trade and job · pdf fileinternational trade and job polarization: ... wolfgang keller1 and...

73
International Trade and Job Polarization: Evidence at the Worker Level Wolfgang Keller 1 and Hˆale Utar *2 1 University of Colorado and NBER 2 Bielefeld University July 15, 2015 Job polarization is the shift of employment and earnings from mid-level wage jobs to both high- and low- wage jobs. Using longitudinal employee-employer matched data covering all residents and workplaces in Denmark, we study the effect of international trade on job polarization as trade barriers fell away with China’s entry into the World Trade Organization. We show that trade can explain the U-shaped pattern of employment changes that is characteristic for job polarization. For the large mid-level wage group of machine operators, already adversely by automatization and the introduction of robots, import competition leads to a loss of eight months of mid-wage employment, and increases of both low-wage and high-wage employment of about four months and one month respectively over a period of eight years. Trade leads to job polarization mainly by shifting workers from initially abundant manufacturing jobs to both high- and low-paying services jobs. Trade leads to less job polarization for women than for men even though women experience overall job polarization more than men, a finding that we relate to the swiftness of the reduction in labor demand caused by import competition. Furthermore, trade has increased gender inequality by shifting women to a lesser extent into high-wage jobs than men. We discuss a number of reasons that might be behind these findings, as well as possible policy implications. * The study is sponsored by the Labor Market Dynamics and Growth Center (LMDG) at the Uni- versity of Aarhus. Support of the Dept. of Economics and Business, Aarhus University and Statistics Denmark are acknowledged with appreciation. We thank Henning Bunzel for facilitating the access to the confidential database of Statistics Denmark and for his support, David Autor for his insightful discussion of the paper and Nick Bloom, Susanto Basu, Dave Donaldson for helpful comments and suggestions.

Upload: lethuy

Post on 12-Feb-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

International Trade and Job Polarization:

Evidence at the Worker Level

Wolfgang Keller1 and Hale Utar∗2

1University of Colorado and NBER

2Bielefeld University

July 15, 2015

Job polarization is the shift of employment and earnings from mid-level wage jobs to both high- and low-

wage jobs. Using longitudinal employee-employer matched data covering all residents and workplaces

in Denmark, we study the effect of international trade on job polarization as trade barriers fell away

with China’s entry into the World Trade Organization. We show that trade can explain the U-shaped

pattern of employment changes that is characteristic for job polarization. For the large mid-level wage

group of machine operators, already adversely by automatization and the introduction of robots, import

competition leads to a loss of eight months of mid-wage employment, and increases of both low-wage

and high-wage employment of about four months and one month respectively over a period of eight

years. Trade leads to job polarization mainly by shifting workers from initially abundant manufacturing

jobs to both high- and low-paying services jobs. Trade leads to less job polarization for women than for

men even though women experience overall job polarization more than men, a finding that we relate

to the swiftness of the reduction in labor demand caused by import competition. Furthermore, trade

has increased gender inequality by shifting women to a lesser extent into high-wage jobs than men. We

discuss a number of reasons that might be behind these findings, as well as possible policy implications.

∗The study is sponsored by the Labor Market Dynamics and Growth Center (LMDG) at the Uni-versity of Aarhus. Support of the Dept. of Economics and Business, Aarhus University and StatisticsDenmark are acknowledged with appreciation. We thank Henning Bunzel for facilitating the accessto the confidential database of Statistics Denmark and for his support, David Autor for his insightfuldiscussion of the paper and Nick Bloom, Susanto Basu, Dave Donaldson for helpful comments andsuggestions.

Page 2: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

1 Introduction

The recent transformation of China from a rather poor and largely closed economy to one

of the largest manufacturing producers over little more than two decades has been among

the most significant changes in the world economy. China’s share of world manufactures

exports rose from 2 % to 4 % over the years 1990 to 1999, only to accelerate pace

and account for 16 % of world exports in manufacturing goods by the year 2013.1 For

manufacturing producers in rich countries such as Denmark, the emergence of China is

felt as a major competitive shock. This is particularly true in the labor-intensive textiles

and clothing sector, where the traditional comparative advantage of low-wage countries

has been compounded by trade liberalization in form of import quota removals through

China’s entry into the World Trade Organization (WTO) in the year 2001.

In this paper we study the employment trajectories of Danish workers to determine

whether import competition from China has caused job polarization. Job polarization

is the shift of employment shares from mid-level wage jobs to both high- and low-wage

jobs. This phenomenon is among the most significant labor market developments in

recent decades because it has been observed in many rich countries.2 Figure 1 shows

that while job polarization has been felt strongly in the United States, developments in

Denmark have been even more dramatic. Mid-level employment share losses affect 60 %

of all occupations (40 % in the U.S.), and it occurred at a faster pace (seven more years

are shown for the U.S.).3 This means that Denmark may provide important new lessons

on job polarization. Our focus will be on the textiles and clothing industry, which faces

1Authors’ calculation using World Development Indicators dataset of the World Bank.2For the Unites States, see Autor, Katz, and Kearney (2006, 2008), Autor and Dorn (2013); United

Kingdom: Goos and Manning (2007); Germany: Spitz-Oener (2006), Dustmann, Ludsteck, and Schon-berg (2009); France: Harrigan, Reshef, and Toubal (2015) and across 16 European countries, see Goos,Manning, and Salomons (2014).

3The figure for Denmark is based on all employees in Denmark aggregated by 3-digit occupationlevel (International Standard Classification of Occupations) excluding agriculture. The figure for theUnited States is taken from Autor and Dorn (2013) and it covers all nonfarm employment in the US.Initial occupational mean wage is based on hourly wage data from 1991 for Denmark and for 1980 forthe U.S.

2

Page 3: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

major import competition from China. In our analysis the effect of import competition

turns on whether a specific worker is employed by a firm manufacturing a product for

which China’s entry into the WTO removes binding import quotas. We study workers’

employment (and to a lesser extent earnings) trajectories over the years 2002 to 2009.

Covering the relatively high rates of export growth during China’s first eight years of

WTO membership, this period captures the short and medium term implications of

increased import competition. The end of our period of observation is determined by

data considerations.4

-.2

0.2

.4.6

0 20 40 60 80 100Wage Percentile (Ranked by Initial Occupational Mean Wage)

1980-2005 U.S.1991-2009 Denmark

100

x C

hang

e in

Em

ploy

men

t Sha

re

Smoothed Changes in Employment by Wage Percentile

Figure 1: Smoothed Changes in Employment in Denmark and in the United States

We employ administrative longitudinal data on the universe of persons aged 15 to 70

years old in Denmark to study the impact of import competition on worker’s movements

between jobs.5 The data set is unusually rich in providing information for each individ-

4Occupational categories were changed in the year 2009. The Great Recession starting in 2008 tookplace too late to be driving our results.

5Our data are not the administrative records themselves but an integrated database created byStatistics Denmark from administrative registers. They are owned by public authorities and supple-

3

Page 4: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

ual worker on his or her employer, hours worked, unemployment history, and level of

education, among other variables. Information on the tasks workers perform is available

at a relatively detailed four-digit level (International Standard Classification of Occupa-

tions, ISCO). We can therefore distinguish workers not only by industry and education

but also by the tasks they perform.

Because we want to exploit a specific trade policy shock–the expiration of the Multi-fiber

Arrangement (MFA) quotas as China acceded the WTO–we focus on workers who ini-

tially were employed in Denmarks textiles and clothing sector.6 The original purpose of

the MFA in the year 1974 was to provide comprehensive protection against competition

from low-wage country exports of textiles and clothing through quantitative restrictions.

After years of multilateral negotiations, it was agreed in the year 1995 that the MFA

would gradually be lifted. China’s non-WTO status rendered it ineligible to benefit from

these trade liberalizations, which changed only once China had joined the WTO in the

year 2001. The subsequent dramatic surge of Chinese textiles and clothing exports and

the resulting increase in the competition is the plausibly exogenous source of shifts in

employment trajectories among Danish workers.7

An advantage of studying the incidence of trade in a single sector is that it eliminates

the influence of demand shocks, technology shocks, or secular trends that might be

correlated with imports in a multi-sector analysis. Our focus on workers with initial

employment in the textiles and clothing sector comes at the cost of a smaller sample

than we would have studying the entire economy. At the same time, we will see that not

only are the forces that drive job polarization in Denmark’s overall economy present in

mented with additional information drawn from various surveys (see Bunzel 2008, Timmermans 2010).Earlier work using this data set includes Groes, Kircher, and Manovskii (2015), Hummels, Jorgenson,Munch, and Xiang (2014).

6The increase in trade with China associated with the MFA quota removals has been employedrecently to study technology upgrading of European firms (Bloom, Draca, and van Reenen 2014), aswell as in Utar (2014, 2015) to study firms’ and workers’ adjustment. These studies do not focus onjob polarization.

7Utar (2014) shows that the quotas were binding, and that their removal led to increased importcompetition. Brambilla, Khandelwal, and Schott (2008) examine the effects of the quota lifting in theU.S.

4

Page 5: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

the textiles and clothing industry, but movements outside of textiles and clothing (and

manufacturing) play a key role in trade’s effect on polarization.

We contribute to a growing literature on the importance of international trade in explain-

ing job polarization, much of which examines changes at the industry or region level.

Recent work on local labor markets has shown that international trade and offshoring

have not played a major role for job polarization in the U.S. (Autor and Dorn 2013), a

result that has been confirmed in other rich countries (Goos, Manning, and Salomons

2014, Michaels, Natraj, and van Reenen 2014). Job polarization is mainly explained

by information and communications technology investments whereby computers, robots

and automatization replace workers that perform easily programmable tasks (so-called

routine-biased technical change; Autor, Katz, Kearney 2006, Goos and Manning 2007).8

Our work advances the literature by shifting the focus from aggregate labor market

consequences to job changes at the worker level. By examining the difference in responses

between workers who are ex ante observationally similar except that one works for a firm

that will compete with Chinese imports while the other worker does not, we provide

causal evidence on the impact of trade on employment polarization. By shedding new

light both on the nature of frictions that workers face when they move between jobs

(such as loss of occupation-specific human capital), this paper contributes to a better

understanding of worker welfare and the overall welfare effect of international trade.

We provide one of the first accounts of job polarization using micro level data for any

country. The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

countries from a world characterized by skill-biased technical change to one characterized

by job polarization. The paper shows that both worker’s education and gender were

important in shaping the emergence of job polarization in Denmark.

This paper is in a long tradition of work examining the role of international trade for

8An exception is Firpo, Fontin, and Lemieux (2011) who find offshoring to be important. Otherstudies of job polarization that do not specifically address the role of international trade include Spitz-Oener (2006) and Dustmann, Ludsteck, and Schonberg (2009).

5

Page 6: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

labor market outcomes, including the increase in relative wage of educated workers in

many countries during the 1970s and 1980s (see Feenstra 2000). The focus in recent open

economy analysis has shifted to tasks instead of industries or education levels (Grossman

and Rossi-Hansberg 2008), which is line with evidence showing that worker outcomes

have become strongly related to occupation characteristics (Acemoglu and Autor 2010).

By affecting the relative labor demand for mid-level versus high- and low-wage jobs,

international trade could in principle be a cause of job polarization. This would require

that the factor content of imports from low-wage countries is intensive in tasks for which

mid-level wages are paid in rich countries. At the same time it can be challenging to

separate technology from trade explanations for job polarization, especially when trade

induces technical change (Bloom, Draca, and Van Reenen 2014, Utar 2014). We seek to

make progress on the causal role of trade by using a specific trade policy shock together

with worker-level information on shifts between occupations and sectors.

Our main finding is that international trade plays a statistically and economically signif-

icant role in explaining job polarization. Imports from China reduced the employment of

a machine operator, a typical mid-level wage textile worker, by about eight months over

the period 2002 to 2009. Trade with China also increased employment of machine oper-

ators in both high- and low-wage jobs by one month and four months respectively. Trade

can explain the U-shaped employment pattern in Figure 1. While this contrasts with

earlier work on the causes of job polarization, it is in line with recent work documenting

a powerful effect of the China trade for labor market outcomes in rich countries.9 In

particular, our finding reconciles worker-level evidence on the sizable effect of import

competition from China (Autor, Dorn, Hanson, and Song 2014, Utar 2015) with the

scant evidence for trade causing job polarization in studies using more aggregate data.10

Trade leads to job polarization mainly by pushing workers from initially abundant mid-

9See Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013), Bernard, Jensen, and Schott (2006), Pierce and Schott (2013),Utar (2014); also Utar and Torres-Ruiz (2013), and Hummels, Jorgenson, Munch, and Xiang (2014).

10Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2014) present evidence that technology and trade both affect outcomesat the level of US local labor markets; their study does not focus on job polarization.

6

Page 7: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

level jobs in manufacturing towards both high- and low-wage jobs in services. We eval-

uate the effect of trade alongside technology and offshoring explanations of job polar-

ization, finding that the trade effect is robust and hardly affected quantitatively by

other explanations. Trade affects most strongly manual labor, workers performing both

routine and non-routine tasks.

The paper also provides a number of interesting results on gender differences in the

experience of job polarization. We find that while women experience overall job polar-

ization more than men, job polarization caused by trade affects women less than men.

Key to understanding this, we believe, is that trade has affected the labor market in

a more concentrated way than technical change did. First, trade led to a reduction

of labor demand mostly in manufacturing, whereas technical change has changed labor

demand both in manufacturing and non-manufacturing. Second, while technical change

has gradually changed the workplace in industrialized countries since the 1980s, the im-

pact of trade was felt more suddenly around China’s entry into the WTO. The higher

costs of transitioning for women in the presence of a sudden drop in labor demand may

be due to differences in the availability of re-training possibilities, or because women

have on average a lower labor market attachment than men.

The next section discusses the facts on job polarization in Denmark during the 1990s

and 2000s. Section 3 introduces a number of possible causes of job polarization by

presenting a number of micro facts on individual worker transitions between occupations

in Denmark’s textiles and clothing sectors. Section 4 provides background on Denmark’s

textiles trade as China entered the WTO, and it describes the data that will be employed.

Regression results on the role of trade for job polarization are presented in section 5. In

this section we also consider technical change and offshoring as alternative explanations

of job polarization, and examine the extent to which trade has affected men and women

differently. Section 6 provides a concluding discussion. An number of additional results

are shown in the Supplementary Appendix.

7

Page 8: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

2 Job Polarization in Denmark

This section describes the overall patterns of labor demand in Denmark that can be

distinguished over the years 1991 and 2009 to set the stage for our analysis. We then

examine demand shifts between broad sectors before focusing on Denmark’s textiles and

clothing workers in the years 2001 and 2009.

2.1 Major patterns of Denmark’s labor demand since the early

1990s

Over the last decades the nature of labor demand has changed in industrialized countries,

and Denmark is no exception to this. This is made strikingly clear by considering

the decade before and after the year 2000 separately. Figure 2 presents the smoothed

changes in employment shares ranked by mean initial occupational wage for all of Danish

workers outside agriculture, as in Figure 1, except that we distinguish the years 1991 to

2000 from the period 2001 to 2009. During the 1990s, we see that labor demand was

increasing with wages. To the extent that we can think of wage as a proxy for worker

skills, this pattern implies that skilled workers have tended to benefit while unskilled

workers have fallen behind during the 1990s. It has been shown that skill-biased technical

change was the most important driver of this pattern (Acemoglu 2002). While a lower

relative demand for less skilled workers could be important in raising inequality, the

policy implication from the 1990s is clear: if skills can shield a worker from declining

labor demand, investing in skills, particularly through education, is a plausible welfare-

enhancing policy.

The pattern for the years 2000-2009 in Figure 2 shows that Denmark’s workers now

live in a different world. Growth of jobs is increasingly concentrated at the tails of

the occupational wage distribution, while the middle of the distribution is hollowed

out. The employment growth pattern in Denmark is U-shaped in the 2000s, as in

8

Page 9: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

many industrialized countries. We are interested in better understanding the reasons for

this, and in particular, the role played by international trade. That would also provide

relevant information for policy makers, at least with trade as an additional dimension

that should be considered in the formulation of labor market policies.11-.

4-.

20

.2.4

0 20 40 60 80 100Wage Percentile (Ranked by 1991 Occupational Mean Wage)

1991-2000 2000-2009

100*

Cha

nge

in E

mpl

oym

ent S

hare

Smoothed Changes in Employment by Wage Percentile

Figure 2: Smoothed Changes in Employment in Denmark by Occupational Wage Per-centile

2.2 Shifts between manufacturing and services, 2000-2009

Given this U-shaped pattern that is the hallmark of job polarization, we follow the

literature and distill the pattern into changes for three separate groups, called low-,

mid-level, and high-wage workers (Autor 2010, Goos, Manning, and Salomons 2014).

The groups are formed based on the median wage paid in an occupation in an initial

11While this paper does not focus on policy, we touch on some of the issues in the conclusions. Autor(2010) discusses economic policy issues in the light of job polarization in the U.S.

9

Page 10: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

year.12 The high wage occupations comprise of managerial, professional, and technical

occupations. Mid-level wage occupations are clerks, craft and related trade workers,

and plant and machine operators and assemblers. Finally, low-wage occupations include

service workers, shop and market sales workers, as well as elementary occupations.13

These wage categories capture also broad differences in terms of skills across workers,

although each wage group encompasses workers in quite different occupations performing

rather diverse sets of tasks.

-.2

-.1

0.1

.2

Low-Wage Mid-Wage High-Wage

Changes in Occupational Employment Share, 2000-2009

Manufacturing Workers in 1999

Service Sector Workers in 1999

Figure 3: Changes in employment shares of low-, mid-, and high wage occupations byworkers’ initial industry, 2000-2009

Figure 3 analyzes employment growth for these three wage groups in Denmark’s man-

ufacturing and services sector during the years 2000 to 2009 (at the worker-level).14

12We rank major ISCO occupations using the median log hourly wage in 1991 across full-time workers.Table A-3 in the appendix present this ranking. Goos, Manning, Salomons (2014) use the 1993 wagesacross European countries (inclusive of Denmark) and arrive at a similar ranking as ours at the 2-digitISCO occupations.

13We follow the literature and focus on jobs outside of agriculture, however, the results are not affectedby this.

14Figure 3 is constructed using all employees of the manufacturing and service sectors respectively in1999, who were born between 1945 and 1984. The figure shows the change in employment shares acrosshigh-, mid-level, and low wage occupations of these workers between 2000 and 2009.

10

Page 11: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

The manufacturing sector employed 440,000 workers in Denmark in 1999, while in the

same year 1,800,000 workers were employed in the service sector. The figure shows that

manufacturing is much more strongly characterized by job polarization than services. In

fact, employment growth in services is monotonically increasing with the wage, which is

the pattern of the 1990s. As we will show below, trade does not only help to explain the

U-shaped pattern in manufacturing but also the fact that employment growth in services

is monotonically increasing across wage groups. This result confirms other findings that

the growth of service jobs is to some extent the flip side of the hollowing out of mid-level

wage jobs in manufacturing (Autor and Dorn 2013, Utar 2015).

It is useful to keep in mind that our analysis tracks workers and their occupation, not

their industry. When Figure 3 shows that manufacturing workers experience reductions

in mid-level wage employment and increases in low-wage employment, in principle this

could be because workers shift within manufacturing from mid-level to low-level jobs

(within-industry shift), or because workers shift from mid-level occupations in manufac-

turing to low-wage occupations in other industries (between-industry shift). If employ-

ment shares were constant over time across industries, observing employment polariza-

tion in a particular industry such as textiles and clothing would imply that mid-level

workers such as assemblers move in roughly equal parts into high wage and low wage

jobs. While this is in principle possible, without between-industry shifts the potential

for job polarization would necessarily seem to be limited: it is difficult to imagine that

many machine operators and assemblers become professionals or managers while others

become laborers, all in the same industry.

Far from constant employment, however, the Danish textiles and clothing industry has

been undergoing massive changes in terms of size: in the year 1999, it employed 13,000

workers, down from 25,000 in 1991, while by the end of 2010 industry employment was

down to 4,500 workers.15 Part of this reduced demand for workers producing textiles

in Denmark after 1999 is due to the removal of import quotas for China (Utar 2014),

15In the year 1999, textiles and clothing accounted for 3 % of total manufacturing employment.

11

Page 12: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

-.3

-.2

-.1

0.1

.2

Low-Wage Mid-Wage High-Wage

Changes in Occupational Employment Share, 2000-2009

T&C Workers in 1999

Manufacturing Workers in 1999

Figure 4: Changes in employment shares of low-, mid-, and high wage occupations byworkers’ initial industry, 2000-2009

although other factors, including a secular declining trend of the labor-intensive indus-

tries and technological factors, are surely present as well. Figure 4 shows the patterns

of job polarization among textiles and clothing and manufacturing workers as a whole.

We see that the job polarization pattern for textiles and clothing is stronger than for

manufacturing as a whole. Thus, job polarization in textiles and clothing accounts

over-proportionally for job polarization in manufacturing.16

In the following section we move from the aggregate to the micro level by providing

some initial evidence on job polarization in Denmark based on movements between jobs

by individual workers.

16It is important to distinguish the impact of trade on job polarization at the firm- versus worker-level. Figure 1 in the Supplementary Appendix show occupational employment share changes withinthe textile and clothing sector. In that figure, rather than following workers and their occupations, wefollow employment within the T&C sector. Along the lines of Utar (2014), occupational employmentshare changes exhibit skill upgrading within the sector, more so among the firms that were exposed toimports coming from China.

12

Page 13: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

3 Facts from individual worker job transitions

In this section we present several facts about worker transitions between occupations

in Denmark during the sample period by looking at two specific two-digit occupations,

drivers and mobile plant operators (ISCO 83) versus machine operators and assemblers

(ISCO 82).

Fact 1: There is substantial variation in worker outcomes at broadly similar wage levels

but different occupations.

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 200920

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Year

Perc

ent

Drivers (ISCO 83)Machine Operators and Assemblers (ISCO 82)

Figure 5: RBTC: Probability of Staying for Machine Operators versus Drivers

Because both drivers and machine operators are among mid-level wage categories (see

Table A-3), reduced employment in either of these occupations may help to explain

the overall finding of job polarization. Nevertheless workers in these two occupations

experienced differences in their job market experience over the sample period. Figure

5 shows the cumulative probability for a worker to stay in her initial occupation over

13

Page 14: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 20090

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Year

Perc

ent

Drivers (ISCO 83)Machine Operators and Assemblers (ISCO 82)

Figure 6: The Rise of Service Worker Employment: Machine Operators versus Drivers

the period 2001 to 2009. First, note that there is a considerable amount of movement

of these workers. By the year 2009, around two thirds of the workers do not work

anymore in the occupation that they worked in the year 2001. This is to some extent

the consequence of the relative ease of switching jobs (low hiring costs, low firing costs)

in the Danish labor market. Second, over these eight years there are marked differences

in the probability of staying in one’s initial occupation: in particular, drivers stay in

their initial occupation with a 15 % higher probability than do machine operators and

assemblers.

In the textile and clothing sector, operators would attend fibre-preparing-, spinning-, and

winding machines. They would also operate weaving, knitting, sewing, bleaching, and

dying machines. Given the relatively narrow and programmable nature of their tasks it is

plausible that the tasks of these operators and assemblers are prone to being automated

14

Page 15: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

and done by robots. This is reflected in a relatively high ”routine task index” (RTI),

which is 0.64 for this occupation.17,18 In contrast, drivers in the textile and clothing

sector, who would drive cars, vans, trucks, as well as forklifts, perform generally less

routine tasks. A driver of a truck takes his load to different destinations, diggers enter

new terrain, or the personal driver of an executive makes new runs. The occupation

of drivers has a relatively low routine task intensity (RTI of -0.99). Our finding that

machine operators and assemblers are less likely to stay in their initial occupation than

drivers points to the importance of routine-biased technical change (RBTC).

Fact 2: Shrinking mid-level wage occupations are a source of growth of low-wage occu-

pations, especially in services.

Figure 6 shows the cumulative probabilities of machine operators and drivers to transi-

tion into personal and protective service occupations (ISCO 51). These service occupa-

tions include protective service workers as well as housekeepers, cooks, hairdressers, and

travel guides. Service occupations require generally relatively few skills and wages are

typically low. At the same time, service tasks are characterized by a relative low level of

routinization (RTI of -0.23). Figure 6 shows that the cumulative probability that a ma-

chine operator transitions into these service jobs is increasing over time, and by the year

2009 7.5 % of all workers that were machine operators in 2001 have moved into person

and protective service jobs. In contrast, drivers rarely move into these service worker

jobs, and the cumulative probability is hardly increasing over time. This is consistent

with recent evidence that the flip side of lower employment in high routine tasks due to

RBTC is increasing service employment (Autor and Dorn 2013). Figure 6 confirms this

result at the level of individual workers.

Fact 3: Import competition leads to worker transitions consistent with job polarization.

17See Autor, Levy, and Murnane (2003), Autor, and Dorn (2013). Autor (2013) discusses this tasksapproach more broadly.

18We thank Anna Salomons for sharing the RTI measure used in Goos, Manning, and Salomons(2014) with us.

15

Page 16: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 200920

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Year

Perc

ent

Machine Operators with Trade ShockMachine Operators without Trade ShockDrivers with Trade ShockDrivers without Trade Shock

Figure 7: Import Competition and Job Polarization

In Figure 7 we show cumulative transitions of drivers (ISCO 83) and machine operators

and assemblers (ISCO 82) out of their occupation depending on whether they were

exposed to increased competition from Chinese producers, or not. We see that both

drivers and machine operators are less likely to stay in their initial occupation in the

presence of Chinese import competition.19 Over the entire period of 2001-2009, machine

operators affected by Chinese import competition have a 29 % lower chance of staying in

their initial industry compared to machine operators not affected by import competition.

The corresponding figure for drivers is 22 %.

In the light of our finding that workers highly exposed to RBTC (such as machine

operators) have a 15 % higher chance to switch occupations than workers little exposed

19The transitions of machine operators over time result in a smoother picture mainly because thereare many more of them than drivers. In 2001 there were 2726 machine operators (ISCO 82) as opposedto only 101 drivers.

16

Page 17: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

to RBTC (such as drivers), the difference in likelihood of staying associated with trade

of 22-29 % appears to be sizable. In section 5 below we will return to this question with

an approach that holds constant a range of worker and firm characteristics to estimate

the causal effect of trade.

Before we turn to this, the next section introduces our data and describes the policy

change that is employed.

4 Workers facing import competition: the data

4.1 Employee-employer matched data

The main database used in this study is the Integrated Database for Labor Market

Research, IDA, which is comprised of person, establishment, and job files.20 The person

files contain annual information on all persons of age 15-70 residing in Denmark with

a social security number. The establishment files contain annual information on all

establishments with at least one employee in the last week of November of each year.

The job files provide information on all jobs that are active in the last week of November

in each year. IDA data-sets are complemented with the domestic production data-set

(VARES) that covers all manufacturing firms with at least 10 employees, and the annual

longitudinal data-set that matches firms with their employees (FIDA). The data-sets are

from Statistics Denmark.

For each worker we have information on their annual salary, hours worked, industry code

of their primary employment, education level, demographic characteristics including age,

gender and immigration status, and occupation of primary employment. Of particular

interest to us here is the information on workers’ occupations. Occupational codes matter

in Denmark because they influence a worker’s wage due to a collective bargaining system.

20See Bunzel (2008) and Timmermans (2010) for more information.

17

Page 18: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Employers and labor unions pay close attention to occupational codes. This explains the

administrative nature of the data. As a consequence, the quality of occupational data

in Denmark is high compared to other countries.21 Information on workers’ occupation

closely follows the international ISCO-88 classification. For most workers, occupational

information is given at a detailed 4-digit level.

There were close to 13,000 workers in Denmark’s textile and clothing industry in the

year 1999. In our analysis we focus on workers who are in working age (17 to 67 years)

throughout our sample period. So there are around 11,000 workers in our sample (see

Table 1, Panel A for summary statistics). The textile and clothing industry is a typical

manufacturing industry in which plant and machinery operator tasks (ISCO occupation

code 8) play a large role; according to Figure A-1, they account for more than 40 % of

all workers. Nevertheless the textile and clothing industry employs workers performing

a diverse set of tasks. Technicians and associate professionals (ISCO 3), craft workers

(ISCO 7), but also clerks (ISCO 4) account each for around 10 % of the textile and

clothing workforce, whereas managers (ISCO 1) make up about 5 % (Figure A-1). Table

A-1 presents worker characteristics for several occupation groups separately. We see that

a majority of professionals (ISCO 2) in our sample is college educated (61 %) whereas,

for example, college educated workers only constitute 6 % among craft workers (ISCO

7).

Workers are on average 39 years old, indicating roughly the middle of the career span.

The share of female workers is 57 %, and 6 % are immigrants (Table 1). The share

of women is highest among clerks (78 %) and lowest among managers (21 %). Eleven

percent of workers are college educated, and 35 % of workers have formal vocational

training. In Denmark vocational education is provided by the technical high schools

(after 9 years of mandatory schooling) and involves several years of formalized training

including both schooling and apprenticeship. Roughly half of the workers have at most

high school education. These figures show that our sample includes workers from a range

21See, for example, Groes, Kircher, and Manovskii (2015) on this point.

18

Page 19: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

of skill levels, important for our analysis of the effects of globalization on manufacturing

workers in advanced countries. Compared to the economy as a whole these workers

belong typically to the mid-level wage group. In Table 1 we report the breakdown of

workers into a three-way wage classification of occupations. As reported in Table 1, 62

% of our workers held mid-level wage jobs in the year 1999.

In the empirical analysis we also employ a number of additional variables to control for

both worker and firm characteristics. They include worker experience, measured by the

number of years each worker was in the labor force between 1980 and 1999, and the

worker’s unemployment history between 1980 and 1999 (see Table 1). Also, note that

80 % of workers are labor union members, and close to 90 % are members in Denmark’s

unemployment insurance program. The high degree of unionization is one indication

that Denmark’s labor market institutions are quite different from those in the United

States, for example, although it is worth noting that this does not make them necessarily

more rigid. In particular, Denmark ranked 6th among 148 countries in terms of its hiring

and firing practices, more de-regulated than the United States which came in 9th in the

same ranking (Global Competitiveness Report 2014). Relatively unrestricted hiring and

firing in Denmark is combined with active labor market policies and a generous social

safety net to yield a system that has been termed “flexicurity”. While the comparatively

limited wage flexibility in Denmark leads us to focus mostly on job polarization in terms

of employment, we will show some results on job polarization in terms of earnings as

well.

The Danish production database is used to identify firms with domestic production in

one or more of the goods that were subject to the MFA quotas for China. We identify

firms that in 1999 produce 8-digit Combined Nomenclature (CN) level goods that are

subject to the MFA quota removal for China, and using a firm identifier we map this

information to worker-level information. In the year 1999, about half of the workers

are exposed to increased import competition in the sense that they are employed at a

firm that will subsequently be affected by quota removals as a consequence of China’s

19

Page 20: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

accession to the WTO. Panel (b) of Figure A-1 compares the distribution of occupations

in the exposed firms with that in the non-exposed firms as a sample balance check. We

see that plant and machine operators is the largest occupation in both sets of firms,

accounting for more than 40 % of the workforce in both exposed and non-exposed firms.

The two sets of firms have also a similar share of managers (ISCO 1). There are some

differences, for example exposed firms have a higher share of clerks (ISCO 4) than non-

exposed firms, while non-exposed firms have higher share of craft workers (ISCO 7).

Overall, however, we do not see major differences between the two sets of firms in panel

(b) of Figure A-1.

Given their importance in the textile and clothing industry, we examine the group of

“plant and machine operators” occupations in more detail. Table A-2 reports summary

statistics on workers initially employed at firms that were exposed to import competition,

versus workers that were not exposed to import competition separately. For example,

sewing machine operators in exposed firms in 1999 were 95.7 % women, while this fraction

was 94 % at non-exposed firms. We also see that 4.3 % of weaving and knitting machine

operators were college educated in non-exposed firms, while 4.9 % of these workers

were college educated in exposed firms. The weaving and knitting machine operators at

exposed firms had a labor market experience of about 16.5 years, compared to about

15.7 years in non-exposed firms. To the extent that longer labor market experience gives

valuable skills, and firms do not want to let go relatively skilled workers, this would bias

the analysis against finding an effect of trade on job polarization. The main finding

from comparing the initial workforce in exposed and non-exposed firms though is that

the differences are small and unlikely to explain our findings.

20

Page 21: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics

Panel A. Characteristics of Workers with Primary Employment in T&C in 1999

Mean SD N

Age 39.174 10.473 10753

Female 0.571 0.495 10753

Immigrant 0.061 0.240 10753

College Educated 0.112 0.316 10753

Vocational School Educated 0.350 0.477 10753

At most High School 0.514 0.500 10753

Years of Experience in the Labor Market 14.500 5.864 10753

Unemployment History Index 127.241 182.741 10753

Log Hourly Wage 4.968 0.348 10753

High Wage Occupation 0.188 0.390 10753

Mid Wage Occupation 0.622 0.485 10753

Low Wage Occupation 0.112 0.315 10753

Union Membership 0.800 0.400 10753

Unemployment Insurance Membership 0.897 0.304 10753

Panel B. Main Outcome Variables

Cumulative Years of Employment in High- and Low Wage Jobs

net of Years of Employment in Mid Wage Jobs (2002-2009)

-0.143 4.938 10753

Cumulative Hours Worked in High- and Low Wage Jobs net of

Hours Worked in Mid Wage Jobs (2002-2009)

-0.062 6.573 10753

Cumulative Salary in High- and Low Wage Jobs net of Salary in

Mid Wage Jobs (2002-2009)

0.175 8.735 10753

Cumulative Years of Employment in High Wage Jobs (2002-2009) 1.379 2.505 10753

Cumulative Years of Employment in Mid Wage Jobs (2002-2009) 2.548 2.847 10753

Cumulative Years of Employment in Low Wage Jobs (2002-2009) 1.025 1.991 10753

Notes: Variables Female, Immigrant, Union Membership, UI Membership, High Wage, Mid Wage and Low

Wage Occupations, College Educated, Vocational School Educated and At most High School are worker-level

indicator variables. The Unemployment History Index is the cumulative sum of the percentage of working

time spent as unemployed within each year since 1980. Data Source: Statistics Denmark.

21

Page 22: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

4.2 Import competition through quota removals

The Multi-fibre Arrangement was introduced in 1974 to govern world trade in the textiles

and clothing. Under this agreement a large portion of textile and clothing exports from

low-wage countries to more developed countries was subject to quantitative restrictions

called quotas. The arrangement provided extensive protection for developed country

textile and clothing industry against competition from low-wage country products. The

liberalization of trade in the textile and clothing industry was not agreed until the

conclusion of the Uruguay Round in 1995, when the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing

(ATC) replaced the MFA, and provisions were made for phasing it out in four steps over

a period of 10 years. Quotas were to be eliminated equivalent to 16 percent of 1990

imports at the beginning of 1995 (Phase I), 17 percent at the beginning of 1998 (Phase

II), 18 percent at the beginning of 2002 (Phase III), and the remaining 49 percent at

the beginning of 2005 (Phase IV).

Quotas covered a wide range of both textile and clothing products ranging from bed

linens to synthetic filament yarns to shirts but at the same time coverage within each

broad product category varied, making it important to utilize MFA quotas at a detailed

product-level. For example, “shawls and scarves of silk or silk waste” was part of a

quota restriction for China while “shawls and scarves of wool and fine animal hair” was

not. “brasseries of all types of textile materials” was under quota but not “corselettes of

all types of textile materials”. As one of the smaller members of the EU, the extensive

coverage of quotas was largely exogenous to the Danish industrial structure. Coverage of

these quotas was determined throughout 1960s and 70s and the negotiations of the MFA

were held at the EU level (Spinanger 1999). Since 1993 the quotas were also managed

at the EU level.

China did not become eligible for quota removal until it joined the WTO at the end

of 2001. While there was a considerable amount of uncertainty as to whether China’s

negotiations for WTO membership would succeed, we choose 1999 as the year to de-

22

Page 23: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

termine whether a firm had a product in its portfolio that would be subject to a quota

removal to limit any anticipation effects. In January 2002, its quotas on Phase I, II and

III goods were removed immediately. By being a WTO member, China was also allowed

to benefit from the scheduled last phase in January 2005.22 We utilize as our measure of

import competition the abolishment of MFA quotas for China in conjunction with her

accession to the WTO.23

Most of the quotas for China had more than 90 % filling rates. Figure 8 shows the

evolution in textile and clothing import shares of China compared to other developing

countries subject to MFA quotas. Clearly China is the country that stands out in this

figure. Using transaction-level import data, Utar (2014) confirms that the MFA quotas

were binding for China and both the 2002 and the 2005 quota lifting cause a substantial

surge of MFA goods from China in Denmark with associated decline in unit prices of

these goods.24 As a consequence, virtually all workers employed at firms subject to

the quota removals faced increased import competition from China. Employing a two-

stage least squares strategy in which exposure to Chinese quota removal instruments for

import competition generally leads to similar results (see Utar 2014). For this reason,

here we employ exposure to Chinese quota removal as our treatment variable.

22Due to a surge of Chinese imports in the first few months of 2005 at European Union (EU) portsin response to the final phase of the quota removal, the EU retained a few of the quota categories until2008. Since the sample period extends over 2008, those few quotas are also included in the currentanalysis.

23Here we focus on China’s accession to the WTO as a shock because while the ATC provided aschedule for gradual dismantling of MFA quotas already in 1995, removal of MFA quotas for Chinadepended on whether and when it would join the WTO. Furthermore, there is significant overlapbetween firms producing quota products subject to 2002 or 2005 phases, making it difficult to separatethe effects of different phases. Finally, due to a surge of Chinese imports in the first few months of 2005at the EU ports in response to the final phase of the quota removal, the EU retained a few of the quotaPhase IV categories until 2008. The selection of the retained categories were clearly endogenous to theEU-wide industrial structure as it was due to the pressure of the European industrialist.

24Khandelwal, Schott, and Wei (2013) shows that the quota removal for China led to an extraefficiency gain in China due to prior mismanagement of quotas by the Chinese government and thedecline in prices were a result of entry of more efficient Chinese producers into the export market.

23

Page 24: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 20090

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

ChinaArgentinaBrazilHong KongIndiaIndonesiaKoreaMacaoMalaysiaPakistanPeruPhillipinesSingaporeSri LankaThailand

Figure 8: Import shares of China and other developing countries subject to MFA quotasin Danish Textile and Clothing Imports 1999-2009

5 Empirical results

To examine the role of trade for job polarization, we consider the following regression:

JP empi = β0 + β1Tradei + ZW

i + ZFi + εi (1)

The dependent variable JP empi is a measure job polarization at the worker level (subscript

i) over the period from 2002 to 2009. On the right hand side we have the measure of

trade (Tradei), as well as measures of worker (ZWi ) and firm (ZF

i ) characteristics. The

sample consists of all workers who are at the working age throughout 2002-2009 and

had their primary employment in textiles and clothing in the year 1999. Equation (1) is

a cross-sectional, worker-level regression relating job polarization during China’s post-

24

Page 25: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

WTO membership period of 2002-2009 to worker-level characteristics in the pre-WTO

year of 1999. In particular, job polarization is defined as

JP empi =

T=2009∑t=2002

{Emphit + Emplit − Empmit }. (2)

In this expression, Empxit is a dummy variable that takes the value of one if worker i in

year t (t = 2002, ..., 2009) has held a job in high-, mid-level, or low-wage occupations,

denoted by x = h,m, l; our classification into these three brackets follows Table A-3.25

The dependent variable JP empi is the number of years that worker i has held primary

employment in a high-wage or low-wage occupation between 2002 and 2009, minus the

number of years that worker i has worked primarily in mid-level wage occupations. By

summing over high- and low-wage employment after netting out mid-level employment,

JP empi conveniently summarizes worker i’s polarization experience. Below we will also

show results that treat the three wage groups separately. The variable Tradei takes the

value of one if in the year 1999 worker i is employed in a firm that domestically manu-

factures a product that with China’s entry into the WTO is subject to the abolishment

of the MFA quotas for China, and zero otherwise.

The vector ZWi includes the following controls for worker i in the year 1999: age, gender,

immigration status, education level, and the logarithm of i’s average hourly wage.26

Further, ZWi includes initial occupation and education controls: indicators for worker

i’s occupation in a high-, mid-level, or low-wage occupation in year 1999, and indicator

variables for at least some college education, vocational education, and at most a (non-

technical) high school degree. We also include information on worker i’s labor market

experience before 1999. First, this is the cumulative sum of the percentage of working

time a worker spent as unemployed within each year since 1980, and the number of

25We also use the European ranking of occupations as provided by Goos, Manning and Salomons(2004). It employs the two-digit International Standard Classification of Occupations 1988 (ISCO-88),and the ranking of occupations as high/mid-level/low is based on the 1993 mean European wage. Ourresults are robust alternatively using European-wide ranking.

26We take the average wage for years 1999 and 2000 to smooth out temporary effects.

25

Page 26: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

years of labor market experience before 1999. Finally, ZWi includes indicator variables

for worker i’s union and unemployment insurance membership status in year 1999.

The vector of firm controls ZFi holds constant differences across workers’ workplaces

in the year 1999 that might induce a spurious correlation. It includes the size of the

firm, measured by the number of full-time equivalent employees, firm quality, proxied

by the logarithm of the average hourly wage paid in this firm, as well as a measure of

the strength of the firm-worker bond, which is the percentage of workers that are not

employed in the same firm from year 1998 to year 1999.

In addition to the measure of job polarization based on years of employment, we will

employ an alternative measure that captures changes in the hours worked of each worker.

It is defined as

JP hrsi =

∑T=2009t=2002 {Hourshit +Hourslit −Hoursmit }

Hoursit0(3)

whereHoursxit is defined as the total number of hours worked by worker i in year t in high-

/mid-level/low-wage wage primary occupations. JP hrsi captures the cumulative hours

worked in high-wage jobs plus the hours worked in low- wage jobs, minus hours worked

in mid-level wage jobs throughout 2002-2009 for worker i; the measure is normalized by

Hoursit0 , which is worker i’s hours worked in his or her primary employment in initial

year t0.27 We also present results for an earnings polarization measure, defined as

JPwagei =

∑T=2009t=2002 {Earningshit + Earningslit − Earningsmit }

Earningsit0(4)

where Earningsxit is total labor earnings of worker i from his/her high-, mid-level, or

low-wage primary occupation, x = h,m, l. In the denominator of equation (4) are worker

i’s initial earnings in his or her primary job.

27To reduce measurement errors, both JPhrsi and the variable JPwage

i , defined below, employ theaverage of the respective values for years 1999 and 2000.

26

Page 27: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

5.1 Can trade explain the U-shaped job polarization pattern?

The estimate of β1 in equation (1) captures the impact of lifting the import quotas

for China on Danish workers’ movements away from mid-level wage jobs towards high-

and low wage jobs. By focusing on the textiles and clothing sector we rule out that

the results are affected by the secular decline of labor intensive industries in advanced

countries, or the corresponding secular increase in non-manufacturing as these forces

are in effect in both the control and the treatment group.28 In addition to industry we

control for firm characteristics that could have an important influence on the results.

Perhaps most importantly, the worker controls ensure that we compare workers within

fairly narrow cells, making the workers that are exposed to import competition virtually

identical to those that are not exposed to import competition from China. To see which

set of variables matters we include them step by step.

Table 2 presents the results from estimating equation (1) for the dependent variable

JP emp. When only Tradei is included on the right hand side, β1 is estimated at about

1.2, see column 1. The estimate indicates that workers exposed to import competition

from China have more than one calendar year of additional employment in high- and

low- wage jobs net of employment in mid-level wage jobs over the eight years from 2002

to 2009. The shift of employment from mid-level to low and high-wage jobs appears

to be stronger for women than for men (column 2). Non-immigrants and relatively

young workers exhibit the employment polarization more strongly than other workers.

Including these demographic controls has only a small effect on the Tradei estimate.

If workers exposed to import competition from China held primarily mid-level jobs,

our dependent variable would be relatively high for these workers simply because they

disproportionately lose their jobs. To account for this we include indicator variables for

worker i’s occupation in the year 1999 by wage categories (high-, mid-level, and low;

28Figure A-2 shows that 52 % of all workers in the sample who were working in 2009 moved to theService Sector by the end of 2009. Figure A-3 shows this figure separately for exposed and non-exposedworkers. The figure is 60 % and 44 % respectively for exposed and non-exposed workers.

27

Page 28: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

see column 3). We find that the indicators for high-wage and low-wage occupations in

1999 come in positive while the mid-level occupation indicator is negative; these results

are plausible as they reflect the influence of the non-switchers on JP empi . Controlling for

initial occupations, we see that the Tradei coefficient is now around 0.8.

We see further that college educated workers are more likely to be experiencing employ-

ment polarization while workers with vocational education less, although these coeffi-

cients are only weakly significant. Employment polarization is increasing in worker’s

wage in 1999 and decreasing with labor market experience (columns 5 and 6). Union

members and workers covered by unemployment insurance experience employment po-

larization less strongly than other workers, presumably because they switch out less of

mid-level employment than other workers (column 7). Overall, beyond the occupation of

a worker initially, controlling for additional worker characteristics has only minor effects

on the Tradei coefficient.

We also add variables at the firm level on the right hand side of equation (1), see

column 8. Firm heterogeneity might affect workers’ accumulation of human capital and

may lead divergent labor market trajectories among workers. We find that polarization

is less likely for workers employed in firms that pay relatively high wages. This may be

both because workers prefer to not leave those firms and because such firms may have

prepared themselves better than other firms for the onset of import competition from

China. Furthermore, there is more polarization for workers at firms that typically have

high separation rates, presumably because the firm-worker bond is less tight than in

other firms. With all worker and firm controls included, the trade effect is estimated at

around 0.8 with a robust t-statistic of about 10 (column 8). This means that on average

exposed workers experience a gross churn of an additional 0.8 years of employment

during 2002-2009, or 0.1 employment years for each year of the sample period.

It is interesting to note that the coefficient estimate for female workers increases as

other worker characteristics are controlled for. In column (7), the coefficient estimate

28

Page 29: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

le2:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

nan

dT

rade

-Y

ears

ofE

mplo

ym

ent

Dep

.V

ar.

:C

um

ula

tive

Yea

rsof

Em

plo

ym

ent

inH

igh

-an

dL

owW

age

Job

sm

inu

sY

ears

ofE

mp

loym

ent

inM

idW

age

Job

s(2

002-

2009

)(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)T

rad

e1.1

67*

**

1.09

9***

0.77

8***

0.78

2***

0.79

1***

0.83

7***

0.85

3***

0.81

6***

(0.0

95)

(0.0

96)

(0.0

88)

(0.0

87)

(0.0

87)

(0.0

88)

(0.0

88)

(0.0

89)

Fem

ale

0.34

6***

0.66

8***

0.62

9***

0.78

9***

0.75

8***

0.82

0***

0.70

6***

(0.0

97)

(0.0

87)

(0.0

87)

(0.0

95)

(0.0

95)

(0.0

96)

(0.0

97)

Imm

igra

nt

-0.8

42**

*-0

.199

-0.3

26-0

.286

-0.6

24**

*-0

.505

**-0

.606

***

(0.1

83)

(0.1

69)

(0.1

72)

(0.1

73)

(0.1

81)

(0.1

82)

(0.1

81)

Age

-0.0

32**

*-0

.024

***

-0.0

20**

*-0

.023

***

-0.0

02-0

.003

-0.0

06(0

.004

)(0

.004

)(0

.004

)(0

.004

)(0

.005

)(0

.005

)(0

.005

)H

igh

-Wage

Occ

3.17

9***

2.85

6***

2.65

0***

2.71

9***

2.85

6***

2.87

3***

(0.1

72)

(0.1

78)

(0.1

88)

(0.1

89)

(0.1

88)

(0.1

88)

Mid

-Wag

eO

cc-2

.102

***

-2.0

88**

*-2

.134

***

-2.0

25**

*-1

.757

***

-1.6

59**

*(0

.154

)(0

.153

)(0

.154

)(0

.156

)(0

.161

)(0

.162

)L

ow-W

age

Occ

1.24

0***

1.29

0***

1.28

8***

1.34

8***

1.56

0***

1.66

3***

(0.1

94)

(0.1

94)

(0.1

93)

(0.1

95)

(0.1

97)

(0.1

99)

Col

lege

0.62

1*0.

566

0.53

60.

580*

0.57

9*(0

.294

)(0

.293

)(0

.292

)(0

.292

)(0

.291

)V

oca

tion

al

-0.6

51*

-0.6

45*

-0.5

69*

-0.5

25-0

.589

*(0

.272

)(0

.271

)(0

.271

)(0

.271

)(0

.270

)at

most

Hig

hS

chool

-0.4

66-0

.421

-0.3

62-0

.372

-0.4

43(0

.270

)(0

.269

)(0

.268

)(0

.268

)(0

.267

)L

og

Hou

rly

Wag

e0.

632*

**0.

823*

**0.

908*

**1.

283*

**(0

.140

)(0

.144

)(0

.144

)(0

.154

)E

xp

erie

nce

-0.0

62**

*-0

.047

***

-0.0

41**

*(0

.011

)(0

.011

)(0

.011

)U

nem

plo

ym

ent

His

tory

0.00

0*0.

001*

*0.

000*

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

Un

ion

Mem

ber

ship

-0.3

54**

-0.3

11*

(0.1

21)

(0.1

21)

UI

Mem

ber

ship

-0.6

20**

*-0

.621

***

(0.1

59)

(0.1

59)

Fir

mW

age

-1.8

68**

*(0

.289

)F

irm

Siz

e0.

000

(0.0

00)

Sep

ara

tion

Rate

0.01

5***

(0.0

02)

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

nu

mb

erof

obse

rvati

on

sis

10753.

Aco

nst

ant

isin

clu

ded

bu

tn

ot

rep

ort

ed.

All

contr

ol

vari

ab

les

are

bel

on

gto

the

init

ial

sam

ple

per

iod

and

par

tof

ZW i

orZ

F i.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

at

the

10

%,

5%

an

d1%

leve

lsre

spec

tive

ly.

Dat

aS

ourc

e:S

tati

stic

sD

enm

ark

.

29

Page 30: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

for the Female indicator is 0.8 and significant at the 1 percent level, that is women have

an additional of 0.8 years of employment away from mid-level jobs toward the tails of

the distribution. The major change occurs when we distinguish movers from stayers by

including the initial occupation controls (compare columns 2 and 3). We will return to

this issue in the discussion below. Once firm-level controls are included, the coefficient

decreases a bit to 0.7, this indicates that women were disproportionately employed in

firms that are more prone to job polarization, with lower wages and higher separation

rates.

Table 3 presents analogous results for our cumulative hours worked measure, JP hrsi .

While the findings are generally similar to those with years of employment, the tendency

towards job polarization is somewhat stronger for hours than for years of employment

(the Tradei coefficient β1 is estimated at 0.87 with hours (column 8), compared to 0.82

with years of employment). This indicates that reducing mid-level worker hours, even

if they continue to be employed, is another channel through which import competition

generates job polarization. But the magnitude differences implies that this channel is

relatively unimportant in Denmark.29

We find also a significant effect from import competition on cumulative earnings polar-

ization, see Table 4. The estimate of 0.96 (column 8) implies that the average exposed

worker sees a shift in earnings away from mid-level and towards high- and low-wage earn-

ings that is roughly equal to the worker’s annual earnings before the fall of the import

quotas for China. The coefficient estimate implies an annualized shift of roughly 12 % of

one year’s earnings over the period of 2002 to 2009. This is quite similar to the average

annual effect measured in hours worked, 11 % of initial annul hours worked as well as

the effect measured in years worked, 10 % of a year. Import competition has a sizable

impact on (cumulative) earnings polarization because workers move across occupations.

29Utar (2015) notes that the main channel through which the import shock is felt at the initialemployer is a reduction in tenure at the initial employer, rather than reduction in hours worked or thehourly wage.

30

Page 31: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

le3:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

nan

dT

rade-

Hou

rsW

orke

d

Dep

.V

ar.

:C

um

ula

tive

Hou

rsW

ork

edin

Hig

h-

and

Low

Wag

eJob

sm

inu

sH

ours

Wor

ked

inM

idW

age

Job

s(2

002-

2009

)(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)T

rad

e1.1

80*

**

1.09

0***

0.77

6***

0.78

1***

0.78

9***

0.86

1***

0.88

2***

0.86

7***

(0.1

26)

(0.1

28)

(0.1

21)

(0.1

20)

(0.1

20)

(0.1

22)

(0.1

22)

(0.1

24)

Dem

ogra

ph

icC

ontr

ols

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Init

ial

Occ

up

atio

ns

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Ed

uca

tion

Contr

ols

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Init

ial

Wag

eye

sye

sye

sye

sL

ab

orM

arke

tH

isto

ryye

sye

sye

sU

nio

nan

dU

IC

ontr

ols

yes

yes

Init

ial

Fir

mC

ontr

ols

yes

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

nu

mb

erof

obse

rvat

ion

sis

10753.

Aco

nst

ant

isin

clu

ded

bu

tn

ot

rep

ort

ed.

Dem

ogra

ph

icco

ntr

ols

are

age,

gen

der

du

mm

y,an

dim

mig

rati

onst

atu

sd

um

my.

Ed

uca

tion

contr

ols

are

du

mm

yva

riab

les

ind

icati

ng

wh

eth

eran

ind

ivid

ual

has

at

most

hig

hsc

hool

deg

ree,

voca

tion

al

trai

nin

g(a

fter

hig

hsc

hool

)or

coll

ege

an

dab

ove

deg

ree

in1999.

Lab

or

Mark

etH

isto

ryva

riab

les

are

un

emp

loym

ent

his

tory

an

dex

per

ien

ceva

riab

les.

Un

emp

loym

ent

his

tory

isth

enu

mb

erof

year

sb

etw

een

1980-1

999

that

the

ind

ivid

ual

spen

tas

an

un

emp

loye

dp

erso

n.

Exp

erie

nce

isth

enum

ber

of

years

per

son

was

inth

ela

bor

mar

ket

bet

wee

n19

80-1

999.

Init

ial

wage

isth

elo

gari

thm

of

the

aver

age

hou

rly

wage

of

an

ind

ivid

ual

(fro

mh

is/h

erp

rim

ary

occ

up

atio

nin

T&

C)

in19

99an

d20

00.

Init

ial

Occ

up

ati

on

sare

ind

icato

rva

riab

les

wh

eth

eran

ind

ivid

ual

was

emp

loyed

in1999

hav

ing

ah

igh

-wage,

mid

-wag

eor

low

-wag

eocc

up

atio

n(o

uts

ide

cate

gory

isu

nsp

ecifi

edocc

up

ati

on

s).

Un

ion

an

dU

IC

ontr

ols

are

Un

ion

mem

ber

ship

an

dU

Im

emb

ersh

ipva

riab

les.

Un

ion

mem

ber

ship

isa

du

mm

yva

riab

lein

dic

ati

ng

ifth

ein

div

idual

isa

mem

ber

of

ala

bor

un

ion

.U

Im

emb

ersh

ipis

ad

um

my

vari

ab

lein

dic

atin

gif

the

ind

ivid

ual

isa

mem

ber

ofth

e(v

olu

nta

ry)

Un

emp

loym

ent

Insu

ran

ceF

un

d.

Init

ial

work

pla

ceco

ntr

ols

are

the

logari

thm

of

the

aver

age

hou

rly

wag

ein

the

wor

kp

lace

in19

99,

the

nu

mb

erof

full-t

ime

equ

ivale

nt

nu

mb

erof

emp

loye

esin

1999,

an

dth

ese

para

tion

rate

in1999

(per

centa

ge

of

emp

loye

esth

atle

ftth

ew

orkp

lace

sin

ceth

ep

revio

us

year

(1998))

.R

ob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

atth

e10

%,

5%an

d1%

level

sre

spec

tive

ly.

Data

Sou

rce:

Sta

tist

ics

Den

mark

.

31

Page 32: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

le4:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

nan

dT

rade

-E

arnin

gs

Dep

.V

ar.

:C

um

ula

tive

Pri

mary

Ear

nin

gsin

Hig

h-

and

Low

Wag

eJob

sm

inu

sP

rim

ary

Ear

nin

gsin

Mid

Wag

eJob

s(2

002-

2009

)(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)T

rad

e1.3

06*

**

1.20

0***

0.89

1***

0.89

6***

0.87

7***

0.94

8***

0.98

1***

0.95

5***

(0.1

68)

(0.1

71)

(0.1

63)

(0.1

62)

(0.1

64)

(0.1

69)

(0.1

69)

(0.1

71)

Dem

ogra

ph

icC

ontr

ols

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Init

ial

Occ

up

atio

ns

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Ed

uca

tion

Contr

ols

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Init

ial

Wag

eye

sye

sye

sye

sL

ab

orM

arke

tH

isto

ryye

sye

sye

sU

nio

nan

dU

IC

ontr

ols

yes

yes

Init

ial

Fir

mC

ontr

ols

yes

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

nu

mb

erof

obse

rvat

ion

sis

10753.

Aco

nst

ant

isin

clu

ded

bu

tn

ot

rep

ort

ed.

Dem

ogra

ph

icco

ntr

ols

are

age,

gen

der

du

mm

y,an

dim

mig

rati

onst

atu

sd

um

my.

Ed

uca

tion

contr

ols

are

du

mm

yva

riab

les

ind

icati

ng

wh

eth

eran

ind

ivid

ual

has

at

most

hig

hsc

hool

deg

ree,

voca

tion

al

trai

nin

g(a

fter

hig

hsc

hool

)or

coll

ege

an

dab

ove

deg

ree

in1999.

Lab

or

Mark

etH

isto

ryva

riab

les

are

un

emp

loym

ent

his

tory

an

dex

per

ien

ceva

riab

les.

Un

emp

loym

ent

his

tory

isth

enu

mb

erof

year

sb

etw

een

1980-1

999

that

the

ind

ivid

ual

spen

tas

an

un

emp

loye

dp

erso

n.

Exp

erie

nce

isth

enum

ber

of

years

per

son

was

inth

ela

bor

mar

ket

bet

wee

n19

80-1

999.

Init

ial

wage

isth

elo

gari

thm

of

the

aver

age

hou

rly

wage

of

an

ind

ivid

ual

(fro

mh

is/h

erp

rim

ary

occ

up

atio

nin

T&

C)

in19

99an

d20

00.

Init

ial

Occ

up

ati

on

sare

ind

icato

rva

riab

les

wh

eth

eran

ind

ivid

ual

was

emp

loyed

in1999

hav

ing

ah

igh

-wage,

mid

-wag

eor

low

-wag

eocc

up

atio

n(o

uts

ide

cate

gory

isu

nsp

ecifi

edocc

up

ati

on

s).

Un

ion

an

dU

IC

ontr

ols

are

Un

ion

mem

ber

ship

an

dU

Im

emb

ersh

ipva

riab

les.

Un

ion

mem

ber

ship

isa

du

mm

yva

riab

lein

dic

ati

ng

ifth

ein

div

idual

isa

mem

ber

of

ala

bor

un

ion

.U

Im

emb

ersh

ipis

ad

um

my

vari

ab

lein

dic

atin

gif

the

ind

ivid

ual

isa

mem

ber

ofth

e(v

olu

nta

ry)

Un

emp

loym

ent

Insu

ran

ceF

un

d.

Init

ial

work

pla

ceco

ntr

ols

are

the

logari

thm

of

the

aver

age

hou

rly

wag

ein

the

wor

kp

lace

in19

99,

the

nu

mb

erof

full-t

ime

equ

ivale

nt

nu

mb

erof

emp

loye

esin

1999,

an

dth

ese

para

tion

rate

in1999

(per

centa

ge

of

emp

loye

esth

atle

ftth

ew

orkp

lace

sin

ceth

ep

revio

us

year

(1998))

.R

ob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

atth

e10

%,

5%an

d1%

level

sre

spec

tive

ly.

Data

Sou

rce:

Sta

tist

ics

Den

mark

.

32

Page 33: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

5.2 Trade and workers’ shift across occupations with different

wage levels

While the previous section has shown that trade can explain the U-shaped pattern of

job polarization, we have so far employed a summary measure of polarization, additions

to the tails minus reductions in the middle of the wage distribution. In order to see what

the relative contribution of tails versus middle of the distribution is, and whether there is

indeed evidence that the hollowing out of the middle is the flip side of gains in the tails,

we now turn to analyzing the high-, mid-level, and low-wage occupations separately.

The regression specification is analogous to equation (1), except that the dependent

variables are summing the years of employment for each occupation category x = h,m, l

separately. For example, JP h,empi is the number of years worker i was employed in high-

wage occupations during the years 2002 to 2009, and analogously JPm,empi and JP l,emp

i

for mid-level and low-wage employment.

Table 5 presents these results. We see that workers exposed to import competition from

China spend about 0.2 years more on average in high-wage jobs, compared to otherwise

similar workers that are not exposed to import competition from China. For mid-level

employment, the coefficient on Tradei is about −0.4, while for low-level employment the

coefficient is again about 0.2 (columns 2 and 3, respectively). Trade has hollowed out the

middle of the wage distribution, and it has added jobs both at the top and the bottom of

the distribution. Furthermore, the sum of the Tradei coefficients across the occupation

categories is approximately equal to zero, and it is likely that the fatter tails and the

hollowed out middle are the flip sides of the same phenomenon. Additional analysis

shows that hours worked losses in mid-level wage jobs are only to 2/3 compensated by

gains in high-wage and low-wage hours, and high-wage hour gains are more important

than low-wage gains. Results for earnings polarization are similar (results are available

33

Page 34: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

le5:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

nan

dIm

por

tC

omp

etit

ion

-Y

ears

ofE

mplo

ym

ent

inH

igh,

Mid

,an

dL

owW

age

Job

s

JP

h,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

l,em

pi

JP

h,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

l,em

pi

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Tra

de

0.22

9***

-0.3

94**

*0.

193*

**0.

216*

**-0

.382

***

0.17

8***

(0.0

40)

(0.0

52)

(0.0

38)

(0.0

40)

(0.0

52)

(0.0

38)

Fem

ale

0.19

9***

-0.3

35**

*0.

171*

**0.

032

-0.3

71**

*0.

292*

**(0

.045

)(0

.057

)(0

.041

)(0

.046

)(0

.060

)(0

.043

)2-

Dig

itIS

CO

Du

mm

ies

no

no

no

yes

yes

yes

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

nu

mb

erof

obse

rvat

ion

sis

10753.

Alt

hou

gh

on

lyco

effici

ent

esti

mate

sof

‘Fem

ale

’co

ntr

ol

isre

port

ed,

all

regre

ssio

ns

incl

ud

ea

con

stan

tan

dth

efu

ll-s

etof

contr

ols

,Z

W ian

dZ

F i.

Inco

lum

ns

(4)-

(6)

init

ial

occ

upati

on

sare

contr

oll

edfo

ru

sin

g2-d

igit

ISC

Oocc

up

atio

nd

um

mie

s.R

obu

stst

and

ard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

at

the

10

%,

5%

an

d1%

level

sre

spec

tive

ly.

Dat

aSou

rce:

Sta

tist

ics

Den

mar

k.

34

Page 35: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

upon request).30

We have also confirmed the robustness of the results by employing a logarithmic trans-

formation of the dependent variable, as well as the revenue share of MFA goods instead

of the Tradei indicator variable. See Tables A-4 and A-5 in the appendix.31

5.2.1 Worker’s susceptibility to job polarization

Occupation While the set of regressors includes indicator variables for each worker’s

initial occupation in the broad wage distribution (high, mid-level, or low-wage occupa-

tion), there are differences across occupations within broader occupation groups in how

susceptible workers are to job polarization; we have seen evidence of that in the case of

machine operators versus drivers in section 2 above. If this variation would be corre-

lated with exposure to import competition our results might be spurious, even though

Figure A-1 shows that the distribution of broad occupational categories for workers at

trade exposed and non-exposed firms was quite similar. We address these concerns by

adding indicator variables for worker i’s employment in each of the 22 two-digit occupa-

tional codes. The results for high-, mid-level, and low-wage employment job polarization

regressions turn out to be not strongly affected by the inclusion of the two-digit occupa-

tional dummies. The trade coefficients for high-, mid-level, and low-wage employment

remain roughly at 0.2, −0.4, and 0.2, respectively (columns 4, 5, and 6 of Table 5). From

this it does not appear to be the case that the trade effect on job polarization is driven

30Our findings here are in line with Utar’s (2015) analysis of worker’s adjustment costs. She showsthat workers who move down the ladder of occupations to ’low-end’ service sector jobs face significantadjustment costs in the form of difficulties in keeping these jobs. These workers suffer from frequentunemployment disruptions while their primary attachment to the labor market continued to be these’low-end’ jobs.

31 In Table A-4 we provide the results from transforming the dependent variables into logarithmicscale (after adding an arbitrary amount to make the minimum value one) and the results are robust.We also employ the manufacturing revenue share of goods that were subject to the removal of quotasfor China in 1999 in worker i’s initial employer as an alternative trade exposure variable. See Utar

(2014, 2015) on these modifications. The revenue share trade variable, T radei , takes into account thedegree in which the initial firms were exposed to the competition. We find that our results are robust(see Table A-5).

35

Page 36: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

by differences in the susceptibility of occupations for polarization.

In addition, we have examined a number of major occupations in more detail by creating

interaction variables, such as Tradei ×Managersi, where Managersi is equal to one if

worker i worked as a manager in year 1999, and zero otherwise. Other occupations for

which we construct interaction variables are professionals, associate professionals and

technicians, clerks, and machine operators. These interaction variables are introduced

together with the Tradei variable.

We find that plant and machine operators (ISCO 8) constitute the group that is most

strongly behind the result that trade causes job polarization (Table A-6, Panel F). We

also present the analysis separately only among machine operators (ISCO 82) (see Table

A-7) and find that trade leads to a loss of eight months of mid-wage employment, and

increases of low-wage and high-wage employment of about four months and one month

respectively over a period of eight years. Outside of machine operator occupations, trade

does in fact not cause a significant hollowing out of employment in mid-level wage jobs.

Managers, associate professionals and technicians, and clerks hardly contribute to our

finding that trade causes job polarization (Panels A, C, and D). Interestingly, profes-

sionals significantly gain mid-level employment through trade, which is the opposite of

the experience of machine operators (Panel B). If job switching triggered by trade lets

professionals to disproportionately stay within the same sector as their tasks are rela-

tively demanded compared to other occupations (see Utar 2014, 2015 as well as Figure

1 in the Supplementary Appendix), this combined with the fact that manufacturing

sector is relatively rich in mid-wage jobs compared to service sectors may explain the

difference. This provides initial evidence for significant differences in the impact of trade

across different occupations. We will return to this in more detail when discussing the

relationship between trade and task characteristics in contributing to job polarization

in section 5.4 below.

36

Page 37: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Education We are also interested in how workers with different levels of education

fare in the face of import competition from China. We employ another set of interaction

variables of the form Tradei×Educi, where Educi takes on a value of one if the highest

education level of worker i in 1999 is college, vocational school, and at most high school,

respectively, and zero otherwise. Including the trade-education interaction together

with the Tradei variable, we find that college-educated workers do not contribute to

job polarization caused by trade (Table A-8, Panel A), in fact college-educated workers

at firms exposed to import competition tend to gain, not lose, in terms of mid-level

employment. In contrast, workers with at most high school education bear the brunt

of the job polarization caused by trade (Panel C). This is in line with the general

pattern of job polarization observed in Denmark between 2000-2009 (see Figure 4 in the

Supplementary Appendix).

5.2.2 Job polarization through shifts within versus between industries

In this section we discuss the impact of trade for high-, mid-level, and low-wage employ-

ment across sectors. The results are shown in Table 6. In the upper left corner, recall

that the coefficient on Tradei of 0.229 means that workers employed in 1999 in textiles

and clothing firms exposed to import competition from China have had between 2002

and 2009 0.229 years of employment more in high-wage occupations than workers that

were not employed by exposed textiles and clothing firms. The question addressed in

this section is whether the job polarization impact of trade is associated with worker

movements between broad sectors.

As columns 2 and 3 show, the gain in high-wage employment that trade has caused is en-

tirely due to workers moving into sectors outside of manufacturing (coefficient of 0.283).

There is no significant high-wage employment gain through trade within manufacturing

(coefficient of -0.054).32 On the other hand, the employment loss in mid-level jobs is

32By construction, the coefficient in column 1 is the sum of the coefficients in columns 2 and 3, andanalogously for the other columns of Table 6.

37

Page 38: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

entirely due to reductions in mid-level manufacturing jobs (columns 5 and 6). Indeed

trade causes increase in mid-wage jobs in the service sector (as it pushes workers toward

the service sector), yet the net effect is negative. Columns 8 and 9 show that the increase

in low-wage employment is split between manufacturing jobs and non-manufacturing.

Overall, the pattern can be summarized by noting that the mid-wage employment losses

are due to decline in manufacturing jobs while employment gains at the tails require to

leave manufacturing, especially if a worker succeeds in moving to high-wage employment.

This finding shows that frictions to the movement of workers across sectors implies that

international trade can increase welfare for some workers (those with sufficiently low

cost of moving) while at the same time it decreases welfare of other workers (those with

high cost of moving), irrespective of any other effects of trade on welfare.

Because non-manufacturing includes a broad set of diverse activities, in the following we

isolate the services sector, see Panel B of Table 6.33 The results indicate that the em-

ployment changes caused by trade into non-manufacturing are almost entirely accounted

for by shifts into the services sector.34 Specifically, columns 1-3 of Panel B show that 100

% of all high-wage employment gain is due to service sector jobs and columns 8 through

9 shows that 60 % of all low-wage employment gain is due to ’low-paid’ service jobs.

Earlier work has emphasized the service sector in the context of job polarization (Autor

and Dorn 2013). We extend this evidence by showing on the basis of micro evidence

that this pattern is particularly true for job polarization caused by trade.

33The other non-manufacturing sectors are agriculture, fishing, energy and construction.34See also Utar (2015) on this.

38

Page 39: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

le6:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

nan

dJob

Shif

tsW

ithin

vers

us

Outs

ide

Man

ufa

cturi

ng

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

Pan

elA

.

Dep

.V

ar

JP

h,emp

iJP

h,emp

iJP

h,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

l,em

pi

JP

l,em

pi

JP

l,em

pi

Wit

hin

Ou

tsid

eW

ith

inO

uts

ide

Wit

hin

Ou

tsid

eM

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.T

rad

e0.2

29***

-0.0

54

0.28

3***

-0.3

94**

*-0

.551

***

0.15

7***

0.19

3***

0.07

4**

0.11

9***

(0.0

40)

(0.0

34)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

52)

(0.0

48)

(0.0

29)

(0.0

38)

(0.0

23)

(0.0

32)

Fem

ale

0.1

99***

0.0

490.

150*

**-0

.335

***

-0.3

39**

*0.

004

0.17

1***

-0.1

20**

*0.

291*

**(0

.045

)(0

.035

)(0

.034

)(0

.057

)(0

.053

)(0

.034

)(0

.041

)(0

.025

)(0

.033

)

Pan

elB

.

Dep

.V

ar

JP

h,emp

iJP

h,emp

iJP

h,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

l,em

pi

JP

l,em

pi

JP

l,em

pi

Wit

hin

Wit

hin

Wit

hin

Wit

hin

Wit

hin

Wit

hin

Manu

f.S

ervic

eM

anu

f.S

ervic

eM

anu

f.S

ervic

eT

rad

e0.2

29***

-0.0

54

0.27

6***

-0.3

94**

*-0

.551

***

0.15

6***

0.19

3***

0.07

4**

0.11

6***

(0.0

40)

(0.0

34)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

52)

(0.0

48)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

38)

(0.0

23)

(0.0

31)

Fem

ale

0.1

99***

0.0

490.

158*

**-0

.335

***

-0.3

39**

*0.

128*

**0.

171*

**-0

.120

***

0.33

2***

(0.0

45)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

34)

(0.0

57)

(0.0

53)

(0.0

31)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

25)

(0.0

32)

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

nu

mb

erof

obse

rvat

ions

is10753.

Aco

nst

ant

isin

clu

ded

bu

tn

ot

rep

ort

ed.

Alt

hou

gh

on

lyco

effici

ent

esti

mate

sof

‘Fem

ale

’co

ntr

olis

rep

orte

d,

all

regr

essi

ons

incl

ud

ea

con

stant

an

dth

efu

ll-s

etof

contr

ols

,Z

W ian

dZ

F i.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗

and

∗∗∗

ind

icat

esi

gnifi

can

ceat

the

10%

,5%

an

d1%

leve

lsre

spec

tivel

y.D

ata

Sou

rce:

Sta

tist

ics

Den

mark

.

39

Page 40: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

5.3 Technology and offshoring explanations for job polarization

In existing analyses of the causes of job polarization technology explanations play a

central role. We therefore expect that routine-biased technical change (RBTC) helps to

explain job polarization in our sample. The question is only to what extent, and whether

trade mimics RBTC, in which case after controlling for RBTC the Tradei variable will

lose its significance. We are also interested in the extent to which the import competition

effect is correlated with offshoring. China is a major offshoring destination, especially

after it entered the WTO, and an increase of textiles and clothing goods from China

could be related to offshoring decisions of Danish firms. Alternatively, if trade turns out

to be unrelated to offshoring, it might be more plausible to think of autonomous Chinese

production as the result of technology diffusion to Chinese-owned firms.

We employ measures of RBTC and offshoring that are well established in the literature.

One, the potential for occupational changes due to RBTC is captured by the routine

task intensity (RTI; the variable is denoted as RTIi) introduced in section 2. Two,

the likelihood of polarization due to offshoring, denoted Offshoringi, is captured by a

measure of Goos, Manning, and Salomons (2014).35 Both RBTC and offshoring variables

are defined at the two-digit level of occupations.36 Table 7 presents these results. All

regressions include the full set of worker and firm controls of Table 2.

We see that workers who were exposed to the import shock have a significantly higher

likelihood of moving to jobs that are located at either end of the wage distribution, while

differences in offshorability help to explain job polarization as well (column 1). The table

gives standardized beta coefficients in square brackets, which indicate that trade has a

larger effect on job polarization than offshoring. Given the central role of computers for

technical change in manufacturing recently, we add next a measure of the intensity of the

35We have also considered Blinder and Krueger’s (2013) offshoring measure, finding broadly similarresults.

36Note that RBTC and offshoring measures are taken from Goos, Manning, and Salomons (2014) andthey are at the 2-digit ISCO level.

40

Page 41: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

worker’s interaction with computers (ICTi, column 2). Note that this does not simply

measure whether the worker is prone to be replaced by a computer. Rather, the measure

picks up that there are certain aspects of the job that can be codified, explaining the

presence of the computer, but the worker’s task might involve to monitor and evaluate

output from the computer, which is likely a non-routine task. We find no significant

effect for this ICT variable.

However, when we add the routine task index (RTI), not only is there more job polar-

ization for routine tasks, as expected, but interacting with computers now enters with

a negative sign (column 3). This suggests that the routine task index helps to separate

routine from non-routine tasks in our ICT variable. The positive and significant coeffi-

cient on RTI in column 3 confirms earlier results that RBTC is a factor explaining job

polarization in Denmark. We estimate a coefficient for Tradei that is hardly affected by

the inclusion of the offshoring and task variables. In terms of beta coefficients the impact

of trade appears to be substantial, larger than that of technology factors captured by

the RTI variable.

Next, we investigate the relationship between import competition from China and off-

shoring. While offshoring affects primarily intermediate inputs trade and the China

quota removal leads to an inflow of final goods into Denmark (Utar 2014), it is neverthe-

less possible that the two are related. In particular, it could be that certain tasks that

workers used to perform in Denmark are offshored to China, where they are combined

with other tasks before the final textiles and clothing good is exported from China to

Denmark.

We employ an interaction variable between import competition from China and off-

shoring, Tradei × Offshoringi, to see whether there is evidence for a complementary

relationship between offshoring and imports from China. The inclusion of the interac-

tion variable turns the linear offshoring effect to zero, while the size of the linear Tradei

effect shrinks to around 0.3 (column 4). Offshoring and imports from China appear to

41

Page 42: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

le7:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

n,

Off

shor

ing,

Tec

hnol

ogy,

and

Tra

de

JP

emp

iJP

emp

iJP

emp

iJP

emp

iJP

emp

iJP

emp

iJP

emp

i(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)

Tra

de

0.8

39**

*0.

842*

**0.

833*

**0.

341*

*0.

712*

**0.

848*

**0.

769*

**(0

.098

)(0

.098

)(0

.098

)(0

.131

)(0

.100

)(0

.114

)(0

.104

)[0

.083

][0

.084

][0

.083

][0

.034

][0

.071

][0

.084

][0

.076

]O

ffsh

orin

g0.1

45**

0.13

8**

0.13

5**

0.00

20.

116*

0.13

5**

(0.0

44)

(0.0

47)

(0.0

47)

(0.0

53)

(0.0

47)

(0.0

47)

[0.0

46]

[0.0

43]

[0.0

43]

[0.0

01]

[0.0

37]

[0.0

43]

Inte

ract

ing

wit

hC

omp

ute

rs(I

CT

)-0

.029

-0.2

26**

-0.2

13*

0.07

3-0

.224

*(0

.069

)(0

.088

)(0

.088

)(0

.098

)(0

.088

)[-

0.00

6][-

0.04

4][-

0.04

1][0

.014

][-

0.04

4]R

outi

ne

Task

Inte

nsi

ty(R

TI)

0.34

8**

0.36

9***

0.38

1***

0.35

9**

(0.1

06)

(0.1

07)

(0.1

07)

(0.1

16)

[0.0

60]

[0.0

64]

[0.0

66]

[0.0

62]

Tra

de*

Off

shori

ng

0.33

5***

(0.0

59)

[0.

087]

Tra

de*

ICT

-0.6

54**

*(0

.100

)[

-0.0

90]

Tra

de*

RT

I-0

.026

(0.1

15)

[-0

.004

]4-

Dig

itIS

CO

Du

mm

ies

no

no

no

no

no

no

yes

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

nu

mb

erof

obse

rvati

on

sis

8702.

Aco

nst

ant

an

dth

efu

llse

tof

contr

ols

,Z

W ian

dZ

F i,

are

incl

ud

edin

all

regre

ssio

ns

bu

tnot

rep

orte

d.

“Off

shor

ing”

isth

eoff

shor

abil

ity

ind

exof

the

corr

esp

on

din

gtw

od

igit

init

ial

ISC

O-8

8occ

up

ati

on

cod

eof

aw

ork

er.

Itis

con

stru

cted

by

Goos,

Man

nin

gan

dS

alom

ons

(201

4).

“IC

T”

isth

ein

dex

vari

ab

lein

dic

ati

ng

the

deg

ree

inw

hic

hth

ein

itia

l(4

-dig

it)

occ

up

ati

on

of

aw

ork

erin

tera

cts

wit

hco

mp

ute

rs.

Itis

anO

*NE

T(v

ersi

on14

)va

riab

lean

dva

ries

acr

oss

4-d

igit

occ

up

ati

on

s.“R

TI”

isth

ero

uti

ne

inte

nsi

tyin

dex

of

the

corr

esp

on

din

gtw

od

igit

init

ial

ISC

O-8

8occ

up

atio

nco

de

ofa

wor

ker

.T

he

RT

Iin

dex

foll

ows

Au

tor,

Lev

yan

dM

urn

an

e(2

003)

an

dA

uto

ran

dD

orn

(2012).

Off

shori

ng

ind

exis

not

avai

lab

lefo

rce

rtai

nIS

CO

2-d

igit

cate

gori

es(s

eeth

eS

up

ple

men

tary

Ap

pen

dix

)an

dIC

Tin

dex

isn

ot

avail

ab

leacr

oss

cert

ain

4-d

igit

ISC

Os

as

they

are

pro

vid

edby

O*N

ET

.F

inal

ly7

%of

wor

kers

hav

eu

ndet

erm

ined

init

ial

occ

up

ati

on

s.H

ence

run

nin

gth

ees

tim

ati

on

sin

aco

mm

on

sam

ple

dec

rease

sth

enu

mb

erof

obse

rvat

ion

sto

8702

.C

ontr

ol

vari

ab

les

are

des

crib

edin

the

note

sof

Tab

le3.

Sta

nd

ard

ized

coeffi

cien

tsare

rep

ort

edin

squ

are

bra

cket

s.R

obu

stst

and

ard

erro

rsar

ere

por

ted

inp

aren

thes

es.

∗ ,∗∗

an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

at

the

10

%,

5%

an

d1

%le

vels

resp

ecti

vely

.D

ata

Sou

rce:

Sta

tist

ics

Den

mar

k.

42

Page 43: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

be complements, most likely because task offshoring leads to new final goods that are

being shipped from China to compete for customers in Denmark. We also consider an

analogous interaction variable between Tradei and ICTi,. Trade hardly leads to job

polarization through workers whose tasks involve interacting with computers, see col-

umn 5. When instead we include an interaction between Tradei and the broader RTIi

variable, it does not enter significantly (column 6). It appears that the ICTi variable

captures quite well the task characteristics that shield a worker from job polarization.37

Finally, column 7 introduces four-digit occupational indicator variables. By construc-

tion, the occupational dummies fully account for the variation in RTI–our RTI variable

varies at the two-digit ISCO level–, and the trade effect is with 0.77 similar in size to

before.

5.4 Unpacking the trade effect

It is important to go further because as noted above, it has been challenging at times to

distinguish trade from technology causes of job polarization. In this section we look at

the intersection of exposure to import competition and specific tasks from the O*NET

data base at the level of individual workers.38 Our approach will be to interact the 0/1

variable Tradei with a measure of the importance of a particular task in that worker i’s

four-digit occupation class. The regression of cumulative worker employment in 2002 to

2009 then includes three terms, in addition to all worker and firm characteristics from

before. These three variables are the linear trade and task measures, denoted by Tradei

and ONETi, together with their interaction Tradei × ONETi. In Table 8 we show

results for six specific O*NET measures; additional results can be found in Tables 2 to

37As we will see below, workers interacting with computers are less likely to lose mid-level wage jobs,and also less likely shift to low-wage jobs than the average worker (Table 8).

38We use O*NET June 2009 version 14. See the data appendix section in the Supplementary Appendixfor further details.

43

Page 44: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

8 of the Supplementary Appendix.39

The six O*NET tasks are representative of routine manual tasks (Panel A), non-routine

manual tasks (Panel B), routine cognitive tasks (Panel C), abstract tasks (Panel D),

information and communication technology-intensive tasks (Panel E), and tasks that

are intensive in face-to-face communication (Panel F). Tasks along these lines have been

emphasized in influential studies of job polarization, and based on this work one would

expect that routine tasks contribute to job polarization (Panes A and C) while non-

routine tasks do not (Panels B and D) (Autor, Levy, Murnane 2003, Autor and Dorn

2013). Tasks that involve intensively interacting with computers would also tend to

be non-routine (the computer itself performs the routine part of the tasks), while face-

to-face communication intensive tasks tend to prevent offshoring and thus reduce job

polarization (Blinder and Krueger 2013, Firpo, Fortin, and Lemieux 2011). We present

results both for the measure that sums the absolute value of employment changes in

high-, mid-level, and low-wage jobs (JP empi ), and for each of these three wage groups

separately.

Starting with the former, we see that workers have been affected quite differently by

trade depending on the specific tasks they perform. On average trade has caused an

employment churn of about 0.8 years in our JP empi measure. The first column of Table 8

shows that the marginal effect of Tradei ranges from essentially zero for routine cognitive

tasks (0.524+(-0.587)= -0.063, see Panel C) to a whopping 1.4 years in the case of non-

routine manual tasks such as those requiring gross body coordination (Panel B). At the

same time, while there is variation in the size of trade’s impact on job polarization, trade

has contributed to job polarization through workers performing most kinds of tasks. We

also see that trade’s effect is particularly high for manual tasks.

In contrast, as expected there are tasks (and associated technologies) that contribute to

39In order to keep the analysis transparent we utilize individual O*NET measures and check therobustness of the results by employing similar O*NET measures classified under the same broad group,rather than creating new composite indices; on this point, see Autor (2013).

44

Page 45: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

job polarization (a positive effect on JP empi ) while other tasks are associated with lower

levels of job polarization (a negative effect on JP empi ). The marginal effect of ONETi

ranges from 0.31 (-0.30+0.61=0.31, Panel B for non-routine manual tasks) to -0.42 (for

ICT intensive tasks Panel E). While routine manual tasks are prone to polarization,

we do not find evidence that this is the case for routine cognitive tasks.40 In line with

expectations is the result that tasks that involve interacting with computers and face-

to-face tend to be less associated with job polarization (Panels E and F).

Looking at the three individual wage groups, we see that across different tasks trade

has caused between almost 0.8 and virtually 0 years of employment less in the mid-

level wage occupations (Panels B and E, column 3). While on average trade leads to a

higher employment of 0.2 years for high-wage occupations, workers performing routine

cognitive tasks do not experience that (column 2, Panel C). In contrast, trade has a

particularly strong effect of shifting workers performing manual tasks into low-wage

occupations (column 4). At the same time, workers that perform ICT-intensive tasks

or require face-to-face communication are less likely shifted through trade into low-wage

jobs (column 4, Panels E and F).

Overall, there is evidence that technology factors and trade overlap to some extent in

causing job polarization. Manual tasks, in particular, whether routine or non-routine,

are prone to job polarization both through technology factors and trade. The fact that

Tradei and ONETi variables are often both significant in Table 8 provides evidence

that technology and trade are sufficiently distinct that we can separately identify their

effect on labor demand. It is also useful to contrast our trade and technology measures

with each other. The O*NET measures highlight important aspects of the worker’s

tasks. At the same time, while the variable Repetitive Motions suggests that these tasks

could be replaced by a robot (e.g. an automated machine-driven process controlled by

a computer), it is not direct evidence of robotization, and it is hard to delineate the

40This is confirmed by results for additional O*NET categories, see Tables 2 and 4 in the Supple-mentary Appendix.

45

Page 46: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

factors that the variable Repetitive Motions picks up. Our comparison of workers who

suddenly are or are not exposed to new import competition from China makes for a

comparatively easy interpretation of the coefficient on Tradei. Strong identification of

the impact of trade is also suggested by the fact that the Tradei × ONETi interaction

effect is estimated quite precisely in all six panels of Table 8 (column 1).41

We now examine gender differences in the way that trade has caused job polarization in

Denmark.

41Also note that in many cases it is the trade-task interaction that yields what one would generallyexpect as the task measure’s marginal effect on job polarization based on earlier research.

46

Page 47: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table 8: Tasks, Trade, and Polarization

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A. Routine Manual TasksTasks with Repetitive Motions

Trade 0.570*** 0.270*** -0.229*** 0.071(0.117) (0.066) (0.062) (0.043)

Repetitive Motions -0.224* -0.312*** 0.050 0.137***(0.089) (0.041) (0.053) (0.034)

Trade*Repetitive Motions 0.397*** -0.022 -0.274*** 0.145***(0.100) (0.052) (0.055) (0.038)

Panel B. Non-Routine Manual TasksTasks with Gross Body Coordination (GBC)

Trade 0.792*** 0.196*** -0.399*** 0.197***(0.095) (0.043) (0.055) (0.040)

GBC -0.304*** -0.494*** 0.050 0.240***(0.091) (0.047) (0.052) (0.030)

Trade*GBC 0.610*** 0.073 -0.374*** 0.163***(0.114) (0.058) (0.064) (0.040)

Panel C. Routine Cognitive TasksEvaluating Information to Determine Compliance with Standards

Trade 0.524*** 0.123* -0.281*** 0.120**(0.107) (0.054) (0.060) (0.043)

Evaluating 0.289*** 0.019 -0.130** 0.139***(0.081) (0.038) (0.048) (0.031)

Trade*Evaluating -0.587*** -0.152** 0.263*** -0.171***(0.113) (0.056) (0.064) (0.047)

Panel D. Abstract TasksTasks that involves thinking creatively (Thinking)

Trade 0.633*** 0.253*** -0.314*** 0.066(0.113) (0.063) (0.061) (0.045)

Thinking 0.200* 0.123** -0.070 0.008(0.081) (0.038) (0.048) (0.034)

Trade*Thinking -0.280** 0.038 0.137* -0.181***(0.098) (0.054) (0.053) (0.040)

Panel E. ICTTasks that involves interacting with computers (ICT)

Trade 0.669*** 0.179*** -0.330*** 0.160***(0.096) (0.048) (0.054) (0.038)

ICT 0.200* 0.359*** 0.009 -0.150***(0.080) (0.038) (0.047) (0.029)

Trade*ICT -0.641*** -0.014 0.387*** -0.239***(0.097) (0.048) (0.055) (0.037)

Panel F. Face to Face Communication Intensive TasksTasks that involve establishing interpersonal relationships

Trade 0.526*** 0.230*** -0.221*** 0.076(0.113) (0.062) (0.061) (0.041)

Interpersonal 0.201** 0.337*** -0.006 -0.141***(0.072) (0.033) (0.043) (0.026)

Trade*Interpersonal -0.420*** -0.007 0.264*** -0.150***(0.085) (0.043) (0.048) (0.033)

Notes: The number of observations is 8819, 9505, 9887, 8876, 9776, and 8816 in Panels A throughF respectively. All regressions include a constant and the full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi . Tasks

measures are from O*NET and vary by workers’ initial 4-digit occupations (ISCO). The availability oftask measures across occupations determine the number of observations. Robust standard errors arereported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively.Data Source: Statistics Denmark.

47

Page 48: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

5.5 Technology, Trade, Man, Woman

We have shown that women tend to experience job polarization more strongly than men

in Denmark. Controlling for worker and firm characteristics, women experience an ad-

ditional gross churn of 0.7 years of employment away from mid-level and into high- and

low-wage jobs (column 8 of Table 2). This finding is in line with the aggregate pattern

in Denmark during the sample period (see Figure 2 in the Supplementary Appendix)

and it also parallels results for the U.S. (Autor 2010, Figure 4). While job churn can

entail substantial job switching costs, the fact that reductions in mid-level employment

for women are accompanied by substantial gains in high-wage occupations may be con-

sidered evidence that women have more successfully adapted to shifts in demand that

have eroded mid-level wage job opportunities than men (Autor 2010).

At the same time to date we know very little on gender patterns of job polarization at

the level of individual workers. In this section we begin by presenting such evidence for

Denmark. First, is there reason to be more encouraged by the pattern for women than

for men, as is the case in the U.S.? Second, we examine the role of trade for these gender-

specific patterns of polarization. In particular, does import competition allow women

to move up from mid-level to high-level jobs, or does import competition increase the

chance that women fall down the job ladder to low-wage jobs? If women move both

up and down the job ladder, are both shifts of equal importance quantitatively? The

following section provides initial answers on these questions.

48

Page 49: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table 9: Trade, Man, Woman

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A.Trade 1.145*** 0.364*** -0.546*** 0.236***

(0.134) (0.065) (0.078) (0.053)Trade*Female -0.575** -0.236** 0.265* -0.074

(0.176) (0.082) (0.104) (0.074)Panel B.

Trade 1.112*** 0.317*** -0.549*** 0.245***(0.135) (0.064) (0.079) (0.053)

Trade*Female -0.584*** -0.176* 0.290** -0.117(0.177) (0.081) (0.104) (0.074)

2-digit ISCO Dummies yes yes yes yesPanel C.

Trade 1.110*** 0.283*** -0.562*** 0.266***(0.140) (0.065) (0.082) (0.055)

Trade*Female -0.659*** -0.171* 0.371*** -0.118(0.181) (0.082) (0.106) (0.075)

4-digit ISCO Dummies yes yes yes yes

Notes: In all regressions the number of observations is 10753. All regressions include a constant andthe full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi . Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗

indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively. Data Source: Statistics Denmark.

To get a better feel of job polarization for women in Denmark, we begin by reporting

results for a number of major occupations: managers, professionals, associate profes-

sionals and technicians, clerks, craft workers, and machine operators. We find that

women that were technicians and clerks in year 1999 experience job polarization much

less than men in these occupations, while women who were machine operators in 1999

experience job polarization to a far greater extent than male machine operators (Table

A-11). Female machine operators in the textiles and clothing industry would typically

be operating sewing machines. We also see that there is no difference between 1999

female and male managers in the extent to which they are employed in high-wage jobs

during the subsequent years 2002 to 2009.

In terms of education, we see that women with college education are less prone to job

polarization than men, while in contrast women with at most high school education

are more prone to job polarization than men (Table A-12, column 1, Panels A and C).

49

Page 50: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

College-educated women are less likely than college-educated men to shift into high-wage

occupations, while high school educated women are just as likely to move into high-wage

jobs as men (column 2, Panels A and C). On the other hand, college educated women are

less likely than college-educated men to move into low-wage jobs (column 4, Panel A).

The fact that women with at most a high school diploma are substantially more prone

to job polarization and they move more into low-wage jobs compared to men is in line

with the general pattern observed in Denmark between 2000-2009 (see Supplementary

Appendix, Figure 4).

Next we examine employment polarization through trade in which women are separated

from men (see Table 9). While job polarization overall has affected women more than

men, the extent to which it is driven by trade is only about half as large for women as

it is for men (column 1, Panel A). One might be concerned that this does not control

for differences in the propensity with which men and women work in different occupa-

tions. To address this issue, we control in Panel B for two-digit and in Panel C for

four-digit occupation fixed effects. The result remains largely unchanged: trade causes

substantially less job polarization for women than for men.

Before we look into the reasons for this it is important to ask whether trade-driven job

polarization has had an impact on gender inequality. Columns 2, 3, and 4 of Table 9

show the impact of trade on cumulative employment in high-, mid-level, and low-wage

occupations separately. The key finding here is that trade has shifted women less than

men into high-wage jobs while at the same time trade has pushed women to the same

extent as men into low-wage jobs.42 Trade is not a woman’s best friend because it raises

gender inequality.

An important question is why we estimate that trade affects women and men differently

in leading to job polarization even when we control for detailed occupation characteristics

(at the four-digit ISCO level). In the following we consider movements within and

42This is true even if we look only at the point estimates and ignore the standard errors.

50

Page 51: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

between industries along the lines of our earlier analysis in Table 6. In Table 10 we

report employment changes for the three wage groups (high, mid-level, low) separately

for manufacturing and non-manufacturing. The question is whether there are differences

in how women and men behave in response to a trade shock across wage groups and

sectors.

We see that trade does not lower mid-level wage employment for women as much as for

men within manufacturing (column 4). At the same time, trade does not shift women

as much as men to high-wage jobs outside of manufacturing (column 3). This suggests

that women stay more in the jobs that are hollowed out (mid-level manufacturing) and

move less to high-paying jobs outside of manufacturing than men. Women tend to be

more stayers, not movers, compared to men. This finding is limited, however, to job

polarization caused by trade, as women in general are found experience job polarization

more (they are more prone to leaving mid-wage jobs). While foregoing high-wage jobs

outside of manufacturing relative to men (column 3), trade exposed womens’ tendency

to stay in mid-level manufacturing jobs might benefit women because they do not shift

as much as men into low-wage jobs within manufacturing as men (column 6).

If trade exposed women are less likely to be separated by their competition exposed firms

compared to trade exposed men, then this may explain why women are relatively less

prone to polarization caused by trade. To better understand this we focus on mid-wage

level jobs within the manufacturing sector (see Table 11). In column (1) of Panel A is

the cumulative employment in mid-wage occupations within the manufacturing sector.

We then decompose the asymmetric effect of trade on women into the effect within and

outside the initial firm in columns 2 and 3 respectively. We repeat the analysis with

cumulative hours worked since women may be relatively likely to accept reduced hours

of work at the initial firm instead of leaving for another job (Utar 2015).

First, comparing the Tradei coefficients of columns 1 and 2, in Panel A, Table 11 shows

that the decrease in mid-level employment caused by trade is entirely due to employment

51

Page 52: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

le10

:T

rade,

Man

,W

oman

-Wit

hin

and

Outs

ide

Man

ufa

cturi

ng

Dep

.V

ar

JP

emp

iJP

h,emp

iJP

m,emp

iJP

l,em

pi

Wit

hin

Ou

tsid

eW

ith

inO

uts

ide

Wit

hin

Ou

tsid

eM

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.M

anu

f.(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)

Tra

de

1.1

45*

**

-0.0

030.

367*

**-0

.661

***

0.11

5**

0.12

7***

0.10

9**

(0.1

34)

(0.0

56)

(0.0

48)

(0.0

74)

(0.0

44)

(0.0

38)

(0.0

39)

Tra

de*

Fem

ale

-0.5

75**

-0.0

90-0

.146

*0.

192*

0.07

3-0

.092

*0.

018

(0.1

76)

(0.0

68)

(0.0

63)

(0.0

96)

(0.0

59)

(0.0

45)

(0.0

62)

Fem

ale

0.9

66*

**

0.09

00.

216*

**-0

.426

***

-0.0

29-0

.078

*0.

283*

**(0

.125)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

71)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

31)

(0.0

43)

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

nu

mb

erof

obse

rvat

ion

sis

10753.

Aco

nst

ant

isin

clu

ded

bu

tn

ot

rep

ort

ed.

All

regre

ssio

ns

incl

ud

ea

con

stant

an

dth

efu

ll-s

etof

contr

ols,

ZW i

andZ

F i.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

at

the

10

%,

5%

an

d1%

leve

lsre

spec

tive

ly.

Dat

aS

ourc

e:S

tati

stic

sD

enm

ark

.

52

Page 53: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

losses at the initial firm, not due to lower employment in other manufacturing firms.

Given the importance of employment losses at the initial firm, does this differ between

men and women? Table 11 shows that import shock does not have any significant

asymmetric effect on women compared to men at the initial firm. That is, both women

and men are affected by the shock to the same extent. This is reassuring because we

have controlled for a substantial number of worker and firm characteristics (see Table

2). Panel A shows that 64 % of the asymmetric effect of trade on women (0.123/0.192)

is due to mid-wage jobs within manufacturing but outside the initial firm. In terms

of hours worked, 71 % of the effect is due mid-wage manufacturing jobs outside the

initial firm. Thus, the difference in the extent that trade causes job polarization for men

and women is largely due to gender differences in the propensity of moving to different

sectors.

What might explain these different responses in the face of a trade shock? It is important

to keep in mind that women do not in general switch jobs and sectors less than men,

because we have seen above that women are more likely than men to gain both high-

and low-wage employment in the services sector (Table 6). The question is why women

are more attached to mid-level manufacturing jobs than men in the presence of a trade

shock? We believe that this could be related to both the suddenness of the trade shock, as

well as its massive size. The shock to labor demand through trade in the Danish textiles

and clothing industry lead to a drastic resizing of the industry. When the industry is

undergoing massive changes, the labor market environment might be similar to that in

times of mass layoffs during recessions (Jacobson, Lalonde, and Sullivan 1993). In the

more recent 2008 Great Recession, aggregate data for the U.S. suggests that women’s

employment rates have recovered less well than those of men (Pew Research Center

2011). It is important to better understand similarities and differences between the

labor market impact of trade on the one, and of recessions on the other hand. What we

have documented is that a sudden and large-scale reduction in labor demand through

trade is relatively more challenging for women than for men, compared to a gradual

53

Page 54: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

shift of labor demand across sectors as, for example, the introduction of information

technology and computers since the early 1980s.43

Table 11: Women and Mid-Wage Occupations

Panel A.Dep. Var Cumulative employment in mid-wage occupations within manufacturing 2002-2009

Within Manuf. Within the Initial Firm Outside the Initial Firm(1) (2) (3)

Trade -0.661*** -0.668*** 0.007(0.074) (0.058) (0.059)

Trade*Female 0.192* 0.069 0.123(0.096) (0.076) (0.074)

Female -0.426*** -0.052 -0.375***(0.071) (0.061) (0.052)

Panel B.Dep. Var Cumulative hours worked in mid-wage occupations within manufacturing 2002-2009

Overall Within Manuf. Within the Initial Firm Outside the Initial Firm(1) (2) (3)

Trade -0.768*** -0.688*** -0.080(0.085) (0.061) (0.071)

Trade*Female 0.205 0.059 0.146(0.116) (0.082) (0.096)

Female -0.390*** -0.038 -0.352***(0.091) (0.066) (0.075)

Notes: In all columns the number of observations is 10753. A constant is included but not reported. All regressionsinclude a constant and the full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi . Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.

∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively. Data Source: Statistics Denmark.

6 Conclusions

Using administrative employee-employer matched data from Statistics Denmark covering

all residents of Denmark, we document that Denmark, like many other rich countries,

experienced job polarization in recent years which coincided with a dramatic increase

in Chinese exports to these countries. We document that employment share changes

of workers in the manufacturing sector exhibit a U-shaped pattern away from mid-

43We have also examined how gender affected the impact of technology factors on job polarizationby employing the interaction of Femalei and O NETi, see Table A-13. Overall, these results showthat the gender difference plays an important role in our finding that trade and technology factors aredistinct causes of job polarization in Denmark.

54

Page 55: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

level and toward high- and low-wage jobs while workers in the service sector experience

employment changes that are increasing with wages and skills between 2000 and 2009.

This is important for at least two reasons. The trade effect is relatively concentrated in

manufacturing, whereas technical change affects also, and increasingly, sectors outside

of manufacturing. Second, while technology has gradually changed the workplace in

industrialized countries since the early 1980s, the intensification of import competition

was felt more suddenly, especially in the early 2000s.

To investigate the causal link between Chinese imports and job polarization, we exploit

the exogenous abolishment of trade quotas for China associated with her entry into the

WTO, and utilize heterogeneity in workers’ exposure to this trade shock within the same

narrow industry. This allows us to distinguish the effects of trade from technical change,

whose effect on job polarization is well established. We have shown that trade can

explain the U-shaped changes in employment that are the hallmark of job polarization.

Trade leads to job polarization mainly by pushing workers from initially abundant mid-

level jobs in manufacturing towards both high- and low-wage jobs in services. We have

seen that trade affects most strongly manual labor, workers performing both routine and

non-routine tasks.

We find that the shift from manufacturing to services is crucial for this trade effect.

Worker level evidence sharpens the focus because it lets us observe, in the data, indi-

vidual worker transitions that are the link between sectors. It may be that worker-level

information is one of the reasons why we have found more evidence that trade causes

job polarization than other studies before us.

We also find that while women experience overall job polarization more than men, women

contribute less than men to the part of job polarization that is related to trade. One

reason for the former may be that even within fine occupation classes women might

tend to perform more routine tasks than men, and it appears that women adjust well

in terms job changes in response to gradual changes. In contrast, in the face of the

55

Page 56: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

sudden reduction in labor demand caused by trade, women do not adjust as well as

men. While it is clear that a sudden shock does not give as much opportunity to plan

and prepare, for example re-training, what explains the gender difference? One reason

might be that because women tend to be more strongly involved with child care and

other joint household activities than men, women have higher short-term adjustment

costs. It could also be that the on average lower labor market attachment of women

compared to men makes it harder for women to move when the change is sudden as

opposed to gradual.

The mid-level wage jobs that job polarization feeds on are primarily manufacturing jobs.

Can one make a case that this matters? A shrinking manufacturing sector in industrial-

ized countries might be quite different from other instances of structural change; it may

have broader implications, by affecting industry clustering, city formation, or innova-

tion.44 Mid-level jobs might have important positive spillovers. To the extent that trade

causes job polarization, it determines the size of these spillovers, and trade should be

considered in the formulation of policies that are designed to internalize these spillovers.

What are the implications of job polarization on inequality? While our results show

that trade tends to increase gender inequality because it shifts men to a greater extent

into high-wage jobs than women, this may be all but a small part of the impact of trade

on inequality. As international economic integration increases, if imports from poor

countries continue to hollow out the middle of the wage distribution in rich countries,

the implied increase in inequality might affect social cohesion and broader political

outcomes in rich countries, and beyond.

44On clustering and city formation, see Moretti (2012). The importance of near-by manufacturingfor innovation is also an important question (Keller, Yeaple, and Zolas 2015).

56

Page 57: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

References

[1] Acemoglu, Daron 2002. “Technical Change Inequality, and the Labor Market”,

Journal of Economic Literature, 40(1) : 7-72.

[2] Acemoglu, Daron, and David Autor 2010. “Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Im-

plications for Employment and Earnings”, Handbook of Labor Economics Volume

4, Orley Ashenfelter and David E. Card (eds.), Amsterdam: Elsevier, forthcoming.

[3] Autor, David 2010. “The Polarization of Job Opportunities in the U.S. Labor

Market: Implications for Employment and Earnings”, Center for American Progress

and The Hamilton Project.

[4] Autor, David 2013. “The “task approach” to labor markets: an overview”, Journal

for Labour Market Research, 46(3): 185-199.

[5] Autor, David, and David Dorn 2013. “The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs

and the Polarization of the US Labor Market”, American Economic Review, 103(5):

1553-1597.

[6] Autor, David, David Dorn, and Gordon Hanson. 2013. “The China Syn-

drome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States”,

American Economic Review, 103(6): 2121-2168.

[7] Autor, David, David Dorn, and Gordon Hanson. 2014. “Untangling Trade

and Technology: Evidence from local Labor Markets”, Economic Journal, forth-

coming.

[8] Autor, David, David Dorn, Gordon Hanson and Jae Song. 2014. “Trade

Adjustment: Worker Level Evidence”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129:

1799-1860.

[9] Autor, David, Lawrance F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney 2006. “The

Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market”, American Economic Review: Papers and

Proceedings, 96(2), 189-193.

[10] Autor, David, Lawrance F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney 2008. “Trends

in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists”, The Review of Economics and

57

Page 58: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Statistics, 90(2), 300-323.

[11] Autor, David, Levy, Frank, and Richard Murnane 2003. “The Skill-Content

of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Investigation”, Quarterly Journal

of Economics, 118, 1279-1333.

[12] Bernard, Andrew B., Bradford J. Jensen and Peter K. Schott 2006. “Sur-

vival of the best fit: Exposure to low-wage countries and the (uneven) growth

of U.S. manufacturing plants”, Journal of International Economics, Elsevier, vol.

68(1), 219-237.

[13] Blinder, Alan, and Alan Krueger 2013. “Alternative Measures of Offshorability:

A Survey Approach”, Journal of Labor Economics, 31(2): S97-S128

[14] Bloom, Nicholas, Mirko Draca, and John Van Reenen 2012. “Trade induced

technical change? The impact of Chinese imports on innovation and information

technology”, NBER Working Paper, No. 16717.

[15] Brambilla, Irene, Amit Khandelwal and Peter Schott 2010. “China’s Ex-

perience Under the Multifiber Arrangement (MFA) and the Agreement on Textile

and Clothing (ATC)”, Robert Feenstra and Shang-Jin Wei (Eds), China’s Growing

Role in World Trade, NBER, Cambridge: MA.

[16] Bunzel, Henning 2008. “The LMDG Data Sets”, mimeo, Univeristy of Aarhus.

[17] Dustmann, Christian, Johannes Ludsteck, and Uta Schonberg 2009. “Re-

visiting the German Wage Structure”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124,

843-881.

[18] Feenstra, Robert 2000. Introduction to “The Impact of International Trade on

Wages”, In Robert C. Feenstra, ed., The Impact of International Trade on Wages,

Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1-11.

[19] Firpo, Sergio, Nicole Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux 2011. “Occupational

Tasks and Changes in the Wage Structure”, IZA Discussion Paper 5542, INstitute

for the Study of Labor (IZA).

58

Page 59: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

[20] Goos, Maarten, and Alan Manning 2007. “Lousy and Lovely Jobs: The Rising

Polarization of Work in Britain”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1),

118-133.

[21] Goos, Maarten, Alan Manning, and Anna Salomons 2009. “Job Polarization

in Europe”, American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 99(2), 58-63.

[22] Goos, Maarten, Alan Manning, and Anna Salomons 2014. “Explaining

Job Polarization: Routine-Biased Technological Change and Offshoring”, Amer-

ican Economic Review, 104(8), 2509-2526.

[23] Groes, Fane, Philipp Kircher, and Iorii Manovskii 2015. “The U-Shapes of

Occupational Mobility”, Review of Economic Studies, 82(2).

[24] Grossman, Gene and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg 2008. “Trading Tasks: A Sim-

ple Theory of Offshoring”, American Economic Review, 98:5, 19781997.

[25] Harrigan, James, Ariell Reshef, and Farid Toubal 2015. “The March of the

Techies: Technology, Trade, and Job Polarization in France, 1994-2007”, presented

at Barcelona GSE Summer Forum 2015.

[26] Hummels, David, Rasmus Jorgensen, Jacob Munch, and Chong Xiang

2014. “The Wage Effects of Offshoring: Evidence From Danish Matched Worker-

Firm Data”, American Economic Review, 104(6): 1597-1629.

[27] Jacobson, Louis, Robert LaLonde and Daniel Sullivan 1993. “Earnings

Losses of Displaced Workers”, American Economic Review, 83(4): 685-709.

[28] Keller, Wolfgang, Stephen Yeaple, and Nick Zolas 2015. “Innovation in the

Age of Offshoring”, in progress.

[29] Khandelwal, Amit, Peter Schott and Shang-Jin Wei 2013. “Trade Liberal-

ization and Embedded Institutional Reform: Evidence from Chinese Exporters”,

American Economic Review, Vol. 103(6): 2169-2195.

[30] Michaels, Guy, Ashwini Natraj and John Van Reenen 2014. “Has ICT Po-

larized Skill Demand? Evidence From Eleven Countries Over Twenty-Five Years”,

The Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(1), 60-77.

59

Page 60: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

[31] Moretti, Enrico 2012. The New Geography of Jobs. New York: Houghton Mifflin

Harcourt

[32] Pew Research Center 2011. “Two Years of Economic Recovery: Women Lose

Jobs, Men Find Them”, by Rakesh Kochhar, July 6, 2011.

[33] Pierce, Justin R. and Peter K. Schott. 2014. “The Surprisingly Swift Decline

of U.S. Manufacturing Employment”, NBER Working Paper No. 18655.

[34] Spitz-Oener, Alexandra 2006. “Technical Change, Job Tasks and Rising Educa-

tional Demand: Looking Outside the Wage Structure”, Journal of Labor Economics,

24, 235-270.

[35] Timmermans, Bram 2010. “The Danish Integrated Database for Labor Market

Research: Towards Demystification for the English Speaking Audience”, DRUID

Working Papers 10-16.

[36] Utar, Hale 2014. “When the Floodgates Open: ”Northern” Firms’ Response to

Removal of Trade Quotas on Chinese Goods”, American Economic Journal: Applied

Economics, 6(4): 226-250.

[37] Utar, Hale 2015. “Workers beneath the Floodgates: Impact of Low-Wage Import

Competition and Workers’ Adjustment”, Bielefeld Working Papers in Economics

and Management, No.12.

[38] Utar, Hale, and Luis Torres Ruiz. 2013. “International Competition and In-

dustrial Evolution: Evidence from the Impact of Chinese Competition on Mexican

Maquiladoras”, Journal of Development Economics, 105: 267-287.

Appendix A

60

Page 61: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

0.1

.2.3

.4D

ensi

ty

ISCO-1

Man

ager

s

ISCO-2

Pro

fess

ionals

ISCO-3

Tec

hnici

ans a

nd A

ssoc

iate

Profe

ssion

als

ISCO-4

Cler

ks

ISCO-5

Ser

vice

Wor

kers

ISCO-6

Skil

led A

gr a

nd F

isher

y Wor

kers

ISCO-7

Cra

ft W

orke

rs

ISCO-8

Plan

t and

Mac

hine

Opera

tors

ISCO-9

Elem

enta

ry O

ccup

ation

s

Unkno

wn

OneDigOc

(a) All Workers

0.1

.2.3

.4

ISCO-1

Man

ager

s

ISCO-2

Pro

fess

ionals

ISCO-3

Tec

hnici

ans a

nd A

ssoc

iate

Profe

ssion

als

ISCO-4

Cler

ks

ISCO-5

Ser

vice

Wor

kers

ISCO-6

Skil

led A

gr a

nd F

isher

y Wor

kers

ISCO-7

Cra

ft W

orke

rs

ISCO-8

Plan

t and

Mac

hine

Opera

tors

ISCO-9

Elem

enta

ry O

ccup

ation

s

Unkno

wn

ISCO-1

Man

ager

s

ISCO-2

Pro

fess

ionals

ISCO-3

Tec

hnici

ans a

nd A

ssoc

iate

Profe

ssion

als

ISCO-4

Cler

ks

ISCO-5

Ser

vice

Wor

kers

ISCO-6

Skil

led A

gr a

nd F

isher

y Wor

kers

ISCO-7

Cra

ft W

orke

rs

ISCO-8

Plan

t and

Mac

hine

Opera

tors

ISCO-9

Elem

enta

ry O

ccup

ation

s

Unkno

wn

Workers employed in exposed firms Workers employed in non-exposed firms

Den

sity

OneDigOcGraphs by AffW

(b) By Import Competition

Figure A-1: Histogram of Workers across Major Occupations in 1999

61

Page 62: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table A-1: Workers’ Characteristics in 1999 by Selective Occupation Groups

Mean SD NISCO 1: ManagersAge 44.912 8.302 555Female 0.211 0.408 555Immigrant 0.020 0.140 555College Educated 0.256 0.437 555Vocational School Educated 0.436 0.496 555At most High School 0.297 0.457 555ISCO 2: ProfessionalsAge 39.461 9.634 152Female 0.362 0.482 152Immigrant 0.013 0.114 152College Educated 0.612 0.489 152Vocational School Educated 0.178 0.383 152At most High School 0.184 0.389 152ISCO 3: Technicians and Associate ProfessionalsAge 37.756 9.097 1338Female 0.652 0.477 1338Immigrant 0.028 0.164 1338College Educated 0.371 0.483 1338Vocational School Educated 0.365 0.482 1338At most High School 0.226 0.418 1338ISCO 4: ClerksAge 36.423 9.569 1093Female 0.780 0.414 1093Immigrant 0.019 0.137 1093College Educated 0.151 0.358 1093Vocational School Educated 0.531 0.499 1093At most High School 0.317 0.466 1093ISCO 7: Craft WorkersAge 40.702 10.381 916Female 0.377 0.485 916Immigrant 0.040 0.197 916College Educated 0.061 0.240 916Vocational School Educated 0.487 0.500 916At most High School 0.425 0.495 916ISCO 8: Plant and Machine OperatorsAge 40.617 10.181 4679Female 0.594 0.491 4679Immigrant 0.090 0.287 4679College Educated 0.032 0.175 4679Vocational School Educated 0.276 0.447 4679At most High School 0.665 0.472 4679ISCO 9: Elementary OccupationsAge 38.046 11.247 923Female 0.510 0.500 923Immigrant 0.052 0.222 923College Educated 0.027 0.162 923Vocational School Educated 0.325 0.469 923At most High School 0.627 0.484 923

Notes: Data Source: Statistics Denmark.

62

Page 63: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table A-2: Workers’ Characteristics in 1999 by Selective Occupations and Import Exposure

Mean SD NWeaving and Knitting Machine Operators employed in non-exposed firmsAge 40.566 10.479 304Female 0.247 0.432 304Immigrant 0.089 0.285 304College Educated 0.043 0.203 304Years of Experience in the Labor Market 15.740 5.439 304Unemployment History Index 1019.102 1509.095 304Weaving and Knitting Machine Operators employed in exposed firmsAge 41.966 9.459 205Female 0.288 0.454 205Immigrant 0.112 0.316 205College Educated 0.049 0.216 205Years of Experience in the Labor Market 16.493 4.813 205Unemployment History Index 1122.215 1557.671 205Sewing Machine Operators employed in non-exposed firmsAge 42.849 9.368 537Female 0.946 0.226 537Immigrant 0.143 0.351 537College Educated 0.020 0.142 537Years of Experience in the Labor Market 15.294 5.579 537Unemployment History Index 2573.940 2511.583 537Sewing Machine Operators employed in exposed firmsAge 43.257 10.026 915Female 0.957 0.202 915Immigrant 0.072 0.259 915College Educated 0.026 0.160 915Years of Experience in the Labor Market 16.216 5.255 915Unemployment History Index 1429.028 1695.268 915Post-Processing Textile Machine Operators employed in non-exposed firmsAge 40.478 9.894 502Female 0.329 0.470 502Immigrant 0.084 0.277 502College Educated 0.064 0.245 502Years of Experience in the Labor Market 14.964 5.535 502Unemployment History Index 1374.861 1736.771 502Post-Processing Textile Machine Operators employed in exposed firmsAge 39.030 9.667 133Female 0.323 0.470 133Immigrant 0.045 0.208 133College Educated 0.030 0.171 133Years of Experience in the Labor Market 15.609 5.145 133Unemployment History Index 1464.586 2002.921 133Cutting, Rope Making, Netting, Leather Textile Machine Operators in non-exposed firmsAge 39.888 9.311 251Female 0.199 0.400 251Immigrant 0.008 0.089 251College Educated 0.020 0.140 251Years of Experience in the Labor Market 16.275 4.791 251Unemployment History Index 1713.175 2117.432 251Cutting, Rope Making, Netting, Leather Text. Machine Operators in exposed firmsAge 40.466 10.201 221Female 0.674 0.470 221Immigrant 0.081 0.274 221College Educated 0.032 0.176 221Years of Experience in the Labor Market 15.330 5.396 221Unemployment History Index 1618.543 2068.907 221

Notes: Data Source: Statistics Denmark.

63

Page 64: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

43%52%

Agr, Fishing, Mining ConstructionManufacturing OthersService

The T&C Workers' Industry Affiliation in 2009

Figure A-2: Industry Affiliation of the 1999 T&C Workers in 2009 (conditional onworking)

34%

60%50%

44%

Exposed Non-Exposed

Agr, Fishing, Mining ConstructionManufacturing OthersService

Graphs by ImportCompetition

The T&C Workers' Industry Affiliation in 2009

Figure A-3: Industry Affiliation of the 1999 T&C Workers in 2009 by exposure to importcompetition (conditional on working)

64

Page 65: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

leA

-3:

Ran

kin

gof

Ma

jor

Occ

upat

ions

inD

enm

ark

Occ

up

ati

on

Med

ian

Log

Mea

nL

ogE

mp

loym

ent

Cor

resp

ond

ing

Hou

rly

Wag

eH

ourl

yW

age

Sh

are

in19

91M

ajo

rin

1991

in19

91IS

CO

Hig

h-W

age

Leg

isla

tors

,S

enio

rO

ffici

als,

and

Man

ager

s5.

430

5.46

00.

042

1P

rofe

ssio

nal

s5.

269

5.32

00.

128

2T

ech

nic

ian

san

dA

ssoci

ate

Pro

fess

ion

als

5.07

85.

101

0.18

63

Mid

-Wage

Cra

ftan

dR

elate

dT

rade

Wor

ker

s5.

032

4.94

50.

149

7P

lant

an

dM

ach

ine

Op

erato

rsan

dA

ssem

ble

rs5.

000

5.01

30.

065

8C

lerk

s4.

907

4.89

80.

170

4L

ow

-Wage

Ele

men

tary

Occ

upat

ion

sin

Sal

es,

Ser

vic

es,

4.84

24.

873

0.10

69

(exce

pt

92)

Min

ing,

Con

stru

ctio

n,

Manufa

ctu

rin

g,an

dT

ran

spor

tS

ervic

eW

ork

ers

an

dS

hop

Sale

sW

orke

rs4.

842

4.79

90.

154

5

Dat

aar

efr

om19

91.

Val

ues

are

exp

ress

edin

2000

Dan

ish

Kro

ner

.A

llhou

rly

wages

are

calc

ula

ted

am

on

gw

ork

ers

wit

hfu

ll-t

ime

job

sem

plo

yed

conti

nu

ousl

yw

ith

atle

ast

one

year

tenu

re.

Em

plo

ym

ent

share

sare

calc

ula

ted

usi

ng

the

nu

mb

erof

emp

loye

esan

dex

clu

din

garm

yan

dagri

cult

ure

/fi

sher

yocc

up

atio

ns.

Dat

aS

ourc

e:S

tati

stic

sD

enm

ark.

65

Page 66: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Appendix B

Table A-4: Job Polarization and Import Shock

Dep. Var. ln(9 + JP empi ) ln(1 + JP h,emp

i ) ln(1 + JPm,empi ) ln(1 + JP l,emp

i )(1) (2) (3) (4)

Trade 0.132*** 0.084*** -0.109*** 0.073***(0.015) (0.012) (0.015) (0.013)[0.079] [0.053] [-0.064] [0.054]

Notes: In all regressions the number of observations is 10753. All regressions include a constant and the full-set ofcontrols, ZW

i and ZFi . Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at

the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively. Standardized coefficients are reported in square brackets. Data Source:Statistics Denmark.

Table A-5: Job Polarization and Import Shock–Alternative Trade Exposure

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

T rade 3.220*** 0.904*** -1.582*** 0.734***(0.316) (0.146) (0.181) (0.138)[0.092] [0.051] [-0.079] [0.052]

Notes: T rade is the revenue share of the quotas at worker i’s initial employer in 1999. In all regressionsthe number of observations is 10753. All regressions include a constant and the full-set of controls, ZW

i

and ZFi . Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at the

10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively. Standardized coefficients are reported in square brackets. DataSource: Statistics Denmark.

66

Page 67: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table A-6: Polarization and Trade by Initial Occupation

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A. Managers (ISCO: 1)

Trade 0.830*** 0.240*** -0.404*** 0.186***(0.093) (0.040) (0.055) (0.040)

Trade*Managers -0.972** -0.429 0.393** -0.149(0.321) (0.241) (0.140) (0.081)

Panel B. Professionals (ISCO: 2)

Trade 0.810*** 0.228*** -0.398*** 0.184***(0.090) (0.040) (0.053) (0.038)

Trade*Profs -2.349** -0.830 1.088*** -0.431(0.724) (0.496) (0.322) (0.233)

Panel C. Associate Professionals and Technicians (ISCO: 3)

Trade 0.864*** 0.191*** -0.438*** 0.235***(0.096) (0.039) (0.057) (0.042)

Trade*Technicians -0.706** 0.203 0.449*** -0.460***(0.259) (0.169) (0.126) (0.077)

Panel D. Clerks (ISCO: 4)

Trade 0.879*** 0.258*** -0.442*** 0.179***(0.093) (0.041) (0.054) (0.041)

Trade*Clerks -0.977** -0.396** 0.570** -0.010(0.313) (0.150) (0.184) (0.087)

Panel E. Craft Workers (ISCO: 7)

Trade 0.803*** 0.214*** -0.402*** 0.187***(0.093) (0.042) (0.054) (0.040)

Trade*Craftsmen -0.328 0.029 0.241 -0.116(0.321) (0.130) (0.204) (0.114)

Panel F. Plant and Machine Operators and Assemblers (ISCO: 8)

Trade 0.360** 0.252*** -0.080 0.028(0.120) (0.064) (0.065) (0.046)

Trade*Operators 0.937*** -0.081 -0.681*** 0.337***(0.175) (0.073) (0.104) (0.077)

Notes: In all regressions the number of observations is 10753. All regressions include a constant andthe full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi as well as the 2-digit ISCO (initial occupation) dummies. Robust

standard errors are reported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and1% levels respectively.

67

Page 68: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table A-7: Trade induced Job Polarization among Machine Operators

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)Among Machine Operators (ISCO: 82)

Trade 1.079*** 0.097* -0.659*** 0.323***(0.148) (0.039) (0.095) (0.072)

Notes: Estimation sample consist of workers who were machine operators (ISCO=82) in the textile andclothing sector in 1999. In all regressions the number of observations is 3773. All regressions include aconstant and the full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi . Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.

∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively.

Table A-8: Polarization and Trade by Education

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A. College Educated

Trade 0.931*** 0.253*** -0.464*** 0.214***(0.095) (0.040) (0.056) (0.042)

Trade*College -0.998*** -0.212 0.609*** -0.178*(0.270) (0.163) (0.140) (0.078)

Panel B. Vocational School

Trade 0.852*** 0.214*** -0.388*** 0.250***(0.108) (0.048) (0.063) (0.048)

Trade*Vocational -0.103 0.040 -0.016 -0.159*(0.180) (0.082) (0.106) (0.075)

Panel C. at most High School Diploma

Trade 0.572*** 0.201** -0.279*** 0.091(0.126) (0.064) (0.071) (0.049)

Trade*HS 0.480** 0.054 -0.226* 0.201**(0.170) (0.077) (0.100) (0.073)

Notes: In all regressions the number of observations is 10753. All regressions include a constant andthe full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi . Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗

indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively.

68

Page 69: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

leA

-9:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

n,

Off

shor

ing,

Tec

hnol

ogy,

and

Tra

de

-H

ours

Wor

ked

JP

hrs

iJP

hrs

iJP

hrs

iJP

hrs

iJP

hrs

iJP

hrs

iJP

hrs

i(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)

Tra

de

0.9

12*

**

0.92

2***

0.91

0***

0.51

4**

0.77

4***

0.96

2***

0.86

4***

(0.1

32)

(0.1

32)

(0.1

32)

(0.1

77)

(0.1

35)

(0.1

54)

(0.1

38)

Off

shor

ing

0.1

68*

*0.

142*

0.13

9*0.

032

0.11

80.

138*

(0.0

58)

(0.0

64)

(0.0

64)

(0.0

72)

(0.0

64)

(0.0

63)

ICT

-0.1

04-0

.339

**-0

.329

*-0

.003

-0.3

34**

(0.0

97)

(0.1

28)

(0.1

28)

(0.1

39)

(0.1

29)

RT

I0.

417*

*0.

434*

*0.

454*

*0.

455*

*(0

.156

)(0

.157

)(0

.156

)(0

.166

)T

rad

e*O

ffsh

ori

ng

0.27

0***

(0.0

76)

Tra

de*

ICT

-0.7

37**

*(0

.134

)T

rad

e*R

TI

-0.0

88(0

.161

)4-

Dig

itIS

CO

Du

mm

ies

no

no

no

no

no

no

yes

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

num

ber

ofob

serv

atio

ns

is8702.

Aco

nst

ant

an

dth

efu

llse

tof

contr

ols

,Z

W ian

dZ

F i,

are

incl

ud

edin

all

regre

ssio

ns

bu

tn

otre

por

ted

.“O

ffsh

orin

g”is

the

offsh

orab

ilit

yin

dex

of

the

corr

esp

on

din

gtw

od

igit

init

ial

ISC

O-8

8occ

up

ati

on

cod

eof

aw

ork

er.

Itis

con

stru

cted

by

Goos

,M

ann

ing

and

Sal

omon

s(2

014)

.“I

CT

”is

the

ind

exva

riab

lein

dic

ati

ng

the

deg

ree

inw

hic

hth

ein

itia

l(4

-dig

it)

occ

up

ati

on

of

aw

ork

erin

tera

cts

wit

hco

mp

ute

rs.

Itis

anO

*NE

T(v

ersi

on

14)

vari

ab

lean

dva

ries

acr

oss

4-d

igit

occ

up

ati

on

s.“R

TI”

isth

ero

uti

ne

inte

nsi

tyin

dex

of

the

corr

esp

ond

ing

two

dig

itin

itia

lIS

CO

-88

occ

up

ati

on

cod

eof

aw

ork

er.

Th

eR

TI

ind

exfo

llow

sA

uto

r,L

evy

an

dM

urn

an

e(2

003)

an

dA

uto

ran

dD

orn

(201

2).

Con

trol

vari

able

sar

ed

escr

ibed

inth

en

ote

sof

Tab

le3.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

atth

e10

%,

5%an

d1%

leve

lsre

spec

tive

ly.

Data

Sou

rce:

Sta

tist

ics

Den

mark

.

69

Page 70: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Tab

leA

-10:

Job

Pol

ariz

atio

n,

Off

shor

ing,

Tec

hnol

ogy,

and

Tra

de

-E

arnin

gs

JP

inc

iJP

inc

iJP

inc

iJP

inc

iJP

inc

iJP

inc

iJP

inc

i(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)

Tra

de

0.9

92*

**

1.00

0***

0.98

8***

0.76

4**

0.85

1***

1.05

5***

0.95

1***

(0.1

77)

(0.1

75)

(0.1

75)

(0.2

43)

(0.1

77)

(0.2

07)

(0.1

80)

Off

shor

ing

0.1

86*

0.16

40.

161

0.10

10.

140

0.16

0(0

.077)

(0.0

87)

(0.0

87)

(0.0

97)

(0.0

86)

(0.0

86)

ICT

-0.0

88-0

.336

-0.3

300.

002

-0.3

29(0

.132

)(0

.174

)(0

.174

)(0

.187

)(0

.175

)R

TI

0.43

8*0.

447*

0.47

5*0.

487*

(0.2

17)

(0.2

17)

(0.2

17)

(0.2

29)

Tra

de*

Off

shori

ng

0.15

3(0

.095

)T

rad

e*IC

T-0

.738

***

(0.1

76)

Tra

de*

RT

I-0

.114

(0.2

11)

4-D

igit

ISC

OD

um

mie

sn

on

on

on

on

on

oye

s

Not

es:

Inal

lco

lum

ns

the

num

ber

ofob

serv

atio

ns

is8702.

Aco

nst

ant

an

dth

efu

llse

tof

contr

ols

,Z

W ian

dZ

F i,

are

incl

ud

edin

all

regre

ssio

ns

bu

tn

otre

por

ted

.“O

ffsh

orin

g”is

the

offsh

orab

ilit

yin

dex

of

the

corr

esp

on

din

gtw

od

igit

init

ial

ISC

O-8

8occ

up

ati

on

cod

eof

aw

ork

er.

Itis

con

stru

cted

by

Goos

,M

ann

ing

and

Sal

omon

s(2

014)

.“I

CT

”is

the

ind

exva

riab

lein

dic

ati

ng

the

deg

ree

inw

hic

hth

ein

itia

l(4

-dig

it)

occ

up

ati

on

of

aw

ork

erin

tera

cts

wit

hco

mp

ute

rs.

Itis

anO

*NE

T(v

ersi

on

14)

vari

ab

lean

dva

ries

acr

oss

4-d

igit

occ

up

ati

on

s.“R

TI”

isth

ero

uti

ne

inte

nsi

tyin

dex

of

the

corr

esp

ond

ing

two

dig

itin

itia

lIS

CO

-88

occ

up

ati

on

cod

eof

aw

ork

er.

Th

eR

TI

ind

exfo

llow

sA

uto

r,L

evy

an

dM

urn

an

e(2

003)

an

dA

uto

ran

dD

orn

(201

2).

Con

trol

vari

able

sar

ed

escr

ibed

inth

en

ote

sof

Tab

le3.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsare

rep

ort

edin

pare

nth

eses

.∗ ,

∗∗an

d∗∗

∗in

dic

ate

sign

ifica

nce

atth

e10

%,

5%an

d1%

leve

lsre

spec

tive

ly.

Data

Sou

rce:

Sta

tist

ics

Den

mark

.

70

Page 71: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table A-11: Polarization and Women by Initial Occupation

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A. Managers

Trade 0.778*** 0.216*** -0.383*** 0.178***(0.090) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

Managers*Female -0.575 -0.082 0.304 -0.189(0.385) (0.292) (0.164) (0.126)

Panel B. Professionals

Trade 0.778*** 0.216*** -0.383*** 0.179***(0.090) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

Profs*Female -1.392 0.456 0.805* -1.043***(0.742) (0.458) (0.360) (0.207)

Panel C. Associate Professionals and Technicians

Trade 0.775*** 0.216*** -0.382*** 0.178***(0.089) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

Technicians*Female -2.174*** -0.640*** 1.104*** -0.430***(0.261) (0.175) (0.125) (0.075)

Panel D. Clerks

Trade 0.734*** 0.209*** -0.357*** 0.168***(0.090) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

Clerks*Female -2.769*** -0.472* 1.659*** -0.638***(0.360) (0.184) (0.208) (0.109)

Panel E. Craft Workers

Trade 0.775*** 0.216*** -0.381*** 0.178***(0.090) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

Craft*Female 0.635 0.202 -0.490* -0.057(0.368) (0.150) (0.234) (0.138)

Panel F. Machine Operators

Trade 0.684*** 0.194*** -0.334*** 0.156***(0.090) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

Operators*Female 2.073*** 0.494*** -1.089*** 0.490***(0.184) (0.078) (0.111) (0.078)

Notes: In all regressions the number of observations is 10753. All regressions include a constant andthe full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi as well as the 2-digit ISCO (initial occupation) dummies. Robust

standard errors are reported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and1% levels respectively.

71

Page 72: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table A-12: Polarization and Women by Education

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A. College Educated

Trade 0.816*** 0.229*** -0.394*** 0.194***(0.089) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

College*Female -1.613*** -0.375* 0.786*** -0.452***(0.269) (0.165) (0.140) (0.078)

Panel B. Vocational School

Trade 0.810*** 0.229*** -0.391*** 0.190***(0.089) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

Vocational*Female -0.371* 0.023 0.190 -0.204**(0.180) (0.082) (0.106) (0.073)

Panel C. at most High School Diploma

Trade 0.802*** 0.228*** -0.387*** 0.187***(0.089) (0.040) (0.052) (0.038)

at most High School*Female 0.844*** 0.056 -0.392*** 0.397***(0.172) (0.078) (0.102) (0.071)

Notes: In all regressions the number of observations is 10753. All regressions include a constant andthe full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi . Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗

indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively.

72

Page 73: Trade and Job · PDF fileInternational Trade and Job Polarization: ... Wolfgang Keller1 and H^ale Utar 2 ... The case of Denmark illustrates well the widely-shared experience in rich

Table A-13: Tasks, Trade, Man, Woman

Dep. Var. JP empi JP h,emp

i JPm,empi JP l,emp

i(1) (2) (3) (4)

Panel A. Routine Manual TasksTasks with Repetitive Motions

Trade 0.752*** 0.246*** -0.368*** 0.138**(0.099) (0.044) (0.057) (0.043)

Repetitive Motions -0.550*** -0.405*** 0.169** 0.024(0.095) (0.049) (0.055) (0.032)

Female*Repetitive Motions 0.884*** 0.139* -0.431*** 0.313***(0.104) (0.055) (0.059) (0.038)

Panel B. Non-Routine Manual TasksTasks with Gross Body Coordination (GBC)

Trade 0.800*** 0.195*** -0.405*** 0.200***(0.094) (0.041) (0.055) (0.041)

GBC -0.854*** -0.611*** 0.355*** 0.112***(0.103) (0.059) (0.055) (0.034)

Female*GBC 1.343*** 0.241*** -0.773*** 0.329***(0.119) (0.065) (0.064) (0.043)

Panel C. Routine Cognitive TasksEvaluating Information to Determine Compliance with Standards

Trade 0.807*** 0.199*** -0.409*** 0.199***(0.093) (0.042) (0.054) (0.040)

Evaluating 0.009 -0.105* 0.013 0.127***(0.083) (0.041) (0.049) (0.030)

Female*Evaluating -0.004 0.104 -0.033 -0.141**(0.116) (0.058) (0.066) (0.046)

Panel D. Abstract TasksTasks that involves thinking creatively (Thinking)

Trade 0.796*** 0.226*** -0.396*** 0.174***(0.098) (0.044) (0.057) (0.043)

Thinking 0.377*** 0.265*** -0.089 0.023(0.096) (0.047) (0.056) (0.034)

Female*Thinking -0.488*** -0.187*** 0.135* -0.165***(0.104) (0.056) (0.058) (0.040)

Panel E. ICTTasks that involves interacting with computers (ICT)

Trade 0.754*** 0.171*** -0.385*** 0.198***(0.093) (0.041) (0.054) (0.040)

ICT 0.744*** 0.512*** -0.270*** -0.038(0.092) (0.048) (0.052) (0.032)

Female*ICT -1.308*** -0.242*** 0.715*** -0.351***(0.102) (0.052) (0.057) (0.038)

Panel F. Face to Face Communication Intensive TasksTasks that involve establishing interpersonal relationships

Trade 0.678*** 0.216*** -0.329*** 0.132**(0.099) (0.044) (0.058) (0.042)

Interpersonal 0.534*** 0.420*** -0.147*** -0.033(0.075) (0.039) (0.043) (0.025)

Female*Interpersonal -0.961*** -0.151*** 0.486*** -0.324***(0.087) (0.045) (0.049) (0.033)

Notes: The number of observations is 8819, 9505, 9887, 8876, 9776, and 8816 in Panels A throughF respectively. All regressions include a constant and the full-set of controls, ZW

i and ZFi . Tasks

measures are from O*NET and vary by workers’ initial 4-digit occupations (ISCO). The availability oftask measures across occupations determine the number of observations. Robust standard errors arereported in parentheses. ∗, ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ indicate significance at the 10 %, 5% and 1% levels respectively.Data Source: Statistics Denmark. 73