accelerated equity offers: the role of internal and...

39
Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and External Certification Mechanisms Hardjo Koerniadi Auckland University of Technology Private Bag 92006, Auckland, New Zealand Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland Toowoomba, QLD 4350, Australia Sie Ting Lau Nanyang Technological University Singapore Alireza Tourani-Rad Auckland University of Technology Private Bag 92006, Auckland, New Zealand Ting Yang Auckland University of Technology Private Bag 92006, Auckland, New Zealand

Upload: doantuong

Post on 03-Jul-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and External Certification

Mechanisms

Hardjo Koerniadi

Auckland University of Technology

Private Bag 92006, Auckland, New Zealand

Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti

University of Southern Queensland

Toowoomba, QLD 4350, Australia

Sie Ting Lau

Nanyang Technological University

Singapore

Alireza Tourani-Rad

Auckland University of Technology

Private Bag 92006, Auckland, New Zealand

Ting Yang

Auckland University of Technology

Private Bag 92006, Auckland, New Zealand

Page 2: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

2

Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and External Certification

Mechanisms

Abstract

We examine the role of internal and external certification mechanisms in the issuance choice of

SEOs between accelerated offers and fully marketed offers. Our empirical work supports the

view that a firm’s internal corporate governance structure and audit fee are associated with the

issuance choice between accelerated and fully marketed offers. Furthermore, we find that after

controlling for the self-selection problem, firms paying higher audit fee incur lower flotation

costs as measured by gross spreads. Finally, we find a significant positive association between

audit fee and the net proceeds raised in SEOs.

JEL Classifications: G14, G24, G32

Keywords: Accelerated offers, seasoned equity, flotation costs, information asymmetry, due

diligence

Page 3: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

3

1. Introduction

In their seminal work, Myers and Majluf (1984) modelled the implications of information

asymmetry on issuing new stock. In their words:

If managers know more than the market does, firms should avoid situations in which

valuable investment projects have to be financed by stock issues. Having slack solves the

problem, and one way to get the slack is to issue stock when there is no asymmetric

information.

However, asymmetric information is always an issue and investment bankers conduct due

diligence before underwriting an issue to mitigate the problem. During the last 15 years,

accelerated bookbuilt offers have become a popular method for issuing seasoned equity offerings

(SEOs).1 Accelerated offers are typically completed in one day compared to 31 days between

filing to offer for fully marketed offers. This raises the question of how issuing firms deal with

asymmetric information while using accelerated offers method for issuing SEOs. We address this

issue by examining the role of certification in reducing the information asymmetry in the context

of issuance choice between accelerated offerings and fully marketed SEOs.

Gao and Ritter (2010) examine the choice between accelerated and fully marketed SEOs.

They also report that fully marketed offers pay higher average gross spreads than accelerated

offers. Furthermore, fully marketed offers are more underpriced compared to accelerated offers.2

Overall, fully marketed offers take longer to issue and incur higher transaction costs. This raises

the question as to why firms use the slower and more expensive method of issuing fully

marketed SEOs. Gao and Ritter (2010) posit that that firms use fully marketed issues when faced

with relatively more inelastic demand curve for their stocks. Autore et al. (2011) suggest that

lower quality issuers prefer accelerated offerings to avoid rigorous pre-issue scrutiny by

1 Gao and Ritter (2010)

2 However, accelerated offers have slightly larger discount and experience slightly more negative stock price

reaction than fully marketed offers.

Page 4: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

4

investment bankers. On closer analysis, it appears that only one of the seven information

asymmetry variables considered by them is significantly associated with the choice of using

accelerated offers as opposed to fully marketed offers3. Therefore, we consider the evidence,

regarding the influence of the quality of issuing firm on issuance choice between fully marketed

and accelerated offers, presented in Autore et al. (2011) to be inconclusive. Hence, in this paper

we examine the role of firm quality proxies, such as their internal and external certification

mechanisms on the issuance choice between accelerated offers and fully marketed offers.

Although accelerated offers are advantageous in terms of speed of issuance and

transaction costs from the perspective of issuers, they pose additional challenges to investment

bankers. First, it increases the competition faced by investment bankers thereby reducing the

underwriting fee charged by them in accelerated SEO offerings.4 Second, accelerated offerings

place additional pressures on investment bankers in performing their due diligence

investigations. The reduced time available for conducting due diligence activities could

potentially increase the cost of such investigations. Alternately, the time constraint imposed by

the accelerated method could necessitate an upper limit on the extent of due diligence

evaluations that can be accomplished by investment bankers5. Although documented due

diligence cases are relatively rare, when they do occur, investment bankers tend to take a

substantial hit. For example, in the case of WorldCom, which conducted two speedy shelf offers,

investors sued underwriters for negligence and Citigroup, one of the firms that sold WorldCom

bonds paid $2.65 billion in settlement6. There is no evidence to indicate that investors or judges

3 Further, as these results are untabulated, we are unable to assess the strength of this relationship.

4 Please see Bortolotti et al. (2008) for empirical evidence (Table 3).

5 These arguments were advanced by Sherman (1999) in the context of shelf offerings. They apply with equal if not

greater force in the case of accelerated offerings. 6 See Morgenson (2004) for further details.

Page 5: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

5

take a more lenient view of due diligence standards for accelerated offerings compared to fully

marketed offers (Morgenson, 2004).

How do investment bankers cope with the challenge of time pressures in conducting due

diligence of accelerated offerings? What can issuing firm managers do to mitigate the difficulties

faced by investment bankers? There is as yet no work on this issue. We contribute to the

literature by examining the importance of potential alternate certification mechanisms that firms

can use in the context of accelerated SEOs.

We suggest that firms can potentially use an internal certification mechanism such as

their corporate governance structure to diminish the role of due diligence activities performed by

investment bankers. We construct a firm’s internal corporate governance score using raw data

on a firm’s reported corporate governance practices and use this as our proxy of internal

certification quality. We posit that firms with better quality internal governance are more likely

to choose accelerated offerings while making SEOs.

We also propose that firms can use external certification mechanisms such as the

purchase of high quality audit services to mitigate the importance of due diligence investigations

by underwriters. We postulate that firms may use audit fee as an external certification

mechanism to reduce the information asymmetry between managers of issuing firms and

potential investors with investment bankers mediating between them. We therefore suggest that

firms which pay higher audit fees are more likely to choose accelerated offerings while making

SEOs.

Our empirical work suggests that these internal and external certification mechanisms

perform three significant roles in the issuance of SEOs. First, by reducing information

asymmetry, certification mechanisms influence the choice between accelerated offerings and

Page 6: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

6

fully marketed offers. Second, we find that certification mechanisms help to reduce the issuance

costs as measured by gross spread. Finally, we find that there is an association between the

efficacy of certification and the net proceeds of SEO issuance.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we provide the

theoretical underpinnings for our empirical tests and develop the hypotheses. In section 3, we

describe the data sources, our sample selection procedures, and the characteristics of our sample.

In section 4, we report our empirical results, discuss the implications, and report results from

robustness checks. Our concluding comments are offered in section 5.

2. Theoretical Underpinnings

2.1 Shelf Registration and Underwriter Certification

The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) adopted Rule 415, also known as shelf

registration, which allowed large firms to register the total amount of securities it wishes to sell

over the subsequent two year period and sell portions of them whenever it chooses. This rule

became effective from November 1983. The SEC stipulated that companies that wish to register

their offerings under Rule 415 must satisfy the following conditions: (i) the aggregate market

value of the firm’s outstanding shares and unaffiliated voting stock should be greater than $150

million; (ii) the firm should not have defaulted on its preferred stock, debt, or rental obligations

in the last three years; (iii) the firm should have met all the disclosure requirements of the

Securities Exchange Act of 1934 during the last three years; and (iv) the firm’s bonds should

have investment grade rating.

Some researchers (see Bhagat et al., 1985; Kadapakkam and Kon, 1989 among others)

argue that shelf offerings hold several benefits for issuing firms. First, Bhagat et al. (1985)

contend that shelf offerings enable the issuer to time the offering dates to take advantage of

Page 7: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

7

favourable market conditions. By aligning the issuance with demand for its shares, issuers would

be able to sell their equity at better prices. Second, the shelf offering process may intensify

competition between underwriters thereby lowering the issuance costs. Finally, shelf offerings

may lower the fixed costs associated with the SEC registration. Under traditional registration

process, there are large fixed cost components due to the SEC registration requirements. With a

shelf registration, the fixed costs of an offering are substantially reduced since it does not require

the preparation or distribution of detailed prospectuses. Empirical evidence supporting the view

that issuance costs are lower for shelf offerings is provided by Bhagat et al. (1985) and more

recently by Autore et al. (2008).

Investors interested in purchasing newly issued equity securities face an adverse selection

problem since managers have privileged access to information that outsiders do not have.

Therefore managers have incentives to issue new shares when the market overvalues them.

Typically, the market price of shares falls when a firm announces a new seasoned equity issue.

In this context, underwriters provide a valuable service by certifying the validity of the current

market price. Underwriters have incentives to correctly price each issue in order to preserve their

reputation.

Shelf registration exacerbates the information asymmetry problem faced by investors.

When a firm utilizes Rule 415, it is not obligated to appoint an underwriter until the date of

offering. In reality, once a shelf registration has been filed, investment bankers make competitive

bids for the issue. Investment bankers have incentives to charge lower fees in order to win the bid

while facing two impediments in performing their due diligence investigations. First, since there

is no guarantee that a given investment banking firm will be chosen to underwrite the offering, it

has no incentives to incur the costs of investigating the firm. Second, the investment banker will

Page 8: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

8

have little time to conduct the due diligence investigation. This is because oftentimes an

underwriter is chosen on the same day that the offering is completed. Denis (1991) attributes

impediments to underwriter certification as the major factor behind the steep decline in shelf

offerings of industrial firms during the years 1984-1988.

However, more recently, Autore et al. (2008) document a resurgence in shelf offerings

during 1990-2003. They acknowledge the difficulties faced by investment bankers in conducting

due diligence of firms that use shelf registration. They suggest that firms that use shelf

registration mitigate the under-certification problem by using shelf offerings during periods

when there is less need for underwriter certification. These include periods following low

abnormal stock price runups, and after prior certification in previous seasoned offerings.

2.2 Accelerated Offers

Shelf offerings may be further classified into accelerated and traditional bookbuilt offers

based on the speed of issuance. Accelerated offerings may be completed quickly. There are two

types of accelerated offers – bought deals and accelerated bookbuilt offers. In a bought deal, the

issuing firm announces the amount of stock it wishes to sell and underwriters bid for these

shares. The underwriter that offers the highest net price wins the deal. The winning underwriter

typically resells the shares to institutional investors within the following 24 hours. Essentially,

bought deals are auctions to underwriters followed by open market sales. In accelerated

bookbuilt offers, investment banks submit proposals specifying a gross spread, but not

necessarily the offer price, for the right to underwrite the shares. The winning bank then forms a

syndicate and markets the shares to institutional investors.

Gao and Ritter (2010) examine the factors that determine issuing firms’ choice of using

accelerated offerings versus traditional fully marketed offerings. They find that accelerated

Page 9: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

9

bookbuilt offerings are typically completed in a single day while fully marketed SEOs take, on

average, 31 days to complete. Also, accelerated offers have lower gross spreads than fully

marketed offers. Accelerated offers further have lower underpricing compared to fully marketed

offers.

From the underwriter’s point of view, in an accelerated offer, there is no time to conduct

an accurate due diligence analysis. Typically, there is far less information gathering and

marketing effort required from underwriters for accelerated offers. In order to win the deal in a

timely manner, the underwriter must quickly assess the market demand before committing an

offer price. Thus, only the largest and most capital intensive underwriters conduct accelerated

offers. The underwriting syndicates are smaller, take much more risk and generate comparable

revenues over shorter periods and effectively “buy” market share and league table rankings. For

the underwriters, insufficient due diligence raises the possibility of increased legal liabilities.

For example, in the case of WorldCom, which conducted two speedy shelf offers, investors sued

underwriters for negligence and were paid over $6 billion in settlement. (Schor, 2006)

Taken together, it appears that issuing firms will benefit significantly from using

accelerated offers rather than fully marketed offers. This raises an important issue. If accelerated

offers are highly beneficial compared to fully marketed offers, then why do issuing firms

continue to use the slower and more expensive method of issuing SEOs? Gao and Ritter (2010)

find evidence consistent with the view that issuing firms that have a more inelastic demand curve

for its shares tend to use fully marketed offers. Also firms making larger size issues use a fully

marketed offer.

2.3 Certification Mechanisms

Page 10: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

10

In this paper, we utilize two certification mechanisms. First, we score a firm’s internal

corporate governance features and consider this as an internal certification device. Second, we

use audit fee paid by the firm as the second certification mechanism. The audit fee paid by a frim

can be considered as an external certification mechanism.

2.3.1 Internal Corporate Governance

Prior literature on the impact of a firm’s internal corporate governance on its valuation,

informativeness of stock prices, and liquidity motivates our selection of internal corporate

governance as a suitable certification mechanism for firms issuing SEOs. Durnev and Kim

(2005) hypothesize that firms with high quality governance are valued higher due to better

investor protection. Their empirical evidence is based on cross-country firm-level governance

data from 27 countries.

Ferreira and Laux (2007) argue that the absence of antitakeover provisions creates

incentives for private information collection. Their rationale follows Grossman and Stiglitz

(1980), who predict that enhancing the cost-benefit trade-off on information collection facilitates

more informed trading and more informative pricing. Furthermore, strong investor protection,

articulated by openness to takeovers is associated with a diminished likelihood of investors

expropriating outside investors. Therefore openness to takeovers has the potential to foster

uninformed ownership and trading, thereby offering more cover for privately informed trading.

Ferreira and Laux (2007) find strong supportive evidence linking a firm’s antitakeover

provisions to its informativeness as measured by idiosyncratic volatility. The more restrictive are

a firm’s antitakeover provisions the less informative is its stock price.

Further evidence on the link between a firm’s internal corporate governance and stock

market liquidity is provided by Chung et al. (2010). They conjecture that corporate governance

Page 11: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

11

affects stock market liquidity because effective governance increases financial and operational

transparency which reduces informational asymmetries between insiders and outsiders. Further,

they posit that governance provisions could potentially improve financial transparency by

mitigating management’s ability and incentives to distort information disclosures. Specific

governance features could preclude managers from acting in their self-interest. Features such as

the use of independent audit committees serve to improve the quality of financial statements.7

Corporate governance features may also improve operational transparency by increasing the

ability of shareholders to discern the quality of management and the actual value of the firm.

Governance provisions strengthen the disciplinary threat of removing the management and

therefore limit the extent to which management can expropriate firm value through shirking,

empire building, overconsumption of perquisites, and risk aversion.8 Summing up, prior

literature provides abundant evidence that a firm’s internal corporate governance improves the

information environment of a firm and thereby reduces the information asymmetry between

insiders and outsiders.

2.3.2 Audit Fee

Both policy makers and academicians believe that the audit fee paid by a firm is

positively associated with the quality of financial reporting. In the words of Lynn Turner, former

chief accountant at the Securities and Exchange Commission:

7 See also Leuz et al. (2003), Ajinkya et al. (2005) and Karamanou and Vafeas (2005).

8 See also Babchuk and Cohen (2005) and Bebchuk et al. (2009).

Page 12: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

12

Certainly throughout the 1980s and 1990s, corporations, sometimes with the

assistance of their audit committees, “twisted” the arms of independent auditors to

reduce their audit fees. Our experience includes corporations who competitively

bid their independent audit work solely to reduce their fees below levels that could

generate a reasonable return for their auditors. In turn, the audit firms reduced the

level of work they needed to perform in their role as gatekeepers for investors.

Inevitably inferior audits resulted.9

Empirical evidence in support of the view that lower audit fees are associated with lower audit

quality is provided by Blankley et al. (2012) who found that auditors of restatement firms charge

lower fees in the years prior to the announcement of restatements.

Ball et al. (2012) posit that managers seeking to disseminate private information need a

mechanism for credibly committing to be truthful. They propose that committing to the provision

of high quality audited financial statements is a potentially effective mechanism. Therefore, they

use the amount of excess audit fees paid by a firm as the proxy for the level of its financial

statement verification. They consider that audit service is a differentiated product that permits

clients to choose their auditor and several aspects of audit quality and effort.

Furthermore, audit fees are affected by the choice of audit firm (Big 4 versus others), the

level of seniority of the audit engagement partner, the number and hourly rate of audit personnel

deployed for the job, the degree of verification sought by the firm, and the frequency of

communication with the audit committee and other key executives. Audit fees are directly linked

to the level and price of audit activity and therefore to the degree of independent verification of

financial reporting.10

2.4 Hypotheses

Issuance Choice

We argue that a firm’s internal corporate governance arrangement could serve as a

potential certification device. Thus firms with high quality internal governance mechanisms may

9 See Turner (2005).

10 See also Simunic (1980) and Watts and Zimmerman (1983).

Page 13: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

13

reduce the extent of due diligence performed by underwriters. Given the benefits of shelf

offerings as compared to non-shelf offerings, good governance firms will choose shelf offerings

over non-shelf offerings. Given our arguments in the previous subsection, we postulate that the

audit fee paid by a firm will serve as an external certification mechanism. We thus posit the

following hypothesis:

H1: Firms with better certification quality are more likely to choose shelf offerings while making

SEOs, other things being equal.

Given the risky nature of the accelerated offer method, it makes sense for underwriters to

use a certification device before accepting a deal. We suggest that firms may use their internal

corporate governance structure and/or audit fee as a potential certification device. In order to

protect their reputation and lower their risk, investment bankers will prefer to underwrite offers

made by high quality firms that certify their quality through internal corporate governance

structure and / or audit fee. Thus we posit:

H2: Firms with better certification quality are more likely to choose accelerated offerings while

making SEO, other things being equal.

Flotation Costs

A key variable of interest is flotation cost. When underwriters bid for an SEO issue, they

are compensated for their risk-bearing and marketing services. Underwriters typically buy an

SEO from the issuers at an offer price discount which is their compensation. In investment

banking parlance, this compensation is called the gross spread. The main components of gross

spread are a) management fee, b) underwriting fee and c) selling concession (see, Lee and

Masulis 2009). Typically, gross spread is scaled by offer price and expressed as a percentage.

Since gross spread includes a compensation for risk, it stands to reason that less risky firms

Page 14: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

14

would have lower gross spreads. Also, a firm’s internal corporate governance setup is an

indicator of agency risks faced by the underwriter. Thus well-governed firms are expected to pay

lower gross spreads as compared to poorly governed firms. Audit fee is an external certification

device and firms paying higher audit fee are purchasing higher quality verification and

authentication services to ensure their financial reporting quality. We therefore expect that firms

paying higher audit fee will enjoy lower flotation costs as investment bankers are likely to be

cognizant of this aspect of a firm while conducting its SEO. We thus posit:

H3: Firms with better certification quality will have lower gross spreads while making SEOs,

other things being equal.

Net Proceeds

The net proceeds of an offer (offer size) could potentially be affected by asymmetric

information. Following the arguments of Myers and Majluf (1984), greater information

asymmetry increases the incentives of mangers to time equity offerings when their stock is

overvalued. This could lead to a negative relation between corporate governance quality and

issue proceeds. Alternately, underwriters could be reluctant to manage large issues of firms with

poor quality. This could lead to a positive relation between the quality of certification (internal

corporate governance or audit fee) and issue size. We prefer the second position as investment

bankers would recognise the risk to their reputation and would be cautious when they suspect

that the firm is overvalued or is of lower quality. We therefore posit:

H4: Firms with better certification quality will raise larger net proceeds while making SEOs,

other things being equal.

Page 15: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

15

3. Data, Sample, and Measures of Governance Quality

3.1 Data and Sample Selection

In this paper, we rely on four sources of data. Equity issuance data are from Thomson Reuter’s

SDC database, raw corporate governance data are obtained from RiskMetrics11

, and accounting

data are extracted from Osiris database maintained by Bureau van Dijk. Finally, audit fee data is

sourced from Audit Analytics database. The sample selection process is detailed as follows. We

first merge all the equity issuances in the US market during 2001 through 2007 with annual

corporate governance data from RiskMetrics. Excluding all the equity issues made by firms

without corporate governance data, resulting in 5,751 issues. After issuances by firms in the

financial industry are further deleted, there are 5,225 issues.12

We then match these issues with

accounting data from Osiris. There are 3,933 issues by firms who have a record in Osiris.

Because we run three separate groups of regressions using three different dependent variables (a

dummy variable indicating shelf offers, a dummy variable for accelerated offers, and the gross

spread as a measure of flotation costs), to maximize the number of observations, we use three

different samples. All these three samples are obtained from the 3,933 issues and formed by

further requiring that data be available for all variables used in our regressions and that all issues

be secondary issues (IPOs and rights offers are excluded). The first sample, shelf offers sample,

has 1,250 issues, and is used to run regressions with the dummy, shelf (one for shelf-registration

and zero otherwise), as the dependent variable. The second sample, accelerated offers sample,

has 1,201 issues, and is used to run regressions using the dummy, accelerated (it equals one if the

11

We compile composite corporate governance measures used in our regressions (G1, G2, G3, G4, and CGI4) from

these raw data. 12

Based on SDC definition of industry, the following industries are excluded: commercial bank, credit institution,

insurance, investment bank, investment fund, other finance, and S&L/thrift.

Page 16: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

16

issue is an accelerated issue and zero otherwise), as the dependent variable. The third sample,

gross spread sample, has 1,040 issues, and is the sample used to run regressions with gross

spread as the dependent variable.13

3.2 Firm Level Corporate Governance Quality

Our primary source of data on corporate governance aspects is from the RiskMetrics Corporate

Governance database. We first describe the sample of firms covered by the database provided by

Institutional Shareholder Services (ISS) of RiskMetrics. For each firm, for each governance

feature, RiskMetrics provides information regarding compliance or its absence. Next, we use

this information and based on best practices, we score each firm on each governance attribute

and construct our own governance ratings, aggregating these attributes. Our choice of this data

source is driven by its widespread use in academic work (Brown and Caylor, 2006; Chung et al.,

2010; Aggarwal et al., 2011).

RiskMetrics provides firm level Corporate Governance Quotient (CGQ) for companies from

2001. The CGQ rankings are designed to measure a firm’s internal governance as represented by

its adoption of governance attributes that increase the power of its minority shareholders. ISS

reports CGQ_Industry (hereafter IndustryCGQ) which gives a firm’s percentile ranking within

its GICS industry group In order to compute these indices, ISS collects information on a set of

governance attributes for a large number of companies. In this paper, we use corporate

governance data for the 2001-2007 period.

13

We use these three samples to run regressions that examine the determinants of issue methods and flotation costs.

For the sake of brevity and exposition, we rely on the largest sample, the shelf offers sample, to describe sample

summary statistics (Table 1), correlations between key variables of interest (Table 2), and univariate analysis (Table

3).

Page 17: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

17

ISS compiles fifty-five governance attributes for each firm. A firm’s performance on each

attribute is determined by examining its regulatory filings, website and annual reports. Firms do

not pay to get rated but are allowed to access their ratings and verify the accuracy of ratings.

Firms can only change their ratings by altering the governance structure and publicly disclosing

it. ISS scores each firm on each attribute depending on whether it meets a threshold level of

acceptability. The fifty five attributes cover four broad categories: board composition and

effectiveness, anti-takeover provisions, compensation and ownership, and audit practices. The

board component of governance encapsulates the aspects of functioning of the board of directors

pertaining to board independence, size, composition of committees, transparency and the conduct

of work. Anti-takeover provisions include the firm’s charter and bylaws, dual-class structure,

role of shareholders, poison pill, and blank check preferred. The compensation and ownership

component deals with executive and director compensation issues, options, stock ownership and

loans. The audit component captures the independence of audit committee and the role of

auditors. Appendix A contains a list of the variables used and the acceptable standards used in

the scoring.

The rating provided by ISS (that is, IndustryCGQ) evaluates the strength, deficiencies, and

overall quality of a company’s corporate governance practices and is designed on the premise

that good corporate governance ultimately results in increased shareholder value. The exact

weighting of the different features of governance in computing the index is not available to us.

Also, ISS claims that CGQ is a “reliable tool for identifying portfolio risk related to governance

and leverages governance to drive increased shareholder value”. However, in addition to the

index scores provided by ISS, we also construct our own index using the raw data provided to us

Page 18: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

18

by RiskMetrics. A clear benefit of constructing our own governance indicator is that we are able

to capture a wide variety of governance features employed by firms.

We create our own governance rating based on the raw data provided by ISS. The

overall score (CGI4) is the sum of the ratings for the four categories of governance practices

mentioned above. The first corporate governance rating, G1, represents board composition and

effectiveness. G2 is the rating that measures anti-takeover defences. G3 is the governance score

that measures managerial compensation and incentives. G4 is the rating that measures the

strength of audit practices. We score each firm based on whether or not it meets the threshold of

good governance for each attribute. Based on this binary coding of each attribute, we first

compute the G1, G2, G3, and G4 scores and then aggregate them to arrive at the overall score for

each firm, CGI4. In our study, we use G1, G2, G3, and G4 to pinpoint the specific governance

mechanisms that are at work. We also use CGI4, and IndustryCGQ, as proxies for the overall

governance quality.

3.3 External Certification

We argue that the certification of an issuer’s quality should be made by players in the equity

issue process, that is, by the issue firm (self-certification), or its underwriters, auditors, or

potential investors interested in the shares issued. Based on this reasoning, we use natural

logarithm of a firm’s total audit fee as a proxy for the certification from its auditors based on the

premise that higher audit fee indicates more effort and work done by the auditors and hence

Page 19: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

19

stronger certification.14

Following Coulton et al. (2012), we use three-year average audit fees to

proxy for external certification.

3.4 Sample Characteristics

Table 1 provides descriptive statistics of the key variables used in this study.

Approximately 64% of the sample equity issues are shelf-registered offers, which is consistent

with the finding in Autore et.al (2008) that there has been a significant revival in the use of shelf

offering since the 1990s. A substantial portion, about 40%, of the sample issues are accelerated

offers.15

This confirms what Gao and Ritter (2010) point out that accelerated offers have gained

increasing popularity during the last decade. The average issue cost for our sample is around

4.3% of the total proceeds. Our four governance components ratings (G1 to G4) are all scaled to

have a maximum possible rating of 0.25, and hence the highest possible value for the overall

rating CGI4 is 1. IndustryCGQ, as discussed before, is the percentile ranking assigned by

RiskMetrics, and therefore have the maximum value of 100. Table 1 indicates that both our four

governance components ratings (G1 to G4) and the two overall governance ratings (CGI4,

IndustryCGQ) show a fair amount of variation across the sample firms.

In addition to the frequency of issue methods, issue costs, and governance quality, we

also provide other firm and issue characteristics that we think may affect firms’ choice of issue

methods and their respective costs. In terms of firm characteristics, an average sample firm has

net sales (used as a proxy for firm size) of US $1.35 billion. A median sample firm generates

about 5% earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT) from its total assets, experiences around 18%

14

Another proxy is the identity of the auditor, e.g., whether the auditor is one of the Big 5 accounting firms.

However, only less than 8% of our observations do not have a Big-5 auditor. We therefore do not include it in the

regressions. 15

The portion of accelerated offers in our sample is comparable to that in Gao and Ritter (2010) (42%) and Autore

et al. (2011) (43%).

Page 20: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

20

growth in sales, and has a long-term debt to assets ratio of 0.28.16

Regarding issue

characteristics, an average sample equity issue raises US $ 171 million. Approximately 75% of

the shares issued are primary shares. In about 45% of the issues, stocks are listed on Nasdaq.

4. Empirical Results

4.1 Preliminary Results

In order to obtain a preliminary understanding between the relation between the quality of

the firm corporate governance and the decision to issue SEO using shelf/ accelerated methods,

we calculate the correlation coefficients between dummy variables for shelf and accelerated,

gross spread and several proxies for governance quality ratings. We present the coefficients and

the p-values for the test of significance in Table 2. The table shows that the choice of shelf offer

and the choice of accelerated offer are both positively correlated with all the governance quality

ratings except for G2 (anti-takeover). Further, the issue costs, as measured by gross spread, are

negatively correlated with all the governance quality ratings except for G2. All the reported

correlations are highly statistically significant. These findings are generally consistent with our

hypotheses that firms with better governance quality are more likely to use shelf-registered or

accelerated offers, and they enjoy lower financing costs. The only exception being the

correlation between G2 (the anti-takeover measure) and issue methods and issue costs that do not

show the expected sign. Another key finding reported in Table 2 is that issue costs are

significantly negatively correlated with shelf and accelerated offers. This is consistent with

Bhagat et al. (1985), who find that stocks sold through shelf offerings incur lower issue costs

than those sold through regular (non-shelf) offerings. Ours results are also consistent with Gao

16

We focus on the medians for accounting measures, because they are less affected by outliers.

Page 21: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

21

and Ritter (2010) who report untabulated results indicating that gross spreads are lower for firms

making accelerated offers.

We then take a step further by utilizing our panel data and sorting all sample issues into

quintiles by our overall governance rating, CGI4. We examine the choice of issue methods, issue

costs, and other important firm and issue characteristics for each of the 5 portfolios (quintiles)

and report our results in Table 3. Panel A shows that as we move from Quintile 1, which contains

firms with the lowest governance quality, to Quintile 5, which contains firms with the highest

governance quality, there is a strict monotonicity in the frequency of shelf offers and accelerated

offers, as well as in the magnitude of issue costs. For instance, only 25.6% of firms in the lowest

governance quality quintile use accelerated offers increasing to 51.7% of firms in the highest

governance quality quintile. These findings provide initial support for hypothesis H2. Except for

firm size, which increases with governance quality, all the other firm and issue characteristics do

not show any clearly discernible patterns across governance quintiles.

We then formally test the significance of the monotonicity found in Panel A of Table 3.

In Panel B of Table 3, we calculate the difference in the frequency of shelf and accelerate offers

and in the issue costs between every 2 consecutive governance quintiles, and test the significance

of the differences. Panel B shows that all the differences in the frequency of shelf offers across

consecutive governance quintiles are statistically and economically significant. For example,

approximately 13% more equity issues are offered through shelf registration when we compare

Quintile 4 with Quintile 3. The differences in the frequency of accelerated offers demonstrate

very similar pattern, though the increase in the use of accelerated offering from Quintile 4 to

Quintile 5 firms is not statistically significant. As for the issue costs, the differences have the

expected sign, two of which are statistically significant. Overall, our univariate analyses as

Page 22: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

22

reported in Table 3 support our hypotheses: firms with better governance quality are more likely

to conduct shelf or accelerated offers, and they also enjoy lower issue costs.

4.2 Regression Results

In this subsection, we investigate the relation between equity offer methods, issue costs, and

certification mechanisms controlling for firm and issue characteristics that may affect issue

methods. First, we examine the determinants of equity offer method by running the following

panel logit regressions:

titiproxiesioncertificat

tiNasdaq

tiprimary

tisizeissue

tileverage

tigrowth

tiROA

tiMarketCap

tidaccelerateor

tishelf

,,8,7,6,5

,4,3,2,1)

,(

,

(1)

The dependent variables are shelf and accelerated which are dummy variables that take the value

of one if an issue is shelf registered or accelerated offer, respectively, and zero otherwise. Firm

size is measured as the natural logarithm of net sales in thousands of US dollars at the last

financial year end before an offering17

. ROA is earnings before interest and taxes scaled by total

assets at the fiscal year end before an equity offering. Growth is the growth rate of net sales

during the year of the equity offering. Leverage is total long-term debt divided by total assets at

the financial year end before an equity offering. Issue size is the natural logarithm of the offer

proceeds in thousands of US dollars. Primary is the proportion of primary shares in the total

shares offered. Nasdaq is a dummy variable that equals one if a firm is listed on Nasdaq and zero

otherwise. The internal certification proxies included are each of the four governance component

ratings and the overall governance quality ranking. We use audit fee as an external certification

proxy. In order to ensure that our results are not distorted by outliers, we winsorize all variables

17

We also used alternate proxies for firm size such as total assets and market capitalization.

Page 23: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

23

except for the dummies at the 1st and the 99

th percentiles. We also estimate the standard errors

through bootstrapping using 200 replications.

Table 4 presents the panel logit regression results for the determinants of shelf-registered

offerings. Our focus is on the relation between shelf offerings and certification mechanisms such

as internal governance quality. We find that all the governance quality ratings except for G2

(anti-takeover) are significantly positively related to the likelihood of a shelf offering. This is

consistent with the univariate results in Table 3 and supports our first hypothesis (H1), that is,

firms with better internal governance quality are more likely to use shelf-registered offerings

when conducting SEOs. Audit fee, our proxy for external certification, is highly positively

associated with the choice of using shelf registration. We also find that firms with higher

financial leverage and offerings which include a higher proportion of primary shares are more

likely to use shelf registered offerings. This indicates that firms utilizing shelf offerings are those

facing tighter financial conditions and having a greater need for external financing (Heron and

Lie, 2004). In addition, Nasdaq firms tend to use shelf offerings less often. To the extent that

Nasdaq firms are typically of higher risk and potentially more difficult to value, this finding

suggests that firms for whom certification by underwriters is more important rely less on shelf

offerings. We also find that larger firms are more likely to use shelf offerings. There is a negative

relationship between issue size and the choice of shelf registration. Firms raising higher proceeds

tend not to use shelf registration.

Results from panel logit regression analyses of the determinants of accelerated offerings

are reported in Table 5. The probability of conducting an accelerated offer increases with a

firm’s governance quality, which is evidenced by the positive and significant coefficient

estimates for all governance ratings except G2. Audit fee, the external certification proxy, is

Page 24: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

24

significantly positively associated with the choice of accelerated offerings in four of the six

models used. This supports our second hypothesis (H2). We also find that larger firms are more

likely to use accelerated offering, which is consistent with Gao and Ritter (2010). Firms with

higher return on assets (ROA) are less likely to use accelerated offerings. The negative

relationship between ROA and the decision to use accelerated offering method is consistent with

the recommendation of Myers and Majluf (1984) who suggest that firms should build up a slack

when conditions are favourable. The positive coefficient estimate for leverage suggests that a

firm’s preference for an accelerated offering may be driven by its tight financial situation. We

also find that firms raising a larger amount of capital or listed on Nasdaq are less likely to use

accelerated offering. This is in line with the finding of Gao and Ritter (2010), as the marketing

service provided by underwriters during a traditional bookbuilt offer is more valuable for such

firms, they tend to use accelerated offerings less often.

In order to perform rigorous tests for the potential impact of certification quality on gross

spreads we need to control for the possibility of self-selection bias. Firms which self-select the

accelerated offerings methods for SEOs may have intrinsic qualities that may also affect the

gross spread. Li and Prabhala (2005) describe in detail the self-selection models commonly used

in corporate finance and provide the rationale for using them. Following Lee and Masulis (2009)

and Bethel and Krigman (2008), we examine the determinants of gross spreads paid by

estimating a Heckman two-stage model to control for the potential selection bias implicit in firms

choosing the accelerated method. The first stage logit estimation uses Model 5 of Table 5. Our

second stage estimation uses gross spread as the dependent variable in the following model:

titiproxiesioncertificat

tiimary

tiLeverage

tiGrowth

tiROA

tiMarketcap

tidGrosssprea

,,6,Pr

5

,4,3,2,1,

Page 25: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

25

We control for firm size, ROA, leverage, growth and primary offerings. Finally, we include

lambda, the inverse mills ratio calculated by the first stage logit model, which is the predicted

probability that a firm uses accelerated method.

Our results are shown in Table 6. We find that after controlling for self-selection, that a

firm’s internal corporate governance has a weak effect on gross spread. However, audit fee, our

external certification variable, has a significant negative effect on gross spread. The panel

regression results show that firms which are more profitable enjoy significantly lower issue

costs. We also find that firms that sell a higher proportion of primary shares bear higher issue

costs, which may be because they require more marketing efforts from the underwriters. Our

empirical results support our third hypothesis (H3). We find that lambda has a reliable positive

impact on gross spread. This finding implies that the decision to select accelerate offerings

method has a positive impact on gross spread after controlling for the self-selection problem.

We investigate the determinants of net proceeds by estimating a Heckman two-stage

model to control for the potential selection bias implicit in firms choosing the accelerated

method. The first stage logit estimation uses Model 5 of Table 5. Our second stage estimation

uses net proceeds (issue size) as the dependent variable in the following model:

titiproxiesioncertificat

tiimary

tiLeverage

tiGrowth

tiROA

tiMarketcap

tisNetproceed

,,6,Pr

5

,4,3,2,1,

We control for firm size, ROA, leverage, growth and primary offerings. Finally, we include

lambda, the inverse mills ratio calculated by the first stage logit model, which is the predicted

probability that a firm uses accelerated method.

Our empirical results, which are reported in Table 7, indicate strong empirical support for

a positive relation between external certification and issue size. Audit fee is strongly positively

Page 26: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

26

associated with net proceeds. Thus firms which face a smaller adverse selection risk are able to

make larger size SEO issues. Internal certification mechanism as proxied by good quality

corporate governance has a weak effect on net proceeds. Firms which have higher ROA are able

to raise more issue proceeds consistent with the view that the market and investment bankers are

less concerned about the misuse of free cash flows when firms have a good track record of

profitability. Market capitalization has a significant positive impact on net proceeds implying

that large firms suffer less from information asymmetry and are therefore able to raise more

money from SEOs. The coefficient of lambda is positive and significant at the one per cent level

indicating that even after controlling for firm characteristics that drive the choice of accelerated

offerings, firms using accelerated offerings raise higher proceeds than firms using non-

accelerated methods. Our empirical evidence supports our fourth hypothesis (H4).

Overall, our results show that both internal and certification devices play a role in

affecting key aspects of a firm’s SEO issuance. Both certification methods (internal and external)

influence the choice of registration method (shelf versus non-shelf) and issuance method

(accelerated versus non-accelerated). However, only the external certification device (audit fee)

is associated significantly with flotation costs and issue size. This evidence suggests that

investment bankers lend greater credibility to external certification provided by audit fee in

setting their gross spread and issue size.

4.3 Robustness Checks

We check the robustness of our empirical findings in two ways. First, we use alternate

proxies for certification. For internal certification, we use Industry CGQ as an alternate proxy.

Our results reported in Tables 4 through 7 show that we get qualitatively similar results in

issuance choice, issuance cost and issuance size models. As an alternate proxy for external

Page 27: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

27

certification (the certification by potential investors), we compare the file offer price with the

initial offer price range and use two dummy variables, below range and above range, to capture

the situations where the final offer price is below or above the initial range, respectively.

Because the difference between the final offer price and the initial price range reflects the

deviation of the potential investors’ assessment of the equity offering from the issuer’s own

assessment, we argue that the larger the difference is, the weaker is the certification from

potential investors. Our empirical evidence supports the validity of this alternate certification

proxy in issuance choice models reported in Tables 4 and 5.

Second, we use alternate proxies for firm size. We use net sales, total assets, and market

capitalization to proxy for size in our tests. Our empirical results are qualitatively similar. We do

not tabulate these results in order to conserve space.

5. Conclusions

Recent work has documented the increased use of accelerated offers in SEOs in the US.

For issuers, the reduction in time taken to issue and the lower issuance costs in the accelerated

offers method compared to fully marketed offers are attractive features. However, the issuance

of new capital via SEOs is fraught with the information asymmetry problem between issuers and

investors. Underwriters typically use due diligence to reduce information asymmetry in order to

sell the issue to potential investors. The reduction in issuance time in accelerated offers affects

the conduct of due diligence. How do high quality issuers differentiate themselves from low

quality issuers in order to issue equity via accelerated offers?

We contribute to the emerging literature by examining this crucial issue. Given the fact

that firms have been paying increasing attention to corporate governance over the last two

decades, we hypothesize that internal corporate governance may serve as a certification device

Page 28: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

28

and allow issuers with strong governance to overcome the under certification problem and take

advantage of shelf and accelerated offerings. We also posit that an external certification

mechanism such as the audit fee paid by the firm may provide a credible means of overcoming

the under certification problem in the context of SEO issuance.We postulate that firms may use

internal and external certification mechanisms to signal lower asymmetry.

Our empirical results confirm our conjecture and indicate that firms with higher

certification quality are more likely to use the accelerated offers method while issuing SEOs.

Using a panel dataset of US SEOs, we find evidence suggesting that these internal and external

certification mechanisms perform three significant roles in the issuance of SEOs. First, by

reducing information asymmetry, certification mechanisms influence the choice between

accelerated offerings and fully marketed offers. Second, we find that certification mechanisms

help to reduce the issuance costs as measured by gross spread. Finally, we find that there exists

an association between the efficacy of certification and the net proceeds of SEO issuance. Our

paper contributes to the securities issuance and corporate governance literature by proposing a

linkage between governance quality and the choice of securities issue techniques and providing

empirical evidence that supports the existence of the linkage.

Page 29: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

29

References

Aggarwal, R., Erel, I., Ferreira, M., Matos, P., (2011). Does governance travel around the world?

Evidence from institutional investors. Journal of Financial Economics 100, 154–181.

Ajinkya, B.; S. Bhojraj; and P. Sengupta (2005). “The Association between Outside Directors,

Institutional Investors and the Properties of Management Earnings Forecasts.” Journal of

Accounting Research, 43, 343–376.

Autore, D. M., Hutton, I., & Kovacs, T. (2011). Accelerated equity offers and firm quality.

European Financial Management 17(5), 835–859.

Autore, D. M., Kumar, R., & Shome, D. K. (2008). The revival of shelf-registered corporate

equity offerings. Journal of Corporate Finance 14, 32–50.

Ball, R., S. Jayaraman and L. Shivakumar. (2012). Audited financial reporting and voluntary

disclosure as complements: A test of the confirmation hypothesis. Journal of Accounting and

Economics 53(1): 136-166.

Bebchuk, L. A., and A. Cohen (2005). “The Costs of Entrenched Boards.” Journal of Financial

Economics, 78, 409–433.

Bebchuk, L. A.; A. Cohen, and A. Ferrell (2009). “What Matters in Corporate Governance?”

Review of Financial Studies, 22, 783–827.

Bethel, J.E., & Krigman, L., (2008). Managing the costs of issuing common equity: The role of

registration choice. Quarterly Journal of Finance and Accounting 47(4), 57-85.

Bhagat, S., Marr, M., & Thompson, G. (1985). The rule 415 experiment: equity markets. Journal

of Finance 40, 1385–1401.

Blackwell, D. W., Marr, M. W., & Spivey, M. F. (1990). Shelf registration and the reduced due

diligence argument: Implications of the underwriter certification and the implicit insurance

hypotheses. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 25, 245-259.

Blankley, A., D. Hurtt and J. McGregor. (2012) Abnormal audit fees and restatements. Auditing: A

Journal of Practice and Theory 31 (1): 79-96.

Bortolotti,B., Megginson,W., Smart,S., (2008). The rise of accelerated seasoned equity

underwritings. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 20 (3), 35–57.

Brown, L., & Caylor, M. (2006). Corporate Governance and Firm Performance. Journal of

Accounting and Public Policy 25, 409-434..

Chung, K. H., Elder, J., & Kim, J-C. (2010). Corporate governance and liquidity. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45, 265-291.

Page 30: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

30

Coulton, J.,Livne, G., Pettinicchio, A., and S. Taylor. (2012). Audit fees and accounting quality:

Inferences from single-period versus multi-period perspectives. Working paper, The University of

Technology, Sydney, Australia.

Denis, D. (1991). Shelf registrations and the market for seasoned equity offerings. Journal of

Business 64, 189–212.

Doidge, C., Karolyi, G. A., & Stulz, R.M. (2007). Why Do Countries Matter So Much For

Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics 86, 1-39.

Durnev, A. & Kim, E.H., (2005) To Steal or Not to Steal: Firm Attributes, Legal Environment,

and Valuation. The Journal of Finance 60(3), 1461-1493.

Ferreira, M., Laux, P., 2007. Corporate governance, idiosyncratic risk, and information flow.

Journal of Finance 62, 951–989.

Gao, X., & Ritter, J.R. (2010). The marketing of seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Financial

Economics 97, 33–52.

Grossman, Sanford, and Joseph Stiglitz, (1980). On the impossibility of informationally efficient

markets, American Economic Review 25, 393–408.

Heron, R. A., & Lie, E. (2004). A comparison of the motivations for and the information content

of different types of equity offerings. Journal of Business 77, 605-632.

Jensen, M. C. & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs

and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305–360.

Kadapakkam, P. & Kon, S. J. (1989). The value of shelf registration for new debt issues. Journal

of Business 62, 271-292.

Karamanou, I., and N. Vafeas. “The Association between Corporate Boards, Audit Committees,

and Management Earnings Forecasts: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Accounting Research,

43(2005), 453–486.

Lee, G., & R. W. Masulis (2009). Seasoned equity offerings: Quality of accounting information

and expected flotation costs. Journal of Financial Economics 92(3), 443-469.

Leuz, C.; D. Nanda; and P.Wysocki. “Earnings Management and Investor Protection: An

International Comparison.” Journal of Financial Economics, 69 (2003), 505–527.

Li K., & Prabhala, N.R. (2005). Self-selection models in corporate finance. Working paper,

University of Maryland.

Mande, V., Park, YK., & Son, M. (2012). Equity or Debt Financing: Does Good Corporate

Governance Matter?. Corporate Governance: An International Review 20(2), 195-211.

Page 31: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

31

Morgenson, G., (2004). Judge in WorldCom action sides with plaintiffs on issue of due diligence

by banks. The New York Times, December 16, 2004.

Myers, S., Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have

information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187–221.

Schor, G.A., (2006). The Due Diligence and Reliance Defenses in WorldCom: Retrospect and

Prospect. Working paper

Sherman, Ann, (1999). Underwriter certification and the effect of shelf registration on due

diligence, Financial Management 28, 5–19.

Simunic, D. A. (1980). The pricing of audit services: Theory and evidence. Journal of

Accounting Research 18 (1): 161–190.

Turner, L. (2005). Comment letter to the Securities and Exchange Commission. April 12.

Available at: http://www.sec.gov/spotlight/soxcomp/soxcomp-turner.pdf

Watts, .L., Zimmerman, J.L., (1983). Agency problems, auditing, and the theory of the firm:

some evidence. Journal of Law and Economics 26, 613–633.

Page 32: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

32

Appendix A

CGQ Rating Variables Summary

Acceptable Governance Standards

Board Composition and Effectiveness (G1) 1. All directors attended 75% of board meetings or had a valid excuse

2. CEO serves on the boards of two or fewer public companies

3. Board is controlled by more than 50% independent outside directors

4. Board size is greater than 5 but less than 16

5. CEO is not listed as having a related-party transaction

6. No former CEO on the board

7. Compensation committee composed solely of independent outsiders

8. Chairman and CEO are separated or there is a lead director

9. Nominating committee composed solely of independent outsiders

10. Governance committee exists and met in the past year

11. Shareholders vote on directors selected to fill vacancies

12. Governance guidelines are publicly disclosed

13. Annually elected board (no staggered board)

14. Policy exists on outside directorships (four or fewer boards is the limit)

15. Shareholders have cumulative voting rights

16. Shareholder approval is required to increase/decrease board size

17. Majority vote requirement to amend charter/bylaws (not supermajority)

18. Board has the express authority to hire its own advisors

19. Performance of the board is reviewed regularly

20. Board-approved succession plan in place for the CEO

21. Directors are required to submit resignation upon a change in job

22. Board cannot amend bylaws without shareholder approval or can do so only under limited circumstances

23. Does not ignore shareholder proposal.

24. Company has policy on mandatory retirement age or term limits for directors

25. All board members participate in accredited director education programs. Anti-takeover (G2) 1. Single class, common

2. Majority vote requirement to approve mergers (not supermajority)

3. Shareholders may call special meetings

4. Shareholder may act by written consent

5. Company either has no poison pill or a pill that was shareholder approved

6. Company is not authorized to issue blank check preferred Compensation and Ownership (G3) 1. Directors are subject to stock ownership requirements

2. Executives are subject to stock ownership guidelines

3. No interlocks among compensation committee members

4. Directors receive all or a portion of their fees in stock

5. All stock-incentive plans adopted with shareholder approval

6. Options grants align with company performance and reasonable burn rate

7. Company expenses stock options

8. All directors with more than one year of service own stock

9. Officers’ and directors’ stock ownership is at least 1% but not over 30% of total shares outstanding

10. Repricing is prohibited

11. An option pricing model is used to measure the cost of all stock-based incentive plans.

12. Non-employee directors should not participate in pension plans

13. Corporate loans should not be given to participants of stock option plans. Audit Practices (G4) 1. Consulting fees should be less than audit fees.

2. Shareholders should be permitted to ratify management’s selection of auditors each year.

3. The entire audit committee is composed of independent directors.

4. The entire audit committee should be composed of financial experts.

Page 33: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

33

Table 1. Summary statistics

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Minimum 1st Quartile Median 3

rd Quartile Maximum

shelf 0.635 0.482 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

accelerated 0.399 0.490 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000

spread 4.264 1.659 0.106 3.500 4.850 5.476 10.693

G1 0.147 0.049 0.000 0.113 0.150 0.188 0.250

G2 0.142 0.036 0.026 0.120 0.145 0.169 0.226

G3 0.144 0.037 0.023 0.114 0.136 0.159 0.250

G4 0.142 0.056 0.028 0.083 0.139 0.194 0.250

CGI4 0.576 0.121 0.261 0.482 0.579 0.667 0.853

IndustryCGQ 54.478 26.311 0.500 33.600 55.000 75.750 100.000

firm size 1,351,474 4,499,174 22 81,484 286,915 861,916 113,000,000

roa -0.017 0.245 -1.891 -0.006 0.054 0.089 0.637

growth 0.441 2.474 -1.000 0.052 0.181 0.403 74.581

leverage 0.291 0.246 0.000 0.040 0.280 0.457 1.680

issue size 171,000 273,000 730 57,800 100,000 180,000 4,180,000

primary 0.751 0.397 0.000 0.543 1.000 1.000 1.000

Nasdaq 0.451 0.498 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000

This table presents the summary statistics for our sample firms over 2001 to 2007. Shelf is a dummy variable that equals one if an

equity offer is a shelf-registered offering and zero otherwise. Accelerated is a dummy variable that equals one if an equity offer is an

accelerated offer and zero otherwise. Spread is the gross spread as a percentage of the principal amount offered. G1, G2, G3, and G4

are ratings of governance quality concerning board of directors, anti-takeover provisions, executive and director ownership and

compensation, and audit practices and other progressive practices, respectively. CGI4 is the sum of G1, G2, G3, and G4. These ratings

are compiled by ourselves using raw data provided by RiskMetrics. IndustryCGQ which is compiled by RiskMetrics, is the percentile

rankings of the governance quality for a firm vis-à-vis its industry group. Higher governance rankings indicate better governance

quality. Firm size is measured by net sales at the last financial year end before an equity offering in thousands of US dollars. ROA is

earnings before interest and taxes scaled by total assets at the last financial year end before an equity offering. Growth is the growth

rate of net sales during the year of the equity offering. Leverage is total long-term debt divided by total assets at the last financial year

end before an equity offering. Issue size is the offering proceeds in thousands of US dollars. Primary is the proportion of primary

shares in the total shares offered. Nasdaq is a dummy variable that equals one if a firm is listed on Nasdaq and zero otherwise.

Page 34: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

34

Table 2. Correlations between equity offering methods and governance quality ratings

shelf accelerated spread G1 G2 G3 G4 CGI4 IndustryCGQ

shelf 1.000

accelerated 0.482 1.000

(0.000)

spread -0.311 -0.491 1.000

(0.000) (0.000)

G1 0.238 0.162 -0.117 1.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

G2 -0.071 -0.067 0.069 0.023 1.000

(0.009) (0.014) (0.015) (0.408)

G3 0.277 0.204 -0.237 0.398 -0.099 1.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

G4 0.309 0.220 -0.240 0.453 0.108 0.544 1.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

CGI4 0.303 0.210 -0.211 0.742 0.328 0.690 0.843 1.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

IndustryCGQ 0.155 0.141 -0.143 0.533 0.099 0.550 0.344 0.574 1.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

This table shows the pairwise correlation coefficients between equity offering methods and governance quality ratings. Numbers in the

brackets indicate the p-values for the test that a correlation coefficient is zero. All variables are as defined in Table 1.

Page 35: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

35

Table 3. Choice of equity issuance methods and governance quality: Univariate analysis

Panel A

Quintile CGI4 Shelf Accelerated Spread Firm Size ROA Growth Leverage Issue Size Primary Nasdaq

1 0.405 0.433 0.256 4.684 785,239 0.067 0.144 0.263 136,600 0.744 0.511

2 0.502 0.522 0.311 4.492 1,054,828 0.057 0.191 0.260 135,300 0.754 0.544

3 0.580 0.641 0.404 4.391 1,225,436 0.049 0.195 0.256 141,700 0.758 0.511

4 0.652 0.767 0.507 3.937 1,289,779 0.053 0.215 0.307 209,300 0.734 0.367

5 0.743 0.814 0.517 3.750 2,405,994 0.047 0.160 0.307 230,400 0.766 0.323

Panel B

2-1 0.089**

(0.019)

0.056*

(0.076)

-0.192*

(0.060)

-269,589

(0.130)

3-2 0.119***

(0.003)

0.093**

(0.012)

-0.101

(0.240)

-170,608

(0.290)

4-3 0.126***

(0.001)

0.104***

(0.008)

-0.454***

(0.002)

-64,343

(0.407)

5-4 0.047*

(0.088)

0.009

(0.414)

-0.187

(0.125)

-1,116,215**

(0.015)

Firm-years are assigned to quintiles based on their CGI4 ratings. Panel A presents the mean value for issuance variables (shelf,

accelerated, spread, issue size, and primary) and firm characteristics (firm size and Nasdaq) for each quintile, and the median of ROA,

Growth, and Leverage for each quintile. Panel B tests the difference in mean shelf, accelerated, spread, and firm size between

consecutive quintiles. For shelf and accelerated, one-sided proportion tests are used. For spread and firm size, one-sided t-tests are

used. All variables are as defined in Table 1. Numbers in the brackets are the p-values. One, two, and three asterisks indicate

significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Page 36: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

36

Table 4. Determinants of shelf-registered offerings: Internal and external certification

1 2 3 4 5 6

Constant -4.532*** (0.000)

-4.664*** (0.000)

-4.947*** (0.000)

-4.375***

(0.000)

-4.949***

(0.000)

-4.615***

(0.000)

Market cap 0.378*** (0.000)

0.372*** (0.000)

0.375*** (0.000)

0.387*** (0.000)

0.401*** (0.000)

-0.371*** (0.000)

ROA -0.927*** (0.000)

-0.990*** (0.000)

-0.968*** (0.000)

-1.05*** (0.000)

-0.967*** (0.000)

-0.993*** (0.000)

Growth 0.079 (0.277)

0.081 (0.267)

0.070 (0.327)

0.039 (0.585)

0.047 (0.488)

0.075 (0.330)

Leverage 0.907*** (0.000)

0.836*** (0.000)

0.894*** (0.000)

0.965*** (0.000)

1.004*** (0.000)

0.855*** (0.000)

Issue Size -0.232*** (0.006)

0.232*** (0.007)

-0.223*** (0.007)

-0.215** (0.016)

-0.229*** (0.008)

-0.240*** (0.003)

Primary 0.643*** (0.000)

0.709*** (0.000)

0.653*** (0.000)

0.690*** (0.000)

0.678*** (0.000)

0.702*** (0.000)

Nasdaq -0.319*** (0.003)

-0.313*** (0.004)

-0.257** (0.019)

-0.254** (0.020)

-0.300*** (0.006)

-0.311*** (0.004)

Below Range -1.535*** (0.000)

-1.554*** (0.000)

-1.474*** (0.000)

-1.495*** (0.000)

-1.470*** (0.000)

-1.530*** (0.000)

Above Range -1.385*** (0.000)

-1.447*** (0.000)

-1.360*** (0.000)

-1.366*** (0.000)

-1.316*** (0.000)

-1.425*** (0.000)

Audit Fee 0.137** (0.017)

0.200*** (0.001)

0.132** (0.029)

0.058 (0.360)

0.048 (0.435)

0.192*** (0.001)

G1 3.750*** (0.000)

G2 -0.326 (0.815)

G3 6.059*** (0.000)

G4 6.357*** (0.000)

CGI4 2.682*** (0.000)

IndustryCGQ 0.003 (0.10)

Log likelihood -487 -494 -485 -473 -477 -493

No. of Obs. 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040

The sample period is 2001 to 2007. The dependent variable is shelf. Market Cap is the

Market Capitalization in US dollars at the last financial year end before an offering. The

coefficients of market cap are multiplied by 10-7

for convenience. Issue size is the natural

logarithm of total proceeds in US dollars. Below range and above range are dummy variables

that equal one if the issue price is below or above the filing price range, respectively, and

zero otherwise. Audit fee is the natural logarithm of a firm’s three-year average total audit fee

in US dollars as of the financial year end before an offering. All the other variables are as

defined in Table 1. All except for the dummy variables are winsorized at the 1st and the 99

th

percentiles. Numbers in the brackets are the p-values. Standard errors are based on the

bootstrapping method using 500 replications. One, two, and three asterisks indicate

significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Page 37: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

37

Table 5. Determinants of accelerated offerings: Internal and external certification methods

1 2 3 4 5 6

Constant 2.435*

(0.068)

2.328*

(0.062)

2.262*

(0.069)

2.884**

(0.024)

2.461*

(0.056)

2.274*

(0.073)

Market Cap 0.547** (0.024)

0.508** (0.036)

0.533** (0.015)

0.591** (0.011)

0.583** (0.015)

0.503** (0.038)

ROA -0.602** (0.011)

-0.642*** (0.003)

-0.644*** (0.005)

-0.668*** (0.004)

-0.635*** (0.005)

-0.648*** (0.003)

Growth 0.026 (0.703)

0.031 (0.643)

0.017 (0.790)

-0.003 (0.966)

0.003 (0.964)

0.024 (0.730)

Leverage 0.915*** (0.000)

0.887*** (0.000)

0.907*** (0.000)

0.949*** (0.000)

0.950*** (0.000)

0.896*** (0.000)

Issue Size -0.208*** (0.006)

-0.207*** (0.003)

-0.209*** (0.003)

-0.213** (0.003)

-0.210*** (0.003)

-0.212*** (0.003)

Primary 0.136 (0.324)

0.175 (0.211)

0.145 (0.283)

0.149 (0.253)

0.147 (0.298)

0.178 (0.186)

Nasdaq -0.451*** (0.000)

-0.436*** (0.000)

-0.419*** (0.000)

-0.405*** (0.000)

-0.442*** (0.000)

-0.444*** (0.000)

Below Range -1.719*** (0.000)

-1.741*** (0.000)

-1.700*** (0.000)

-1.691*** (0.000)

-1.683*** (0.000)

-1.719*** (0.000)

Above Range -1.438*** (0.000)

-1.490*** (0.000)

-1.437*** (0.000)

-1.400*** (0.000)

-1.391*** (0.000)

-1.466*** (0.000)

Audit Fee 0.139*** (0.008)

0.182*** (0.001)

0.147*** (0.008)

0.091 (0.117)

0.096* (0.089)

0.172*** (0.001)

G1 2.456** (0.014)

G2 -0.871 (0.494)

G3 3.030** (0.021)

G4 3.992*** (0.000)

CGI4 1.541*** (0.000)

IndustryCGQ 0.003 (0.119)

Log likelihood -531 -534 -531 -524 -527 -622

No. of Obs. 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040

The sample period is 2001 to 2007. The dependent variable is accelerated. Market Cap is the

Market Capitalization in US dollars at the last financial year end before an offering. The

coefficients of market cap are multiplied by 10-7

for convenience. Issue size is the natural

logarithm of total proceeds in US dollars. Below range and above range are dummy variables

that equal one if the issue price is below or above the filing price range, respectively, and

zero otherwise. Audit fee is the natural logarithm of a firm’s three-year average total audit fee

in US dollars as of the financial year end before an offering. All the other variables are as

defined in Table 1. All variables except for the dummy variables are winsorized at the 1st and

the 99th

percentiles. Numbers in the brackets are the p-values. Standard errors are based on

the bootstrapping method using 500 replications. One, two, and three asterisks indicate

significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Page 38: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

38

Table 6. Determinants of gross spread: Heckman two-stage model estimations

1 2 3 4 5 6

Constant 3.889*** 3.844*** 3.970*** 4.131*** 3.76*** 3.830***

(0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)

Market Cap -1.11*** -1.15*** -1.16*** -1.15*** -1.10*** -1.17***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

ROA -1.727*** -1.753*** -1.789*** -1.884*** -1.847*** -1.814***

(0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)

Growth 0.181* 0.171 0.182 0.160 0.151 0.186*

(0.094) (0.131) (0.112) (0.165) (0.179) (0.094)

Leverage -0.403 -0.417 -0.458 -0.392 -0.354 -0.445

(0.352) (0.312) (0.288) (0.395) (0.409) (0.297)

Primary 0.844*** 0.997*** 0.919*** 0.888*** 0.895*** 0.911***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Audit Fee -0.216** -0.190** -0.182** -0.225** -0.243** -0.185**

(0.015) (0.042) (0.049) (0.019) (0.013) (0.042)

G1 4.01**

(0.030)

G2

1.966

(0.328)

G3

-0.703

(0.770)

G4

2.955*

(0.083)

CGI4

1.706*

(0.056)

IndustryCGQ

0.005

(0.138)

Lambda 1.693*** 1.622*** 1.624*** 1.706*** 1.737*** 1.666***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) R-squared 0.445 0.446 0.450 0.447 0.446 0.444

No. of Obs. 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040

The sample period is 2001 to 2007. The dependent variable is spread. Market cap is in

thousands of US dollars and is measured at the financial year end before an offering. The

coefficients of market cap are multiplied by 10-7

for convenience. Audit fee is the natural

logarithm of a firm’s three-year average total audit fee in US dollars as of the financial year

end before an offering. All the other variables are as defined in Table 1. All variables except

for the dummy variables are winsorized at the 1st and the 99

th percentiles. Numbers in the

brackets are the p-values. Standard errors are based on the bootstrapping method using 500

replications. One, two, and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level,

respectively.

Page 39: Accelerated Equity Offers: The Role of Internal and ...docs.business.auckland.ac.nz/Doc/Chandrasekhar-Krishnamurti-11... · Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti University of Southern Queensland

39

Table 7. Determinants of net proceeds: Heckman two-stage model estimations

1 2 3 4 5 6

Constant 15.087*** 15.084*** 14.978*** 15.153*** 15.005*** 15.054***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Market Cap 1.79*** 1.79*** 1.81*** 1.80*** 1.82*** 1.79***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

ROA 0.363** 0.363* 0.319* 0.300* 0.337* 0.355**

(0.048) (0.052) (0.079) (0.099) (0.069) (0.050)

Growth 0.093** 0.092* 0.087** 0.079 0.081* 0.092**

(0.046) (0.064) (0.035) (0.102) (0.097) (0.043)

Leverage 0.538*** 0.539*** 0.543*** 0.576*** 0.574*** 0.541***

(0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Primary -0.052 -0.049 -0.081 -0.075 -0.063 -0.055

(0.627) (0.669) (0.476) (0.481) (0.543) (0.589)

Audit Fee 0.188*** 0.188*** 0.177*** 0.162*** 0.166*** 0.187***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

G1 0.034

(0.962)

G2

0.057

(0.945)

G3

1.683

(0.113)

G4

1.658**

(0.027)

CGI4

0.579*

(0.098)

IndustryCGQ

0.001

(0.557)

Lambda 0.456*** 0.456*** 0.484** 0.508*** 0.498*** 0.465***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

R-squared 0.465 0.496 0.457 0.437 0.486 0.464

No. of Obs. 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040 1040

The sample period is 2001 to 2007. The dependent variable is net proceeds. Market cap is in

thousands of US dollars and is measured at the financial year end before an offering. The

coefficients of market cap are multiplied by 10-7

for convenience. Audit fee is the natural

logarithm of a firm’s three-year average total audit fee in US dollars as of the financial year

end before an offering. All the other variables are as defined in Table 1. All variables except

for the dummy variables are winsorized at the 1st and the 99

th percentiles. Numbers in the

brackets are the p-values. . Standard errors are based on the bootstrapping method using 500

replications. One, two, and three asterisks indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level,

respectively.