when it cannot get better or worse: the asymmetric impact of …mbrandt/papers/published/... ·...

41
When It Cannot Get Better or Worse: The Asymmetric Impact of Good and Bad News on Bond Returns in Expansions and Recessions * Alessandro Beber Michael W. Brandt Amsterdam Business School Fuqua School of Business University of Amsterdam Duke University and NBER Abstract We examine empirically the response of bond returns and their volatility to good and bad macroeconomic news in economic expansions and recessions. We find that the information content of macroeconomic announcements is most important when it contains bad news for bond returns in expansions and, to a lesser extent, when it contains good news for bond returns in contractions. In particular, we observe the strongest bond market response to bad news in the release of non-farm payrolls in expansions. During recessions, inflation news are relatively more important when they contain good news. We also document that macroeconomic news impacts substantially the volatility of bond returns at all maturities by increasing jump intensities and by altering the distribution of the jump size. While a large proportion of employment news results in a jump in expansions at all maturities, inflation news becomes more important in recessions and particularly at medium maturities. * We thank two anonymous referees, Andrew Ang, Jean Boivin, Jean-Pierre Danthine, Joost Driessen, Marc Giannoni, Pascal St-Amour, Josef Zechner (the editor) and seminar participants at Cass Business School, Columbia University, and University of Lausanne for helpful comments. We also thank Clara Vega and Informa Global Markets for providing some of the announcement data.

Upload: others

Post on 01-Feb-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • When It Cannot Get Better or Worse:

    The Asymmetric Impact of Good and Bad News

    on Bond Returns in Expansions and Recessions∗

    Alessandro Beber Michael W. Brandt

    Amsterdam Business School Fuqua School of BusinessUniversity of Amsterdam Duke University

    and NBER

    Abstract

    We examine empirically the response of bond returns and their volatility togood and bad macroeconomic news in economic expansions and recessions. Wefind that the information content of macroeconomic announcements is mostimportant when it contains bad news for bond returns in expansions and, toa lesser extent, when it contains good news for bond returns in contractions. Inparticular, we observe the strongest bond market response to bad news in therelease of non-farm payrolls in expansions. During recessions, inflation news arerelatively more important when they contain good news. We also document thatmacroeconomic news impacts substantially the volatility of bond returns at allmaturities by increasing jump intensities and by altering the distribution of thejump size. While a large proportion of employment news results in a jump inexpansions at all maturities, inflation news becomes more important in recessionsand particularly at medium maturities.

    ∗We thank two anonymous referees, Andrew Ang, Jean Boivin, Jean-Pierre Danthine, Joost Driessen,Marc Giannoni, Pascal St-Amour, Josef Zechner (the editor) and seminar participants at Cass BusinessSchool, Columbia University, and University of Lausanne for helpful comments. We also thank Clara Vegaand Informa Global Markets for providing some of the announcement data.

  • 1. Introduction

    Investors receive every day a wealth of information, ranging from news about corporate

    cash flows to news about the economic fundamentals. Investors process this information

    and update their expectations of the economy’s future growth, inflation, and discount rates,

    thus affecting asset prices. However, some macroeconomic information is more relevant than

    other, and the same information can have a different importance at different stages in the

    business cycle. Moreover, the same information can have a different impact on different

    assets and, even for the same asset, a different impact on returns than on volatility.

    This paper studies these different aspects of information jointly. In particular, we examine

    empirically the response of U.S. Treasury bond returns and their volatility to good and bad

    macroeconomic news in economic expansions and recessions. We will uncover interesting

    asymmetric effects when investors and monetary authorities are confronted with different

    type of news at different times.

    The design of our analysis is straightforward. We first study the effect of macroeconomic

    announcements on bond returns using a regression specification that allows for an asymmetric

    impact of good and bad macroeconomic news in different phases of the business cycle. We

    find that the information content of the announcements is most important for bond returns

    when it contains bad news for the bond market in expansions and, to a lesser extent, good

    news for the bond market in contractions. We observe the strongest bond market response

    to bad news in the release of non-farm payrolls during expansionary periods. This effect is

    apparent at all maturities. During recessionary periods, inflation news are relatively more

    important when they contain good news and particularly at short maturities.

    Motivated by the strong economic significance of these results, we then formulate and

    estimate a statistical model of bond returns incorporating jumps that depend explicitly

    on the timing and information content of scheduled macroeconomic news. The estimates

    of this model show that macroeconomic news has a substantial impact on bond volatility

    by increasing jump intensities and by affecting the distributions of the jump size. The

    relation between macroeconomic news and jumps, however, depends on the combination

    of the announcement type, the maturity of the bond, and the phase of the business cycle.

    Specifically, the proportion of releases resulting in a jump decreases dramatically for short

    maturities and is generally lower in recessions. Jumps on announcement days are associated

    predominantly with non-farm payroll releases, but inflation news becomes relatively more

    associated with jumps in recessions and at medium maturities.

    The estimation of the model of bond returns with jumps confirms the findings from the

    regression analysis that the response of the term structure to the macroeconomic release

    1

  • depends on the multifaceted aspects of information. More importantly, given the rich

    structure of the model that we hypothesize, the estimates provide a detailed account of

    jump dynamics as the conduit through which macroeconomic information enters the bond

    market.

    A number of papers investigate the effect of macroeconomic announcements on

    financial markets along different lines. Fleming and Remolona (1999) study the effect of

    macroeconomic news on bond returns, while Jones, Lamont and Lumsdaine (1998) document

    the effect on bond volatility.1 However, they do not condition their analysis on different

    phases of the business cycle and they do not disentangle the effect of good versus bad news.

    Recent work by Boyd, Hu and Jagannathan (2005) investigates the response of stock and

    bond market returns to civilian unemployment rate news in expansions and recessions, but

    they do not consider the release of non-farm payrolls and, most importantly, they do not

    separate the effect of good versus bad news.2 Andersen, Bollerslev, Diebold and Vega (2003)

    show that the responses of foreign exchange rates to macroeconomic news vary with the

    sign of the news. However, their sample period is all in an expansion phase of the business

    cycle. The contribution of our paper is thus to show that the effect of macroeconomic

    announcements on bond market returns and volatility depends jointly on the type of news,

    on the sign of the news, and on the phase of the business cycle.

    Recent theoretical work describes the asymmetric response of stock prices to news in

    good or bad times (e.g., Veronesi, 1999). The driving mechanism is the agents’ uncertainty

    about the state of the economy and the associated learning process. Specifically, investors

    believe that the economy follows a two-state regime-switching process, with low and high

    states corresponding to recessions and expansions. Agents solve a signal extraction problem

    to determine the probability of being in the high state. Suppose that investors believe

    that the high state almost surely prevails. Then if bad news arrives, two things happen:

    expected future asset values decrease, and second, state risk increases. Risk-averse investors

    require additional returns for bearing this additional risk; hence they require an additional

    discount on the asset price, which drops by more than it would in a present-value model.

    In the bond market, the response to macroeconomic news is peculiar for the key role of

    the monetary authority that has direct effects on short-term yields and some influence on

    1Other papers document the effect of macroeconomic news on bond returns or volatility for differentsample periods, announcement sets, underlying assets. Recent work by Christiansen and Ranaldo (2007)and Brenner, Pasquariello, and Subrahmanyam (2006) focus instead on the effect of macroeconomic newson comovements of stock and bond markets.

    2Andersen, Bollerslev, Diebold and Vega (2007) study a more comprehensive set of macroeconomicannouncements with respect to Boyd, Hu, and Jagannathan (2005), but their sample period includes onlyone short recession. Furthermore, they also do not separate the effect of good versus bad news.

    2

  • long-term yields via inflation expectations. We can think, for example, of an asymmetric

    Fed reaction function by which, at the beginning of an expansion with low rates, positive

    economic news raise the likelihood of future increases in the target rate by more than bad

    news raise the likelihood of future decreases in the target rate. In this setting, the response

    of bond prices to macroeconomic news depends critically on the content of the news and on

    the phase of the business cycle.

    The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we describe the announcements and bond

    market data. In Section 3, we present the results of our regression specification. In Section

    4, we describe and estimate the jump model. Section 5 concludes.

    2. Data

    Our data has a number of key features that allow us to address our research questions.

    First, it covers a long sample period including several expansions and recessions. Second,

    it contains detailed information on the timing and content of macroeconomic news. Lastly,

    our bond market data is observed at a daily frequency, so that we can precisely relate asset

    prices to macroeconomic releases. This section describes the announcement data, the data

    characterizing the stages of the business cycle, and the U.S. Treasury bond market data.

    2.1. Survey and Announcement Data

    We obtain data on the dates, release times, actual released figures, and median forecasts for

    five of the most important U.S. macroeconomic information releases from Money Market

    Services (MMS) and Informa Global Markets, covering the period from February 1980

    through December 2003. MMS conducts a survey of about 40 money market managers

    on the Friday of the week before the release of each economic indicator. MMS reports the

    median forecast from the survey, which is made available to the market and the business

    press immediately after the survey is taken. The availability of a direct measure of the

    expected release – the median forecast – allows us to avoid potential biases of using time-

    series econometric models to infer market expectations.

    We consider a set of four key announcements describing inflation dynamics by the

    consumer price index (CPI) and the producer price index (PPI) and labor market

    dynamics by the civilian unemployment rate (CUR) and non-farm payrolls (NFP).3 These

    3In a previous version of this paper, we have also considered the announcements of the Federal OpenMarket Committee federal funds target rate (FOMC) to describe the conditions of the money market.However, we have not found any significant result and thus we have decided to leave it out. The FOMCcould be irrelevant in our setting because of the potential inaccuracy of the MMS forecast of FOMC withrespect to market based forecasts (e.g., Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) use the prices of the Federal FundsFutures). Another reason could be that changes of the target rate occur sometimes outside the scheduledeight meetings per year.

    3

  • announcements are released widely and virtually instantaneously at a precise scheduled

    time. The statistical agencies impose lock-up conditions to ensure that the information

    is not released to the public before the scheduled time (see Fleming and Remolona, 1999).

    These announcements are all timed at 8:30am ET and are monthly. A majority of the

    announcements occur on a Friday and the employment report (CUR and NFP) is normally

    the first government information release concerning economic activity in a given month.

    Panel A of Table 1 describes in more detail the macroeconomic announcements in our sample.

    Several studies have examined the accuracy of the MMS forecasts. We find strong

    evidence that the MMS median forecast has predictive ability for the actual release. We

    also find that the median forecast is usually an unbiased predictor. We observe only one

    case in which the median forecast is not an efficient predictor. This happens whenever the

    prediction of the CPI, which is always announced after the PPI, is collected before the PPI

    actual release. In these few cases, the market learns about inflation from the PPI release and

    the median forecast of the CPI should take this into account.4 We thus obtain the expected

    CPI from a regression on the median MMS CPI forecast and the actual PPI release.

    2.2. Expansions and Recessions

    We measure expansions and recessions using the experimental coincident recession index

    (XRI-C) constructed by Stock and Watson (1989) and available for all our sample period.

    The XRI-C is a monthly estimate of the probability that the economy was in a recession in

    that month, constructed using four series of leading indicators such as industrial production,

    real personal income less transfer payments, real manufacturing and trade sales, and total

    employee-hours in non-agricultural establishments. Several papers in the literature used

    XRI-C to measure the state of the economy (e.g., Boyd, Hu, and Jagannathan (2005); Hong,

    Tourous, Valkanov (2007)).

    An important feature of the XRI-C is that it establishes a real-time coincident public

    forecasting record. It is thus different from other indexes constructed by Stock and Watson,

    such as the experimental leading index (XLI) and the experimental recession index (XRI),

    which are based on leading indicators and forecast the growth of the economy in the following

    six months. Furthermore, the XRI-C uses only information that is publicly available

    at a certain point in time. In contrast, the NBER business cycle dates for expansions

    and recessions make use of information that becomes available later. Stock and Watson

    discontinued the publication of the index after the end of our sample, but the Federal

    Reserve Bank of Chicago now publishes a monthly expansion index, the Chicago Fed National

    4We find that in our sample period the actual PPI has strong predictive ability for the actual CPI andthus PPI information is relevant in determining CPI predictions.

    4

  • Activity Index (CFNAI), which is based on an extension of the methodology used to construct

    the original XRI-C. Positive (negative) values of the CFNAI index indicate that the economy

    is expanding above (below) its historical growth trend. For our sample period, the XRI-C

    and the CFNAI index have a large correlation equal to −0.84.Since we aim to describe the different response of the bond markets to macroeconomic

    news according to the perceived state of the economy, we use the XRI-C in our empirical

    analysis. The correlation between a dummy variable reflecting the NBER business cycle

    dating and the XRI-C is equal to 0.78 during the period 1980–2003. It is also interesting to

    note that the economy was in a recession phase, the XRI-C indicator was above 50%, for

    about 15% of the time during our sample period 1980–2003.

    2.3. Futures Data

    We focus on the futures market as opposed to the cash market because futures contracts

    are typically used to speculate on events such as macroeconomic news and because futures

    market prices are not affected by the liquidity biases of the cash market (e.g., the on-the-run

    versus off-the-run spread).5 We obtain daily prices of a set of U.S. Treasury bond futures

    that require delivery of bonds with different maturities. The contracts mature in March,

    June, September, and December. More specifically, we obtain data for the 30-year Treasury

    bond futures (from February 1980 through December 2003), for the 10-year Treasury note

    futures (from June 1982 through December 2003), for the 5-year Treasury note futures (from

    May 1988 through December 2003), and for the 2-year Treasury note futures (from June 1990

    through December 2003) traded at the CBOT. We also obtain data for the 90-day Treasury

    bill futures (from February 1980 to August 2003), traded at the CME.

    In Table 1, Panel B and C, we show summary statistics for daily returns computed on

    the settlement prices of all these futures contracts.

    3. Regression Model

    In this section, we study the effect on bond returns of good and bad macroeconomic news

    in expansions and recessions using a regression model. This is the simplest approach to

    investigate whether there is any news effect and to what extent this effect is asymmetric

    along two dimensions (different type and different times of the news). The regression model

    is unsophisticated and does not suggest a specific mechanism for macroeconomic news to be

    impounded into bond prices.

    3.1. Methodology

    5Other papers studying the effect of macroeconomic news on the bond market have used futures marketprices for the same reasons. See, among others, Ederington and Lee (1993), Bollerslev, Cai and Song (2000),Andersen, Bollerslev, Diebold, and Vega (2007).

    5

  • To gauge the extent to which an announcement contains new information, we construct the

    following standardized measure of surprise:

    Skt =Akt −Xkt

    σk, (1)

    where Akt is the value of the main statistic released in announcement k at time t, Xkt

    denotes the corresponding median survey forecast, and σk is the (unconditional) empirical

    standard deviation of the innovations Akt − Xkt. Standardizing the surprise by σk allowsus to compare the regression coefficients across different announcement types. We allow

    different announcement surprises to have different effects on the bond returns and we also

    allow these effects to be different in expansion versus recession phases. We thus estimate for

    each announcement type the following regression:

    rt,t−1 = αk + βexp,k (1−XRIt) Sk + βrec,kXRItSk + ek, (2)

    where rt,t−1 represents the day-to-day return for each of the Treasury bond futures and XRItis the probability of being in a recession phase at time t as indicated by the value of the

    recession index XRI-C.6

    We further examine whether the announcement effects vary with the sign of the surprise.

    For this, we generalize equation (2) by allowing for different slope coefficients depending on

    the good and bad news as follows:

    rt,t−1 = αk + βGexp,k (1−XRIt) SktGkt + βBexp,k (1−XRIt) SkBkt+ βGrec,kXRItSktGkt + βBrec,kXRItSkBkt + ekt,

    (3)

    where Gkt = 1 and Bkt = 0 if the information released in announcement k at time t is

    good news (for the Treasury market) and Gkt = 0 and Bkt = 1 otherwise. Whether an

    announcement is good or bad news for the bond market is ultimately an empirical question.

    However, to facilitate interpretation and consistency of our results, we define as good (bad)

    news all negative (positive) surprises, as defined in equation (1). It is generally the case in

    our sample that negative (positive) surprises generate positive (negative) bond returns.

    3.2. Results

    Table 2 presents the results of estimating equation (2) on bond returns at five different

    maturities. The importance of allowing for different effects of macroeconomic news in

    6For the announcements considered in this paper, CUR and NFP are always released jointly in theEmployment Report. In this case, we include both the CUR and the NFP surprise in the regression ofequation (2) to isolate the marginal effect of each announcement type.

    6

  • expansions and recessions is apparent. Macroeconomic news matters more in expansions, as

    the statistical significance of the coefficients readily shows. The explanatory power of this

    model with respect to a non state-dependent model is in all cases substantially higher, with

    an average increase in the R2 ranging between 19% for the short-end of the yield curve to a

    31% increase for the long-end (results not tabulated). In most cases, a statistical test rejects

    the restricted model with no state-dependence at least at the 10% significance level.

    This asymmetric effect is striking also economically. For the release of NFP, which is

    generally significant both in good and bad times, the effect of a surprise in expansions is on

    average 30% larger than in recessions.

    Another general result in Table 2 is the negative signs of all the statistically significant

    coefficients, with the exception of the coefficient on the civilian unemployment rate (CUR).

    The release of a higher than expected CPI, NFP, PPI or a lower than expected CUR are all

    bad news for the bond market, since they lead to negative bond returns. These effects are

    most relevant for the release of NFP.

    In particular, our results that employment report surprises matter for bond returns in

    recessions are in contrast with the non-significant findings of Boyd, Hu, and Jagannathan

    (2005). This discrepancy could be due to several reasons. First, our two sample periods

    do not coincide. We study the period 1980 through 2003, whereas Boyd et al. (2005) look

    at 1972 through 2000. About one third of their sample, including the 1973-1975 recession,

    is affected by the U.S. monetary policy of the pre-Volker period, which has been shown

    to respond less strongly to inflation expectations (e.g., Boivin and Giannoni, 2002) and

    to depart from Taylor-type rules (see, Primiceri, 2005). Second, Boyd et al. (2005) focus

    on the release of CUR and ignore the contemporaneous announcement of NFP. The NFP

    release is considered the most relevant of all scheduled macroeconomic announcement for

    bond returns by a number of papers (e.g., Balduzzi, Elton, Green, 2001). Furthermore, since

    the release of the employment report occurs at the same time, failing to control for all the

    news component can affect the results.7 Finally, we measure the expected outcome of the

    macroeconomic release as the median analyst forecast from MMS, as it is now standard in

    the announcement literature. Boyd et al. (2005) use instead an econometric model, which

    is typically estimated using data that were not available in real-time. In contrast, survey

    median forecasts are widely available before the release. Furthermore, survey forecasts seem

    to be more efficient and less biased than econometric models (e.g., Ang et al., 2007), at least

    for inflation forecasting.

    7We rerun our analysis ignoring NFP to have an indication of the importance of this effect for our sample.We find, like Boyd et al. (2005), that the release of the CUR has no significant effect in recessions for bondreturns of the US, TY, FV and TU. We do find a significant effect, however, for TB returns.

    7

  • The results of Table 2 do not allow to disentangle the effect of good and bad news

    in expansions and recessions. We may have reasons to believe, however, in an asymmetric

    response of bond prices in good and bad times. For example, we could think of an asymmetric

    Fed reaction function by which, at the beginning of an expansion with low rates, positive

    economic news raise the likelihood of future increases in the target rate by more than bad

    news raise the likelihood of future decreases in the target rate.

    For this purpose, we estimate the richer specification of equation (3) and present the

    results in Table 3. We observe that the explanatory power of this specification basically

    doubles for the release of the CPI and slightly increases for the employment report and the

    PPI. Accordingly, the restriction that the coefficients on good and bad news are the same in

    expansions and in recessions is always rejected at least at the 5% level for the CPI, is never

    rejected for the PPI, and is rejected in most cases for the release of the employment report.

    However, when the NFP is considered in isolation (separately from the CUR), we always

    reject the restriction of equal coefficients for good and bad news.

    The overwhelming evidence in Table 3 is that bad news is what matters in good times

    and, to a slightly lesser extent, good news is what matters in bad times. When signals of

    overheating of the economy materialize, because of higher than expected releases of CPI or

    NFP with the economy in an expansion phase, bond returns show a negative response at all

    maturities. In contrast, signals of a deteriorating economy in a recession, e.g., the release

    of lower than expected NFP, determine positive bond returns. Bond returns also seem to

    have a positive response to news of a decelerating economy in expansions arising from lower

    than expected NFP or lower than expected PPI. Notice that we defined a negative surprise

    as good news. As a result, all the estimated coefficients on good news are multiplied by

    negative quantities and thus have an opposite effect on bond returns. Finally, news of an

    accelerating economy in recessions do not seem to impact bond returns at any horizon.

    The interpretation of these results and the comparison of the economic significance across

    maturities is more meaningful if we translate the effect of a surprise on returns to the effect

    of a surprise on yields. We map returns into yields using a simple duration adjustment for

    each segment of the yield curve, using the standard formula for the modified duration:

    dP

    P= −DmdY (4)

    dY = −dPP

    /Dm (5)

    where dP/P is the return on the underlying, Dm is the modified MacCauley duration, and dY

    is the change in yields. We obtain the return on the underlying dP/P as the return generated

    8

  • by a one-standard deviation announcement surprise. We then calculate the duration of each

    Treasury futures contract as the modified duration of a deliverable bond with the average

    maturity in the maturity range.8 Using the measure for bond returns suggested above and

    the appropriate modified duration, we obtain a measure of the effect on yields.

    In Figure 1, we use the formula in (4) and the estimates of Table 3 to plot the effect of

    a one standard deviation surprise in CPI, NFP, CUR, and PPI on bond yields at different

    maturities. The upper plot shows that in good times the effect on yields of bad news is

    greatest at the shorter horizon and declines for longer maturities. The NFP, and the CPI

    to a lesser extent, are the only announcements that, besides showing the strongest effect on

    short-term yields, have economically significant effect on yields at longer maturities. The

    central plot shows that the effect of good news in bad times is dominated by CPI and CUR

    at the short-horizon, whereas only the release of NFP has consistent significant impacts on

    longer yields. The bottom plot shows that the effect of good news in good times is weaker

    in economic terms with respect to the previous cases and is concentrated in the short-end of

    the yield curve.

    We repeat all the analysis carried out in this section using two alternative definitions of

    expansions and recessions. First, we use a dummy variable reflecting the NBER business

    cycle dates, set equal to zero in expansions and equal to one otherwise. Although the NBER

    dates are not an ideal indicator because the dates of the business cycle were not known

    in real-time, it is still useful for comparison with some of the literature. Second, we use

    the CFNAI expansion index, which is considered the natural successor of the XRI-C and is

    constructed from a broader set of indicators. We find that using a NBER dummy does not

    change the results. More specifically, we obtain the same significant coefficients across the

    board, although the explanatory power is always lower with the NBER dummy. Moreover,

    when a coefficient is not significant with XRI-C is also not significant with the NBER dummy.

    When we use the CFNAI expansion index, more precisely (-CFNAI), we obtain the same

    results of using XRI-C and a similar explanatory power.

    4. State-Dependent Jump Model

    In this section, we extend the analysis of the effects on bond returns of good and bad

    macroeconomic news in expansions and recessions using a state-dependent jump model. This

    model puts a detailed structure on the conduit through which macroeconomic information

    enters the bond market. We start by specifying the model and then present the results of

    the estimation.8We obtain the following modified durations for each Treasury futures: 11.82 for the 30-year Treasury

    bond futures, 6.09 for the 10-year Treasury note futures, 3.93 for the 5-year Treasury note futures, 1.71 forthe 2-year Treasury note futures, 0.24 for the Treasury-bill futures.

    9

  • 4.1. Methodology

    Our econometric specification for the volatility of bond returns builds on the model of Maheu

    and McCurdy (2004) for individual stock returns. We model innovations to the daily log

    return as the sum of a heteroskedastic shock associated with diffusive information flow and

    a jump term capturing the effect of a sudden release of important news.9 However, the

    Maheu and McCurdy’s autoregressive conditional jump intensity parametrization is not well

    suited for the bond market, because anecdotal evidence shows that jumps tend to occur on

    macroeconomic announcement days and these information releases are not autocorrelated.

    Therefore, we explicitly allow the jump arrival rate to increase on announcement days. We

    also let the jump size mean on announcement days to depend on announcement surprises.

    We start by specifying the log futures return as the sum of a time-varying conditional

    mean, a normal innovation ²1,t+1 representing diffusive information flow, and a jump

    innovation ²2,t+1 representing the effect of sudden information arrival:

    xt+1 = ln Ft+1 − ln Ft = µt+1 + ²1,t+1 + ²2,t+1. (6)

    We assume that both innovations have a conditional mean of zero and are contemporaneously

    independent. Furthermore, the first innovation is distributed:

    ²1,t+1 = σt+1zt+1, where zt+1 ∼ N[0, 1]. (7)

    The second innovation is governed by a Poisson jump distribution with a time-varying

    conditional jump intensity λt. That is, the conditional probability of observing nt+1 = j

    jumps between dates t and t + 1 is:

    Prob[nt+1 = j

    ∣∣Φt]

    =exp (−λt+1) λjt+1

    j!, for j = 1, 2, . . . . (8)

    The jump innovation can then be expressed as:

    ²2,t+1 =

    nt+1∑

    k=1

    Yt+1,k − θt+1λt+1, (9)

    where Yt+1,k represents the size of the kth jump, if it occurs, drawn independently from a

    normal distribution with time-varying conditional mean θt+1 and constant volatility δ.

    9Some other papers in the literature have used econometric specifications with time-varying jumpintensities. For example, Bekaert and Gray (1998) and Neely (1999) both model probability of realignmentsfor target zones exchange rates as a function of interest rate differentials and other economic variables. Das(2002) allows the jump intensity of Fed fund rates to vary with the day of the week or with FOMC meetings.

    10

  • 4.1.1 Conditional Variance

    The conditional variance of returns is also divided into two components. First, we assume

    that the volatility of the normal innovation ²1,t+1 follows a standard GARCH process:

    σ2t+1 = ω + α²2t + βσ

    2t , (10)

    where ²t denotes the sum of the two return innovations ²1,t + ²2,t. This specification allows

    both return innovations to affect future volatility through the coefficient α and for volatility

    shocks to be persistent through the coefficient β. Second, the conditional volatility of the

    jump innovation ²2,t+1 is governed by the jump process and is given by:

    var[²2,t+1

    ∣∣Φt+1]

    = λt+1(θ2t+1 + δ

    2), (11)

    where the information set Φt+1 contains all the macroeconomic information up to time t + 1

    but not the financial information, i.e. the bond return innovation ²2. The contribution of

    jumps to the total conditional variance is time-varying with the conditional intensity λt+1

    and the square of the jump-size mean θ2t+1.

    The conditional variance function of equation (10) constrains the normal and the jump

    innovations to affect future volatility in the same way through the parameter α. However,

    the two components of ²t could have in general a different effect. Since we cannot perfectly

    disentangle the two innovations from observed returns, we use a proxy for the importance

    of the jump innovation. We thus estimate the ex-post expected number of jumps occurred

    during period t and allow this estimate to affect the feedback of past innovations on expected

    future volatility:

    σ2t+1 = ω +(α + αjE

    [nt

    ∣∣Φt])

    ²2t + βσ2t , (12)

    where E[nt

    ∣∣Φt]

    is the ex-post estimate of the expected number of jumps occurred between

    time t− 1 and t using period t information. We provide further details on the methodologyused to estimate the ex-post number of jumps in section 4.1.4 that describes the properties

    of the distribution of returns implied by the model.

    Given the focus of this paper on asymmetric effects of good versus bad news across the

    business cycle, we also estimate richer specifications of the conditional variance function of

    11

  • equation (12). More specifically, we model the conditional variance as follows:

    σ2t+1 = ω + g(Φt

    )²2t + βσ

    2t (13)

    g(Φt

    )=

    (1−XRIt

    )(αexp + αexpj E

    [nt

    ∣∣Φt]+ αexpa I (²t) + α

    expaj I (²t) E

    [nt

    ∣∣Φt])

    + (14)

    XRIt(αrec + αrecj E

    [nt

    ∣∣Φt]+ αreca I (²t) + α

    recaj I (²t) E

    [nt

    ∣∣Φt])

    where E[nt

    ∣∣Φt]

    is again the ex-post estimate of the expected number of jumps occurred

    between time t− 1 and t using period t information, I (²t) is an indicator variable equal toone when ²t < 0, and XRIt is the recession index XRI-C at time t.

    10 The function g(Φt

    )

    needs to be positive to have a well-specified GARCH process. However, this constraint is

    never binding with the parameter estimates obtained in the empirical section of this paper.

    Expected volatility responds to past innovations through the function g(.). This function

    allows the feedback to be unconditionally different in expansions versus recessions (αexp and

    αrec). The feedback can also be different depending on whether the observed innovation

    has likely been a jump, through the additional effect of αj. Furthermore, observed negative

    innovations also generate an additional response of volatility, through the parameters αa, in

    case of normal innovations, and αaj, in case of expected jump. The jump and asymmetric

    feedback effects are allowed to be different in expansion versus recession phases.

    4.1.2 Effect of Macroeconomic News

    The ultimate goal of our model is to capture changes in the futures returns in response to

    macroeconomic announcements for different phases of the business cycle. To accomplish this,

    we allow the macroeconomic announcements to affect the return dynamics in three distinct

    ways. First, we let the mean log return µt be different in expansions and recessions:

    µt+1 = µexpt+1(1−XRIt+1) + µrect+1XRIt+1, (15)

    where, following our notation above, XRIt is the probability of being in a recession phase

    at time t as indicated by the value of the recession index XRI-C.

    The second and more prominent role of macroeconomic announcements is through the

    conditional jump intensity. Consistent with the empirical fact that the majority of extreme

    Treasury market moves have occurred on announcement days (e.g., Fleming and Remolona,

    1999), we allow the jump intensity to increase on announcement days from λ0 to λ0 + λk,

    where k denotes either the CPI release, the Employment Report (CUR and NFP) release,

    10Maheu and McCurdy (2004) use a similar specification for the conditional variance of stocks and stockindices. However, they do not distinguish between expansion and recession phases.

    12

  • or the PPI release. More concretely, we model the conditional jump intensity as:

    λt+1 = λ0 +∑

    k=cpi,er,ppi

    λkDk,t+1, (16)

    where Dk,t+1 is a dummy variable signaling whether the announcement k is scheduled between

    dates t and t + 1. Notice that unless λ0 = 0, which the model accommodates, jumps can

    occur on non-announcement days, as they do in the data. We do not expect the intensity

    of the jump process to be different in expansion versus recession phases. Our intuition is

    supported by a likelihood ratio test that shows no significant improvement for more general

    versions of equation (16) (results not reported).

    Finally, we model the conditional mean of the jump size distribution on announcement

    days as a function of the new information released. To gauge the extent to which an

    announcement contains new information, we use the standardized measure of surprise

    constructed in equation (1). We allow different announcement surprises to have different

    effects on the jump size mean and we also allow these effects to be different in expansion

    versus recession phases:

    θt+1 = (1−XRIt+1)(

    θexp0 +∑

    k=cpi,cur,nfp,ppi

    θexpk Sk,t+1

    )+

    XRIt+1

    (θrec0 +

    k=cpi,cur,nfp,ppi

    θreck Sk,t+1

    ).

    (17)

    The intuition underlying this specification is that the sign and magnitude of the immediate

    market reaction to the announcement depends on the news content. However, this link is far

    from deterministic in the data, which leads us to model the mean jump size, as opposed to

    the jump itself, as a function of the surprise. On non-announcement days, the mean jump

    size is equal to θexp0 in expansions and θrec0 in recessions.

    4.1.3 Asymmetric Effects of Macroeconomic News

    Given the focus of the paper on asymmetric effects of macroeconomic news, we also estimate

    our model with a more general version of equation (17) that allows good and bad news to

    have different effects in expansions and recessions. More concretely, we express the mean of

    13

  • the jump size as:

    θt+1 = (1−XRIt+1)(

    θexp0 +∑

    k=cpi,cur,nfp,ppi

    θexpGk Gk,t+1Sk,t+1 + θexpBk Bk,t+1Sk,t+1

    )+

    XRIt+1

    (θrec0 +

    k=cpi,cur,nfp,ppi

    θrecGkGk,t+1Sk,t+1 + θrecBkBk,t+1Sk,t+1

    ) (18)

    where Gkt = 1 and Bkt = 0 if the information released in announcement k at time t is a

    negative surprise, and Gkt = 0 and Bkt = 1 otherwise, similarly to the equation (3) for bond

    returns.

    We allow the mean of the jump size to be different than zero during non-announcement

    days and when the actual release is equal to the median forecast.11 Furthermore, the intercept

    will absorb the effects of macroeconomic news on the jump size mean that are not related

    to the surprise.

    4.1.4 Distribution of Returns

    Conditional on j jumps occurring, our model implies the following distribution of log returns:

    f (xt+1|nt+1 = j, Φt) =1√

    2π(σ2t+1 + jδ

    2) exp

    (−(xt+1 − µt+1 + θt+1λt+1 − θt+1j)

    2

    2(σ2t+1 + jδ

    2)

    ).

    (19)

    The unconditional distribution is then obtained by forming an expectation over the number

    of jumps for each date:

    f (xt+1|Φt) =∞∑

    j=0

    f (xt+1|nt+1 = j, Φt) Prob (nt+1 = j|Φt) . (20)

    Finally, the likelihood function is the product of the T unconditional log return distributions.

    Note that the likelihood function involves infinite summations over the number of possible

    jumps. In practice, we truncate the summations at 20. It turns out that, for our parameter

    estimates, the conditional Poisson distribution has zero probability for more than ten jumps.

    We can use the unconditional distribution of returns implied by our model to construct

    an ex-post probability distribution for the number of jumps occurred at t+1, conditional on

    11For all the model specifications, we use a likelihood-ratio test to reject the restriction of a zero interceptin the equation for the jump size mean. In all cases, we reject the restriction and, consistently, we find thatthe intercept is statistically different from zero, either in expansions, or in recessions, or in both.

    14

  • the information at time t + 1:

    Prob (nt+1 = j|Φt+1) = f (xt+1|nt+1 = j, Φt) Prob (nt+1 = j|Φt)f (xt+1|Φt) . (21)

    The probability that at least one jump has occurred at time t+1 can then easily be obtained

    as the complement to one of the probability of having had no jumps at all:

    Prob (nt+1 ≥ 1|Φt+1) = 1− Prob (nt+1 = 0|Φt+1) . (22)

    4.2. Results

    We estimate the state-dependent jump model by standard maximum likelihood using daily

    data on the returns of Treasury bond futures for contracts with different maturities.

    Table 4 shows the estimates of the model where we allow for the effect of macroeconomic

    news on the jump dynamics in expansions and contractions, retaining however the simpler

    specifications for the conditional variance in equation (12) and for the mean of the jump size

    in equation (17).12 The results on the conditional variance parameters are intriguing. The

    feedback of the current innovation and volatility on future conditional volatility is similar

    at all maturities, except for the shortest, where current innovations are relatively more

    important. When we allow the feedback of the innovation on future volatility to depend

    on the ex-post probability of a jump, we infer that jump innovations are not persistent.

    More specifically, we observe that the feedback coefficient α is almost completely offset by

    αj when the observed innovation was very likely to be a jump. This pattern holds for all

    the maturities. Our evidence is consistent with the results of Jones, Lamont and Lumsdaine

    (1998), but it is more general, since we identify jump innovations endogenously rather than

    imposing that only announcement day innovations can have a different feedback on future

    volatility.

    The conditional variance of the estimated state-dependent jump model leads to

    interesting volatility dynamics for different segments of the yield curve. In Figure 2, we plot

    the conditional variance implied by the model for the 30-year Treasury bond futures and for

    the 5-year Treasury-note futures over the recent period 2001 to 2003. The total conditional

    variance is the sum of a GARCH component, as in equation (12), and a jump component, as

    in equation (11). The plot illustrates well that the GARCH component describes the smooth

    changes in daily volatility, whereas jumps take care of abnormal episodes of volatility.

    12The main results of the model are unaffected by the use of these simpler specifications. We return tothe most general version of the model later in the paper.

    15

  • Table 4 also shows that in general the mean return µ is statistically positive both in

    expansions and in contractions, but it is always more economically significant in recessions

    for all maturities. This is evidence of higher risk premiums in contraction phases and is

    consistent with previous results on counter-cyclical risk-aversion (e.g., Engle and Rosenberg,

    2002; Gordon and St-Amour, 2004).

    The significant results on the jump parameters confirm the importance of augmenting a

    basic GARCH specification. The unconditional jump intensity λ0 is significantly positive for

    all the maturities. This confirms our intuition that jumps can be triggered by macroeconomic

    announcements that are not included in our sample or by other categories of events. However,

    the macroeconomic announcements we consider play a leading role in determining the

    jump dynamics. We obtain a significantly positive estimate of λk for the CPI release, the

    Employment Report, and the PPI release, indicating that the jump intensity rises sharply

    on these announcement days for all the maturities. The Employment Report is the most

    important announcement in this respect. In contrast, the CPI release is usually the least

    important in increasing the intensity of a jump. When we compare jump intensities across

    maturities, we observe that the CPI is most relevant for the jump intensity of the five-year

    futures, but it is not significant for the Treasury-bill. The employment report has equally

    important effects for all maturities, less so for the two-year futures. Finally, the PPI release

    affects less the intensity of a jump for shorter maturities, but it turns out to have always

    a stronger impact than the CPI announcement. This last result is likely to depend on the

    timing of the announcements, where the PPI is always released at least one day before the

    CPI in our sample.

    When we look at the parameters describing the jump magnitudes, we observe that,

    both in expansions and recessions, the size of the jumps is drawn unconditionally from a

    distribution with a negative mean, except for the shortest maturity in recessions, and a

    volatility decreasing with shorter maturities. Again, the macroeconomic announcements

    play an important role. In expansion phases of the business cycle, the estimates that are

    significant are generally negative, that is positive (negative) surprises in the announcements

    have a negative (positive) impact on the mean of the jump size. This effect is highly

    statistically significant for the release of NFP: when payrolls are higher than expected in

    periods of economic growth, the size of jumps in bond returns is drawn from a distribution

    with a lower mean, i.e. there is a greater probability of observing higher yields. We register

    the opposite effect when payrolls are lower than expected in periods of economic growth.

    Economically, a one standard deviation positive NFP surprise in expansion decreases the

    jump-size mean by 0.3%. Considering that the average number of jumps induced by the

    employment report in one year is 1.4 (0.34+1.06), this corresponds to a more negative mean

    16

  • of the jump size distribution of 0.42%. The release of the CPI in expansions has similar

    effects on the long maturity, it is not significant for intermediate maturities, and it switches

    sign in the short term.

    In contraction phases of the business cycle, however, the effects of economic releases are

    less clear. When the NFP is higher than expected, the mean of the jump size increases and

    viceversa for lower than expected NFP. The effect of CPI on bond returns at the longer

    maturities is also reversed. The release of the PPI has always a negative effect, significant

    however only at the two and five year maturities. This evidence suggests that it is indeed

    important to allow for different responses to the same announcements in expansions versus

    contractions. We can nevertheless obtain further insights and a deeper interpretation of these

    kind of results by disentangling the effect of good and bad news in good and bad times. We

    will devote Section 4.2.2 to this exercise.

    Table 5 presents the characteristics of the jump and volatility dynamics implied by the

    estimated state-dependent jump model. Panel A shows summary statistics for the jump

    intensity λt, for the jump size mean θt, and for the part of the total variance induced by the

    jumps (var[²2,t+1

    ∣∣Φt]/

    var[rt+1

    ∣∣Φt]), using the estimated model on all the days in our sample,

    considering the actual timing of scheduled macroeconomic news, and separating expansions

    versus contractions. We conduct non-parametric tests on the samples of λt, θt, and the

    variance induced by the jumps for the different segment of the yield curve and we find in all

    cases that the samples come from distributions with different medians.13

    We observe that the jump intensity is highest for the longest maturity, it is about at the

    same level for the ten and five year maturity, and it decreases for shorter maturities. These

    intensities range from 0.34 jumps per year (about one jump every three years) at the long

    end to 0.13 jumps per year (about one jump every seven and a half years) at the short end

    of the yield curve. The median jump intensities clearly resemble the unconditional jump

    intensity estimates presented in Table 4. The mean of the jump size distribution is always

    negative, less so for shorter maturities. There are no appreciable differences of these statistics

    between expansion and recession phases, except for the jump-induced variance that is lower

    in recessions at the very long- and short-end of the yield curve.

    The proportion of the total variance induced by the jumps is highest for the two-year

    futures, where jumps generate on average more than half of the variance, and lower for longer

    maturities. This evidence on the prominence of the middle maturity range for the variance

    induced by the jumps is consistent both with a macroeconomic news explanation and with an

    order flow explanation. In fact, Fleming and Remolona (1999b) find that the high-frequency

    13The results of the non-parametric tests are not reported, but are available on request from the authors.

    17

  • responses of 5-minutes bond yields to macroeconomic announcements over the period 1991 to

    1995 have a hump-shaped pattern that peaks around two to three years. We do not observe

    this pattern in our analysis of returns in the previous section for our longer sample at the

    daily frequency. There would thus be a closer link between high-frequency returns dynamics

    and jump-induced variance then there is with daily returns. However, Brandt and Kavajecz

    (2004) observe that, on non-announcement days, the strongest response of yields to order

    flow imbalance is at the two-five-year maturity range. We argue that the jump innovations

    to the price process, triggered either by macroeconomic announcements or price discovery,

    are most important for the maturity range containing securities that are more universally

    held and used for hedging.

    Panel B of Table 5 investigates more closely the pattern of jumps implied by the estimated

    model. We use the ex-post probability of having at least one jump derived in equations (21)

    and (22) to determine the average frequency of jumps in our sample. We observe the highest

    number of average jumps per year for the five-year futures. The comparison of expansions

    and recessions shows that for all the different futures contracts the average number of jumps

    is lower in recessions. We obtain further insights when we relate the jump dynamics to the

    pattern of macroeconomic announcements. For example, we observe that the proportion of

    jumps occurring on the same day of a macroeconomic release varies a lot with the maturity.

    Less than 35% of the total number of jumps occurs on announcement days for the two-year

    futures, i.e. the majority of observed jumps are unrelated to our set of macroeconomic

    releases, but more than 60% of the jumps occurs on announcement days for the longest

    maturity futures.14 The analysis across business cycle phases shows that in recessions jumps

    are slightly less related to macroeconomic news than in expansions for all maturities, except

    at the short-end of the yield curve, where jumps on announcement days are more frequent

    in recessions than in expansions.

    We can investigate the same issues from a different perspective, that is the proportion

    of macroeconomic announcements that results in a jump. We observe that less than 30%

    of the macroeconomic releases in our sample causes a jump for the shortest maturities -

    the two-year futures and the Treasury bill -, whereas more than 60% of the announcements

    generates a jump for the five-year and longer maturity securities. For all maturities except

    at the short-end of the yield curve, the proportion of macroeconomic releases resulting in

    14Note that this descriptive analysis has three limitations. First, we cannot talk about a causal linkbetween macroeconomic news and jumps in a strict sense. We are only arguing that, since we observenews and jump on the same day, they are very likely to be related. Second, we are only considering fourmacroeconomic releases, but the set of influential announcements is certainly wider. If this is the case, thereported proportions are biased downward. Lastly, we consider that a jump has occurred when the ex-postprobability is greater than 0.5 (see Table 3, Panel B), but this threshold is arbitrary.

    18

  • a jump is lower in recessions, indicating that unconditionally learning about the state of

    the economy from news is less than a surprise when the economy is in contraction. We can

    further develop this reasoning by looking at each macroeconomic release separately. The

    release of the CPI is more frequently a cause of jumps for the intermediate maturities and

    particularly for the two-years in recessions. The employment report (ER) is always the most

    relevant release and increases in importance with shorter maturities, whereas the PPI exhibit

    the opposite pattern of decreasing importance with maturity.

    In Figure 3, we summarize these results. We observe more clearly that announcements

    are relatively more important in causing jumps in expansions rather than in recessions and

    for longer than for shorter maturity securities. The release of the employment report is

    invariably the most influential, both in expansions and recessions. The only exception seems

    to be the two-year horizon, where the role of inducing jumps of the three releases that we

    consider is more balanced.

    4.2.1 Specification Tests

    To ensure that the model is reasonably well specified with respect to the inclusion of the

    timing and information of macroeconomic news, we conduct a sequence of specification tests.

    Specifically, starting with a version of the model with constant jump intensity (i.e., λt = λ0),

    we use likelihood ratio tests to sequentially examine each restriction with respect to the

    general model estimated in Table 4.

    Table 6 shows the results of three specification tests. First, we find that, for all the

    Treasury futures, a constant jump intensity is strongly rejected in favor of the most general

    version of the model. It is thus statistically important to allow the intensity of the jump to

    be time-varying. The second tested restriction is to allow the intensity of the jump to be

    different on announcement days, but with no distinction of the announcement type. Again,

    we strongly reject this restriction for all the different segments of the yield curve, except

    for the two years. It seems therefore essential to allow different announcements to affect

    differently the intensity of the jump process. Lastly, we constrain the mean of the jump size

    to be independent on the information content of the macroeconomic release. This restriction

    is again strongly rejected for all the maturities. From these specification tests, we conclude

    that the features of the proposed state-dependent jump model are all statistically important

    to accurately describe the returns of the bond futures.

    4.2.2 Asymmetric Effect of Macroeconomic News

    We argue that the information content of macroeconomic news can have different effects on

    bond markets depending on observing good news versus bad news, in good or bad times.

    19

  • To disentangle these asymmetric effects, we use the general specification for the jump size

    mean formalized in equation (18).

    Table 7 presents the results for the effects on the mean of the jump size. The results

    on the other characteristics of the model are not different from the estimates of the simpler

    specification presented in Table 4 and are thus not reported. A likelihood ratio test shows in

    all cases a significant statistical improvement in generalizing the specification for the mean

    of the jump size. More specifically, it is statistically important to allow good and bad news

    to have different effects in good or bad times and this characteristic of the model seems

    especially crucial for the shorter maturities.

    We observe that the parameter estimates are mostly significant for bad news in expansion

    phases of the business cycle. In contrast, good news in good times do not seem to

    systematically affect the distribution of the size of the jump in bond returns. We register

    the most relevant effects of the information in macroeconomic news on jump dynamics when

    the release of the NFP is higher than expected in an expansion phase of the business cycle.

    In this case, the distribution of the size of jumps in Treasury bond futures returns has a

    negative conditional mean for all maturities. We observe a very similar pattern for PPI

    announcements, with higher than expected releases leading to more negative jump size

    means. The announcement of CPI has the opposite impact, except for the longest maturity:

    a positive CPI surprise leads to a distribution of the jump size with a higher conditional

    mean.

    In recession phases, the pattern of the relevant information is less clear, but good news

    (negative surprises) tend to be more important in affecting jump dynamics. More specifically,

    when the released NFP is lower than expected, the size of the jump in returns for shorter

    maturities is drawn from a distribution with a negative mean.15 This pattern is similar,

    although less significant, for the CPI. In contrast, jump after good news in the PPI release

    are drawn from a distribution with a higher mean, although this effect is significant only for

    intermediate maturities.

    The interpretation of these results is again more meaningful, if we translate the effect of

    a surprise on returns to the effect of a surprise on yields. The mapping between returns and

    yields goes again simply through the duration of each segment of the yield curve as shown

    before in equation (4). In this case, we obtain the return on the underlying dP/P as the

    mean size of a jump triggered by a one-standard deviation announcement surprise occurring

    with intensity λt. We then calculate the duration of each Treasury futures contract as the

    15We observe a negative impact on the mean of the jump size, because the parameter estimate θrecG,nfp ispositive, but the surprise is always negative.

    20

  • modified duration of a deliverable bond with the average maturity in the maturity range.

    Using the measure for bond returns suggested above and the appropriate modified duration,

    we obtain a measure of the effect on yields.16

    Figure 4 plots the effect of a one standard deviation surprise in NFP, PPI and CPI on the

    mean of the jump size distribution of yields at different maturities. We also plot two standard

    deviation bands, obtained from the standard errors of the parameter estimates.17 Panel A

    shows the most significant case, the effect of positive surprises in an expansion phase of the

    business cycle. The exception is the release of the CUR, for which we actually show the effects

    of negative surprises, since the sign of the surprise has the opposite implications with respect

    to the other macroeconomic announcements. The release of a lower than expected CUR has

    similar implications for the labor market than the release of an higher than expected NFP.

    Yields for all maturities rise in response to higher than expected numbers for NFP and PPI

    releases. In contrast, the results for the release of CUR are never significantly affecting the

    mean of the jump size in expansion. We interpret the results for NFP and PPI as evidence

    that an unexpected pickup in economic growth when the economy is rising is perceived as

    indication of overheating, which leads short and long term interest rates to increase. The

    effect of a positive CPI surprise is less intuitive. We observe a general reduction in yields,

    with a higher yield only at the longest maturity, implying a steeper yield curve. Either an

    expected pickup in economic growth or higher expected future inflation would tend to raise

    long-term rates relative to short rates, steepening the yield curve. It is more difficult to

    explain why a higher than expected CPI release would reduce the mean of the jump size in

    yields at the intermediate maturities. In fact, the market seems to interpret positive shocks

    to CPI differently than PPI. However, any interpretation of the CPI results should be taken

    cautiously, because the CPI is often released the day after the PPI and, although we control

    for the PPI release in forming the CPI expectation, the results could still be affected by

    overreaction or underreaction to PPI news.

    Panel B shows the effect of negative surprises in the NFP, PPI, CPI release and positive

    surprise in the CUR release, in a recession phase of the business cycle. When the release of

    PPI is lower than expected, we observe a general reduction in yields. The monetary policy

    16The measure of bond returns is the effect of a one standard deviation surprise in the macroeconomicannouncement obtained as an expected jump size times an intensity measure. As such, the change in yieldscan be interpreted in the same logic as the jump effect of a macroeconomic surprise.

    17We obtain the error bands of the effect on yields using the bond return dP/P computed as the jump sizemean parameters plus/minus two standard errors and the procedure outlined above to convert bond returnsinto bond yields. This methodology delivers a good approximation of the true confidence bands, since thecovariance between the intercept and the slope term of the jump size mean is negligible and negative (e.g.,the covariance between θexp0 and θ

    expB,nfp for the 30-year Treasury bond futures is -1.01e-08 when θ

    expB,nfp is

    1.35e-02) and the standard error of the jump intensity term exerts a second order effect.

    21

  • has the expected expansionary bias, since the economy is in recession and inflation shows

    indications of being below analyst estimates. Furthermore, during a recession, the negative

    inflation shock is also likely to lower investors’ inflation expectation. This latter effect could

    explain the drop in long term yields. The release of weaker than expected NFP numbers

    in a recession phase does not have very significant effects. We observe a flattening of the

    yield curve that is consistent with future rate hikes being less likely when the economy is in

    a recession and payrolls are showing no sign of recovery. Alternatively, lower than expected

    NFP numbers could lower payroll pressure on production costs, resulting in lower inflation

    expectations, and therefore lower long term yields. The release of higher than expected CUR

    has significant effects mostly on the ten and five-year yields, where we observe reduction in

    yields consistent with signs of slow growth in recessions. It is interesting to see that CUR has

    some significant effects in recession, but was never relevant in expansions, indicating that

    the bond market looks at different indicators to gauge the state of the economy in different

    phases of the business cycle. The release of a lower than expected CPI does not significantly

    affect the mean of the jump size, except that it implies higher short term yields. It is hard

    to interpret this result in isolation, it only makes sense when we observe that the yield curve

    becomes flatter. However, the release of the PPI very shortly before implies again that all

    inferences should be taken with caution.

    4.2.3 Jumps and Asymmetric Feedbacks on Conditional Volatility

    We further examine the effect of macroeconomic news on volatility dynamics using a

    richer specification for conditional volatility. More specifically, Table 8 presents the results

    of estimating the state-dependent jump model with the GARCH component specified in

    equation (13), where we allow for different feedback on future volatility of normal versus

    jump innovations in expansions versus recessions, and asymmetries of positive and negative

    innovations. We do not report the estimates for the parameters of the model that are not

    related to volatility, because they are very similar to the general estimation results described

    in Table 4.

    A likelihood ratio test indicates that the richer specification for the conditional volatility

    function is especially important for the longest and shortest maturity. In general, we observe

    that the feedback of innovations on future conditional volatility is stronger in recessions. We

    attribute the low or non-significant αrec for the five and two year maturity to the shorter

    sample that contains only two recessionary periods. The feedback of the jump innovations

    αexp,recj is always negative and statistically significant, both in expansions and in recessions,

    indicating that the effect of jumps on future volatility tends to not persist. We find evidence

    of asymmetric volatility for the longest and shortest maturity, but only in expansions. In

    22

  • both cases, if the negative innovation is likely to be a jump, the higher persistence αexpa is

    almost completely offset by the asymmetric jump feedback term αexpaj .

    Figure 5 exploits the parameters estimated in Table 8 to plot the effects of positive and

    negative innovations in expansions and recessions, separating normal innovations from jump

    innovations, i.e. the innovations that were jumps with a probability of 50%. We observe

    the lower persistence of positive normal innovations in expansions versus recessions, but the

    higher persistence of negative normal innovations in expansions versus recessions because of

    asymmetric volatility. We also notice how jump innovations dampen persistence and this is

    true in expansions, recessions, positive and negative innovations.

    5. Conclusion

    We analyze the effects of good and bad macroeconomic news on bond market returns and

    volatility, during economic expansions and economic contractions. Specifically, we identify

    a high-frequency relation between yields and the economy, whereas the macroeconomic

    literature has typically modeled interactions at a lower frequency.

    We find that the information content of the announcements is most important for bond

    returns when it contains bad news for the bond market in expansions and, to a lesser extent,

    good news for the bond market in contractions. Furthermore, the response of the bond

    market depends on the announcement type, on the bond maturity, and on the business

    cycle. We also find that macroeconomic news impact substantially the volatility of bond

    returns at all maturities through increased jump intensities and different distributions of the

    jump size. The proportion of the total variance induced by the jumps is greatest for the

    medium term maturities of two and five years. Finally, we observe that the impact of jumps

    on volatility does not persist, consistent with Jones, Lamont, and Lumsdaine (1998).

    In bond markets, monetary authorities play a key role, with direct effects on short-

    term yields and some influence on long-term yields via inflation expectations. Our results

    are consistent, for example, with an asymmetric Fed reaction function by which positive

    economic news induce a strong increase in the likelihood of higher future target rates in

    expansions, but only a marginal increase in contractions. In this setting, the response of

    bond prices to macroeconomic news depends critically on the content of the news and on

    the phase of the business cycle.

    Furthermore our paper shows the importance of modeling volatility in the bond market

    using both a diffusive and a jump component and incorporating the timing and information

    of macroeconomic news, allowing for different dynamics in expansions and recessions. A

    challenging area for future study is to incorporate these results in developing no-arbitrage

    models of the term structure of Treasury bond yields.

    23

  • References

    Andersen, T.G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F.X., and Vega, C. (2007) Real-time pricediscovery in stock, bond and foreign exchange markets, Journal of International Economics,forthcoming.

    Andersen, T.G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F.X., and Vega, C. (2003) Micro effects of macroannouncements: Real-time price discovery in foreign exchange, American Economic Review93, 38–62.

    Ang, A., Bekaert, G., and Wei, M. (2007) Do macro variables, asset markets or surveysforecast inflation better?, Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 1163–1212.

    Bekaert, G. and Gray, S.F. (1998) Target zones and exchange rates: An empiricalinvestigation, Journal of International Economics 45, 1–35.

    Bernanke, B.S. and Kuttner, K.N. (2005) What explains the stock market’s reaction toFederal Reserve policy?, Journal of Finance 60, 1221–1257.

    Bollerslev, T., Cai, J., and Song, F.M. (2000) Intraday periodicity, long memory volatility,and macroeconomic announcement effects in the U.S. Treasury bond market, Journal ofEmpirical Finance 7, 37–55.

    Boyd, J.H., Hu, J., and Jagannathan, R. (2005) The stock market’s reaction tounemployment news: Why bad news is usually good for stocks, Journal of Finance 60,649–672.

    Brandt, M.W. and Kavajecz, K.A. (2004) Price discovery in the U.S. Treasury market: Theimpact of orderflow and liquidity on the yield curve, Journal of Finance 59, 2623–2654.

    Brenner, M., Pasquariello, P., and Subrahmanyam, M. (2006) Financial markets and themacro economy, Working Paper, University of Michigan.

    Christiansen, C. and Ranaldo, A. (2007) Realized bond-stock correlation: Macroeconomicannouncement effects, Journal of Futures Markets, forthcoming.

    Das, S.R. (2002) The surprise element: Jumps in interest rates, Journal of Econometrics106, 27–65.

    Ederington, L.H. and Lee, J.H. (1993) How markets process information: News releases andvolatility, Journal of Finance 48, 1161–1191.

    Engle, R.F. and Rosenberg, J. (2002) Empirical pricing kernels, Journal of FinancialEconomics 64, 341–372.

    Fleming, M.J. and Remolona, E.M. (1997) What moves the bond market?, Federal ReserveBank of New York Economic Policy Review, 31–50.

    Fleming, M.J. and Remolona, E.M. (1999) Price formation and liquidity in the U.S. Treasurymarket: The response to public information, Journal of Finance 54, 1901–1915.

    Fleming, M.J. and Remolona, E.M. (1999b) The term structure of announcement effects,Working Paper, Bank for International Settlements.

    Gordon, S. and St-Amour, P. (2004) Asset returns and state-dependent risk preferences,Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 22, 241–252.

    24

  • Hong, H., Torous, W., and Valkanov, R. (2007) Do industries lead stock markets?, Journalof Financial Economics 83, 367–396.

    Jones, C.M., Lamont, O., and Lumsdaine, R.L. (1998) Macroeconomic news and bondmarket volatility, Journal of Financial Economics 47, 315–337.

    Maheu, J.M. and McCurdy, T.H. (2004) News arrival, jump dynamics and volatilitycomponents for individual stock returns, Journal of Finance 59, 755–793.

    Neely, C.J. (1999) Target zones and conditional volatility: The role of realignments, Journalof Empirical Finance 6, 177–192.

    Stock, J. and Watson, M. (1989) New indexes of coincident and leading economic indicators,in Olivier, J., Fisher, S. (ed.): NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989 (Cambridge, MA).

    Veronesi, P. (1999) Stock market overreaction to bad news in good times: A rationalexpectations equilibrium model, Review of Financial Studies 12, 975-1007.

    25

  • Table 1: Macroeconomic News and Futures Returns Summary Statistics

    This table shows summary statistics for macroeconomic news and for daily returns on the 30-yearTreasury bond futures (US), the 10-year Treasury note futures (TY), the 5-year Treasury notefutures (FV), the 2-year Treasury note futures (TU), and the 90-day Treasury bill futures (TB).Panel A shows the announcements, their abbreviations, the reported units of the variables, the timesat which the announcements are normally released, and the number of times two announcementsare concurrent (same date and time). Panel B shows statistics on daily continuously compoundedreturns for the full sample that is available for each futures contract. Panel C shows statistics ondaily returns for the longest sample common to all the futures contracts.

    Panel AConcurrent

    AnnouncementsAnnouncement Abbrev. Units Time CPI CUR NFP PPI

    Consumer Price Index CPI % Change 8:30 ET 282 0 0 0Civilian Unemployment CUR % Level 8:30 ET 0 282 282 13Nonfarm Payrolls NFP Thousands 8:30 ET 0 282 282 13Producer Price Index PPI % Change 8:30 ET 0 13 13 282

    Panel B

    US TY FV TU TB

    First Obs Feb-1980 Jun-1982 May-1988 Jun-1990 Feb-1980Last Obs Dec-2003 Dec-2003 Dec-2003 Dec-2003 Sep-2003Obs 6054 5469 3968 3526 5965Mean+ 0.0399 0.0449 0.0238 0.0079 0.0079StDev+ 0.1189 0.0718 0.0425 0.0211 0.0214Skewness -0.0692 -0.0357 -0.4764 -1.0419 0.3349Kurtosis 5.1034 5.9126 6.4016 10.8327 14.5480Min -0.0324 -0.0286 -0.0222 -0.0103 -0.0071Max 0.0394 0.0342 0.0118 0.0065 0.0140

    Panel C

    US TY FV TU TB

    First Obs Jun-1990 Jun-1990 Jun-1990 Jun-1990 Jun-1990Last Obs Sep-2003 Sep-2003 Sep-2003 Sep-2003 Sep-2003Obs 3353 3353 3353 3353 3353Mean+ 0.0420 0.0358 0.0276 0.0084 0.0077StDev+ 0.0921 0.0615 0.0421 0.0210 0.0074Skewness -0.4209 -0.5271 -0.5872 -1.0220 0.7597Kurtosis 4.5016 5.5767 6.5843 10.8010 12.1037Min -0.0298 -0.0286 -0.0222 -0.0103 -0.0036Max 0.0246 0.0142 0.0114 0.0065 0.0043

    + Daily mean return and standard deviation are annualized.

    26

  • Table 2: Effect of Macroeconomic News on Bond Returns

    This table shows parameter estimates for the following regression:

    rt,t−1 = αk + βexpk (1−XRIt) Sk + βreckXRItSk + ek,

    where rt,t−1 represents the day-to-day return for each of the Treasury bond futures, XRIt is theprobability of being in a recession phase at time t, and S denotes the standardized announcementsurprise. The day-to-day return is computed on the 30-year Treasury bond futures (US), the 10-year Treasury note futures (TY), the 5-year Treasury note futures (FV), the 2-year Treasury notefutures (TU), and the 90-day Treasury bill futures (TB).

    US TY FV TU TB

    CPI α 0.00028 0.00020 0.00018 0.00018 0.00011βexp -0.00123∗ -0.00085∗∗ -0.00091∗∗ -0.00043∗∗ -0.00017∗

    βrec -0.00244 -0.00211∗∗ -0.00057 -0.00003 -0.00035R2 0.045 0.052 0.055 0.047 0.037

    CUR α 0.00060 0.00021 0.00014 0.00007 0.00019∗

    βexp 0.00091 0.00096∗∗ 0.00083∗∗ 0.00042∗∗ 0.00020∗

    βrec 0.00297 -0.00001 0.00012 0.00027 0.00097∗∗

    NFP βexp -0.00446∗∗∗ -0.00320∗∗∗ -0.00240∗∗∗ -0.00101∗∗∗ -0.00061∗∗∗

    βrec -0.00303 -0.00211∗ -0.00170∗∗ -0.00102∗∗∗ -0.00059∗∗∗

    R2 0.181 0.216 0.294 0.308 0.171

    PPI α 0.00028 0.00075 0.00047 0.00015 0.00001βexp -0.00220∗∗∗ -0.00096∗∗ -0.000212 0.00001 -0.00043∗∗∗

    βrec 0.00135 0.00111 0.00097∗ 0.00035 -0.00011R2 0.038 0.017 0.015 0.012 0.048

    ∗ ∗ ∗, ∗∗, and ∗ denote statistical significance at the one, five, and 10 percent levels,respectively.

    27

  • Table 3: Effect of Good and Bad News on Bond Returns

    This table shows parameter estimates for the following regression:

    rt,t−1 = αk + βGexpk (1−XRIt) SktGkt + βBexpk (1−XRIt) SkBkt+ βGreckXRItSktGkt + βBreckXRItSkBkt + ekt,

    where rt,t−1 represents the day-to-day return for each of the Treasury bond futures, XRIt is theprobability of being in a recession phase at time t, S denotes the standardized announcementsurprise, and Gkt = 1 and Bkt = 0 if the information released in announcement k at time t is goodnews (for the Treasury market) and Gkt = 0 and Bkt = 1 otherwise. The day-to-day return iscomputed on the 30-year Treasury bond futures (US), the 10-year Treasury note futures (TY), the5-year Treasury note futures (FV), the 2-year Treasury note futures (TU), and the 90-day Treasurybill futures (TB).

    US TY FV TU TB

    CPI α 0.00073 0.00109∗∗∗ 0.00092∗∗∗ 0.00047 0.00016βGexp 0.00080 0.00109 0.00043 0.00010 0.00015βBexp -0.00286∗∗∗ -0.00266∗∗∗ -0.00211∗∗∗ -0.00101∗∗∗ -0.00043∗∗∗

    βGrec -0.00665∗∗∗ -0.00357∗∗ 0.00028 0.00023 -0.00116∗∗

    βBrec -0.00019 -0.00148∗ -0.00117 -0.00016 0.00016R2 0.095 0.100 0.099 0.084 0.103

    CUR α 0.00089 0.00014 0.00001 -0.00001 0.00017βGexp 0.00039 -0.00031 -0.00041 -0.00005 0.00014βBexp 0.00119 0.00185∗∗∗ 0.00248∗∗∗ 0.00108∗∗∗ 0.00026βGrec 0.00167 0.00338∗ 0.00271 0.00065 -0.00011βBrec 0.00303 -0.00082 -0.00138 0.00006 0.00108∗∗

    NFP βGexp -0.00339∗∗∗ -0.00253∗∗∗ -0.00156∗∗∗ -0.00068∗∗∗ -0.00052∗∗∗

    βBexp -0.00634∗∗∗ -0.00452∗∗∗ -0.00390∗∗∗ -0.00161∗∗∗ -0.00076∗∗∗

    βGrec -0.00319 -0.00275∗∗ -0.00239∗∗∗ -0.00117∗∗∗ -0.00056∗∗

    βBrec 0.00035 0.00110 0.00014 -0.00097 -0.00054R2 0.189 0.233 0.334 0.339 0.178

    PPI α 0.00054 0.00046 0.00044 0.00002 -0.00001βGexp -0.00266∗∗ -0.00131∗∗ -0.00030 -0.00021 -0.00046∗∗

    βBexp -0.00166 -0.00032 -0.00008 0.00033 -0.00042βGrec 0.00081 0.00102 0.00114∗∗ 0.00042∗∗ 0.00005βBrec 0.00217 0.00111 0.00072 0.00015 0.00022R2 0.040 0.019 0.016 0.023 0.048

    ∗ ∗ ∗, ∗∗, and ∗ denote statistical significance at the one, five, and 10 percent levels,respectively.

    28

  • Table 4: Estimates of the State-Dependent Jump Model

    This table shows estimates for daily returns on the 30-year Treasury bond futures (US), the 10-year Treasury note futures (TY), the 5-year Treasury note futures (FV), the 2-year Treasury notefutures (TU), and the 90-day Treasury bill futures (TB) of the following model:

    ²1,t+1 = σt+1zt+1, zt+1 ∼ N[0, 1], ²2,t+1 =nt+1∑

    k=1

    Yt+1,k − θt+1λt+1

    σ2t+1 = ω +(α + αjE

    [nt

    ∣∣Φt])

    ²2t + βσ2t , µt+1 = µ

    expt+1(1−XRIt+1) + µrect+1XRIt+1

    λt+1 = λ0 +∑

    k=cpi,er,ppi

    λkDk,t+1

    θt+1 =(1−XRIt+1

    )(θexp0 +

    k=cpi,cur,nfp,ppi

    θexpk Sk,t+1

    )+XRIt+1

    (θrec0 +

    k=cpi,cur,nfp,ppi

    θreck Sk,t+1

    )

    US TY FV TU TB

    ω × 106 0.9810∗∗∗ 4.4483∗∗∗ 0.0021∗∗∗ 0.5273∗∗∗ 14.6029∗∗∗α 0.0737∗∗∗ 0.0878∗∗∗ 0.0701∗∗∗ 0.0411∗∗∗ 0.1387∗∗∗

    αj -0.0561∗∗∗ -0.0640∗∗∗ -0.0531∗∗∗ -0.0352∗∗∗ -0.1239∗∗∗

    β 0.9370∗∗∗ 0.9188∗∗∗ 0.9321∗∗∗ 0.9571∗∗∗ 0.8756∗∗∗

    µexp × 104 1.5124∗ 0.8729∗ 0.4063 0.2004 0.0325µrec × 104 5.2735∗∗ 4.7239∗∗∗ 3.1109∗∗∗ 1.8189∗∗∗ 0.9623∗∗∗

    λ0 0.3429∗∗∗ 0.3161∗∗∗ 0.3213∗∗∗ 0.1641∗∗∗ 0.1320∗∗∗

    λcpi 0.3501∗∗∗ 0.3957∗∗∗ 0.4650∗∗∗ 0.1989∗∗∗ 0.0635λer 1.0574∗∗∗ 1.2604∗∗∗ 1.0151∗∗∗ 0.5447∗∗∗ 0.9802∗∗∗

    λppi 0.6823∗∗∗ 0.6944∗∗∗ 0.5370∗∗∗ 0.1565∗∗∗ 0.1548∗∗∗

    θexp0 × 104 -5.3039∗ -4.7729∗∗∗ -2.4921∗ -4.4213∗∗∗ -0.42493θexpcpi × 104 -29.2192∗∗∗ 0.5324 8.4604 9.6003∗∗ 3.2602∗∗θexpcur × 104 4.9841 -3.7622 -0.9755 -3.5334 -0.1045θexpnfp × 104 -33.1023∗∗∗ -21.3446∗∗∗ -22.2312∗∗∗ -4.1504 -0.8882∗θexpppi × 104 15.1112 4.8902 1.4131 5.1144 1.7234θrec0 × 104 -29.8123∗∗∗ -24.3031∗∗∗ -14.1431∗∗∗ -3.1804 4.4326∗∗∗θreccpi × 104 57.6348∗∗ 34.6237∗ 15.5484 8.1934 5.3218θreccur × 104 -30.5386 -26.1379 28.8390∗∗ 4.1004 3.7019∗θrecnfp × 104 43.4328∗∗ 21.1036∗∗ 19.7344∗∗ 18.4301∗∗∗ 6.8400∗∗∗θrecppi × 104 -22.4381 -18.2351 -18.7093∗∗ -14.7223∗∗∗ -2.7254δ 0.0055∗∗∗ 0.0039∗∗∗ 0.0026∗∗∗ 0.0022∗∗∗ 0.0010∗∗∗

    logL 21,766.60 22,306.00 18,195.90 18,870.40 35,506.50Obs 6054 5469 3968 3526 5965

    ∗ ∗ ∗, ∗∗, and ∗ denote statistical significance at the one, five, and 10 percent levels,respectively.

    29

  • Table

    5:

    Model-Im

    plied

    Jum

    pand

    Vola

    tility

    Dynam

    ics

    Thi

    sta

    ble

    show

    ske

    yfe

    atur

    esim

    plie

    dby

    the

    esti

    mat

    edju

    mp

    mod

    elfo

    rda

    ilyre

    turn

    son

    the

    30-y

    ear

    Tre

    asur

    ybo

    ndfu

    ture

    s(U

    S),

    the

    10-y

    ear

    Tre

    asur

    yno

    tefu

    ture

    s(T

    Y),

    the

    5-ye

    arTre

    asur

    yno

    tefu

    ture

    s(F

    V),

    the

    2-ye

    arTre

    asur

    yno

    tefu

    ture

    s(T

    U),

    and

    the

    90-d

    ayTre

    asur

    ybi

    llfu

    ture

    s(T

    B).

    Pan

    elA

    show

    sth

    eex

    pect

    ednu

    mbe

    rof

    jum

    ps(λ

    t),th

    em

    ean

    ofth

    eju

    mp

    size

    (θt)

    ,an

    dth

    epr

    opor

    tion

    ofth

    eco

    ndit

    iona

    lvar

    ianc

    eth

    atis

    expl

    aine

    dby

    the

    jum

    pco

    mpo

    nent

    (i.e

    .,va

    r[ ²2,t+

    1

    ∣ ∣ Φt]/

    var[ r

    t+1

    ∣ ∣ Φt] )

    .T

    here

    port

    edva

    lues

    are

    sam

    ple

    med

    ians

    abov

    ean

    dm

    ean

    abso

    lute

    devi

    atio

    nsfr

    omth

    em

    edia

    nsbe

    low

    .Pan

    elB

    show

    sth

    ein

    ferr

    ednu

    mbe

    rof

    jum

    psfo

    rth

    efu

    llsa

    mpl

    e,th

    eav

    erag

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    jum

    pspe

    rye

    ar,th

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    anno

    unce

    men

    tda

    ysin

    the

    sam

    ple,

    the

    infe

    rred

    num

    ber

    ofju

    mps

    occu

    rrin

    gon

    anno

    unce

    men

    tda

    ys,t

    hepr

    opor

    tion

    ofju

    mps

    occu

    rrin

    gon

    anno

    unce

    men

    tda

    ys,a

    ndth

    epr

    opor

    tion

    ofan

    noun

    cem

    ent

    days

    that

    resu

    ltin

    jum

    ps.

    Pan

    elA

    US

    TY

    FV

    TU

    TB

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    λt

    0.34

    290.

    3429

    0.34

    290.

    3161

    0.31

    610.

    3161

    0.32

    130.

    3213

    0.32

    130.

    1641

    0.16

    410.

    1641

    0.13

    200.

    1320

    0.13

    200.

    0970

    0.09

    730.

    0955

    0.10

    940.

    1094

    0.10

    990.

    0933

    0.09

    330.

    0930

    0.04

    060.

    0406

    0.04

    090.

    0530

    0.05

    310.

    0520

    θ t-6

    .04e

    -4-5

    .79e

    -4-2

    .64e

    -3-5

    .16e

    -4-5

    .16e

    -4-2

    .16e

    -3-2

    .84e

    -4-2

    .72e

    -4-1

    .07e

    -3-4

    .29e

    -4-4

    .38e

    -4-1

    .02e

    -4-2

    .80e

    -5-3

    .30e

    -53.

    75e-

    45.

    38e-

    42.

    64e-

    46.

    52e-

    43.

    10e-

    41.

    40e-

    44.

    08e-

    42.

    24e-

    41.

    27e-

    43.

    17e-

    41.

    02e-

    45.

    50e-

    51.

    80e-

    48.

    60e-

    53.

    30e-

    58.

    80e-

    5ju

    mp-

    indu

    ced

    0.31

    870.

    3264

    0.26

    090.

    3697

    0.36

    970.

    3727

    0.43

    060.

    4332

    0.41

    580.

    5551

    0.56

    120.

    5255

    0.41

    960.

    4597

    0.17

    52va

    rian

    ce0.

    1261

    0.12

    350.

    1342

    0.13

    110.

    1317

    0.12

    610.

    1190

    0.12

    150.

    1000

    0.10

    460.

    1060

    0.09

    170.

    2458

    0.23

    760.

    2232

    30

  • Pan

    elB

    US

    TY

    FV

    TU

    TB

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    all

    exp

    rec

    N.ju

    mps

    +10

    0286

    913

    392

    482

    698

    682

    607

    7532

    228

    735

    473

    418

    55N

    .ju

    mps

    per

    year

    ++

    41.3

    842

    .25

    36.4

    242

    .24

    42.7

    438

    .34

    42.9

    743

    .41

    39.6

    422

    .83

    23.3

    819

    .10

    19.8

    220

    .69

    15.0

    3N

    .an

    noun

    cem

    ent

    days

    839

    718

    121

    759

    670

    8954

    648

    165

    473

    411

    6283

    171

    012

    1N

    .ju

    mps

    onan

    noun

    cem

    ent

    days

    612

    534

    7853

    948

    554

    348

    314

    3411

    010

    010

    245

    209

    36ju

    mps

    onan

    n.da

    ysov

    eral

    lju

    mps

    0.61

    0.61

    0.59

    0.58

    0.59

    0.55

    0.51

    0.52

    0.45

    0.34

    0.35

    0.29

    0.52

    0.50

    0.65

    jum

    pson

    ann.

    days

    over

    allan

    n.da

    ys0.

    730.

    740.

    640.

    710.

    720.

    610.

    640.

    650.

    520.

    230.

    240.

    160.

    290.

    290.

    30ju

    mps

    onC

    PI

    ann.

    days

    9685

    1179

    736

    7970

    922

    193

    1412

    2ju

    mps

    onC

    PI

    over

    jum

    pson

    ann.

    days

    0.16

    0.16

    0.14

    0.15

    0.15

    0.11

    0.23

    0.22

    0.26