what’s the difference? a s - diva...

47
WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS OF THE EVOLUTION OF THE FAMILY GAP IN S WEDEN Submitted by Anna Fornwall Department of Economics Supervisor Håkan Selin Spring term, 2019

Upload: others

Post on 23-Aug-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE?

A DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS OF THE EVOLUTION OF THE

FAMILY GAP IN SWEDEN

Submitted by

Anna Fornwall

Department of Economics

Supervisor

Håkan Selin

Spring term, 2019

Page 2: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

ABSTRACT

In this study, I compare men and women with and without children to analyze the effect

of children on wages and earnings. By comparing the gender wage gap to the family gap for

men and women respectively, I find that there is still a persistent, yet rather small, family gap

for women. The constant family gap for women supports the notion that a greater fraction

of the gender wage gap can be explained by effects of having children now than previously.

When using yearly earnings instead of hourly wages, the gender wage gap increases whereas

the family gap for women decreases.

This implies that although there are several policies with the aim of reducing gender wage

differences and creating possibilities for women to combine work and family, there are still

concrete effects that arise from taking the responsibility for children. Because the effect of

having children is seemingly constant over time for women, the results from this study imply

that specific policies are needed to prevent and battle the difference in labor market outcomes

that arise because of the differing effects from caring for children.

Keywords: Gender wage gap, Family gap, Wage inequality, Child penalty

Page 3: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

CONTENTS

1 INTRODUCTION 4

2 BACKGROUND AND LITERATURE REVIEW 6

2.1 THE GENDER WAGE GAP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.2 DIFFERENCES IN THE USE OF PARENTAL LEAVE AND FAMILY RESPONSI-

BILITY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.3 EFFECTS OF BEING OUT OF THE LABOR FORCE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

2.4 THE FAMILY GAP – ESTIMATING THE WAGE IMPACT OF CHILDREN . . . . 8

3 THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 11

3.1 LABOR SUPPLY THEORY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

3.2 HUMAN CAPITAL THEORY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

3.3 SIGNALING THEORY AND STATISTICAL DISCRIMINATION . . . . . . . . . . 14

3.4 SELF-SELECTION THEORY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

4 DATA 16

4.1 DATA SOURCE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

4.2 VARIABLE DESCRIPTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

5 EMPIRICAL METHOD 21

5.1 ORDINARY LEAST SQUARES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

5.2 FAMILY AND GENDER GAP IN EACH WAVE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

5.3 INTERPRETATION OF ESTIMATES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

5.4 LABOR EARNINGS AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

5.5 PROBABILITY OF BEING IN EMPLOYMENT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

6 RESULTS 25

6.1 FAMILY AND GENDER GAP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

6.2 YEARLY EARNINGS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

6.3 PROBABILITY OF BEING IN EMPLOYMENT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36

6.4 DISCUSSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

2

Page 4: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

7 CONCLUSION 39

3

Page 5: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

1 INTRODUCTION

For the past few decades, there has been a growing body of research examining the wage

differential between men and women. Decomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and

an unexplained part, the explained part has slowly converged over time and what remains could

to some extent be attributed to the gender difference in effects of children [Kleven et al., 2018].

Sweden has one of the most generous parental leave insurances in the world, and was the

first country to allow fathers to receive benefit on the same terms as mothers when caring for

their children [SCB, 2018]. Despite the possibility to share family responsibilities equally,

the outtake of parental leave days is heavily skewed with women still accounting for the vast

majority of the parental leave [Försäkringskassan, 2018]. The difference in outtake varies with

income and educational level of the parents and the sector in which they work.

There is also a lot of research examining the effects of having children and taking parental

leave. These effects differ between men and women, with women experiencing a much more

negative effect than men. This negative effect is referred to as the “family penalty”, which is

the effect of children on labor market outcomes that cannot be explained statistically

[Staff and Mortimer, 2012]. Because of the longstanding wage differences between men

and women, one approach to examine the effect on wage due to children is to compare women

with children to women without children. The differences in wage between the two groups,

when accounting for observable characteristics, is defined as “the family gap” – the difference

in wage that occurs between comparable individuals when one of the two has at least one child

and the other one has no children [Waldfogel, 1998]. The family gap has received growing

research interest in the past few years, with Kleven et al. [Kleven et al., 2018] accounting

for the most recent research. In their paper “Children and Gender Inequality: Evidence from

Denmark” they are investigating the family gap in Denmark using an event study approach, and

they argue that although the gender wage gap has decreased in the past few decades, the family

gap remains constant.

The aim of this thesis is to investigate how the family gap has developed over time in

Sweden and how it can be related to the general gender wage gap during the same time period.

The data used for the analysis is the Swedish level of living surveys (SLLS) conducted in six

waves. SLLS is unique in that they have collected hourly wage data for individuals in all waves,

which is normally not possible to access. In the most similar study conducted by Kleven et al in

4

Page 6: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Denmark, a measure of wage is constructed by using yearly earnings divided by hours worked,

which they themselves point out likely biases the results somewhat.

The research question of this paper is therefore “how has the family gap evolved in Sweden

over time and how does this development relate to the general gender wage gap?”. The research

question is of relevance in a policy perspective as the wage gap between men and women is

still a challenge in the Swedish labor market. An increased understanding of the reasons for

its development over time with regards to having children is of importance in order to reduce

this difference in the future. Because Sweden has a particularly well-developed parental leave

and child benefit system, the results may very well differ from other countries, either in a more

positive or more negative direction.

There are two main contributions of this study. Firstly, there has, to the best of my knowl-

edge, not been any similar historical analysis of the development of the family gap in Sweden.

Secondly, the study uses gross hourly wages as the dependent variable in the analysis. Data on

hourly wages is often difficult to retrieve for earlier years, which is the reason for why most

historical analyses depend on monthly or yearly labor income instead. Using hourly wage as

the dependent variable makes it possible to separate the effect of children on wages from the

effect of children on hours worked. For this reason, I believe that this study will fill a gap in

the existing literature.

The outline of the paper is organized as followed: Section 2 provides background and previ-

ous literature in the research area; section 3 describes the theoretical framework. Furthermore,

the data used for the analysis is presented in section 4, along with some variable descriptions;

section 5 covers the method used to retrieve the results, which are presented in section 6. Lastly,

section 7 provides a brief summary and conclusion of the results.

5

Page 7: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

2 BACKGROUND AND LITERATURE REVIEW

This section starts by a presentation of research on the general wage differences between men

and women. Then, statistics and research regarding the gender differences in factors relevant

to labor market outcomes are discussed. Lastly, previous literature on the family gap and its

implications are reviewed.

2.1 THE GENDER WAGE GAP

Understanding the wage differentials between men and women has been an important research

agenda for decades. The difference can be decomposed into two parts – explained and un-

explained. Much of the variation between men and women can be explained by observed

differences in educational and career choices, differences in the amount of unpaid work and

family responsibilities [Blau and Kahn, 2017]. The explained gap has somewhat decreased

over time, but the pace has slowed down and there is still a persistent unexplained gap that

remains [Kleven et al., 2018]. This has been explained in different ways; statistical discrimi-

nation towards women, differences in preferences and psychological attributes being some of

the most common examples from literature [Bertrand, 2011]. The gender wage gap opens up

mainly in ages 30-40 (SCB, 2013), when many individuals have young children, with men and

women following similar trends before becoming parents. [Kleven et al., 2018]

2.2 DIFFERENCES IN THE USE OF PARENTAL LEAVE AND FAMILY RE-

SPONSIBILITY

One reason for why studying Sweden is particularly interesting is because of its generous poli-

cies on parental leave benefits and public childcare. The parental leave insurance was first

introduced in 1974, replacing the previous maternal leave insurance [SCB, 2018]. The new

insurance made it possible for men to receive social benefits on the same terms as women when

taking leave from work to care for their children. This encouraged men to be more involved

in their children and acknowledged the child’s right to both parents. Although the insurance

was changed to induce economic incentives for couples to share family responsibilities more

equally, women accounted for 99,5 percent of the outtake in 1974. Women have since grad-

ually decreased their share of parental leave and men have increased theirs, but the averages

6

Page 8: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

between the groups still differ significantly, with women being responsible for a vast majority

of the parental leave still. [Försäkringskassan, 2018]

Since being introduced in 1974, the scheme of the insurance has underwent a number

of changes; the maximum length of the parental leave benefit has been prolonged gradually

through several reforms and is presently set at 480 days, with 90 days being reserved for each

parent since 2002. (Ibid.) The parental leave benefit can be divided into two levels of replace-

ment. For 90 of the total 480 days, the replacement is set at a low, fixed level whereas benefit

for the remaining 390 days is calculated based on previous earnings. There is, however, a cap

for maximum level of benefits. (Ibid.)

Women on average take more time away from the labor market when becoming parents,

thus also taking on a larger share of unpaid work in the home [Försäkringskassan, 2018]. The

difference in parental leave may impact long-run patterns within families, with women tak-

ing temporary parental leave more than men to care for sick children or choosing to work

part-time. Differences in outtake between men and women and the design of the parental

leave insurance causes women to fall behind men when they have children. Angelov et al.

[Angelov et al., 2016] show that there are small gender differences in wage prior to having

children, but significantly larger differences 15 years after the birth of the first child. The great-

est differences occur in couples where the woman would have had a lower income and wage

development than the man even without children.

2.3 EFFECTS OF BEING OUT OF THE LABOR FORCE

Having children has a negative effect on women’s wages, but not men’s, and the penalty remains

after controlling for the length of the leave and other characteristics [Staff and Mortimer, 2012].

The wage penalty could be because of a loss of human capital due to the time spent away from

the labor market but if so, men and women would be equally affected by taking the same

amount of parental leave, which is not the case. Another explanation of the penalty could

be statistical discrimination, with employers promoting men more than women in terms of

wages and advancement [Benard and Correll, 2010]. Since mothers more than fathers take the

initial parental leave associated with having a child, this also affects the amount of unpaid

work the parents perform at home and the pattern of which parents divide temporary parental

leave when the child is sick later [Forssell, 2002, Försäkringskassan, 2013]. Knowing this, it

may be rational for the employer to discriminate against women, knowing that they on average

7

Page 9: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

will spend less time at work than men. In contrast to the punishment that women experience

after becoming mothers, fathers seem to rather be rewarded for having children; with wages

increasing after having a child [Benard and Correll, 2010]. This can be compared to the wage

premium of married compared to single men, perhaps suggesting that being married and having

children signal responsibility [Chun and Lee, 2001].

However, men and women taking out the same amount of parental leave are not equally

affected. Assuming that men and women, conditioning on a set of characteristics, have the

same potential outcomes, being out of the labor force should have the same impact on all

individuals independent on gender. Furthermore, the loss of human capital should be the same

for a given time period independent on what the time out is devoted to, i.e. taking parental leave

should not cause a different loss in human capital than taking a leave for other non-educational

or work-related reasons. Albrecht et al. [Albrecht et al., 1999] studied this in Sweden in the

nineties, by comparing the effect of different types of career interruptions on wages to estimate

the specific effect of parental leave. The results suggested that women’s labor market outcomes

were seemingly unaffected by taking parental leave, whereas men experienced a negative effect.

This either suggests that men taking parental leave sends a negative signal to employers whereas

it’s expected of women, or that women are already being statistically discriminated against in

terms of expectations of parental leave, so that they have been penalized already before taking

the leave.

2.4 THE FAMILY GAP – ESTIMATING THE WAGE IMPACT OF CHILDREN

One of the first and most eminent researchers on the family gap is Jane Waldfogel [Waldfogel, 1998,

Waldfogel, 1997]. In a paper from 1997, she examines the evolution of the family gap in the US

using the National Longitudinal Survey of Young Women between 1968 and 1988. While high-

lighting that the gender wage gap has decreased over time as a result of higher labor force par-

ticipation and education among women, Waldfogel discuss the persistent tendency of women

having less labor market experience than comparable men. Likewise, the wage differential be-

tween women with and without children – the family gap – appears to be rather constant over

time. In order to account for the difference in labor market experience, she uses a measure of

“potential labor market experience” in her estimates, as well as controlling for both parental

and marital status. She finds that even after controlling for actual labor market experience and

other characteristics, women with children earn lower wages than women without children.

8

Page 10: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Additionally, after performing some heterogeneity tests, Waldfogel suggests that the wage dif-

ferential cannot be attributed to differences in unobserved characteristics between women with

and without children. The results ultimately imply that women suffer a family penalty when

having children that persists when controlling for labor market choices and personal attributes.

Building on the previous paper, Waldfogel continued studying the matter in mainly the US

and Britain. When the first few studies were published just before the millennium, she argued

that although the gender wage gap had decreased in the United States in the previous decades,

the family gap had actually widened. One reason for this may, according to Waldfogel, be

that several policies have been implemented to encourage and legalize equal pay, but fewer on

maternity and childcare. The direction in which maternity leave affects wage is according to

most research ambiguous. On the one hand, maternity leave enable new mothers who would

otherwise have remained out of the labor force to come back to their previous job without

a decrease in wage. On the other hand, some mothers likely stay at home longer than they

otherwise would have. However, previous studies suggest that the main impact of maternity

leave is that more women choose to return to the labor force after childbirth. In her paper

“Understanding the “Family Gap” in Pay for Women with Children” [Waldfogel, 1998], she

compares the US to some Scandinavian countries including Sweden and Denmark. She argues

that as opposed to the US, which at the time had a family gap of about 10-15%, neither Denmark

nor Sweden has any noteworthy family gap. What is interesting in this context is that Kleven

et al. [Kleven et al., 2018], has published a study showing that Denmark now has a family gap.

Whereas the gender gap was lower in Denmark than in the US before the millennium, as shown

by Waldfogel, the levels are now much more similar.

Kleven et al. use an event study approach based on the birth of the first child. The identi-

fication strategy relies on the assumption that although the decision of having children is not

random, the timing of the first child is. Their results show that men and women follow the same

trends in labor market outcomes prior to childbirth. However, directly following the birth of

the first child, women fall behind men and the trend for women never recovers. In addition to

studying the impact of children on wages, Kleven et al. also investigate the incentives among

women to switch to “family friendly” jobs after forming a family. Family friendly jobs are

described as firms with more flexible characteristics and a larger share of women employed.

Self selection into more family friendly work environments have been discussed as a possible

determinant of the gender wage gap in previous studies [Goldin, 2014], but this is the first study

9

Page 11: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

to show how the segregation is associated to having children. Ultimately, the results of Kleven

et al. [Kleven et al., 2018] imply that the wage differential caused by having children, i.e. the

family gap, has evolved over time in Denmark and is presently responsible for the remainder

of the unexplained gender wage gap.

Another recent study on the family gap is one by Lundborg et al. [Lundborg et al., 2017].

In their paper “Can Women Have Children and a Career”, they use an IV approach with IVF

treatments. The identification strategy is based on the assumption that the chance of having a

successful IVF treatment is random and not correlated with previous labor market outcomes.

Individuals that have all received IVF treatments, but where only some has succeeded, are then

compared in terms of labor market outcomes. Thus, it is possible to interpret the difference in

labor market outcomes between parents and non-parents as the causal effect of having children.

Lundborg et al. find that having children has large negative impacts on women’s labor market

outcomes, both in the short and the long term. The results suggest that women choosing to work

in lower paid jobs when they become mothers can explain a large portion of the wage decrease.

They also suggest that although women receiving IVF treatments likely differ to other women,

the results are likely generalizable to all women.

Lastly, Angelov et al. [Angelov et al., 2016] investigate the income and wage trajectories

for Swedish couples before and after parenthood in their paper “Parenthood and the Gender

Gap in Pay”. The approach is based on comparing the within-couple gaps in wage before

and after having children. They find that the effects on wages are substantially negative and

long lasting for women. 15 years after the birth of the first child, the wage gap between men

and women have increased by 32 and 10 percentage points. They provide some evidence of

explanations for this in terms of comparative advantages of working at home and in the labor

market.

10

Page 12: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

3 THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

This section provides a theoretical framework for the following analysis. First, a short overview

of labor supply theory is presented. Then an introduction to human capital theory follows, and

lastly signaling theory and self-selection theory are presented.

3.1 LABOR SUPPLY THEORY

Simplified, the labor market consists of firms and workers; firms accounting for the demand

and workers accounting for the supply of labor. On a market with free competition, wages

are determined by setting supply equal to demand [Borjas, 2016]. In the textbook example,

wage represents marginal productivity of the worker and since there is variation in marginal

productivity, there is variation in wages. Wages and labor market outcomes are thus determined

by several factors affecting the skills and marginal productivity of workers. These consist of

observable factors as educational level and working experience, and unobservable factors as

effort. [Mankiw and Taylor, 2017]

Workers account for the supply of labor in the economy, offering their time and produc-

tivity to firms at a cost. The labor supply varies between demographic groups and over time

[Borjas, 2016]. The traditional framework for analyzing labor supply is called the “neoclassi-

cal model of labor-leisure choice”, in which any worker has a fixed number of hours a day to

allocate between labor and leisure. The allocation depends on the individual’s preferences, as

taking time for leisure has an alternative cost in terms of the wage that individual could have

earned if the time was instead spent on labor. There is thus a trade-off between labor and leisure

(ibid.).

Gary Becker [Becker, 1965] formalized a model for explaining household’s choice of al-

location of time. In his unitary model, households are both the consumers and workers and

they gain utility from consuming and means of consuming, though disutility, from working.

This model has later been criticized in that it assumed that couples have joint preferences and

that there is no “work” in the household. In terms of labor supply, the work performed in the

household is then grouped with consumption of labor, although the labor choice may be that of

working in the labor force or in the household [Johnson, 2010]. Becker suggested however that

as one person’s consumption depends on the others time spent working in the joint model, it is

rational that women perform more of the work in the household and men in the labor market.

11

Page 13: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

This argument is based on women’s potential earnings being lower than the potential earnings

of men traditionally.

The labor supply of women has gradually increased in the past few decades, but is still

below that of men in most countries. Much of this increase has been explained as a result

of changing attitudes towards women working, as well as increased wages for women and

thus higher incentives to work [Gardiner, 1997, Bertrand, 2011]. As the potential earnings of

women increase, Becker’s argument of the rational choice in households no longer holds, but

the division of house and labor market work is still determined by gender to a large extent

[Gardiner, 1997].

In recent work, Blau and Kahn [Blau and Kahn, 2013] examine how the labor supply of

women is affected by the presence of more family-friendly policies. They build on the exist-

ing theory by suggesting that these policies can affect women’s labor supply in two opposite

directions: on the one hand by making it possible for women to combine work and family, they

facilitate labor market entry for women who would have otherwise remained at home. On the

other hand, long, paid parental leave likely causes even career-oriented women to stay at home

longer than they otherwise would have. Likewise, women with a strong labor market commit-

ment may have incentives to adjust their labor supply to part-time and possible positions of

lower levels.

3.2 HUMAN CAPITAL THEORY

Gary Becker [Becker, 1962] formalized the first modern human capital theory. Human capital

refers to the stock of skills an individual has, and so human capital investments refer primarily

to investments made in an individual’s skills and productivity, but it can also include invest-

ments in physical and emotional health. These are factors that increase individual productivity

and subsequently wage. There are different types of human capital investments, where the

main investments are usually seen as education and on-the-job training. On the job training

can be either of a general character or firm specific. General training increases the individual’s

productivity regardless of workplace, whereas specific training increases productivity on the

current job, but cannot be transferred to a different job or sector. There are also other types

of human capital investments such as acquiring knowledge of the labor market and economic

system and increasing emotional and physical health. Previous research has found that higher

levels of human capital are positively related to earnings. Likewise, skills are negatively corre-

12

Page 14: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

lated with unemployment. When trying to measure a causal effect of human capital on wages,

there are two main problems. Firstly, human capital can normally not be directly observed, so

instead some proxy is used as a measure of human capital, normally years of schooling and

labor market experience. Secondly, there is a potential ability bias. It could be argued that

this should not cause any trouble, as human capital is the stock of skills and knowledge of an

individual. However, there is a positive correlation between being more able and the amount

of education and training, which may attribute an excessive amount of credit to investments in

human capital.

Mincer and Ofek [Mincer and Ofek, 1982] developed Becker’s model further. By inves-

tigating how wages respond to career interruptions, they showed that human capital must be

maintained or it depreciates. In their paper from 1982, they find that wage rates are lower at

reentry for individuals that have left the labor market and increases with the length of the in-

terruption. These results supported the theory of human capital depreciation, as a break from

the labor force would cause a decrease in the human capital stock because of a loss of specific

on-the-job investments, but it would be constant regardless of the length of the interruption,

unless human capital depreciated over time. When “leavers” reenter the labor market, they thus

enter with lower wages than when they left. However, Mincer and Ofek found that there was a

rapid initial wage growth for the leavers once they came back. Because human capital is less

costly to reconstruct once lost than to construct new human capital, they explain this as leavers

having decreased their human capital stock, they are less productive and earn lower wages.

The alternative cost for investing in human capital is thus lower for leavers than for those who

stayed, and so when reentering the labor market they make large investments in their human

capital.

According to this theory, being out of the labor force does not only keep human capital

from increasing, but even reduces it – human capital is an investment that must be maintained

continuously or it depreciates [Mincer and Ofek, 1982]. This implies that taking leave to care

for children would cause a decrease in human capital for the individual taking leave, thus

implying that a decrease in earnings following the leave could be a consequence of the decrease

in productivity. However, if this is the case, then men and women would be affected equally by

the leave and the effect of the leave should be the same as the effect of any other leave, which

is not the case [Albrecht et al., 1999].

13

Page 15: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

3.3 SIGNALING THEORY AND STATISTICAL DISCRIMINATION

As opposed to the human capital theory, which assumes that investing in schooling increases

actual productivity, signaling theory suggests that schooling does not increase productivity per

se. Signaling theory instead proposes that education signals productivity to employers and that

it is that signal that is reflected in offered wages. [Spence, 1973]

The signaling theory builds on the assumption that the costs of investing in education, sig-

naling costs, are negatively correlated with productivity capability. If this assumption does not

hold, then all individuals would invest the same amount so that they are not distinguishable in

their signal. [Spence, 1973]

Signals are thus characteristics that employers use as an implication for true productivity. In

this context, the signaling of being a parent rather than that of education is of interest. This can

be either positive or negative and likely differs between men and women. Gender should not

be a signal in terms of productivity per se, since the same amount of education should signal

the same amount of productivity, regardless of sex [Spence, 1973]. There are however other

aspects of the signal of gender, which have been brought up earlier in the literature review.

Given that women on average, conditional on education and previous labor market outcomes,

tend to take on more family responsibility and care for children once becoming a parent, simply

being a woman sends a signal of a lower average labor market commitment of the group. As the

employer cannot distinguish which individuals will be more committed, being a woman may

cause employers to statistically discriminate and invest more in men. [Bielby and Baron, 1986]

Previous research indicates that whereas women with children are perceived as less compe-

tent and engaged in work, men with children are considered to be loyal and reliable.

[Benard and Correll, 2010]

3.4 SELF-SELECTION THEORY

Human capital assumes that different amounts of human capital stock affect wages, and as-

sumes that human capital can be seen as homogeneous. Self-selection theory criticizes this

homogeneity assumption that all the variation in wages can be explained by different amounts

of human capital. Self-selection theory instead suggests that there are different kinds of human

capital, with different pay-offs in terms of wage [Polachek, 1981]. The self-selection theory

introduces occupational choice and its importance for wages. Since occupational patterns dif-

14

Page 16: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

fer with demographic groups, the main interest in this context is occupational sorting based

on gender. The basic assumption of the model assumes that the goal for all individuals is to

maximize lifetime earnings. For different occupations, there are different levels of atrophy.

Atrophy is defined as “the loss in potential lifetime earnings from labor force intermittency”. It

is thus the wage decrease caused by skills not being continuously used. The smaller the loss in

wage because of an interruption, the lower is the atrophy [Polachek, 1981]. In terms of gender

differences, the model assumes that men and women have the same characteristics on average

and differ only in expected lifetime labor force participation. It follows that gender differences

in occupation can be attributed to the differences in lifetime labor force participation. Because

atrophy differs between jobs, it is rational for individuals to choose an occupation that maxi-

mizes lifetime earnings given the expected dropout rates from the labor force. Since women

have lower labor force participation than men, it may be rational for men and women to choose

different occupational paths, and for women to choose occupations with lower atrophy and thus

lower wages [Polachek, 1981]. Traditionally, women tend to take more parental leave – both

directly following childbirth and later temporary to care for sick children. Knowing that they

will likely have career interruptions, it is rational for women to invest in education and choose

occupations for which the wage decrease following an interruption is low, even if the initial

wage is lower than for other occupations. A related but different possible explanation of occu-

pational sex segregation could be because of differing preferences between men and women.

Assuming that some women and men are family-oriented and therefore willing to forego higher

earnings in exchange for employment that provide better work-life balance, this would suggest

that there are self-selection effects [Gash, 2009]. The self-selection theory thus provides some

alternative explanation of the family penalty in wages. Family friendly employment is charac-

terized by jobs with a more flexible working environment and, in more recent research, a higher

share of women in the workplace. [Gash, 2009]

15

Page 17: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

4 DATA

This section presents the data used to conduct the analysis. It also contains some variable

descriptions in addition to the descriptive statistics.

4.1 DATA SOURCE

This paper uses the Swedish level-of-living surveys (SLLS) collected by the Swedish institute

for social research at Stockholm University. The survey has been carried out in six different

waves, the first one in 1968 and the most recent one in 2010.

The original aim of SLLS, beginning with the first wave in 1968, was to survey a random

sample of approximately one per mille of the Swedish population in ages 15-74. In the latest

wave however, the sample consisted of about 6000 individuals in ages 18-75, with a response

rate of 72%.

Throughout the years, the survey has developed. After the three first waves, further di-

mensions were introduced in the 1991 survey. Family events, information on each individuals

partner and the composition of labor market interruptions were all included in the question-

naire. For the purpose of this study, all available waves are used in order to examine how the

family and gender gaps have developed over time. The additional variables for the later waves

regarding children and parental leave are of particular interest for this study. Unfortunately,

no suitable proxy is available for similar estimation for the earlier waves, and for this reason

parental leave outtake is not included in the analysis.

There are however great advantages of using the SLLS. Because many of the dimensions in

the survey are the same over time, this presents a rare opportunity of comparability over time.

Likewise, because of the extensive time period for which SLLS has been carried out, it provides

historical data for completely comparable variables. Furthermore, SLLS contain hourly wage

data for all survey years, which is unusual for data from the time of the first few surveys years.

This is also one of the main advantages of the SLLS data, as previous research has suggested

that the use of monthly or yearly labor earnings may bias the results somewhat.

The data is conducted on mainly different population samples at each point in time, thus

constituting repeated cross-sectional data on multiple dimensions. About a thousand individu-

als have however been surveyed in each wave, thus compiling panel data for these individuals.

Although panel data would be preferable in order to answer the research question, the panel

16

Page 18: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

data sample is not large enough for the purpose of the thesis, so the approach uses the repeated

cross sections for all individuals instead. This also means that there is no possibility of estimat-

ing causal effects in terms of the research question using the available data. Therefore, the aim

of this thesis is to give a descriptive analysis of the associations between cause and effect.

4.2 VARIABLE DESCRIPTION

Table 1 shows the variable descriptions of the variables of interest in the following analysis.

Table 1: Variable Description

Variable Description

Gross hourly wage Gross hourly wage, collected for each wave. The wage is expressed in SEK and is

based on several wage variables in the SLLS data, including bonuses and an average

of weekly hours worked. All wage variables adjusted with CPI, using 2010 as the

index year and thereafter logged.

Yearly labor earnings The variable is constructed by using the gross hourly wage and then multiplying it by

hours worked in the previous year.

Employed Dummy variable encoded as 1 if the individual had a positive number of hours worked

in the year before the survey and 0 otherwise.

Married Dummy variable with levels [ Married, Not married ]. Generated by using the variable

"Civil state according to the interview" and with "Married" as the reference. For the

survey years of 2000 and 2010, couples living together but not being married are also

indicated as married.

Age Age in years by the survey year. Calculated by using survey year and year of birth.

The sample has been limited to only include observations aged between 25-65 years at

the time of the survey.

Education Total number of years of education. Observations with more than 20 years of education

has been removed from the sample.

Experience Total number of years employed in the labor force. Individuals with more than 50

years of experience have been removed from the sample.

Children Dummy variable with levels [0,1], where 1 indicates having children and 0 indicates

not having children. The variable was generated by first adding the number of children

living at home and the number of children not living at home.

Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics for the observations with a positive gross hourly

17

Page 19: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

wage, i.e. the subsample used for the main analysis. Because the dependent variable used

in the main analysis is gross hourly wage, all observations with no value in that variable has

been removed from the analysis. This is mainly because the Swedish Level of Living Survey

(SLLS) cover ages 18-74, which indicates that removing observations lacking wage data likely

decreases the age span of the analysis somewhat further than the initial restriction of 25-65

years old at the time of the survey. This is also confirmed in the descriptive statistics, where the

mean age is higher than for the full samples.

The descriptive statistics imply that the women in the sample have on average lower educa-

tion and experience in the first few waves, but catches up to men in more recent year, and even

exceed men in terms of education for the last three waves. This is in line with previous studies.

Tables 3 and 4 give the same descriptive statistics of means but grouped on individuals with

and without children.

Table 2: Sample Means: All Individuals

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women

Log wage 4.53 4.24 4.71 4.46 4.67 4.50 4.71 4.55 4.88 4.76 5.10 5.0

(0.342) (0.396) (0.279) (0.294) (0.240) (0.258) (0.235) (0.216) (0.227) (0.214) (0.302) (0.237)

Age 42.7 43.2 41.7 42.0 41.8 41.4 41.6 42.2 42.2 43.4 43.9 45.2

(11.2) (10.8) (11.4) (11.2) (11.1) (10.7) (10.8) (10.6) (11.0) (10.5) (11.1) (10.9)

Experience 25.9 17.7 24.1 17.0 23.4 17.4 22.1 18.8 21.9 20.8 22.8 22.2

(12.1) (10.9) (12.6) (10.6) (12.6) (10.3) (12.1) (10.1) (12.4) (10.8) (12.3) (11.7)

Education 8.22 8.35 9.59 9.40 10.3 10.2 11.3 11.4 12.2 12.5 13.3 13.8

(2.57) (2.75) (3.34) (3.01) (3.31) (3.18) (3.08) (2.96) (2.91) (2.91) (2.67) (2.80)

Share with children 74.1% 72.6% 76.1% 79.6% 75.5% 81.2% 70.7% 80.6% 70.3% 78.8% 71.2% 81.2%

No. of observations 1376 879 1390 1035 1385 1347 1350 1438 1211 1288 1074 1062

18

Page 20: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Table 3: Sample Means: Individuals With Children

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women

Log wage 4.56 4.22 4.73 4.45 4.69 4.50 4.74 4.55 4.90 4.76 5.14 5.0

(0.297) (0.394) (0.280) (0.310) (0.238) (0.268) (0.233) (0.215) (0.227) (0.212) (0.264) (0.238)

Age 43.7 44.5 42.9 42.8 43.4 42.3 44.2 43.8 44.9 45.1 46.4 46.8

(10.8) (9.98) (11.0) (10.8) (10.6) (10.2) (9.93) (9.95) (10.1) (9.82) (10.1) (10.2)

Experience 27.2 17.0 25.5 16.4 25.4 17.5 25.0 19.7 24.8 22.2 25.4 23.8

(11.5) (10.3) (12.0) (9.90) (12.0) (9.72) (11.3) (9.53) (11.5) (10.1) (11.4) (11.1)

Education 8.10 8.08 9.44 9.18 10.0 10.0 11.1 11.2 12.0 12.3 13.2 13.6

(2.45) (2.67) (3.32) (2.96) (3.30) (3.17) (3.15) (2.90) (2.94) (2.85) (2.70) (2.75)

No. of observations 1019 638 1057 824 1045 1094 955 1158 851 1015 765 868

Table 4: Sample Means: Individuals Without Children

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women

Log wage 4.43 4.29 4.65 4.50 4.62 4.54 4.64 4.57 4.83 4.77 5.02 5.0

(0.434) (0.399) (0.268) (0.218) (0.239) (0.206) (0.226) (0.220) (0.219) (0.221) (0.368) (0.235)

Age 40.0 39.9 37.9 39.1 36.8 37.5 35.3 35.7 35.7 37.3 37.8 37.7

(11.9) (12.3) (11.9) (12.5) (11.0) (11.6) (10.1) (10.6) (10.3) (10.7) (11.2) (11.0)

Experience 22.3 19.6 19.6 19.0 17.4 17.4 15.2 15.1 14.8 15.7 16.2 15.3

(13.1) (12.2) (13.1) (12.6) (12.6) (12.4) (11.0) (11.4) (11.5) (11.6) (12.0) (11.7)

Education 8.55 9.05 10.1 10.2 11.1 11.1 11.8 12.6 12.6 13.5 13.6 14.9

(2.86) (2.82) (3.37) (3.06) (3.20) (3.08) (2.86) (2.94) (2.80) (2.90) (2.59) (2.79)

No. of observations 357 241 333 211 340 253 395 280 360 273 309 194

19

Page 21: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Lastly, table 5 shows the difference in means for men and women, with and without chil-

dren. The values are calculated by subtracting the means of individuals without children from

the means of individuals with children.

Table 5: Difference in Means for Men and Women, With and Without Children

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Has Children: Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women

∆ Log wage 0.13 −0.07 0.08 −0.05 0.07 −0.04 0.1 −0.02 0.07 −0.01 0.12 0

∆ Age 3.7 4.6 5.0 3.7 6.6 4.8 8.9 8.1 9.5 7.8 8.6 9.1

∆ Experience 4.9 −2.6 5.9 −2.6 8.0 0.1 9.8 4.6 10.0 6.5 9.2 8.5

∆ Education −0.45 −0.97 −0.66 −1.02 −1.1 −1.1 −0.7 −1.4 −0.6 −1.2 −0.4 −1.3

∆ Observations 662 397 724 613 705 841 560 878 491 742 456 674

A few notes are of interest here. Firstly, when only looking at sample means, men and

women with children show the opposite difference in wages compared to men and women

without children. Whereas men with children have higher mean wages than men without chil-

dren, women with children have lower mean wages than women without children. The indi-

viduals with children are also older than individuals without children. Secondly, for the four

most recent survey years, both men and women with children have more experience than all

individuals without children. Lastly, regarding the fact that women in more recent years exceed

men in terms of education when looking at all individuals, i.e. with and without children, it is

interesting to note that this difference is mainly driven by women without children.

The opposite directions of the wage differences for men and women with children could

possible be a result of the "child premium" for men discussed in previous literature, as opposed

to the child penalty for women. The difference in wages are not likely explained by differences

in years of education, as women with children have almost the same or slighlty longer edcu-

cation than men. There could however be differences in the type or level of education, which

I do not have access to for the whole period. The difference in experience could however be a

determinant, if the women’s experience is lower because they take on more responsibility for

the family and household once they become mothers.

20

Page 22: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

5 EMPIRICAL METHOD

This section is outlined as followed: first, there is a description of the method used to retrieve

the results for the analysis. Second, a base model is specified for the family and gender gaps.

Third, an alternative measure of wage is introduced to the model as the dependent variable and

lastly, a model for investigating differences in employment probability is presented.

5.1 ORDINARY LEAST SQUARES

Ideally, we would have had a large longitudinal dataset where fertility was randomly assigned

to individuals. That way, we would have comparable individuals where children would cause

the only difference. A second best option would have been to have access to the same type

of data, but instead using an event study to see how wages respond to children shortly after

having a child and a few years after. However, as this requires a large set of panel data, it is

unfortunately not feasible for this paper. For this reason, the main method for the analysis is

using a simple ordinary least squares.

Although the method in this paper may not be the best for the research question, I believe

it is the most suitable one given the prerequisites. There are however other perks of using the

Swedish Level of Living Surveys (SLLS). As previously discussed, the SLLS data contain vari-

ables that have been the same for all waves, and are thus completely comparable. Furthermore,

it has the very unique perk of containing hourly wage data for all samples. This is especially

unusual, as many studies in the area do not have access to hourly wage data for earlier years,

although it has been argued that it is the most reliable wage measure when analyzing the gender

wage gap.

5.2 FAMILY AND GENDER GAP IN EACH WAVE

For each of the six waves, a base specification is used, including only the variables of interest in

order to get a picture of the uncontrolled family and gender wage gaps. The base specification

is:

ln(GHWi,t) = β1Womani,t + β2Woman× Childreni,t + β3Childreni,t + εi,t, (1)

21

Page 23: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

where the dependent variable is logged gross hourly wages. To make the monetary difference

comparable across the survey years, the wage variable has been adjusted to the consumer price

index (CPI) with 2010 as the index year. The variable of interest is “Children”, which is a

dummy variable that equals 1 if the individual has at least one child and 0 otherwise. It is

also of interest to examine and identify whether the effect of children on wages change with

the number of children. The initial idea was therefore to compare how different numbers of

children as well as having children of different ages affect wages differently. Unluckely, in-

cluding all of the population parameters decreased the sample size of each subset to greatly.

Therefore, only the binary variable indicating children or no children is included. Furthermore,

the base specification includes an interaction term between being female and having children.

The interaction term estimates the additional effect of having children for women.

In a modification of the base specification, a wage equation in an adjusted form of the one

proposed by Mincer will be used. The specification including all controls is:

ln(GHWi,t) = β0 + β1Womani,t + β2Woman× Childreni,t + β3Childreni,t

+ β4Educationi,t + β5Experiencei,t + β6Experience2i,t + β7Agei,t

+ β8Age2i,t + β9Marriedi,t + εi,t

(2)

The additional variables in this specification are Education, Experience, Age and Marriage

status. Education is total number of years in education and Experience is total number of

years employed, thus years of experience. The experience variable is included both linearly

and squared, since existing literature in the area suggests that wage increases non-linearly with

experience. The specification also includes a dummy-variable for being married. The reason

for including civil status is because previous research has shown that women’s wages tend to

decrease when they get married, whereas an increase have been found for men. This increase

in wages for married men has been referred to as a “marriage premium”. Again, the initial

aim was to include different types of civil status such as single, divorced or widowed as well

as married. However, in order for the sample population to remain of reasonable size, only an

indicator of being married or not being married is included. However, for the waves in 2000

and 2010, being in a couple and living together will also be indicated as married in the variable

for Married, as it has become a common alternative to marriage in more recent years. Lastly,

22

Page 24: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

the variable Age is included both linearly and squared, as proposed by previous research in the

area [Waldfogel, 1997].

The identification strategy of the method is selection on observables. By controlling for

the observable characteristics, we make the assumption that all individuals are absolutely com-

parable except for the fact that some of them have children and some do not. Thus having

children is as if randomly allocated and the only differing effect on wage between individuals

will be that of being a parent. This is however a rather strong assumption, as parenthood is for

the most part a conscious choice. Individuals making the choice of becoming parents likely

differ in unobserved characteristics from those not making the choice of parenthood. Although

this problem remains when only comparing women with and without children as well, the as-

sumption is that there are less unobserved characteristics differing between women in general

than between women and men. Thus the chance of estimating the wage impact of children

specifically likely increases when only comparing women that are parents with women who

are not. However, this is also the main reason for why the aim of the analysis is to estimate the

associations between variables, rather than the causal effects.

Only variables that are available for all of the waves will be included in the specification.

Unfortunately, this means leaving out some of the most important variables in the later survey

years, such as total number of months on parental leave and number of parental leave weeks

per child.

5.3 INTERPRETATION OF ESTIMATES

It is of importance to note that because of the nature of the data and the research question at

hand, no causal inference can be drawn from the results. Instead, coefficients of the parame-

ters are interpreted as associations − or correlations − between the variables of interest. The

potential causes for the effects are discussed further on but without the possibility to draw any

conclusions about the causality.

5.4 LABOR EARNINGS AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE

When studying the gender wage gap as well as the family gap, it is of interest to examine how

wages differ independent of labor supply. That is, to ensure we are looking at the wage gap

and not the difference in labor supply, we need hourly wages. However, as this is not feasible

in many cases when studying longer time periods or using old register data, many studies have

23

Page 25: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

instead had to rely on monthly wage or yearly labor earnings. I argue that one of the main

contributions of this paper is the fact that hourly wage data is available for all waves, i.e. a

time period of about 40 years. In order to investigate the implication this might have on the

results, I perform a similar analysis to the main one, but using yearly labor earnings instead of

hourly wages. The variable is constructed by multiplying the wage variable used in the main

analysis with hours worked last year. Although this is a rough measure that likely has some

measurement error in the dependent variable, it should provide some evidence of the differing

results obtained by different measures of wage. Since the same independent variables are used

as in the main analysis, only the potential measurement error in the dependent variable should

have a potential of posing a problem. If that is the case, the estimates will simply suffer from

attenuation bias, i.e. they will be less precise yet unbiased.

5.5 PROBABILITY OF BEING IN EMPLOYMENT

In addition to the main analysis using logged gross hourly wages as the dependent variable as

well as an alternative wage measure, a supplementary test of probability of being employed

will also be analyzed. The dependent variable used for these regressions is constructed as a

binary variable taking the value of one if the individual has a positive amount of working hours

in the year before the survey, and zero otherwise. For the purpose of this part of the analysis,

a linear probability model will be used in order to estimate the likelihood of being in the labor

force, given the presented control variables.

When estimating the probability for a binary dependent variable, it could be argued that a

logistic probability model (logit) should be used instead of a linear probability model (LPM).

This is because the linear probability model allows for probabilities below 0 and above 1, which

is obviously not possible theoretically. A second issue with the LPM is that probabilities are

linear in the independent variables. However, the estimates of LPM and logit are often similar,

and because the independent variables of interest in this case are binary as well, the issue of

probabilities being linear in the independent variables does not pose a problem in this context.

Furthermore, the LPM has more intuitive interpretations, and so for the purpose of this analysis

it poses a more suitable option.

Because the labor supply affects the wages in terms of labor market outcomes such as

advancement, it is of interest to examine if it differs between groups and if so, what it is that

determines the difference.

24

Page 26: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

6 RESULTS

This section starts by a presentation of the results obtained from the analysis of the evolution

of the family and gender gaps, using two different model specifications. Furthermore, results

on earnings are presented and lastly on the probability of being employed.

6.1 FAMILY AND GENDER GAP

The results from the base specification with no controls are shown in table 6. This specification

includes only gender, having children and an interaction between being female and having

children, as these are the variables of interest. The interaction term between being a woman

and having children is included in the model in order to estimate both the gender wage gap and

the family gap in the same regression. The gender wage gap is thus the coefficient for gender,

and the family gap is the difference between the gender coefficient and the two coefficients

indicating the effects of children. The effect of being a woman, that is the estimate of the gender

wage gap, is negative for all waves but with estimates decreasing in magnitude. This implies

that when not including controls in the model, the estimated gender wage gap has decreased

over the time period studied. The estimate for 2010 is not significant, but previous estimates

suggest that the gender wage gap is emerging when not including controls. The coefficient

for the variable indicating having children is positive but decreasing between the first and the

last wave. Similarly, the estimate for the additional effect of being female with children is

decreasing between the first and last survey year, but with some fluctuations across years.

25

Page 27: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Table 6: Specification With No ControlsDependent variable:

log(as.numeric(GRHW))1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Woman −0.139∗∗∗ −0.150∗∗∗ −0.085∗∗∗ −0.073∗∗∗ −0.057∗∗∗ −0.028(0.030) (0.025) (0.021) (0.017) (0.018) (0.025)

Woman × Children −0.202∗∗∗ −0.132∗∗∗ −0.106∗∗∗ −0.118∗∗∗ −0.090∗∗∗ −0.111∗∗∗

(0.035) (0.028) (0.023) (0.020) (0.020) (0.028)

Children 0.126∗∗∗ 0.086∗∗∗ 0.065∗∗∗ 0.097∗∗∗ 0.073∗∗∗ 0.114∗∗∗

(0.022) (0.018) (0.015) (0.013) (0.014) (0.018)

Constant 4.434∗∗∗ 4.648∗∗∗ 4.622∗∗∗ 4.641∗∗∗ 4.831∗∗∗ 5.024∗∗∗

(0.019) (0.016) (0.013) (0.011) (0.012) (0.015)

Observations 2,255 2,425 2,732 2,788 2,499 2,136R2 0.144 0.169 0.109 0.127 0.082 0.055Adjusted R2 0.143 0.168 0.108 0.126 0.081 0.053Residual Std. Error 0.361 (df = 2251) 0.284 (df = 2421) 0.248 (df = 2728) 0.224 (df = 2784) 0.219 (df = 2495) 0.269 (df = 2132)F Statistic 126.393∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2251)164.413∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2421)110.968∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2728)134.485∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2784)74.679∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2495)41.152∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2132)Note: ∗p<0.1; ∗∗p<0.05; ∗∗∗p<0.01

26

Page 28: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

When instead using estimates from the regressions including controls that can be found in

table 7, figure 1 show the gender wage gap in terms of estimated gross hourly wage when in-

cluding the effects of children, and controlling for observable covariates. Men are the reference

group, plotted as the intercept line at 0.

Figure 1: Gender Wage Gap Accounting for Effects of Children

-0.25

-0.20

-0.15

-0.10

-0.05

0.00

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Survey Year

Est

imat

eof

Hou

rly

Wag

e(l

og)

Women

Error Bars Represent 95 % Standard Errors For Estimates

Estimated Wage Difference

The figure shows an overall decrease of the gender wage gap, with women still falling

below men but less and less so. This is in line with the findings of previous studies. However,

the difference between men and women is larger in magnitude compared to official statistics

as well as previous studies; the magnitude is similar to what is usually found for the explained

gender wage gap. This could possibly be explained by the fact that when accounting for the

effects of children, the wage estimate for men becomes higher and the wage estimate for women

becomes lower. This can be seen more clearly in figure 2, where the family gaps for men as

well as women are graphed.

27

Page 29: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Figure 2: Family Wage Gaps

-0.2

-0.1

0.0

0.1

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Survey Year

Est

imat

eof

Hou

rly

Wag

e(l

og)

Men with Children Women with Children Women without Children

Error Bars Represent 95 % Standard Errors For Estimates

Estimated Wage Difference

What is of interest in this graph is the family gap for men and women respectively, i.e. the

difference between men with and without children as well as the difference between women

with and without children. Men with children are plotted as the top, two-dashed line and

men without children are plotted as the intercept line. The effect of children for men is thus

seemingly positive, with fathers having higher wage estimates than non-fathers for all the years

studied. The difference is however decreasing; the positive effect of children on the wages of

men is about half the magnitude in 2010 as compared to 1968.

The trend in the family gap for women shows a rather different pattern. Women encounter

the opposite effect of having children from that of men, namely a negative one. This is in line

with previous research and the notion that men with children benefit from a "child premium" as

opposed to the "child penalty" faced by women. Furthermore, whereas the family gap for men

has decreased steadily over time, the family gap for women has remained on a level of between

3-5%. Although the difference may not seem severe, it is of great economic significance if

women with children have constantly lower wages than women without children.

It is also worth noting that a number of reforms were implemented in the 70’s in order to

increase the possibility of combining family and work, yet there is no significant drop in the

family gap for the subsequent years.

28

Page 30: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

The full results of the main analysis are found in table 7. The regressions include controls

for experience, education, age and marriage status. These findings, graphed above in figures

1 and 2 show that the gender wage gap (excluding the effect of children) has consistently

decreased since the first observed wave in 1968 and until the last observed wave in 2010.

When taking all control variables into account, the remaining gender wage gap is estimated to

be about 16% in 1968, and "only" about 8% in 2010. The estimates are significantly different

from zero and effects are of both statistic and economic significance. The additional effect of

children for women is negative for all survey years but overall decreasing. However, the full

effect for women with children is retrieved by adding all of the estimates for which [Woman=1]

and [Children=1], and so the decreasing positive effect of children for men and women with

children has to be taken into account as well. Still, the complete wage difference for women

with children compared to men without children has decreased from about −21% in 1968 till

about −11% in 2010. However, the wage difference for women without children compared

to men without children has decreased from about −17% in 1968 till about −8% in 2010,

implying no significant differences in the family gap − it seemingly persists.

29

Page 31: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Table 7: Specification With ControlsDependent variable:

Gross Hourly Wage (log)

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Woman −0.165∗∗∗ −0.160∗∗∗ −0.083∗∗∗ −0.096∗∗∗ −0.092∗∗∗ −0.079∗∗∗

(0.026) (0.022) (0.019) (0.016) (0.016) (0.023)

Woman × Children −0.114∗∗∗ −0.077∗∗∗ −0.075∗∗∗ −0.070∗∗∗ −0.045∗∗ −0.053∗∗

(0.032) (0.026) (0.022) (0.019) (0.019) (0.026)

Children 0.093∗∗∗ 0.066∗∗∗ 0.049∗∗∗ 0.051∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗ 0.042∗∗

(0.021) (0.017) (0.016) (0.014) (0.014) (0.019)

Education 0.069∗∗∗ 0.046∗∗∗ 0.034∗∗∗ 0.033∗∗∗ 0.032∗∗∗ 0.040∗∗∗

(0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)

Experience 0.020∗∗∗ 0.013∗∗∗ 0.014∗∗∗ 0.015∗∗∗ 0.018∗∗∗ 0.012∗∗∗

(0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003)

Experience2 −0.0003∗∗∗ −0.0002∗∗∗ −0.0002∗∗∗ −0.0002∗∗∗ −0.0002∗∗∗ −0.00005(0.0001) (0.00004) (0.00004) (0.00004) (0.00004) (0.0001)

Age 0.002 0.014∗∗∗ 0.006 0.002 −0.008 0.013∗

(0.006) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005) (0.007)

Age2 −0.00004 −0.0001∗∗∗ −0.0001 −0.00003 0.00003 −0.0002∗∗∗(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.00005) (0.0001) (0.0001)

Not married −0.078∗∗∗ −0.022 0.001 −0.017∗ −0.029∗∗∗ −0.068∗∗∗

(0.018) (0.014) (0.011) (0.010) (0.010) (0.013)

Constant 3.635∗∗∗ 3.764∗∗∗ 3.940∗∗∗ 4.085∗∗∗ 4.484∗∗∗ 4.176∗∗∗

(0.124) (0.093) (0.089) (0.080) (0.094) (0.128)

Observations 2,255 2,423 2,732 2,788 2,499 2,136R2 0.356 0.366 0.254 0.286 0.222 0.198Adjusted R2 0.354 0.363 0.252 0.284 0.219 0.195Residual Std. Error 0.314 (df = 2245) 0.249 (df = 2413) 0.227 (df = 2722) 0.202 (df = 2778) 0.202 (df = 2489) 0.249 (df = 2126)F Statistic 137.977∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2245)154.471∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2413)103.055∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2722)123.592∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2778)78.774∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2489)58.399∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2126)Note: ∗p<0.1; ∗∗p<0.05; ∗∗∗p<0.01

30

Page 32: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

6.2 YEARLY EARNINGS

When using yearly labor earnings as the dependent variable, the results differ from the main

analysis of the paper. Because the yearly earnings is a variable generated by multiplying hourly

wage with hours worked, the idea is to get a rough measure of the yearly labor earnings. The

comparison between the results is however not entirely intuitive, as the unit of measure differ

between wage for one hour worked and wage for a year of hours worked. The results without

control variables can be found in table 8 and the results including control variables are shown

in table 9.

When only including the variables of interest but no other controls, the gender wage gap

shows no obvious trend, although the gap is overall diminishing over time. The additional effect

of being a woman with children is negative for all survey years, but decreasing over time. The

coefficient for having children is positive here as well, but with no obvious downward trend

over time.

31

Page 33: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Table 8: Earnings Without ControlsDependent variable:Yearly Earnings (log)

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Woman −1,461.749∗∗∗ −1,103.100∗∗∗ −1,152.277∗∗∗ −848.012∗∗∗ −487.015∗∗ −690.807∗∗∗

(205.832) (213.915) (190.255) (175.900) (207.372) (222.403)

Woman × Children −2,920.007∗∗∗ −2,622.924∗∗∗ −1,859.235∗∗∗ −1,311.648∗∗∗ −1,127.744∗∗∗ −730.316∗∗∗

(240.766) (241.917) (214.574) (201.356) (239.741) (252.390)

Children 777.012∗∗∗ 669.545∗∗∗ 372.979∗∗∗ 523.389∗∗∗ 760.384∗∗∗ 879.122∗∗∗

(151.979) (153.328) (143.219) (134.970) (161.994) (164.632)

Constant 9,564.397∗∗∗ 9,290.048∗∗∗ 9,295.185∗∗∗ 9,262.472∗∗∗ 9,207.666∗∗∗ 9,752.764∗∗∗

(130.615) (133.687) (124.376) (113.715) (135.574) (139.702)

Observations 2,237 2,364 2,724 2,742 2,437 2,076R2 0.366 0.325 0.269 0.159 0.071 0.072Adjusted R2 0.365 0.324 0.268 0.158 0.070 0.071Residual Std. Error 2,464.447 (df = 2233) 2,402.646 (df = 2360) 2,290.005 (df = 2720) 2,225.454 (df = 2738) 2,554.418 (df = 2433) 2,379.040 (df = 2072)F Statistic 429.627∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2233) 378.479∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2360) 332.802∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2720) 172.889∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2738) 62.091∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2433) 53.875∗∗∗ (df = 3; 2072)Note: ∗p<0.1; ∗∗p<0.05; ∗∗∗p<0.01

32

Page 34: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Table 9: Earnings With ControlsDependent variable:Yearly Earnings (log)

Woman −1,411.536∗∗∗ −1,068.750∗∗∗ −1,095.468∗∗∗ −853.544∗∗∗ −650.615∗∗∗ −817.837∗∗∗

(196.043) (206.863) (183.474) (169.721) (200.085) (216.672)

Woman × Children −2,268.349∗∗∗ −2,044.933∗∗∗ −1,595.060∗∗∗ −1,066.511∗∗∗ −812.790∗∗∗ −505.651∗∗

(238.640) (242.330) (212.896) (199.935) (233.549) (246.481)

Children 892.696∗∗∗ 527.411∗∗∗ 284.333∗ 201.247 192.608 375.526∗∗(158.468) (161.565) (152.131) (147.619) (172.130) (176.709)

Education 189.045∗∗∗ 162.385∗∗∗ 125.330∗∗∗ 116.183∗∗∗ 149.976∗∗∗ 172.041∗∗∗(20.226) (16.639) (15.258) (15.483) (20.563) (21.586)

Experience 249.407∗∗∗ 180.483∗∗∗ 220.388∗∗∗ 249.135∗∗∗ 315.983∗∗∗ 196.005∗∗∗(21.467) (21.044) (21.437) (23.107) (28.067) (29.472)

Experience2 −3.826∗∗∗ −2.422∗∗∗ −3.517∗∗∗ −3.845∗∗∗ −4.240∗∗∗ −2.175∗∗∗

(0.436) (0.417) (0.418) (0.441) (0.529) (0.562)

Age −164.764∗∗∗ −12.109 −21.136 −70.930 −230.664∗∗∗ 50.853(48.279) (46.148) (47.497) (47.491) (62.722) (63.863)

Age2 1.571∗∗∗ −0.202 −0.095 0.291 1.715∗∗ −1.266∗

(0.559) (0.529) (0.540) (0.524) (0.690) (0.698)

Not married 679.498∗∗∗ 271.582∗∗ 376.358∗∗∗ 133.489 −104.559 −119.774(134.222) (131.958) (110.975) (106.631) (123.008) (126.830)

Constant 8,439.090∗∗∗ 6,118.721∗∗∗ 6,374.781∗∗∗ 7,480.348∗∗∗ 10,058.480∗∗∗ 5,197.390∗∗∗(923.300) (872.359) (868.192) (847.548) (1,145.732) (1,211.519)

Observations 2,237 2,362 2,724 2,742 2,437 2,076R2 0.434 0.375 0.324 0.227 0.151 0.139Adjusted R2 0.432 0.373 0.322 0.225 0.148 0.135Residual Std. Error 2,331.324 (df = 2227) 2,315.340 (df = 2352) 2,203.468 (df = 2714) 2,135.944 (df = 2732) 2,445.340 (df = 2427) 2,295.022 (df = 2066)F Statistic 189.842∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2227) 156.732∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2352) 144.690∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2714) 89.260∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2732) 47.906∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2427) 37.129∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2066)Note: ∗p<0.1; ∗∗p<0.05; ∗∗∗p<0.01

33

Page 35: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

When instead including the same control variables as in the analysis of hourly wages, the

results show similar patterns in the gender wage gap. In order to simplify the comparison of

the two approaches in terms of wage measures, the results from table 9 are graphed in figures

3 and 4, in the same way as the hourly wage difference was graphed in the previous section.

The gender gap in earnings is graphed in figure 3, again with men as the reference group,

plotted as the intercept line at zero. The gender gap is seemingly greater when using yearly

labor earnings as a wage measure than when using hourly wages. This is because the logged

hourly wage only measures the effect of being female and having children on the hourly wage,

and this effect is negative. The total income effect for women with children can however be

decomposed into two parts: the effect on the hourly wage and the negative effect on the number

of hours worked. When taking both effects into account, we obtain the total yearly income

effect, which is greater than each effect separately.

Figure 3: Gender Gap in Earnings

-0.25

-0.20

-0.15

-0.10

-0.05

0.00

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Survey Year

Est

imat

eof

Yea

rly

Ear

nin

gs(l

og)

Women

Error Bars Represent 95 % Standard Errors For Estimates

Estimated Difference in Earnings

Lastly, the results from table 9 showing the family gaps are graphed in figure 4. Once again,

men without children are graphed as the intercept line and are thus the reference group. The

family gap for men is the difference between men with children, the two-dashed line at the top,

and men without children, i.e. the intercept line. The results for men are somewhat similar

when using logged yearly earnings as the dependent variable to the results of the main analysis

34

Page 36: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

using logged hourly wages. Men with children do not have yearly labor earnings much higher

than men without children, compared to the analysis using hourly wage. This is likely because

men do not change their labor supply to the same extent as women when they have children and

so there is only one effect at work, namely that on wages, and so there are no greater differences

in results between the different wage measures. The child premium for men seems to decrease

over time, causing the family gap for men to emerge. This is similar to what was found in

the main analysis. There is however a slight increase for the year 2010, but over the full time

period studied the family gap seemingly decreases for men.

Regarding the family gap for women however, the results differ significantly from those

in the analysis using logged hourly wages as the dependent variable. According to the results

using yearly labor earnings as the dependent variable, the family gap for women has decreased

considerably over time. These findings suggest that the decrease in the gender wage gap can

likely be explained by the increase in yearly earnings for women with children, since the gap

between men and women without children has remained at a more or less constant level for the

past few decades. Following the analysis of the hourly wage, these findings are likely the result

of women with children working a lot more than previously rather than an increase in wages

for women with children. This would suggest that it is the wage rather than the labor supply in

terms of hours worked that is driving the family gap for women.

35

Page 37: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Figure 4: Family Gaps in Earnings

-3000

-2000

-1000

0

1000

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Survey Year

Est

imat

eof

Yea

rly

Ear

nin

gs(l

og)

Men with Children Women with Children Women without Children

Error Bars Represent 95 % Standard Errors For Estimates

Estimated Difference in Earnings

6.3 PROBABILITY OF BEING IN EMPLOYMENT

Figure 5 show the share of the population that are employed. The figure to the left shows the

difference between men and women over time, and the figure to the right show the difference

between women with and without children over time. In both cases, the differences between

the groups seem to have decreased over time, at least when only looking at the raw differences

and not controlling for any covariates. It should be noted that a significant drop in the share

employed can be seen for the survey year of 1974. Although there are no obvious outliers

observed in the data, it is possible that this is because of a measurement error.

36

Page 38: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Figure 5: Share of Population in Employment

0.70

0.75

0.80

0.85

0.90

0.95

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Survey Year

Proportion

Employed

Men Women

0.7

0.8

0.9

1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Survey Year

Proportion

Employed

Children No Children

For the analysis of the probability of being in the labor force, a binary variable has been

constructed and used as the dependent variable. As previously discussed in the section Empir-

ical Method, the variable was constructed by using hours worked in the year before the survey,

encoding individuals with positive hours worked as 1, and those with zero or no value in hours

worked as 0. The results can be found in table 10 in appendix. Unfortunately for the purpose

of the analysis, the subsample of individuals not in the labor force is too small to obtain sig-

nificant results for most of the waves, and so it is not possible to draw any conclusions of the

implications of what determines the probability of being employed over time. Furthermore, the

effects are not only statistically insignificant, but they are also quite small.

6.4 DISCUSSION

The estimated gender wage gap including controls is larger when accounting for the effect of

children. As previously discussed, the reason for this is that the wage estimate for men is higher

when including the effect of children, whereas the opposite is true for women. Although the

evolution of the gap follow a similar trend as found in previous research, the magnitude of the

difference is greater and the decreasing trend over time is not as steep.

The family gap for men suggests that men with children benefit from a "child premium",

37

Page 39: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

as opposed to the child penalty suffered by women. This is in line with previous research

suggesting that whereas women with children are perceived as less dedicated to work, men

with children are seen as more reliable.

A different, or additional, possibility is that there is selection in the type of men and women

that have children. Assume for example that men that are successful in the labor market are

also successful in the "marriage market". Social skills are important in the search for a spouse,

but it is also important in the labor market. Assuming that men with good social skills have a

better chance of finding a spouse and having children, then the positive effect of children on

wage for men could at least partly be explained by selection.

Selection could be an explanation for women as well, but rather self-selection. If women

that knows that they will eventually have children makes different educational and career

choices than women who do not plan to have children, then self-selection into less demand-

ing and thus lower paid jobs could explain part of the effect. Because of the expectations and

the expected labor force participation of women, it is rational to make decisions that maximize

lifetime-earnings given for example career interruptions, as discussed in the theory section.

When using yearly labor earnings instead of hourly wages, the estimated gender wage gap

is even greater. When looking at the family gaps in terms of labor earnings, it seems that

women with children has either had a significant increase in wages or in labor supply over time.

Judging by the results obtained in the main analysis with hourly wages, I would say it is the

latter rather than the former. The difference in the results obtained highlights the importance of

using hourly wages when studying wage gaps, as the alternative approach does not distinguish

between the effects on wage and on labor supply.

The minimal number of observations lacking employment in data did not suffice for ob-

taining significant results, unfortunately. Since the findings of the wage and earnings analyses

differed, it would have been interesting to get a clearer picture of what it is that determines the

probability of employment. Previous literature suggest that women tend to work part time to

a greater extent than men, in which case they would be indicated as employed in this analysis,

even though the labor supply likely differs significantly.

38

Page 40: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

7 CONCLUSION

In this study, the evolution of the gender and family wage gaps in Sweden are addressed. Pre-

vious research has mainly focused on the gender wage gap, and by controlling for children

rather than investigating the heterogeneous effects thereof. The aim of this study was to pro-

vide a broader picture of how the differences in wages caused by children have evolved over

time, both between men and women but also between individuals of the same gender with and

without children.

The results from the main analysis of the gender wage gap suggest a decrease in the dif-

ference between men and women, which is in line with previous research. The difference is

however greater when accounting for the effects of children, and does not decline as rapidly.

The family gap is seemingly decreasing for men with and without children, whereas the family

gap between women with and without children is seemingly rather constant over time. Al-

though the family gap has been found to be of a greater magnitude in previous research as well

as for other countries, the findings of this study show that the difference is persistent in Sweden

as well.

When using yearly labor earnings as the dependent variable instead of hourly wages, the

gender gap is of yet greater magnitude. Because the measure is constructed by multiplying

hourly wage with hours worked, women having a lower labor supply than men likely explain

the increased difference.

In terms of the family gap when studying yearly labor earnings, the findings of this sub-

analysis is similar for men, but entirely different for women. Whereas the main analysis suggest

that the family gap for women has remained on a somewhat constant level, the family gap for

women in terms of yearly earnings has seemingly decreased significantly to the extent that it

has almost disappeared in 2010. Because of the way that the earnings variable is constructed,

the decrease of the family gap is likely caused by women with children working far more hours

now than in the first few waves. This would also suggest that the family gap for women cannot

be explained by differences in labor supply. However, as I do not have access to neither the

sector of work nor the field or level of education, it is possible that women with children differ

in unobserved characteristics from women without children, causing them to make different

educational and occupational choices.

The findings of this study suggest that there is still a persistent, yet rather small, family gap

39

Page 41: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

for women. The aim of the thesis was to answer the research question of how the family gap

has evolved over time in Sweden and how it can be related to the gender wage gap. While

the gender wage gap is decreasing over time, the family gap for women remains at a persistent

level. Although the setting for the paper does not allow me to make any causal interpretations,

I believe that the findings of this paper supports the notion that a greater fraction of the gender

wage gap can be explained by effects of having children now than previously.

The generous parental benefit system in Sweden is often seen as something admirable, yet it

is associated with several challenges. The benefit system was introduced with the aim that more

women would have the possibility of combining work with family. However, if the generosity

of the system causes women to make different educational and labor market choices in order

to care for children, then employers may statistically discriminate towards women with the

expectation that they will be out of the labor market more than men, for example by taking

more temporary parental leave to care for sick children. One major challenge with the parental

leave system is thus that although it makes it possible to combine work and family, it may cause

some women to have more and longer career interruptions. In combination with the subsequent

risk of statistical discrimination, these are possible mechanisms that make women fall behind

men.

The former argument suggests that although the parental leave benefit system as well as

gender equality policies have been introduced to decrease the differences between men and

women, there are still concrete effects that arise from taking the responsibility for children.

Because the effect of having children is seemingly constant over time for women, the results

from this study imply that specific policies are needed to prevent and battle the difference in

labor market outcomes that arise because of the differing effects from caring for children.

The family gap between women in general does likely conceal heterogeneous effects with

differing magnitudes with respect to level of education as well as the sector of employment.

Although this was not possible to investigate with the data available and within the scope for

this thesis, it would be interesting to test this hypothesis in future research. It would clarify

further which groups among women that are most affected by having children and thereby how

policies in this area should be directed to be most efficient.

40

Page 42: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

REFERENCES

[Albrecht et al., 1999] Albrecht, J. W., Edin, P.-A., Sundström, M., and Vroman, S. B. (1999).

Career interruptions and subsequent earnings: A reexamination using swedish data. The

Journal of Human Resources, 34(2):294–311.

[Angelov et al., 2016] Angelov, N., Johansson, P., and Lindahl, E. (2016). Parenthood and the

gender gap in pay. Journal of Labor Economics, 34(3):545–579.

[Becker, 1962] Becker, G. S. (1962). Investment in human capital: A theoretical analysis.

Journal of Political Economy, 70(5):9–49.

[Becker, 1965] Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. The Economic Journal,

75(299):493–517.

[Benard and Correll, 2010] Benard, S. and Correll, S. J. (2010). Normative discrimination and

the motherhood penalty. Gender and Society, 24(5):616–646.

[Bertrand, 2011] Bertrand, M. (2011). New perspectives on gender. Handbook of Labor Eco-

nomics, 4.

[Bielby and Baron, 1986] Bielby, W. T. and Baron, J. N. (1986). Men and women at work: Sex

segregation and statistical discrimination. American Journal of Sociology, 91(4):759–799.

[Blau and Kahn, 2013] Blau, F. D. and Kahn, L. M. (2013). Female Labor Supply: Why is the

US Falling Behind? National Bureau of Economic Research, S.l.

[Blau and Kahn, 2017] Blau, F. D. and Kahn, L. M. (2017). The gender wage gap: Extent,

trends, and explanations. Journal of Economic Literature, 55(3):789–865.

[Borjas, 2016] Borjas, G. J. (2016). Labor economics. New York; McGraw-Hill Eduation;, 7.,

international edition.

[Chun and Lee, 2001] Chun, H. and Lee, I. (2001). Why do married men earn more: produc-

tivity or marriage selection? Economic Inquiry, 39(2):307–319.

[Forssell, 2002] Forssell, J. (2002). Hushållsproduktion och föräldraledighet: att städa, tvätta

och laga mat - med och utan barn. PhD thesis.

41

Page 43: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

[Försäkringskassan, 2013] Försäkringskassan (2013). Ojämställd arbetsbörda: Föräl-

draledighetens betydelse för fördelning av betalt och obetalt arbete.

[Försäkringskassan, 2018] Försäkringskassan (2018). Förändringar inom socialförsäkrings-

och bidragsområdena 1968-01-01—2018-09-01.

[Gardiner, 1997] Gardiner, J. (1997). Gender, care and economics. Macmillan, Basingstoke.

[Gash, 2009] Gash, V. (2009). Sacrificing their careers for their families? an analysis of the

penalty to motherhood in europe. Social Indicators Research, 93(3):569–586.

[Goldin, 2014] Goldin, C. (2014). A grand gender convergence: Its last chapter. The American

economic review, 104(4):1091;1119;–1119.

[Johnson, 2010] Johnson, R. D. (2010). Extracting a revised labor supply theory from becker’s

model of the household. Journal of Socio-Economics, 39(2):241–250.

[Kleven et al., 2018] Kleven, H., Landais, C., and Egholt Søgaard, J. (2018). Children and

gender inequality: Evidence from denmark. NBER Working paper 24219.

[Lundborg et al., 2017] Lundborg, P., Plug, E., and Rasmussen, A. (2017). Can women have

children and a career? iv evidence from ivf treatments. American Economic Review,

107(6):1611–1637.

[Mankiw and Taylor, 2017] Mankiw, G. N. and Taylor, M. P. (2017). Economics. Cengage

Learning, Andover, fourth edition.

[Mincer and Ofek, 1982] Mincer, J. and Ofek, H. (1982). Interrupted work careers: Deprecia-

tion and restoration of human capital. The Journal of Human Resources, 17(1):3–24.

[Polachek, 1981] Polachek, S. W. (1981). Occupational self-selection: A human capital ap-

proach to sex differences in occupational structure. The Review of Economics and Statistics,

63(1):60–69.

[SCB, 2018] SCB (2018). Women and men in sweden. facts and figures 2018.

[Spence, 1973] Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,

87(3):355–374.

42

Page 44: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

[Staff and Mortimer, 2012] Staff, J. and Mortimer, J. T. (2012). Explaining the motherhood

wage penalty during the early occupational career. Demography, 49(1):1–21.

[Waldfogel, 1997] Waldfogel, J. (1997). The effect of children on women’s wages. American

Sociological Review, 62(2):209–217.

[Waldfogel, 1998] Waldfogel, J. (1998). Understanding the ’family gap’ in pay for women

with children. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(1):137.

43

Page 45: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

LIST OF FIGURES

1 Gender Wage Gap Accounting for Effects of Children . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

2 Family Wage Gaps . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

3 Gender Gap in Earnings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

4 Family Gaps in Earnings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36

5 Share of Population in Employment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

44

Page 46: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

LIST OF TABLES

1 Variable Description . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

2 Sample Means: All Individuals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

3 Sample Means: Individuals With Children . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

4 Sample Means: Individuals Without Children . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

5 Difference in Means for Men and Women, With and Without Children . . . . . 20

6 Specification With No Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

7 Specification With Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

8 Earnings Without Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

9 Earnings With Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

10 Probability Model with Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

45

Page 47: WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE? A S - DiVA portaluu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1333030/FULLTEXT01.pdfDecomposing the gender wage gap into an explained and an unexplained part, the explained

Table 10: Probability Model with ControlsDependent variable:

Employed1968 1974 1981 1991 2000 2010

Woman 0.035∗ 0.015 0.027 −0.019 −0.023 0.034∗∗(0.020) (0.024) (0.019) (0.022) (0.024) (0.015)

Woman × Children −0.002 0.057∗∗ 0.046∗∗ 0.107∗∗∗ 0.089∗∗∗ 0.009(0.024) (0.027) (0.022) (0.026) (0.028) (0.018)

Children −0.025 −0.047∗∗ 0.0003 −0.057∗∗∗ −0.061∗∗∗ −0.007(0.016) (0.019) (0.016) (0.019) (0.021) (0.013)

Education 0.004∗∗ 0.015∗∗∗ 0.014∗∗∗ 0.016∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗ 0.001(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001)

Experience 0.004∗ 0.047∗∗∗ 0.041∗∗∗ 0.014∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗ −0.004∗∗

(0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002)

Experience2 −0.0001∗∗ −0.001∗∗∗ −0.001∗∗∗ 0.00000 −0.0002∗∗∗ 0.0001∗∗(0.00004) (0.00004) (0.00003) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.00004)

Age −0.012∗∗ −0.050∗∗∗ −0.049∗∗∗ 0.012∗∗ 0.003 0.008∗

(0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.006) (0.006) (0.004)

Age2 0.0001∗∗ 0.0005∗∗∗ 0.0004∗∗∗ −0.0003∗∗∗ −0.0003∗∗∗ −0.0001∗

(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.00005) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.00005)

Not married −0.005 −0.013 −0.010 −0.034∗∗ −0.033∗∗ −0.004(0.014) (0.015) (0.012) (0.014) (0.015) (0.009)

Constant 1.109∗∗∗ 1.402∗∗∗ 1.483∗∗∗ 0.524∗∗∗ 0.469∗∗∗ 0.788∗∗∗

(0.093) (0.093) (0.082) (0.103) (0.121) (0.084)

Observations 2,857 3,831 3,803 3,728 3,776 2,714R2 0.013 0.371 0.428 0.109 0.147 0.015Adjusted R2 0.010 0.370 0.427 0.106 0.145 0.011Residual Std. Error 0.260 (df = 2847) 0.334 (df = 3821) 0.271 (df = 3793) 0.322 (df = 3718) 0.363 (df = 3766) 0.189 (df = 2704)F Statistic 4.118∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2847) 250.590∗∗∗ (df = 9; 3821) 315.779∗∗∗ (df = 9; 3793) 50.308∗∗∗ (df = 9; 3718) 72.258∗∗∗ (df = 9; 3766) 4.470∗∗∗ (df = 9; 2704)Note: ∗p<0.1; ∗∗p<0.05; ∗∗∗p<0.01

46