why should economists be interested in cultural policy

4
5/25/2018 WhyShouldEconomistsBeInterestedinCulturalPolicy-slidepdf.com http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/why-should-economists-be-interested-in-cultural-policy Why Should Economists be Interested in Cultural Policy? DAVID THROSBY  Department of Economics, Macquarie University, Sydney, Australia Cultural policy is an area of public policy-making with signifi- cant economic content. This paper suggests five areas where the theories, tools, and methods of economic analysis can make a contribution to the formation of a rational cultural policy: support  for the creative arts; cultural goods in international trade; the management of cultural assets; industry and innovation; and  foreign policy.  I Introduction In recent years, cultural policy has begun to figure more prominently in national and interna- tional policy agendas around the world. An important driver of this trend has been a grow- ing recognition of the contribution the cultural sector makes to output, employment, incomes, exports and growth in the economy. This fact alone might be sufficient to indicate a positive answer to the question posed in the title of this paper. But there is more to it than is implied simply by an appeal to industry economics. This paper suggests five areas where the theories, tools and methods of economic analysis can make a contribution to the formation of a rational cultural policy: support for the creative arts; cultural goods in international trade; the management of cultural assets; industry and innovation; and foreign policy. These issues have particular relevance in Australia at the present time, given that the federal government intends to introduce a new national cultural policy during its present term.  II Supp ort for the Arts To the extent that developed countries have had an explicit cultural policy in the past, such policies have mainly focussed on the creative arts. Elements have included: subsidy for artistic production by artists and arts organisations; sup- port for cultural institutions such as museums and galleries; assistance to consumers to encour- age access and participation; use of regulatory instruments such as copyright protection for cre- ative works; and support for arts education. One of the longest-running debates in the field of cultural economics 1 has been whether or not there is a plausible economic rationale for policy interventions in this area (Towse, 1997, pp. 499–719; Frey, 2011). Many suggestions have been put forward to explain the existing levels of arts subsidy, including rent-seeking and regulatory capture by artists, and the possi- bility that the arts are merit goods. The most persuasive argument from the viewpoint of neo- classical economics is that the arts are a case of market failure. If the production of artistic goods and services yields public-good benefits JEL classification: Z11 Correspondence: David Throsby, Department of Economics, Macquarie University, Sydney, Australia. Email: [email protected] 1 A field now established as a mature sub-discipline of economics; for overviews of the field, see Throsby (1994, 2006), Towse (2011). THE ECONOMIC RECORD, VOL. 88, SPECIAL ISSUE, JUNE, 2012, 106–109 106  2012 The Economic Society of Australia doi: 10.1111/j.1475-4932.2012.00808.x

Upload: dora-leitao-xarepe

Post on 15-Oct-2015

12 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Economia da Cultura

TRANSCRIPT

  • ists be Interested in

    THE ECONOMIC RECORD, VOL. 88, SPECIAL ISSUE, JUNE, 2012, 106109Why Should Econom

    Cultural Policy?

    DAVID TH

    uar

    puperf ea rgoos;

    exports and growth in the economy. This factalone might be sufficient to indicate a positiveanswer to the question posed in the title of thispaper. But theresimply by an apppaper suggests fitools and methomake a contriburational culturalarts; cultural goomanagement of cultural assets; industry andinnovation; and foreign policy. These issueshave particular relevance in Australia at thepresent time, given that the federal government

    and galleries; assistance to consumers to encour-age access and participation; use of regulatoryinstruments such as copyright protection for cre-

    arts education.ates in the fieldwhether or not

    ic rationale fora (Towse, 1997,any suggestionslain the existing

    levels of arts subsidy, including rent-seekingand regulatory capture by artists, and the possi-bility that the arts are merit goods. The mostpersuasive argument from the viewpoint of neo-

    JEL classification: Z11

    Correspondence: David Throsby, Department of

    Economics, Macquarie University, Sydney, Australia.Email: [email protected]

    1 A field now established as a mature sub-disciplineof economics; for overviews of the field, see Throsby(1994, 2006), Towse (2011).intends to introduce a new national culturalpolicy during its present term.

    classical economics is that the arts are a case ofmarket failure. If the production of artisticgoods and services yields public-good benefits 2012 The Economdoi: 10.1111/j.1475is more to it than is impliedeal to industry economics. Thisve areas where the theories,ds of economic analysis cantion to the formation of apolicy: support for the creativeds in international trade; the

    ative works; and support forOne of the longest-running debof cultural economics1 has beenthere is a plausible econompolicy interventions in this arepp. 499719; Frey, 2011). Mhave been put forward to expDepartment of Economics, Macq

    Cultural policy is an area ofcant economic content. This patheories, tools, and methods ocontribution to the formation offor the creative arts; culturalmanagement of cultural assetforeign policy.

    I IntroductionIn recent years, cultural policy has begun to

    figure more prominently in national and interna-tional policy agendas around the world. Animportant driver of this trend has been a grow-ing recognition of the contribution the culturalsector makes to output, employment, incomes,106

    ic Society of Australia-4932.2012.00808.xROSBY

    ie University, Sydney, Australia

    blic policy-making with signifi-suggests five areas where the

    conomic analysis can make aational cultural policy: supportds in international trade; theindustry and innovation; and

    II Support for the ArtsTo the extent that developed countries have

    had an explicit cultural policy in the past, suchpolicies have mainly focussed on the creativearts. Elements have included: subsidy for artisticproduction by artists and arts organisations; sup-port for cultural institutions such as museums

  • in addition to the private benefits enjoyed byconsumers, a prima facie case for governmentintervention may be established, as long as thebenefits to be gained from intervention outweighthe costs.

    case for special treatment; it is argued that thecultural content of these goods yields value tothe community that is not reflected in markettransactions. Such value may be expressible asthe communitys willingness to pay for thesocial benefits derived from local cultural indus-tries,3 and also possibly as a cultural value thattranscends economic evaluation, reflected in the

    2012 WHY SHOULD ECONOMISTS BE INTERESTED IN CULTURAL POLICY? 107From a policy standpoint, the validity of themarket-failure case for arts support must reston whether or not there is empirical evidencefor significant public-good effects, and if so,whether the community is willing to pay forthem out of taxation or by some other means.Such evidence was gathered for Australia morethan two decades ago (Throsby & Withers,1984), and more recently a study of willingnessto pay for conservation of cultural heritagefound positive results (Allen Consulting Group,2005). However, contemporary processes of cul-tural policy formation would be helped by newdata in this area, especially given improvementsin techniques for measuring demand for publicgoods.

    III Cultural TradeCultural goods and services such as films,

    television programs, etc. have presented prob-lems for international trade negotiations eversince the formation of the GATT in 1947. Whenthe WTO was established in 1993, France andCanada proposed that it should include anexception for cultural products. This was notaccepted, but a de facto exemption for audio-visual products has existed in the GeneralAgreement on Trade in Services (GATS),because countries can decline to make commit-ments for these specific products; this provisionallows governments to pursue their own culturalpolicies of protection for domestic producersand distributors, if they so desire.Economists have taken a keen interest in

    these issues.2 The argument for treating culturalproducts differently in trading arrangementsdepends on a definition of such products thatdifferentiates them from ordinary commercialgoods. It is now generally agreed that culturalgoods and services exhibit three distinct charac-teristics: they require creativity in their manu-facture; they convey symbolic meaning ormessages; and they embody, at least potentially,some intellectual property. It is the second ofthese properties that is the principal basis of the

    2 For overviews, see Acheson and Maule (2006),Schulze (2011). 2012 The Economic Society of Australiaimportance to society of issues such as culturalidentity, diversity, etc.

    IV Cultural AssetsAn important aspect of cultural policy con-

    cerns the efficient management of a countrys,regions or local communitys cultural assets.Economics has made a contribution to under-standing this problem by proposing the conceptof cultural capital as a distinctive form of capi-tal in the economy (Throsby, 1999; Ulibarri,2000; Cheng, 2006; Wang, 2007). Cultural capi-tal includes tangible assets such as heritagebuildings, artworks, etc., and intangible culturalitems such as language, rituals, traditional skills,etc. These are assets which embody or give riseto a distinctive form of value over and abovewhatever economic value they may possess.This specific value has been labelled culturalvalue, and theoretical and policy interest liesin identifying and measuring it in terms thatare objectively distinguishable from the sortsof value measured by the tools of economicanalysis.4

    Research on the nature of cultural capital ineconomics has pointed to the parallels betweenthis concept and that of natural capital as it hasevolved in environmental and ecological eco-nomics. Both forms of capital have been inher-ited from the past, will deteriorate if notmaintained and impose a duty of care in theinterests of intergenerational equity. Both canbe integrated into the framework of sustain-able development as a basis for formulatingstrategies for long-term management (Rizzo &Throsby, 2006).The immediate issue for cultural policy con-

    cerns finding the optimal balance between theeconomic and cultural values yielded in the flow

    3 As revealed, for example, in a study of Australiandemand for local content in television programs(Papandrea, 1999).

    4 Measurement issues are discussed in OBrien(2010).

  • of services provided by cultural capital assets. issues. But their economic implications are not

    108 ECONOMIC RECORD JUNEThis may be interpreted as identifying the trade-offs implied in a social welfare function inwhich economic and cultural value are argu-ments. Such information may assist, for exam-ple, in deciding whether or not to demolish ahistoric building that stands in the way of adevelopment project: How much economicreturn is a society prepared to give up in orderto achieve a certain cultural payoff?

    V Cultural IndustryOver the past ten years or so the concept

    of the creative economy has taken shape(UNCTAD, 2010). Following the establishmentof the Creative Industries Task Force in the UKin 1997, interest grew in a number of countries,notably in Europe, in the creative industries as adynamic subsector of the macroeconomy thatcontributes significantly to growth in output andto employment creation (Caves, 2000). In par-ticular, these industries are seen as importantdrivers of innovation which lead in turn to tech-nological change, growth and competitiveadvantage both for businesses and for wholeeconomies.The cultural industries those producing cul-

    tural goods and services as defined above area subset of the creative economy; they includethe arts, film, media, digital applications such asvideo games, publishing, architecture, designand fashion industries, all of which conveysome cultural content in their output (Throsby,2008). In policy terms, these industries lie at theintersection between cultural and economicpolicy. The fact that they all contribute in oneway or another to the cultural wellbeing ofsociety makes them an object of interest topolicy-makers concerned with the generation ofcultural and social value in the community. Atthe same time, the very real contribution theseindustries make to economic outcomes meansthat they attract the attention of ministersresponsible for employment, innovation, tradeand industrial development.

    VI Foreign PolicyApart from trade as discussed above, econo-

    mists have two reasons for taking an interest incultural policy when seen in an internationalcontext. The first has to do with cultural diplo-macy, international cultural relations and theexercise of soft power. At first glance thesemight seem like purely diplomatic or politicalfar below the surface. The adage where cultureleads, trade follows is more than just an articleof faith. There are strong arguments forbelieving that bilateral economic relations aresignificantly enhanced through the mutual under-standing fostered by cultural exchanges andintercultural dialogue. Cultural policy in thisarea requires a collaborative endeavour betweenministries for culture and foreign affairs.The second aspect of international economics

    of concern to cultural policy relates to the roleof culture in development (Sen, 2004; Common-wealth Group on Culture and Development,2010). The fact that culture is intimately con-nected with human development in the ThirdWorld has implications for the direction of for-eign aid provided by developed countries andalso for the lending strategies of agencies suchas the World Bank. It is becoming increasinglyclear that small-to-medium enterprises producingcultural goods and services for local markets indeveloping countries can contribute significantlyto economic empowerment, cultural cohesionand sustainable development. Thus, aid and lend-ing programs can be aimed at supporting small-scale cultural industries in developing countriesthrough measures such as technical assistance,micro-credit, business start-ups, investment fund-ing, entrepreneurial training, etc. Managing theseprocesses is of concern to cultural policy in bothgiving and receiving countries.

    VII ConclusionsThere are many policy arenas beyond those

    discussed above which demonstrate why econo-mists should be interested in cultural policy,including education, urban and regional devel-opment, media and communications, labourmarkets and intellectual property law (Throsby,2010). Economists in a number of countries inEurope, North and South America, Asia andelsewhere have made important contributions tothe cultural policy debate in all of these arenas.In Australia, by contrast, there has been littleinterest shown by economists in discussion ofcultural policy issues. It may be hoped that theprocess of formulating a new national culturalpolicy in this country currently underway couldbring about a reversal in this state of affairs,if only because ABS data for the Australianeconomy in various years indicate that: thecreative industries comprise around 3 per centof GDP; the value of production of cultural 2012 The Economic Society of Australia

  • goods and services is more than $50 billion perannum; the cultural industries account for about4 per cent of employed persons; annual fundingfor cultural activities by federal, state and localgovernments is almost $7 billion; and about 4per cent of household spending is on culturalproducts. In the words of former Prime MinisterPaul Keating,5 this could be described as abeautiful set of numbers.

    REFERENCES

    Acheson, K. and Maule, C. (2006), Culture in Inter-national Trade, in Ginsburgh, V. and Throsby, D.(eds), Handbook of the Economics of Art andCulture, vol. 1. Elsevier North-Holland, Amster-dam; 114182.

    Papandrea, F. (1999), Willingness to Pay for Domes-tic Television Programming, Journal of CulturalEconomics, 23, 14764.

    Rizzo, I. and Throsby, D. (2006 ), Cultural Heritage:Economic Analysis and Public Policy, in Gins-burgh, V. and Throsby, D. (eds), Handbook of theEconomics of Art and Culture, vol. 1. Elsevier North-Holland, Amsterdam; 9831016.

    Schulze, G.G. (2011), International Trade, in Towse,R. (ed.), Handbook of Cultural Economics, 2ndedn. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham; 23644.

    Sen, A. (2004), How Does Culture Matter?, in Rao,V. & Walton, M. (eds), Culture and Public Action.Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA: 3758.

    Throsby, D. (1994), The Production and Consump-tion of the Arts: a View of Cultural Economics,Journal of Economic Literature, XXXII: 129.

    Throsby, D. (1999), Cultural Capital, Journal of Cul-

    2012 WHY SHOULD ECONOMISTS BE INTERESTED IN CULTURAL POLICY? 109Allen Consulting Group (2005), Valuing the Price-less: the Value of Historic Heritage in Australia.Research Report 2. Heritage Chairs and Officials ofAustralia and New Zealand, Sydney.

    Caves, R.E. (2000), Creative Industries: ContractsBetween Art and Commerce. Harvard UniversityPress, Cambridge, MA.

    Cheng, S.W. (2006), Cultural Goods Production,Cultural Capital Formation and the Provision ofCultural Services, Journal of Cultural Economics,30, 26386.

    Commonwealth Group on Culture and Development(2010), Commonwealth Statement on Culture andDevelopment. Commonwealth Foundation, London.

    Commonwealth of Australia (1994). Creative Nation:Commonwealth Cultural Policy. Department ofCommunications and the Arts, Canberra.

    Frey, B.S. (2011), Public Support, in Towse, R.(ed.), Handbook of Cultural Economics, 2nd edn.Edward Elgar, Cheltenham; 3707.

    Ginsburgh, V.A. and Throsby, D. (eds) (2006), AHandbook of the Economics of Art and Culture,vol. 1. Elsevier North-Holland, Amsterdam.

    OBrien, D. (2010), Measuring the Value of Culture:A Report for the Department for Culture, Mediaand Sport. DCMS, London.

    5 It might be noted in the present context that Keat-ing was the architect of Australias first significantcultural policy, Creative Nation, born 1994, died withthe change of Federal government in 1996; seeCommonwealth of Australia (1994). 2012 The Economic Society of Australiatural Economics, 23, 312.Throsby, D. (2006), Introduction and Overview,

    in Ginsburgh, V. and Throsby, D. (eds), Handbookof the Economics of Art and Culture, vol. 1. Else-vier North-Holland, Amsterdam; 322.

    Throsby, D. (2008), Modelling the Cultural Industries,International Journal of Cultural Policy, 14, 21732.

    Throsby, D. (2010), The Economics of CulturalPolicy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Throsby, D. and Withers, G.A. (1984), What PriceCulture? Occasional Paper Series, Australia Coun-cil, Sydney.

    Towse, R. (ed.) (1997), Cultural Economics: The Arts,the Heritage and the Media Industries. EdwardElgar, Cheltenham.

    Towse, R. (ed.) (2011), A Handbook of Cultural Eco-nomics, 2nd edn. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.

    Ulibarri, C.A. (2000), Rational Philanthropy and Cul-tural Capital, Journal of Cultural Economics, 24,13546.

    UNCTAD (2010), The Creative Economy 2010. Uni-ted Nations Conference on Trade and Development,Geneva.

    Wang, X. (2007), An Analysis of Optimal Allocationand Accumulation of Cultural Capital, DoshishaUniversity Policy and Management, 9, 197213.