transaction taxes, traders’ behavior and exchange rate...

45
WORKING PAPERS SERIES WP06-13 Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks Markus Demary

Upload: others

Post on 12-Mar-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

WORKING PAPERS SERIES

WP06-13

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

and Exchange Rate Risks

Markus Demary

Page 2: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and

Exchange Rate Risks

Markus Demary

Department of Economics Olshausen Str. 40, 24118 Kiel

University of Kiel, Germany E-Mail: [email protected]

this version: November 13, 2006

Abstract: We propose a new model of chartist-fundamentalist-interactionin which both groups of traders are allowed to select endogenously betweendi!erent forecasting models and di!erent investment horizons. Stochasticinterest rates in both countries and di!erent behavioral assumptions fortrend-extrapolating and fundamental based forecasts determine the agents’market orders which drive the exchange rate. A numerical analysis of themodel shows that it is able to replicate stylized facts of observed financialreturn time series like excess kurtosis and volatility clustering. Within thisframework we study the e!ects of transaction taxes on exchange rate volatil-ity and traders’ behavior measured by their population fractions. Simula-tions yield the result that on the macroscopic level these taxes reduce thevariance of exchange rate returns, but also increase their kurtosis. Moreover,on the microscopic level the tax harms short-term speculation in favor oflong-term investment, while it also harms trading rules based on economicfundamentals in favor to trend extrapolating trading rules.

Key words: Chartist-Fundamentalist-Interaction, Exchange Rates, Finan-

cial Market Volatility, Transaction Taxes

We are grateful for financial support from the EU STREP ComplexMarkets contract

number 516446.

Page 3: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks i

Contents

1 Introduction 1

2 The Model Economy 4

2.1 Fundamental Factors and Arbitrage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4

2.2 Traders’ Demand for Foreign Currency . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

2.3 Traders’ Forecasting Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

2.4 Evolution of Trading Rules . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

2.5 Institutional Properties and Price Setting . . . . . . . . . . . 15

3 Non-Stochastic Steady States 17

4 Simulation Results 17

4.1 The Baseline Simulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

4.2 Sensitivity to Transaction Tax Rate Changes . . . . . . . . . 28

4.2.1 Statistical Properties of the Exchange Rate . . . . . . 28

4.2.2 Fundamental Traders and Technical Traders . . . . . 30

4.2.3 Short-term and Long-term Traders . . . . . . . . . . 31

5 Conclusion 32

6 Appendix: Derivation of the Multi-Period Forecasts 33

6.1 Fundamentalists’ Forecasts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

6.2 Chartists’ Forecasts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

Page 4: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 1

1 Introduction

Foreign exchange markets are excessively volatile and risky due to spec-

ulative bubbles and crashes. These transitory bubbles and crashes do not

reveal rational arbitrage-free pricing behavior but might be due to irrational

and trend-chasing behavior of speculators. Because trend-chasing behavior

and short-term speculation leads to excessive risks, policy instruments like

transaction taxes are proposed for reducing speculative attacks and exces-

sive risks.

Survey data of foreign exchange markets yields empirical evidence of het-

erogenous expectations among traders. Due to survey studies like the one

conducted by Taylor, M. and H. Allen (1992), these short term ex-

pectations are excessively volatile and display extrapolation behavior, while

long term expectations are regressive and therefore of a stabilizing nature.

Based on this empirical fact several studies like Brock and Hommes

(1997, 1998), Chiarella and He (2002), DeGrauwe and Grimaldi

(2006) and Lux and Marchesi (2000) start to incorporate heterogenous

expectations into economic models of exchange rate determination.

Because econometric tests on rational expectations in the foreign exchange

market1 are rejected and the e"cient market approach cannot explain the

stylized facts of financial market time series, researchers switched to the

chartist-fundamentalist approach based on the empirical evidence of het-

erogenous expectations from survey studies. This model framework is an al-

ternative expectations hypothesis and an appealing building block for mod-

els of the foreign exchange market. It assumes that traders are bounded

rational in that they do not use all available information and economic

1See Taylor and Allen (1992) and Menkhoff (1997) among others.

Page 5: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 2

models to forecast the exchange rate. Instead they rely on simple rules of

thumb because they do not know the whole structure of the model. Most

of these interacting agent models assume that the market is populated by

two types of traders. The chartist trader type searches for patterns in past

exchange rates like trends and trend reversals for forecasting future rates,

while fundamentalist traders search for over- and undervaluations and ex-

pect them to be corrected in the future. Moreover, this approach allows

agents to choose endogenously one of this two views of the world. The suc-

cess of this model framework to explain stylized facts of financial markets

like the exchange rate disconnect, excess volatility, volatility clustering and

excess kurtosis encourages to elaborate on them. Moreover, there is also

empirical evidence for the chartist-fundamentalist approach2.

Studies like Westerhoff (2003) use the chartist-fundamentalist approach

for analyzing the e!ects of market regulations in foreign exchange markets.

Westerho! finds that small transaction taxes lower exchange rate volatility

while a high Tobin tax rate will lead to an increase. He explains this finding

with the composition of chartists and fundamentalists in the population.

Small transaction taxes make destabilizing chartism unprofitable and in-

crease the fraction of fundamentalist traders which stabilizes the exchange

rate. If the tax rate exceeds a certain threshold also fundamentalism will

be unprofitable and the fraction of chartist traders will rise, so that this

destabilizes the exchange rate again and volatility will rise.

Mannaro et al. (2005) find in their simulation study within an artificial

stock market framework that volatility will fall by 2% for a tax rate of 0.1%,

2Engle and Hamilton (1990) find that there is regime switching in exchange rates inthat there are phases of trends and mean-reversion. Vigfusson (1997) finds empiricalevidence by estimating parameters of the chartist-fundamentalist model in a Markov-switching framework.

Page 6: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 3

while it will fall by 8% for a tax rate of 0.5% with respect to the reference

situation without taxes. Moreover, the percentage fraction of fundamental-

ists will rise due to the imposition of the transaction tax. In a simulation

with only random traders and chartists a small tax can also lead to a small

increase in volatility.

In this paper we want to introduce an extended version of the chartist-

fundamentalist model for the foreign exchange market. Our model is similar

to the models of Brock and Hommes (1997, 1998), Chiarella and He

(2002) and DeGrauwe and Grimaldi (2006) among others. In contrast

to these models we allow agents to choose between di!erent investment

horizons, such that there are short-term chartists and fundamentalists and

long-term chartists and fundamentalists. Moreover, we also deviated from

the commonly used discrete choice model for the evolution of trading rules

and introduce another evolutionary mechanism that also allows to choose

between di!erent investment horizons. Simulations of the baseline model

show that the model does well in replicating stylized facts like the unit-root

property of exchange rates, clustering of return volatility and excess kurtosis

in the distribution of returns.

The second task of our paper is to introduce transaction taxes into the

model in order to analyze, how these taxes influence traders behavior and

financial market risks. Simulations yield the result that on the microscopic

level transaction taxes prevent long term traders to switch to short term

speculation. On the macroscopic level these taxes reduce the variance of

exchange rate returns but also increase their kurtosis. Moreover, the tax

harms short-term speculation in favor of long-term investment, while it also

harms trading rules based on economic fundamentals in favor to trend ex-

trapolating trading rules.

Page 7: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 4

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: The next section

presents the model economy, while section three will present the numeri-

cal analysis of the model, while section four concludes.

2 The Model Economy

The model is similar to that proposed by De Grauwe and Grimaldi

(2006). Building blocks of the model are

(i) the agents’ portfolio selection problem,

(ii) the agents’ forecasts via di!erent forecasting models,

(iii) agents’ evaluation of these portfolio rules by comparing their past

profitability, and

(iv) in our model the exchange rate is set by a market maker in contrast to

DeGrauwe and Grimaldi (2006) , while traders are also allowed

to choose between di!erent investment horizons.

2.1 Fundamental Factors and Arbitrage

In this model the fundamental factors driving the exchange rate are the

gross rates of return on the domestic and foreign bond with one-period

maturity. We assume both interest rates R = (1 + r) to follow stochastic

mean-reverting processes of the form

ln Rt = (1 ! !) ln R + ! ln Rt!1 + "t, "t " N (0,#2), (1)

Page 8: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 5

where R is the long-run average interest rate, ! # [0, 1] is the rate of mean-

reversion and "t is a random innovation to the interest rate.

Analogue, the rate of return on the foreign one-period-bond follows

ln R"

t = (1 ! !) ln R" + ! ln R"

t!1 + ""t , ""t " N (0,#2). (2)

Assuming homogeneous interest rate expectations and that all agents know

the data generating processes for the interest rates, they can price the long-

term bonds according to the expectations hypothesis of the term structure.

The expectations hypothesis states that no arbitrage should be possible

between the rates of return of a long-term bond and the rates of return of

a sequence of one-period bonds over the maturity of the long-term bond.

This gives us the following valuation formula for long-term bonds

ln Rt,N =1

N

N!

n=0

Et ln Rt+n. (3)

Using the fact that the n-period-ahead forecast of the autoregressive process

for the interest rate is

Et ln Rt+n = !n ln Rt + (1 ! !n) ln R (4)

and applying the rule for the finite geometric series yields the long-term

interest rate

ln Rt,N =1

N

"

·1 ! !N

1 ! !· ln Rt + n !

1 ! !N

1 ! !ln R

#

. (5)

Figure 1 shows the time series of short-term and long-term interest rates

of a typical simulation run.

Page 9: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 6

Fig. 1: Fundamental Factors

0 50 100 1500.015

0.02

0.025

0.03

0.035

0.04

0.045Fundamental Factors

Time

Inte

rest

Ra

tes

Short!Term Interest Rate

Long!Term Interest Rate

Note: Model generated time series from the baseline simulation. The used parameter

values are those given in table 1. The first 1000 data points were removed.

Deviations from the no-arbitrage interest rate parity condition

Eitst+n

st

=

$

Rt,n

R"

t,n

%n

(6)

arise because interest rates follow stochastic processes. This deviation

promises profits for foreign exchange traders and provokes them to demand

foreign currency in the financial market. Note, that st is the bilateral ex-

change rate, while $ is the transaction tax rate. If this equation holds with

equality the expected interest rate change will o!set the interest rate dif-

ferential and no trade will occur, because all profits are already arbitraged

away.

Page 10: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 7

2.2 Traders’ Demand for Foreign Currency

Following DeGrauwe and Grimaldi (2006) we assume that each agent

can invest into a domestic asset and a foreign asset. In contrast to De-

Grauwe and Grimaldi (2006) both assets are risky due to the random-

ness of domestic and foreign interest rates and due to exchange rate risks.

We assume overlapping generations of traders, who enter the market for

their pertinent investment horizon. Afterwards they will leave the market

and consume their profits. The timing of each period is as follows:

(i) trader i enters the market. He observes interest rates, the exchange

rate and the past profits of the other traders. Depending on the past

profits of the other traders, he decides to be a short-run or long-run

fundamentalist or to be a short-run or long-run chartist trader,

(ii) depending on the interest rate di!erential and his expected depreciation

of the exchange rate the trader decides how much to invest in the

domestic and the foreign asset,

(iii) after the trader has realized his profit, he leaves the market and con-

sumes.

Agents are assumed to have preferences towards risks with constant absolute

risk aversion characterized by the following utility function

U(W it+n,!i) = ! exp{!!iW

it+n}, (7)

where W it is agent i’s wealth at time t, n # {1, ..., N} is the agents’ invest-

ment horizons, and !i is the agents Arrow-Pratt measure of absolute risk

Page 11: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 8

aversion. The agent’s wealth is assumed to follow

W it+n = (R"

t )nst+nd

it(1 ! $)2 + (Rt)

n(W it ! std

it), (8)

where R = (1+r) and R" = (1+r") are the gross returns on the domestic and

foreign bond, while st is the bilateral exchange rate between both countries.

The tax rate for foreign exchange market transactions is denoted with $ #

[0, 1]. The first part is the return on the foreign asset, while the second term

measures the costs of borrowing in the domestic country. For n = 1 and

$ = 0 this budget constraint collapses to the one proposed by DeGrauwe

and Grimaldi (2006).

If we assume wealth to be normally distributed we can simplify the portfolio

selection problem by maximizing the certainty equivalent

U(W it ,!i) = Ei

t!1[Wit ] !

!i

2Varit!1[W

it ] (9)

subject to the same budget constraint. Maximization yields the following

demand function for agent i with investment horizon n

di,nt =

Eit[W

it+n]

!iVarit[Wit+n]

=(R"

t )n(1 ! $)2Ei

t[st+n] ! (Rt)nst

!#2i,t

. (10)

Thus, trader i’s demand is decreasing in his degree of risk aversion, in a

higher risk #2i,t, decreasing in the transaction tax rate $ , and increasing in

the expected profit. For n = 1 and $ = 0 the demand function collapses to

the one used in DeGrauwe and Grimaldi (2006).

If we assume, following Brock and Hommes (1997) that the risk evaluation

is the same for all agents and constant over time, the demand function

Page 12: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 9

simplifies to

di,nt = %

&

(R"

t )n(1 ! $)2Ei

t[st+n] ! (Rt)nst

'

. (11)

2.3 Traders’ Forecasting Models

We assume that the true data generating process for the exchange rate is

unknown to the agents. Therefore they use ad-hoc rules for forecasting. We

assume that two types of forecasting rules are used. A rule which reacts

on trends in the exchange rate is commonly called chartist rule or technical

trading rule. The other technique called fundamentalist forecasting rule

looks for over- and undervaluations of the exchange rate with respect to its

arbitrage free fundamental value and expects a reversion back to it.

The fundamentalist forecasting rule for the one-step-ahead prediction of the

exchange rate can be written as

Eft [st+1 ! st] = &f · (sf

t ! st). (12)

Thus, this rule predicts an exchange rate change such that &f ·100% of the

disequilibrium sft ! st, that is the deviation of the realized exchange rate st

from the arbitrage-free exchange rate sft , will be corrected by the subsequent

exchange rate change. Note that the two step ahead forecast assumes that

&f ·100% of the remaining disequilibrium (1!&f ) · (sft !st) will be corrected

by the subsequent exchange rate change and so on. Thus, the n-step ahead

forecast will be

Eft [st+n ! st+n!1] = &f (1 ! &f )n!1 · (sf

t ! st). (13)

Page 13: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 10

For n = 1 this forecasting model collapses to the one used in DeGrauwe

and Grimaldi (2006), Lux and Marchesi (2000), Chiarella and He

(2002) and Brock and Hommes (1997).

The expected exchange rate change Eft [st+n] can be derived from the fore-

casted exchange rate changes as

Eft [st+n] ! st = Ef

t [st+n ! st+n!1] + Eft [st+n!1 ! st+n!2] + ... + Ef

t [st+1 ! st]

=(

1 ! (1 ! &f )n)

· (sft ! st), (14)

where the explicit derivation can be found in the appendix.

Fundamentalists believe that the arbitrage-free exchange rate sft is the ex-

change rate under which the uncovered interest rate parity condition holds

with equality

sft = st!1 ·

Rt!1

R"

t!1

. (15)

Therefore, if sft realizes, the exchange rate change o!sets the possible profits

from the interest rate di!erential and no arbitrage should be possible.

The technical forecasting rule for the one-step-ahead prediction can be spec-

ified as follows

Ect [st+1 ! st] = (&c) · (st ! st!1). (16)

Thus, this forecasting model predicts a trend continuation. If the exchange

rate change st ! st!1 is one, than this forecasting model predicts the next

exchange rate change to be &c. As usual in the theory of autoregressive

models we use the last period’s forecast to predict the next future exchange

rate if we do not have information about realizations. Thus, the two-step-

ahead forecast expects an exchange rate change of (&c)2 and so on. Thus,

Page 14: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 11

the n-step-ahead prediction will be

Ect [st+n ! st+n!1] = (&c)n · (st ! st!1). (17)

For n = 1 this forecasting model collapses to the one used in DeGrauwe

and Grimaldi (2006), Lux and Marchesi (2000), Chiarella and He

(2002) and Brock and Hommes (1997).

Equivalent to the fundamentalists’ technique, chartists calculate the ex-

pected exchange rate change Ect [st+n ! st] as

Ect [st+n ! st] = Ec

t [st+n ! st+n!1] + ... + Ect [st+1 ! st] (18)

=1 ! (&c)n

1 ! &c· &c · (st ! st!1), (19)

where the explicit derivation can be found in the appendix.

2.4 Evolution of Trading Rules

The agents’ strategy space consists of five trading rules. The agent can either

be a short-run fundamentalist or a short-run chartist, or the trader can be

a long-term fundamentalist or a long-term chartist. The fifth possibility for

the agents is to stay inactive, that means not to trade.

Page 15: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 12

Fig. 2: Possibilities to Change Trading Strategies

SRTT

SRFT LRFT

LRTT

t !"# t + N

t !"# t + 1

t !"# t + N

t !"# t + 1

t !"# t + Nt !"# t + Nt !"# t + 1t !"# t + 1

Note: The abbrevation SRTT denotes short-run technical trader, while LRTT denotes

long-run technical trader, while SRFT denotes short-run fundamental trader and LRFT

long-run fundamental trader. The fifth alternative for traders is to stay inactive for one

period which is not included in the graphic.

Because we assume that agents may have multi-period investment horizons,

the information concerning the individual agents investment horizon is saved

in the matrix !t, which has the dimension 5$M and may have for example

the following form

!t =

*

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

,

1 1 100 84 1

1 1 61 31 1

1 1 87 54 1

......

......

-

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

/

. (20)

The first two columns of this matrix identify the short run fundamental-

ist and the short run chartist, who have an investment horizon of one by

construction. Columns three and four identify the long term fundamental-

ist and the long term chartist and the time until their investment matures.

Agents are allowed to stay inactive for one period. This information is given

in column five. Agents 1, ...,M are given in rows. Thus, this matrix reads as

Page 16: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 13

follows. If agent 1 is a long run fundamentalists, then the time to maturity

of his investment is 100 periods. If he is a long term chartist, then the time

to maturity is 84 periods. This matrix is updated as follows

!t+1 = !t ! [0,0,1,1,0], (21)

where 0 is a 1 $ M vector of zeros, 1 is a 1 $ M vector of ones and M is

the number of agents. Thus, the investment horizon of long term agents

decreases by one period until maturity is reached. After that it switches

back to the maximum investment horizon of N periods. The starting value

for this updating process is generated by a random draw for the columns

three and four.

Agents are only allowed to change their trading rules when maturity is

reached. Thus short-term traders and inactive traders are allowed to switch

every period, long term traders are not allowed to switch for N periods.

The information about which agent is allowed to switch is contained in the

matrix St, with

St(i, j) = 1 %= !t(i, j) = 1 (22)

St(i, j) = 0 %= !t(i, j) &= 1. (23)

Thus, if St(i, j) = 1 then agent i is allowed to change his trading rule, if he

is type j. If St(i, j) = 0, then agent i with trading rule j is not allowed to

change his type. Because this matrix only contains information if an agent

is allowed to switch or not. The matrix tells us for example that agent one

is allowed to change his type, if he is type one, two or three, but he is not

allowed to switch if he is type four. Thus, this matrix does not tell us, which

trading rule the agent is currently using. This information is contained in

Page 17: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 14

the matrix "t, where "t(i, j) is one if agent i uses the trading rule j and

zero otherwise. Thus, the row sum of this matrix is one, because an agent

can only use one trading rule at the same time.

We assume that agents switch to the trading rule, which was the most suc-

cessful in the past if they are allowed to switch. Therefore agents calculate

the profits each trading rule yielded over the last N periods. The vector of

past profits is given by

#t =(

'f,1t ,'c,1

t ,'f,Nt ,'c,N

t , 0)

, (24)

where the agents realizes a profit of zero if he stays inactive.

The profit of agent i is measured by the variable 'i,nt

'i,nt =

0

st(R"

t!n)n(1 ! $)2 ! st!n(Rt!n)n1

· di,nt , (25)

for i # {c, f} and n = 1, ..., N .

Table 1: Cash Flows of Short-term and Long-term Traders

Short-term Trader

time t t + 1 ... t + N

di,1t !d

(i,1)t

&

(1 ! $)2(1 + R"

t )St+1

'

— —

Long-term Trader

time t t + 1 ... t + N

di,Nt — — !d

(i,N)t

&

(1 ! $)2(1 + R"

t,N)NSt+N

'

Here we replaced the forecast Eit!nst with the realized exchange rate st.

Thus, 'i,nt measures the profit per unit currency that results from the ex-

Page 18: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 15

change rate change and the interest rate di!erential times the amount of

currency demanded. This expression is similar to the one used in Grimaldi

(2004) and DeGrauwe and Grimaldi (****) with the di!erence that we scale

the profit per unit currency by the currency demanded by the agent.

The vector #!

t has the entry one at the same place, where #t has its

maximum and zeros at all other entries. Thus, this vector indicates to which

trader type the agent has to switch if he is allowed to switch. The switching

of agents is conducted, by replacing the pertinent row in the matrix "t with

the vector #t. This operation is conducted if an agent is allowed to switch.

This is possible if the condition

S(i, j) = 1 & "(i, j) = 1 (26)

holds. If

S(i, j) = 0 & "(i, j) = 1, (27)

then "(i, j) = 1, that means, the agent is not allowed to switch and has to

use his old trading strategy. In all other cases the matrix "(i, j) has the

entry zero.

The information about the number of agents, who are allowed to trade and

the number of agents being using one special trading rule is contained in

these matrices.

2.5 Institutional Properties and Price Setting

The market maker collects all individual demands in order to determine the

market demand. Individual demands di,nt can be aggregated to the market

demand Dt by adding them, while weighting them with the population

Page 19: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 16

fractions wi,nt of traders, who are allowed to trade

Dt = wc,1t dc,1

t + wc,Nt dc,N

t + wf,1t df,1

t + wf,Nt df,N

t (28)

! wc,1t!1'

c,1t!1 ! wc,N

t!N'c,Nt!N ! wf,1

t!1'f,1t!1 ! wf,N

t!N'f,Nt!N . (29)

Agents are allowed to trade at the beginning of their investment and at the

end of their investment. They have to pay back the loan they raised in order

to invest which is denoted in their home currency and because they want

to consume in their home country. The last e!ect is captured by the last

term in this equation.

If market demand is positive, the market maker will rise the price of the

exchange rate, while he will lower it, if market demand is negative. Thus

the exchange rate changes proportional to the sum of all market orders.

The behavior of the market maker can be approximated by the following

price impact function3

st+1 = st + (stDt. (30)

The exchange rate return can be calculated as

)t+1 =st+1 ! st

st

= (Dt. (31)

Thus, the model is complete now. Because it cannot be solved analytically,

we will rely on results derived by numerical simulations in the next section.

3Kyle (1985) derives this price impact function as the solution of his continuous doubleauction model. Lux and Marchesi (2000) and Westerho! (2003) also use this pricingrule within an agent-based-framework.

Page 20: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 17

3 Non-Stochastic Steady States

At the steady state all shocks will be zero and all variables will be constant.

Thus a steady state is characterized by

"t = ""t = 0 (32)

and

Rt = Rt!1 = R,R"

t = R"

t!1 = R", st = st!1 = s, (33)

di,t = di,t!1 = 0,'i,t = 'i,t!1 = 0, (34)

while the population fractions are undetermined.

Summing up, the steady state is characterized by equal rates of return

in both countries and no exchange rate change. Therefore we get zero

demands and zero profits, because the exchange rate equals its no-arbitrage

fundamental value.

4 Simulation Results

The model is simulated with the parameters given in table 2. For the

baseline simulation we set the transaction tax rate to zero in order to have

a benchmark for the policy simulations conducted later.

Page 21: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 18

Table 2: Calibrated Parameters for Baseline Simulation

Model Parameters

mean reversion parameters standard deviations of shocks

!1 = 0.96 !2 = 0.96 #1 = 0.03 #2 = 0.03

risk aversion parameters max. horizon simulation length

*C = 1 *F = 1 N = 100 T = 100 000

exchange rate response forecasting parameters

( = 0.01 &C = 0.9 &F = 0.8

transaction tax number of agents

$ = 0 300

Note: These parameters are used for the baseline simulation of the model without trans-

action taxes.

We assume the interest rates in both countries to be quite persistent because

empirical exchange rate data are also quite near a unit-root process. Thus,

we assume the two interest rate processes to follow

ln Rt = 0.04 · 1.005 + 0.96 · ln Rt!1 + 0.03 · "t, "t " N (0, 1). (35)

For the risk aversion we assume chartist traders and fundamentalist traders

to have the same value for the Arrow-Pratt measure of absolute risk aversion.

Moreover, we assume chartists to have an extrapolation parameter less than

one

ECt st+n ! st = 0.9n(st ! st!1), (36)

such that their forecasting model predicts a return of 0.9 for the next period,

if the current return is one and the two-period return to be 0.81.

Page 22: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 19

For the fundamentalist traders we assume that they expect exchange rate

disequilibria to be corrected with 80% per period. Thus, their forecasting

model becomes

EFt st+n ! st = 0.8 · 0.2n!1 · (sf

t ! st). (37)

Furthermore, we set the exchange rate response to

st+1 = st + 0.01 · stDt. (38)

4.1 The Baseline Simulation

Figures 3 and 4 show the simulation outcome of the baseline model with-

out taxes. The exchange rate shows a random walk like behavior like empir-

ical financial time series. One can clearly see that the time series displays

periods of trends and crashes as we typically find in financial market time

series.

Page 23: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 20

Fig. 3: Exchange Rate: Baseline Simulation

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 40000.8

0.9

1

1.1

1.2

1.3

1.4

1.5Model Implied Exchange Rate

Time

Exchange R

ate

Note: Model generated time series from the baseline simulation. The used parameter

values are those given in table 2. The first 1000 data points were removed.

A second stylized fact which the model is able to reproduce is volatility

clustering and excess kurtosis which can be seen from figure 4.

Page 24: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 21

Fig. 4: Exchange Rate: Baseline Simulation

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000!0.03

!0.02

!0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03Model Implied Exchange Rate Returns

Time

Exchange R

ate

Retu

rns

Note: Model generated time series from the baseline simulation. The used parameter

values are those given in table 2. The first 1000 data points were removed.

Both, in empirical time series as well as in the model produced time series

periods of high volatility and periods of low volatility tend to cluster to-

gether. Moreover as can be seen in the figure is, that extreme returns are

realized quite frequently.

By looking at figure 5 we can analyze this phenomenon in greater detail.

The upper subfigure shows a quantile-quantile-plot with respect to the nor-

mal distribution. Here quantiles of the standard normal distribution are

plotted against the quantiles of the empirical return distribution. If the

data is normally distributed all points should lie on the 45# line.

Page 25: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 22

Fig. 5: Return Distribution: Baseline Simulation

!4 !3 !2 !1 0 1 2 3 4!0.04

!0.02

0

0.02

0.04

Standard Normal Quantiles

Quantile

s o

f In

put S

am

ple

Quantile!Quantile!Plot

!0.03 !0.02 !0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.030

50

100

150

200Return Distribution

Data

Return Distribution

Normal Distribution

Note: Model generated time series from the baseline simulation. The used parameter

values are those given in table 1. The blue line represents the kernel density of the

model generated exchange rate returns, while the green line is the density of a normally

distributed random variable with the same mean and the same variance. The first 1000

data points were removed. The used parameter values are those given in table 2.

From this figure we can see deviations from the normal distribution in the

positive and negative extreme parts. In the lower subfigure the estimated

kernel density of the returns is plotted together with the density of a nor-

mally distributed random variable with the same mean and variance as the

input sample for comparison. From this figure can be seen that the density

of the model generated data has a higher peak and fatter tails with respect

to the normal distribution which means that this distribution is leptokurtic.

Page 26: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 23

The phenomenon of volatility clustering can be analyzed in more detail from

figure 5.

Fig. 6: Autocorrelation Functions: Baseline Simulation

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80!0.5

0

0.5

1

Lag

Sam

ple

Auto

corr

ela

tion

Autocorrelation Function: Raw Returns

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 800

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Lag

Sam

ple

Auto

corr

ela

tion

Autocorrelation Function: Squared Returns

Note: Model generated time series from the baseline simulation. The used parameter

values are those given in table 2. The first 1000 data points were removed.

Figure 6 plots the autocorrelation function of returns and squared returns

for 100 lags. Here, raw returns display only small serial correlation which

means that exchange rate returns are not predictable from their past data.

This finding is in line with the e"cient market hypothesis. In contrast to this

squared returns display strong correlations over 100 lags. This indicates that

although returns themselves are uncorrelated they are not independently

distributed because squared returns display high serial dependencies. We

Page 27: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 24

can interpret squared returns as a noise measure for volatility because

Var[rt|It!1] = E[r2t |It!1] and r2

t = E[r2t |It!1] + vt (39)

=' r2t = Var[r2

t |It!1] + vt. (40)

Therefore, high serial correlations of squared returns indicates that volatility

is serially correlated and therefore predictable. Small correlations in returns

and large correlations in squared returns can also be found in empirical date

as you can see in figure 6. Thus, our model is also able to replicate this

stylized fact of financial data.

Table 3: Summary Statistics of the Baseline Simulation

Model USD-Euro YEN-USD GBP-USD

mean 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

st. deviation 0.006 0.006 0.007 0.006

skewness -0.021 0.014 -0.487 -0.135

kurtosis 4.549 3.619 7.335 6.573

ARCH 0.285 0.014 0.056 0.065

GARCH 0.715 0.977 0.942 0.922

Note: Mean, variance, skewness and kurtosis are calculated from the model generated

exchange rate return data by using the parameters given in table 2. ARCH and GARCH

are the coe"cients of an GARCH(1,1) model fitted to the model generated return data.

The exchange rate data used in columns 3,4 and 5 are taken from the FRED2 database

of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis in daily frequency. The data is available under

the series-ID: DEXUSEU, DEXJPUS, and DEXUSUK.

Page 28: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 25

Table 3 contains summary statistics of the baseline simulation in compar-

ison with summary statistics of empirical exchange rate return data. The

mean of simulated returns and empirical returns is always zero, while the

variance of the model equals the empirical returns because of the model

calibration. The kurtosis of empirical data and of the baseline simulation is

always greater than 3, which is the kurtosis of a normally distributed ran-

dom variable. This fact also could be seen from the quantile-quantile-plot

and the kernel density graphs. Moreover, we fitted a GARCH(1,1) model to

the baseline simulation data and the empirical data. The GARCH-model

due to Bollerslev (1996) assumes the data to be conditional normally

distributed

rt|It!1 " N (0,#2t ), (41)

while the variance is assumed to follow an autoregressive process

#2t = + + !r2

t!1 + (#2t!1. (42)

New information about volatility can enter the model through squared re-

turns, while the last term measures the persistency of volatility. Empirical

studies usually find ! to be less than 0.1 and ( approximately 0.9, with

!+( close to one. This is an indication of the strong persistency in volatil-

ity. From table 3 you can infer, that this fact can also be found in estimates

for the three exchange rate return time series as well as for the model gen-

erated return time series. Thus, our model is also able to replicate this

stylized fact.

Page 29: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 26

Fig. 7: Fraction of Fundamentalist and Technical Traders: Baseline

Simulation

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 40000

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Fundamentalists Proportion

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 40000

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Chartists Proportion

Note: Model generated time series from the baseline simulation. The used parameter

values are those given in table 2. The first 1000 data points were removed.

Figure 7 plots the evolution of the population fractions of traders using

the technical trading rules and the fundamental trading rules. We can

clearly see from this figure that from time to time majorities for one of this

two trading rules emerge. It seems that the system is switching between

states in which one of the two rules is used by all traders and that their

view changes surprisingly. This is an indication of herding behavior among

traders. If we compare this figure with figure 4 we see that the periods

in which one of the two trading rules dominates the market correspond to

the high volatility and low volatility period in the exchange rate returns.

Page 30: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 27

Thus, herding behavior is a source of the volatility clusters produced by the

model.

Fig. 8: Fraction of Short-run and Long-run Traders: Baseline Simulation

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 40000

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Short!run Traders

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 40000

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Long!run Traders

Note: Model generated time series from the baseline simulation. The used parameter

values are those given in table 2. The first 1000 data points were removed.

Figure 8 plots the time variation of population fractions of traders hav-

ing either short-term investment horizons or long-term investment horizons.

Similar to figure 7 the system is switching between the two views of the

world. Thus, the market is either dominated by long-term traders or by

short-term traders. The dominance of short-term traders is an indication

of speculative attacks on one currency. If we compare this figure to figure

4 we can again see that speculative attacks correspond to high volatility

periods in the exchange rate returns.

Page 31: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 28

All in all, this section showed, that our model is able to reproduce devi-

ations of the exchange rate from the fundamental value, random walk or

martingale behavior of the exchange rate, volatility clustering and fat tails

in the distribution. Moreover, we learn about traders behavior that our fi-

nancial market is characterized by herding behavior of traders. The market

is either dominated by traders using trend-extrapolating trading rules or

trading rules based on economic fundamentals. Moreover we see that the

market is characterized by periods dominated by long-term or by short-term

traders. This is an indication of speculative attacks on one currency.

The success of our model in replicating stylized facts of financial data en-

courages to use it for economic policy analysis by varying the transaction

tax rate in order to analyze the e!ects of transaction taxes on financial risks.

This we will do in the next section.

4.2 Sensitivity to Transaction Tax Rate Changes

4.2.1 Statistical Properties of the Exchange Rate

Table 4 shows summary statistics of the model generated exchange rate

returns for di!erent values of the transaction tax rate.

Page 32: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 29

Table 4: Variation of the Transaction Tax

! 0% 1% 2% 4% 6%

mean 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

SE (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

variance 0.005 0.004 0.003 0.002 0.002

SE (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001)

skewness 0.051 0.084 0.206 0.369 0.425

SE (0.102) (0.242) (0.481) (0.774) (0.817)

kurtosis 3.617 5.923 9.911 15.048 16.667

SE (0.649) (4.178) (6.787) (8.929) (9.632)

Note: The remaining parameters are set to the values given in table 2. The statistics

are averages of 100 simulation runs of size 1000. The used parameter values are those

given in table 2. Standard errors are reported in parenthesis.

Page 33: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 30

The statistics reported in this table are averages over 100 simulation runs of

size 1000. From the table one can infer that the mean exchange rate return

does not change due to changes in the transaction tax rate, while their

variance is monotonically declining. Moreover one can see that although

positive transaction tax rates reduce the variance of exchange rate returns

they rise their kurtosis. Thus, positive transaction tax rates increase the

probability of extreme positive and negative returns. This limits the success

of taxes to reduce risks in foreign exchange markets.

4.2.2 Fundamental Traders and Technical Traders

From table 5 one can infer how positive transaction tax rates influence

traders behavior. The numbers belonging to this table are also averages

over 100 simulation runs of size 1000 and are based on the same seed of ran-

dom numbers like the statistics in table 3. From this table one can infer

that the number of traders using the fundamental trading rules is decreas-

ing in the transaction tax rate while the number of traders using chartist

rules is increasing. Moreover, the number of traders staying inactive are

rising slightly in the transaction tax rate. Thus, under positive transac-

tion tax rates chartist rules are more profitable than fundamental trading

rules which is a contradiction to the conventional view of the proponents

of a securities transaction tax who propose that traders will rely more on

economic fundamentals under positive tax rates.

Page 34: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 31

Table 5: Average Percentage Fractions of Used Trading Rules

! 0% 1% 2% 4% 6%

fundamental 0.875 0.847 0.787 0.750 0.756

SE (0.107) (0.102) (0.085) (0.080) (0.070)

technical 0.125 0.152 0.212 0.249 0.242

SE (0.107) (0.101) (0.085) (0.080) (0.070)

inactive 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002

SE (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

short-term 0.868 0.633 0.413 0.256 0.228

SE (0.113) (0.217) (0.197) (0.127) (0.110)

long-term 0.132 0.366 0.586 0.743 0.770

SE (0.113) (0.217) (0.197) (0.127) (0.110)

inactive 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002

SE (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

Note: Average percentage fractions of used trading rules during a typical simulation runfor di!erent transaction tax rates ! . The results of each column are based on the sameseed of random variables. The statistics are averages of 100 simulation runs of size 1000.The used parameter values are those given in table 2. Standard errors are reported inparenthesis.

4.2.3 Short-term and Long-term Traders

From table 5 one can also infer that the number of short term traders is

decreasing in the transaction tax rate while the number of long term traders

is increasing. This is in line with the conventional view that a transaction

tax makes short term trading more costly and therefore prevents speculative

attacks in favor of long term investments.

Page 35: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 32

5 Conclusion

This study wants to analyze the e!ectiveness of a transaction tax within an

agent-based framework. We propose a new model for the foreign exchange

market with four types of agents: short- and long term fundamentalists and

short- and long-term chartists. Stochastic interest rates in both countries

lead to temporal arbitrage opportunities and therefore to demand for foreign

currency. A market maker aggregates the agents’ market orders and rises the

exchange rate due to positive excess demand and lowers it due to negative

excess demand.

Simulations of the baseline model without transaction taxes produce time

series with realistic time series properties like in empirical exchange rate

date. This means that the model is capable to reproduce stylized facts of fi-

nancial variables like the unit root property, volatility clustering and excess

kurtosis. A comparison with empirical data shows that the model is able

to replicate these stylized facts very well. Moreover, our financial market

is characterized by periods dominated by traders using trend-extrapolating

trading rules or by trading rules based on economic fundamentals. Further-

more, periods emerge which are dominated either by short-term speculators

or by long-term investors. This is an indication of sudden speculative at-

tacks on one currency.

The economic policy analysis of our model shows that positive transaction

taxes are capable of reducing volatility. The disadvantage of this policy

instrument is, that the probability of extreme positive or negative exchange

rate returns is increased. That means higher transaction tax rate increases

the kurtosis of the return distribution. The tax alters traders behavior by

reducing short-term speculation in favor of long-term investments, which is

Page 36: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 33

in line with the arguments of the proponents of the Tobin tax. In contrast

to their view, in our model the tax favors trend extrapolating trading rules

an punished trading rules based on economic fundamentals. Because trend

extrapolating trading rules are a source of destabilization of the exchange

rate, this can be the reason why the transaction tax increases the kurtosis

of the return distribution.

Summing up, further research should look for analytical solutions to a sim-

plified version of this model and for extensions by the incorporation of other

long-term investment strategies into the model in order to get more infor-

mation about the e!ectiveness of transaction taxes on traders’ behavior and

the reduction of risks in financial markets.

6 Appendix: Derivation of the Multi-Period

Forecasts

6.1 Fundamentalists’ Forecasts

The one-step-ahead forecast of the future change in the exchange rate is

given by

EFt

(

st+1 ! st

)

= &f2

sft ! st

3

. (43)

Thus, the fundamentalists’ forecast yields, that (1 ! &f )2

sft ! st

3

disequi-

librium will remain. Thus, the next predicted exchange rate change will

be

EFt

(

st+2 ! st+1

)

= &f (1 ! &f )2

sft ! st

3

. (44)

Page 37: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 34

Again, (1 ! &f )22

sft ! st

3

disequilibrium will remain. In general, we have

EFt

(

st+n ! st+n!1

)

= &f (1 ! &f )n!12

sft ! st

3

. (45)

If fundamentalists want to forecast the exchange rate st+n, they have to

forecast the future exchange rate changes as we have done before and then

to calculate

Eft st+n = st + Ef

t

(

st+1 ! st

)

+ Eft

(

st+2 ! st+1

)

+ ... + Eft

(

st+n ! st+n!1

)

(46)

= st + &f (sft ! st) + &f (1 ! &f )(sf

t ! st) + ... + &f (1 ! &f )n!1(sft ! st)

= st +&

&f (1 ! &f )0 + &f (1 ! &f ) + ... + &f (1 ! &f )n!1'

(sft ! st)

= st + &f&

(1 ! &f )0 + (1 ! &f ) + ... + (1 ! &f )n!1'

(sft ! st)

By applying the rule for the geometric series, we can write this as

Eft st+n = st +

2

1 ! (1 ! &f )n3

(sft ! st). (47)

6.2 Chartists’ Forecasts

The one-step-ahead forecast of the next exchange rate change is given by

Et

(

st+1 ! st

)

= &c(st ! st!1), (48)

Page 38: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 35

while the one-step-ahead forecast for the subsequent exchange rate change

is given by

Et

(

st+2 ! st+1

)

= &cEct(st+1 ! st) (49)

= (&c)2(st ! st!1).

In general, we have

Et

(

st+n ! st+n!1

)

= &cEct(st+n!1 ! st+n!2) (50)

= (&c)n(st ! st!1). (51)

For forecasting the future exchange rate st+n chartists have to forecast the

exchange rate changes as we have done before and then to calculate

Ectst+n = st + Ec

t [st+1 ! st] + Ect [st+2 ! st+1] + ... + Ec

t [st+n ! st+n!1](52)

= st + &c(st ! st!1) + (&c)2(st ! st!1) + ... + (&c)n(st ! st!1)

= st +&

&c + (&c)2 + ... + (&c)n'

(st ! st!1)

= st + &c&

(&c)0 + (&c)1 + ... + (&c)n!1'

(st ! st!1)

By applying the formula for the geometric series we get

Ectst+n = st + &c ·

(1 ! &c)n

1 ! &c· (st ! st!1). (53)

Page 39: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 36

References

[1] Bollerslev, T. (1986), ”Generalized Autoregressive Conditional

Heteroskedasticity”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 31, 307-327.

[2] Brock, W. and C. Hommes (1997), ”A Rational Route to Random-

ness” Econometrica, Vol. 65, 1059-1095.

[3] Chiarella, C. and T. He (2002), ”An Adaptive Model on Asset

Pricing and Wealth Dynamics with Heterogeneous Trading Strategies,”

Computing in Economics and Finance, Vol. 135, Society for Compu-

tational Economics.

[4] DeGrauwe, P. and M. Grimaldi (2006), ”Exchange Rate Puzzles:

A Tale of Switching Attractors”, European Economic Review, Vol. 50,

1-33.

[5] Engel, C. and J. Hamilton (1990), ”Long Swings in the Dollar:

Are They in the Data and do Markets Know It”, American Economic

Review, Vol. 80, 689-713.

[6] Farmer. D. and S. Joshi (2002), ”The Price Dynamics of Common

Trading Stategies”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,

Vol. 49, 149-171.

[7] Kyle, A. (1985), ”Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading”, Econo-

metrica, Vol. 53, 1315-1336.

[8] Lux, T. and M. Marchesi (2000), ”Volatility Clustering in Finan-

cial Markets: A Micro-Simulation of Interacting Agents”, Journal of

Theoretical and Applied Finance, Vol. 3, 675-702.

[9] Mannaro, K., M. Marchesi and A. Setzu (2005),

Page 40: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

Markus Demary

Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks 37

”The Impact of Transaction Taxes on Traders’ Behavior and

Wealth: A Microsimulation” , Working Paper, available at:

http://www.essex.ac.uk/wehia05/Paper/Parallel4/Session3/

MarchesiM.pdf

[10] Menkhoff, L. (1997), ”Examining the Use of Technical Currency

Analysis”, International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 2,

307-318.

[11] Taylor, M. and H. Allen (1992), ”The Use of Technical Analysis

in the Foreign Exchange Market”, Journal of International Money and

Finance, Vol. 11, 304-314.

[12] Vigfusson, R. (1997), ”Switching between Chartists and Fundamen-

talists: A Markov Regime-Switching Approach” Journal of Interna-

tional Money and Finance, Vol. 2, 291-305.

[13] Westerhoff, F. (2003), ”Heterogeneous Traders and the Tobin Tax”,

Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol. 13, 53-70.

Page 41: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

!!"#$%&'()*)+#,(,+#%+,(

(

List of other working papers:

2006

1. Roman Kozhan, Multiple Priors and No-Transaction Region, WP06-24 2. Martin Ellison, Lucio Sarno and Jouko Vilmunen, Caution and Activism? Monetary Policy

Strategies in an Open Economy, WP06-23 3. Matteo Marsili and Giacomo Raffaelli, Risk bubbles and market instability, WP06-22 4. Mark Salmon and Christoph Schleicher, Pricing Multivariate Currency Options with Copulas,

WP06-21 5. Thomas Lux and Taisei Kaizoji, Forecasting Volatility and Volume in the Tokyo Stock Market:

Long Memory, Fractality and Regime Switching, WP06-20 6. Thomas Lux, The Markov-Switching Multifractal Model of Asset Returns: GMM Estimation

and Linear Forecasting of Volatility, WP06-19 7. Peter Heemeijer, Cars Hommes, Joep Sonnemans and Jan Tuinstra, Price Stability and

Volatility in Markets with Positive and Negative Expectations Feedback: An Experimental Investigation, WP06-18

8. Giacomo Raffaelli and Matteo Marsili, Dynamic instability in a phenomenological model of correlated assets, WP06-17

9. Ginestra Bianconi and Matteo Marsili, Effects of degree correlations on the loop structure of scale free networks, WP06-16

10. Pietro Dindo and Jan Tuinstra, A Behavioral Model for Participation Games with Negative Feedback, WP06-15

11. Ceek Diks and Florian Wagener, A weak bifucation theory for discrete time stochastic dynamical systems, WP06-14

12. Markus Demary, Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Risks, WP06-13 13. Andrea De Martino and Matteo Marsili, Statistical mechanics of socio-economic systems with

heterogeneous agents, WP06-12 14. William Brock, Cars Hommes and Florian Wagener, More hedging instruments may

destabilize markets, WP06-11 15. Ginwestra Bianconi and Roberto Mulet, On the flexibility of complex systems, WP06-10 16. Ginwestra Bianconi and Matteo Marsili, Effect of degree correlations on the loop structure of

scale-free networks, WP06-09 17. Ginwestra Bianconi, Tobias Galla and Matteo Marsili, Effects of Tobin Taxes in Minority Game

Markets, WP06-08 18. Ginwestra Bianconi, Andrea De Martino, Felipe Ferreira and Matteo Marsili, Multi-asset

minority games, WP06-07 19. Ba Chu, John Knight and Stephen Satchell, Optimal Investment and Asymmetric Risk for a

Large Portfolio: A Large Deviations Approach, WP06-06 20. Ba Chu and Soosung Hwang, The Asymptotic Properties of AR(1) Process with the

Occasionally Changing AR Coefficient, WP06-05 21. Ba Chu and Soosung Hwang, An Asymptotics of Stationary and Nonstationary AR(1)

Processes with Multiple Structural Breaks in Mean, WP06-04 22. Ba Chu, Optimal Long Term Investment in a Jump Diffusion Setting: A Large Deviation

Approach, WP06-03 23. Mikhail Anufriev and Gulio Bottazzi, Price and Wealth Dynamics in a Speculative Market with

Generic Procedurally Rational Traders, WP06-02 24. Simonae Alfarano, Thomas Lux and Florian Wagner, Empirical Validation of Stochastic

Models of Interacting Agents: A “Maximally Skewed” Noise Trader Model?, WP06-01

2005

1. Shaun Bond and Soosung Hwang, Smoothing, Nonsynchronous Appraisal and Cross-Sectional Aggreagation in Real Estate Price Indices, WP05-17

Page 42: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

2. Mark Salmon, Gordon Gemmill and Soosung Hwang, Performance Measurement with Loss Aversion, WP05-16

3. Philippe Curty and Matteo Marsili, Phase coexistence in a forecasting game, WP05-15 4. Matthew Hurd, Mark Salmon and Christoph Schleicher, Using Copulas to Construct Bivariate

Foreign Exchange Distributions with an Application to the Sterling Exchange Rate Index (Revised), WP05-14

5. Lucio Sarno, Daniel Thornton and Giorgio Valente, The Empirical Failure of the Expectations Hypothesis of the Term Structure of Bond Yields, WP05-13

6. Lucio Sarno, Ashoka Mody and Mark Taylor, A Cross-Country Financial Accelorator: Evidence from North America and Europe, WP05-12

7. Lucio Sarno, Towards a Solution to the Puzzles in Exchange Rate Economics: Where Do We Stand?, WP05-11

8. James Hodder and Jens Carsten Jackwerth, Incentive Contracts and Hedge Fund Management, WP05-10

9. James Hodder and Jens Carsten Jackwerth, Employee Stock Options: Much More Valuable Than You Thought, WP05-09

10. Gordon Gemmill, Soosung Hwang and Mark Salmon, Performance Measurement with Loss Aversion, WP05-08

11. George Constantinides, Jens Carsten Jackwerth and Stylianos Perrakis, Mispricing of S&P 500 Index Options, WP05-07

12. Elisa Luciano and Wim Schoutens, A Multivariate Jump-Driven Financial Asset Model, WP05-06

13. Cees Diks and Florian Wagener, Equivalence and bifurcations of finite order stochastic processes, WP05-05

14. Devraj Basu and Alexander Stremme, CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM?, WP05-04

15. Ginwestra Bianconi and Matteo Marsili, Emergence of large cliques in random scale-free networks, WP05-03

16. Simone Alfarano, Thomas Lux and Friedrich Wagner, Time-Variation of Higher Moments in a Financial Market with Heterogeneous Agents: An Analytical Approach, WP05-02

17. Abhay Abhayankar, Devraj Basu and Alexander Stremme, Portfolio Efficiency and Discount Factor Bounds with Conditioning Information: A Unified Approach, WP05-01

2004

1. Xiaohong Chen, Yanqin Fan and Andrew Patton, Simple Tests for Models of Dependence Between Multiple Financial Time Series, with Applications to U.S. Equity Returns and Exchange Rates, WP04-19

2. Valentina Corradi and Walter Distaso, Testing for One-Factor Models versus Stochastic Volatility Models, WP04-18

3. Valentina Corradi and Walter Distaso, Estimating and Testing Sochastic Volatility Models using Realized Measures, WP04-17

4. Valentina Corradi and Norman Swanson, Predictive Density Accuracy Tests, WP04-16 5. Roel Oomen, Properties of Bias Corrected Realized Variance Under Alternative Sampling

Schemes, WP04-15 6. Roel Oomen, Properties of Realized Variance for a Pure Jump Process: Calendar Time

Sampling versus Business Time Sampling, WP04-14 7. Richard Clarida, Lucio Sarno, Mark Taylor and Giorgio Valente, The Role of Asymmetries and

Regime Shifts in the Term Structure of Interest Rates, WP04-13 8. Lucio Sarno, Daniel Thornton and Giorgio Valente, Federal Funds Rate Prediction, WP04-12 9. Lucio Sarno and Giorgio Valente, Modeling and Forecasting Stock Returns: Exploiting the

Futures Market, Regime Shifts and International Spillovers, WP04-11 10. Lucio Sarno and Giorgio Valente, Empirical Exchange Rate Models and Currency Risk: Some

Evidence from Density Forecasts, WP04-10 11. Ilias Tsiakas, Periodic Stochastic Volatility and Fat Tails, WP04-09 12. Ilias Tsiakas, Is Seasonal Heteroscedasticity Real? An International Perspective, WP04-08 13. Damin Challet, Andrea De Martino, Matteo Marsili and Isaac Castillo, Minority games with

finite score memory, WP04-07 14. Basel Awartani, Valentina Corradi and Walter Distaso, Testing and Modelling Market

Microstructure Effects with an Application to the Dow Jones Industrial Average, WP04-06

Page 43: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

15. Andrew Patton and Allan Timmermann, Properties of Optimal Forecasts under Asymmetric Loss and Nonlinearity, WP04-05

16. Andrew Patton, Modelling Asymmetric Exchange Rate Dependence, WP04-04 17. Alessio Sancetta, Decoupling and Convergence to Independence with Applications to

Functional Limit Theorems, WP04-03 18. Alessio Sancetta, Copula Based Monte Carlo Integration in Financial Problems, WP04-02 19. Abhay Abhayankar, Lucio Sarno and Giorgio Valente, Exchange Rates and Fundamentals:

Evidence on the Economic Value of Predictability, WP04-01

2002

1. Paolo Zaffaroni, Gaussian inference on Certain Long-Range Dependent Volatility Models, WP02-12

2. Paolo Zaffaroni, Aggregation and Memory of Models of Changing Volatility, WP02-11 3. Jerry Coakley, Ana-Maria Fuertes and Andrew Wood, Reinterpreting the Real Exchange Rate

- Yield Diffential Nexus, WP02-10 4. Gordon Gemmill and Dylan Thomas , Noise Training, Costly Arbitrage and Asset Prices:

evidence from closed-end funds, WP02-09 5. Gordon Gemmill, Testing Merton's Model for Credit Spreads on Zero-Coupon Bonds, WP02-

08 6. George Christodoulakis and Steve Satchell, On th Evolution of Global Style Factors in the

MSCI Universe of Assets, WP02-07 7. George Christodoulakis, Sharp Style Analysis in the MSCI Sector Portfolios: A Monte Caro

Integration Approach, WP02-06 8. George Christodoulakis, Generating Composite Volatility Forecasts with Random Factor

Betas, WP02-05 9. Claudia Riveiro and Nick Webber, Valuing Path Dependent Options in the Variance-Gamma

Model by Monte Carlo with a Gamma Bridge, WP02-04 10. Christian Pedersen and Soosung Hwang, On Empirical Risk Measurement with Asymmetric

Returns Data, WP02-03 11. Roy Batchelor and Ismail Orgakcioglu, Event-related GARCH: the impact of stock dividends

in Turkey, WP02-02 12. George Albanis and Roy Batchelor, Combining Heterogeneous Classifiers for Stock Selection,

WP02-01

2001

1. Soosung Hwang and Steve Satchell , GARCH Model with Cross-sectional Volatility; GARCHX Models, WP01-16

2. Soosung Hwang and Steve Satchell, Tracking Error: Ex-Ante versus Ex-Post Measures, WP01-15

3. Soosung Hwang and Steve Satchell, The Asset Allocation Decision in a Loss Aversion World, WP01-14

4. Soosung Hwang and Mark Salmon, An Analysis of Performance Measures Using Copulae, WP01-13

5. Soosung Hwang and Mark Salmon, A New Measure of Herding and Empirical Evidence, WP01-12

6. Richard Lewin and Steve Satchell, The Derivation of New Model of Equity Duration, WP01-11

7. Massimiliano Marcellino and Mark Salmon, Robust Decision Theory and the Lucas Critique, WP01-10

8. Jerry Coakley, Ana-Maria Fuertes and Maria-Teresa Perez, Numerical Issues in Threshold Autoregressive Modelling of Time Series, WP01-09

9. Jerry Coakley, Ana-Maria Fuertes and Ron Smith, Small Sample Properties of Panel Time-series Estimators with I(1) Errors, WP01-08

10. Jerry Coakley and Ana-Maria Fuertes, The Felsdtein-Horioka Puzzle is Not as Bad as You Think, WP01-07

11. Jerry Coakley and Ana-Maria Fuertes, Rethinking the Forward Premium Puzzle in a Non-linear Framework, WP01-06

12. George Christodoulakis, Co-Volatility and Correlation Clustering: A Multivariate Correlated ARCH Framework, WP01-05

Page 44: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

13. Frank Critchley, Paul Marriott and Mark Salmon, On Preferred Point Geometry in Statistics, WP01-04

14. Eric Bouyé and Nicolas Gaussel and Mark Salmon, Investigating Dynamic Dependence Using Copulae, WP01-03

15. Eric Bouyé, Multivariate Extremes at Work for Portfolio Risk Measurement, WP01-02 16. Erick Bouyé, Vado Durrleman, Ashkan Nikeghbali, Gael Riboulet and Thierry Roncalli,

Copulas: an Open Field for Risk Management, WP01-01

2000

1. Soosung Hwang and Steve Satchell , Valuing Information Using Utility Functions, WP00-06 2. Soosung Hwang, Properties of Cross-sectional Volatility, WP00-05 3. Soosung Hwang and Steve Satchell, Calculating the Miss-specification in Beta from Using a

Proxy for the Market Portfolio, WP00-04 4. Laun Middleton and Stephen Satchell, Deriving the APT when the Number of Factors is

Unknown, WP00-03 5. George A. Christodoulakis and Steve Satchell, Evolving Systems of Financial Returns: Auto-

Regressive Conditional Beta, WP00-02 6. Christian S. Pedersen and Stephen Satchell, Evaluating the Performance of Nearest

Neighbour Algorithms when Forecasting US Industry Returns, WP00-01

1999

1. Yin-Wong Cheung, Menzie Chinn and Ian Marsh, How do UK-Based Foreign Exchange Dealers Think Their Market Operates?, WP99-21

2. Soosung Hwang, John Knight and Stephen Satchell, Forecasting Volatility using LINEX Loss Functions, WP99-20

3. Soosung Hwang and Steve Satchell, Improved Testing for the Efficiency of Asset Pricing Theories in Linear Factor Models, WP99-19

4. Soosung Hwang and Stephen Satchell, The Disappearance of Style in the US Equity Market, WP99-18

5. Soosung Hwang and Stephen Satchell, Modelling Emerging Market Risk Premia Using Higher Moments, WP99-17

6. Soosung Hwang and Stephen Satchell, Market Risk and the Concept of Fundamental Volatility: Measuring Volatility Across Asset and Derivative Markets and Testing for the Impact of Derivatives Markets on Financial Markets, WP99-16

7. Soosung Hwang, The Effects of Systematic Sampling and Temporal Aggregation on Discrete Time Long Memory Processes and their Finite Sample Properties, WP99-15

8. Ronald MacDonald and Ian Marsh, Currency Spillovers and Tri-Polarity: a Simultaneous Model of the US Dollar, German Mark and Japanese Yen, WP99-14

9. Robert Hillman, Forecasting Inflation with a Non-linear Output Gap Model, WP99-13 10. Robert Hillman and Mark Salmon , From Market Micro-structure to Macro Fundamentals: is

there Predictability in the Dollar-Deutsche Mark Exchange Rate?, WP99-12 11. Renzo Avesani, Giampiero Gallo and Mark Salmon, On the Evolution of Credibility and

Flexible Exchange Rate Target Zones, WP99-11 12. Paul Marriott and Mark Salmon, An Introduction to Differential Geometry in Econometrics,

WP99-10 13. Mark Dixon, Anthony Ledford and Paul Marriott, Finite Sample Inference for Extreme Value

Distributions, WP99-09 14. Ian Marsh and David Power, A Panel-Based Investigation into the Relationship Between

Stock Prices and Dividends, WP99-08 15. Ian Marsh, An Analysis of the Performance of European Foreign Exchange Forecasters,

WP99-07 16. Frank Critchley, Paul Marriott and Mark Salmon, An Elementary Account of Amari's Expected

Geometry, WP99-06 17. Demos Tambakis and Anne-Sophie Van Royen, Bootstrap Predictability of Daily Exchange

Rates in ARMA Models, WP99-05 18. Christopher Neely and Paul Weller, Technical Analysis and Central Bank Intervention, WP99-

04 19. Christopher Neely and Paul Weller, Predictability in International Asset Returns: A Re-

examination, WP99-03

Page 45: Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior and Exchange Rate Riskswrap.warwick.ac.uk/1755/1/WRAP_Demary_fwp06-13.pdf · 2010-11-19 · Markus Demary Transaction Taxes, Traders’ Behavior

20. Christopher Neely and Paul Weller, Intraday Technical Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market, WP99-02

21. Anthony Hall, Soosung Hwang and Stephen Satchell, Using Bayesian Variable Selection Methods to Choose Style Factors in Global Stock Return Models, WP99-01

1998

1. Soosung Hwang and Stephen Satchell, Implied Volatility Forecasting: A Compaison of Different Procedures Including Fractionally Integrated Models with Applications to UK Equity Options, WP98-05

2. Roy Batchelor and David Peel, Rationality Testing under Asymmetric Loss, WP98-04 3. Roy Batchelor, Forecasting T-Bill Yields: Accuracy versus Profitability, WP98-03 4. Adam Kurpiel and Thierry Roncalli , Option Hedging with Stochastic Volatility, WP98-02 5. Adam Kurpiel and Thierry Roncalli, Hopscotch Methods for Two State Financial Models,

WP98-01