world bank documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. policy incentive, diversification...

52
ReportNo. 14564-CE Sri Lanka Nonplantation Crop Sector Policy Alternatives March 20, 1996 Agriculture and Natural Resources Division Country Department I South Asia Region ke~~2 : z-0''0 'f'"''';''.''X'''''''ze''i'WSv.. X t ' '''; ,- ,t,e,~~~~~~~~~~~~< ''t,,.t- ~~~~~~~~, ;E7 j.#t6 *''i,'atF .. 7W.. ;,7 .j !_ ,. ,' ,:. ',,.:'''_ D~ocument of -the' Wordd Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Upload: others

Post on 07-Apr-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

Report No. 14564-CE

Sri LankaNonplantation Crop Sector Policy AlternativesMarch 20, 1996

Agriculture and Natural Resources DivisionCountry Department ISouth Asia Region

ke~~2

: z-0''0 'f'"''';''.''X'''''''ze''i'WSv.. X t

' '''; ,- ,t,e,~~~~~~~~~~~~< ''t,,.t-

~~~~~~~~, ;E7 j.#t6 *''i,'atF

..

7W.. ;,7 .j

!_

,. ,' ,:. ',,.:'''_

D~ocument of -the' Wordd

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Page 2: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

CURRENCY EQUIVALENTS(December 1995)

Currency Unit = Sri Lankan Rupee (SL Rs.)SL Rs.53.98 = US$1.0

SL Rs.1.0 = US$0.019

WEIGHTS AND MEASURESI hectare (ha) = 2.47 acres

ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS

ARP - Agricultural Research PolicyARTI - Agrarian Research and Training InstituteBOC - Bank of CeylonCARl -Central Agricultural Research InstituteCARP - Council on Agricultural Research PolicyCBC - Commercial Bank of CeylonCBSL - Central Bank of Sri LankaCRBs - Cooperative Rural BanksCWE - Cooperative Wholesale EstablishmentDRC - Domestic Resource CostEPC - Effective Protection CoefficientFCD - Food Commissioner's DepartmentFPS - Floor Price SchemeGOSL - Government of Sri LankaGPS - Guaranteed Price SchemeHFC - High-value Food CropHNB - Hatton National BankHORD - Horticultural Research and Development InstituteIIMI - International Irrigation Management InstituteLDO - Land Development OrdinanceMALF - Ministry of Agriculture Lands and ForestryMASL - Mahaweli Autlhority of Sri LankaMECs - Minor Export CropsMPCs - Multipurpose CooperativesNAFNS - National Agriculture, Food and Nutrition StrategyNCRCS - New Comprehensive Rural Credit SchemeOFCs - Other Food Crops, a.k.a. Other Field CropsPB - People's BankPMB - Paddy Marketing BoardRCD - Rural Credit Department (of CBSI.)RFI - Rural Financial IntermediaryRRDBs - Regional Rural Development BanksRRDI - Rice Research and Development InstituteSANASA - see TCCSSAEP - Second Agricultural Extension ProjectSSM - Sarvadava Shramadana MovementTCCS - Thrift and Credit Cooperative SocietyTEWA - Termination of Employees ActWP# - Working Paper No. (6 in total, available on request)

Page 3: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

SRI LANKA

NONPLANTATION CROP SECTOR POLICY ALTERNATIVES

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY .................................... i

I. THE PROBLEM .................................... 1Sectoral Goals and Strategies ............................. 1The Policy Dilenmma ................................... 3

II. MARKETS ........................................ 3Output Markets ...................................... 3

Rice ........................................ 3Wheat .4Other Food Crops (OFC) ............................ 5Fruits and Vegetables .............................. 6

Input Markets ....................................... 7Fertilizer . ...................................... 7Seeds ......................................... 7

III. INCENTIVE POLICY. 8Price, Trade and Marketing Policy. 8Incentive Coefficients - NPCs, EPCs and ESCs. 9Agriculture versus Industry .11Agriculture versus Agriculture . 11Comparative Advantage - DRCs .13Irrigation Subsidy - Cost and Distribution .13Irrigation Policy Reform .14Trade Policy Refonn ................................. 16Price Fluctuations and Trade .18

This report is based on the output of two workshops in Sri Lanka, four background papers written by local Sri Lankanconsultants, and the findings of a mission to Sri Lanka in November-December 1994. Mission members were Robert Huntand Douglas Lister (Joint Task Managers SAIAN). Shahid Khandker (PSP), Terrence Abeysekera (SAISL), and PeterBloch, Antonio Brandao, Paul Harrison and Forhad Shilpi (SAlAN Consultants). Input was also received from PeerReviewers and Departmental management and staff. The Country Director is Ms. Mieko Nishimizu (SAIDR) and theDivision Chief is Mr. Ridwan Ali (SAIAN). The Green Cover draft was widely disseminated among Government officialsand various institutions and individuals in Sri Lanka in September-October 1995. A revised draft report, together with thedrafts of dissemination proceedings and responses to major comments was resubmitted for comment in January 1996.Thereafter, some factual errors were corrected and issues relating to sequencing were included.

Background papers were prepared in Sri Lanka by staff and consultants of ARTI (Marketing), CARP (Technology Transfer),IMI (Paddy Land Alternatives), MARGA (Exports), and two independent consultants Messrs. S. Berugoda andR.D. Wanigaratne (Land). Copies are available from the institutions and individuals.

Page 4: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

IV. RURAL FINANCE .......... ........................ 18Overview ....................................... 18Market Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18Credit Financing ................. ... ... ... ... ... ... . 19Interest Rates, Savings and Input Financing ....... . . . . . . . . . . . . 20Credit Constraints . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21Credit and Subsistence Agriculture ........ . .. . . . . . . . . . . .. . . 23Rural Credit System - Outlook ......... . .. . . .. . . . .. . . .. . . 24,Policy Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

V. LAND ........................ ..................... . 25Land Tenure Policy .............. ... .. ... .. .. ... .. .. . 25Farm Size ....................... .... .... ..... .. . 25Land Ownership ................. ... ... ... ... ... ... . 26Land Utilization and Cropping Intensity ....... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27Cropping Pattern ................ ... ... .... .. ... .... . 27Land Market ....................... .... .... ..... .. . 29Policy Conclusions ............... ... ... ... .. ... ... .. . 29

VI. FARM FAMILY INCOME AND OUTPUT ADJUSTMENT ..... . . . 30

VII. TECHNOLOGY GENERATION AND TRANSFER ...... . . . . . . . . 33Overview ....................................... . 33Research/Extension Link ........... .. .. .. .. .. . .. .. .. .. . 33Policy Conclusions and Proposed Actions ....... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

VIII. PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER ......... . . . .. . . . . .. . . . . . . 34The Current Situation - What We have Learned ...... . . . . . . . . . . . 34Policy Choices - Future Directions for the Sector ...... . . . . . . . . . . 34The Growth Challenge ............ .. .. .. ... . .. .. ... . . . 35Reforn Priorities ................. ... .. .... ... .. .... . 36Sequencing Policy Reform .............................. 37Government's Stance on Sectoral Reform ..................... 38Discussion and Dissemination in Sri Lanka .................... 39'

BACKGROUND WORKING PAPERS (Separate volume available on request)

1. Domestic Marketing in the Nonplantation Crops Sector of Sri Lanka2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in

Sri Lanka3. Outward Orientation, Income Distribution and Employment in Sri Lanka's

Nonplantation Crop Sector4. Rural Finance and Sectoral Performance in Sri Lanka5. Land Tenure Issues in the Nonplantation Crop Sector of Sri Lanka6. Working Paper Tables

Page 5: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Rural Staynation - Resolvinp the Dilemma1. Growth from nonplantation agriculture remains stagnant and income low. The primary source of thisgrowth has been Other Food Crops (OFCs - chilies, onions, potatoes, etc). Assuming no data errors, OFC output isgrowing in intensity, as the total area under these crops has not grown. More rapid output growth of these higher valuedOFCs could be a way out of the stagnation in the sector, but so far this has not happened. With over 60% ofSri Lanka's population rurally based and mainly in the nonplantation sector, the sector's stagnation is of growing concernto Government, particularly in terms of its implications for rural poverty. Despite its low returns per acre relative toother food crops and Government support for more diversified crop-land use, low-valued paddy remains the dominantcrop. Why this is so has been a dilemma.

2. Two rural markets, the off-farm labor market and the land market, are at the root of the output puzzle.Off-farm wage rates are higher than returns to family labor for all crops except paddy. With free water, farm familiesmaximize income through growing paddy and working off-farm. Paddy's relatively low labor requirement maximizesoff-farm employment per farm family, while still fully utilizing the land. The lack of marketable title perpetuates thisstagnation in agriculture. Unavailability of title constrains farmers from increasing farm size and developing adiversified portfolio of income-generating crops. If the land market was working efficiently, able farmers would increasefarm size and farming activities and make the most of the commercial opportunities available to diversify a part of theircropping activities and so increase their incomes. Those with more advantage in off-farm activities would phase outof farming, specialize in off-farm activities and by doing so increase their incomes too. For now, all must do both.

The Study3. Workshops and discussions in 1993/94 in Colombo and background topic papers clearly established theneed to explain why more widespread use of diversification as a farm-income increasing strategy is not seen and to drawpolicy conclusions from the results. Examination of farm input and output markets and technology transfer shows noconstraints. Price and trade policies, and rural credit markets are also not responsible. But land and labor markets areseen as major determinants of farmers' behavior. The study's policy recommendations are aimed at getting nonplantationagriculture moving again, assuming that sustainable growth with equity is the desired policy goal. Importantly, duringthe study it became abundantly clear that access to the off-farm labor market was far more important than farm size forcreating equity in income-earning opportunities. Appreciation of the major role played by the off-farm labor marketis key to understanding of farmers' behavior and provides the basis for the direction of the recommendations.

The Findines4. Markets Work Well - generally. An important general finding is that, except for land, agriculturalmarkets in Sri Lanka are quite competitive. The ease with which buyers and sellers can participate ensures that thesemarkets work so well. This is very important, as it says that the often talked about "mudalali", or monopolisticmiddleman, is not really a force of any importance in the sector.

5. The Government and the Markets. Government itself has a major direct presence in most agriculturalmarkets. Being caught between the interests of the farmer and the consumer, Government's own performance here hasbeen erratic, at times taking the side of the farmer and then the consumer. The frequency and unpredictability ofchanges in these market interventions by Government has heightened market volatility, causing unforeseen losses forproducers and traders alike. This has greatly reduced private sector investment in the marketing process, particularlystorage, and has increased domestic marketing losses.

6. Towards a development partnership. Instead of reacting to every fluctuation, however minor, Governmentmust trust private sector marketing processes and adjust its own role to a background one of facilitating and promotecompetition in these processes. To fully convince the markets of the seriousness of its commitment to this approach,Government will need to divest itself of all marketing activities, through selling these off or closing them down.

7. Paddy Costs versus Competitiveness -- > Large Subsidies to Irrigation and Paddy. Overall, Sri Lankacurrently shows no comparative advantage in production of rice or OFCs in either major or minor, irrigated or rainfedagriculture. Domestic production is much more costly than imports. Obviously, with appropriate amendment in theincentive structure for farmers and improvement in productivity, this will change. While not all rice production isnoncompetitive with imports, a large amount is. This non-competitive output is currently maintained by massive-transfers amounting to US$250 million, or 3% of GDP annually. With no cost recovery, the annual equivalent of thesubsidy to major new irrigation systems is as much as Rs.50,000 (US$1,000) per ha per year. This is a transfer from

Page 6: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

ii

taxpayers to farmers, except that, instead of being in cash, Government predetermines how farmers should spend it, i.e.on irrigation. In return, 'armers grow a low-value crop, paddy, giving Govemment and the economy a very low returnon irrigation investment. The subsidy to paddy, paid by consumers through paying 30% more than world prices forrice, costs about US$125 million per year. In sum, close to 5% of GDP goes to supporting noncompetitive riceproduction. The concentration of irrigation expenditure on construction of large scale irrigation systems results in adistribution of the irrigation subsidy heavily skewed to few lucky farmers, about 3 % of all farmers. The situationcalls for substantive reform in both irrigation and trade policy.

8. Agriculture versus Industry -> a pro-irrigated agriculture bias. Government's trade policy, anti-agriculrure in the past, caused a bias in private investment away from agriculture. Now, progressive reduction inprotection for manufacturing industry, combined with continued protection for import-competing crops (rice, chiliesonions and potatoes) and massive subsidies to agriculture (primarily to large scale irrigation schemes) with no costrecovery, has leveled the playing field overall, so that there appears to be almost no difference in protection given toagriculture and industry. But the average situation hides major variations within agriculture. Plantation crops receivevery little protection. The main beneficiary from irrigation subsidies is output from large-scale irfigated agriculture,especially the newer schemes. By contrast, production based on minor irrigated agriculture benefits less, and rainfedagriculture not at all. In addition, trade policy provides import competing crops, like paddy and chilies etc, withsubstantial protection over most manufacturing industry, especially where grown on large scale irrigation systems.

9. Agriculture versus Agriculture -- > a bias against export crops. Within agriculture, trade policy'ssubstantial protection against import competition causes a strong bias against export crops. Faced with such treatment,Government's stated policy and exhortation for increasing exports from agriculture has had no real impact on producers.Trade reform is badly needed to level the playing field between import and export crops and between producers andconsumers, especially low income consumers.

10. Irrigation's Future - Subsidies or Reform? Sri Lanka's high level of rice self-sufficiency has been verycostly to achieve, as has its efforts to alleviate poverty through large-scale irrigation developments. The goals andstrategies here clearly deserve to be reconsidered, even if only because of their likely financial unsustainability. To start,it must be accepted that, in economic terms irrigation water, unlike drainage, is a private good, and so should bedirected by market forces. For this, the basic legal and institutional structures needed to permit market forces to operatemust be developed. These center around enforceable water property rights for individual farmers and water markets.Only this will permit efficiency and sustainability in utilization of this vital resource.

11. Trade Reform - good for Growth and Poverty Alleviation. It is important for Government to come togrips with trade reform right away. Although a phased reduction in import tariffs on rice and other import-competingcrops will lower onfarm earnings, this will impact on large farmers only. If reasonably phased, this will be small andwell within annual price fluctuations, making it invisible. At the same time, farmers will have the opportunity to phaseinto production of higher valued export crops. With a decline in rice prices, consumers will benefit, as will most smallfarmers because they consume more rice than they produce. Proportionately, this will be very important for the poor,both rural and urban. Price stability will improve, as seasonal price fluctuations in world rice markets are far less thanin domestic markets.

12. Rural Credit Markets. Presently demand for rural credit is limited because input financing is now largelyfrom "own sources", made possible by the high volume of off-farm earnings. Rural credit markets, though presentlylimited, are quite competitive and becoming more diverse. Stimulated by the scope for reducing of the cost of credit,new forms of rural banking, via semi-formal, NGO-type, institutions, are developing to meet customers needs andmarket niches. The lion's share of this business is to meet rural demand for nonagricultural loans, since, as noted, mostagricultural needs are currently more than met by off-farm earnings.

13. Concessional credit from the Government, NCRCS loans, are responsible for only a very small share(7.5 %) of input financing in nonplantation crop agriculture. The explanation for the low utilization rate NCRCS loanslies in the relative interest rates for saving and borrowing and the small volume of inputs per farmer. The savings depositrate is so well below the NCRCS concessional loan rate that it makes sense for small farmers to pay for inputs out ofsurplus earnings. In the meantime, rural savings are so large relative to purchased inputs, that farmers could well affordto purchase more inputs without credit. This also means that Government's concessional credit program has no impacton current sector performance. Also, NCRCS loans generally do not reach the poor farmers. Yet subsidized interest*rates and losses underwritten in the NCRCS program combine to cost the budget about US$4 million per year. So theprogram should be discontinued. As for the poorest farmers, the Government may consider a tightly targeted program.

Page 7: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

iii

14. But all is not well in rural credit markets. With rapid sectoral growth, the demand for rural credit wouldincrease and the shallowness of the rural financial markets would become a problem, particularly in supplying long-termcredit so necessary for fixed investment. Furthermore, the poor health of the credit institutions could result in rapiddeterioration in loan portfolios and institutional viability in the absence of good management and tight supervision bybanking authorities. Also, at present, Government borrowing to meet a large fiscal deficit has pushed up interest ratesto a level that adversely affects viable economic activities in all sectors including agriculture.

15. Land - the forgotten factor market. Lack of a land market seriously constrains long-run sectorperformance. Government land is for lease only; intergenerational transfers are permitted, but not sale or sublease.In the absence of a land market, irrigation scheme settlers wishing to exit agriculture face a choice of abandoning avaluable farm or entering the uncertain informal market. Private sector land sales, the only ones permitted by law, arevery few, as disputed title makes these very difficult. Records show an extremely low turnover rate of private land.

16. Land Tenure Policy --> depresses returns to land. Government policy, aimed at equitable distributionof land, has fostered a smallholder agriculture. Land legislation and settlement administration has successively limitedfarm size and constrained the rights of both owners and operators. Government owns 55 % of nonplantation crop land,mainly in large scale irrigation systems. Private sector land is mainly in older, village-based minor irrigation schemes.Much private land is subject to ownership disputes. Population pressure and societal inheritance practices have causedsubstantial fragmentation on both private and public land, leaving average farm-size well below the public sectorirrigation scheme norm of I ha. Overall, 72 % of farms are below I ha. The cropping pattern is heavily paddy oriented,with an 80% share, despite the relatively low net income per ha. Farmers' inability to increase farm size and so earnan income from farming that is competitive with other possibilities causes them to grow paddy and work off farm. Thisdepresses returns to land and any investments in it, particularly investment in irrigation, and to human capital moreproductively employed off-farm.

17. Why Paddy? - because off-farm wages are high. Why do small farmers choose to continue to grow alow valued commodity, rice, when higher income crops are available? Simply because, for all crops except paddy, off-farm work pays higher wages than the hourly return to family labor. Faced with the inability to sell land and leaveagriculture or expand farm size and specialize in agriculture, the combination of paddy production and off-farmemployment provides the greatest income-earning opportunity. Labor Force Survey data, confirmed by individual villagesurveys, show that, on average, Sri Lankan farmers spend considerable time working off-farm, averaging 40% of familyincome from this. This pattern of use gives the most returns to farm family labor and so makes sense for the family.Although greater production of traditional import competing crops (e.g. chilies or onions) would substantially expandfarm income, because the resulting implicit family wage rate declines to below the off-farm wage rate, this woulddepress overall family income and so does not happen.

18. Breaking the Land Deadlock! Only Government can provide the means to break the deadlock here andallow the positive elements of market forces to go.to work. For public sector land, full privatization, i.e. fullymarketable, freehold title would be the best solution. In the absence of full privatization, long-term leases with provisionfor transfer would be a major improvement. Legislation and programs to establish public and private sector institutionsand professions to facilitate development of land markets are also required. Only in this way can farm size adjustautomatically to changing commodity prices and increased risks. For private sector land, incentive systems to promoterapid resolution of disputed titles (i.e. tax penalties and rewards) are an immediate necessity. Land values in irrigationsettlements depend heavily on irrigation cost recovery policy. Therefore, amendment of irrigation cost recovery policyshould be transparent, and phased to avoid overvaluation and subsequent financial stress in land markets.

19. Subsistence Farmers - a problem within a problem. Where farm size is too small to generate an adequateincome and the family has insufficient access to the off-farm labor market, a problem of noncommercial or "subsistence"agriculture arises. Trapped in terms both of farm size and employability, these are non-commercial or subsistencefarmers. Broadbased intervention policies, such as floor prices or subsidized inputs, transfer financial benefits tocommercial agriculture, but have little impact on subsistence farmers' small incomes from farming. Separate programsneed to be developed to assist here But to succeed, program design must reflect a full appreciation of the currentsituation, especially the obstacles to growth for both subsistence farmers and the sector overall.

20. Extension and Research - a circular trap? Agricultural extension, the means for technology transfer,suffers from an "identity crisis". This is due to the supply driven nature of the present service in a demand driventworld. Organized along commodity lines, it is largely focussed on physical output, while its customers are concernedwith income. Periodically, it restructures itself in an attempt to come to grips with reality, but its inadequate incentive

Page 8: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

iv

structure leaves these efforts well short of what is needed. As a result, it is permanently out of touch with its customers'needs. Government should confine its extension activity to provision of information through broadbased multimediasystems, while customer specific activities should be privatized. Otherwise, it is difficult to see how to avoid regularrecurrence of such identity crises for the extension service. Placed on a firm commercial footing, all parts deliveringvalue added to commercial agriculture would flourish, while those not needed would be retrenched. In research,wholesale privatization may not be desirable. But, interaction with commercial, demand-oriented extension companieswould greatly aid in improving the focus and impact of research.

21. Private Extension and the Subsistence Farmer. At first glance, privatization of extension services forsubsistence agriculture may not appear feasible. Although it could help them, and so be socially desirable, individualfarmers may be unable to see the benefits and so unwilling to pay for them. Even where the benefits are seen, cash-flowproblems may limit access to this input. Government could very easily overcome this via a contract with privateextension companies to deliver these services to subsistence farmers, initially at a subsidized rate, as part of an overalldevelopment package for subsistence agriculture.

22. The Growth Challenge - Getting Agriculture Moving! Simply put, this is the fundamental challengefacing Sri Lankan policy makers. Years of policy induced stagnation have made the growth challenge facing the sectorand thus the economy very great. For sectoral growth to move from 2% to a modest 3.5% p.a., output from paddyland would need to grow year in and year out by about 5 % p.a., i.e. over 20 times its present rate (assuming the growthof OFCs remain the same as now and plantation crops grow at 1 % p.a.). This is simply not possible for paddy itself.Instead, to get agriculture moving the cropping pattern will need to change in response to a corrected incentive structure.

23. Government - a new role in commercial agriculture? What should be Govermment's contribution to thesector and in what form should it be made? To achieve the needed growth in a sustained manner, Government shouldrethink its role in the sector. Its traditional "interventionist" approach no longer has the impact needed. It is quite clearthat direct market interventions, regulations or appeals are no longer of any value if these are not in the best personalinterests of farmers in general. Instead of calling for the desired results, Government will need to use the signals towhich farmers now respond and set these so as to get the needed results. Government will need to adopt a moredistanced stance relative to its current "hands-on" mode and to operate more in the background, leaving the actualproduction and marketing entirely in private hands, including the allocation of inputs such as credit and land.

24. Government - a new approach to subsistence agriculture? Alongside this recornmercialization, directGovernment programs to address the needs of subsistence farmers must also be priority. At the core of this are carefullytargeted programs designed to relieve constraints to income generation for those who choose to remain in agriculture,and assist those who wish to exit agriculture to do so on the best possible terms. For individual persons exitingagriculture, it will be through expansion of off-farm employment by ensuring adequate infrastructure investment. Forthose remaining in agriculture, this will be by increasing productivity from enlarged farm size (from land freed as othersleave agriculture) and improved farming abilities.

25. Priorities for Agriculture: Priority actions to get agriculture moving again are: initiation of trade policyliberalization, adopting a policy of full private ownership of agricultural land and fully operational land markets,implementation of land privatization and land market development programs, commercialization of the irrigation system,through creating water property rights and markets and a system of management by owners, phasing out of allGovernment sponsored market intervention programs (including privatization of the PMB, CWE, all public sectorfinancial intermediaries, and the commercial activities of the Food Commissioners Department). This will allowmainstream agriculture to recommercialize. Generally, agricultural sector administrators should take the approach oftheir colleagues in industry and trade.

26. Sequencing Reforms: At present lower import protection and increased irrigation costs, which wouldreduce paddy profitability, may also reduce output. Without a well functioning land market, land utilization woulddecline while strong off-farm labor demand would absorb the surplus farm labor. Rural income may increase, butagricultural output and income would decline. But access to long-term credit is a prerequisite for smallholders to accessland markets and so expand. Long-term credit requires marketable collateral (titled, freehold land) and enforceablecredit discipline, which calls for institutional development in land titling and recording, as well as change from currentad hoc loan forgiveness interventions in agricultural credit to assistance in enforcement of legally binding loan contracts.Uncertainty in irrigation policy on water property rights and charges introduces uncertainty in land valuation, which willVdepress land markets. Finally, introduction of some taxation may be necessary to equalize any differences in assetacquisition costs between the nonplantation sector and other sectors. Otherwise, any difference will be capitalized into

Page 9: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

V

the market value of land, again making it difficult for smallholders to expand farm size. Any program to address theproblem must take these aspects into account in designing the sequence of reform.

27. Governiment's Preparedness: Government is well aware of the challenge it faces in revitalizing thenonplantation sector. In this regard, a major policy speech' noted the requirement for "substantive structural change",while noting Government's "confidence in the rural masses and their ability to make rational choices". The degree ofalignment between this statement of policy intent and the findings of this study shows a sound appreciation of the natureof the situation by Government. With the exception of agricultural markets, where Government intervention rather thanstructure or conduct of the market is the problem, the study's findings are in complete agreement with Government'spolicy intent. It is hoped that the study will provide greater depth to understanding the current situation and thus a basisfor improved design of reform policies and measures.

1/ Policy Statenient ot the Government of Sri Lanka on the Occasion of the opening of Parliament, 6 January, 1995,by H.E. Chandrika Bandaranaike Kuniaratunga. President.

Page 10: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,
Page 11: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

SRI LANKA

NONPLANTATION CROP SECTOR POLICY ALTERNATIVES

I. THE PROBLEM

1.1 Poor overall performance, shown by the very low growth rate in sectoral income, is the central problem. In theplantation sector the reasons for this are now quite well understood'. But, up to now, the determinants of performancein the nonplantation crop sector remain unexplained.

1.2 Agriculture is still one of the largest sectors in the economy, with 18% of GDP (excluding forestry and fishing -3.5% of GDP), about 45% of employment and 24% of gross exports in 1992. Sectoral growth has been poor, about

2% p.a (constant terms) over the past 10 years (1982-92), or half the national average. Some 65% of the populationlive in rural areas and are seen as largely dependent on agriculture for their livelihood.

1.3 Allocation of land for nonplantation crops is mainly for Paddy, a low valued commodity. Although averageincome per acre from Other Food Crops is three times that of Paddy, and, since 1980, the international price of ricehas declined, in real terms, by over 6% annually, this allocation has remained constant. Domestically, the averageannual decline of 1.4% in the domestic producer price over the past 10 years, has barely been offset by yield gains.This may explain why the sector, with 25% of total employment, still only receives 12 % of GDP. But the question ofwhy or how such resource allocation emerged, and what sustains it, unanswered thus far, is central to explaining sectorperformance. Land tenure policy and conditions in the off-farm labor market emerges as pivotal here.

Sectoral Goals aiid Strategies

1.4 The National Agriculture, Food and Nutrition Strategy (NAFNS)2, published in 1984 remains the solecomprehensive sectoral policy document available. It took as a starting point GOSL's four sectoral objectives, namely:

* Self-sufriciency in basic foods, rice, milk, sugar, fish and pulses;_ Expansion of export capacity to increase agriculture's contribution to the balance of payments;* Enhancement of incomes and creation of new employment opportunities in the rural sector; and- Improved nutritional status of the people.

1.5 Implementation strategies in the NAFNS document for the nonplantation crop sector centered on paddy. Withrice self-sufficiency perceived as virtually attained, the concern was disposal of surpluses. Substitution for importedwheat, 'iversification of land out of paddy, and concessional supplemental nutrition programs were all proposed.Substantive progress towards sugar self-sufficiency was seen as a major near-term objective. Agroindustry was seenas "a key element in generation of off-farm employment and the basis for rural industries'. A conducive policyatmosphere was seen as essential here. In development of "Other Field Crops' (almost all 'Other Food Crops") 'thetraditional in-built bias in favor of rice' was noted as a major inhibiting factor to progress in diversification.

1.6 As with many small island countries and isolated areas, the history of Sri Lanka is bound up with the continuousstruggle for survival, particularly the struggle to ensure adequate food supplies. Consequently, it is normal to find thatall facets of rice, the staple food of most Sri Lankans, are a major focal point of the socio-economic history. Forcenturies, "temple and tank" (irrigation) were the focal point of rural life. History illustrates how a ruler's worth wasmeasured in no small part by his contribution to these two elements3 . This perspective appears unchanged even today.Avoidance of dependency on volatile international markets drives the pursuit for food self-sufficiency. Investment inlarge-scale irrigation schemes has both supported this pursuit, and created land for the landless.

I/ See Sri Lanka Tree Crops Strategy, World Bank Report No. 12356-CE, July 5. 1994.

2/ National Agricultural and Food Strategy A Change in Perspective. National Planning Division, Ministy of Finance andPlanning, Colombo, Sri Lanka. June 1984.

3/ See "Food and [he People" R.L. Brohier, Lake House Publishers, Colombo, 1975.

Page 12: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

2

1.7 Overall, the strategy document felt that "There are good prospects to raise incomes and improve nutrition ofsmiallholders through removal of constraints to productivity, wider opportunities to produce and market their crops, anda more versatile and adaptive institutional framework to execute the required changes." The NAFNS document was notofficial Government policy, rather it was developed by a central Government agency and "presented for furtherdiscussion and review".

L .8 Following World War 11, the basic elements of current sectoral intervention by Government became a permanentfeature and progressively institutionalized. Direct Government intervention has been the strategy of all governments overthe past 30 years in pursuit of sectoral policy objectives; rice self-sufficiency being the primary one. In this scheme,domestic producer and consuiaer price policies are the central focus of medium-run policy measures, while in the longerrun fixed assets, particularly land, have been the focus of intervention. Trade policy was designed to be supportive ofdomestic price policy.

1.9 Policy discussion in response to declining sectoral performance, has ranged between promoting commercial,export-oriented agriculture and continued protection of a peasant-structured agriculture. Depending on the ministry(central or line) the call has been for more of the former or the latter; but sustained action has been negligible. On onehand caught between the populist sentiment embodied in the policy objectives and the high economic cost of theinterventionist strategy required to pursue them, and on the other between the desire for improved sector performanceand the possible political cost of pursuing this, Government has been unable to make any direct headway in rationalizingsector policy. With past policy measures now a tradition, the social dimension has overridden any commercialdimension to Sri Lanka's agricultural policy. There may be little conviction in the appropriateness of the currentobjectives and strategies, but there appears an equal inability to recast them. Unable to sustain high cost irrigationinvestment and with land reform possibilities exhausted, the objectives pursued implicitly narrowed to a more affordable,yet still politically acceptable set, namely:

o Food Security - redefined as "rice self-sufficiency at an affordable cost";* Cointrolling cost of living for the poor; and- Maintaining farm income.

1. 10 Pursuit of these objectives involved continuation of Government's dominance in the economic life of the sector,through direct regulation of price levels and land use, state trading, and direct control over trade. While this was acontinuation of earlier policies, over time there was an easing of legislation directing land use, and a reduction in statetrading with a concomitant relaxation in enforcement of Government set producer prices. Direct intervention in trade,although changed in character due to the reduction in state trading, remained as active as ever, with no change in thedisruptive nature of its ad hoc character. The primary motivation for these changes appears to have been the need tocontrol Government spending rather than improve sector performance. Reduction in state trading meant reduction forTreasury in the trading losses and financial charges it faced on behalf of the state trading agencies. With indirectintervention replacing the direct approach, underlying policy remained unchanged.

1.11 Despite Sri Lanka's good social indicators, this affordable-cost approach does not appear to be working. Theopportunity cost of defining "food security" in terms of "physical self-sufficiency" may actually be unaffordably highin terms of sectoral growth foregone. Certainly the current level of "food security" was purchased at a high cost throughinvestment in very capital-intensive irrigation schemes to produce a low valued commodity. This lack of growth in therural sector also constrains both direct and secondary growth in income and employment.

1.12 The new Government, elected in August 1994, in fulfillment of an election commitment, reduced some foodprices, particularly bread and rice. This was accomplished through increased import of wheat and resale as flour atsubsidized prices by the CWE (Cooperative Wholesale Enterprise), a major state trading agency. The negative impacton the domestic rice price required increased purchases by the PMB (Paddy Marketing Board), which was also requiredto sell rice purchased at below cost as part of the food price reduction effort. In addition, since the wheat flour subsidywas untargetted, its effects were regressive with the 20% highest income household receiving 32% of the subsidy andthe 20% lowest income households receiving only 9%. Subsequently, Government indicated that these measures weretemporary and that "a natural balance will be restored to the market place".

Page 13: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

3

The Policy Dilenmma

1.13 Despite its low returns per acre relative to other food crops and Government support for more diversified crop-land use, low-valued paddy remains the dominant crop. Why this is so has been a dilemma. Although net revenue peracre averages about four times that of paddy', with no growth in the 12% of cropped land allocated to Other FoodCrops (OFCs), diversification has been highly concentrated on a small area. With very little distributive element, theimpact on poverty alleviation is limited.

1.14 Diversification has been a policy of Government for sometime now, as manifest in the Amendment to theAgrarian Services Act discontinuing the restricted use of paddy land, and the gradual development of a research andextension capability in this area. Despite this, and the superior farm income generated, actual diversification of landuse is negligible, as growth in output of Other Food Crops has been intensively rather than extensively based. Thisoutput stagnation is a major concern to Government policy makers, and its cause, though frequently debated, remainsunidentified.

1.15 There appears to be some capacity for further expansion in output from traditional 'Other Food Crops' (i.e.import competing crops, primarily chilies, onions and potatoes), in view of the protection afforded through the traderegime. Although the present economic viability of these is questionable, creating an additional dilemma for policymakers, this does not explain the static allocation of land to production of these. Seasonal price fluctuations here arelikely to be relatively large. This would incline risk averse farmers towards lower, but more stable, income from paddyproduction. Nonetheless, the data indicates that existing producers not only continue in production but are actuallyintensifying output effort on the same area and thus risk. Also, the continuing decline in income from paddy could beexpected to at least partially offset aversion to risk. Finally, the impact of the somewhat arbitrary import regime forOFCs needs scrutiny to see if this source of price fluctuation can be reduced5.

1.16 The study systematically examines the performance of the concerned product and factor markets to determinetheir contribution to current sectoral performance and identify elements which might impede adjustment and growth.The report summarizes the detailed product and factor market assessments and interprets these in the light of the policymakers dilemma concerning policies needed to improve sectoral performance. Specific markets examined arepaddy/rice, and major OFCs (chilies, potatoes and onions) on the output side, and on the input side, purchased inputs(seed and fertilizer), rural finance, and land.

U. MARKETS'

OutDut Markets

Rice2.1 Structure. With over 800,000 mostly small farmers selling to numerous independent traders and millers (over7,000 in 1986, according to a PMB survey), who in turn supply milled rice to consumers, the domestic market forpaddy/rice is basically competitive. Because of the relatively low level of technology used, there is little marketconcentration at this stage, and charges for storage and distribution functions are reasonable, indicating competitivepricing. Information on prices is readily available, and there are no significant barriers to entry. Inputs for paddy/ricetrading such as trucks and casual labor are also readily available. The credit market is ready to provide both workingcapital and investment financing for mills and stores. Bank financed industrial credit lines have provided substantialinput financing for these.

2.2 Conduct. Although structurally competitive, the operation of the paddy market is heavily influenced byGovernment policy. Government's main intervention arm is PMB. It is responsible for administering the Guaranteed

4/ Cost of Cultivation of Agricultural Crops, Maha 1992/93. Socio-Economic & Planning Centre, Dept. of Agriculture, Peradeniya,March 1994, Tables 8 & 18. This factor varies from 3 to 7 depending upon the crop, year, and data base.

5/ Imports by state tnading agencies in high production season, a not infrequent occurrence. would not occur if the importer was a stricdlycommercial entity.

6/ Detailed analysis of performanlce of the domestic markets is in WP#I.

Page 14: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

4

Price Scheme (GPS), even though, for reasons of its small market share (25,000 tons annually or about 2% of themarketed quantity of paddy over the period 1989-93), it has been powerless to guarantee a price to producers. The factthat producer prices have been below the "guaranteed" price in the main harvest months confirms that PMB is no longereffective in carryiig out its main function. Also, given that PMB purchases paddy delivered to its stores and that mostof its purchases are from private traders and cooperatives, with only a small amount coming directly from farmers, itis likely that most of the margin between the "PMB" price and the "free market" price is captured by traders rather thangoing to producers. But activity in the wholesale market competes away much of this margin to the retail market andso to the consumer.

2.3 The other major Government lever over the rice market is tariff policy. Present policy is for imports to be madeby the private sector, either by normal licensed traders or by licensed 'bondsmen", who are pennitted to import withoutpaying duty until their rice is released onto the domestic market from bonded warehouses. Since November 1993, animport duty of 35 % (on a standardized import price of US$225/ton) has been maintained. In early December 1994, therate was reduced to 20%.

2.4 Performance. PMB's ineffectiveness in influencing prices has not been without substantial costs. Over time,PMB has incurred a heavy penalty for the relatively high prices which it has paid for paddy. For instance, in 1994,the wholesale market price for rice tended to be consistent with the open market price of paddy and in consequencePMBs own high procurement price plus costs associated with handling, storing and milling means that it has not beenable to cover its costs for rice when selling on the local market. Under instructions from the Government, in the secondhalf of 1994, PMB sold at least part of its stocks of rice at a price of Rs. I 1/kg (US$220/ton), resulting in a loss of aboutRs.4/kg (US$80/ton). PMB was expected to lose Rs.2/kg (US$40/ton) on its total rice sales during 1994. Totaloperating losses for 1994 were seen to be in the order of Rs. 150-200 million (US$3-4 million).

2.5 The wholesale price of rice in late 1994 was too low for imported rice to be released profitably onto the domesticmarket, although because of the need to rotate stocks, small quantities of imported rice have been sold by bondsmenat a loss, both to the Cooperative Wholesale Establishment (CWE) and through the Pettah market wholesalers. InDecember 1994, imported rice was being offered at a wholesale price of Rs. 16.75/kg (US$335/ton), but was meetingslow demand. To have fully covered the bondsmens' costs, a price of at least Rs. 19/kg (US$380/ton) or Rs. 17.3/kg(US$346/ton) with the new lower tariff, would have been required. This situation, which is not commerciallysustainable, results from: (a) a relatively high level of domestic paddy production; (b) a currently buoyant internationalmarket for rice; and (c) the availability of heavily subsidized flour and bread which are suppressing demand for rice.

2.6 Policy Conclusions. The Government's rice market policy has failed to achieve its objective of supportingproducer prices, and has prove very costly to the Government. It has also resulted in higher-than-world prices for riceto consumers.

2.7 Prowosed Actions. Local production should be protected by a moderate tariff (10-20 percent). All quantitativeimport restrictions should be dropped. Guaranteed minimum producer prices should be removed, PMB and CWEprivatized, and the commercial activities of FCD discontinued.

Wheat.2.8 Structure. Unlike rice, the wheat market is basically non-competitive, i.e. a Government monopoly. The amountof wheat imports, accounting for 100% of the country's flour requirements in 1994 and 1995, is administrativelydetermined to achieve a fixed domestic price. Even though the private sector has been allowed to import 40% of thetotal (since the beginning of 1994), almost all imports are through the Government-owned CWE. Milling is handledexclusively by a single private firm, PRIMA, which has a 25-year contract with the Government which began in 1980.

2.9 Conduct. Under the PRIMA contract, the Government is obligated to provide 435,000 tons of wheat annuallyfor milling. For each ton of wheat milled, PRIMA must return about three-quarters (740 kg) in the form of flour (oralternative products such as semolina) in exchange for being allowed to keep the remaining wheat bran and other by-products of milling for export as animal feed ingredients. In practice, PRIMA has almost twice this capacity and millsthe totality of the country's imported wheat, producing only one type of all-purpose flour made from 50% hard and 50%soft wheat. Virtually all of the output from the PRIMA mill is provided to CWE which has the flour distributed by theFood Commissioner's Department (FCD). The mill is fully amortized, and at the expiration of the contract in 2005,it is expected to be handed over in good working order to the Government free of charge.

2.10 Performance. Until August 1994, the fixed price of flour had been slightly above CWE's costs, and over theyears CWE had been able to make a modest profit from flour trading. This has now changed with the price of flour

Page 15: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

5

being reduced to Rs.7/kg or about 60% of its current cost of production. The loss incurred is currently being absorbedby CWE, with the official explanation that CWE is sharing past profits with consumers. In reality, CWE's past foodtrading profits (about US$12 million) have already (December 1994) been absorbed by the flour loss. Future loses willneed to be very quickly recompensed if CWE is to remain a viable and credit-worthy organization. Estimates are that1995 losses from continuing with this program are likely to be of the order of Rs.4 billion (US$80 million), more thanfive times CWE's equity at the end of 1993.

2.11 Flour is distributed at a standard fixed price throughout the country by the Food Commissioner's Department(FCD) which has over 50 warehouses with a total storage capacity of 500,000 mt. Only 40% of this capacity, however,is utilized. Some flour in FCD's stores is also reported to be in poor condition (clumpy and variable in moisturecontent), reflecting difficulties in inventory management. This is disposed of as animal feed. Approximately 90% ofthe flour is distributed to some 7-8,000 Multipurpose Cooperative Societies (MCPS), while 10% goes to 8,000 bakeries.The price of the 450 gram loaf of bread is officially unregulated, but bakers allege pressure to maintain the price at alevel which does not cover their costs, resulting in a poor quality product. The prices of other flour products such asnoodles, pasta, pastry and other types of bread are not controlled. The attempts to control the price of flour and the450 gram loaf are intended to hold down the cost of living, but are not part of the targeted food subsidy system whichrelies on food stamps. Flour and flour products account for about 9% of the family food budget, second only to riceat 23 %.

2.12 Perhaps the biggest concern over the wheat and flour policy is that, although Sri Lanka is a country which growsrice and imports wheat, the Government is adopting a contradictory policy whereby consumer demand is beingartificially suppressed for rice by having a policy of.protection, but encouraged for wheat and flour by direct subsidy.The budgetary cost of this operation is substantial. Because Sri Lanka is now near to rice self-sufficiency (and indeedin surplus for much of the year), this combination of policies is likely to lead to increasing volatility in domestic paddyprices. When exports are needed to clear the market, prices would fall to the adjusted world price less the transportcosts, yet at times of shortage the domestic price would rise to the world price plus transport, plus duty.

2.13 Policy Conclusions. The present heavily public sector controlled system of wheat marketing has led to a variablequality product with a high cost to the budget. Although it has benefited consumers through lower prices for wheatproducts, it has created distortions in the substitute rice market which contradict the Government's rice price policy.

2.14 Prowosed Actions. Commercial imports of wheat and flour should be opened to all interested parties in theprivate sector, while imports of wheat and flour under Government-to-Government arrangements (e.g. US PL480) shouldbe auctioned. It is understood that these arrangements would apply after the Government has satisfied its contractualcommitment to PRIMA. The domestic price of flour should no longer be subject to any form of control, and distributionat the wholesale and retail level should be fully liberalized. The facilities of CWE and FCD concerned with wheatmarketing should be privatized. To facilitate private marketing of wheat, paddy millers should be encouraged toinvestigate the possibility of investing in small-scale flour milling equipment.

Other Food Crops (OFC)2.15 Structure. Maize, pulses, chilies, onions and potatoes are largely marketed on a competitive basis by the privatesector, but with the partial exception of chilies, there is no intermediate processing stage. The raw products areprocured in the rural areas by assemblers who package them in gunny bags and either sell them via the Pettah (Colombowholesale market) commission agents, or deliver them to "polas" (local town and village fairs) where they are sold toconsumers via private retailers. Because some of these products are produced by larger, more commercial farmers,particularly potatoes and onions, significant quantities move directly from farmer to wholesaler, bypassing the assembler.Storage is undertaken by farmers, assemblers and wholesalers. Commissions in the Pettah market for these commoditiesare around 5 %, compared to 3% for rice, and retail margins are also greater than for rice.

2.16 Conduct. Direct Government intervention in the OFC markets has been minor. However, because there isofficially a guaranteed price scheme covering maize, some of the pulses and grains, and until 1992, dry chilies, somepurchases have been made by PMB. The main intervention was in 1979 when PMB purchased about 10,000 tons ofmaize or about one-third of the total crop. In most years, the market price has been significantly above the FPS setprice. CWE has also purchased some of these crops on a commercial basis. The most significant involvement was in1992 when CWE purchased some 15% of the big onion crop and 12% of green gram supplies. It also became involvedin big onion trading in 1994, although this was a specifically Government-inspired intervention, and so was not entirelyon a commercial basis. Overall, only about 3 % of OFC production has been handled by PMB and CWE.

Page 16: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

6

2.17 The main influence by Government on OFC markets has been through trade, via both policy measures and directtrading. Imports of chilies and onions are subject to quotas which are so restrictive that they ban all imports in someyears. The quotas are imposed in an ad hoc manner, generally during the domestic harvesting season. For potatoes,the policy does not allow any imports, although imports of seed potatoes are allowed under a licensing scheme.

2.18 In addition to quantitative restrictions, imports of chilies, onions and potatoes are subject to tariffs. For onions,the ad valorem rate is 35 percent and the specific duty Rs.9/kg. The highest tariff applies. For chilies, the ad valoremand specific rates are 35 percent and Rs.20/kg, respectively. For potatoes, they are 35 percent and Rs.12/kg. Importsof chilies and onions have been a monopoly of CWE; but since 1993, private traders are allowed to import up to 40%of the total.

2.19 Performance. Government's policy of quantitative restrictions, high tariffs and direct trading in onions andchilies during certain periods of the year, together with the effective exclusion of the Jaffna region's production fromthe Colombo market, has meant that prices have been quite volatile. Very low prices at harvest time have been followedby rapid price increases as domestic supplies run down, but imports are banned. For example, the wholesale price ofbig onions, reported by ARTI to have averaged Rs. 12/kg (US$240/ton) in September 1994, had increased to Rs.261kg(US$520/ton) by the fourth week of November and to over Rs.30/kg by early December (US$600/ton). This price riseis substantially greater than the likely cost of storage, indicating that there are some discontinuities in the market.

2.20 Part of the reason for the high price volatility associated with these crops is that market participants find itdifficult to be confident about the environment within which they trade. Traders fear that Government may rapidlychange the rules and naturally, they try to position themselves so that such changes do not impose a heavy financialburden. One way of doing this is to hold minimal stocks, thereby making storage unattractive. A case in point occurredin late 1994 when onion, potato and chili farmers and traders were led to believe that no imports would be allowed untilJanuary 15, 1995. However, the Government subsequently changed its mind and liberalized imports as of December7, 1994. While economically sound, this sudden reversal unexpectedly reduced the profitability of investments instorage, causing losses for some and reducing future willingness and ability of private traders to invest in storage.

2.21 Policy Conclusions. Direct trading by CWE and PMB in OFC combined with quantitative restrictions on OFCimports constitute unnecessary interference in a basically competitive market where traders would normally even outprice fluctuations through storage, given a more neutral policy environment. At different times, producers, consumersand would-be investors in storage have been the victims of the resulting price volatility.

2.22 Proposed Actions. Importation of OFC should be liberalized, and made subject to a moderate tariff (10-20%)only, with no nontariff restrictions. CWE's and PMB's activities in the OFC markets should be discontinued.

Fruits and Vegetables2.23 Structure. Marketing of perishable fruits (mango, lime, papaya, passion fruit, plantain bananas, pineapple andorange) and vegetables (cabbage, tomato, beans, carrots, radish and leeks) is handled entirely by the private sector. Themain clearing market is the wholesale market at Pettah in the heart of Colombo. Traffic here is very congested, makingaccess difficult and so increases transaction costs. Wholesale stalls are leased from the municipality at a low rate, butthere are substantial barriers to entry with rents being garnered by the long-established stallholders who only pass ontheir businesses within the family. The market is thus competitive, but within a restricted context. Alternative informalsites are developing outside both Pettah and Colombo itself; but these are still quite small.

2.24 Conduct. Mark-ups between the Colombo wholesale price and retail price appear very high for vegetables, butreasonable for fruit. One of the reasons for the apparently large mark-up for vegetables is the very high level ofphysical losses incurred at the retail level. Vegetables are brought from their production areas into Colombo in sackswhich are roughly handled and piled high on non-refrigerated trucks. They are wholesaled within the same containersin the crowded Pettah market; consequently, it is only when the retailer unpacks his purchases that the transit lossesare evident and reflected in the unit price. With fruit, which is largely retailed by the piece, much of this type of lossis reflected differently in lower unit weights or quality to the consumer.

2.25 Performance. A review of margins for individual commodities suggests that with low value added products,retailers attempt to make a minimum spread per kg sold, while minimizing price fluctuations. So, for example, at theend of September 1994, when cabbage was very cheap and wholesaled at Rs.4/kg, the retail price was Rs. 18/kg, giving-a spread of Rs. 14/kg and a percentage mark-up of 350%. By the beginning of December, the wholesale price ofcabbage had risen to Rs. 13/kg, but the retailers add on had increased only to Rs. 15/kg, giving a percentage mark-upof 129%.

Page 17: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

7

2.26 Policy Conclulsions. Even though margins within the retail vegetable trade do not appear excessive, given theperishability factor, one way in which these could be reduced would be to enlarge and improve wholesale facilities toreduce the large physical losses presently being incurred. Moving the wholesale market from central Colombo to a newsite with larger purpose-designed buildings and offering the new stalls and other facilities to be bid for by competingwholesalers would also help reduce barriers to entry and stimulate competition. Both producers and consumers wouldbenefit.

2.27 Proposed Actions. Develop project proposal for donor financing of a new market in a new location.

Input Markets

Fertilizer2.28 Structure. With 15 registered importers, a range of distributors and distribution points throughout the country,including the Agrarian Service Centers (ASCs), and adequate and relatively inexpensive trucking, the fertilizer marketis structurally competitive. Government owned industries used to dominate the industry, but the situation has changedrapidly, partly as a result of the sell off of the Government firms' assets. Over 60% of imports are now in privatehands.

2.29 Conduct. Although prices are nominally fixed, the availability of significant discounts for quantity, which aredecided on a company by company basis, means that in reality there is price competition. Prices charged by one of thecompanies a]so differentiate between location of supply by amounts which are generally consistent with transport costs.Clients are also given the option of lowering their costs by using recycled sacks.

2.30 Performance. Supply problems have arisen, but these are due to Government intervention rather than to marketstructure. For example, in an attempt to maintain fertilizer prices at a constant level to the farmer, the Govemmentrestored the subsidy which was removed in 1990, but all indications were for further changes, including a possiblevoucher system7. If importers or traders believe that fertilizer prices will go up in the near future, it would be rationalfor them to withhold supplies at the moment with the expectation of selling them at much higher prices in the future.A further cause of shortages is that Japanese aid fertilizer, which is normally delivered in time for the Maha season,and is distributed at a more subsidized price than other fertilizer, has been delayed.

2.31 Policy Conclusions. Evidence shows that fertilizer consumption regained and even surpassed the levels achievedwhen fertilizer was subsidized in the late 1980s, so that it is not necessary to subsidize fertilizer to ensure its use.Sudden shifts in subsidy administration are also disruptive for both producers and consumers and may lead to rent-seeking behavior. There may also be environmental reasons not to stimulate fertilizer consumption.

2.32 Proposed Actions. The fertilizer subsidy should be eliminated. Grant funded fertilizer should be auctioned tothe public.

Seeds2.33 Structure. In 1991, the seed market consisted of 46% paddy seed estimated at Rs. 1.1 billion (US$22 million),38% potato seed worth about Rs.0.9 billion (US$18 million) and 17% other field crops and vegetable seed valued ataround Rs.0.4 billion (US$8.0 million). These figures probably underestimate the 1994/95 value by some 30%. Theyalso exclude other field crops which might be important for an emerging private sector seed industry such as cotton,sunflower, maize and soybean. Seeds used may be either the farmers' own retained seed (47% by value), seedspurchased from another farmer (21 %), seeds procured through formal suppliers (31 %) or seeds from 'other' sources,e.g. landlords, or merchants to whom crops are contracted (I %).

2.34 The formal supply system for seeds in Sri Lanka is partly private and partly public. Historically, paddy seedhas been handled by the public sector, the production of which (both on their own farms and under contract) peaked atabout 15,000 tons in the mid-1980s, but now amounts to only about 4,000 tons or less than 5% of total gross needs.

7/ This subsidy was replaced in April 1995 with a scheme which puts a ceiling on the budgetary cost and limits its application to fourhasic fertilizers, Urea, ainmmonium sulphate, muriate of potash, and triple super phosphate. Based on announced subsidized prices per5t)kg sack, the effective rate of subsidy is now: urea 40%, ammonium sulphate 15%, muriate of potash 9% and triple super phosphate22%. The subsidy is patid to importers. Increases in import prices will be passed on to farners to maintain the budgetary ceiling.Decreases in world prices will be deducted from subsidy payments, reducing the budgetary cost.

Page 18: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

8

The level of certified seed is believed to be far below the optimum level. Although paddy is not a hybrid and so seedcan be reproduced at the farm level without specialized technology, the need to maintain purity and regularly introducenew improved varieties suggests that about 20% of all paddy seed planted each year should be certified seed. Privatebusiness has been allowed to participate in seed paddy production since 1990, particularly in the production of certifiedseed from registered seed. However, the rate of growth has been limited and private production of certified seed isunlikely to amount than more than 1 % of total seed in 1994/95.

2.35 Conduct. One of the reasons for the slow development of private sector supplied seed is Government's seedregistration policy. Government requires that varieties be approved and registered before they can be sold. Anotherreason is what is seen by the private sector as Government selling seed well below the cost of production therebyconstituting unfair competition. A recent announcement by the Department of Agriculture that they are to reduce theircertified paddy seed prices by a further Rs.50 per bushel (about US$50/ton) for the 1995 Maha season planting hascaused at least one large private sector paddy seed producer to plan for a drastic cut-back in his own production andmarketing plan. The Ministry of Agriculture, Lands and Forestry (MALF) is not in agreement with this conclusion,believing instead that private sector seed companies are insufficiently committed to providing paddy seed in a mannerwhich meets farmers needs.8

2.36 For high-valued vegetable seeds, the market is largely in the hands of the private sector, which distributesthrough agents and sub-agents in the districts. Many vegetable seeds are imported, as too are seed potatoes. The lattersituation results mainly from the anomaly whereby importation of potatoes for consumption has generally been bannedwhereas importation of seed potatoes is permitted. This has created an incentive to import consumption potatoes underthe guise of seed potatoes.

2.37 Performance. Despite this peculiarity, the predominantly private sector operated system of seed production forhigh value vegetables appears to work reasonably well. Analysis of Government's performance in paddy seedproduction, however, has indicated operational inefficiencies.

2.38 Policy Conclusions. The general policy of Government in this area should be to intervene only in areas of marketfailure. Government financed plant breeding should be restricted to nonhybrid seeds only and all testing, registrationand certification should be aimed at overcoming any problems of asymptotic information in the domestic seeds market.Where Government believes that commercial seed is not as advertised and farmers are generally unaware of this, itshould carry out tests on the seed and make the results widely known in the seeds market. In the interests of developinga private sector seed industry capable of supplying high quality seeds to farmers at reasonable prices, Government'sinvolvement in paddy seed should be confined to the research linked areas: adaptive breeding; carrying out variety trials;testing, registration and certification, but only as a voluntary service to farmers and seed dealers, who should be freeto buy or not to buy Government registered/certified seed. The private sector should undertake all commercial seed salesand distribution, so as to avoid any possibility of unfair competition from public sector seed companies whosemanagements are not faced with hard budget constraints and financial self sustainability. There should be no restrictionson import of seeds other than for minimum basic phytosanitary reasons. Otherwise, Government policy is likely to bethe root cause of a major constraint in access to new technology by the sector. MALF indicates a general acceptanceof this policy approach and claims to be following it.

III. INCENTIVE POLICY

Price, Trade and Marketine Policy

3.1 With its central role in food consumption, intervention measures center on the farmgate price of paddy. AGuaranteed Price Scheme (GPS) was introduced for paddy in 1948, which set the domestic producer price above theinternational equivalent price. Implementation was through direct Government intervention via a Government purchaseprogram (the Department of Agrarian Services until 1971, and thereafter the Paddy Marketing Board (PMB). The GPSis still in force, though in recent years, events have made it insignificant. In the late 70s, the GPS was extended, in theform of a Floor Price System (FPS) to cover some OFCs, and dampen domestic price fluctuations. But, due to policyinduced decline in the activities of the Cooperative Wholesale Establishment (CWE) and PMB, its impact appears hasbeen superseded by the underlying restrictive import policy.

81 Tue difference of opinion here arises from differing perceptions/definitions of farmers needs and leads to the critical question of the financialsustainability of MALF's tiwn paddy seed supply service.

Page 19: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

9

3.2 Up to 1978, marketing of rice and import of rice, potatoes, chilies and onions were very much under directGovernment control. At its peak, Government, through CWE and PMB, purchased 64% of output in 1965, which,together with imports by CWE, were distributed to consumers by the Food Commissioner's Department (FCD) throughMultipurpose Cooperative Societies (MPCs) and authorized private agents, enabled Government to control (keep down)open market prices. Rice rationing, first introduced in World War 2, was reintroduced in 1960 to redistribute thedomestic production as a result of difficulty in access to foreign exchange and so imports. For the following 7 years,as much as 80% of all rice consumed annually was rationed rice. Subsequently, this declined to about 50%, as a newGovernment reduced the rationed allowance in response to the budgetary strain (17% of Government expenditure in1975) of a rising program cost, due to rapidly increasing world food prices; as compensation, Government did eliminateall charges for the reduced ration.

3.3 Following a change in Government in 1977 came substantial liberalization of the economy in favor of outwardorientation and reduced Government activity. Aimed mainly at industry, it left agricultural price and trade policyfundamentally untouched. But there was a marked reduction in the aggressiveness with which the policy aims of theprevious Government were pursued. Govemment allowed the real level of protection from competition by imports toerode and Nominal Protection Coefficients (NPCs) for rice9 fell from 1.5 in 1976 to 0.7 in 1979 (0.49 when exchangerate adjusted). Also, Government intervention in paddy marketing was greatly reduced, so that purchases by PMB fellfrom 32% of output in 1978 to 4% by 1981 and remained at or about this level thereafter.'"

Incentive Coefficients - NPCs. EPCs and ESCs

3.4 Overview. As a rule, sectoral policy incentives are set by Government intervention in the prices of tradedgoods, i.e. outputs and purchased inputs, via trade measures (tariffs, quotas, licenses, etc) and direct subsidies, e.g. onoutputs and purchased inputs such as fertilizers. On the output side, these trade protection effects are measured by theNPC or nominal protection coefficient, while for the output and input sides combined, the amount of protection ismeasured by the EPC or effective protection coefficient. But in Sri Lanka, the big story is in the subsidies given tonontraded inputs, particularly irrigation water. The effect here is measured by the ESC or effective subsidy coefficient.This is the deepest measure of protection. It is generally not a major factor in explaining sectoral performance. Butwhere Government has financed major irrigation works, and in the absence of any cost-recovery, this can become amajor factor, as it has in Sri Lanka.

3.5 NPCs. In recent years (1985-93) NPCs" for the main import-competing crops (paddy, chili, onion and potato)were well above 1. The NPC for rice, the main non-plantation crop in Sri Lanka, averaged 1.2 for the entire 1985-93period, though showing an upward trend in 1990's. It is now about 1.3. This indicates that on average the barriers torice imports held the domestic price at 20% above the import price. The NPC for wheat, the main substitute for ricein consumption,'2 averaged 1.0 for the entire period, except for late 1994, when consumption of wheat flour wasgranted a subsidy of about 40%. For 1985-93 period, NPCs averaged 1.3 for chili, 2.0 for big onions, and 1.6 forpotato. On average, onion is the most protected crop, followed by potato and chili and then rice. Between the twosubperiods (1985-89 and 1990-93), average protection for rice and big onion has risen, whereas it remained unchangedfor chili and potato. Using production weights, the average NPC for the import competing crops works out to be 1.33in 1993, which is very close to NPC for rice (1.3).

3.6 EPCs - Import Competing Crops. Effective Protection Coefficients (EPCs) measure the net incentive providedto the production of a crop by taking account of the protection or disprotection received by the traded inputs used in itsproduction. The protection provided to traded inputs (fertilizer, agrochemicals, farm machinery etc) since 1990 wassmall. The Maha 1993 EPCs for paddy (estimated for different districts with different water regimes) range between

91 Derined an the ratio of domestic price over border equivalent price.

1O/ Economic Policies and Agricultural Performance in Sri Lanka 1960-1984. Eric Thorbecke and Jans Svejnar, OECD Paris, 1987,Tables 28 & 29.

II/ For details on estimation of incentive and comparative advantage coefficients and review of other estimates see Working Paper #4:Policy Incentives Diversification and Comparative Advantage.

12/ All whetit consumed in Sri Lanka is imported.

Page 20: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

10

1.34 and 1.38.'3 Earlier EPC estimates (1990 Maha)'4 of between 1.23 to 1.47 show little or no change.5 AverageEPCs for paddy and import competing vegetable crops (based on chilies) in 1993 were 1.36 and 1.70. Both EPCestimates are very close to NPC estimates for the respective year, implying that output price policy played a much moredominant role than input price policy in setting the price-based production incentives for farmers.

3.7 EPCs - Export Crops. Fruits, vegetables, foliage plants, medicinal herbs, etc are the main export crops of thenon-plantation sector. The export earnings from fruit, vegetables and foliage plants experienced steady growth over thelast decade. Among the other minor exports, cinnamon and raw tobacco experienced stable growth. Export of othercrops fluctuated widely over the last decade. Under export orientation, policy incentives include a subsidy program forproviding financial assistance from Export Development Board (EDB) for investment, income tax exemption, waiverof duties on intermediate goods import under the Board of Investment (BOI) incentive package. The targets of theincentive package are big commercial enterprises whose capital investment exceeds Rs. 10 million and who export about70-90 percent of their output. EDB informs that fruits and vegetables are not included under this program, and nationalaccounts data show no subsidy payment. The incentive package for minor exports included fertilizer subsidy, directsubsidy to the producers and a price support scheme for coffee, cloves, pepper, nutmeg and nutmeg oil. In 1993, thedirect and fertilizer subsidy amounted about Rs.9.6 million. The subsidy paid under the price support scheme was aboutRs. 16.8 million. The national accounts data also show that the export tax on MECs was about Rs.0. I million. On thewhole, the total subsidy was less than a percent of value added in the minor export sector. Including fruits andvegetables, the EPC for the export crops during the 1990-93 period, is estimated (from national accounts data) to average1.02 implying a virtually neutral policy regime. The overall EPC for the non-plantation crop sector is estimated to be1.24 in 1993.16

3.8 ESCs - Nonplantation Crops. Although agriculture also receives considerable subsidies on nontraded factorsof production, these do not enter into estimation of EPCs. Including these would make the actual level of effectiveprotection to agriculture much greater than seen from the EPC ratio. Irrigation, research, and extension, for which costrecovery is zero, are a major source of assistance to crop agriculture, which, when taken into account, materially affectthe picture. Industry does not receive a similar volume of subsidies. For irrigation, since no charges are collected, theirrigation subsidy amounts to 100% of the annual capital cost repayment, finance charges and O&M costs. In large-scaleirrigation systems, the construction cost subsidy is equivalent to an annual payment of about Rs.50,000 per ha (aboutUS$1,000), or 96% of the economic value added per ha for paddy. The O&M subsidy here is equivalent to an annualpayment of about Rs. 1,350 per ha, or 3.5% of economic value added for paddy. For rehabilitation investment, thesubsidy equates to an annual payment of Rs.7,000 to Rs. 10,500, and an O&M subsidy equivalent to an annual paymentof Rs.600 to Rs.1,350, depending on whether the scheme is a minor or major one. This equates to 21% or 27%, and2% or 4% respectively of value added for paddy in economic terms.'" These are not implicit costs, but are actuallyincurred through the Government budget allocations in support of irrigation schemes. In return for this, on average riceconsumers (primarily taxpayers and the poor) have paid about 20% more for rice (currently 30%) than they would ifimports had been liberalized.

3.9 Clearly agriculture receives far more favorable treatment than might be perceived to be the case from the EPCestimates arising from Government intervention in markets in outputs and traded inputs. Taken with the EPC estimate,they cause it to increase by these same amounts. For paddy produced on a recently constructed large-scale irrigationscheme, the EPC is effectively increased from 1.34 to an ESC of 2.30. For other import competing and export cropsgrown on irrigated land the protection effect is similar to rice protection. The magnitude is not as great because of thelarger value added in these. Overall, the average increase in protection nation-wide to paddy is about 20% and 10%overall for the nonplantation sector. Clearly irrigation subsidies add significant increases in protection, especially fornew large scale irrigation systems.

1 3/ The EPCs tend to be smaller in the major irrigation scheme areas, where average paddy yield is much higher than other areas, i.e.minor irrigationi schemes and rainfed areas.

14/ Edirisingihe N., Abeyratne F.. Somarathne W.G.. Wickramarachi P., and Tudwe P.l., (1991), 'Efficiency and Policy Incentives inRice Productioln in Sri Lanka", ARTI/IFPRI.

15/ Aniual variatimnsls in yields and/or inputs could account for the 10% difference

I W, The reintroduction of the fertilizer subsidy in late 1994 will increase the EPCs for all crops in 1995.

17! See WP#3, Tatble 5.5.

Page 21: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

I1

3.10 ESCs - Plantation Crops. The plantation sector has traditionally been heavily taxed. In recent years this policyapproach changed with elimination of the export tax on the sector. The EPC is now is estimated to be around 1.0 forboth 1990 and 1993 (Edwards 1993). However, two factors not accounted for in these estimates are the fmnancialsubsidies afforded the plantation sector by Government and the resident excess labor force of the plantation corporations,i.e. a subsidy and a tax. The ESC for plantation crops including these elements is 1.03. As with manufacturing,plantation crops are also highly disprotected relative to irrigated agriculture.

Agriculture versus Industry

3.11 Manufacturing Industry EPC. The most recent estimate for this is 1.7. From the relative values of theEPCs, agriculture appears less protected than the manufacturing sector. Although the gap has closed somewhat in recentyears, the average level of protection given to industry appears quite high relative to agriculture. The industry EPCabove is restricted in coverage to imports only, and is derived from the tariff schedule rather than comparison of actualprices; but tariff collection has been subject to widespread, ad hoc exemptions, thus reducing the effective well belowthe actual rate. Also, in the past 2 years, import tariffs have been restructured into 3 bands, with a maximum of 35 %and a minimum of 15%, further reducing protection to industry. As a result, this estimate is seen as a grossoverestimate of the actual level of protection afforded manufacturing imports. More seriously, by excludingmanufactured exports, which now make up about 60 % of manufacturing industry output, the average level of protectionafforded manufacturing industry is even more overstated. With no direct support from Government, the EPC for theseis taken to be 1.00, the weighted average of the two gives an EPC of 1.30. This compares to an overall average ESCfor agriculture of 1.32. Bearing in mind that the average for agriculture hides tremendous variations, this indicates thatoverall there appears to be little difference in protection given to the two sectors.

3.12 The degree of protection of the various crops relative to manufacturing industry is shown in Table 3. 1, withthe crops, differentiated by type of irrigation system. Average nonplantation crops protection (ESC 1.45) is above thatfor manufacturing (EPC 1.3) and particularly above export manufacturing (EPC 1.00). Relative to exportmanufacturing, nonplantation crop agriculture receives far more protection. Only rainfed export crops receive the samezero protection as manufacturing exports. The extent of protection increases with the size of the system and is inverselyrelated to the age of the system. This simply says that the higher the per-acre investment costs the greater the subsidytransferred. Large systems cost more per acre than small, and new systems cost more per-acre than rehabilitated ones.An ESC of 1.03 is estimated for plantation crops. This gives a weighted overall ESC for agriculture of 1.32. Allowingfor the upward bias in the import substitution manufacturing EPC (1.70), and the inevitable increase in crop EPCs in1995 as a result of the reintroduction of the fertilizer subsidy, agriculture is undoubtedly protected relative to industry.But the aggregate average hides tremendous variations in protection within nonplantation agriculture arising from thevery high costs of irrigation and the complete absence of any cost recovery. Irrigated crops receive a far greater levelof protection relative to manufacturing industry than rainfed crops, so that paddy grown in Mahaweli receives 230%more protection than do manufacturing exports such as garments. Paddy grown in rainfed areas only receives 40% moreprotection. But, export vegetables average only 3% more, while export vegetables grown in rainfed areas receive thesame protection as manufactured exports, i.e. zero.

Agriculture versus Agriculture

3.13 Within the nonplantation crop sector, the relatively favorable treatment given to paddy and other import-competing crops compared to export crops, i.e. on average 47 % more protection for rice (117% more for rice inMahaweli) and 69% on average for other import-competing crops, shows a strong anti-export bias in agricultural tradepolicy too. This estimate is not subject to the concerns mentioned in respect to industry. Although other factors,particularly land tenure policy, are a severe constraint to sector performance, until the trade policy playing field islevelled diversification will not occur and sector output will likely remain very inward oriented.

Page 22: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

12

Table 3. 1: Sri Lanka Trade Policy Protection - Crop Agriculture Relative to Manufacturing Industry.

EPC | EPC | ESC Crop Protection (ESC 1993) relative to:l | Import Substg. Export Manufacturing

Crop 1990 1993 1993 Manufacturing. Manufacturing. Average.

Rice - rainfed 1.47 1.34 1.34 0.79 1.40 1.03

Rice - in a new major irrigation system 1.39 1.34 2.30 1.35 2.30 1.77

Rice - in a rehabilitated major 1.23 1.36 1.63 0.96 1.61 1.25irrigation system l

Rice - in a rehabilitated mnior 1.31 1.38 1.60 0.94 1.60 1.23irrigation system

Rice - average 1.33 1.36 1.56 0.92 1.59 1.20

Import-Competing Vegetables - rainfed na 1.68 1.68 0.99 1.35 1.29

Import-Competing Vegetables - in a na 1.68 2.26 1.33 1.57 1.74new major irrigation system

Import-Competing Vegetables - in a na 1.70 1.82 1.07 1.41 1.40rehabilitated major irriganion system l

Import-Competing Vegetables - in a na 1.72 1.80 1.06 1.39 1.39rehabilitated minor irrigation system

Import-Competing Vegetables - average 1.28 1.70 1.79 1.05 1.39 1.38

Export Crops (Vegetables) - rainfed na 1.00 1.00 0.59 1.00 0.77

Export Crops - in a new major na 1.05 1.25 0.74 1.16 0.96irrigation system l

Export Crops (Vegetables) - in a na 1.03 1.10 0.65 1.04 0.85rehabilitated major irrigation system l

Export Crops (Vegetables) - in a na 1.01 1.05 0.62 1.03 0.81rehabilitated minior irrigation system l

Export Crops (Vegetables) - average 1.00 1.02 1.06 0.62 1.03 0.82

Nonplantationi Crop Sector Average na 1.35 1.45 0.85 1.28 1.12

Plantation (Tree) Crops 1.00 1.00 1.03 0.61 1.03 0.79

Agriculture Average na 1.24 1.32 0.78 1.20 1.02

Import Substituting Manufacturing. na 1.70 1.70 . 1.70 1.31

Export Manuacttiurine na 1.00 1.00 0.59 - 0.77

Manufacturing Average 1.80 1.30 1.30 0.77 1.21 -

Sources: Nonplantation Sector 1990: - Edirisinghe N., Abeyratne F., Somarathne W.G., Wickramarachi P., and Tudwe P.I., (1991), 'EfficiencyalId Policy Incentives in Rice Production in Sri Lanka", ARTIIIFPRI.Nouiplantation Sector 1993: Para 3.8 and Working Paper #2. Averaged using: Within Crops area wts. Rainfed 0.31, New 0.04, Maj. Ir 0.41, MinIr. 0).24. Between crops VA wts Rice 0.30, Imp. Comp. 0.33, & Exp. Comp. 0.37.Plantation: Adjusts public sector EPC (1.0) for financial subsidies and labor taxes and weights with smallholder plantation EPC (1.0).Agriculture Average: Weighted average, using 1993 value added shares as weights. Nonplantation 0.68, Plantation 0.32.Import Manufacturing: - Edwards C. (1993) Protectionism and Trade Policy in Manufacturing and Agriculture: Sri Lanka Institute of Policy Studies.Estimation process gives upward bias, but used in the absence of any meaningful basis to adjust for this."Export Manufacturing: - aLssumes no export subsidies and refund of import taxes on inputs.Manufacturing Average: - weighted average of industrial production, 60% exports and 40 % import substitutes.

IS/ Edwards also estimated NPCs and EPCs for agriculture. The NPCs are similar to those here, but the EPCs are seen as too high dueto omission oif finanice charges. See Working Paper #2.

Page 23: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

13

Commarative Advanta2e - DRCs

3.14 The efficiency of resource use in production is measured by estimating the Domestic Resource Cost (DRC).19

By valuing inputs at their respective shadow prices, the DRC, takes account of the taxes and subsidies applied to thenon-traded inputs also. For paddy in Sri Lanka, the DRC ratio varies from 2.16 in new largescale irrigation systemsto 1.53 in rainfed production.20 It is generally higher in regions with higher yields, implying a negative relationshipbetween yield and DRC, due to higher irrigation investment and O&M costs. But the estimates exceed unity for allregions, and the average DRC is estimated to be 1.73 (Maha 1993). This clearly indicates that more than one Rupeeof resources (Rs. 1.73 in fact) is used to produce one Rupee's worth of rice valued in foreign exchange. The policyimplications here are serious, as this shows that Sri Lanka does not currently possess comparative advantage for oneof its major crops and that rice could have been obtained for less intemationally. This problem may have worsened inrecent years as the average DRC, estimated under similar assumptions for Maha 1990 was only 1.22.21 The DRC forchili also exceeds unity, being 1.68 in Anuradhapura (rainfed), and 2.17 in Jaffna (irrigated), implying that, on average,the economy also suffers losses in production of these. All estimates take a 6 year construction period and a croppingintensity of 2. Because these values are over-optimistic, the DRCs are biased downwards, making the situation lookbetter than is likely to be the case.22 Clearly this has lessons for future irrigation investment in Sri Lanka, a fact ablydemonstrated in a recent International Irrigation Management Institution (IIMI) publication.22

3.15 Exchange Rates. Exchange rate overvaluation is often claimed to be a reason for such high levels of protectionand lack of comparative advantage (i.e. EPCs and DRCs). In the past, the exchange rate in Sri Lanka may have beenovervalued, thus taxing tradables such as rice. This does not appear to be so at present. With the DRCs for the large-scale irrigation projects reaching towards 3, throwing all the adjustment on the exchange rate would require a 200%depreciation of the present exchange rate to provide comparative advantage for rice produced in Mahaweli. But theexchange rate regime has not been the source of any substantial bias against agriculture. Partial equilibrium analysis,using varying scenarios, indicates little if any exchange rate overvaluation.24 Consequently, no significant adjustmentin the level of protection, i.e. sectoral EPCs, appears likely on this account.

Irrization Subsidy - Cost and Distribution

3.16 Developing and sustaining this production required substantial Govemment expenditure, primarily on irrigationinfrastructure. These are almost all transfers from taxpayers to paddy producers.2" With no cost recovery, the size ofthe total transfer here may be gauged by multiplying the subsidy per ton of crop in the various systems by the volumeof output. Based on 1993 output levels, this amounts to about Rs. 12 billion (US$240 million) for paddy and Rs.400

19/ The DRC ratio shows the cost of domestic resources used to produce a unit of foreign exchange earning. Alternatively, it shows thevalue (cost) of the resources used to produce a unit of the product (e.g. rice). The more above I the greater the loss involved inproduction, while die more below I the greater the economic profit and comparative advantage.

20/ In Sri Lanlika. irrigarion water is provided free of any cost. The Operation and Maintenance (O & M) cost per year is estimated to beabout Rs. 1556 per ha in rehabilitated major irrigation schemes outside Mahaweli area, followed by Rs 1331 per ha in newlyconstructed major irrigation schemes ii Mahaweli area and Rs.600 in rehabilitated minor irrigation schemes. Using market wage andexchianige rates, the DRC ratios are estimared under the assumption that irrigation cost is equal to 0 & M cost in rehabilitated schemes.

21/ Edirisinghe N.. Abeyratne F., Somarathne W.G., Wickramarachi P., and Tudwe P.l., (1991), 'Efficiency and Policy Incentives inRice Production in Sri Lanka", ARTI/IFPRI.

22/ See WP#2, para 5.7 (page 15).

23/ Aluwihare. P.B. and Masao Kikuchi. 'Irrigation Investment Trends in Sri Lanka: New Construction and Beyond.' International IrrigationManagement Institute, Colombo, Sri Lanka, 1991.

24/ WP#3, Annex I and Table Al.3, Estimation of Equilibrium Exchange Rate 1993.

25/ Because die price elasticities of supply and demand for paddy are still low, the deadweight element of these costs is quite small andiistead it is a transfer to paddy producers. The elasticities are currendy estimated as: -0.67 for demand and 0.09 for supply. See WP#3.

Page 24: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

14

million (US$8 million) for chili, or a total annual cost of about US$250 million.26 The per ton loss, 25% of importprice ot paddy and 20% for chili, is significant. At the national level, this amounts to an annual transfer of about 3%of GDP in 1993.

3.17 Farmer families resettled in large-scale irrigation schemes were selected from congested, low-income areas.This must call into question the merits of large-scale irrigation investment as an approach to poverty alleviation. Riceself-sufficiency is the alternative argument, especially where farm families are no longer poor. But the very high andonigoinig cost of this approach to self-sufficiency must question its sustainability as well as its wisdom. If the sector hadto pay its own way, as the overall economy must, then paddy would need an enormous increase in protection againstimports to allow it to meet this bill. This would simply have the result of shifting the subsidy burden from Sri Lankantaxpayers to Sri Lankan consumers.

3.18 The massive irrigation subsidy mainly benefits farmers in major irrigation systems and so its distribution isextremely skewed. In fact, the subsidy per ha to farmers in recently constructed major irrigation systems amounts to5 times that given to major rehabilitated major systems and 7 times that for rehabilitated minor systems. For rainfedsystems, the ratio is infinite, as these receive no irrigation subsidy. But only 4% of the cropped area is in new largescale irrigation systems, while 41 % is in major rehabilitated schemes. Minor schemes account for 24% of the croppedarea; while rainfed area is 31 %. Farm size appears to be much smaller (rural congestion much greater) outside themajor irrigation systems, where settler activity is subject to greater administrative control. This adds to the skewnessof the distribution of the irrigation subsidy. If'informal division of holdings in Government's irrigated settlementschemes is taken into account, this may not be as significant.

Irri2atlon Policy Reform

3.19 Full correction in the current situation requires a policy of full cost recovery (capital costs as well as O&M)from beneficiaries of the irrigation system, i.e. farmers; as only this will shut off the excess demand for underpricedirrigation land. But this will still only ensure financial viability. To move towards a fully economically efficientirrigation system requires a system which permits market forces to determine the price of irrigation water throughinteraction of supply and demand for this. Because irrigation water is a private good, establishment of a market systemis quite feasible, although, because the water is expensive to move around (including allowing for third-party effects),markets are likely to remain very localized.

3.20 Perceived market failures in irrigation systems appear the underlying reason for Governments' traditionaltreatment of it as a public good.2' These perceptions arise mainly from the existence of major scale economies instorage and distribution structures and from the absence (or non-enforcement) of water rights.2 ' Externalities, mainlydue to the private cost being less than the social cost for many competing water uses may also cause market failure.Natural monopolies of large-scale storage and distribution schemes give rise to market imperfections only.

3.21 Treating irrigation water as a public good inhibits much needed institutional reform, and the creation ofindependent and (eventually) private irrigation agencies. Policy makers and planners continually call for betterperformance by public-sector irrigation institutions, despite the absence of institutional autonomy and adequate financialincentives for personnel. The situation is well summarized by Repetto: 'For the most part, management problemsare symptomatic of the underlying conflicts in the political economy of public irrigation. But, many of theremedial projects deal mostly with the symptoms and not the underlying conflicts. If performance in publicirrigation is treated either as a mechanical or design problem, or as a management problem, and the more

26/ Inlsufficient data were available to estimate the DRC for onions and potatoes. It is seen as less than that for chili (due to higher transportcosts), but the combined volume produced is much greater (5 times), suggesting economic losses for these on the order of perhaps anotherUS$10 million.

27/ The key defining characteristics of a public good here are 'nonsubtractabilitv' (the ability to consume as much of a good as desired with noreduction in the aimount available to others) and 'nonexcludabilitv' (the inability to exclude specific individuals - e.g. users who fail to pay ashare of the costs - from consuming a good). Street lighting is a good example of both.

2h/ For a detailed discussion see: Rogers, Peter. Comprehensive Water Resources Management: A Concept Paper. World Bank WorkingPLaper WPS 879, Matrchl 1992.

Page 25: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

15

fundamental difficulties of the political economy of public irrigation are not resolved, efforts to improveperformance will probably have limited success. ̀29

3.22 Capturing the scale economies in storage and distribution requires massive investment, for whichGovernment has traditionally been the source. This has strengthened Governments' view of irrigation asa public good, leading to an exclusive public sector administration for the system. The administeredsystem is entirely "supply driven", in which the water users have little or no say. Administrative pricingof the water assigns a cost-plus value to water and ignores the underlying supply-demand situation. Thisgenerally results in undervaluing the water by comparison with what users value it at and encourageswaste in use. To correct this, an approach needs to be developed which recognizes and addresses thesevital shortcomings automatically and in an ongoing fashion. In other words, what is needed here is aninstitutional structure which would permit direction of system operations by market forces, and thusconvert the system from one which is "supply driven" to one which is "demand driven.

3.23 To restore financial and physical sustainability and also efficiency to the irrigation system, hidden gains or rentsneed to be made clear and tradable; there needs to be a direct connection between water charges and deliveries. Atpresent, there is no direct commercial relationship between irrigation water suppliers and users, and no managementautonomy in irrigation agencies. Both are major factors in the breakdown of administrative, nonmarket, discipline.Options to address the problem are: (a) direct legal intervention to restore discipline, by exhortation and coercion;(b) revival of the existing agency through reorganization and realignment of staff and responsibilities; (c) turn the systemover to user groups; (d) restructure the agency as an autonomous public utility, with a hard budget constraint and amandate of self-sustainability; or (e) privatization.

3.24 Exhortation has no lasting impact, and coercion is unacceptable. Internal reorganization, regularly tried,regularly fails. Being unable to address the basic underlying problems, it can only address the manifestations of theproblems. Often, there are unbridgeable differences in opinion and interests between the legislature and the irrigationagency. This results in little administrative independence for the irrigation agency, which anyway faces a multiplicityof objectives (many of which are neither commercial nor consistent).

3.25 The solution lies in commercializing any service or product which is not a public good. Irrigation is not a publicgood and so should be commercialized. In this way, market incentives can promote needed improvements in efficiency.Within each scheme, an autonomous public utility, independent of the regular civil service, is an absolute minimum.This approach can only be as successful as the Government's commitment to the independence and commercialism ofthe utilities. Complete privatization in the form of a user-owned and operated utility company is preferable. Thisremoves any doubts about independence and commercialism, clearly resolves property rights issues and avoids thepossibility of private investors exploiting farmers or the need for a regulatory authority. A judgement needs to be madein the case of each system as to whether or not it is ready for such an institutional turn-around.

3.26 A public utility will permit development of the needed two-way links between the supply and demand sides ofthe irrigation water market. Financial self-reliance will provide the stimulus for utility management to ensure cost-effectiveness and profitability. It will also provide the incentive to collect water-delivery charges and those for otherservices, thus restoring financial discipline in users. Users in turn will demand improvements in operations and willonly pay for what they get. Farmer Organizations (groups of individual users), would be a counter balance to themonopoly power of the utilities, but only if adequately developed. Finally, legalization of water sales between users(individuals and groups) will permit efficient pricing of water in local markets, leading to more efficient on-farm wateruse. Linking drainage service charges to water delivery charges for collection by utilities could enhance drainage costrecovery, ensuring financial viability for drainage O&M and helping with finance for drainage expansion.

3.27 While the institutional and legal aspects of any restructured system should be flexible, the basic elements mustbe present. Creation of legally enforceable water property rights and legalization of markets in these (lease and sale)are vital to progress here. Creating user water rights and legalizing water trading can be expected to provide atransparent market value for water, and its opportunity cost of the factor. This promotes more efficient use of thisscarce resource, through equalization of the marginal value product of water in its alternative uses.

29/ Repeulo, Rubert C. Deceniber 1986. Skimming the Water: Rcnt-seekinig and the Performance of Public Irrigation Systems. WorldResources InStitulte, Rcsearch Report #4. Washington, D.C.

Page 26: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

16

3.28 Institutional options for any irrigation scheme will vary depending on the social development of the local area.Where democratic and developed farmers' organizations exist, they should, together with other user groups, (localGovernments, industry associations, and environmentalists, for instance) take over system operation. In practice, thisis occurring at an increasing rate in a few countries--Spain, Chile, the US, and (most successfully) Mexico, for example.Although the Bank supports such user organizations, their development is of necessity slow. Even in Mexico userorganizations must pass through a well-monitored development phase before the system is turned over to them.

3.29 The incentive for user groups to take over their system depends very much on the their ability to perceive andcapture otherwise foregone benefits. The benefits are generally in the form of lower costs and an improved watersupply. To the extent that farmers in Sri Lanka make informal payments (rents) to acquire 'free' irrigation water, thefirst possibility holds. But accessing this benefit in a cost-effective manner requires that user groups act as directorsof the public utility administering the system; otherwise, the practice of extracting informal payments will continue.If timeliness and equity in delivery of water is a problem, again user groups will have an incentive to take over thesystem. Such a take-over is best phased in, as user groups are organized, federated and trained to carry theresponsibility of operating their own system (e.g. as in Mexico).

3.30 Where such incentives are not available, an autonomous, self-financing, commercial public utility is required.In existing systems, full cost recovery (investment and O&M) may not be possible without excessive shrinkage ofeconomic activity. Since investment costs are sunk, recovery may be limited to rehabilitation and O&M costs withouthindering efficiency. If farm income per ha is unable to bear even rehabilitation costs, then recovery may be limitedto O&M costs only, with no rehabilitation investment undertaken. In effect, this means running down the fixed asset,i.e. an eventual shrinkage in irrigated area.

3.31 With increased costs the quality of management input to farming becomes more important. As a result, it islikely that the number of farmers will decline as the less efficient ones move permanently off-farm and average farmsize will increase. This will result in increased profitability in agriculture and offset forces tending to shrink irrigatedarea. The entire process is simply the normal result of price-cost squeezes, and one designed to ensure continuedeconomic efficiency in fanming systems. It is likely that conditions in Sri Lanka's land market will hinder thisadjustment process as it has up to now (see Chapter V. Land).

Trade Policv Reform

3.32 The subsidy given to paddy prices directly arises from the import protection given to paddy and is borne byall domestic rice consumers in direct proportion to their volume of consumption. The relative burden depends upon theimportance of rice in the purchases of the individual or household. Obviously, for the poor, any additional cost for ricewill be a much heavier burden than for the wealthy. Measured by the NPC in 1993, the increase in rice prices overwhat it would have been in the absence of any import protection is about 30%. Taken as a share of the gross value ofrice production, this amounts to about US$125 million, or 2% of GDP.

3.33 Because trade policy reform can bring rapid results, a more detailed analysis was made of the likely outcomeof trade reform within the agricultural sector only. For this, a simple multimarket (partial equilibrium) mode130 wasdeveloped to reflect the relevant features of the sector. The model draws together actual sector data on variables of themajor commodity groups"' in the form of a series of interactive markets which adjust to change via own and crosselasticities ,32

3.34 The impact of exogenous changes in policy variables on key elements of sector performance are assessedthrough the changed equilibrium levels of the markets included. The main results are presented below. Due to thepartial-equilibrium nature of the model, not all the intersectoral impact of change is seen. As a result, the bulk ofadjustment to policy change falls on the agricultural sector. But, as seen above, most of the policy-induced distortionsappear emerge from within the sector. The transparency of the modef's approach makes the results intuitivelyacceptable, giving confidence to the direction, if not the precise magnitude, of the results.

31)/ For details of the multimarket analysis see WP# 3.

31/ Output, prices, income, employment, trade, and policy (tariffs, quotas) variables.

321/ The whelt flour subsidy, introduced in August 1994, is not seen as sustainable and so is not included in the model.

Page 27: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

17

3.35 The policy reforms examined progressively extend partial liberalization of trade restrictions to the major outputmarkets impacted by trade policy; beginning with rice, then incorporating import competing crops, i.e. chilies, potatoesand onions, and finally sugar. Reducing the rice import tariff by 10% impacts on both rural and urban households.Both groups are subdivided to represent three income groups, lower, middle and upper.

3.36 A 10% reduction in the rice import tariff causes a reduction in the cost of a major food, leading to a declinein the cost of living for both rural and urban populations. Real income increases for all, except the largest farmers (highincome rural households), even though nominal farm income declines by 1.23% due to the decline in the rice price. Thisresults from the price decline effect dominating the income effect, together with the fact that much householdconsumption is financed by off-farm earnings.33

3.37 The largest increase in real income goes to rural low income households (0.77% for the 10% tariff reduction),as these are almost entirely net consumers of rice and rice is the largest component of food purchases. This is 9 timesgreater than the gain to high income rural households. Incomes of urban groups at all levels increase, as these are allnet consumers of rice. The next largest income increase goes to the low income urban households (0.71 %), for whomrice is a also a major part of household expenditure. Gains here are twice as large as those to high income urbanhouseholds. This underlines the very negative effect of trade protection on rice for the poor, and so confirms the earlierfindings of the Bank's study on poverty in Sri Lanka,4 and the very positive distributional impact Qf trade reform.Rice imports and consumption all increase, while production of import competing crops (chilies, potatoes and onions)declines, due to a substitution of rice in aggregate consumption. This also happens to tree crops, but is offset byincreased exports. Production and export of high valued vegetables increases by 0. 1% and 6.0% respectively, offsettingthe decline in production and increase in imports of rice and other import-competing crops, demonstrating the realityof the anti-export bias already noted agriculturaltrade policy. There is a small decline in on-farm employment, 0.07%,reflecting the inevitable adjustment out of agriculture. Also, a decline in Government revenues of 0.2% results froma decline in the price of rice. Overall, the outcome is seen to aid export development and poverty alleviation.

3.38 Expanding this to include a 10% increase in the import quota for import competing crops show similar results,but with increased magnitude. While nominal farm income declines by 1.84%, again this is offset by a decline in thecost of living such that real incomes increase to a greater extent than previously for all rural groups. As expected, urbanhousehold income increases more than before, with the increase again being almost twice as large for lower than upperincome urban households. Production of rice and export vegetables increase marginally at the expense of the importcompeting crops.35 Again, imports of rice and import competing crops increase, while Government revenues decreaselargely due to decrease in tariff revenues from imports of rice and sugar. As before, export of export crops increases,but still by less than 1%. Onfarm employment declines by a modest 0.12%. The wage rate declines by 1.15%, butthis is in isolation of ongoing expansion in the off-farm labor market, which has been pushing up agricultural wage ratesquite rapidly in recent years.

3.39 Partial liberalization of sugar along with rice and import competing crops results in the same 1.84% declinein nominal farm income. Real income changes are more positive (or less negative) due to the price effect of the declinein sugar price. Gains to rural low income households are about 5 times more than to the rural upper income households.Gains to the lower income urban households remain almost twice as large as to the upper income urban households.Sugar production declines, but by less than 1 %. Reallocation of the sugar area gives a slight increase in rice production.Production of import competing crops declines but not as much as before. Production and export of export vegetablesincreases, by 0.04% and 10% respectively. Onfarm employment declines by 0.12% and Government revenue from taxesand tariffs on these commodities by 2.29%. The latter reflects the size of sugar's contribution to overall tariff revenuein the sector.

3.40 Overall, these trade reform scenarios show that the positive aspects of policy reform are very encouraging andthe downside impact is remarkably small. Under the present structure, even with full liberalization, expansion in exportcrops will be slow initially, primarily because of the current low level of output and also because the supply response

33/ See IFPRI Research Report of November 15, 1984. on "analyses of a series of issues which influence the performance of the Sri Lankanfood stamp program". Table 39 - Value of Production and Share of Income by Landholding Size, (page 101).Research funded by the Office of Nutrition of AID under Grant DAN -1275-G-SS-2124-)0.

34/ World Bank Report No. 13431-CE, Sri Lanka Poverty Assessment, January 11, 1995. paras 2.79-2.88.

35/ This result is very sensitive to the cross price elasticity of supply between rice and imported crops.

Page 28: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

18

has been policy constrained in the past.' The highly positive income effects on the poor, both rural and urban, arevery welcome. The gains to low income urban dwellers and the rural landless, and thus the budget through reductionin transfer expenditures, provides a powerful reason to initiate the adjustment process. The anti-agriculture bias seenin overall trade policy must also militate against greater export oriented investment. But elimination of this has onlya small impact initially, as the land market is nonfunctioning, and so potential investors would still have problemsaccessing the necessary fixed factor of production.3' However, the significance of off-farm employment on overallfarm family income at present is very great (cf Chapter VI). Because of this, trade reform in isolation of other morefundamental reform may have a perverse effect on aggregate sectoral output.3 8 In this case, there may be a validreason to delay trade policy reform pending adjustment in policies regarding land tenure and the rural credit market (cfSequencing Policy reform, paras

Price Fluctuations and Trade

3.41 It is sometimes argued that trade liberalization will cause greater fluctuation in prices of domestic food products,thus increasing risk to farmers and consumers and destabilizing domestic output levels due to the far higher level offluctuation in world prices. A comparative analysis of seasonal and annual price fluctuations in the domestic andinternational rice markets shows quite the contrary in Sri Lanka.39 The coefficient of variation for monthly wholesalerice prices in Sri Lanka was 8. 1, while for rice priced fob Bangkok it was only 1.4 (both averaged over 8 years). Thesame measure of price fluctuation based on annual average price between 1984 and 1991 was 31.4 for Sri Lankanwholesale rice prices and only 15.6 for fob Bangkok rice prices. Clearly import liberalization could bring significantprice stability to Sri Lanka's domestic rice market.

IV. RURAL FINANCE

Overview

4.1 As with most of the markets in Sri Lanka's agricultural sector, the rural credit market functions quite well.Competitively structured and with widespread retail coverage, physical access is available to almost everyone.Structurally, the sector shows increasing sophistication as different styles of intermediation evolve to carve outspecialized niche markets for themselves. The smallholder structure of the nonplantation crop sector results inagricultural credit being restricted to a very small share of sectoral economic activity. In the event of liberalization andcreation of conditions for growth in the sector, the structure and capacity of the rural financial system may need to becarefully monitored by the banking authorities.

Mvlarket Structure

4.2 The supply side of Sri Lanka's rural credit market comprises three types of institutions: (i) formal,(ii) semiformal, i.e a hybrid of formal and informal, and (iii) informal.4' The formal institutions comprise banks whichuse the branch network to deliver banking services to the rural clients. Semiformal institutions are a hybrid system ofboth formal and informal institutions, which combine features of strength of both institutions and provide links betweenformal and informal systems. The semiformal institutions derive resources from within and outside the economy4' tocleliver credit and other financial services. The informal institutions are the traditional rural credit structures such as

3(1 It is likely that ltie supply elasticity for paddy is much lower than would be with a fully operational land market.

37/ The non tLUICiE1io 1m1g or water markers is likely to have a similar effect.

3X/ Depending on the divisibility ot the labor input in paddy production.

39i See WP#6. Table 9.

4(1/ For details see WP# 4.

41/ Menilbers jivhigs and grant financinig frotm oreign sources.

Page 29: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

19

moneylenders who apparently use largely their own funds to lend to rural clients. Other informal lending includes ownand extended family sources.

4.3 Formal sources are: the two state-owned bank's, Banik of Ceylon (BOC) and Peoples's Bank (PB) with 287 and327 branches respectively, two-thirds of which are rurally located; the Rural Credit Department of the Central Bank ofSri Lanka (RCD/CBSL); and four private commercial bank's, the Commercial Bank of Ceylon (CBC) the HattonNational Bank (HNB), Sampath Bank, and Seylan Bank. Currently, these lend a total of about Rs. 10 billion annually,about 12 % of which goes to agriculture, including for both plantation and nonplantation crops, livestock and fisheries.

4.4 Semiformal sources comprise two Government controlled institutions, 17 Rural Regional Development Banks(RRDBs), and Cooperative Rural Banks (CRBs), and some 150 independent NGOs who engage in financialintermediation to varying degrees. The RRDBs have 160 branch offices. Although coordinated by the CBSL, whichnominates each RRDB's 5 person board, they operate independently in pursuit of deepening the rural financial structure.The CRBs are offshoots of the Multipurpose Cooperative Societies and work closely with Peoples Bank in mobilization,lending and pawnbroking. The primary NGO is the Thrift and Credit Cooperative Society (TCCS) known in Sinhaleseas SANASA, with about 731 thousand members in 7,632 village-based primary organizations, which are federated intoa national level organization. The Sarvadaya Shramadana Movement (SSM), is the second largest. It differs fromTCCS in being focussed mainly on the poor (those with difficulty in accessing credit). Presently, TCCS resources comemainly from obligatory member savings, which, with an interest spread permits own resource generation. It nowgenerates about Rs.600 million annually and lends about Rs.700 million. With an overall loan/deposit ratio of 1:2, itis very much self reliant for funding. Most other NGOs, including SSM, aim primarily at nonconventionally credit-worthy persons, obtaining some resources from external grants and from the IDA financed Janasaviya Trust Fund(established 1990). The volume here is relatively small and not aimed at commercial agriculture.

4.5 Informal sources of credit are mostly village based and quite amorphous. They include full-time and part-timemoney lenders, traders and family lenders. With overlap and gradation across the spectrum, it is difficult to directlyestablish the contribution of the various sources. Credit extended by traders is likely to be prefinanced in part by theformal sector. CBSL reports indicate that a substantial amount of informal lending comes from local persons engagedin fulltime service activities (including public-sector employees). Own-financing maybe the most important source ofinput financing in the rural sector.

4.6 On the demand side, in addition to agriculture and fisheries, loans in rural areas are utilized for small-scaleindustry, housing, electrification and water supply, and "projects/commerce" (i.e. trade). These account for 60-65%of all advances from formal and semiformal Fls in the rural sector.42

Credit Financing

4.7 Crop production financing from the banking sector is provided by an array of formal sector FIs, but primarilythe two public sector banks, Bank of Ceylon (BOC) and Peoples Bank (PB). Sources of funds are: i) own funds; andii) own funds onlent under a Government guarantee (New Comprehensive Rural Credit Scheme). Market rates arecharged for own funds, while NCRCS loans carry concessional rates.43 Although the specifics of coverage change,interventionist schemes of this nature have been a feature of Sri Lankan rural credit for the past 30 years. The rate ofuptake has been low relative to input use. Two-thirds of NCRCS financed loans are for paddy production and the restfor import competing crops.

4.8 Term financing for agriculture, mainly for food (rice) processing, is provided by the banking industry, bothpublic and private. Multilateral loans are a sizeable source of funds here, including the Bank's lines of industrial credit.Onlending rates are market oriented, being set at marked up deposit rates.

4.9 A comprehensive measure of the annual volume of short-term credit to the non-plantation crop sector from theformal and semi-formal Fls is elusive. In the meantime, NCRCS loans appear the best available measure. These have

42/ CBSL Annual Report 1993, Table 1.70.

43/ The NCRCS concessionial onlending rate is 16%, compared to market rates of around 23%. Government refunds the difference to theonlending Fis anid also guarantees to cover 50% of all loan losses. Up to 1994, the NCRCS loans were eligible for refinancing by theCentrall Banki of Sii Lalika's (CBSL). This is currently discontinued.

Page 30: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

20

been unrestricted in volume and carry concessional lending terms, as well as protection for lenders in the form of aguarantee of 50% cover for all losses. These features make it very attractive to both lenders and borrowers, and unusualcircumstances would be required to transact cultivation loans outside of the program. Since its inception in 1986 through1993, NCRCS credit to the nonplantation sector, has increased by 19% p.a. or 6% p.a. in constant volume terms. Bycomparison, Purchased Inputs have only increased by 0.22% annually in constant volume terms over the same period.But the share of NCRCS financing of Purchased Inputs only increased from 5.3% to 7.9%. The rapid growth inNCRCS financing reflects the small base at the outset, as well as the likelihood that some RFIs substituted NCRCSfinancing for their own resources due to its relative attractiveness (cf para 4.19).

Interest Rates, Savinigs and Input Financini

4.10 Interest rates under NCRCS loans are compared with commercial loan rates and savings rates below. Therelevant deposit rate for small farmers with uncertain cash flows is the regular savings accounts rate (i.e. the minimumrate); the higher rates apply to time deposits and savings certificates. Over the entire 1986-94 period, despite theconcessionary nature of NCRCS, the loan rate has well been above the deposit rate, making it far less costly to financepurchases from own funds than from NCRCS credits. At the lower end of their range, commercial bank rates appearcompetitive with NCRCS rates. But the weighted average prime rate of commercial banks, 14.2% p.a. in 1986 andrising to 20.5 in 1994, has always been well above the NCRCS rate. So, although small farmers do not qualify as primeborrowers, this of no loss to them.

Table 4.1 SRI LANKA - Agricultural Loan and Deposit Rates - 1986-94.

Period NCRCS COMMERCIAL BANK LOANS SAVINGSLOANS Immovable Unsecured DEPOSITS

Collateral

1986-90 9% p.a. 12-30% p.a. 13-33% p.a. 6-14% p.a.

1990 12% p.a. 9-28% p.a. 13-35% p.a. 5-14% p.a.

1991-92 14-16% p.a. 9-30% p.a. 13-33% p.a. 6.5-14% p.a.

1993 16% p.a. 13.8-28% p.a. 16.5-33% p.a. 6.5-14% p.a.16.5-28% p.a. l

1994 16% p.a. 15-28% p.a. 16.5-36% p.a. 6.5-14% p.a.

Sources: NCRCS - CBSL Rural Credit Department. Others - CBSL Annual Report 1993 Table 89.

4.11 In 1992, a typical year, and the most recent for which comprehensive data are available, the record forpaddy and OFCs was:

Total Purchased Inputs Rs. 11,228.8 million44

Cultivation Loans - NCRCS Rs.864.9 million45 7.5% of Purchased Inputs

At first glance, the low level of credit financing of inputs (7.5 %) might be seen as a constraint to sectoral performance.However, CBSL data for 1992 show Cultivation Loans as less than half of all loans and only 14% of all savings.

44/ National Accounts of SL 1993 - Final estimates Table 9 (p 63). Excludes hired labor, much of which is not a cash tmansaction.

45/ CBSL AniiiLutl Report 1993 Table 1.69.

Page 31: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

21

Total Savings - Rural Sector Rs. 5,983.7 milliontTotal Loans - Rural Sector Rs. 2,148.1 million4 ' 36% of SavingsCultivation Loans - NCRCS Rs. 864.9 millione 14% of Savings and 40% of Loans.

In other words, over 90% of purchased inputs are financed from informal sources. Total Rural Savings net ofCultivation Loans equals about half the Value of Purchased Inputs, showing substantial surpluses available in aggregateafter financing of input purchases. This indicates that, in aggregate, farmers can finance their purchased inputs fromearnings prior to saving.

4.12 Cultivation Loans in 1992 account for about 30% of Total Loans in the Rural Sector and Crop Loans for only30%. Two-thirds of all loans are for nonagricultural purposes, mainly housing, electrification and water supply. Ruraldwellers seemn to prefer to borrow for housing improvement over agricultural inputs. This could be taken to indicatea supply-side credit constraint arising from formal and semiformal RFls, restricting own-funds loans for home-equityinvestments, due to the fact that the latter may act as their own collateral, whereas farm land is non-mortgageable, whichwould limit the total of input credit to the amount covered by Government schemes (NCRCS), However, Total Loansare only about 1/3 to 1/4 of Total Savings (36% in 1992), while Cultivation Loans are In7 of Total Savings (14% in1992). Consequently, it is clearly feasible to expect most inputs to be own-financed, unless rural savers and farmersare not the same group, which in aggregate is unlikely. The negative spread between the deposit and loan rates providesa strong incentive for own financing of inputs.

4.13 Rural sector income appears quite sufficient for all input financing at present. Also, the informal marketcompetes successfully with the formal market, even where this has access to concessional credit. One conclusion ofinterest to policy makers is that, in this situation of high levels of off-farm incomes, the deposit rate, not the borrowingrate, is likely to be a significant factor in determining the volume of inputs used in the nonplantation crop sector.

Credit Constraints

4.14 It is often contended that there are nonmarket-based factors that constrain credit to agriculture and so limitsector performance. Structurally, the rural credit market would appear to be quite competitive. Entry and exit for FIsis easy; a sizeable number exist, and with a large branch network, making local monopolies unlikely. However, specificsupply- and demand-side aspects of the credit market have been highlighted as evidence to the contrary.

4.15 On the supply side, the relatively low level of purchased inputs, high transaction costs, the development of semi-formal, group-help based RFIs, and the existence of a concessional credit program (NCRCS) and its lack of expansion,are all advanced as indicators of constrained credit supply. On the demand side, inability of potential borrowers to meeteligibility criteria is put forward as a constraint to expression of demand for credit.

4.16 Purchased inputs, at 25% of value added may appear low; however, to attribute this to a credit constraint onlymay be very misleading. Despite its lack of comparative advantage, Sri Lanlka's paddy yield is comparable to that forsimilar Asian countries, suggesting a surfeit of inputs if anything. Also, the opportunity cost with respect to off-farmemployment (cf Chapter V) questions the value of additional onfarm effort in terms of income generation. These wouldbe demand shifters, but not exogenous constraints to the supply of credit.

4.17 Transaction costs may be higher than necessary, due to the lack of managerial autonomy in public-sectorbanking. High administrative costs (heavily state-oriented ownership and restrictive labor regulations have lead to over-staffing). While policy determined, this is not aimed directly at credit supply. The same situation does not arise inprivate sector commercial banks, making a prima facie case for privatization of the two public sector commercial banks.Also, while this is one area capable of improvement, it does not appear to have had any impact on credit availability,only on the cost of credit. Also, this is offset by the concessionally priced NCRCS credit program.

46/ CBSL Annual Report 1993 Table 1.70. i.e. rit amount afrer financing purchased inputs.

47/ CBSL Annual Reporn 1993 Table 1.70.

4XI CBSL Annual Repon 1993 Table 1.69. Includes PB and BOC data. but may or may not includc sornc or all rmral loan data in Table1.70.

Page 32: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

22

4.18 Development of a semi-formal credit supply is seen aimed at expanding access to credit, and so incomegeneration. Structurally it lies between formal and informal credit sources, competing with both. In competing withformal sources, it endeavors to overcome factors constraining access to formal suppliers (mainly collateral, biasedselection, and lack of credit discipline.)'9 To do this, it uses group-discipline (supervision) to substitute for collateral(or heavy supervision) and enforce a sustainable credit culture. To compete with informal lending sources, mainlymoneylenders, it maintains low overheads and prices it loans on a cost plus basis. In this fashion, it has successfullycarved out a market niche. Its success appears to lie in its ability to supply credit at a lower cost, thus substituting forformal and informal sources rather than creating new credit. TCCS, the major player in semi-formal credit supply, hasonly 25 % of its annual loan portfolio in crop agriculture. Since TCCS is demand driven (by its members), this lendingpattern is likely to be responsive to their demands rather than being supply driven.

4.19 Semi-formal RFIs rely heavily on own funds for resources, so the impact on the rural savings rate will be areasonable indicator of whether or not the semi-formal sector is a credit creator or substitutes for other sources of credit.Unchanged rural savings rates implies credit substitution and increased rates, credit creation. The share of savingsgenerated, while believed substantial, is indeterminable due to the unavailability of PB and BOC data on savingsmobilized by source (rural and other). However, if, as CBSL indicates,"e rural savings mobilization is mainly by thesemi-formal institutions, this implies no change in the savings rate induced by the expansion of semi-formal RFIs, andso no credit creation, but possible improved access to credit.

4.20 The concessional NCRCS credit program faces no policy determined supply constraint. Instead, the amountutilized is limited by demand for input financing and competition from other sources, mainly own savings financing.Discounted by the recovery rate, the effective average cost of NCRCS credit to farmers (16% x 0.7 = 11.2%) is abovethe deposit rate. At best this leaves farmers indifferent as to the use of their surplus earnings between saving andpurchasing inputs. When even minor transaction costs are added to credit financing, the balance comes down againstcredit financing of inputs. Since concessional agricultural credit has been available for about 30 years in Sri Lanka, andbranch banking is widespread, lack of information concerning availability is unlikely as a reason for non-expansion.The high default rate,5' makes all formal cultivation loans unprofitable; but FT losses under NCRCS are under half thatof losses on own funds.52 As a result, private sector commercial banks are unwilling to enter this field, and.the publicsector banks will restrict activities here to the extent that these losses are uncompensated for.5" The high spread andthe high default rates certainly constrain NCRCS loan volume, but again these are endogenous constraints, and notattributable to any anti-concessional lending stance.

4.21 Difficulty in accessing credit due to an inability to meet eligibility conditions, often used to infer an exogenousconstraint on ability to express demand, is more likely to be an endogenous supply-side effect. As seen above, highdefault rates, combined with limited loss guarantees, generally result in losses to Fls, and so a reluctance by formalsector FIs to enter or expand this credit activity.5' To limit their losses, FIs may try to select out high-risk borrowers.Although no more than risk-weighted pricing, this is often incorrectly seen as discriminating against subsistence farmers.At present, no private sector commercial banks undertake NCRCS lending."

49/ Collection rates for these semi-formal RFIs are generally close to 100%. But even for the semi-fornal RFIs with group based lending,collection rates for agricultural loans are well below there average. Consequendy, even for these RFls, loan portfolios are heavily biasedagainst loans for purchased inputs in agriculture.

50/ CBSL Annual Report 1993 (page 165), Mobilization of Rural Savings.

51/ Averaging about 30% since 1970, it dropped to 159% in the mid-80s, but has since risen again. CBSL Annual Report 1993, Table 93.

52/ For commercial loans, Rs.(123xO.7)-123 = -Rs.36.9, i.e. Actual return minus expected return gives a loss of Rs.36.9 for every Rs. 100lent; while for NCRCS loans, the loss is only Rs. (I1 6x0.7)-116 + ((116x0. 7)-116)x.05 = -Rs. 17.4, or 47% of the loss under comnercialconditions (assuming no difference in default rates).

53/ Faced with a high level of liquidity, formal Fis outflank the indiscipline problem through udlizing local taders as intenmediaries byseasonal-financing of inputs stocks. Traders can employ good selection criteria, as being local, they avoid the asymptotic informationtrap, and being private they are not susceptible to political pressure. Finally, they will have low collection costs. The extent of thisis unknown.

54/ In Sri Lanka, the fact that only the public sector banks participate in NCRCS is seen as evidence of this.

55/ The impact on private sector commercial banks' portfolio performance of debt-forgiveness in public sector rural credit schemes is unknown.

Page 33: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

23

4.22 Government has endeavored to create a more favorable environment for banks through guaranteeing 50% oflosses incurred under NCRCS, and strengthening the framework for debt recovery; the political process, to which publicsector banks are highly amenable, may have severely weakened the end product. Over time, client selection bynoncommercial Fls has not permanently impacted on the default rate. This suggests that selection may be beyond theprerogative of management, and instead determined by elements extemal to the Fls unconcerned with institutionalperformance. In this case, NCRCS credit would only be available to persons with some political standing in rural areas,which would constrain access by poor farmers.

4.23 Inability to use land as collateral is sometimes seen as a substantive obstacle to access, but very likely only forthe marginal borrower,5" i.e. for the subsistence farmer, who faces the greatest likelihood of nondeliberate default.Concessional credit programs aim to overcome this pricing problem. Here it appears that NCRCS terms areinsufficiently concessionary to overcome the risk to Fls. But the more generous the concession package the greater thebudgetary cost. The answer lies in restructuring the approach to one of very restricted targeting, heavily focussed onsubsistence agriculture as the appropriate target group. However, while not a constraint now, the nonavailability of landas collateral is likely to be a major constraint to development of a long-term credit market, which will be essential fora competitive land market.

4.24 Other, unpublished, data57 indicate that lending in 1992 and 1993, by formal and semiformal institutions, forpaddy and OFC production was about Rs.5 billion, or 45% of the Value of Purchased Inputs. This (unpublished)volume is 6 times the amount lent under the NCRCS concessional scheme, giving Rs.4 billion of nonconcessional loans.Since there are no policy restrictions on the volume of credit covered by the concessional program, it is difficult tounderstand why either a lender or borrower would choose to operate outside the comforts of the program. But evenif true, because this still leaves the majority of inputs as own-financed, and surplus savings remain unchanged, this doesnot appear to change the fact that no, nonmarket-based, credit constraint is in evidence.

Credit and Subsistence Aericuiture

4.25 The existence of net savings in rural areas alongside concessional credit is seen due to the varying net positionsof individual farmers, i.e. some are net savers and some are net credit users." Combined with stagnant outputperformance, this could also be interpreted as an indication of constrained access to credit. But as shown in ChapterVII, expanding output under present conditions can well result in loss of income, making this interpretation unlikely.However, this is only true so long as off-farm employment is available. Where it is not, it is quite possible to have asituation where a farmer has labor surplus to the farms requirements and output is constrained through lack of inputfinancing. With competitive financial and input markets, and no evidence of any aggregate input-financing constraint,this situation is likely to be structurally induced, arising from farm size being viewed by the credit market as too smallto be viable as the sole source of family income (cf para 5.19).

4.26 About 30% or so of the farmers (about 1/2 million farmers) on the lower end of the farm size distribution5

are the farmers whose productivity will be constrained by access to input financing if they are unable to find off-farmemployment and/or access to credit. But these are the people Binswanger and Rosenzweig wrote about in their note"Are Small Farmers too Small to be Efficient", addressing the problems of micro-sized farms in South India. Poorfarmers, due to their asset scarcity, do not have the capacity to carry risk (i.e. bear intertemporal losses), and becausethe cost of insurance is so high,' the market, however perfect, is unable to provide them credit. It is unrealistic toexpect the commercial credit market to provide inputs to such people, whose needs should be addressed in a different

56/ Unsecured loans carry the same interest rates as collaterized loans - Table 4. 1.

57/ Provided to the mission by CBSL Rural Credit Department.

58/ Some may also he due to the defaulter group, for whom the cost of borrowing (0%) is way below the opportunity cost (the savingsdeposit rate).

591 i.e. widt a farm size of less than 0.5 ac (0.2 ha) i.e. the average was about 0.2 ac (0.08 ha) in 1982. Sri Lanka Census ofAgriculture 1982 General Report. Table 8B (p. 16).

60/ Crop insuranice is very costdy because of the covariant nature of the risks facing the pool of insured (i.e. each insured's crop sufferfrom the same natural hazards as the next), the high cost of the asymptotic information and moral hazard problems (policing andpaying). As a result, crop insurance is almost never successful and should not be seen as a possible solution.

Page 34: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

24

manner, i.e through programs targeted to subsistence agriculture rather than through programs for commercialagriculture, including commercial credit.

Rural Credit Svstem - Outlook

4.27 Because the agricultural credit system is relatively shallow (as a proportion of sectoral economic activity), thequestion arises as to whether or not it would have the capacity to meet expanded credit demand in the event of anupsurge in sectoral output? It is likely that loan appraisal capacity and ability would prove to be at least one limitingfactor, especially where new activities are involved. This could result in a significant increase in nonperforming loansand endanger the financial strength of the credit intermediaries. The public sector banks already have sizeable problemsin this respect. The semiformal intermediaries, while appearing to be relatively free of such problems now, do not havethe size and diversity of operations to permit them to bear substantial losses. Where the sector is also undergoing afundamental structural adjustment, particularly in terms of farm size, this concern would be enhanced. Thus in the eventof rapid growth in the nonplantation sector, additional monitoring of the health of the rural financial institutions and closesupervision by the Central Bank would be needed.

4.28 The likely requirement by rural financial intermediaries that loans be fully collateralized by fixed assets, suchas land would reduce this risk. This could enhance the adjustment process through helping the less efficient farmersto conclude where their best financial interests lie. Because such collateralization would require freehold land titlingand establishing a land market, it will inevitably act as a severe brake on expansion of sectoral economic activity as wellas biasing the gains towards those already with access to financing and cause the premature exiting of otherwise wellqualified farmers. This points to the need to move ahead as rapidly as possible with a land title reform program andestablishing the institutions necessary for land titling and registration as a prerequisite to a land market.

4.29 The role of Government in rural credit must also change from one of providing concessionary credit whichundermines credit discipline to one of ensuring development of a competitively structured credit system. It must alsoplay it's part in resolving credit discipline problems through cessation of all loan-forgiveness programs and provisionof systems for rapidly and equitably resolving all valid loan contracts.

4.30 Under fulltime professional farming, substantial credit financing would be required for to meet input needs,especially where output is expanding rapidly. The current high level of the nonconcessional interest rate, around 23-25%, could prove too costly for many activities, especially new crops with uncertain returns. This high rate is not areflection of the functioning of the rural credit market, but of the overall macrobalances in the economy. Trying toresolve or even alleviate the problem through direct interventions in the rural credit market will only create furtherproblems, as any concessional scheme facing a sector with high credit needs must inevitably be rationed, leading tobiased distribution, resource misallocation, nonviable credit institutions and growing economic and financial losses.Instead, any high interest rate problem needs to be addressed at its source, i.e imbalances in public sector revenues andexpenditures.

Policv Conclusions

4.31 Overall the rural credit market appears to work well. Competition is certainly present in aggregate, with allsources of credit supply in competition within and among the major segments of supply and no evidence of any supplyconstraint is present. On the demand side, the high level of own financing appears to largely eliminate any commercialcredit pricing issues. Although these will inevitably exist for asset poor and remotely located individuals andcommunities, this cannot be taken as an indication of a poorly performing market. Institutional performance may alsobe weak in some RFIs, which if corrected would lower transaction costs; again this is not a sign of a distressed market.Thus, while improvements are possible to enhance the cost-effectiveness and coverage of the rural credit system, thereis no evidence that this in anyway constrains credit availability in aggregate and thus sector performance.

4.32 Although NCRCS is a relatively small share of input financing and a substitute for already available financing,it still represents a significant cost to taxpayers, amounting to about Rs. 190 million (US$4 million) in 1993. The majorconcerns with access to credit appear entirely on the supply-side, but are seen to be endogenous market driven factorsSand unrelated to market structure or policy-induced factors. On balance, the credit market would appear competitivezind unconstrained by any non-market based factors, and so is unlikely to be a constraint to sector performance. The

Page 35: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

25

concessional NCRCS credit system may well be creating an excess of credit. Terminating the program would botheliminate the excess and reduce the budgetary burden.

4.33 External influence in agricultural-input loan repayment, mainly from political sources, has greatly reduced creditdiscipline among farmers, who tend to see these loans as grants. The resulting losses to the financial system has ledan unwillingness on the part of the RFIs to actively pursue lending for agricultural inputs. This contraction in financialintermediation in rural areas will need to be reversed to permit growth. In short, to reverse this, political interventionin loan portfolio management in this area will need to cease. The only feasible way to achieve this is to establish astructure by which such intervention becomes ineffective. Autonomization/privatization of the entire banking system(similar to the approach recommended for irrigation) is the only feasible way to achieve this.

4.34 Rationalization of Government involvement in the agricultural credit market should center around separatingall concessional credit programs into those which are strictly commercially oriented and those which are aimed atsubsistence farmers. Commercial programs should be sold to commercial banks, and any public sector commercial RFIsshould be restructured as necessary and privatized. Noncommercial activities, aimed at subsistence farmers should betightly targeted and structured so as to minimize leakage into commercial areas. In effect, this would be a subsistenceagriculture project, with the objective of making these farmers commercially viable.

V. LAND

Land Tenure Policv

5.1 Land tenure policy and legislation in Sri Lanka emerged from the recommendation of the Land Commissionof 1927 for preservation of smallholder agriculture through holding Crown Land in trust for the whole community.Successive legislation, in the form of the Paddy Lands Acts of 1953 and 1958 and subsequent amendments, regulatedtenant farming activities, with a heavy bias in favor of permanency for the incumbent tenant and fixing the maximumrent in terms of volume of output (15 bushels of paddy per acre). The Land Reform Law of 1970, and the 1975Amendment to this, nationalized large estates including tree crops plantations and regulated the size of paddy farmsnationwide, alienating excesses to the public sector for redistribution to smallholders as tenants in perpetuity. This hasleft a ceiling of on private, owner operated paddy land of 25 acres, while for tenant farming and in public sectorirrigation schemes, the ceiling is 5 acres.

5.2 The Agricultural Productivity Law of 1972 provided for dispossession of agricultural lands not used produc-tively. Subsequently, the Agrarian Services Act of 1979 restricted the use of paddy land to the production of paddyonly, but limited dispossession to only voiding the owners right to cultivate such lands. The 1991 Amendment to theAgrarian Services Act provided for appeal against dispossession orders and eliminated the restriction on the croppingof paddy land.

5.3 The primary objective of land policy has been to provide fixed assets for landless farmers in the form of land.With a rapid post-WWII spurt in population growth, and in the absence of corresponding growth in other sectors,pressure on land grew more intense. By the time of the Land Reform Law (1970), 75% of holdings were already below5 acres, so that the redistributive impact of the Act was small. Other efforts to provide land to the landless focussedon finding idle public sector land for redistribution. Estimates of up to 2 million acres of rainfed agricultural land havebeen made, but substantiation is difficult. In any case, this land, lacking in water, is bound to be marginal, requiringmuch larger farm size to ensure viability.

Farm Size

5.4 In line with longstanding policy objectives, land tenure policy is heavily focussed on poverty alleviation, farmsize is generally small and farm numbers and size in Sri Lanka's nonplantation sector are distributed relatively evenly(Figure 5.1). The most recent agricultural census (1982) showed 91 % of all farms were of 2 ha (5 acres) or less. Theseoccupied 60% of the nonplantation agricultural area, but almost 100% of the actual cultivated area. Irrigation-development has been dovetailed with this land tenure policy through creation of resettlement schemes in major irrigationinvestments, providing a maximum irrigated area of 2 acres, plus 1/2 acre of "highland" or nonirrigated land. Currently72% of farms are 1 ha (2.5 acres) or less. But this data is 15 years old and does not reflect the current picture.

Page 36: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

26

Continued population pressure, with no significant rural-urban migration, varying legislative codes, multiple user andinheritance rights, and protracted legal procedures, have all resulted in widespread informal multiple co-ownership andfurther fragmentation in privately owned land, resulting in continuous decrease in effective farm size over time. Despitelegislative prohibition, the same forces have inevitably led to informal fragmentation in state-owned lands (irrigationsettlements) and, although not well documented, all indications are that this continues to grow.6 '

F~~ure 51: t4onplantadon Seci~or .amNmesm ........% cumulative ............... .. .90 iSil000j0-:0-CT!:.0. .j;Xi: g itE: iEESt!0.-,0 iDigai. i.00000.F.!t ti-400- tl.:.e, -igig!000.g;-it-E-;X0-:ift:-0X,li--,440.t :0000..... -..,-g.. .......| :l l;:l i; i m i:; iw' it;00:;l :;:} l: -ti ::. :"'--;E t t: iS00.isu0.5.100^0'Non,UM*U ' '.,-',S.'.'... . '...".....'' '.".'.'.'.""

P -:! lig :;;SEt , tigl: iS00; C;0-0 .esmiL.fiL:0.00tl;0-00": H as t. %. . . .. . . ...i.s...tS' '-0- i-fff :-S:-;: ' b it' (':: f-'0:S ;::f; '7 o: :!0:.f:f;t'S; S : :''! i ff:ft, 2.fff:E :; f : fiS -;::iL f ; A: -:-.:. S i f . i..-.... ...

. . . . . ..... .. ....-. ........ .... . . -. . .. .. .... . .... ... .. ...... ... . ...... :- : - .-

S. ...- : - -- .-. ,.,- : .... ,.*.

...... ... . ... . ... . . . . .

A A A7N.. S a S~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~...... .

Sourc.i $jt Lute AuIwjhur.i 0mev. li..S....t ....(.t....w.b....8...

. . . ...:. -:0 -::g -;... . . .. . .. i .00!....F-ifi:d '::: d. iA .: . ..:f:i ../ ... .. .0-|, .:!i .. ....t: Fte0:!:,......":'V .. . .TS": ..iS i;;;.iS. ;SA :-,i , ;-; .iSSf-SA ;# - . ...... i .. . ...-...-. ff.,. . .- . . .

...0-004-0-t. 00:.5... . . .. . . ... ... : igE.. li7 . .7 .:- g- -5 |.:.-.... E: . . ... ..g;;-7. g g... . g- A-gg: 75g

5.5 With0 84% of;ii :ig gi :0 00 the total, thet s itate; dom tgina::-0-tll$ies lan ow erhi in Sri Lanka eve in agrculur (66 excldin

: .}.f.-.f.;.. f.E.. !.Zl!AS; .... -- :ir :W.;W ,# f.:: i: -

: i.,;-gLi-g,.i-i! 70: i: t!:,.;i;E .; ! Wit. i; ,. .iE.00E, i l. # .442E....... .... ......... .. ..70;.

inland waters). Agricultural land accounts for approximately 2.79 million ha or about 43% of the total land mass. Ofthis 63 % is owned by the state, but farmed by private fartners under varying tenure arrangements. The distribution ofthis is shown in Table 5. 1. Tenancy arrangements vary in degrees of restriction as to use and transfer, ranging fromvery restrictive LDO leases (99 year leases with unitary use, access and succession, and acceptance of mortgagesrestricted to cooperative societies and seizure or foreclosure for debt repayment disallowed), to 'Swarnabhoomi" (GoldenLands)62 land grants (permanent titles, but having a significant restriction in a requirement for prior permission beforetransfer and registration of title as an effort to prevent subdivision and multiplicity of ownership).

5.6 As a result, neither LDO (Land Development Ordinance - 0.82 million ha) lease nor Swarnabhoomi grant lands(0.1 million ha) are acceptable as mortgageable collateral by commercial banks. This fact qualifies them as less thanpurely private property, although Swarnabhoomi lands are classified as privately owned in Sri Lanka. Although ongoingsince 1982, the rate of conversion of LDO use permits to Swarnabhoomi grants has been extremely slow. Only 6% ofstate owned agricultural land is under Swarnabhoomi grant title. A more general restriction on sales of Governmnentsettlement land is that it can only be sold to the same class of farmer, i.e., a Government-settled peasant farmer holdingnot more than 1 ha, so this limits the sales possibilities. Since settlement holdings are constrained in size to I ha, this

.......... . ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~.

61/ See WP# 5.

6V/ Recently chaniged to) Jayahhoomi; whichl has approximately the same meaning in English as Swarnabhoomi.

Page 37: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

27

further limits the sales possibilities. Finally, since the land is not mortgageable and such small farmers are unlikely tohave sufficient savings, effectively any formal market is eliminated here.

Land Utilization and Cropping Intensity

5.7 Both land use and cropping intensity are low. In 1992, permanent crops,63 utilized about 1.0 million ha ofagricultural land, leaving about 1.7 million ha of agricultural land for utilization by nonplantation crops, i.e., annualcrops.' Actual area cultivated for these crops65 was 0.69 million ha, or 44% cropped in Maha, and 0.4 million ha,or 25% in Yala. These are very low utilization rates are attributed by IIMI to a shortage of irrigation water relativeto land.& Availability of water may constrain overall land utilization, but would not explain cropping intensity,particularly in irrigated areas. Paddy cropping intensity has been as high as 140% in the past decade. But this is nowmuch lower. The recent 3-year average was only 109%.67 While the explanation would appear to lie at a morefundamental level, it does appear that people in agriculture may be deliberately reducing their farming effort. Inevitablythis must impact very negatively on irrigation investment returns. But, it can only be seen as an indicator rather thanan explanation of the poor performance in the nonplantation crop sector.

5.8 Time series data show the aswedummized (irrigable) area to be increasing at a faster rate than the gross areacropped by paddy, causing the ratio of the two, i.e. the cropping intensity to decline. About 80-85% of theaswedummized area, or 540 thousand ha, is irrigated. Government owned, large and medium scale schemes accountfor about 55 % of this, the remainder being much older, community developed, village-level schemes. But, these largeand medium schemes generally have sufficient water for both Maha and Yala crops. These also account for the morerecent additions to the aswedummized area, suggesting that the decline in cropping intensity is more likely to be in theolder, village-tank schemes (cf paras 6.2 - 6.3). Change in rainfall pattern or poor maintenance could cause this toohappen; in which case, the expected response would be a substantive change in cropping pattern away from crops withhigh water demand and low value towards higher valued and less water intensive crops. But this is not seen. In anycase, the loss to the economy through low land utilization and cropping intensities is undoubtedly significant.

CropDin2 Pattern

5.9 Despite its low relative profitability, paddy is by far the dominant crop in the non-plantation crop sector. It occupies77 % of nonplantation cropped land in Maha and 81 % in Yala. 6B Income from paddy (GDP per ha) is among the lowestof all major crop groups in Sri Lanka. In the nonplantation sector, on average, GDP per ha from the widely variedOther Food Crops (OFC) group is 7-times that of paddy, up from 4-times in 1980.4 These margins appear too largeto be explained by the average-versus-marginal returns to fixed factors argument. Neither does limitation in marketdemand for OFCs explain the situation, as individual suppliers are too small for this to impact on their output decisions.

5.10 Nonetheless, despite its relatively low profitability, paddy dominates the cropping pattern, utilizing a croppedarea 4-times greater than that for OFCs. Since farmers are not charged for water, its cost does not enter into GDPcalculations. Yet, water is the constraining factor in Sri Lankan agriculture and paddy is a highly water-intensive crop.Imputed costing for water, even at its financial cost, would push the relative profitability ratio even more in favor ofOFCs. In economic terms, the cost to the economy of such a cropping pattern is seen to be extremely high. The cost

3.3/ Comprising tea. rubber and coconut, fruit plantations, and spices (Minor Export Crops)

04/ Mainly Paddy and Other Food Crops (OFCs), including grains, pulses, fruits and vegetables.

6%5. In 1989-90, the last year in which all island data was published.

66/ 'Potential of Diversified Cropping in the Paddy Lands of Sri Lanka". Mimeo version page 17. IIMI, Colombo, December 1994.

(i7 Average of 1988/89-90191 - Agricultural Statistics of Sri Lanka 1992 Table 5.5

68/ Based on 1989-9t crop data, but year-to-year variation is small. Due to water constraints, Yala cropped area is only 60% of the areacropped in Maha.

6)/ See WP#6. Taible 10t. Also note, this fatetor vanes between 3 and 7 depending on the crop, year, and data base.

Page 38: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

28

3;;0 X03 -CATEG:ORYE }i f030

i:: ~ L cc i 00- t:-:Inlandgilt ,,'gWate s 14ggli;:. {,20 m*ln hi I:-t : 5-02::T:iiFu0resi st&: Re :ig-rv :s 2g .18 nuill -- h tt ii it3 3% - t-: :

* iA whtLh..~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~......

-- unde...r O lease QZ millf l. . .

vi : : :Xs.0 .000 .................00-$ 0. -

. .- . T r ee.C.. . ...P l.at io. .... .... .

.Ur.- b aa : ArElel 0;2 I0 mil hi 0;i0

....- ... -:i.t wi iich ...i e G;I7 m i h-S .- ' . '-~ To0ial Large fnJarid Waters, -ores.,0ts and Wild bfe Reserves arid Urban Areat'P-'$L $at.i.' iro. f. .

w) Jt.emaindei derive ahme%tally

i-q psutm x*ll;Mith try s Ag-ureXa to e LrelyPwatelyi Owne (to Col Imb th ari0 .~ne or i0wmIe -~ h 20^ is 1 -noly b0 Wiaa4e I( gg -.1 ti Tnru 5;0tis ;;la,nl* wll Tb*!; - r - .k ;rtuocmTreE:rnps And;mor~ Saw Lanka 19 iage 41 r h rn a ade o-f-f} Prvll Owei l: n -. I : ~ t b :

::!Z. Y-rginU*Wil lad ertdfve,4.a inty-:-4 -W: -gr...-t-r.l lnd ar i,-.f 2; 5g - d ... hi.t.. ~ c lanS Envir i su,rvs Es e h s ad b fe-R.......i E: ml 1......... ....T. of therrigationsus idyalone(i.. te t r b s 3% of G (a 3

fro -th impor tEasriff whfSich : + is bon bytecnueidsaohr2 fGPt h ot(aa33)

5.11 It wuld pparthavtthsdmnancreofpdy,a lw: vaud, lo famicm-gnrtn comdiy s att

ig % %it.Sk'tfigS~~~...... Et .:: . .. .... .. ..... Id.lLWt.: 0::

source of poor performance in the nonplantation crop sector. However, low valued output and small farm size wouldappear a sure combination to encourage these less profitable farmers to exit agriculture so as to improve their incomeearning possibilities. This is a common phenomenon, and occurs in many countries. It is generally accomplished byselling the fixed assets, mainly land, and entering the nonfarm labor market. This allows average farm size to increase,thus increasing individual farm incomes to a level comparable with nonfarm incomes, even where overall sectoral incomemay be growing very slowly. Labor productivity will improve as the poor performers will be the first to exit. Becauseof the lack of a land market, this normal adjustment mechanism is not available to the sector. Larger farms will alsohave the ability to bear risk and so enhance the likelihood of diversification as tulltime farmers seek to expand incomet-earning opportunities.

Page 39: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

29

Land Market

5.12. Over the 4-year period 1989-92, the average annual value of total registered land transfers in Sri Lanka wasRs.714 million.7t' The nature of this land and the area involved is unspecified. Capitalizing the income stream frompaddy gives a land value of Rs.135 thousand per ha.'' Assuming (overgenerously) all land transferred to beagricultural, gives an annual sales volume of about 5300 ha, or 0.025% of the stock. At this rate, it would take 200years to turnover (reallocate) all privately owned agricultural land and half a century to reallocate the entire stock(ignoring multiple sales). Although many transfers will be intergenerational, this is a very slow rate.' The fact thatover 90% of all transactions are for "considerations" rather than mortgage financed may be an indication of thisconcentration on intergenerational transfers. But it could also result from difficulty in getting mortgage financing forasset transactions where title is so heavily disputed. Information on the market mechanisms and transaction costs aresketchy and anecdotal at best, due mainly to the narrowness of the market itself.'

5.13 It is important to note that even with needed policy reform in both trade and irrigation, the cropping pattemwould still remain highly paddy oriented. Even the development of land markets and full-time farmers would not changethis. As seen from the results of the simple model,'4 a 10% reduction in import constraints on rice and other importcompeting crops (chilies, onions, etc.) actually causes an increase of 0.18% in rice output. Even increasing the riceelasticity of supply 5 times, from the generally accepted 0.09 to 0.45, only causes a 0.9% decline in rice output. Asa result, it seems clear that paddy will remain very much the dominant crop.

Policy Conclusions

5.14 In brief the position here is:- Government owns the majority of the agricultural and irrigated land;- farm size is very small, and declining;- cropping intensity is low and declining;- the cropping pattern continues to be dominated by low valued paddy;- the formal land market is unable to contribute to changing farm size; but- needed policy changes will not bring radical cropping changes; paddy will still dominate.

5.15 The net result is that expected adjustment is not occurring. Normal adjustment in farm size is blocked by thecombination of Government dominance of land ownership and an ineffective land market. Policy makers should lookto amending this situation as it is a hindrance to adjustment and so sector performance. Farmers with nonviable holdingsand low productivity farmers are being trapped in agriculture without the possibility of exiting short of abandoning theirfixed assets.

5.16 A generalized policy of private ownership of agricultural land should be adopted. Accompanying this shouldbe programs in settlement areas to transfer ownership to listed tenants without delay. In private sector land, mechanismsto rapidly resolve disputed title should be established. Swift action by all concerned parties (public and private) shouldbe encouraged through a tax-based incentive system to speed up both title transfer (public sector) and dispute resolution(private sector).'5 Programs should also be developed to enhance the efficiency and transparency of the land market,including providing at cost, all public sector generated and stored information concerning land records, policies,

70/ For details see WP#6, Table 7.

71/ Assuming a cropping ihtensity of I. 1. For details see WP#6. Table 11.

72/ Normally a finmn generation lasts about 35 years (i.e. from age 25 to 60); thus all farm land would change ownership at least once inthis time period.

73/ For a description of land laws, public secEor land institutions, and sample indicators of the extent of title disputes, see"Land Tenure Study', Mimeo. S. Berugoda, Colombo, December 1994.

74/ See WP#3, Table 6 and Appendix i.

75/ The rationale for this would be compensation of the state for lack of full economic use of agricultural land.

Page 40: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

30

programs, and transfer processes. All restrictions on minimum size holdings should be eliminated'6 to legalize thestatus quo and permit more orderly, market-based reallocation. Restrictions on land use, beyond those based ondemonstrably valid urban zoning and environmental considerations, should all be eliminated. There appears no strongrationale for an upper bound on farm size, and this should be increased to not less than 500 acres to permit developmentof commercial agriculture.

5.17 The financial value placed on irrigated land will be critically dependent on cost recovery policy for public sectorexpenditures on irrigation investment and O&M. Continuation of the current zero cost recovery policy will result ina value much higher than with a full cost recovery policy. To avoid confusion and needless financial stress, Governmentwill need to be completely transparent and consistent about its irrigation cost recovery policy from the start. This willallow the market to discount the land value for this, even if timing is uncertain. Inconsistency and abrupt change willcause undue financial stress and may lead to exploitation of some group or other of land owners. Also, considerationshould be given to restricting sales of newly privatized Government land, for perhaps 3-5 years, to prevent unwantedsales gluts at the outset of the program. However, leasing of all types should be legalized immediately. Demand-basedtitling programs for public sector land might assist here, but run the risk of being designed to bureaucratically delay theprivatization process.

5.18 The institutional elements for land markets need to be established. This will take time and require legislativeaction. Title Registration requires passing a "Registration of Title Act" to establish the basis for registration,reconciliation of disputes, transfer of title, and administration of the process. Allied to this is the need for a "Surveyingand Mapping Act" to provide for the operation land surveying activities, including minimum qualifications, registration,licensing and bonding of professionals, distinction between public and private sector activities. Training needs capacityfor public and private sector agents should be provided for. Because of the critical limiting nature of water in respectto productivity and value of agricultural land in Sri Lanka, unless its property status is established at the outset,uncertainty here will depress the value of land. As a result, creation of private water property rights will also becomenecessary to create the flexibility necessary for efficient functioning of factor markets. Drafts of both acts wereapproved in principle by the Cabinet in 1990. These, and other land related legislation, should be reviewed to ensurefocus on facilitation of development of an efficient market system and contain no obstacles to this. Sri Lankan officialsshould establish an operating timetable for this.

VI. FARM FAMILY INCOME AND OUTPUT ADJUSTMENT

6.1 The issues uncovered in respect to the incentive structure, rural credit, and land markets do not explain whythere is no adjustment in the cropping pattern from a high-cost low-valued paddy to a lower-cost higher-valued mixture.These issues are external to the farm; instead, the explanation for this must be sought within the farm.

6.2 Rural areas contain about 65 % of the population and 40 % of the labor force, but agriculture accounts for only25% of total GDP. With an average farm of I ha and 0.81% irrigated, a cropping intensity of 1.1, and cropped bypaddy, average labor utilization is only 106 days (120x0.8xl.l), and yields an annual net income of about Rs.25thousand, or Rs.5000 ($100) per family member. This compares with a national average of Rs.28,395 or $588 percapita (1993). Left to depend on agriculture, rural dwellers would be far less well off than their urban cousins. Clearly,the income differential is too large to be sustained in an economy with an open labor market, particularly since theaverage scenario utilizes less than one third of the available work-time. In fact, a substantial volume of income is earnedoff-farm. Labor Force Survey data for 1993 (see Table 6.1) 7 show that persons whose main occupation is agriculturespent on average one third of their working time in a non-agriculture occupation, and derived 41% of their income fromnon-agricultural work. For some, this can be as high as 80% of their income. Even persons whose principaloccupations are non-agricultural average half their time working in the sector, although earning only 16% of theirincome in the sector.

76/ The public doesn't want them and they are unenforceable.

77/ For details see WP#6. Tables I and 2A.

Page 41: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

31

Table 6.1: Sri Lanka - Labor Allocation and Returns by Occupation.

% Non ||___________ J Agriculture | Share agriculture Share

(Principal Occupation - Agriculture) _

Hours (million) 12.5 66 6.3 34

Inc. (Rs. million) 134 59 92.7 41

Wages (Rs./hr) 11 - 15 |

(Principal Occupation - Nonagriculture)

Hours (million) 24.2 52 22.8 48

Inc. (Rs. million) 158 16 818 84

Wages (Rs./hr) 7 - 36 -

Source: Sri Lanka Quarterly Labour Survey 1993 - unpublished data.

6.3 Detailed investigations of this area are only now just beginning in Sri Lanka. An initial report 7, based ona survey of two villages (one wet and one dry zone village), confirms the aggregate picture seen from the Labor ForceSurvey data above. The villages averaged 200 (216 and 192) families and 4.75 (4.6 and 4.9) people per family. Farmsize varied, averaging 0.30 ha aswedummized and 0.31 ha upland in the wet zone village, and 0.9 ha azwedummizedand 0.30 ha upland in the dry zone.79 In the wet zone village, 40% of surveyed farmers and 90% of all householdsreported nonagricultural activities, while in the dry zone village 10% of farmers and 56% of households did so.' Non-farm income averaged 81 % of total family income in the wet zone village and 55 % in the dry zone village.8 ' 1

6.4 Analysis of family farm-income from the average farming situation in major and minor irrigation schemes andrainfed agriculture shows imputed hourly earnings rates ranging from Rs. I I to Rs. 14.' These compare well with theaggregate figure of Rs. 1 1 per hour for farm labor obtained from Labor Force Survey data. This Survey also shows,for persons whose primary occupation is agriculture, an off-farm average wage rate of Rs. 15 per hour. On the face ofit, there might appear to be little advantage to working on or off farm, particularly for those at the higher end of thehourly earnings scale. But a more interesting fact emerging from the analysis is that the amount of family laborabsorbed on the average farm is quite small, ranging from a high of 350 days on farms in major irrigation schemes toa low of 180 days on rainfed farms. At 1.5, the average cropping intensity'M in the analysis is well above the actual

78/ Report on Workshop on Rural Diversification (Project No IDRC 90-0117) May 27-29, 1994, Negombo, Sri Lanka. Socio-Economicsand Planning Cemtre. Department of Agriculture, Peradeniya, Sri Lanka.

79/ Note this dry zone village is in the Mahaweli irrigation scheme area, but the farm size is well below the minimum authorized area of I ha.

80/ This and the Labor Force Survey, confirm the preliminary findings in regard to increasing off-farm employment in Sri LankaPoverty Assessment, World Bank Report No. 13431-CE, January 11, 1995, para 1.22.

81/ For details by type of employment see Working Paper #6, Table 1.

82/ With no discernible change in either area sown or method of sowing for paddy (broadcasting 80%, transplanting et al 20%). paddyoutput levels clearly did not suffer froilm expanded off-farm employment opportunities. Also, it appears that increase inaswedummized area offset the impact of the decline in cropping intensity.

83/ These are averaged over paddy and major OFCs and over both Maha and Yala seasons. Disaggregation by crop and season widensthe range to Rs. I to Rs.23 per hour.

84/ Assuming major and minor irrigation schemes as state owned land and rainfed as privately owned gives a weighted cropping intensity of 1.5.

Page 42: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

32

average of 1.1. Also, the farm size used (I ha) may overstate the actual average. Consequently, the estimated the rateof family labor utilization may be on the high side. The average rural family comprises 5.1 persons, providing 1.965years of labor, or about 590 days.5 The overarching conclusion is that, even where fully farmed, the average SriLankan farm remains a source of surplus labor, inevitably requiring family members to seek off-farm employment tomeet demands for higher income.

6.5 If the cropping pattern were adjusted to 100% OFCs (chili, onion and potato) and 0% paddy, family farmincome and family labor utilization would increase. Income and family labor use respectively would increase by factorof 2.4 and 3 for major irrigated farms, 3 and 2.8 for minor irrigated famis and 3 and 2.4 for rainfed farms. In fact,the average family could not meet this incremental labor demand internally. But importantly, before the inevitabledecline in output prices, on major irrigated farms hourly eamings would decline from Rs.14 to Rs.12 per hour (15%),giving greater incentive for off-farm employment. Meanwhile, on minor irrigated and rainfed areas earnings per hourwould increase from Rs. 11 and Rs. 14 to Rs. 12 and 18, or about 9% and 29% respectively. The increased hourlyeamings on minor irrigated farms is still not quite competitive with off-farm possibilities (Rs.15), but the increase inrainfed areas clearly is. Yet here, as seen from village survey data (para 2.38), the level of off-farm employmentappears to be higher than elsewhere. Three factors may account for the apparent contradiction. Wet zone (rainfed)areas are closer to major urban centers with larger labor markets and higher wages. Wet zone land, being largelyprivately owned land, suffers from far more fragmentation and greater title dispute, in many areas is climaticallyunsuitable for production of high valued OFCs, and, due to water shortages has low cropping intensities. This wouldresult in reduced average farm size and income per ha, and so reduce hourly earnings to levels lower than estimatedhere. These factors are not well reflected in the summary analysis, but are clearly evidenced in the village survey study(para 2.37).86 This may also apply to smaller minor irrigation schemes, many of which are in the wet zone. Inconclusion, it appears that the combination of high hourly retums to paddy and competitive off-farm employmentpossibilities sets the labor utilization pattern and farm output in Sri Lanka's nonplantation crop sector in favor of paddy(despite its relatively low return per ha) and off-farm employment.87

6.6 Within this scenario, it might be seen as possible to achieve some growth through increasing paddy yield.However, movement in the factors determining the trade off facing farm families here does not favor more intensivepaddy cultivation. Most yield increasing efforts require significant incremental labor and management input, as wellas more water and fertilizer.8 8 But real wage rates are increasing as is the fertilizer/paddy price ratio. Indivisibilitymay also be a factor at work here. Off-farm employmnent will likely be lumpy, as employers will require minimumvolumes of time from employees. Farm activities will also be somewhat indivisible. Both will prevent family laborfrom achieving precise efficiency in allocation of their labor, and the balance appears tilted against spending additionaltime on the farm. In sum, real returns to paddy are declining, making it unlikely that anything short of a newtechnological breakthrough might reverse this stagnation.

6.7 The absence of an active land market may be at the heart of the low supply elasticities for most crops. Unableto adjust farm size to meet income needs, farm families seek alternative means to meet these needs. As shown above,the constrained optimum appears to be a mixture of farm and nonfarm activities. Unable to obtain sufficient fixedfactors to match available family labor in an optimal fashion, and unable to exit agriculture without abandoning theirfixed asset, farm families are constrained to be part-time farmers only. As a result, the cropping pattern is as muchdetermined by off-farm as on-farm opportunities, causing a reduction in the normally anticipated response. But notethat even with substantive policy change to bring the needed sector revitalization, paddy will still remain the principalcrop (para 5.12).

85/ Farrmer I year. spouse 0.5 years, 3.1 children with 0.15 years each and 300 days per farmer per year available for work.

86/ Report on Workshop on Rural Diversification (Project No IDRC 90-0117) May 27-29, 1994, Negombo, Sri Lanka. Socio-Economicsand Planning Centre. Department of Agriculture, Peradeniya, Sri Lanka.

87/ For furnher confinnation of this see Section 3.2 (pp 24-25) in: Dunham, David. Contract Farming and Export Horticulture: Can AgribusinessRevitalize the Peasant Sector in Sri Lanka?, Institute of Policy Studies, Research Studies Agricultural Policy Series No. 3. Colombo,February 1995.

88/ Rice Yield and Production Stagnancy in Sri Lanka. S. Wirasinghe and S. Emityagoda, Department of Agriculture, TechnologyTransfer Division, MADR, Peradeniya. Mimeo.

Page 43: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

33

VII. TECHNOLOGY GENERATION AND TRANSFER

Overview

7.1 The focus of attention of research and extension, which has been dominated by the public sector, has been onachieving rice self-sufficiency, a goal which has been very largely achieved. Since the mid-1980's, however, rice yieldshave stagnated, and there has been a growing realization that the research and extension system has not moved on toaddress the more pressing issues constraining production of higher value crop and livestock products, in response tomarket signals. However, there is only so much that the public sector can do efficiently in a dynamic market drivencontext where the private sector is likely to have a comparative advantage.

7.2 Research. Agricultural research has been dominated by public sector research institutes. Since the January1994, restructuring of the Department of Agriculture (DOA) into autonomous commodity based research anddevelopment institutes, the Rice Breeding Research Center at Batalagoda has been known as the Rice Research andDevelopment Institute (RRDI), and has been assigned the totality of work on rice. The Dry Zone Research Center atMaha Illuppalama has been given responsibility for other field crops consisting of condiments (chilies, onions), coarsegrains (maize, millet, sorghum), grain legumes (green gram, black gram, cowpea) and oil seeds (sesame, soyabean,groundnut), and designated the Field Crops Research and Development Institute. The Central Agricultural ResearchInstitute (CARI) has been assigned responsibility for fruit crops, vegetables, roots and tuber crops and ornamental plants,and has come to be designated as the Horticulture Research and Development Institute (HORDI).

7.3 Comparing agricultural research before 1977 with that since, there is a perception that output is low, itsdirection questionable and the impact on the farmer is small. However, private sector research initiatives have been verylimited. Also, within the research institutes, there is no system whereby good research is duly rewarded, whileremuneration and conditions of service (remoteness, etc.) are relatively poor. The Agricultural Research Project (ARP)has tried to help prioritize research expenditures through the introduction of Advanced Research Program Planning anda contract research program, together with improved staff training and facilities. But this has not remedied the overallsense of lack of direction which affects many researchers. Under these circumstances, the research system is widelyperceived as supply driven.

7.4 Extension. The extension system has been disrupted by institutional changes. In the mid-1980s, after it wasrealized that agriculmral extension was costing the Government almost 1 % of agricultural GDP, with staff salaries aloneaccounting for 80-90% of operating costs, expenditures for the system were drastically cut. The Government alsotransferred 2,400 village-level extension agents (KVS) to its Poverty Alleviation Program. In addition, as part of thedevolution of authority from the center to the provinces in the late 1980s, the Provincial Councils acquired operationalresponsibility for extension. Under the Second Agricultural Extension Project (SAEP), the Government has been tryingto deliver better service to farmers at less cost. SAEP has fewer, but better trained, agents and makes much wider useof mass media. It has also established the farmer-centered farming system approach and, within this framework,introduced the use of problem census/problem solving techniques. However, many of the Provincial Councils still donot have the necessary capabilities or resources to sustain an effective system.

Research/Extension Link

7.5 Despite the efforts of SAEP to strengthen the link between research and extension through the problemcensus/problem solving approach, research is still the responsibility of one provincial organization, while extension isthat of another. Today's limited connections between research and extension are personal and informal.

Policy Conclusions and Proposed Actions

7.6 Agricultural research and extension can only have meaning in the context of a well defined agriculturaldevelopment policy, but this has been lacking in recent years which has led to an "identity crisis' in theresearch/extension community. In the new context of market driven development, however, the bulk of new researchand extension, particularly in relation to higher-value export crops, is likely to come from the private sector, askentrepreneurs supply inputs and technology to farmers as part of contract farming arrangements. What remains in thepublic sector needs to be made more demand driven. Government will still have a major role in extension, but adifferent one. Systematic provision of information on new technologies, farming systems, market prospects and prices

Page 44: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

34

in a broad-based manner and in a form readily utilizable by farmers is needed. Since the externalities here aresignificant and the benefits from increased productivity substantial, this is a legitimate role for Government and onewhich needs to be recognized. However, services involving customizing such information in the form of designing farmmanagement plans and recommending inputs for specific situations are better carried out by private sector extensionservices. Since much agricultural technology contains public good elements, this can make it difficult for private firmsto appropriate the benefits of research. Consequently, Government will likely continue to play its traditional role here,pending more complete development of intellectual property rights. An overall assessment of the economic efficiencyof the current and alternative models for generation and extension of technology which explicitly focuses to the aboveprincipals and considerations would appear to be a priority in this area.

VIII. PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER

The Current Situation - What have We Learned.

8.1 Sector Performance is stagnant, with low cropping intensity, even on fully irrigated lands and heavyconcentration on low valued paddy.

Product Markets are competitive, but their efficiency would be improved if Government phased out its directinvolvement.

Input Markets are also competitive and work well.

Trade Policy is inward looking, aimed at protecting domestic producers,resulting in non-competitive output.

The Land Market is heavily constrained by property rights issues, including unresolved ownership claims inprivate sector land and an inability to reallocate land leased by the public sector and so permit minimum farmsize to be market determined.

The Rural Credit Market, although not cost-effective, is competitive and largely unaffected by Government'sconcessionary credit program for agriculture, which addresses poverty with concessionary credit, failing on bothfronts.

Overall Incentive Policy has a pro-agriculture but an anti-export bias, thus depressing potential export-orientedinvestment and so output in the sector.

The Rural Labor Market appears to work quite well, as it substantially enhances farm incomes. But beinghighly informal, little else is known about it in terms of its ability to clear itself. More generally, regulationof the formal labor market must impact negatively on employment creation and on the efficiency of the informalmarket in the overlap area.

Technology Transfer is a troubled area, lacking any mechanism for self-direction. Its excessive commnodityorientation limits its contribution to sector performance. Here, an in-depth economic assessment is badlyneeded to provide a basis for future direction and institutional structure.

Policy Choices - Future Directions for the Sector.

8.2 In this situation, what are the policy options available to Government which might promote the objective ofincreasing sectoral growth?

8.3 The product and input markets are quite competitive; but their cost-effectiveness could be improved (marketingmargins lowered) by elimination of all commodity-based intervention activities by public sector agencies. Also,additional efforts to promote transparency through well-run market information and analyses programs should showworthwhile improvement in functioning of the market. Amending the incentive structure to permit market determinedinvestment flows to agriculture and remove the anti-export bias within agriculture would give substantial gains. Also

Page 45: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

35

here, tarrification of all nontariff barriers should be accomplished without delay. However, as the multimarket analysisshows, these alone will not resolve the problem.

8.4 Access to credit is not a problem for commercial agriculture, but is for subsistence farmers. With substantialoff-farm earnings and low growth, growth in demand for on-farm credit is inevitably slow. With enhanced sectoraleconomic activity tWis would change. In the meantime, the issue of institutional inefficiency and high transaction costsshould be addressed.

8.5 Technology transfer appears quite confused as to its appropriate role and how best to organize itself for this.Insofar as commercial agriculture is concerned, privatization should be considered, leaving a public sector componentto focus on areas where, for various reasons, the private sector may be reluctant to pursue. Programs specificallydesigned to meet, and focussed exclusively, on the problems of subsistence farmers need to be developed independentof those for commercial agriculture. Access to input financing and technology will inevitably be two important programareas here.

8.6 Although the rural labor market may appear to work well, as noted in Sri Lanka Poverty Assessment," partof the overall Sri Lankan labor market, it is constrained by Government regulation. Experience in India and Zimbabweshows anti-retrenchment regulations depress job volume.' Thus, the recomrnmendation of the Sri Lanka PovertyAssessment report, to eliminate such regulation, should be implemented.

8.7 The inactive land market is a major problem. Because of this, farmers who wish to acquire more land cannotdo so with any certainty in permanence of possession, which impacts on efficiency of use; while farmers who wish toexit agriculture are unable to do so in more than a part-time fashion, which also impacts on efficiency of use. Byimpeding the development of full-time farming, this in turn constrains the cropping pattern to one which severelyconstrains returns to fixed factors, primarily land, which is has been developed at very high cost, thus giving theeconomy very poor, and even negative, returns for large scale investment in this area. The remedy here is to initiatea land market.

The Growth Challen2e

8.8 Within the sector, in 1993, Plantation Crops (tea, rubber and coconut) accounted for 24% of agricultural GDP,Paddy for 24% and Other 52%. Over the 1984-92 period, average annual growth9' in sectoral GDP was: Total 2.04%,Plantation Crops 0.16%, Paddy 0.22%, and Other92 4.08% p.a. If more rapid sector growth is the goal, 4.0% p.a.could be seen as a modest growth-oriented target growth rate for Total sectoral GDP. If Other continues to grow by3.5 % p.a., and the combined growth rate of Plantation Crops can be stabilized at 0.5 % p.a., output from Paddy" muststill grow by 7.5% p.a. to achieve the sectoral target rate. This is an unlikely achievement at present. Reducing thesectoral target growth rate to 3.5% and increasing the Plantation Crops growth rate to 1.0% p.a. still leaves a requiredgrowth rate from paddy (irrigated) land of 4.92% p.a., or 22 times the present growth rate. No amount of growthpromoting effort for paddy itself is likely to achieve this.

8.9 This gives perspective to the dimensions of the challenge facing Sri Lankan agricultural sector policy plannersand administrators. Since production of paddy and import competing crops already incurs major losses for the economy(para 4.8), this is clearly not an advisable direction for growth promotion. Instead, the entire nonplantation crop sectorneeds to be restructured to place it on an economically sound footing.

89/ Sri Lanka Poverty Assessment, World Bank Report No. 13431-CE, January 11, 1995

90/ Fallon and Lucas, The Impact of Job Security Regulations in India and Zimbabwe, World Bank Economic Review. Vol 5, No 3 pp.395-413.

91/ Using on 3-year averages at the beginning and end points.

92/ Made up principally of potatoes, chilies, onions. Also included are Minor Export Crops and Livestock. Minor Export Crops andLivestock each account for only 4% of sectorai GDP and so do not impact greatly on overall sectoral performance.

93/ i.e. the land occupied hy Paddy.

Page 46: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

36

Reform Priorities

8.10 Public sector marketing activities, incentive policy, land markets, and subsistence agriculture are all priorityareas to be addressed. Government should undertake a program to phase out of all its involvements in marketing,including privatization of CWE and PMB, and terminate all commercial activities of the Food Commissioner'sDepartment. Incentive policy reform should aim at removal of the pro-agriculture and anti-export biases through aprogram of tariffication of all nontariff barriers and a phased reduction of these tariffs to a nominal level of 10-15%,i.e. just enough to dampen extreme external price fluctuations and retain some revenue for Government. The effect ofprice fluctuation on farm income, already small due to the size of off-farm earnings in total income, will be muchreduced as farm size increases, and with it diversification and larger agricultural incomes. Since the impact on onfarmincome is quite small, the gains to poor consumers attractive, trade reform should begin without delay.

8.11 Land tenure policy needs to be totally overhauled to facilitate development of a fully functional land market.This includes active promulgation and training programs on policies, professionals and processes related to sale andpurchase of agricultural land, active encouragement of transactions through elimination of non-economically justifiedrestrictions on ownership and size of farms, incentive-based policies to speed up privatization of public sector landholdings and speedy resolution of ownership disputes in the private sector. Current draft legislation needs to be reviewedto establish its adequacy here, and resubmitted to cabinet and the legislature for approval. Since land without irrigationwater is clearly of little value in much of Sri Lanka, resolution of water property rights will also be necessary.

8.12 Due to the size of the problem, there appears an urgent need to upgrade the approach to dealing withsubsistence farmers. While this is a dynamic problem and amenable to market solutions, past policy, which restrictedthe functioning of rural markets important to resolution of this, has constrained the adjustment process, leading to aballooning in the current size of the problem. This group94 cannot be classified as commercial farmers due to the smallsize of their farms, or as landless farmers eligible for poverty alleviation type assistance. But they appear to be caughtin the middle with no assistance program appropriate to their needs available to them. Left on their own, they are likelyto be exploited as agriculture becomes increasingly commercial, as it must in order to generate returns commensuratewith the resources made available to it.

8.13 Not all subsistence farmers will wish to, or be capable of, remaining in agriculture. Here the program shouldassist them to exit agriculture on the best possible financial terms, i.e. obtaining full market value for their land andtraining them for alternative off-farm employment. Others, who are potentially capable of becoming viable, should betaken into a custom designed extension program which would teach them technical skills and management practices onan intensive basis which would allow them to enhance their income generating capacities. Between the two extremesare those who are potentially viable farmers wish to remain in agriculture but whose farm size is too small.Development of land markets and suitable commercial credit facilities will take too long to assist these. Governmentcould consider forming a land bank, using land acquired from those exiting agriculture to augment farm sizes of thisgroup. To ensure viability, it would be necessary to run such a land bank on strictly commercial terms.

8.14 To encourage off-farm employment creation, rural employers should be exempt from restrictive laborlegislation, particularly the Termination of Workers Act (TEWA). Employees should have the enforceable right, butwithout obligation, to form employee unions. Relations between employers and employees should be determined bydirect negotiation between representatives of both parties. The role of the state here should be to ensure adherence toagreed bargaining rules. Concerns for basic health and safety should be addressed separately under independentlegislation.

8.15 Other areas in need of attention by policy makers are credit and technology. The general approach in creditshould be to end all Government intervention in commercial credit activities and confine its interests to provision ofadequate liquidity to the system and ensuring its financial soundness and structural competitiveness. This should beaccomplished through the Central Bank and the Ministry of Finance. In this vein, all public sector rural creditintermediaries should be privatized by selling them off to the private sector and closing down those for whom there areno buyers.

'4/ Based on the 1982 Census of Agriculture, a total of between 0.5 and 1.0 million farmers and their dependents, or 2.5 to 5.0 miilionpeople are estimated to be in the nonplantation sector.

Page 47: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

37

Seauencine of Poliev Reform

8.16 Correct sequencing is important so as to maintain momentum and avoid conflicting policy situations andundesired results. The major elements of the reform process which are seen to be substantively interdependent, whichincluding all markets and policies which impact on sectoral income, and are in need of adjustment to improve theirfunctioning, need careful examination in this regard. Thus, the main fixed factor market, land, input markets forirrigation water and long-term credit, and the import markets for competing products - rice and fruits and vegetables,are all of concern here. There may also be a need to introduce taxation measures into the sector to provide a morebalanced investment climate between assets in this sector and in others.

8.17 Land and Credit Markets: Development of land markets is a major prerequisite for a more dynamic, growth-oriented nonplantation sector. But in the current situation, pursuit of this alone is unlikely to make much progress.Without liquidity in the form of long-term credit, farmers are unlikely to have financing available to purchase land. Amajor impact of this would be an inability of farmer-buyers to compete with investors. It will also result in depressedland prices, and so a reluctance on the part of sellers to participate. Avoiding this requires thatdeficiencies in the rural credit market, namely collateral to secure long-term loans and much improved credit discipline.Collateral requires marketable land titles. These would go to improving discipline, along with cessation by Governmentof all loan forgiveness programs, and assistance to the credit market in speedily resolving nonrepayment of claims.These interrelationships clearly illustrate the important symbiosis between credit and land markets.

8.18 Import Protection and Irrigation Cost Recovery Policies: Reform in here will reduce profitability of rice. Ifpursued in isolation, this may increase output of other higher valued crops, and so returns to fixed factors, i.e. land andirrigation. Since these are more labor-intensive crops, farmers will need to spend more of their working hours on-farmthan at present. In the present situation, this will only occur if off-farm wage rates decline relative to hourly returnsfrom these other crops. But this implies a retrenchment in the non-farm sectors of the economy; something which iscertainly not desired. Greater on-farm labor input by individual farmers would also occur if farm-size could expandto where farmers could specialize in full-time farming and earn incomes at least as good as what they can now earnthrough the combination of paddy farming and off-farm employment. This requires that land can be reallocated at itsfull value, i.e through a transparent, formal land market. Otherwise, reduction in rice profitability from policy reformhere may cause farmers to put more work time' in off-farm employment and less into farming, reducing riceproduction and actually depressing output in agriculture.

8.19 Irrigation Cost Recovery Policy and Land and Credit Markets: Future policy here is also very important tothe functioning of the land market in Government-owned irrigation systems. The value of the land is significantlyaffected by its access to water and the cost of collection, storage, and delivery of the water to the land. The presentpolicy is to charge zero for this service. This is (or will be) reflected by the market in the financial value of the land,and any future cost recovery here will reduce this market value of the land. Cost recovery here is not determined byany market functions; instead it depends entirely on Govemment policy. As such, it is not in anyway responsive tomarket conditions and so is uncertain. The real concem here is uncertainty not cost recovery. This uncertainty impactsnegatively on the process of market-valuation of land. The market will significantly discount land values to allow forpolicy change in cost recovery which negatively impacts on farm income. Often, the discount will be overestimated toerr on the side of caution by buyers and this will depress the market. This uncertainty will be magnified in the creditmarket. As a risk reduction practice, banks will generally extend long-term loans in amounts less than the 100 percentof the asset collateralizing the loan. Here, with the land purchased as collateral, the liquidity available to the land marketwill be substantially decreased, further depressing the land market.

8.20 Policy altematives available to Government to reduce the cost to the taxpayer of providing free water toirrigated agriculture range from the politically difficult policy of charging and collecting water fees to transferringresponsibility for each system to the users, to transferring ownership of the system to the users. Each altemativerequires a decision as to what charges to collect as part of the policy, i.e. delivery charges incorporating both capitalcosts and annual O&M costs, or, in the case of system transfer, charges to recover capital plus the capitalised O&Mcosts already incurred. Again, any uncertainty regarding Government's long-term policy stance here will be discountedin the market value of land and again in the collateral value assigned to it by the credit markets.

95/ Depending on the variability of labor inputs in paddy production.

Page 48: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

38

8.21 Agricultural Taxation: Small-scale agriculture in Sri Lanka, as in many other developing countries, is notsubject to direct taxation. In this situation, it is to be expected that development of a land market could well lead tosignificant acquisition of land by investors as part of portfolio management. To ensure that the focus of investment inland is for production rather than portfolio management, it may be necessary to consider introduction of agriculturaltaxation in the form of a transaction tax and resource rent or an imputed income tax on land holdings above somemaximum size. The objective here should not be to exclude investors from purchasing land. This would only reduceliquidity in the land market and penalize those already holding land assets and wishing to dispose of them, such asfarmers wishing to exit agriculture. The appropriate objective here is to avoid excessive investment in land as a storeof assets, which would occur if the costs of acquiring and holding land were significantly less than the same costs forother assets in the economy. Such a situation would cause the market value of the asset to increase well above thepresent value of the earnings stream, making it difficult for professional farmers to acquire land.

8.22 A Pilot Approach: Improving the functioning of the rural credit market is a prerequisite and would appearrelatively uncomplicated. Also, agricultural transfer programs should be separated into commercial and subsistenceprograms. Done simultaneously, this will enhance the acceptability of both. Land titling and registration will inevitablybe slow. But it could be implemented more rapidly on an area basis, which, combined with advances in credit andcommercialization of agriculture, could form the nucleus of a pilot program to field test the aggregate reforms. Clearlyit is unlikely that trade policy could be packaged with this, but reform in current irrigation policy could and should.this could be based on either development of user property rights or straightforward gradual cost recovery. The propertyrights approach is preferable in the long run, and even in the short run when Sri Lanka's past history of cost recoveryeffort is considered.

Government's Stance on Sectoral Reform

8.23 In its first major policy statement,' the current Government acknowledged the failure of past policies asdemonstrated by "the present sorry state of agriculture and the rural population" and undertook to "remove theinstitutional and policy obstacles which have reduced agricultural profitability and constrained investment". The speechacknowledged that this would involve "substantial structural change", but that Government had "confidence in the ruralmasses and their capacity to make rational choices". Major policy changes in the nonplantation crop sector wouldinclude:

- removal of hidden anti-agriculture discrimination from "inequitable macroeconomic and trade policies";

- eliminating all kinds of monopolies in agricultural markets and fostering greater competition;

- realigning the roles of the public and private sector, particularly in irrigation;

- creation of off-farm employment as the only viable approach to rural poverty;

- improving rural infrastructure to enhance private investment in agroindustry and promote outgrower systems;and

- freeing farmers to make the best use of their assets, including lifting restrictions on leasing land and grantingfreehold title in settlement schemes.

In Governments' own words: "the new strategy is designed to ensure that the creative energy and independent spirit offarmers is not stifled by bureaucracy and over regulation."

8.24 The remarkable degree of alignment between the recommendations emerging from this study and Government'sstatement of policy intent indicates a firm grasp of the nature of the situation by Government. With the exception ofagricultural markets, where Government rather than structure or conduct is the problem, the study's findings are incomplete agreement with Government's policy intent. It is hoped that the study will provide greater depth tounderstanding the current situation and thus a basis for improved design of reform policies and measures.

W6/ Policy Statement of die Government of Sri Lanka on the Occasion of the opening of Parliament, 6 January, 1995, by H.E. ChandrikaBandaranaike Kumara.unga. President.

Page 49: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

39

Discussion and Dissemination

8.25 A brief visit in August 1995, introduced the report to the Ministries of Finance and Planning, Agriculture Landsand Forestry, and Irrigation (including MASL), CBSL, and the Institute of Policy Studies. Dissemination and extensivediscussions were held from September 18 to October 4, 1995. A series of mini-workshops (9), each on different aspectsof the study, was the approach. It allowed individuals and agencies, from Government, academia, and the private sectorto focus on aspects of interest to them, permitting smaller audiences and more focussed discussion. Written commentsand questions were also given to the mission by various sources. Summaries of the individual discussion sessions andresponses to the major points of the written submissions have been circulated to GOSL officials and agencies.

8.26 Overall: Govenunent economic policy planners at the highest level are well aware of the issues and broadlyshare the Bank's strategy view, although they may differ on the detail of sequencing and timing in policy change.Reservations were expressed in the line ministries and agencies (Agriculture Lands and Forestry, and Irrigation -including MASL), primarily by noneconomists, about the findings overall. Much of this centered around the role ofthe off-farm labor market in explaining farmers' behavior, particularly with the combination of off-farm employmentpossibilities and land tenure policy motivating the production decisions of peasant farmers. But the ability of theintegrated nature of the storyline to demonstrate, in an intuitively acceptable manner, just how the sector would adjustto the various hypothetical situations posed by discussants, including wholesale rural-urban migration, large-scaleinternational conflict, and total stagnation in the nonfarm sectors, aided the non-economist audiences in appreciating thepossible contribution of the study's findings in explaining how current sectoral performance is brought about. The sizeof the overall share of off-farm earnings in total farm family income in (42% in 1993) raised both scepticism andconcern. Discussion of the supporting data 97 9S provided some perspective on this concern.

8.27 Background Papers: Six background working papers were distributed at the workshops. These provide thebasis for the analysis and conclusions. It was strongly recommended that these be reviewed for their adequacy insubstantiating the conclusions, and that the associated data and calculations be checked carefully for their accuracy.

8.28 Follow-utp: Direct follow-up action was not seen as possible at this time by MALF. Agreement was reachedwith MALF and the National Planning Department of the Ministry of Finance and Planning (NPD), that considerationshould be given to several follow-up studies aimed at operationalizing the major findings of the report.

i . Rural Wholesale Market Activities - a survey of volumes and costs to establish an information base;

2. Commercial Infrastructure in Large-scale Irrigation Schemes - the adequacy of this in facilitating ruralcommerce;

3. Land Tenure Status in Government owned Lands - i.e the impact of the informal market and how best toresolve negative effects, including needed legal and institutional changes;

4. Reducing Subsistence Agriculture - i.e., development of meaningful criteria to identify subsistence farmers,determine the economic factors primarily responsible for their situation, and propose means to resolve these;and

5. Pettah and surrounding markets in Colombo - the impact of barriers to entry to Pettah on development of spill-over markets and conditions of entry to these, and the impact of these developments on the overall efficiencyof the marketing process.

8.29 It was agreed that the mission would prepare draft terms of reference for these studies for comment by MALFand NPD. Thereafter, these would be finalized for implementation under the associated Japan Grant for projectpreparation.

97/ Department of Census and Statistics, Ministry of Finance and Planning. GOSL. Unpublished data extracted from the Sri LankaQuarterly Labor Survey. 1993.

981 The agricultural wage rate, which has risen rapidly, and the demise in production of high valued gherkins, are good examples of independentdata which support the findings of the Quarterly Labor Survey.

Page 50: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,
Page 51: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,
Page 52: World Bank Documentdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/en/... · 2. Policy Incentive, Diversification and Comparative Advantage of Nonplantation Crops in Sri Lanka 3. Outward Orientation,

'4~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~'

S .4 , s * ' s gk a . a e > ^ - -. ;

IMAGING

R eprt No: 1,464 CET y p e;