yearbook on international investment law & policy...

37
1 iii YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015–2016 Edited by Lisa E. Sachs Lise J. Johnson

Upload: others

Post on 19-Jun-2020

7 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

1

iii

YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL

INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY

2015– 2016

Edited byLisa E. Sachs

Lise J. Johnson

Page 2: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

1

iv

Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6DP,United Kingdom

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,

and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark ofOxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries

© Oxford University Press 2018

The moral rights of the authors have been assertedImpression: 1

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored ina retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, without the

prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permittedby law, by licence or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics

rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of theabove should be sent to the Rights Department, Oxford University Press, at the

address above

You must not circulate this work in any other formand you must impose this same condition on any acquirer

Crown copyright material is reproduced under Class LicenceNumber C01P0000148 with the permission of OPSI

and the Queen’s Printer for Scotland

Published in the United States of America by Oxford University Press198 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016, United States of America

British Library Cataloguing in Publication DataData available

ISBN 978– 0– 19– 880972– 2

Printed and bound byCPI Group (UK) Ltd, Croydon, CR0 4YY

Links to third party websites are provided by Oxford in good faith andfor information only. Oxford disclaims any responsibility for the materials

contained in any third party website referenced in this work.

Page 3: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

v

v

COLUMBIA CENTER ON SUSTAINABLE INVESTMENT

The Columbia Center on Sustainable Investment (CCSI) is a leading applied research center and forum for the study, practice, and discussion of sustainable international investment. CCSI focuses on analysing important topical policy- oriented issues and constructing and implementing an investment framework that promotes sustainable development and the mutual trust needed for long- term investments that can be practically adopted by governments, companies, and civil society. The Center undertakes its mission through interdisciplinary research, advisory projects, multi- stakeholder dialogue, educational programs, and the development of resources and tools. The Center’s website is found at http:// ccsi.columbia.edu/ .

Page 4: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

vi

vi

SUBMISSION POLICY

The Investment Yearbook is an annual publication published by Oxford University Press in association with the Columbia Center on Sustainable Investment. It draws on the guidance of a distinguished Advisory Board, ongoing engagement by an Editorial Committee consisting of leading academics in the field of invest-ment law and policy, and skilful work by an Editorial Staff of students from Columbia Law School.

The Investment Yearbook addresses legal and policy issues in the area of inter-national investment— from national, regional, and international perspectives. The Editorial Committee invites for publication manuscripts that are of out-standing quality in terms of academic rigor, quality of the argument, origin-ality, and contribution to the field of international investment law and policy. The Investment Yearbook will not consider a manuscript that has been published previously. Every manuscript that is considered for publication will be assessed through an external double- blind peer- review process. The style of the manu-scripts should be in accordance with the OSCOLA guidelines, as adapted to the Yearbook (available from the Editorial Committee).

The Editorial Committee welcomes the submission of manuscripts to the Investment Yearbook. Manuscripts should be electronically sent to the Columbia Center on Sustainable Investment, [email protected].

Page 5: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

vii

vii

PEER REVIEWERS

The Editorial Committee of the Investment Yearbook thanks all those who helped in the preparation of this publication and especially the peer reviewers, who include:

Aurelia AntoniettiJulian AratoDaniel BehnNeale BergmanChristophe BondyMarc BungenbergLee CaplanDiane DesiertoKatia Fach GomezTom GinsburgHenning Grosse Ruse- KhanJan KleinheisterkampMarkus KrajewskiJurgen KurtzSimon LesterLukas LinsiPetros MavroidisTed MoranDelphine Nougayrède

Martins PaparinskisAntonio ParraClint PeinhardtKarl P. SauvantPrabhash RanjanSudhanshu RoyBorzu SabahiDavid SchneidermannJeremy SharpeJingxia ShiIgnacio TorterolaElisabeth TuerkLukas VanhonnaekerTania VoonJason Webb YackeeLou WellsJane WillemsHerfried WossKatia Yannaca- Small

Page 6: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

viii

Page 7: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

ix

ix

FOREWORD

This edition of the Yearbook is a remarkable reflection of the global scene of invest-ment, investment law (with some elements of trade law) and investment dispute settlement. It describes and analyzes numerous changes and developments which occurred in the two-year period of 2015–16. Looking at the different elements of the puzzle and trying to identify some of the significant themes, what strikes the reader? The question is posed accepting that the themes mentioned below may not necessarily be the main ones and that the list is inevitably incomplete.

First, there is the continuing complexification of the economics and financials of investment. As Strauss well shows, an increasing proportion of foreign investment is intrafirm investment, reflecting financing choices made within multinational enterprises (MNEs). As a result, a high proportion of investment is constituted by reinvestments of earnings into the affiliate’s operations. Linked with this is the use of special purpose entities (SPEs) often merely channeling investment flows through one country before they reach their final destination, with the consequence that statistics more and more take the corporate group as the rele-vant entity to measure financials flows. Speaking of financial flows and statistics, one notes the significant slowdown of outbound investments from developed economies since the peak in 2007. At the same time, according to Blackrock and reported by Strauss, investors are holding globally USD 50 trillion in un-invested cash. If some of that money could be unleashed and invested in sustainable pro-jects in developing economies, this would benefit the local populations as well as the investors. Be this as it may, the repercussions of the changing economic framework create significant challenges for investment law and dispute settle-ment. Certain newer treaties do provide for some solutions, but others do not. Under many treaties, such basic issues as the definition of a protected investment are still raising unsettled questions. Feldman, who focuses on MNEs and invest-ment treaties, proposes the development of a test requiring protected investors to have a meaningful connection both to their home state and to the host state of the investment, in other words a sort of dual proximity test. Whether that is the way forward—or one of the ways—remains to be seen.

Another theme that emerges is the continued trend towards the assertion of the state’s power to regulate and the setting up of mechanisms to give it priority over investors’ rights. These prioritization mechanisms, which are well-documented in the paper by Coleman, Johnson, Sachs, and Gupta, include filter mechan-isms, binding interpretations issued by treaty parties, carve outs and exceptions,

Page 8: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Foreword

x

x

self-judging clauses, and other limitations on arbitral powers. This trend is also evident in Magraw’s discussion of important developments in arbitration case law. It is certainly a result of the current return of the state, after the last peak of globalization and the financial crisis of 2008. As part of this rebalancing pro-cess, one also counts the notion of introducing investors’ obligations, such as compliance with corporate social responsibility, anti-corruption, or human rights obligations. So far, these ‘obligations’ are mostly framed as non-binding, and it will be interesting to see whether this trend evolves towards binding obligations or not. The return of the state also seems to incite arbitral tribunals to show more deference towards decisions made by states about the exercise of their regulatory powers. In this respect, Remmer shows a clear increase in state wins in the out-comes of investor–state arbitrations. At the same time, she observes a difference between middle- and lower-income states whose outcome record does not com-pare favorably with that of states with high-income levels. Remmer attributes this difference to the existence of asymmetries in access to information.

This brings us to still another theme that emerges from the current debates on investor–state dispute settlement (ISDS), which is equality. Like Remmer, who sees an information inequality, Bain finds that ‘some are more equal than others’ in investment arbitration, a concern that matches a topic currently addressed by the Institut de droit international. Bain considers that arbitral tribunals should take a more proactive role in enforcing equality of parties and adopt a ‘more substan-tive’ approach to this fundamental principle of procedure. While improvements can certainly be made, it remains the case that inequality due to dispute-external circumstances is a fact of life in any dispute settlement mechanism, be it domes-tic or international and whatever its subject matter. This said, the concern for equality that comes to light now in various ways, precisely when state wins clearly prevail, may well be seen like another expression of the general unease with ISDS. Would the concern also exist if disputes were brought before an investment court set up by the states?

The increased number of state wins could also be due to the fact that the pros-pect of investor claims causes states to internally vet proposals for regulatory measures, with the result that some measures that would otherwise have been taken do not pass the vetting process and are never enacted. On this issue, van Harten’s and Scott’s paper opens a fascinating research field, which is particu-larly valuable because the relevant data is by definition difficult to gather. On the basis of the information obtained in over fifty interviews conducted with govern-ment officials of Ontario, Canada, there appears indeed to be empirical evidence that the risk of being sued in ISDS may influence regulatory decision-making. Incidentally, this undoubtedly strengthens the need for consistency in arbitral decisions, a topic on which I have written elsewhere. In this context, it would be interesting to know whether investment arbitration has a similar prevention effect in other states, especially less developed economies. A current project of the

Page 9: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Foreword

xi

xi

Center for International Dispute Settlement (CIDS) in Geneva will hopefully shed light on this latter question.

These are just a few thoughts inspired by the many contributions in this Yearbook. One could obviously go on, because many other developments that we discussed would deserve attention, for instance the accelerating ‘expansive, even aggressive Chinese commercial and investment treaty practice’, so described by Lim, with by now 145 BITs and about 20 FTAs with investment provisions. Or Brazil’s cooperation and facilitation treaties, addressed in Caetano Xavier and Fontoura Costa’s contribution, that show a willingness to protect foreign investment by way of treaties after years of restraint, and at the same time dispense with invest-ment arbitration and focus on dispute prevention. Finally, one could speak of the European proposal for an investment court, a project that—among other reform initiatives—will be pursued in the framework of UNCITRAL’s Working Group III starting this fall of 2017, in other words a topic for the next Yearbook.

Gabrielle Kaufmann-KohlerGeneva

25 October 2017

Page 10: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

xii

Page 11: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

xiii

xiii

PREFACE: TOWARDS A TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY INVESTMENT AGREEMENT

Joseph E. Stiglitz*

Investment agreements have rightly come under attack in recent years. Many years ago, there was an attempt to arrive at a multilateral investment agreement, along the lines of the World Trade Organization (WTO) multilateral trade agree-ment. That effort failed. Because these agreements have taken on a central role in recent trade agreements, and because they have increasingly become a stumbling block, it is important to understand better both the politics and economics of these agreements.1

There are two underlying questions: what motivated the drive for these agree-ments? What was supposed to be protected? If investors were worried about nationalization (expropriation), in most cases, they could have bought insurance from the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA), part of the World Bank Group, or from national authorities that offered similar protection. Besides, expropriations have been a rarity in recent decades. This suggests that something else drove the Investment Agenda. I will return to this question at the end.

First, though, I want to describe what I believe a ‘good’ agreement might look like—something markedly different from what has appeared in recent trade and bilateral investment treaties.

Basic Premises

Any investment agreement should begin with two basic predicates:

(1) The provision of justice is a basic public function that should not be privat-ized; the current system of dispute resolution privatizes this function, and for

* Parts of this preface were previously distributed as a series of Roosevelt Institute Policy Briefs, Tricks of the Trade Deal: Six Big Problems with the Trans-Pacific Partnership, 2016. I am indebted to Felicia Wong, Nell Abernathy, Adam Hersh, Lori Wallach, and Lise Sachs for helpful discussions, and Matthieu Teachout and Debarati Ghosh for research and editorial assistance.

1 A decade ago, I wrote a long law review article of investment agreements (See Stiglitz, 2008). Since then, such agreements have proliferated, and their adverse consequences have become even clearer than they were then.

Page 12: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xiv

xiv

no good reason—other than perhaps more favorable outcomes to corporations. The private system is very costly, putting poor countries at a disadvantage.2 The WTO appellate system proves that one can create well-functioning international commercial courts.

In opposing the investment agreement embedded in trade and investment pacts, I was among the more than 200 law and economics professors who signed a letter to the President in October 2017 describing the devastating deficiencies in the standard investor–state dispute settlement (ISDS) process, focusing on problems with it from the perspective of US law and policy.3 We noted that:

Over the past two centuries, the United States has established a framework of rules that govern lawsuits against the government and continually refines them through democratic processes. These include rules on court procedures and evidence, which are designed to ensure the fairness, legitimacy and reliability of proceedings; on who may bring lawsuits and under what circumstances, which are designed to bal-ance the right to sue with the need to ensure that government action is not made impossible due to unlimited litigation; on the power of courts, which are designed to ensure that judges do not overly intrude on legitimate policy decisions made by elected legislatures or executive officials; on appropriate remedies, which are crafted to achieve policy aims such as deterrence, punishment, and compensation; and on the independence and accountability of judges.

But the investment agreements overturn all of this.

However, through ISDS, the federal government gives foreign investors— and for-eign investors alone—the ability to bypass that robust, nuanced, and democratic-ally responsive US legal framework.

Specific objections include:  ‘. . .  ISDS proceedings lack many of the basic pro-tections and procedures normally available in a court of law’, and ‘there is no oversight or accountability of the private lawyers who serve as arbitrators, many of whom rotate between being arbitrators and bringing cases for corporations against governments’.

I had separately written to Congress in May 2015 expressing some of my own concerns:4

The high cost of access to such legal mechanisms violate a basic tenet of US just-ice: that legal institutions to resolve civil disputes are a public good to which all

2 The costs of private arbitration are high—Australia reportedly spent more than $50 million defending against a suit from Philip Morris on ‘plain packaging’ regulation, similar to Uruguay’s regulation. There are incentives to drive up costs: arbitrators are paid by the hour (unlike profes-sional judges).

3 The letter, issued 25 October 2017, is available at: http://bit.ly/2i7oiqS. The press release by Public Citizen is available at: http://bit.ly/2hTr5EP.

4 ‘Where Progressives and Conservatives Agree on Trade:  Current Investor–Trade Dispute Settlement Model is Bad for the United States’, Letter to Congress, Roosevelt Institute, 18 May 2015, available at: http://bit.ly/2ig0vWJ.

Page 13: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xv

xv

should have access. Private tribunals that effectively require millions of dollars in legal costs to use will privilege big businesses with an advantage over small busi-nesses and other stakeholders.

Still another objection relates to federalism. Investment agreements are signed by national governments, but they cover the behavior of sub-national governments as well. In the US, for instance, the federal government would have to provide compensation were a state or local government to be in breach of the investment agreement. (This is not just a hypothetical possibility: Mexico’s national govern-ment had to pay for an action of a municipality—restricting the use of land in the center of a city being used as a toxic waste dump.) The risk this poses to fed-eralism is obvious, as I mentioned in my 2015 letter:

[T] he investment protections written into US agreements extend to all actions taken by states and local governments. While these provisions do not necessarily proscribe the imposition of regulations, they impose a cost on US taxpayers for any loss in expected profits as a result. While the clear intent of the Constitution was to cede full authority for such regulation (other than, for instance, that affecting interstate commerce) to the States, the clear intent of these trade agreements is to use the Treaty Authority to limit the power of states and localities to regulate.

The problematic nature of resulting de facto federal authority over state actions (even actions which were never explicitly reserved for the Federal Government, and thus were reserved to the states) is heightened by the magnitude of the awards, discussed below, which could be well beyond the ability of a municipality to pay, were the burden shifted from the national government to the subnational unity. Since the agreement does not force a change in action, but simply compensation for the action, it is hard to see the national government agreeing to fund a persist-ent action giving rise to an investment claim; thus, either the Federal government would impose the costs on the subnational authority—and since they are even more constrained than the federal government, they would be financially ‘forced’ to change their behavior—and would prohibit the action. The trade agreement is thus, in effect, binding the states and municipalities to the broad standards of conduct and potential liabilities in the treaty. This is irrespective of the issue or measure and whether such issue or measure is (possibly solely) within the domain of the subnational unity, at least as far as the investments of foreign firms, con-stituting a major expansion of the reach of the Federal government in a way that arguably goes well beyond the Constitution.

We concluded in the joint 2017 letter:

Freed from the rules of US domestic procedural and substantive law that would have otherwise governed their lawsuits against the government, foreign corpor-ations can succeed in lawsuits before ISDS tribunals even when domestic law would have clearly led to the rejection of those companies’ claims. Corporations are even able to re-litigate cases they have already lost in domestic courts. It is ISDS arbitrators, not domestic courts, who are ultimately able to determine the bounds of proper US administrative, legislative, and judicial conduct.

Page 14: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xvi

xvi

(2) A basic function of the state is to protect the environment and citizens’ health and safety and to ensure the economy functions well; regulations are an import-ant tool for accomplishing these basic functions. The imposition of regulations will adversely affect those who are being regulated. A corporation selling a prod-uct which contains carcinogens will see its profits decrease if it is told it can’t sell the product. A firm that exploits its workers with unhealthy working conditions may see its profits decrease if it is told it can’t do that. A financial firm that is told that it can’t engage in predatory lending too will see its profits decrease. There is no end of ‘bad practices’ that corporations engage in, all for the purpose of mak-ing money; and stopping them from doing so naturally reduces their profits.5 But all countries have decided that it is unconscionable to have to pay those corpor-ations engaging in such nefarious actions for not engaging in them.

The magnitude of the change intended to be brought about by investment agree-ments is brought out by a quote attributed to a Toronto lawyer, Barry Appleton, who has been creative in expanding corporate claims under the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and was involved in suing Canada in both the Ethyl and SD Myers cases: ‘It wouldn’t matter if a substance was liquid plutonium destined for a child’s breakfast cereal. If the government bans a product and a US based company loses profits, the company can claim damages under NAFTA.’

One can view all of this within the perspective of rights in general, and prop-erty rights in particular. Individuals have rights, for example, the right to free speech. Corporations are creations of the state, and as such have no inalienable rights. Whatever rights they may have are derived rights, derived from the rights of those that are stakeholders in the firm (e.g. the rights of the ‘owners’) or rights that are given to them by the laws that create them. Thus, modern corporations are created with limited liability, but this limited liability should not be absolute, but constructed in ways which serves societal interests. Thus, I argue below that when a corporation engages in actions which put lives of individuals or the envir-onment in danger, the officers of the corporation should be held liable. In this view, then, corporations have no fundamental right to kill people, for example, through the sale of cigarettes, or opium, or other dangerous products. If they had that fundamental right, then (it could be argued) that they need to be compen-sated for taking away that right through regulation.

The standard Coasian debate on property rights pitted smokers versus non-smok-ers, suggesting that either assignment of property rights could lead to an efficient solution. One could give the property right of ‘air’ to smokers, in which case non-smokers would have to pay smokers not to smoke; or one could assign the property right to the non-smokers, in which case the smokers would have to

5 Nobel Prize winners George Akerlof and Robert Shiller have written a beautiful book detail-ing in sector after sector how corporations ‘phish for phools’ (See Akerlof and Shiller, 2015).

Page 15: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xvii

xvii

bribe the non-smokers if they wanted to smoke. In the cases under discussion here, though, societies have by and large come to a clear view: corporations (or for that matter individuals) have no inherent right to pollute, or to engage in other activities which inflict harm on others; and, therefore, there is no neces-sity to compensate them when regulations are passed stopping them from doing so. Indeed, in many cases, those committing those harms can be sued for the damage imposed, though it is often hard to prove in any given case a link, even though for the population as a whole, the link is indisputable. Thus, most coun-tries have adopted the polluter pay principle:  that the polluter not only is not compensated for stopping polluting, but that he has to pay for the damage that his pollution has caused.

Investment agreements (as they have been written in the past) turn all of this on its head. Those agreements say that governments have to pay polluters not to pollute, they have to pay cigarette and asbestos companies not to produce prod-ucts that kill, and they have to pay banks not to engage in practices that exploit others. Of course, the agreements are filled with words that only lawyers can understand—and different lawyers understand them in different ways. A simple trade agreement like the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) Agreement ran to some 6,000 pages, ensuring that virtually no Congressman could have read it before he voted on it. And amongst those 6,000 pages, there would have been no passage with inflammatory words such as, ‘this agreement enshrines a corporation’s right to kill. A corporation shall be fully compensated for any law or regulation depriv-ing corporations of this fundamental property right’. But this, in effect, is what the investment agreements do. They circumvent the standard way that property rights get assigned and re-assigned, through open democratic debate, and substi-tute a subterfuge, a de facto reassignment through seemingly obscure provisions of a trade and investment agreement.

The power that these investment agreements give to corporations and the extent to which the normal democratic processes for regulation and legislation are undermined cannot be overestimated. As I  noted in the ISDS briefing paper written for the Roosevelt Institute,6 ‘Two arbitrators can, in effect, undermine decisions of Congress and the president, ordering billions of dollars in payments for their lost investment value and guesstimated lost profits. They can sue over pretty much any law, regulation, or government decision.’

Six Fundamental Questions

Any investment agreement has to answer six questions.

6 See Part I of the series of Roosevelt Institute Policy Briefs, Tricks of the Trade Deal: Six Big Problems with the Trans-Pacific Partnership, 2016.

Page 16: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xviii

xviii

a) What is protected?

The objective of investment agreements should be to protect against discrimin-ation against foreign firms. Existing agreements have done something quite differ-ent: They have sought to curb the ability of the state to regulate, to legislate, and to redefine property rights. Rather than adhering to the well-established polluter pays principle, these agreements set a new precedent that governments would have to compensate corporations for not polluting or imposing other harms on others. TPP carved out an exemption that would allow for tobacco regulations to be passed without requiring the nation to compensate the tobacco company for losses. Every other area of regulation was seemingly left in—meaning, for example, nations could be sued for regulating carbon emissions or cutting sub-sidies to the fossil fuel industry to address climate change. Not only should it be clear that no investment agreement should curtail the ability of government to regulate, so too, no investment agreement should curtail the ability of govern-ment to end any corporate subsidy. Of course, this is especially true in the case of subsidies to fossil fuels.

Current agreements actually create discrimination against domestic firms: Foreign firms have rights not given to domestic firms, which encourages inversions, with all the adverse consequences for growth, development, and public finances that result. In the United States, Courts have ruled that the government does not have to compensate firms who experience a loss in profits or the value of their assets as a result of regulations, and for good reason: such compensation would hobble the ability of government to undertake actions to protect the health and safety of their citizens, protect the environment, or ensure a sound economy. Presumably banks would have had to be compensated when new regulations were passed to curb their excessive risk taking, their abusive credit card practices, their predatory lending, or other acts of malfeasance not covered by existing legislation. If such regulations had been in place when it was discovered that asbestos was danger-ous, rather than the asbestos producers compensating those that their product injured (killed), the government would have had to compensate these firms for not producing their dangerous products.

Such suits are not just a fantasy: they have occurred repeatedly, most notably in areas of health and the environment. Philip Morris’ suit against Uruguay’s plain wrapping regulations for cigarettes is perhaps the most notorious example: the regulation worked.7 Smoking was discouraged, Philip Morris lost expected profits,

7 Philip Morris v Uruguay, ICSID Case No. ARB/10/7. (The details of the case can be found here: http://bit.ly/2AIUTM8.) In this and the many other cases adjudicated under the investment agreements, no claim was made concerning discrimination, demonstrating that discrimination is not the central concern of these agreements. Although this case was ultimately decided in favor of Uruguay, it was on a 2–1 basis, so even this egregious case is not one that arbitrators deemed to be frivolous or a clear win for the government. Additionally, in this case, the World Health

Page 17: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xix

xix

and so it felt justified in suing. Advocates of these provisions point out that they do not interfere with the ability to regulate: the government is not compelled to change its law, just to provide for compensation for those who are injured. But for cash-starved governments, the threat of massive payments has a chilling effect on regulation; and indeed, I believe that is one of the main intents—not just to compensate those who have lost through regulations, but the ‘preventive’ effect of discouraging such regulations. Thus, the adverse effects of the investment agree-ments are not to be measured just by the suits that governments have lost, or even by the changes in policies that these suits have induced, but by the harder to measure but far broader negative impacts on desirable regulation or action.8

Anyone who participates in policy arenas touched by the investment agreement knows this situation well. The Investment Agreement sits there, in the fore-ground, shaping the set of policies that a country should consider. One can hear the debate: If we do X, we will almost surely be sued by Y. The Retort: But won’t we win? The Answer: With the biased system of adjudication (the ISDS dispute settlement process described below), who knows? There is a risk we can lose, with no appeal. And besides, do we want this distraction? Do we want other foreign investors to read the dispute as if we are unfriendly to foreign investors? Normally, the conversation will end with something like this: It just doesn’t seem to be worth the risk. Isn’t there something else we can do that almost accom-plishes what we want, but reduces the risk of running afoul of the investment agreement, at least in the minds of foreign investors?

I was in Chile in 2011 visiting the President and the Finance Minister. But my quiet conversations behind the scenes with those who formulate the law were equally telling. In the Chile–US Trade Agreement, which came into force in 2004, there was a provision relating to the free flow of capital. Chile had had more stability in its exchange rate, and economy, partly because it had long had a system of capital controls on the influx of capital. Those, like me and the former head of the UN Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA), José Antonio Ocampo, argued that this system was important in managing the ‘cap-ital account’, in ensuring that excessive in and out flows didn’t create booms and busts that wreak havoc to the economy. Our views, which we articulated in a series of books and conferences, have now become mainstream.9

Organization weighed in with an amicus brief. What would happen if the host state’s measures were more cutting edge and hadn’t yet received the stamp of approval of an international body? The government would likely have had a much more difficult time defending itself.

8 Kyla Tienharra, ‘Regulatory Chill and the Threat of Arbitration:  A View from Political Science’ in Evolution in Investment Treaty Law and Arbitration (Cambridge University Press 2011) 606, 615; Julia G Brown, ‘International Investment Agreements: Regulatory Chill in the Face of Litigious Heat?’ (2013) 3(1) Western Journal of Legal Studies. See also the chapter by Gus Van Harten and Dayna Nadine Scott in this volume.

9 See, for instance, Stiglitz et al (2006) and Ocampo and Stiglitz (2008).

Page 18: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xx

xx

Even the International Monetary Fund (IMF) supports capital account man-agement along the lines we had been advocating. (Though, of course, earlier they had taken quite the opposite position, attempting to change their charter in Hong Kong in 1997 to allow them to put pressure on countries that had not fully liberalized. Fortunately, that earlier venture failed.) The nature of global capital flows is that there are surges into or out of developing countries. It is these surges that are so destructive. Sometimes the surge is created by ‘animal spirits’, a sudden change in views about whether, for example, East Asia is a safe place to put one’s money. Sometimes the surge is brought about by a change in a particu-lar government policy. That was the case in 2011, when the US government had begun its most expansionary policy ever, driving not just short term interest rates to zero, but also longer term rates. Capital sought higher returns elsewhere. Not surprisingly, there was a surge to those that seemed strong and well managed, including Chile, Brazil, and Israel. This money brings with it more costs: at the time, the countries were booming, and didn’t need more stimulation. The inflow of money would have raised the exchange rate, hurting export industries, includ-ing the new ones being established as part of the development process. There was a consensus, I would say, both among economists and among the ‘afflicted’ countries that something should be done to dampen these flows—to avoid the historically loaded term ‘capital controls,’ such interventions were called ‘capital account management techniques’.

Brazil, South Korea, Israel, and Indonesia went ahead. But Chile worried: if Chile did, would it be contravening the trade and investment agreement? Could it be sued? With what consequences? Even though the case for Chile taking action was overwhelming, it did not, and I believe that the trade and investment agreement was critical in that decision.

In the case of the TPP, the United States Trade Representative (USTR) claimed that in the agreement there is language to avoid the abuses of previous investment agreements. Others, however, had a different reading of TPP. What is unambigu-ous is that there are massive ambiguities, providing a field day for lawyers. All of this is unnecessary. Arguably, a simpler statement could say: The purpose of invest-ment agreement provisions is not to curtail regulation, but to ensure that regulations cannot be written to discriminate against foreign firms and cannot be enforced in a discriminatory manner.

But even this does not suffice: the 2008 crisis as well as the East Asian Financial crisis made it clear that cross-border capital flows can be very destabilizing, and need to be regulated differently, and more tightly, than domestic financial trans-actions. Even the IMF now recognizes this.10

10 See IMF Policy Paper (2016).

Page 19: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxi

xxi

b) If there is a violation, what are the damages that can be collected?

A second key question is, if a government is found to violate the rights of an investor, what is the compensation that should be paid? A natural answer is that investors should be able to recover the amount they have spent. While that is the natural answer, it is not the answer in the typical investment agreements. Rather, these agreements allow investors to recover their expected profits.

The distinction is important for two reasons. First, because expected profits can be so much higher than the amount spent, this provision provides a strong incen-tive for investors to sue. And secondly, while the amount spent can be ascertained with reasonable reliability, expected profits are conjectural.

Consider, for instance, Philip Morris’s suit against Uruguay for its tobacco regu-lation. Is it reasonable to assume that smokers who could so easily be influenced not to smoke by a change in packaging would not have quit smoking eventually, perhaps as a result of an advertising campaign against smoking or social trends related to the growing awareness of the dangers of smoking? The capricious arbi-tration system leaves it to three lawyers to decide what the company’s profits would have been in the absence of the regulation. Any economist knows how fraught such calculations are, and no economist would feel comfortable leav-ing the decision up to a panel of three lawyers, especially when one of them has been picked by the suing corporation, and the other one appointed only with concurrence.

The analysis requires a highly speculative ‘counterfactual’—what the world would be like in the future but for the regulation. Good law tries to eschew such speculation. In this case, there was no need for reliance on such speculative cal-culations; there is an alternative: reimbursing corporations for their investments.

Why, one might ask, should one have such a speculative and expansive basis for compensation when investors could be fully protected against losses? The answer is simple: current agreements are structured as if the objectives are to enrich the corporations and to have a chilling effect on all regulations. Simply compensating for the lost investment might not have sufficed for these purposes.

That the lawyers have failed in their calculation of ‘future profits’ seems clear from numerous decisions. For instance, in the widely cited Myers case,11 Canada was forced to compensate a company for a regulation prohibiting shipping cer-tain toxic wastes to the US, even though the US prohibited the shipment, as did an international treaty. Any reasonable counterfactual would lead to the conclu-sion that the toxic waste shipment would not have occurred even if Canada had

11 SD Myers, Inc v Government of Canada, UNCITRAL (1976). (The details of the case can be found here: http://bit.ly/2AFWPnW).

Page 20: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxii

xxii

introduced the ban, and, therefore, there was no loss in Myers’s expected profits. But the arbitration panel ruled otherwise.

Interestingly, awards have been paid even when there was corruption involved in getting the contract. While a war against corruption is being waged elsewhere, the fruits of corruption are being guaranteed in investment agreements.12

c) Who can bring an action?

Under a fair investment agreement—one not just focused on corporate inter-ests— all stakeholders should have the right to pursue legal action if there has been a harm in violation of the agreement by either the regulatory state or the investor. However, under the standard investment agreements, ‘host’ country governments and citizens cannot sue foreign investors that violate local environ-ment, public health, consumer protection, and labor laws—and they certainly do not have recourse to arbitration tribunals to redress their grievances. A balanced system would ensure that any rights that allow corporations to litigate violations should also be guaranteed to governments, civil society, and others affected by a violation on the part of corporations of legal rights of citizens and/or a failure of firms to live up to their responsibilities. The legal process for redress of a vio-lation of a corporation’s rights seeks to bypass the normal legal process within the country. As I comment below, I am skeptical about the desirability of this kind of bypass. But if such a bypass should be granted to corporations, it should also be granted to other stakeholders in our economic system; and it needs to be recognized that if corporations have rights, they also have responsibilities, and those responsibilities include complying with all the laws of the land. And if one is skeptical of the ability of government to enforce the rights of corporations, one should be equally (or more) skeptical of the ability or willingness of governments to enforce the rights of citizens and others in a case where a large multinational corporation has violated those rights. Moreover, corporations have excelled in their ability to use cross-border legal machinations to avoid both taxes and legal liability: When corporations enter a country, they need to post bond or provide other surety that they will provide for any compensation for any harm they do to others. Most importantly, it must be possible to pierce the corporate veil and pass responsibility up through the increasingly complex web of global value chains; and since CEOs and other top managers often manage to avoid responsibility for their acts—with compensation coming out of the pockets of shareholders—there needs to be a system of holding managers accountable, including through prison

12 In another famous case, Indonesia had to pay more than USD 300 million in compensation for canceling a contract that the IMF itself had strongly recommended being cancelled because of the conditions under which it had been obtained. Cemex Asia Holdings Ltd v Republic of Indonesia, ICSID Case No. ARB/04/3. (The details of the case can be found here: http://bit.ly/2zHohSR).

Page 21: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxiii

xxiii

terms, with extradition treaties embedded in investment agreements for malfea-sance on the part of corporate officers.13

Over time, arbitration panels and new investment agreements have taken an increasingly expansive view of who can sue, including what it means to make an investment in a country. Simply having an office may be treated as an ‘invest-ment’. The opportunities for suits for lost profits are unbounded: a small invest-ment can bring large returns from litigations. Buyers of bonds may be considered as investors, and sue over any attempt at restructuring—possibly making restruc-turing in practice impossible. Since the nineteenth century, there has been a principle that debtors have the rights to a fresh start; under extreme exigencies there needs to be debt write-down. But forcing the issuing country to compen-sate a bondholder for the loss of value would de facto preventing that fresh start. I believe that investment agreements should (at most) have a narrow remit:  to protect those making substantial real investments in the country from a loss of their investments in a discriminatory manner as a result of a government action. As I noted earlier, this simple statement has to be qualified in two ways. There may be some situations (which should be explicitly specified) where differential treatment should be acceptable, for example, concerning cross-border financial flows. And there may be some actions, such as full expropriation without com-pensation, which might be covered whether discriminatory or not (since firms can obtain insurance against the latter, for simplicity, I would not include that within the investment treaty).14

d) How can a private actor bring an action?

Among the most criticized aspects of investment agreements is that investors can sue governments directly, creating an asymmetry between states and investors that did not previously exist. Traditionally, only governments can sue investors (with limited exceptions, where governments agree to be sued for certain liabili-ties), not the other way around. I believe that the approach should be similar to the WTO, where only governments can bring actions against government.

Many governments (such as Brazil) have made it clear that this system of ISDS is unacceptable. I agree. A firm (or another stakeholder) that believes that some provision of the agreement has been violated resulting in harm to the stakeholder

13 Famously, in the Bhopal chemical disaster in India, it proved impossible to hold the officials of Union Carbide accountable. See Chapter 7 in Stiglitz (2006) for a brief discussion.

14 It should be obvious that even what appears to be a straightforward agreement in practice may entail many complexities, in particular, in deciding whether a particular action is discrim-inatory. If the only seller of large cars is a foreign company, then a regulation pertaining to large cars but not to small cars could be viewed as discriminatory. Yet many countries make such dif-ferentiation as a matter of public policy. The investment agreement should make clear that there should be a high bar in proving discrimination, i.e. deference should be given to the government in a finding of the desirability of that particular act as advancing a public purpose.

Page 22: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxiv

xxiv

should have recourse to petition its government to bring a case. If this provision was put in place, the worst abuses of ISDS would not occur. It is unlikely that the US government would have brought a case against Uruguay for its tobacco regulation or against Canada for prohibiting the shipment of toxic waste to the US. Requiring the government to bring the case puts the case at least through a filter, a judgment of whether the suit makes sense from the perspective of overall policy. A government where the given act would not have been deemed grounds of suit would be wary of bringing a suit against another government. The US government recognizes the right to interfere with the packaging of cigarettes. It knows that health advocates would like plain packaging, because such packaging discourages purchases. Health authorities know that it is internal political rea-sons that are holding back such a requirement here—the power of the cigarette companies and tobacco farmers. Most government officials would secretly con-gratulate Uruguay for doing what it is doing. Accordingly, it is hard to see how they could bring a suit against Uruguay, or if they did, whether they would put into the case the resources necessary to win.

e) What is the mechanism for adjudicating disputes? And under what ‘law’?

Disputes should be adjudicated according to broadly accepted rules of law. One of the most vilified, and rightly so, aspects of the investment agreements embod-ied in TPP and other trade agreements, is that the judicial standards fall far below twenty-first century standards. The problems have, by now, been well doc-umented, and could easily be remedied:

1) A case should only be brought after exhaustion of domestic remedies. Thus, a case would be heard by an international tribunal only after the plaintiff had gone through the country’s court system. The plaintiff could bring such a case if they had been discriminated against, either in terms of the regulation itself or in terms of the way that domestic courts had treated them. (Recall, I have argued that the only protection should be for discrimination. There can, of course, be complaints about other laws, but these are complaints that should be evaluated solely in terms of the countries’ constitution and other laws. A foreigner should have no special standing. If the investor doesn’t like the legal framework, he doesn’t have to invest in the country. But he should have no right to change the laws according to his interests or beliefs, or to be compensated when he knowingly enters a country where there is a different legal tradition.)

2) Adjudication should be done by a permanent court, with a permanent appel-late court, with permanent judges chosen on the basis of the highest judicial standards. This could either be a newly established Investment Court or one of the courts of the constituent countries (e.g. a panel of judges from the Supreme Courts of the two countries). This would eliminate the problems of conflicts of interest, conflicting findings, and the absence of appeal, that

Page 23: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxv

xxv

have made the ISDS process a mockery of justice. (Today, a judge in one case can be an advocate in an almost parallel case. He would obviously have an incentive in the first case to make a ruling that he could cite to help win the second. Judges have an incentive not to rule against the larger countries, since the larger countries are embroiled in more suits, and being seen as contrary to the interests of the US or another large country may cost one dearly—one won’t be chosen to be either judge or counsel, and losing the legitimacy in the eyes of these countries may cause the whole system to unravel. This could play a role in the oft-cited finding that the larger countries are less likely to lose cases. President Obama boasted that the US had never lost a case, though Canada had lost more than a dozen NAFTA cases, and settled others in ways that were unfavorable to Canada’s broader interests. It may be that the US just happened to have better cases, or that it could afford better lawyers; but there is a darker, more sinister interpretation, just suggested.) Of course, the court/appellate body would be limited to adjudicating state-to-state claims for the narrow breaches that should be the subject of investment agreements.

3) The international tribunal adjudicating such disputes should conform to the basic principles practiced by commercial courts in the EU and US, includ-ing those pertaining to evidence, precedence, appeal, and transparency. Of course, there are differences among countries in the details of these judi-cial processes, and a committee of jurists from the relevant countries should resolve such differences, with their decisions then approved by the parlia-ments. (Trade ministers may not be in the best position to judge among alter-native judicial processes and procedures.) Because issues in one case may have relevance in other cases, or be important as matters of principle, non-litigants should be allowed to file briefs.

In the private arbitration, others with an interest in the outcome of the case—those whose lives might be at risk if a regulation were circumscribed or repealed, as might likely happen if the corporation seeking damages prevails—cannot typ-ically present their concerns. Because precedents may play little or no role, two almost identical cases can emerge with different outcomes, providing no guid-ance forward; and with no system of appeal, these problems are exacerbated.

f) What is the mechanism for revision?

The arbitration panels have sometimes come to peculiar or at least unexpected or unanticipated interpretations of certain words in an investment agreement. An agreement might, for instance, specify ‘appropriate compensation’, not spell-ing out what that means. An expansive arbitration panel might decide that that meant compensation for a loss of expected profits, and with a small number of international law firms engaged as judges and advocates in such cases, this may become the ‘norm’, contrary, perhaps, even to the expectations of all parties to the agreement. As I wrote in my Roosevelt Institute briefing paper, ‘Investment

Page 24: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxvi

xxvi

agreements guarantee a “minimum standard of treatment,” a vague standard that corporate-friendly arbitrators have interpreted liberally in past decisions, invent-ing obligations for governments that do not exist in the actual text of agreements or host countries’ laws.’

Words are always subject to different interpretations, and when tens or even hun-dreds of millions of dollars are at stake, good lawyers can make good arguments for an interpretation that is favorable to their client, regardless of the costs to soci-ety. When this happens domestically, the legislature makes a correction, spelling out what it is that was meant. With trade and investment treaties, there is no way in which such corrections can be made systematically.

So too, economies and technologies change, and a provision that made sense at one time may not make sense a quarter or half century later. Built into agree-ments are specifics, like the time period of data exclusivity for biologics. There is disagreement about what the appropriate number should have been in, say, 2014 (with the President of the United States suggesting 7 years, his own USTR arguing for 12 years, many in the scientific community arguing for 0.) But there should be no disagreement that whatever that number in 2014, there is no a priori reason it should be the same twenty-five years later. Again, there is no systematic way for revisions. Opening up an agreement for renegotiation opens up a ‘can of worms’. But there should be an understanding that specific provisions (like the misinterpretation of certain words by dispute panels) should periodically be analyzed and reviewed, and that this should be done not just by trade ministers, who often are captured by special interests, but in an open process involving civil society, legislators, and others.

Concluding Comments

We have seen that investment agreements are not about discrimination, as their advocates dishonestly purport. Indeed, there have been very few cases in which the investor succeeded on a claim of discrimination, of receiving less favorable treatment than the domestic investor.15 They are about expanding the power of

15 Based on the data on claims available from UNCTAD (http://investmentpolicyhub.unc-tad.org/ISDS/FilterByBreaches), Lisa Sachs and Lise Johnson found ‘that there have only been 8 cases in which the investor succeeded on a claim that it received less favorable treatment than the domestic investor. Importantly, however, in none of the cases did the tribunal find that there was intentional nationality-based discrimination against the investor. Rather, liability was usu-ally based on protection of an upstream segment (e.g. domestic producers of sugar or other agri-cultural commodities) or downstream segment (domestic producers of hazardous wastes) of the value chain that negatively affected the downstream or upstream foreign investor; in other cases, liability was a result of disparate treatment in the law (or its enforcement or application) that the tribunal didn’t agree with but that had nothing to do with nationality (3 cases).’ See Sachs and Johnson (2017).

Page 25: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxvii

xxvii

corporations, at the expense of the rest of society. If investment agreements were really about discrimination, they would have been narrower; and in narrowing their focus, they would have avoided much of the controversy surrounding them. But narrowing their focus would have undermined their true objective.

One of the sources of comparative advantage of the US and other advanced countries is their rule of law. Indeed, with capital and skilled labor increasingly mobile, this is one of the true sources of comparative advantage. One might won-der, then, why would advanced countries give up this comparative advantage, helping to ensure that developing countries provide even stronger property rights than do developed countries? Surely, doing so is not in their national interests. But we need to remember: trade and investment agreements are crafted in secret, with corporations at the table, and broader interests absent. Such agreements are not in the national interest, but in narrow corporate interests. They facilitate the movement of jobs out of a country, by ensuring property rights protection when factories move abroad, and ensuring the output of those factories easy entry into the US (or other advanced country that is party to the agreement), regardless of the environmental and labor standards of the country or how those standards are enforced. They provide no recourse to those in the advanced country that see unfair competition in developing countries not enforcing whatever weak stand-ards have been agreed to or are encoded in the laws of the country; but provide full recourse when corporations’ profits are at risk. The threat of factories moving out of a country—to a locale with better property rights protection but fewer labor and environmental protections—weakens workers’ bargaining rights. The decrease in wages, especially of unskilled workers, may not be a matter of collat-eral damage in the process of globalization, an unfortunate side-effect; but it may in fact have been the ‘main show’.16 This decrease in wages, of course, increases profits. The change in property rights—reflected in the regulatory takings pro-vision—makes it all the more difficult for countries domestically to pass regu-lations protecting citizens’ welfare, through environmental, health, safety, and economic regulations. This too enhances corporate profits, again at the expense of the rest of society.

Investment agreements between developed countries and those between a devel-oped country and developing country pose distinct problems. In both cases, investment agreements in their current form should be viewed as an unacceptable change in property rights, giving more power to corporations and diminishing that of ordinary citizens.

Developing countries may gain jobs, but they pay a high price, as country after country has learned. South Africa discovered that it could be sued as it tried to

16 This thesis is developed further in Stiglitz (2017).

Page 26: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxviii

xxviii

rectify through its black empowerment laws a half century of racial discrimin-ation through apartheid. Egypt discovered that it could be sued as it tried to ensure a minimal standard of living for its workers through a minimum wage law.

If there is to be investment agreements between developed and developing coun-tries, they need to be narrowly circumscribed, to issues of discrimination, and there is a need to create an international investment court to adjudicate disputes. I suspect that corporations will be little interested in such an investment agree-ment, which would fulfill the purported objective of investment agreements.

But for developed countries, investment agreements are even more problematic. These agreements are sold as providing property rights protections not otherwise afforded to investors. The objections raised by the proposed agreement between the US and EU make clear the lack of logic in these agreements: (1) Both the US and the EU have good systems of property rights; (2) Both the US and the EU have good judicial systems for enforcing those property rights; (3) If there is a deficiency in either the judicial system or the property rights regime, it should be remedied for all investors, indeed all citizens, not just foreign investors.

The only justification for an investment agreement is the belief that courts in the US will discriminate against corporations from the EU and vice versa. No evi-dence that this is a real problem has been presented. The investment agreements seem to be solving a problem that does not exist. But in doing so, they create mas-sive new problems, including an undemocratic redefinition of property rights. If it were that there were a problem of discrimination, the remedy would be a simple agreement, again focusing on discrimination, as a last recourse, after exhaustion of domestic courts, with adjudication through an international investment tribu-nal, not the faux justice of private arbitration.

It is time to see these investment agreements for what they are:  a behind the scenes power grab on the part of corporations. At least in their current form, they have no place in a democratic society.

References

Akerlof, GA and Shiller, RJ, 2015, Phishing for Phools: The Economics of Manipulation and Deception (Princeton University Press 2015)

International Monetary Fund, 2016, ‘Capital Flows— Review of Experience with the Institutional View’ Policy Paper, available at:  https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2016/110416a.pdf

Ocampo, JA and Stiglitz, JE (eds), Capital Market Liberalization and Development (Oxford University Press 2008)

Sachs, L and Johnson, L, ‘Discrimination Against Foreign Investors: Myth or reality?’ CCSI Briefing Note (forthcoming 2017).

Page 27: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Preface

xxix

xxix

Stiglitz, JE, Globalization and Its Discontents (WW Norton Company 2002)Stiglitz, JE, Globalization and Its Discontents Revisited: Anti-globalization in the Era of

Trump (WW Norton Company 2017)Stiglitz, JE, Making Globalization Work (WW Norton Company 2006)Stiglitz, JE, ‘Regulating Multinational Corporations: Towards Principles of Cross-Border

Legal Frameworks in a Globalized World Balancing Rights with Responsibilities’ (2008) 23(3) American University International Law Review 451–558. Grotius Lecture presented at the 101st Annual Meeting of the American Society for International Law, Washington, DC, 28 March 2007

Stiglitz, JE, Tricks of the Trade Deal: Six Big Problems with the Trans-Pacific Partnership, 2016, Roosevelt Institute Policy Briefs, available at:  http://rooseveltinstitute.org/tricks-trade-deal-six-big-problems-trans-pacific-partnership/

Stiglitz, J E, Ocampo, JA, Spiegel, S, Ffrench-Davis, R, and Nayyar, D, Stability with Growth: Macroeconomics, Liberalization, and Development (Oxford University Press 2006)

Page 28: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

xxx

Page 29: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

xxxi

xxxi

CONTENTS— SUMMARY

Author Biographies  xli

PART I

1. Explaining Global Trends in FDI in 2015 and Beyond 3Ilan Strauss

2. International Investment Agreements, 2015– 2016: A Review of Trends and New Approaches 42Jesse Coleman, Lise Johnson, Lisa Sachs, and Kanika Gupta

3. Notable Developments in International Investment Arbitration Case Law: 2015– 2016 116Kendra Magraw

PART II

4. The Outcomes of Investment Treaty Arbitration: A Reassessment 147Karen L Remmer

5. Multinational Enterprises and Investment Treaties 176Mark Feldman

6. Investment Law’s Roots in Customary International Law: Why Investment Law and Trade Diverge Regarding the Right to Regulate 226Shu XU, Yingying WU, and Henry Hailong JIA

7. Embedding the International Investment Regime: An Assessment of UNCTAD’s Proposal for Reform 261Jean- Michel Marcoux

8. When Some Are More Equal than Others: The Need for a More Substantive Conception of ‘Equality of the Parties’ in Investment Arbitration 292Eve Bain

9. Federal States and Investment Arbitration 327Facundo Pérez- Aznar

Page 30: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Contents—Summary

xxxii

xxxii

10. Has China Become ‘Legally’ a Market- Economy Country on 11 December 2016 under the WTO Antidumping Agreement? Analysing an Open Question 357Giorgio Sacerdoti

11. Fragrant Harbour and Oyster Mirror: Beijing’s Investment Treaty Policy towards Hong Kong and Macao 376Chin Leng Lim

12. Investment Treaties and the Internal Vetting of Regulatory Proposals: Further Findings from a Case Study from Canada 412Gus Van Harten and Dayna Nadine Scott

13. Expropriation in Brazil’s Cooperation and Facilitation Investment Agreements: A Failed Attempt to Think Outside the Box 445Ely Caetano Xavier Junior and José Augusto Fontoura Costa

Page 31: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

xxxiii

xxxiii

CONTENTS— DETAILED

Author Biographies  xli

PART I

1. Explaining Global Trends in FDI in 2015 and Beyond Ilan Strauss

A. Introduction  1.01

B. FDI Flows in 2015: Investment Without Growth  1.081. Increase in European FDI: Both inward and outward?  1.112. Increase in FDI into Asia?  1.183. Cross- border M&A and ‘corporate reconfigurations’  1.24

C. Was FDI in 2015 Really Such an Aberration? A Look at FDI Trends  1.301. Changing US corporate investment behaviour: Structural or

cyclical? A Bayesian VAR approach  1.34

D. FDI as Reflecting the Intra- firm Financing Decision  1.411. Financial market drivers  1.682. Real economy impact of FDI financing  1.713. Substitute financing  1.734. Shift away from control exercised by managers  1.77

E. Conclusion  1.80Appendix: Description of the Bayesian VAR Regression  38

2. International Investment Agreements, 2015– 2016: A Review of Trends and New ApproachesJesse Coleman, Lise Johnson, Lisa Sachs, and Kanika Gupta

A. Introduction  2.01

B. Expanded Awareness and Interest  2.13

C. Negotiation and Ratification  2.171. Trends and impacts  2.212. Implications for future outcomes  2.35

D. Addressing Asymmetries?  2.361. Access to dispute settlement  2.40

a. Filter mechanisms  2.41

Page 32: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Contents—Detailed

xxxiv

xxxiv

b. Other limitations on arbitral power  2.48c. Alternatives to ISDS  2.52

2. Right to regulate  2.53a. Preambular texts  2.58b. Other provisions on the right to regulate  2.61c. Implications  2.73d. Retaining regulatory space through narrowed jurisdiction  2.78

3. Investor obligations  2.81

E. Conduct of Arbitrators  2.891. Impartiality, independence, and avoiding conflicts  2.902. Arbitrator qualifications  2.993. Multilateral investment court  2.103

F. Conclusion  2.108

3. Notable Developments in International Investment Arbitration Case Law: 2015– 2016 Kendra Magraw

A. Introduction  3.01

B. Security for Costs  3.04

C. Disclosure of Third- Party Funding  3.18

D. Strategic Investment Structuring to Benefit from Investment Treaty Protection  3.25

E. First Decisions in the Energy Charter Treaty Cases Against Spain  3.39

F. Host States’ Right to Regulate  3.54

G. Enforcement and Set- Aside Proceedings  3.67

H. Conclusion  3.76

PART II

4. The Outcomes of Investment Treaty Arbitration: A Reassessment Karen L Remmer

A. Introduction  4.01

B. Prior Research Findings  4.05

C. Theoretical Perspectives  4.15

D. Empirical Analysis  4.25

E. Sensitivity Analysis of Multinomial Logit Models  4.40

F. Conclusion  4.43

Appendix  173

Page 33: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Contents—Detailed

xxxv

xxxv

5. Multinational Enterprises and Investment Treaties Mark Feldman

A. Introduction  5.01

B. The Reciprocal Protection and Promotion of Investments under IIAs  5.18

C. MNE Reliance on International Production Networks and Transit Investment  5.231. International production networks  5.242. Transit investment and the expanding role of SPEs  5.30

D. Free Rider Category One: Claimants Acting as Exporters rather than Investors  5.351. ‘Investor’ characteristic no 1: Host state investment as centre of

gravity for interrelated operations  5.472. ‘Investor’ characteristic no 2: Significant scale of host state investment  5.613. ‘Investor’ characteristic no 3: Preponderant share of damages

concerns host state operations  5.674. ‘Investor’ characteristic no 4: Significant share of value created

captured in host state  5.735. ‘Investor’ characteristic no 5: Outside operations inextricable

from investing activity in the host state  5.80

E. Free Rider Category Two: Claimants Lacking a Meaningful Connection to their Home State  5.891. Policy option one: Barring claims by SPEs as investors  5.912. Policy option two: Allowing case- by- case review of SPE claims by

treaty parties  5.100a. Standards for triggering a host state’s right to deny treaty

benefits  5.103b. Home state involvement in connection with a decision to

deny treaty benefits  5.110c. The time by which a denial of benefits must occur  5.114

3. Policy option three: Allowing claims by SPEs as investors  5.120

F. Free Rider Category Three: Claimants Lacking a Meaningful Connection to their Host State Investments  5.1291. Reflective loss claims  5.1312. Indirect investment claims  5.1423. A ‘remoteness’ limitation  5.144

G. Conclusion  5.153

6. Investment Law’s Roots in Customary International Law: Why Investment Law and Trade Diverge Regarding the Right to Regulate Shu XU, Yingying WU, and Henry Hailong JIA

A. Introduction  6.01

B. Substantive Obligations in International Investment Law  6.13

Page 34: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Contents—Detailed

xxxvi

xxxvi

1. Two key substantive obligations and their roles in international investment law  6.14

2. FET  6.17a. Treatment of the balancing issue  6.18b. The relevance of CIL to the FET obligation  6.23

3. Expropriations  6.32a. The balancing issue under rules concerning

expropriations 6.33b. The relevance of CIL to rules concerning expropriations 6.39

C. The Exceptions Jurisprudence in International Investment Law  6.451. Exceptions in CIL  6.46

a. The only- way requirement  6.47b. Self- contribution  6.48c. The scope of legitimate rationales  6.49d. Compensation  6.51e. Overall assessment  6.53

2. Exceptions in IIAs  6.54

D. Conclusion  6.65

7. Embedding the International Investment Regime: An Assessment of UNCTAD’s Proposal for Reform Jean- Michel Marcoux

A. Introduction  7.01

B. Embedded Liberalism and Regime Change in International Investment Law  7.071. From economic liberalism to social protection: A double

movement  7.082. Norm- governed change and norm- transforming change  7.133. A potential application to the international investment regime  7.17

C. UNCTAD’s Proposal as a Norm- Governed Attempt at Embedding the International Investment Regime  7.231. UNCTAD’s framing of the international investment law reform  7.24

a. The need for an embedded international investment regime  7.25b. Proposing a norm- governed change  7.33

2. Statements from members of the investment community  7.43a. A shared understanding to embed the international

investment regime  7.44b. The prevalence of a norm- governed change  7.50

D. Conclusion  7.59

Page 35: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Contents—Detailed

xxxvii

xxxvii

8. When Some Are More Equal than Others: The Need for a More Substantive Conception of ‘Equality of the Parties’ in Investment Arbitration Eve Bain

A. Introduction  8.01

B. Development of the Principle  8.041. Origins  8.052. Content and function of these principles  8.083. International Court of Justice  8.124. Investor– state arbitration  8.17

C. New Forms of Dispute Settlement and an Age- old Principle  8.201. Presentation of evidence  8.20

a. Claiming privilege  8.23b. State secret privilege  8.24c. Balancing competing interests  8.28d. Logistical issues  8.32

2. Exercise of state coercive power  8.36

D. Shifting the Balance  8.401. Inherent powers of international courts and tribunals  8.41

a. Drawing adverse inferences  8.44b. Responding to misuse of coercive authority  8.48

2. Managing costs to ensure equality  8.52

E. Conclusion  8.57

9. Federal States and Investment ArbitrationFacundo Pérez- Aznar

A. Introduction  9.01

B. Rules on State Responsibility in International Law and Federal States  9.091. Applicable rules on state responsibility  9.092. Distinction between attribution and the creation of an

international obligation  9.143. Distinction between attribution and jurisdiction  9.234. Provisions on federal states in IIAs  9.28

C. Substantive Provisions in IIAs and Federal States  9.381. National and most- favoured- nation treatment  9.382. Umbrella clauses  9.46

D. Relationships Between Subdivisions and Federal States and Investment Arbitration  9.511. Relationship prior to a dispute  9.51

Page 36: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Contents—Detailed

xxxviii

xxxviii

2. Relationship during a dispute  9.553. Relationship after a dispute: The issue of financial responsibility  9.62

E. Conclusion  9.68

10. Has China Become ‘Legally’ a Market- Economy Country on 11 December 2016 under the WTO Antidumping Agreement? Analysing an Open Question Giorgio Sacerdoti

A. Introduction  10.01

B. The Accession Protocol Provisions Governing AD Investigation and Determination of AD Duties on Chinese Products after 11 December 2016  10.05

C. The Regulation of AD Investigations by the EU Taking into Account Section 15 of China’s AP as Applicable 11 December 2016  10.08

D. Procedural Preconditions for Disregarding ADA Methodologies and Using the ‘Analogue Country’ Methodology  10.16

E. Determining the AD Regime After the Lapse of Section 15(a)(ii)  10.291. Interpretive criteria  10.302. Interpretation of section 15(a) after the cancellation of

subparagraph (a)(ii)  10.35

F. What Basis for a WTO Compliant Solution?  10.39

G. Conclusion  10.52

11. Fragrant Harbour and Oyster Mirror: Beijing’s Investment Treaty Policy towards Hong Kong and Macao Chin Leng Lim

A. Introduction  11.01

B. Treaty Succession and Moving Territorial Frontiers  11.05

C. Commercial Realities: The Vast Network and Greater Scope of Protection which Chinese Treaties Provide 11.15

D. Tza Yap Shum v Peru  11.20

E. A Persistent Misunderstanding over ‘Autonomy’  11.25

F. Sanum v Lao 11.35

G. Hong Kong, Macao, and the Issue of ‘Unequal’ Treaties  11.42

Page 37: YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015…ccsi.columbia.edu/files/2014/03/YB-2015-16-Front-matter.pdf · YEARBOOK ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT LAW & POLICY 2015– 2016

Contents—Detailed

xxxix

xxxix

H. The Pacta Tertiis Problem  11.541. The Sino– British and Sino– Portuguese devolution agreements  11.542. How the Sanum tribunal saw it  11.603. The ‘moving treaty frontiers’ rule, and the ‘whole territory’ clause  11.624. A misplaced controversy over the Sino– Laotian notes verbale  11.69

I. Modern ‘Consensual’ Arrangements  11.74

J. Distinguishing a Subsequent Treaty Intent from Laotian Acceptance of the Sino– Portuguese Arrangement  11.78

K. Putting a Question of Principle to the Task of Stifling a Claim  11.83

L. Conclusion  11.87

12. Investment Treaties and the Internal Vetting of Regulatory Proposals: Further Findings from a Case Study from Canada Gus Van Harten and Dayna Nadine Scott

A. Introduction  12.01

B. Background  12.061. The context of Ontario, Canada  12.062. Method  12.10

C. Findings  12.151. ISDS risks and pressures for government  12.15

a. Financial risks of ISDS for government  12.16b. Non- financial risks of ISDS for government  12.21c. Impacts of ISDS on individual officials  12.28d. Opportunity costs of ISDS  12.33

2. Factors that can override ISDS risks  12.36a. Political commitment as an overriding factor  12.37b. The example of the Ontario Pesticides Act  12.45c. Conflicting views of ISDS costs  12.54d. Conflicting views of the orientation of potential

ISDS claimants  12.60e. Conflicting views of federal responsibility  12.68f. Varying knowledge of ISDS  12.72g. ISDS risks may still stymie proposed measures  12.76

3. Trade values and health or environmental decision- making  12.84a. Perceived ‘true believers’ among trade officials  12.85b. Trade officials’ views of trade values and environmental

goals  12.91c. Other officials’ views of trade values and environmental

goals  12.95

D. Discussion 12.104

E. Conclusion 12.110