explanations, including the changing relative

    importance of technology shocks and shocks to aggregate demand, an improvement in

    monetary policy and a decrease in labor market frictions 5. In the absence of a structural

    model, we will focus on the hypothesis that labor market frictions drove the change in

    the correlation of unemployment and productivity. We will limit our comparison to the

    United States and Italy, two countries that at first glance do not seem to have very much

    in common in terms of labor market flexibility.

    Barnichon (2010) offers insight into why decreasing labor market frictions would

    affect the correlation between unemployment and productivity. He suggests that if hir-

    ing costs decline, it is easier for firms to adjust the number of workers in response to

    fluctuations in demand. As a result, hours per worker and effort6 fluctuate less. Barni-

    4See figures 7 - 9 in the Appendix5See Barnichon (2010), Gali and Gambetti (2008), Gali and van Rens (2010)6Effort, which may be measured as approximate labor utilization by the number of hours per em-

    ployee, overtime hours, the ratio of production to non-production workers, accident rates, and materialsinput growth (Marchetti and Nucci (2006)) is not included in our analysis

    9

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    12/46

    chon (2010) also finds that the elasticity of hours per worker has increased leading to an

    increased volatility of hours per worker.

    Gali and van Rens (2010) and Gali and Gambetti (2008) offer similar explanations

    to explain the shift in correlation between productivity and output. Gali and van Rens

    (2010) suggest that labor market frictions make it costly to adjust employment, which

    implies firms rely more on the intensive margins (hours and effort) in response to de-

    mand. As a result of their structural model analysis, they find that as frictions fall,

    it becomes optimal to adjust labor more through employment and less through effort.

    Furthermore, they state that recent evidence points to a rise in the elasticity of labor

    input with respect to output.

    Following Barnichon (2010), we should expect to see similar characteristics and tim-

    ing in the United States and Italy along the following dimensions:

    1) a rising share of temporary workers

    2) a decline in the unionization rate

    3) a sectoral shift from manufacturing to services7

    We focus here on a comparison between United States and Italy according to these

    three points and the additional moments.

    4.2.1 Temporary workers

    Temporary workers is a difficult dimension on which to compare the United States and

    Italy, in large part because several definitions of what it means to be a temporary worker

    exist.8 However, in the United States it is clear that temporary workers played a bigger

    7The connection between the sectoral shift from manufacturing to services and labor market flexibilitymay not be immediately obvious. However, DAgostino et al. (2006) find that institutional frameworksaffecting the degree of flexibility in the labor market play an important role in the level of service sectoremployment. For example, in their econometric analysis of the determinants of service sector employ-ment, they find a negative effect of the rate of national union density on the service sector employmentshare. They report similar results for the effect of national employment protection legislation.

    8See Osterman (2001) for a full list of definitions.

    10

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    13/46

    role in the US economy starting in the late 70s and early 80s. According to Osterman

    (2001), from "1979 to 1995 the temporary help supply industry grew at a rate of 11.2

    percent a year, five times the rate for total U.S. non-farm employment". In addition,

    Osterman (2001) shows that, according to Census data, between "1988 and 1996 fully 22

    percent were in business services and engineering/management services, i.e. the two

    sectors, which supply contract and contingent labour".

    The series for temporary workers in Italy also displays an upward trend starting

    with the mid 80s (figure 11).9 The slope of the trend becomes more pronounced after

    1993, when a series of labor market reforms were implemented in Italy. According to

    this criterion, the two countries seem to have a similar evolution.

    4.2.2 Decline of unionization rate

    The evolutions of the trade union densities are presented in figure 11 in the Appendix.

    The rate of union membership in the United States experienced a "modest and concen-

    trated decline in the 1979 to 1984 period" (Gosling and Lemieux (2004)), with the peak of

    union membership in absolute terms in 1979 with 21 million (Mayer (2004)). However

    by 2003 union membership stood at 15.8 million (Mayer (2004)). In terms of propor-

    tion, only 11.5% of employed workers were union members in 2003 (Mayer (2004)). In

    addition to a decrease in membership, unions also became less relevant for setting em-

    ployment terms. Union wage setting in the 1990s is described as decentralized with

    "unions [having] little influence over pay in the private sector" (Gosling and Lemieux

    (2004)).

    The evolution of the trade union density in Italy displays a declining trend starting

    with the beginning of the 80s. The pattern is very similar to the one of US, although in

    9Unfortunately we lack data before 1983 so we cant assess whether there was a structural break in themid 80s or the increase started much earlier.

    11

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    14/46

    absolute terms the unionization rate for US is much lower than the one in Italy over the

    entire sample period. However, in order to accurately compare the two countries along

    this dimension we need to consider as well the evolution of the coverage rate in Italy,

    since for US the two indicators coincide. In the case of Italy, the coverage and unioniza-

    tion rates differ because the impact of the policies adopted by the members of the union

    extend to all the workers and not just to union members. The coverage ratio has de-

    creased since the beginning of the 1970s until 2000 and displays two main shifts in the

    trend, one in the mid 80s and the other one at the beginning of the 90s. These changes

    can be associated with the two breaks in the correlation between unemployment and

    productivity observed in our data, as well as two labor market reforms that took place

    in Italy, one in the mid 1980s and one in 1993 (Jimenez-Rodriguez and Russo, 2010).

    The process of deregulation from 1984 consisted mainly of the introduction of part-

    time contracts and the abolishment of the mechanism of automatic wage indexation,

    characterized by uniform wage adjustments to inflation across workers. The reforms

    implemented in 1993 regarded a broad range of issues and established a new institu-

    tional framework for bargaining procedures, union representations and general em-

    ployment policies. The agreements provided a foundation for a better representation of

    employees and collective bargaining (OECD (2004) ; Visser (2008)). The Income Policy

    Agreement from 1993 created a new bargaining system which incorporated a national

    and regional level. The former is meant to protect the purchasing power of wages,

    while the second aims at coordinating the additional wage components with firm per-

    formance and therefore improves the flexibility of the wage determination by making

    it more market driven and sensitive to the economic conditions (Devicienti, Maida, and

    Pacelli, 2006).

    Although the reforms implemented in 1993 were meant to increase the flexibility of

    the labor market, it is not clear to what extent they were implemented in an efficient

    12

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    15/46

    manner and whether the objective was achieved. However, assuming that these insti-

    tutional changes lead to a certain extent to a decrease in the rigidities, according to our

    data these effects are associated with a negative correlation between unemployment

    and productivity and not a positive one.

    4.2.3 Sectoral shift from manufacturing to services

    According to Kutscher and Personick (1986), a substantial shift in employment between

    the manufacturing and service sectors can be observed beginning in the late 1970s:

    the goods-producing sector lost 3 million jobs between 1979 and 1983, "while service-

    producing jobs increased every year during that time span, by a total of 4.1 million"

    (1986). While the goods-producing sector recovered slightly in the mid-1980s, the "gain

    was dwarfed by the almost 3.0 million new service-producing jobs added in that single

    year" (Kutscher and Personick (1986)). See figure 10 in the Appendix for the evolution

    in employment shares in the US.

    The sectoral shift from manufacturing to services took place in Italy as well, in very

    similar proportions with the one in the US. We can notice from figure 10 that the propor-

    tion of workers in the service sector relative to manufacturing increased between 1970

    and 2011, with a more pronounced upper trend in the mid 80s.

    4.2.4 Labor market conclusions

    Empirical evidence points towards some similarities across the labor markets in US and

    Italy, such as a common evolution of temporary workers and a sectoral shift from man-

    ufacturing to services. However, these features are common to many industrialized

    countries. More importantly, there are substantial differences regarding the role played

    by labor unions in each country. Therefore, while the countries display similar trends

    towards flexibility since the 1970s, the evidence points to a more flexible market in US.

    13

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    16/46

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    17/46

    Business Cycle Statistics: United States and Italy

    Italy

    All Sample 1970-1983 1983-1993 1993-2011

    Corr (Unemployment, productivity) -0.06 -0.07 0.44 -0.50

    Corr (Unemployment, productivity) -0.06 -0.05 -0.07

    Corr (Productivity, output) 0.81 0.88 0.73 0.78

    Vol: Employment to output 0.50 0.44 0.56

    Vol: Hours relative to output 0.44 0.31 0.55

    US

    All Sample 1970-1983 1983-2011

    Corr (Unemployment, productivity) -0.01 -0.35 0.24

    Corr (Productivity, output) 0.39 0.64 0.20

    Vol: Employment to output 0.70 0.64 0.78

    Vol: Hours relative to output 0.29 0.24 0.36

    In terms of the procyclicality of productivity, the US and Italy display different be-

    havior. In the United States, the strength of this correlation falls significantly in the

    second half of the sample, while it remains constant in Italy. We find the US labor mar-

    ket to be more flexible than its Italian counterpart thus reinforcing for the claim made

    by Gali and van Rens (2010) that increased labor market flexibility is responsible for the

    vanishing procyclicality of productivity. However, both Italy and the United States haveexperienced a relative increase in the volatility of employment and hours with respect

    to output over the second half of the sample. In their paper, Gali and van Rens (2010)

    attribute this increase in labor input volatility to firms increasing reliance on labor input

    adjustments in order to meet changes in output, and find that as labor market frictions

    decrease in their model, the volatility of employment relative to output increases as

    15

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    18/46

    well.

    Furthermore, Barnichon (2010) attributes 60% of the switch in the correlation be-

    tween labor productivity and unemployment to structural changes related to the labor

    market and monetary policy, which suggests the correlation pattern should reflect the

    degree of labor market flexibility to some extent. The similarity in the pattern of the

    correlation between the United States and Italy suggests that labor market flexibility is

    not likely to be the only relevant explanation for the developments in the evolutions of

    correlations. However, he does not denote which of the two structural changes are more

    important, so our conclusion is only tentative and further research is needed.

    5 Conclusion

    Recent developments in business cycle statistics have been documented only for US. In

    this paper, we address (i) the sign shift in the unconditional correlation between produc-

    tivity and unemployment, (ii) a decrease in the procyclicality of productivity and (iii)

    an increase in the volatility of employment and hours relative to output for 10 OECD

    countries. Barnichon (2010) provides two main explanations for these developments,

    one consisting of an increase in the size of technology shocks relative to other shocks

    and another based on a increase in labor market flexibility. The purpose of this paper is

    twofold. First, we extend the analysis to other OECD countries in order to investigate

    whether the changes in correlations remain valid and group the countries according

    to similar evolutions of the series. Second, we investigate whether the degree of labor

    market flexibility could be a valid explanation for similar developments and patterns in

    the group formed by US and Italy. In order to asses this assumption we look at empiri-

    cal evidence regarding the evolution of temporary workers, unionization rates, sectoral

    shifts. Finally, we analyze additional business cycle statistics, such as the cyclicality of

    16

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    19/46

    labor productivity and the volatilities of macroeconomic series, in order to determine

    whether the three developments listed above are consistent and reflect the characteris-

    tics of the labor market within our group of interest.

    We find that there are significant differences in the flexibility and evolution of the

    labor markets in US and Italy despite the high similarities in the patterns of correlations

    between unemployment and labor productivity. The two countries display similarities

    only in terms of the evolution of temporary workers and sectoral shifts from manufac-

    turing to services, the latter being a common feature of most industrialized countries.

    However, the role played by the unions point to a more flexible market in US. Fur-

    thermore, the effects of the reforms implemented in Italy at the beginning of the 90s

    are associated with a switch in the correlation from positive to negative and not vice

    versa. Finally, the procyclicality of productivity declined only in US and not in Italy,

    which provides evidence for Gali and van Rens (2010) claim that increased labor mar-

    ket flexibility is responsible for the vanishing procyclicality of productivity. However,

    we consider that labor market flexibility is not likely to be the only relevant explanation

    for the developments in the evolutions of correlations between labor productivity and

    unemployment, and the increase in the volatility of employment and hours relative to

    output. We do not assess here the explanation based on the relative evolution of tech-

    nology and non-technology shocks, therefore this hypothesis remains as a ground for

    future research.

    17

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    20/46

    References

    Barnichon, R. (2010). Productivity and Unemployment over the Business Cycle. Journal

    of Monetary Economics 57.

    DAgostino, A., R. Serafini, and M. Ward-Warmedinger (May 2006). Sectoral Explana-

    tions of Employment in Europe: The Role of Services. European Central Bank: Working

    Paper Series 625.

    Devicienti, F., A. Maida, and L. Pacelli (2006). The Resurrection of the Italian Wage

    Curve. LABOR Center for Employment Studies Working Paper (52).

    Gali, J. and L. Gambetti (2008). On the Sources of Great Moderation. American Economic

    Journal: Macroeconomics 1(1), 2657.

    Gali, J. and T. van Rens (2010). The Vanishing Procycality of Labor Productivity. Unpub-

    lished manuscript.

    Gosling, A. and T. Lemieux (2004). Labor Market Reforms and Changes in Wage In-

    equality in the United Kingdom and the United States. Seeking a Premier Economy: The

    Economic Effects of British Economic Reforms, 1980-2000 June.

    Jimenez-Rodriguez, R. and G. Russo (2010). Aggregate Employment Dynamics and

    (Partial) Labor Market Reforms? Center for Studies in Economics and Finance Working

    Paper (260).

    Kutscher, R. and V. Personick (1986). Deindustrialization and the shift to services.

    Monthly Labor Review June.

    Marchetti, D. and F. Nucci (May 2006). Labor effort over the business cycle. Banca

    DItalia: Temi di discussione del Servizio Studi 625.

    18

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    21/46

    Mayer, G. (2004). Union Membership Trends in the United States. Congressional Research

    Service: CRS Report for Congress August.

    Nickell, W. (2006). The Cep-Oecd Institutions Data Set. CEP Discussion Paper 759.

    OECD (2004). Wage-setting Institutions and Outcomes. OECD Employment Outlook,

    127181.

    Osterman, P. (2001). Flexibility and Commitment in the United States Labour Market.

    International Labour Organisation, Research Programme: "Adjustment of labour markets toeconomic and structural change: labour market flexibility, security and labour market poli-

    cies 18.

    Stat, O. (2012). Real gdp, average hours per worker, employment, unemployment.

    Statistics.

    Stock, J. H. and M. W. Watson (2002). Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why? NBER

    Macroeconomics Annual 17, 159218.

    Visser, J. (2008). The Quality of Industrial Relations and the Lisbon Strategy. European

    Commission, Industrial relations in Europe.

    19

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    22/46

    6 Appendix

    6.1 Robustness check

    Robustness Check, Business Cycle Statistics: United States and Italy

    Italy

    All Sample 1970-1983 1983-1993 1993-2011

    Corr (Unemployment, productivity) -0.02 -0.05 0.32 -0.29

    Corr (Unemployment, productivity) -0.02 -0.05 0.01

    Corr (Productivity and output) 0.77 0.88 0.68 0.73

    Vol: Employment to output 0.53 0.45 0.60

    Vol: Hours to output 0.47 0.33 0.62

    US

    All Sample 1970-1983 1983-2011

    Corr (Unemployment, productivity) -0.08 -0.38 0.12

    Corr (Productivity and output) 0.55 0.71 0.44

    Vol: Employment to output 0.65 0.61 0.70

    Vol: Hours to output 0.28 0.23 0.35

    20

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    23/46

    6.2 Figures

    Figure 1: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    21

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    24/46

    Figure 2: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    22

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    25/46

    Figure 3: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    23

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    26/46

    Figure 4: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    24

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    27/46

    Figure 5: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    25

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    28/46

    Figure 6: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    26

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    29/46

    Figure 7: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    27

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    30/46

    Figure 8: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    28

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    31/46

    Figure 9: 10 year rolling correlations between unemployment and productivity

    29

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    32/46

    Figure 10: Sectoral shift from manufacturing to services

    30

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    33/46

    Figure 11: Temporary workers and Trade Union Density

    31

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    34/46

    Figure 12: Evolution of volatilities: Focus group

    -0.01

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    US: 10-year rolling standard deviation of output

    Output

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    Q11970

    Q21971

    Q31972

    Q41973

    Q11975

    Q21976

    Q31977

    Q41978

    Q11980

    Q21981

    Q31982

    Q41983

    Q11985

    Q21986

    Q31987

    Q41988

    Q11990

    Q21991

    Q31992

    Q41993

    Q11995

    Q21996

    Q31997

    Q41998

    Q12000

    Q22001

    US: 10-year rolling standard deviation ofemployment

    Employment

    0

    0.001

    0.002

    0.003

    0.004

    0.005

    0.006

    0.007

    11970

    21971

    31972

    41973

    11975

    21976

    31977

    41978

    11980

    21981

    31982

    41983

    11985

    21986

    31987

    41988

    11990

    21991

    31992

    41993

    11995

    21996

    31997

    41998

    12000

    22001

    US: 10-year rolling standard deviation of hours

    32

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    35/46

    Figure 13: Evolution of volatilities: Focus group

    0

    0.002

    0.004

    0.0060.008

    0.01

    0.012

    0.014

    Q11970

    Q21971

    Q31972

    Q41973

    Q11975

    Q21976

    Q31977

    Q41978

    Q11980

    Q21981

    Q31982

    Q41983

    Q11985

    Q21986

    Q31987

    Q41988

    Q11990

    Q21991

    Q31992

    Q41993

    Q11995

    Q21996

    Q31997

    Q41998

    Q12000

    Q22001

    US: 10-year rolling standard deviation of

    productivity

    Productivity

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    Q1

    1970

    Q2

    1971

    Q3

    1972

    Q4

    1973

    Q1

    1975

    Q2

    1976

    Q3

    1977

    Q4

    1978

    Q1

    1980

    Q2

    1981

    Q3

    1982

    Q4

    1983

    Q1

    1985

    Q2

    1986

    Q3

    1987

    Q4

    1988

    Q1

    1990

    Q2

    1991

    Q3

    1992

    Q4

    1993

    Q1

    1995

    Q2

    1996

    Q3

    1997

    Q4

    1998

    Q1

    2000

    Q2

    2001

    Italy: 10-year rolling standard deviation ofproductivity

    Productivity

    33

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    36/46

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    37/46

    Figure 15: The cyclicality of productivity

    -0.04

    -0.03

    -0.02

    -0.01

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Q12003

    Q32004

    Q12006

    Q32007

    Q12009

    Q32010

    The procyclicality of productivity in Italy,1970Q1-2011Q4

    Real GDP: Deviations from trend Productivity: Deviations from trend

    -0.06

    -0.05

    -0.04

    -0.03

    -0.02

    -0.01

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Q12003

    Q32004

    Q12006

    Q32007

    Q12009

    Q32010

    The procyclicality of productivity in the US,

    1970Q1-2011Q4

    Real GDP: Deviations from trend Productivity: Deviations from trend

    35

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    38/46

    Figure 16: Volatility ratios: Focus group

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    Q119

    70

    Q219

    71

    Q319

    72

    Q419

    73

    Q119

    75

    Q219

    76

    Q319

    77

    Q419

    78

    Q119

    80

    Q219

    81

    Q319

    82

    Q419

    83

    Q119

    85

    Q219

    86

    Q319

    87

    Q419

    88

    Q119

    90

    Q219

    91

    Q319

    92

    Q419

    93

    Q119

    95

    Q219

    96

    Q319

    97

    Q419

    98

    Q120

    00

    Q220

    01

    Italy: Volatility ratios over time

    Employment/Output Hours/Output

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.40.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    Q11970

    Q21971

    Q31972

    Q41973

    Q11975

    Q21976

    Q31977

    Q41978

    Q11980

    Q21981

    Q31982

    Q41983

    Q11985

    Q21986

    Q31987

    Q41988

    Q11990

    Q21991

    Q31992

    Q41993

    Q11995

    Q21996

    Q31997

    Q41998

    Q12000

    Q22001

    US: Volatility ratios over time

    Employment/Output Hours/Output

    36

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    39/46

    Figure 17: Volatilities

    0

    0.002

    0.004

    0.006

    0.008

    0.01

    0.012

    0.014

    0.016

    0.018

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Australia: 10-year rolling

    standard deviations

    Employment Lab prod1 Real GDP Hours

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Canada: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    Real GDP Employment Lab prod1 Hours

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    0.03

    0.035

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    2000

    Finland: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    37

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    40/46

    Figure 18: Volatilities

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    France: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Real GDP Employment Lab prod1 Hours

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Italy: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Real GDP Employment Lab prod1 Hours

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    11972

    21973

    31974

    1975

    11977

    21978

    31979

    1980

    11982

    21983

    31984

    1985

    11987

    21988

    31989

    1990

    11992

    21993

    31994

    1995

    11997

    21998

    31999

    2000

    Norway: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    38

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    41/46

    Figure 19: Volatilities

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    Q11970

    Q21971

    Q31972

    Q41973

    Q11975

    Q21976

    Q31977

    Q41978

    Q11980

    Q21981

    Q31982

    Q41983

    Q11985

    Q21986

    Q31987

    Q41988

    Q11990

    Q21991

    Q31992

    Q41993

    Q11995

    Q21996

    Q31997

    Q41998

    Q12000

    Q22001

    New Zealand: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    Real GDP Employment Lab prod1 Hours

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    1970

    1971

    1973

    1974

    1976

    1977

    1979

    1980

    1982

    1983

    1985

    1986

    1988

    1989

    1991

    1992

    1994

    1995

    1997

    1998

    2000

    2001

    Sweden: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Japan: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Real GDP Employment Lab prod1 Hours

    39

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    42/46

    Figure 20: Volatilities

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    Q11971

    Q21972

    Q31973

    Q41974

    Q11976

    Q21977

    Q31978

    Q41979

    Q11981

    Q21982

    Q31983

    Q41984

    Q11986

    Q21987

    Q31988

    Q41989

    Q11991

    Q21992

    Q31993

    Q41994

    Q11996

    Q21997

    Q31998

    Q41999

    Q12001

    UK: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Real GDP Employment Lab prod1 Hours

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02

    0.025

    0.03

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    US: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Real GDP Employment Lab prod1 Hours

    40

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    43/46

    Figure 21: Volatilities

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15

    0.2

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Australia: 10-year rollingstandard deviations

    Unemployment

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    0.12

    0.14

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Canada: 10-year rolling

    standard deviations

    Unemployment

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15

    0.2

    0.25

    0.3

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    2000

    Finland: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    41

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    44/46

    Figure 22: Volatilities

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    France: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    Unemployment

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.040.05

    0.06

    0.07

    0.08

    0.09

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Italy: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Unemployment

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15

    0.2

    0.25

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    Norway: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    42

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    45/46

    Figure 23: Volatilities

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    Q11970

    Q21971

    Q31972

    Q41973

    Q11975

    Q21976

    Q31977

    Q41978

    Q11980

    Q21981

    Q31982

    Q41983

    Q11985

    Q21986

    Q31987

    Q41988

    Q11990

    Q21991

    Q31992

    Q41993

    Q11995

    Q21996

    Q31997

    Q41998

    Q12000

    Q22001

    New Zealand: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    Unemployment

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15

    0.2

    0.25

    1970

    1971

    1973

    1974

    1976

    1977

    1979

    1980

    1982

    1983

    1985

    1986

    1988

    1989

    1991

    1992

    1994

    1995

    1997

    1998

    2000

    2001

    Sweden: 10-year rolling standard

    deviations

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    Japan: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Unemployment

    43

  • 7/31/2019 The role of labor markets in business cycle statistics

    46/46

    Figure 24: Volatilities

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    0.12

    Q11970

    Q21971

    Q31972

    Q41973

    Q11975

    Q21976

    Q31977

    Q41978

    Q11980

    Q21981

    Q31982

    Q41983

    Q11985

    Q21986

    Q31987

    Q41988

    Q11990

    Q21991

    Q31992

    Q41993

    Q11995

    Q21996

    Q31997

    Q41998

    Q12000

    UK: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Unemployment

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    0.12

    0.14

    0.16

    Q11970

    Q31971

    Q11973

    Q31974

    Q11976

    Q31977

    Q11979

    Q31980

    Q11982

    Q31983

    Q11985

    Q31986

    Q11988

    Q31989

    Q11991

    Q31992

    Q11994

    Q31995

    Q11997

    Q31998

    Q12000

    Q32001

    US: 10-year rolling standard deviations

    Unemployment