trade credit in europe

24
Trade credit in Europe Paper prepared for the 31st Meeting of the EUROPEAN WORKING GROUP ON FINANCIAL MODELING (EWGFM), November 7-9, 2002, Agia Napa, CYPRUS By Nico van der Wijst and Suzan Hol Norwegian University of Science and Technology N-7491 Trondheim, Norway [email protected] Preliminary version, all comments welcome ABSTRACT: The study of trade credit is well justified by its importance as a source of finance for the corporate sector in most western countries. Trade credit is special, however, because its use may be driven by different factors compared to other sources of finance. Trade credit may follow the flow of goods and services through a company, and thus be sensitive to operational rather than financial factors. Further, firms that supply trade credit assume the role of financial intermediaries. This role is commonly considered to be based on the possibilities to resolve market imperfections in the normal course of business and not as a separate activity. This may eliminate, or even reverse, the effect of market imperfections compared to other forms of financial intermediation such as banking. This paper addresses these issues from a theoretical as well as an empirical point of view. It discusses the theories of trade credit found in the literature and the market imperfections on which they are based. Their conclusions are summarized in a number of hypotheses that are tested empirically. The data used in the study refer to different European countries. To our knowledge, trade credit has not been studied on this European wide scale before. The main conclusion of this paper is that receivables and payables generally are not influenced in opposite directions by the determinants suggested in the literature, but in the same

Upload: josephsam

Post on 23-Jan-2015

295 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

DESCRIPTION

 

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Trade credit in Europe

Trade credit in Europe

Paper prepared for the 31st Meeting of the

EUROPEAN WORKING GROUP ON FINANCIAL MODELING (EWGFM),

November 7-9, 2002, Agia Napa, CYPRUS

By

Nico van der Wijst and Suzan Hol

Norwegian University of Science and Technology

N-7491 Trondheim, Norway

[email protected]

Preliminary version, all comments welcome

ABSTRACT:

The study of trade credit is well justified by its importance as a source of

finance for the corporate sector in most western countries. Trade credit

is special, however, because its use may be driven by different factors

compared to other sources of finance. Trade credit may follow the flow of

goods and services through a company, and thus be sensitive to

operational rather than financial factors. Further, firms that supply trade

credit assume the role of financial intermediaries. This role is commonly

considered to be based on the possibilities to resolve market

imperfections in the normal course of business and not as a separate

activity. This may eliminate, or even reverse, the effect of market

imperfections compared to other forms of financial intermediation such

as banking.

This paper addresses these issues from a theoretical as well as an

empirical point of view. It discusses the theories of trade credit found in

the literature and the market imperfections on which they are based.

Their conclusions are summarized in a number of hypotheses that are

tested empirically. The data used in the study refer to different European

countries. To our knowledge, trade credit has not been studied on this

European wide scale before. The main conclusion of this paper is that

receivables and payables generally are not influenced in opposite

directions by the determinants suggested in the literature, but in the

same direction. Further a strong industry influence is found in the use of

trade credit.

Page 2: Trade credit in Europe

1 IntroductionBy all measures, trade credit is a major source of financing for the

corporate sector. At the end of 1998, US corporations had $2.501 billion

(109) outstanding in accounts payable1, roughly a quarter of their total

debt. This amount also represents roughly a quarter of the total market

value of all shares on NYSE2 in December 1998. Further, vendor

financing is reported to have accounted for approximately 2.5 times the

combined value of all new public debt and primary equity issues in the

USA during a given year in the 1990s (Ng, Smith and Smith, 1999) In

Europe, trade credit is typically 20% to 25% of total liabilities, but

occasionally it can be as high as 80% some industries and low as 5% in

others.

In addition to its obvious importance, trade credit deserves special

attention for at least two other reasons. First, trade credit is generated

by the flow of goods and services through a company rather than by

financial decisions. This could make the use of trade credit dependent on

the determinants of those flows, i.e. operational rather than financial

factors. To the extent that this is the case, trade credit will behave as

noise in models that are exclusively based on financial variables. This

could cause an important omitted variable bias in models of e.g. capital

structure and debt maturity structure. Second, firms that supply trade

credit assume the role of financial intermediaries. This role is commonly

considered to be based on the possibilities to resolve market

imperfections in the normal course of business and not as a separate

activity. This may eliminate, or even reverse, the effect of market

imperfections compared to other forms of financial intermediation such

as banking. This also suggests that trade credit is at least partly

determined by different factors than the other liabilities.

On the other hand, there is probably no area in finance that is so

much pervaded by conventions, rules of thumb and traditions as trade

credit is. Textbooks tell us that, for example, shoe manufacturers

commonly use “5/10, net 30” as terms of sale, while toy manufacturers

generally sell goods on terms of “2/30, net 50” (Brealey and Myers

(2000)). The most usual terms of trade in various industries are published

in handbooks and they are probably widely used as reference by

newcomers in an industry. This suggests that trade credit may also partly

be determined by conventions rather than financial policy.

The purpose of this paper is to analyze the determinants of trade

credit from a theoretical as well as an empirical point of view. The

theoretical determinants are surveyed in a study of the literature. Their

1 Statistical abstract of the United States 2001, http://www.census.gov/2 http://www.nyse.com

1

Page 3: Trade credit in Europe

conclusions are formulated in hypotheses that are tested in the empirical

part of the study. The tests are performed on a large database comprising

industry average data of 10 European countries over a number of years.

To our knowledge, trade credit has not been studied on this European

wide scale before.

The rest of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 summarizes

the theoretical and empirical literature on trade credit. The data used in

this study are described in section 3, while section 4 presents the models

and the estimation results. Conclusions are formulated in section 5.

2 Literature review

2.2 Theoretical studies

Although trade credit is a comparatively ‘small’ topic in finance, many

theories explaining its use have been presented over the years. The

number of empirical studies is correspondingly large. A common

denominator in many theories of trade credit is that it offers the

possibility to resolve market imperfections in the normal course of

business and not as a separate activity. This can make trade credit a

more efficient way to resolve market imperfections than other forms of

financial intermediation such as banking. For instance, the normal cycle

of ordering, delivery and payment may generate information that

otherwise would remain hidden or would be costly to obtain by parties

not involved in the transaction. The market imperfections incorporated in

theories of trade credit are summarised in Table 1.

- Information asymmetries:

-default risk (Smith, 1987)

-monitoring costs (Jain, 2001)

-product quality (Long, Malitz and Ravid, 1993) , (Lee and Stowe,

1993)

- Arbitrage:

-tax differences (Brick and Fung, 1984)

-interest rate differences (Emery, 1984), (Schwartz, 1974)

- Bankruptcy costs (Mian and Smith, 1992)

- Transaction costs (Ferris, 1981)

Table 1: Market imperfections modelled in theories of trade credit

Smith (1987) views trade credit as a contractual device for dealing with

informational asymmetry. The terms are set such that they function as a

screening contract that elicits information about buyer default risk: the

2

Page 4: Trade credit in Europe

seller learns the state of the buyer from the fact that it takes the

expensive trade credit or not. The value of this information can be higher

to a seller who made a nonsalvageable investment in the buyer than it is

to an outside financier. This theory predicts that trade credit terms will

be relatively uniform within industries but differ between industries

depending on the size of nonsalvageable investments in buyers. Cash or

net terms are expected when these investments are not significant, while

deep cash discounts are expected in risky industries where goods are

subject to more volatility in value.

A similar line of reasoning is followed in Jain (2001) and Mian and

Smith (1992) where it is argued that sellers can inspect the buyers’

financial position at lower costs than outside parties as banks. These

lower monitoring costs justify a role for the sellers as financial

intermediaries between banks and the buyers. This theory predicts that

trade credit is more important in industries that are more concentrated

on the supply side and less concentrated on the demand side (such as the

wholesale and retail trade) and in industries where monitoring costs are

more severe (e.g. manufacturing).

Trade credit can also play a role in signalling information about

product quality. This idea is elaborated in, among others, Long et al.

(1993) and Lee and Stowe (1993). When there is informational

asymmetry about product quality, trade credit can serve to distinguish

high and low quality goods and producers. Thus, trade credit can be

interpreted as an implicit warranty guaranteeing product quality by

giving the buyer a net period over which to test the product. This relates

trade credit to the length of the production cycle, the difficulty of

ascertaining product quality and possibly size (as proxy for established

reputation).

Another financial approach to trade credit, and one of the earliest, is

the suggestion that it reflects arbitrage. Emery (1984) argues that when

different firms are confronted with different borrowing and lending rates,

trade credit may be used to arbitrage the difference. Similarly, Schwartz

(1974) develops a model that suggests that trade credit will flow

predominantly from firms that have relatively easy access to capital

markets to firms that have productive uses for funds but relatively poor

access to capital markets. Thus, better-established firms that have

already enjoyed a substantial rate of growth and profitability are led to

participate in the financing of smaller, newer firms.

Alternatively, Brick and Fung (1984) bases its model on tax

differences. Firms in high tax brackets can gain by offering trade credit

to firms in lower tax brackets. An empirical implication is that, within an

industry, buyers prefer trade credit if their tax bracket is lower than that

of the seller.

3

Page 5: Trade credit in Europe

Ferris (1981) presents a transactions theory of trade credit, in which

trade credit is viewed as an instrument facilitating the exchange of

goods. This theory ties trade credit use to the variability and uncertainty

in the firms trading flows. Trade credit can substantially reduce

transaction costs by separating the exchange of goods from the exchange

of money, e.g. by paying bills only monthly rather than every time goods

are delivered. This enables the planning of payments and by letting

payments accumulate the patterns of receipts and disbursements can be

matched. It greatly simplifies cash management. The transactions motive

is widely presumed to underly a substantial part of the aggregate stock of

trade credit, even in studies that analyse financing motives (e.g. Schwartz

(1974), and Nilsen (2002)).

Finally, if a buyer defaults, the seller is likely to be in a better

position to reclaim value from repossessed goods than a financial

institution. This is argued by Mian and Smith (1992) in an extensive study

of receivables management policies. Since the seller already has the

expertise and the network to sell the goods, the costs of repossessing and

resale will be lower. The more durable the goods are, and the less they

are transformed by the buyer, the greater the advantage of the seller

over financial institutions will be.

Some other theories stress the importance of trade credit as a

marketing instrument e.g. Emery (1987). When firms face a highly

seasonal demand, varying price or production or using customer- or

product-queues (inventories) may be comparatively costly. Varying the

terms of trade credit, i.e. providing more lenient terms in slack periods,

can be an efficient alternative. This reduces the effective price that

buyers pay, while leaving the nominal price unaltered.

Brennan et al. (1988) and Mian and Smith (1992) take this argument

a step further and suggest that trade credit may be used to effectuate

price discrimination in situations where ‘normal’ price discrimination is

either too costly or illegal.

As a final remark it is noted that many of the above theories argue

for a different role of trade credit compared with other forms of finance.

This can be illustrated with the tax effect. In Brick and Fung (1984, p.

1174) it is argued that, all other things being equal, buyers with low

effective tax rates would prefer trade credit and therefore are more likely

to have higher levels of accounts payable relative to similar buyers with a

higher effective tax rate. In the neo-classical trade-off theory of capital

structure, on the other hand, debt levels are chosen as a trade-off

between the expected tax advantage of debt and the expected costs of

financial distress. In this theory, low effective tax rates are associated

with low levels of debt. Similar arguments apply to the advantage that

trade partners have in collecting information or recovering value from a

4

Page 6: Trade credit in Europe

bankrupt estate. This clearly illustrates the hazards of analysing capital

structure without regard for debt maturity and the composition of short-

term debt in trade credit and other short-term debt.

2.2 Empirical studies

In view of the variety of different theories of trade credit, it is hardly

surprising that the empirical evidence, both inside and outside the

context of these theories, is rather mixed. Table 2 summarises the

support found for the various theories in different empirical studies.

The arbitrage-based theories seem to get the least support in the

empirical literature, while informational asymmetries get the widest

support. Among the marketing instrument theories, demand variation

smoothing gets no support while price discrimination is supported by

more than one study. The widest support by far is found for the

transactions theory. Early studies as Herbst (1974) as well as more

recent papers like Ferris (1981), Long et al. (1993) and Nilsen (2002)

underline the importance of the transactions theory.

The evidence regarding the effect of monetary policy variables on

trade credit is also mixed. Ng et al. (1999) report that trade credit

policies are stable over time and do not vary with interest rates.

However, Nilsen (2002) concludes that non-rated firms increase their use

of trade credit in period of contractionary monetary policy. A similar

conclusion was reached much earlier by Nadiri (1969).

Finally, descriptive statistics of trade credit policies in different

periods, industries and countries can be found in several studies, see e.g.

Petersen and Rajan (1997), Ng et al. (1999) and Wilson and Summers

(2002).

- Information asymmetries

-default risk/monitoring costs: supported Petersen & Rajan ‘97

-product quality: supported Long et al ’93, Ng et al, ’99

- Arbitrage

-tax differences: not supported Long et al ’93

-interest rate differences/liquidity: not supported Long et al ’93, Ng et

al, ’99

- Bankruptcy costs: supported Petersen & Rajan ‘97

- Transaction costs minimization: supported Herbst, ’74, Ferris, ’81,

Long et al ’93,

Nilsen, 2002

- Price discrimination: supported Petersen & Rajan ’97, Ng et al,

’99

5

Page 7: Trade credit in Europe

- Demand variation smoothing: not supported Ng et al, ’99

Table 2: Empirical evidence regarding theories of trade credit

3 Data and descriptive analysis

3.1 Data

The data used in this paper were collected and made available by the

European Commission, Directorate General Economic and Financial

Affairs, BACH database. BACH (Bank for the Accounts of Companies

Harmonised) is a database containing harmonised annual accounts

statistics of non-financial enterprises for 11 European countries, plus

Japan and the United States. In this paper 10 European countries are

used; the eleventh European country in the database (Finland) had too

many missing observations. An overview over the countries used in this

paper and their codes are given in the appendix. The BACH database is

composed by institutions from the twelve European Union Member States

and European Commission and OECD. Members are Oesterreichische

Nationalbank, Bank Nationale de Belgique, Bank of England, Statistics

Finland, Banque de France, Deutsche Bundesbank, Bank of Greece,

Central Bank of Ireland, Centrale dei Bilanci, Centraal Bureau voor de

Statistiek, Banco de Portugal, and Banco de España.

The accounts are 'harmonised' through a common layout for balance

sheet, profit and loss accounts, statements of investments and statements

of depreciation. They are based on the Fourth Council Directive

(78/660/EEC of July 1978). All data are given in amounts in the local

currency and in current prices, i.e. in 1000 NLG for the Netherlands,

1000 BEF for Belgium, 1000 FRF in France, 1 million ESP in Spain, 1000

PTE in Portugal, 1 million ITL in Italy, 1000 ATS in Austria, 1000 DKK in

Denmark, 1 million SEK in Sweden and 1 million DM in Germany.

More information about the database can be found on the website of

the European Commission of Economic and Financial Affairs:

http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy_finance/indicators/bachdatabase/bachdatabase_whatisbach_en.htm

In each country, we have taken the most detailed sectoral information

possible. This means the sectors with BACH code 1 (energy and water,

including refining industry), BACH code 3 (building and civil

engineering), BACH code 5 (transport and communication) and BACH

code 6 (other services) on a one-digit level. The sectors with BACH code 4

(trade) are available on a two-digit level. Finally, the sectors with BACH

6

Page 8: Trade credit in Europe

code 2 (manufacturing industry) are available on a three-digit level.3 A

conversion table from BACH to NACE codes is given in the appendix.

Using industry average data has the advantage over the obvious

alternative of individual data that idiosyncratic elements and

measurements errors can be assumed to average out. Moreover, industry

average data are more often publicly available, as the BACH database

illustrates, and better suited to construct homogeneous time-series. The

data used here have a panel character. This substantially enhances the

possibilities to analyse these data. The disadvantage of this type of data is

also obvious: average behaviour, if it exists at all, may be hard to explain.

However, Ng et al. (1999) report that trade credit terms show wide

variation across industries but little variation within industries. To the

extent that this observation is also valid for the data at hand, this justifies

the analysis of industry averages.

3.2 Descriptive analysisTo give an impression of the variation and structure in the data, we first present a

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

31

32

33

34

39

43

45

46

49

35

1

Country Code

AR/TA

AP/TL

Figure 1: Accounts receivable over total assets (AR/TA) and accounts payable over total liabilities (AP/TL) for sector BACH code 2 in 1996. 4

graph of the percentages of accounts payable and receivable in the various countries. The amount of accounts payable in the total liabilities and the amount of accounts receivable in total assets in 1996 for sector 2 are given in Figure 1 above. In this randomly chosen year, the percentage of accounts payable varies between the countries from around 10 to over 40%, while the percentage of accounts receivable ranges from around 5 to over 30%. When we look at the whole dataset, the maximum percentages of accounts payable in any year in any sector ranges from 30% (in the Netherlands) to 83% (in Denmark). Similar numbers for the percentage of accounts receivable are 27% (in Denmark) to 58% (in Spain).

3 Some sectors were not available for the following countries: Denmark (sectors 5, 6, 41, 42, 44), Germany (sectors 1, 5, 6, 42, 44) and Portugal (sectors 6, 42, 43, 44). 4 In 1992 for the Netherlands (country code 31).

7

Page 9: Trade credit in Europe

Next, we present a table with the same ratios per country and

industry. Table 3 shows this information across different industries

(codes 1, 3, 5, 6) and within the manufacturing industry (211-234).

S

C 1 3 5 6 21

1

21

2

21

3

22

1

22

2

22

3

23

1

23

2

23

3

23

4

31 ar/

ta

10 24 6 15 12 12 3 15 6 7 9 12 10 13

ap/

tl

10 26 8 10 14 15 7 18 8 21 15 13 13 16

32 ar/

ta

10 29 16 9 15 11 15 27 24 18 18 28 20 24

ap/

tl

16 32 21 10 20 14 27 32 34 38 26 36 26 36

33 ar/

ta

8 32 4 19 24 21 20 31 31 19 20 28 25 34

ap/

tl

7 30 6 14 34 29 31 32 37 34 32 34 34 39

34 ar/

ta

7 49 7 11 16 17 30 36 41 24 23 34 29 35

ap/

tl

15 48 11 12 27 29 41 34 47 54 38 33 34 45

39 ar/

ta

10 35 11 40 31 26 32 37 38 29 30 36 33 37

ap/

tl

17 30 24 46 28 30 38 38 41 42 34 37 37 40

43 ar/

ta

4 22 15 6 11 9 14 14 11 9 13 19 13 13

ap/

tl

8 15 21 11 20 10 16 14 17 18 21 15 16 16

45 ar/

ta

11 24 NA NA 17 12 13 21 17 13 12 14 17 15

ap/

tl

11 23 NA NA 21 18 14 18 22 27 16 16 15 16

46 ar/

ta

5 14 9 6 8 8 6 9 7 4 12 18 5 11

ap/

tl

5 14 13 8 24 12 14 12 9 9 22 23 8 18

49 ar/

ta

NA 11 NA NA 10 8 7 16 13 7 12 18 15 17

ap/ NA 14 NA NA 22 16 17 17 15 31 27 28 22 18

8

Page 10: Trade credit in Europe

tl

35

1

ar/

ta

5 28 6 NA 17 13 28 27 28 24 21 22 17 25

ap/

tl

7 30 8 NA 30 22 44 30 43 23 24 30 24 30

Table 3: Overview over percentage of accounts receivable over total assets (ar/ta) and accounts payable over total liabilities (ap/tl) for all sectors (S) in all countries (C) in the year 1996. Exception: for the Netherlands (31) 1996 was not available, so 1992 is used.

This breakdown represents roughly the lowest aggregation level available

in the data. Based on this, we calculated the largest difference between

the percentages of accounts payable / accounts receivable between the

different sectors (codes 1, 3, 5, 6), and within sector 2 (manufacturing).

Manufacturing is the only sector with enough sub sectors to make this

operation meaningful. This calculation was done for every country

resulting in two numbers for every item (accounts receivable or accounts

payable) for every country. The general conclusion from these

calculations is that the difference within sectors is smaller than the

difference between sectors. Although this analysis is crude and far from

conclusive, it does indicate support for the findings from Ng. et al., that

the differences between sectors are larger than within sectors.

4 Model and estimation resultsThe empirical model is constructed to reflect, as far as the data allow, the

theoretical determinants discussed in section 2. The following influences

and their proxy-variables are included in the model:

- Informational asymmetry: A high degree of informational asymmetry

is associated with, among other things, high monitoring costs, which

make debt financing relatively unattractive. However, trade partners

avoid monitoring costs by collecting information in normal course of

business, which gives them, other things equal, an advantage vis-à-vis

informational asymmetry. This makes the hypothesized effect on

accounts payable positive. A corresponding effect on accounts

receivable is less obvious and therefore not formulated. The variable

investments in daughter companies (as a fraction of total assets) is

used as a proxy variable for informational asymmetry. Firms and

industries that are characterized by a high degree of cross investments

are relatively intransparent, necessitating high monitoring costs.

- Taxes: As was argued before, trade credit is expected to flow from

firms in high tax brackets to those in low brackets. So low tax rates are

9

Page 11: Trade credit in Europe

hypothesized to be associated with high levels of accounts payable and

low levels of receivables. As no direct measure of the tax rate is

available, the alternative non-debt tax shields represented by

depreciation charges are used to approximate (inversely) the tax effect.

- Interest rate: the arbitrage argument specifies that trade credit flows

from firms with a low interest rate to firms with a high one. This means

a positive effect on accounts payable and a negative effect on accounts

receivable. However, the endogenous interest rate used here (total

interest paid/total liabilities) also reflects cross sectional differences in

riskiness, which makes the total effect ambiguous.

- Industry dummy variable: are included to capture industry specific

effect not represented by other variables. Dummy variables for the first

digit sectors are included (see the appendix for an overview of the first

digit sectors). The “last” available sector dummy (usually for sector 6)

is omitted to avoid perfect multicollinearity in combination with the

intercept. No hypotheses are formulated regarding the sign or the size

of the influence of these dummies.

- Size: sales and costs of goods sold are used as a size variable, but in a

flexible specification (see below) that allows for scale effects. Different

size variables are used to avoid bias caused by differences in gross

margin. As trade credit is expected to flow predominantly from larger

better-established firms to the smaller, newer ones, the ratio of

accounts payable to size is expected to decrease with size. The

opposite effect is expected for accounts receivable: the ratio of

receivables to size is expected to increase with size. This means that a

positive intercept is expected for receivables and a negative intercept

for payables.

The following specification is used to estimate the relations and test the

hypotheses:

(1)

where:

- Y = variable to be explained (accounts receivable and accounts

payable)

- Size = size variable (turnover and cost of goods sold for receivables

and payables respectively)

- invd = investments in affiliated and daughter companies,

10

Page 12: Trade credit in Europe

- depr = depreciation charges,

- inr = interest payments on debt,

- ta= total assets,

- tl = total liabilities minus trade credit,

- dumsi is a dummy for sector i

- a, bi = coefficients to be estimated.

Note that in the above equation:

scale effects are expressed as the intercept a. If a > 0 then the ratio

of AR or AP to size decreases with size, while the reverse is true if a <

0. The former is expected for accounts payable, the latter for accounts

receivables.

if a, b2-4 and the dummy variables are all = 0, then the equation boils

down to the ratios of AR and AP to size. This facilitates an easy

interpretation of the results.

for the non-size variables a multiplicative specification is used

because they are expected to influence the b1 coefficients rather than

the absolute amount of debt. An exponentional specification is chosen

for the dummy variables, which can take zero value.

Equation (1) is not linear and the results are provided with the non-linear

least squares procedure in the SPSS package, using the Levenberg-

Marquardt algorithm. The hypotheses are summarized in Table 4 below

in terms of the expected signs of the coefficients of the variables:

Expected signs

Ascale effect

B1size

B2inf.

asymm.

B3tax

B4interest

AR Negative Positive Negative NegativeNegative

AP Positive Positive Positive Positive Positive

Table 4: Hypothesized signs for accounts receivable (AR) and accounts

payable (AP)

The estimation results based on the pooled panel data are given in table

5.

CountryYears

A B1 B2 B3 B4 R2 N

Netherla

nds (31)

AR 3.58 105 s

(0.72 105)

0.011 s

(0.005)

-0.066 s

(0.023)

-0.452 s

(0.095)

-0.170

(0.103)

0.92

1

216

1981-

1992

AP 2.17 105 s

(0.38 105 )

0.152 s

(0.015)

-0.055 s

(0.017)

0.245 s

(0.072)

0.100

(0.079)

0.94

8

11

Page 13: Trade credit in Europe

Belgium

(32)

AR 2.40 106

(2.59 106 )

0.009 s

(0.003)

NA -1.028 s

(0.087)

0.117 s

(0.052)

0.98

6

198

1989-

1999

AP 4.98 106 s

(1.52 106)

0.164 s

(0.027)

NA -0.105 s

(0.040)

-0.072

(0.037)

0.99

2

France

(33)

AR -1.76 106

(1.40 106)

0.034 s

(0.011)

-0.171 s

(0.031)

-0.521 s

(0.077)

0.017

(0.046)

0.86

2

336

1984–

1999

AP -6.54 105

(6.68 105)

0.003 s

(0.000)

-0.094 s

(0.020)

0.148 s

(0.042)

-0.090 s

(0.027)

0.95

6

Spain

(34)

AR 4.89 104 s

(1.21 104)

0.120 s

(0.040)

0.041

(0.035)

-0.372 s

(0.064)

0.134 s

(0.042)

0.88

7

306

1983–

1999

AP 4.16 104 s

(0.63 104)

1.018 s

(0 .253)

-0.110 s

(0.027)

0.349 s

(0.045)

-0.137 s

(0.031)

0.94

4

Italy (39) AR -2.45 106 s

(0.45 106)

0.377 s

(0.081)

0.036

(0.032)

-0.201 s

(0.065)

0.070 s

(0.032)

0.92

4

324

1982–

1999

AP -0.87 105

(2.99 105)

0.573 s

(0.118)

0.064 s

(0.032)

0.035

(0.082)

-0.024

(0.031)

0.93

2

12

Page 14: Trade credit in Europe

CountryYears

A B1 B2 B3 B4 R2 N

Austria

(43 5)

AR 2.88 105

(2.22 105)

0.003 s

(0.001)

NA -0.973 s

(0.078)

NA 0.85

8 360

1980–

1999

AP 1.09 106 s

(0.15 106)

0.023 s

(0.008)

NA -0.571 s

(0.093)

NA 0.83

6

Denmark

(45 6 7)

AR 3.97 105

(2.32 105)

0.203

(0.142)

-0.016

(0.060)

0.483 s

(0.196)

-0.357 s

(0.155)

0.87

9

183

1983–

1998

AP 7.81 105 s

(1.29 105)

2.117

(1.377)

-0.021

(0.049)

0.902 s

(0.223)

-0.084

(0.154)

0.93

5

Sweden

(46)

AR -1764.630

(942.807)

0.034 s

(0.011)

-0.032

(0.062)

-0.453 s

(0.112)

0.213 s

(0.060)

0.87

9

126

1991–

1997

AP -337.050 s

(325.902)

0.052 s

(0.008)

-0.067 s

(0.028)

-0.238 s

(0 .053)

0.153 s

(0.028)

0.97

1

Germany

(49)

AR 435.667

(369.841)

0.001 s

(0.000)

-0.227 s

(0.043)

-1.193 s

(0.080)

0.209 s

(0.068)

0.95

1

143

1987–

1997

AP 462.935 s

(163.293)

0.048 s

(0.010)

-0.270 s

(0.032)

-0.139 s

(0.040)

0.006

(0.044)

0.97

5

Portugal

(351 2)

AR 2.66 107 s

(0.37 107)

0.015 s

(0.005)

-0.068 s

(0.027)

-0.524 s

(0.101)

-0.169 s

(0.041)

0.98

2

140

1990–

1999

AP 2.07 107 s

(0.72 107)

0.142 s

(0.066)

0.023

(0.033)

-0.051

(0.127)

-0.059

(0.044)

0.98

4Table 5: Results of the non-linear regression for 10 European countries. Standard errors are given in brackets. If a variable is significant different from zero at 5% level, this is indicated with a ‘s’.

Inspecting Table 5 we note the following. The hypothesized opposite

scale effects are not found in the data: the switch in the signs of the

intercepts does not occur at all. The intercepts in payables are positive,

as expected, and significantly so in 7 of the 10 cases. A significantly

negative intercept is found in one case. To a lesser degree, the same

results are found in receivables, however: positive intercepts in 7 cases,

5 Other value adjustments and provisions are included in the depreciation

charges. 6 Other charges are added to interest paid on financial debts. 7 Trade credit (accounts payable) is constructed from total short-term debt minus other short-term debt.

13

Page 15: Trade credit in Europe

and significantly positive in 3. The hypothesized negative intercept is

found only in 3 cases, 1 of which is significantly < 0.

In all the tested countries, the size variables are positive though not

always significantly so. In nine out of the ten countries, the size variable

for both accounts receivable and accounts payable is significant.

The signs of the coefficients of the information asymmetry proxy,

investments in affiliated and daughter companies, are predominantly

negative, both in the results for payables and receivables. The

hypothesized positive effect on payables is found in 2 cases, only once of

which is significantly > 0. Again, no significant opposite effects are found.

In six out of the available eight countries (for two countries this variable

was not available), this variable has the hypothesized sign for accounts

receivable, of which four are significant.

The hypotheses regarding taxes are supported more often. In four of

the ten countries this hypothesis is supported, with mainly significant

coefficients. In the other countries no switch in sign is found, although

the variable is often significant: in five cases the variable is as expected

for accounts receivable only (not payables). In the remaining country the

sign is only correct for accounts payable. In all, the coefficient of the tax

variable is significant in 18 out of 20 cases. Given the fact that these data

are from many countries with large differences in tax systems, these

results indicate that the tax shield proxy is a good variable to explain

trade credit.

Finally, the hypothesized switch in sign in the effect of interest rate

on accounts receivable and accounts payable was found in 1 out of 9

cases but the coefficients were not significant (in one country the interest

rate on debts was not available). With ten out of the eighteen estimated

coefficients significantly ≠ 0, there is an effect of the interest rate on

trade credit, but the effects on payables and receivables are often not in

the expected direction.

The R2 of the regressions are usually around 0.9, which is high but

not unusual for the specification used.

14

Page 16: Trade credit in Europe

5 ConclusionMost theories of trade credit specify, implicitly or explicitly, different

effects on accounts receivable and payable. This is to a large extent

obvious: the factors that stimulate taking up trade credit from suppliers

(e.g. capital scarcity) deter the supply of it to customers. So an analysis of

both receivables and payables with largely the same model should

produce opposite effects. Surprisingly, more often than not the same

effects are found, as Table 6 below illustrates.

Ascale effect

B2inf.

asymm.

B3tax

B4interest total

same effects 10 6 6 4 26

opposite

effects

0 2 4 5 11

Table 6: Qualitative summary of effects

In sign and significance, the tax effect comes closest to the hypotheses

but even there the rejections are the majority.

Concluding, it appears that the financial explaining trade credit, only give

a partial explanation and that evidently important factors are missing in

the model used here.

15

Page 17: Trade credit in Europe

ReferencesBrealey, R. and S. Myers (2000) Principles of Corporate Finance. Sixth

edition,

MacGraw Hill New York.

Brennan, Micheal J., Vojislav Miksimovic and Josef Zechner (1988)

Vendor financing.

The Journal of Finance 43:5, pp1127-1141.

Brick E.I. and Fung W.K.H. (1984) Taxes and the Theory of Trade Debt.

Journal of

Finance 39, 1169-1176.

Emery G.W. (1984) A Pure Financial Explanation for Trade Credit.

Journal of Financial

and Quantitative Analysis 19, 271-285.

Emery G.W. (1987) An Optimal Financial Response to Variable Demand.

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22, 209-225.

Ferris J.S. (1981) A Transactions Theory of Trade Credit Use. Quarterly

Journal of Economics 96, 243-270.

Herbst A.F. (1974) Some Empirical Evidence on the Determinants of

Trade Credit at the Industry Level of Aggregation. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis 9, 377-394.

Jain N. (2001) Monitoring Costs and Trade Credit. Quarterly Review of

Economics and Finance 41, 89-110.

Lee Y.W. and Stowe J.D. (1993) Product Risk, Asymmetric Information,

and Trade Credit. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

28, 285-300.

Long M.S., Malitz I.B. and Ravid S.A. (1993) Trade Credit, Quality

Guarantees, and Product Marketability. Financial Management 22,

117-127.

Mian S.L. and Smith C.W. (1992) Accounts Receivable Management

Policy: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Finance 47, 169-200.

Nadiri M.I. (1969) The Determinants of Trade Credit in the U.S. Total

Manufacturing Sector. Econometrica 37, 408-423.

Ng C.K., Smith J.K. and Smith R.L. (1999) Evidence on the Determinants

of Credit Terms Used in Interfirm Trade. Journal of Finance 54,

1109-1129.

Nilsen J.H. (2002) Trade Credit and the Bank Lending Channel. Journal of

Money, Credit, and Banking 34, 226-253.

Petersen M.A. and Rajan R.G. (1997) Trade Credit: Theories and

Evidence. Review of Financial Studies 10, 661-691.

Schwartz R.A. (1974) An Economic Model of Trade Credit. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis 9, 643-657.

16

Page 18: Trade credit in Europe

Smith J.K. (1987) Trade Credit and Informational Asymmetry. Journal of

Finance 42, 863-872.

Wilson N. and Summers B. (2002) Trade Credit Terms Offered by Small

Firms: Survey Evidence and Empirical Analysis. Journal of Business

Finance and Accounting 29, 317-351.

17

Page 19: Trade credit in Europe

AppendixDescription of the countries in the BACH database and their codes.

CODE COUNTRY CODE COUNTRY

31 The Netherlands

43 Austria

32 Belgium 45 Denmark

33 France 46 Sweden

34 Spain 49 Germany

39 Italy 351 Portugal

Description of the sectors in the BACH database, and conversion table from BACH sector codes to new NACE codes. CODE SECTOR NACE Rev. 1

1 ENERGY AND WATER (including refining industry)

10 + 11 + 12 + 23 + 40 + 41

2 MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY  

21 Intermediate products  

211 Extraction of metalliferous ores and preliminary processing of metal

13 + 27.1 + 27.2 + 27.3 + 27.4

212 Extraction of non-metalliferous ores and manufacture of non-metallic mineral products

14 + 26

213 Chemicals and man-made fibres 24

22 Investment goods and consumer durables  

221 Manufacture of metal articles, mechanical and instrument engineering

27.5 + 28 + 29.1-6 + 33

222 Electrical and electronic equipment including office and computing equipment

30 + 31 + 32 + 29.7

223 Manufacture of transport equipment 34 + 35

23 Non-durable consumption goods  

231 Food, drink and tobacco 15 + 16

232 Textiles, leather and clothing 17 + 18 + 19

233 Timber and paper manufacture, printing 20 + 21 + 22

234 Other manufacturing industries not elsewhere specified (n.e.s)

25 + 36

3 BUILDING AND CIVIL ENGINEERING 45

4 TRADE  

41 Wholesale trade, recovery services 51

42 Sale of motor vehicles, wholesale and retail trade

50.1 + 50.3 + 50.4

43 Retail trade 52.1-52.6 + 50.5

44 Hotels-Restaurant 55

5 TRANSPORT AND COMMUNICATION 60 + 61 + 62 + 63 + 64

6 OTHER SERVICES N.E.S 50.2 + 52.7 + 67 + 70 + 71 + 72 +  73 + 74 + 75 + 80 + 85 + 90 + 91 + 92 + 93 + 95

18

Page 20: Trade credit in Europe

19