03. household and intrahousehold models

Upload: eliceokj

Post on 04-Apr-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    1/34

    3 . HOUSEHOLD AND INTRAHOUSEHOLD MODELS

    PPS603Microeconomics of International Development Policy

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    2/34

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    3/34

    Agricultural Households as Consumption and Production Units

    Standard microeconomic theory relies on two fundamental, separate

    agentsthe consumer and the producer.

    But households in developing countries are often consumers andproducers of specific goods. This is especially true for staples

    (e.g., rice, maize, wheat).

    We focus on the agricultural household, which is both a productionand a consumption unit. Well talk of agricultural household

    models (AHMs).

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    4/34

    Good 1

    Good 2

    IC0

    IC1

    *

    1x

    *

    2x

    21/pp

    Direction of IncreasingUtility

    Refresher: Consumer Theory

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    5/34

    pw/

    *L

    ),(* AELF

    Labor

    Output

    Refresher: Production Theory

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    6/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    }2,1{iTwo individuals:

    Each individual has a level of consumption ci and a level of leisure

    The price of the consumption good isp and the price of labor (and

    thus leisure) is wThe household produces some of the consumption good according to

    the production function F(L,A), whereL denotes labor used on the

    farm andA denotes the amount of cultivable land

    Endowments of time and land are andPrice of one unit of land is r

    i

    L

    iEA

    E

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    7/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    The households maximization problem is thus

    subject to),,,(max 2121,,, 2121

    ccUcc

    mmmhh

    rALLwALpFrAwLccp )(),()( 2121

    hffLLLL

    21

    hf AAA mfA

    AAE

    i

    m

    i

    f

    i

    L

    iLLE

    0,,,,, mfm

    i

    f

    iii AALLc Resource

    Constraints

    IncomeExpenditures

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    8/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    The problem of the household is to maximize its utility subject to a

    budget constraint (expenditures cannot exceed income) and

    several resource constraints.

    The above problem can be reduced by substituting the resource

    constraints into the budget constraint: this yields the following

    version of the households maximization problem.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    9/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    The households maximization problem is then

    subject to

    The new budget constraint is called the full-income constraint, andthe next equation represents farm profits.

    ),,,(max2121

    ,,, 2121

    ccUcc

    ALL

    rEEEwwccp )()()( 212121

    rAwLALpF ),(

    0,,, ALc ii

    Farm Profit

    New Budget Constraint

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    10/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    The new problem is recursive: ifUis characterized by non-satiation,

    then the full-income constraint is binding and household utility is

    increasing in farm profitthe higher the profits from the farm, the

    better off the householdand the optimal choices ofL andA do

    not appear in the objective function.The problem can then be rewritten as

    subject to

    where * is the profit function, which only depends on prices.

    ),,,(max2121

    ,,, 2121

    ccUcc

    ALL rEEEwrwpwccp )(),,()()( 21*

    2121

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    11/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    This setup allows to

    1. Maximize profit; then

    2. Maximize utility

    In other words: with complete markets, production decisions onlydepend on prices and plot characteristics, and notonhousehold endowments or preferences.

    This is called the Separation Property: production decisions areseparable from consumption choices (but not the other wayaround).

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    12/34

    LE

    ),( cu

    pw/

    ),(A

    ELF

    Labor,

    - Leisure

    Output,

    Consumption

    Good

    *L

    ),(* AELF

    Profit),/(

    AEpw

    *c

    *

    LE

    The Agricultural Household Model with Separability

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    13/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    The Separation Property holds even if one market is missing (e.g., in

    our example, either land or labor).

    The Separation Property rarely ever holds in practice, as it is quite

    likely that more than one market goes missing.

    When there are multiple (i.e., two or more) market failures, theSeparation Property fails to hold, and household consumption is

    constrained by household production, so to speak.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    14/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model: Multiple Missing Markets

    Suppose now that both markets (land and labor) are missing.

    The Separation Property does not hold: the household no longermaximizes profit, and production decisions depend on the

    preferences of the household and its endowments.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    15/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    More specifically, and assuming for simplicity that there is only one

    individual in the household, we have

    subject to),(max,,,

    cUfh

    LLc

    mhAhf wLwLELLpFpc ),(

    Lmf ELL

    MLm

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    16/34

    Basic Agricultural Household Model

    IfLm = M, the problem becomes

    subject to

    But then, the first-order conditions yield

    and the production decision now depends on preferences and

    endowments (see graph).

    ),(max,

    cUc

    wMEMEpFpc AL ),(

    L

    c

    FU

    U

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    17/34

    M

    ),(A

    ELF

    wM

    c

    -Leisure

    Labor

    *q*c

    ),( cu

    fL

    MLf

    A

    B C

    The Agricultural Household Model with Non-Separability

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    18/34

    Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models

    Knowing what we know about market failures, we come to the crux

    of this section: What do the data have to say?

    In other words, does the Separation Property hold in practice?

    The short answer is that the bulk of the empirical evidence is in

    favor ofrejecting the Separation Property.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    19/34

    Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models

    Benjamin (1992) tests for separation in Indonesia.

    Idea:Holding everything else constant, supply-side (i.e., productionfactors) variables should not affect labor demand, and demand-

    side variables (i.e., consumption factors) should not affect laborsupply.

    Test: Household composition has no effect on the households labor

    allocation at the margin.

    Benjamin cannot reject the null hypothesis.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    20/34

    Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models

    Problem: The test is not very powerful, since the bulk of the

    probability mass lies with non-rejection, i.e., a nonresult.

    Even though Pitt and Rosenzweig (1986) also cannot reject

    separation in an earlier round of the same Indonesian data, these

    results should be taken with a grain of salt.

    The vast majority of empirical studies reject the Separation

    Property (Collier, 1983; Carter, 1984; Jacoby, 1993; Kevane,

    1994; Barrett, 1996; Udry, 1999).

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    21/34

    Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models

    For example, Jacoby rejects that the Separation Property holds in

    Peru.

    Idea: Households set their marginal productivity of labor equal to

    the market wage.

    Test: a = 0 and b = 1 in the regression

    Jacoby rejects the null hypothesis of separation.

    iii ebWaMPL

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    22/34

    Agricultural Household Models

    What to remember from all this? The following points are key:

    1. What happens when the Separation Property holds?

    2. The Separation Property holds if there is only one market

    failure.

    3. When the Separation Property fails to hold, production decisions

    depend on preferences and endowments.

    4. The Separation Property has been largely rejected.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    23/34

    Intrahousehold Models: A Technical Aside

    In the AHM, we assume that one utility function can represent the

    preferences of many individuals.

    This is inconsistent with the methodological individualism of

    economic theory.

    For such aggregation to be possible, a lot of structure needs to be

    imposed on the preferences ofeach individual of the household

    (Gorman, 1953).

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    24/34

    Response to Aggregation Limitation

    To overcome this, we can make strong assumptions about the

    intra-household distribution of resources

    For example, Beckers Rotten Kid Theorem assumes thehousehold includes a benevolent dictator who redistributes

    resources efficiently, i.e., up to the point where everyones

    marginal utility of income is the same.

    In this case, the household is (analytically) indistinguishable from

    a single individual.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    25/34

    Intra-Household Modeling

    There is no good reason, however, to believe that the unitary AHMis a good representation of reality.

    In fact, evidence points to the fact it is not (Alderman et al., 1995).

    Manser and Brown (1980) and McElroy and Horney (1981)develop models of the household based on cooperative gametheory (i.e., bargaining within the household).

    In this case, resources are allocated efficiently, but the allocation isdetermined by threat points (i.e., the utility achieved by eachindividual in case of cooperation breakdown).

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    26/34

    Intra-Household Modeling

    Browning and Chiappori (1994), for their part, only assume that the

    intra-household allocation is efficient.

    If markets are complete, the households production decisions are

    not a function of its preferences or endowments (this should be

    familiar to you by now.)

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    27/34

    Intra-Household Modeling

    Browning and Chiapporis (1994) requirement that the households

    allocation efficient is much weaker than the requirements of the

    unitary AHM. Why is that?

    As a result, these efficient household models are more realistic

    and true to form than the unitary AHM.

    Additionally, it makes a lot of sense for a households allocation of

    resources to be efficient (but think of what could make the

    efficiency assumption not hold)

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    28/34

    Empirical Evidence on Intrahousehold Models

    Folbre (1984) originally asked why development microeconomists

    aggregate a number of individual preferences into a single utility

    function and offered a solid critique of the AHM.

    She then develops a conceptual framework with which to study

    households, based on four propositions.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    29/34

    Empirical Evidence on Intrahousehold Models

    1. Altruism coexists with conflicts over distribution of goods and

    leisure time

    2. Individual income shares are partly determined by bargaining

    power.

    3. The relative bargaining power of men, women, and children

    changes over the development process.

    4. Changes in bargaining power lead to changes in the distribution

    of goods and leisure time and affects the price of goods

    (including children) produced in the household.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    30/34

    Empirical Evidence on Intra-Household Models

    Thus, Folbres paper constitutes the first pass at empirically

    studying intra-household models.

    Her empirical results contradict the benevolent dictator argument

    put forth by Becker, by and large, and indicate that the unitary

    household model might not be the best way to model households.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    31/34

    Empirical Evidence on Intra-Household Models

    Similarly, Udry (1996) wishes to test the proposition that intra-household allocations are Pareto-efficient.

    After developing a relatively simple theoretical model, he proceedsto test empirically that gender has no effect on yields, i.e.,whether a man or a woman exploits a given plot, the yieldremains the same, ceteris paribus.

    Using data from Burkina Faso, he rejects the null hypothesis.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    32/34

    Empirical Evidence on Intra-Household Models

    At the end of the day, he estimates that the output loss due to this

    inefficiency is about 6%, i.e., households operate at about 94% of their

    efficient level. Contrast this with Carrs (2011) qualitative evidence to

    the contrary.

    The evidence is thus damningto say the leastboth for the AHM and

    the efficient household model.

    Still, those models are often retained in the literature in order to study

    microeconomic phenomena that are external to the household.

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    33/34

    Consequences for Policy

    If households do not behave in a unitary fashion, then transfer

    programs may not reach their intended recipients (e.g., food

    distribution programs and children).

    Depending on our goals, we may need a good understanding of how

    resources are allocated within the household (e.g., it is often

    preferable to give cash or food to women rather than men).

  • 7/29/2019 03. Household and Intrahousehold Models

    34/34

    Intrahousehold Allocation of Technology

    In Lee and Bellemare (2011), we wanted to know whether owning amobile phone was associated with increased prices for a cashcrop.

    Using data from a rural area of the Philippines, we find thathousehold mobile phone ownership is not associated with asignificant increase in the price of onions.

    When controlling for who owns the mobile phone within thehousehold, however, we find that mobile phone ownership by thefarmer or his spouse is associated with price increases, but notownership by the farmers children. It thus looks as though theintrahousehold allocation of technology may also matter.