analysts’ responsiveness and market …...analysts’ responsiveness and market underreaction to...

40
Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business School Columbia University New York, NY 10027 Email: [email protected] Phone: 212-854-0159 Fax: 212-316-9219 October 2004 Preliminary. Comments Welcome. I thank Mei Cheng, Stephen Penman, K.R. Subramanyam, Richard Willis, and Paul Zarowin for helpful comments and suggestions. I also thank I/B/E/S for providing analysts’ forecast information. All errors are my own.

Upload: others

Post on 30-May-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction

to Earnings Announcements

Yuan Zhang

611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business School

Columbia University New York, NY 10027

Email: [email protected]

Phone: 212-854-0159 Fax: 212-316-9219

October 2004

Preliminary. Comments Welcome.

I thank Mei Cheng, Stephen Penman, K.R. Subramanyam, Richard Willis, and Paul Zarowin for helpful comments and suggestions. I also thank I/B/E/S for providing analysts’ forecast information. All errors are my own.

Page 2: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction

to Earnings Announcements

Abstract This study shows that analysts vary significantly in their responsiveness to earnings announcements, where responsiveness is defined as promptness of analysts’ first forecast revisions for the next quarter since the prior quarterly earnings announcements. Further evidence indicates that analysts’ responsiveness improves the efficiency of their expectations of future earnings immediately after the earnings announcements, which in turn mitigates the magnitude of the post-earnings-announcement drift. The results provide direct support for the “delayed response” hypothesis that prior research proposes to explain market underreactions.

Page 3: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

1

Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements

1. Introduction

This study seeks to examine (i) how responsive sell-side security analysts (hereafter,

“analysts”) are to quarterly earnings announcements in revising their forecasts for future

earnings and (ii) whether their responsiveness is associated with the extent to which they, as

well as the market, underreact to earnings announcements.

Stylized valuation models frequently posit that stock price is a function of expected

(permanent) earnings based on available information. The efficient market hypothesis

suggests that upon receiving new information, investors instantaneously adjust their

expectations of earnings, which is in turn reflected instantaneously in stock prices.

However, researchers have been able to document evidence inconsistent with the

efficient market hypothesis. One of the most persistent anomalies is the post-earnings-

announcement drift, where stock prices continue to drift for a long period after the earnings

announcements. Since the phenomenon was first reported by Ball and Brown (1968), it has

survived robustness checks, including extension to more recent data (e.g., Bernard and

Thomas 1989; Chan, Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok 1996; Doyle, Lundholm, and Soliman 2003).

As Fama (1998) puts it, the post-earnings-announcement drift is an anomaly that is “above

suspicion.”

A number of studies have attempted to explain the post-earnings-announcement drift.

Bernard and Thomas (1989) suggest that the “delayed response” hypothesis is a more likely

explanation for the drift than the “risk premium” hypothesis. Hong and Stein (1999) propose

Page 4: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

2

that market underreacts because private information diffuses gradually across investors.1 In

explaining why the market underreacts to public information such as earnings announcements,

Hong and Stein suggest that although the news itself is public, it might require some other,

private, information to convert this news into a judgment about value, thus the “gradual

information diffusion” explanation continues to apply.

Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998) propose a model of investor sentiment to

explain market under- and overreaction. Their model is based on literature on the psychology

of decision making. In particular, they suggest that market underreaction is consistent with a

phenomenon documented in psychology, namely conservatism, defined as the slow updating

of models in the face of new information.

While these papers have different perspectives in explaining market underreaction,

one common and important implication of their explanations is that investors are slow in

adjusting their expectations for future earnings upon receiving new information, which I

generally refer to as the “delayed response” hypothesis. Few studies, however, have directly

tested this hypothesis by focusing on the speed at which investors adjust their expectations

after news releases.

This study seeks to directly test the “delayed response” hypothesis. Specifically, I

examine the responsiveness of analyst forecast revisions after quarterly earnings

announcements. I focus on analysts because general investors’ earnings expectations are not

directly observable. On the other hand, one of analysts’ major responsibilities is to issue

1 In Hong and Stein’s (1999) model, there are two types of investors: news watchers and momentum traders. It is the gradual information diffusion among the news watchers that they suggest leads to market underreaction.

Page 5: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

3

earnings forecasts to guide the general investors, and their forecasts have significant influence

on investors (Schipper 1991).2

I define analysts’ responsiveness as the promptness of their first forecast revisions for

the next quarter after the prior quarterly earnings announcements. Consistent with the

“delayed response” hypothesis, I find that, based on analyst-firm-quarter specific observations,

about 44% of analysts (hereafter, “responsive analysts”) issue forecast revisions within two

trading days after the earnings announcement, whereas the average number of calendar days

between the earnings announcements and the first forecast revisions is thirty-four days for the

other 56% of analysts (hereafter, “non-responsive analysts”). Additional analysis shows that

relative to those for the responsive analysts, the absolute forecast errors are in fact

significantly larger for the non-responsive analysts, suggesting their lack of prompt responses

is not because the earnings announcements convey relatively less new information with

respect to their prior information set. This also suggests that the responsive analysts’ forecasts

are more accurate. Further, the responsive analysts not only react more promptly, but also

more completely to the earnings announcements—their first forecast revisions have higher

correlations with the earning surprises than do those of the non-responsive analysts.

Abarbanell and Bernard (1992) examine whether the post-earnings-announcement

drift can be explained by analysts’ underreaction to earnings announcements and find

supporting evidence that analyst forecast errors exhibit positive serial correlations.

Accordingly, to investigate the effect of analysts’ responsiveness on the extent of market

underreaction, I first examine its effect on the serial correlation of analyst forecast errors two 2 It is not uncommon that researchers use analyst forecasts to proxy for market expectations (e.g., Conrad, Cornell, and Landsman 2002; Liang 2003). Fried and Givoly (1982) suggest that analysts’ forecasts provide a better surrogate for market expectations than forecasts generated by time-series models.

Page 6: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

4

trading days after the earnings announcements, the starting point of my measure of the post-

earnings-announcement drift. While both responsive and non-responsive analysts appear to

underreact to earnings announcements, responsive analysts underreact to a significantly lesser

extent. In fact, the serial correlation in their forecast errors is less than half of that in non-

responsive analysts’ forecast errors. This result also holds at the firm level with mean forecast

errors, where the firm-level analysts’ responsiveness is measured by the percentage of

responsive analysts following the firm.

Finally, I investigate the effects of analysts’ responsiveness on the magnitude of the

post-earnings-announcement drift. I find that the drift is significantly lower when the

percentage of responsive analysts following the firm is higher. Specifically, over the sixty-

trading-day period starting from the third trading day after the earnings announcements, the

drift is about one third lower for firms followed by responsive analysts only than firms

followed by non-responsive analysts only.

In sum, the results of this study show that a majority of analysts are not responsive to

earnings announcements in revising their forecasts for future earnings. Further, analysts vary

significantly in their responsiveness (and completeness) in incorporating information in

earnings announcements into their forecast revisions. Most importantly, the difference in

responsiveness affects the efficiency of their expectations, and hence the efficiency of market

expectations, of future earnings immediately after the earnings announcement, which in turn

affects the magnitude of the post-earnings-announcement drift.

Thus, this study provides direct support for the “delayed response” hypothesis for the

post-earnings-announcement drift discussed above. It suggests that the speed at which market

participants incorporate new information into their forecasts for future earnings and into stock

Page 7: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

5

prices is indeed associated with the extent of market underreaction. As suggested by Hong

and Stein (1999) and Barberis et al. (1998) respectively, the delayed response may be caused

by analysts requiring additional, private information to convert the news in the earnings

announcements into a judgment about future earnings, or simply by their cognitive

conservatism.

This study also extends the literature by focusing on an alternative aspect of market

efficiency. Unlike many prior studies that focus on the instantaneity of stock prices in

incorporating new information (e.g., Ball and Brown 1968), this study examines the

instantaneity of analysts in incorporating new information into their forecast revisions. While

focusing on stock prices speaks to market efficiency aggregately, focusing on analysts’

forecast revisions has the advantage of providing information about individual investors’

behavior. Since stock prices are ultimately driven by individual market participants’ behavior,

understanding their responses to information releases helps us understand the reasons for

market efficiency or inefficiency.

A number of studies examine the efficiency of analysts’ forecasts. However, as

discussed in more details later, while these studies focus on whether and to what extent

analysts underreact or overreact to prior information by examining the serial correlation of

their forecast errors (e.g., Abarbanell and Bernard 1992; Easterwood and Nutt 1999), they do

not specifically address the promptness of analysts’ incorporating public information into

their forecasts. Both the timing and the magnitude of analysts’ reaction to public information

are important because the market efficiency hinges on both the instantaneity and the

completeness of the stock prices in reflecting available information.

Page 8: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

6

This study also underscores the importance of examining analysts’ responsiveness to

information releases in order to fully understand the characteristics of analysts and their

forecasts. In addition to pointing out that analysts’ responsiveness per se is an important

aspect of analyst forecast efficiency, this study also finds that responsive analysts not only

respond more promptly, their responses are also more complete and their forecasts more

accurate. Thus, this study suggests that analysts’ responsiveness to information releases is

potentially a good indicator of analysts’ forecasting ability, which can help investors

differentiate among analysts. This implication is consistent with Cooper, Day, and Lewis

(2001) who find that lead analysts can be identified by the timeliness of their earnings

forecasts.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 examines the

timing and magnitude of analysts’ responses to earnings announcements. Section 4 examines

the effects of analysts’ responsiveness on their underreaction to the earnings announcements,

and on the post-earnings-announcement drift. Section 5 concludes.

2. Data and Descriptive Statistics

I focus on analysts’ forecast revision for the next quarter after the current quarterly

earnings announcement, since prior studies (e.g., Bernard and Thomas 1990) suggest that the

post-earnings-announcement drift is caused by investors’ failure to recognize the

autocorrelation structure of quarterly earnings. I obtain analyst forecast revision and earnings

announcement data from I/B/E/S detail file3 and stock return and price data from CRSP. As

3 The I/B/E/S data is obtained from WRDS, where the detailed file provides not only the analyst forecast information but also corresponding earnings announcement information.

Page 9: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

7

discussed below, I also use information from I/B/E/S identification file and adjustment file to

make certain adjustments.

The sample starts with all I/B/E/S individual analyst forecasts for quarterly earnings

per share with fiscal period ending between 1988 and 2002. I delete observations with zero

analyst-specific identification code4 or missing CUSIP. I also delete observations with (i)

forecast date on or after the corresponding earnings announcement date or (ii) earnings

announcement date before or more than ninety days after the corresponding fiscal period end,

as these observations are potentially subject to data error or other irregularities. For firm-

quarters that are followed by I/B/E/S on a diluted basis, I use the dilution/primary adjustment

factor in the identification file to convert the forecast and actual earnings per share to a

primary basis.

For each analyst-firm-quarter, I retain only the most recent forecast before the

corresponding earnings announcement. I then require that this analyst has at least one forecast

for the next quarter of the same firm issued before the current earnings announcement and at

least one issued after. At this stage, 396,001 analyst-firm-quarters remain in the sample. All

EPS variables (forecasts or actuals) are then unadjusted for stock splits based on information

from the I/B/E/S adjustment file. I next require fiscal period end stock price and return

information necessary to calculate size-adjusted returns (SARj,t, defined in Section 4)

available from CRSP, yielding a sample of 333,758 observations. To prevent undue

influences by outliers, I delete observations with extreme 1% forecast errors (FEi,j,t, defined

4 I/B/E/S assigns a zero identification code if the broker did not provide an analyst name to be associated with the estimate.

Page 10: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

8

below) at both tails, which results in a final sample of 327,084 analyst-firm-quarters,

representing 103,681 firm-quarters.

Figure 1 plots the timeline of various information events. For each analyst i who

follows firm j, I denote her latest forecast for quarter t as Fi,j,t and the corresponding actual

earnings per share as Ej,t. The forecast error for quarter t, FEi,j,t, is calculated as (Ej,t - Fi,j,t)/P,

where P is the firm j’s stock price at the end of fiscal quarter t. Additionally, I denote her

latest (first) forecast for quarter t+1 before (after) quarter t earnings announcement as Fi,j,t+1a

(Fi,j,t+1b), and the corresponding actual earnings per share as Ej,t+1. The forecast revision for

quarter t+1 upon quarter t earnings announcement (REVi,j,t+1) is thus calculated as (Fi,j,t+1b -

Fi,j,t+1a)/P.

Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for the sample. The number of analyst-firm-

quarters increases steadily over the sample period, consistent with prior research (e.g., Ivković

and Jegadeesh 2004). The average number of calendar days from quarter t earnings

announcement to the analyst’s first forecast revision for quarter t+1 since (inclusive), on the

other hand, decreases steadily from 33 days in 1988 to 13 days in 2002. The decrease in

medians is even more salient, from 27 days in 1988 to merely 2 days in 2002. This suggests

that analysts have gotten more responsive over the sample period, although a considerable

number of analysts still do not react immediately upon the earnings announcements.

Table 1 also presents the means and medians of analysts’ forecast errors (FEi,j,t) and

their forecast revisions (REVi,j,t+1). The mean and median forecast errors at the time of the

earnings announcements are more frequently negative in the early years and more frequently

positive in later years, suggesting analysts have gone from being relatively optimistic to

Page 11: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

9

relatively pessimistic over the sample period.5 Finally, both the mean and median of analysts’

first forecast revisions for the next quarter after the current quarter’s earnings announcements

are negative for every year in the sample period. This is consistent with evidence presented in

Ivković and Jegadeesh (2004, Table 3 Panel B) that more of the first forecast revisions after

the earnings announcements are downward revisions than upward revisions.

A couple of econometric issues warrant discussion before I move on to the empirical

evidence. To correct for the autocorrelation and generalized conditional heteroskedasticity

embedded in the sample, the t-statistics in the regressions are adjusted using generalized

method of moments (GMM) as described in Newey and West (1987) with six lags. To

minimize the effects of outliers, I delete observations with extreme forecast errors as

described in the sample selection process. In addition, all regressions reported in the tables are

estimated after deleting observations with absolute studentised residuals greater than 2 (e.g.,

see SAS 1989).

3. How Responsive are Analysts to Earnings Announcements?

3.1. Timing of Analyst Forecast Revisions

In light of the stylized model discussed at the beginning of the paper, the efficient

market hypothesis predicts that upon receiving new information, rational investors

instantaneously update their expectations for future earnings. However, while new

5 Richardson, Teoh, Wysocki (forthcoming) also find analyst forecast errors at the time of earnings announcements are on average optimistic in earlier years and pessimistic in recent years, although their focus is the change in bias (optimism to pessimism) during the year. They suggest that the pessimistic bias in analyst forecasts outstanding at time of earnings announcements in recent years is driven by the “earnings-guidance game” in which analysts walkdown their estimates to a level the firm can beat at the earnings announcements.

Page 12: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

10

information may become available to the market everyday, analysts do not necessarily revise

and publish their forecasts everyday. Their revision activities potentially depend on the extent

to which the new information alters their expectations for future earnings.

Bagnoli, Levine, and Watts (2004) find that among various corporate information

events, analyst forecast revisions tend to cluster to a greater extent after earnings

announcements than after earnings guidance or other events. They argue that this is because

the earnings announcements deliver news in a clear and relatively consistent format at

predictable times and consist largely of financial information prepared in accordance with

generally accepted accounting principles. They also argue that earnings announcements may

induce more analyst forecast revisions because of the directness of the link between earnings

and firm valuation. In addition, as Francis et al. (2002) document, there is a growing tendency

for managers to include additional, significant information in an earnings release such as

income statement line items, balance sheets, cash flow information, and forecasts. This

additional information also helps analysts in revising their forecasts for future earnings.

Thus, given the significant implications of earnings announcements for future earnings

as well as for firm values, although analysts do not necessarily revise their forecasts each time

they receive new information, they are more likely to do so after the earnings announcements

than after other corporate information events. Consistent with Bagnoli et al. (2004), Stickel

(1989) finds that analysts avoid revising for two weeks before an earnings announcement and

more frequently revise immediately after the announcement. Similarly, Ivković and Jegadeesh

(2004) find that analysts’ forecast revisions concentrate on the days immediately after the

earnings announcements. However, unlike the current study, none of the above studies is

specifically interested in the effects of analysts’ responsiveness on market underreaction.

Page 13: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

11

To examine analysts’ responsiveness to earnings announcements, I first present

distributions of the number of calendar days from the earnings announcement of quarter t to

the analyst’s first forecast revision for quarter t+1 since. Panel A of Table 2 shows that

inconsistent with the prediction that analysts instantaneously adjust their expectations upon

the earnings announcements, on average it takes 20 days before an analyst revises her forecast.

The median is 7 days. The first and third quartiles are 2 and 31 days respectively, whereas the

standard deviation is 25 days. The distribution is very similar after I delete observations with

zero analyst-specific forecast error where the earnings announcement potentially conveys

minimal information to the analyst.

Figure 2 plots the timing of analysts’ issuance of forecast revision with respect to the

earnings announcement date. The pattern mirrors that of the post-earnings-announcement drift

documented in prior studies (e.g., Ball and Brown 1968). Specifically, a relatively large

portion of revisions takes place immediately after the earnings announcement, yet the

activities of revisions continue into months after the earnings announcements. In fact, about

50% of analysts do not revise their forecasts within five calendar days after the earnings

announcements. About 14% of analysts revise their forecasts during the second month and

11% do so during the third month and beyond after the earnings announcements.

I formerly measure an analyst’s responsiveness by RESPi,j,t, which equals 1 if she

issues a forecast revision within two trading days after the earnings announcement (i.e., the

event window is from trading day 0 to trading day 2), and 0 otherwise. To the extent that one

expects stock prices to have reflected the information immediately after the event, one would

also expect investors to have processed the information and revised their expectations for

future earnings by the same time. Event studies typically use one or two trading days after the

Page 14: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

12

event as the end of the event window. I choose two trading days to allow for the possibility

that analysts may need more time to convert the information in earnings announcement into a

formal forecast for future earnings or they may need more time to acquire additional

information from the firm.

Panel B of Table 2 shows that only 43.67% of analysts revise their quarter t+1

forecasts during the event window (i.e., RESPi,j,t=1). This percentage is virtually unchanged at

43.82% if I delete observations with FEi,j,t=0.6 I next analyze analysts’ responsiveness by

industry, where firms are classified into 48 industries following Fama and French (1997).

Panel B lists industries with at least 1% of analyst-firm-quarters in the sample that have the

highest or lowest percentage of responsive analysts. Electronic Equipment has the highest

percentage of responsive analysts (56%), followed by Measuring and Control Equipment

(53%), Business Services (51%), and Electrical Equipment (51%). On the other hand,

Chemicals has the lowest percentage of responsive analysts (35%), followed by Trading

(38%), Automobiles and Trucks (38%), and Food Products (38%). While there is some degree

of variation in analysts’ responsiveness across different industries, the evidence suggests that

even in industries with the highest percentage of responsive analysts, only slightly more than

half of the analysts revise their forecasts for future quarters promptly.

Panel C examines analysts’ responsiveness at the firm level, where the responsiveness

is measured by FRESPj,t, the percentage of responsive analysts among all those who follow

the firm for the quarter. Only about 18% of firm-quarters have 100% of responsive analysts

6 Ivković and Jegadeesh (2004) find frequency of responsive revisions similar to that reported in the current study when they examine only the first forecast revisions by the analysts since the earnings announcements.

Page 15: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

13

following the firm. In contrast, 46% of firm-quarters have no responsive analysts following at

all.

Overall, the descriptive statistics in Table 2 suggest considerable variations in

analysts’ responsiveness and more importantly, they suggest a majority of analysts, despite

their expertise, do not adjust their expectations instantaneously after earnings announcements

which potentially provide significant, new information. This evidence is consistent with the

“delayed response” explanation for the post-earnings-announcement drift, raising questions

regarding the efficiency of the analyst forecasts as well as the efficiency of the market.

I next examine certain analyst-specific or firm-specific variables conditional on

analysts’ responsiveness. Table 3 shows that while mean and median number of calendar days

from firms’ announcing Ej,t to analysts’ issuing Fi,j,t+1b are only 2.50 and 2 respectively for

responsive analysts, they are as high as 34 and 27 days respectively for non-responsive

analysts.7 The next variable of interest is AFEi,j,t, the absolute value of FEi,j,t, which reflects

the amount of new information the earnings announcement conveys to the analyst with

respect to her prior information set reflected in Fi,j,t. One would expect higher probability for

the analyst to react immediately to the earnings announcement with higher AFEi,j,t.

In contrast to this expectation, responsive analysts’ forecasts are in fact more accurate

than non-responsive analysts, for both means and medians. Similarly, the absolute value of

forecast error for quarter t+1 before the quarter t earnings announcement, calculated as

AFEi,j,t+1a=Abs(Ej,t+1 - Fi,j,t+1

a)/P, is also significantly lower for responsive analysts than for

7 The average number of calendar days between fiscal period end and the first forecast revision by the non-responsive analysts is 59 days and the median is 53 days. Thus, considering that the SEC requires firms to file 10-Q forms within 45 calendar days after the fiscal period end, it is unlikely the lack of prompt reaction by non-responsive analysts is completely driven by the need for additional, comprehensive information from the 10-Q forms.

Page 16: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

14

non-responsive analysts. These results suggest that the lack of reactions by the non-responsive

analysts are not because the earnings announcements convey less information with respect to

their prior information set or they have relative information advantage over the responsive

analysts before the earnings announcements.8 Further, AFEi,j,t+1b, the counterpart of AFEi,j,t+1

a

after the earnings announcements, is significantly lower for responsive analysts than for non-

responsive analysts. This suggests that the first forecasts of the responsive analysts since the

earnings announcements are more accurate than those of the non-responsive analysts, even

though on average the non-responsive analysts issue forecast revisions almost one month after

the earnings announcements, and potentially have access to additional information during this

period.

The results regarding the absolute forecast errors so far suggest that the lack of prompt

reaction by non-responsive analysts is not driven by less new information contained in the

earnings announcements relative to their prior information set. Instead, the results seem to

suggest that non-responsive analysts generally have lower ability to forecast earnings

accurately. This raises the possibility that non-responsive analysts’ forecasts are of lower

quality (e.g., Cooper et al. 2001) and that their lack of prompt reaction is due to their lower

ability to understand the implications of current earnings for future earnings.

I also examine the signed forecast errors, FEi,j,t, conditional on analysts’

responsiveness. The evidence reported in Table 3 suggests that analysts are more likely to

revise their forecasts promptly when the earnings announcements convey “good news.” The

average forecast error is 0.0002 for responsive analysts but -0.0004 for non-responsive

8 For example, prior to the enactment of Regulation Fair Disclosure in October 2000, certain analysts may gain information advantage over other analysts because of selective disclosures by managers.

Page 17: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

15

analysts. This is consistent with Hong, Lim, and Stein (2000) that the market seems to

underreact more to “bad news”—“bad news travels slowly.” Untabulated results show that

34% of the non-responsive analyst-firm-quarters have negative earnings surprises, versus 27%

of the responsive analyst-firm-quarters.

Another analyst-specific variable reported in Table 3 is analysts’ firm-specific

experience. Mikhail, Walther, and Willis (1997) suggest that analysts’ forecast accuracy

improves as they gain firm-specific experience. In addition, Mikhail, Walther, and Willis

(2003a) find that analysts with longer firm-specific experience underreact to prior information

to a lesser extent. Accordingly, I next examine EXPi,j,t, measured as the number of quarters

that the analyst has followed the firm by quarter t. Consistent with these studies, on average,

responsive analysts have 9-quarter firm-specific experience, longer than the 8-quarter firm-

specific experience of the non-responsive analysts. The difference is statistically significant.

Finally, I examine three firm-specific variables including age, market capitalization,

and analyst coverage. Prior studies suggest that firms with older age have lower information

uncertainty and lower price momentum (Jiang, Lee, and Zhang 2004), and that the market

incorporates information more efficiently for larger firms and firms with greater analyst

coverage (e.g., Elgers, Lo, and Pfeiffer 2001; Foster, Olsen, and Shevlin 1984; Hong et al.

2000). To the extent that analysts’ responsiveness is associated with the information

efficiency of the firm, one would expect that firms followed by responsive analysts are older,

larger, and followed by more analysts. The descriptive statistics in Table 3 show that

consistent with expectations, firms followed by responsive analysts have significantly higher

analyst coverage (NUMANAj,t) and larger market capitalization (LOGMVj,t) than those

Page 18: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

16

followed by non-responsive analysts.9 However, analysts seem to be more responsive to

younger firms as opposed to older firms (AGEj,t).

3.2. Magnitude of Analyst Forecast Revisions

The previous subsection examines how promptly analysts revise their earnings

forecasts for the next quarter. In this subsection, I focus on the extent to which analysts

incorporate the news in the earnings announcements to their forecast revisions. Prior studies

suggest that market reactions to earnings announcements are correlated with the “surprises” or

new information contained in the announcements (e.g., Fried and Givoly 1982). To the extent

that market reactions reflect investors’ revisions of expectations of future earnings, one would

expect that analysts’ forecast revisions are also correlated with the earnings surprises.

Consistent with this, Easterwood and Nutt (1999) find that analysts forecast revisions are

correlated with their previous forecast errors. However, the measure of forecast revisions in

their study is relatively “stale,” as it is based on the changes of analysts’ consensus forecasts

from eight months before to four months after the earnings announcements.

In the context of the current study, I am specifically interested in the effects of quarter

t earnings surprises on analysts’ forecast revisions for quarter t+1, and in particular, whether

the magnitude of this effect varies with analysts’ responsiveness. If an analyst responds more

promptly after an earnings announcement in revising her forecast for future earnings, it is

probably because she understands better the implications of current earnings for future

9 Note that the descriptive statistics of analysts following are based on per analyst-firm-quarter, as opposed to per firm-quarter.

Page 19: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

17

earnings, as discussed in the previous subsection. Thus, her responsiveness is expected to be

indicative of the extent to which she incorporates the information into her forecasts revision.

The forecast revision REVi,j,t+1 is as defined in Table 1. I use FEi,j,t, the analyst-

specific forecast error for quarter t, to measure the news in the earnings announcements to the

analyst, since different analysts may have different information set and probably an analyst’s

individual information set is best reflected in her own forecast. I investigate the relation

between forecast revisions and the news in the earnings announcements by estimating the

following model:

REVi,j,t+1 = β0 + β1FEi,j,t + β2FEi,j,t × RESPi,j,t + β3RESPi,j,t + β4FEi,j,t × EXPi,j,t

+ β5EXPi,j,t + β6FEi,j,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (1)

I start the analysis by estimating a base model which simply regresses REVi,j,t+1 on

FEi,j,t with the pooled sample. The results are reported in Column (1) of Table 4. The

coefficient on FEi,j,t is significantly positive with a magnitude of 0.486, suggesting analysts

revise their forecasts in accordance with the new information conveyed in the earnings

announcements. The next two columns in Table 4 report this regression estimated for

responsive analysts and non-responsive analysts separately. For responsive analysts, the

coefficient on FEi.j,t is significant at 0.528, and the R-squared is 28.93%. In contrast, the

coefficient is only 0.457 and R-squared 22.44% for non-responsive analysts.

To test the statistical significance of the difference in the coefficient on FEi,j,t, I next

include an interaction term between FEi,j,t and RESPi,j,t, allowing FEi,j,t to have different

coefficients conditional on analysts’ responsiveness. The results are reported in Column (4).

The interaction term has a significantly positive coefficient of 0.071, suggesting the difference

Page 20: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

18

between the extent to which responsive and non-responsive analysts incorporate the news into

their revisions is statistically significant.

Finally, I estimate the complete version of model (1) which controls for the effects of

the analyst’s firm-specific experience and the firm’s analyst coverage on the correlation

between REVi,j,t+1 and FEi,j,t. It is necessary to include these control variables because Table 3

shows that analysts’ responsiveness are correlated with these two variables and prior studies

suggest these variables are associated with the information efficiency of the security market

(e.g., Mikhail, Walther, and Willis 2003b; Elgers et al. 2001).10 The results, presented in the

last column of Table 4, show that RESPi,j,t continues to have a significantly positive, albeit

somewhat smaller, effect on the relation between analysts’ forecast revisions and earnings

surprises, suggesting that this effect is not subsumed by firm-specific experience or analyst

coverage. On the other hand, EXPi,j,t has an insignificant effect, while NUMANAj,t has a

significantly positive effect as expected.

4. Does Analysts’ Responsiveness Affect Market Underreaction?

4.1. Analysts’ Responsiveness and Analysts’ Underreaction

In this Section, I explicitly test whether delayed analysts’ response (i.e., lack of

analysts’ responsiveness) contributes to market underreaction. I start by examining whether

analysts’ responsiveness mitigates analysts’ underreaction to the earnings announcements,

where analysts’ underreaction is measured by the serial correlation in their forecast errors.

10 I include analysts’ coverage, but not firm size, as a control variable because prior research has shown that analysts’ coverage is highly correlated with firm size. However, including firm size as an additional control variable in all my tests does not qualitatively alter the implications of my empirical results.

Page 21: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

19

The results in Section 3 suggest that in comparison to those of non-responsive analysts,

responsive analysts’ forecast revisions are associated with new information in earnings

announcements to a greater extent. However, this result per se does not necessarily imply that

the responsive analysts underreact to a lesser extent than do non-responsive analysts. As

Easterwood and Nutt (1999) point out, to test whether analysts systematically underreact (or

overreact) to news in earnings announcements about future earnings, one needs to benchmark

analysts’ reactions against the true earnings innovation series. To achieve this, one needs to

examine the autocorrelation in analysts’ forecasts errors. If the analyst fully understands the

implications of current earnings surprise for future earnings and instantaneously adjusts her

forecast for future earnings accordingly, her forecast errors should not be autocorrelated.

A number of studies find that analysts’ forecast errors are correlated with prior

information, suggesting they underreact to that information. For example, Abarbanell (1991)

finds that analysts’ forecast errors are positively correlated with prior returns and surprises in

recent earnings announcements (see also, e.g., Mendenhall 1991). Abarbanell and Bernard

(1992) specifically examine if the post-earnings-announcement drift is caused by analysts’

underreaction to the earnings announcements. They present evidence that analysts’ forecast

errors exhibit positive serial correlation, but conclude that analysts’ underreaction is at best

only a partial explanation for stock price underreaction to earnings. Finally, Mikhail et al.

(2003a) find that analysts underreact less to prior information as they gain firm-specific

experience and Mikhail et al. (2003b) show that this effect mitigates the post-earnings-

announcement drift.

As Easterwood and Nutt (1999) suggest, the literature on security analysts defines

“forecast efficiency” as analysts accurately incorporating new information on a timely and

Page 22: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

20

unbiased fashion. Research on analysts’ underreaction such as that discussed about, however,

has largely ignored the timeliness perspective of the efficiency of analysts’ forecasts. For

example, Abarbanell and Bernard (1992) measure the serial correlation in analysts forecast

errors only as of the last forecast revisions before next quarter’s earnings announcements.

While this research design is capable of documenting the extent of analysts’ underreaction as

of the measurement date, if any, it fails to capture analysts’ immediate reaction to earnings

announcement and the possibility that the extent of analysts’ underreaction may be correlated

with their responsiveness.

I incorporate the timeliness perspective by focusing on the extent of analysts’

underreaction immediately after the earnings announcements. I measure analysts’

expectations of future earnings immediately after the earnings announcements using Fi,j,t+1,

their forecasts outstanding at the end of the second trading day after the announcements.

Specifically, Fi,j,t+1 equals to Fi,j,t+1b for responsive analysts and Fi,j,t+1

a for non-responsive

analysts. Since non-responsive analysts have not updated their forecasts, their latest forecasts

prior to the earnings announcements are still considered valid. I examine the autocorrelation

in analyst forecast errors using the following model:

FEi,j,t+1 = β0 + β1FEi,j,t + β2FEi,j,t × RESPi,j,t + β3RESPi,j,t + β4FEi,j,t × EXPi,j,t

+ β5EXPi,j,t + β6FEi,j,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (2)

where FEi,j,t+1=(Ej,t+1 - Fi,j,t+1)/P. Other variables are as defined previously.

As in Section 3.2, I first estimate a base model which regresses FEi,j,t+1 on FEi,j,t. The

coefficient on FEi,j,t is 0.82, indicating significant underreaction, on average, by analysts at the

end of second trading day after the earnings announcements. Prior studies that use the latest

analyst forecasts before the next quarter’s earnings announcements typically report a

Page 23: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

21

coefficient around 0.15.11 The decrease in the serial correlation from immediately after

quarter t’s earnings announcements to immediately before quarter t+1’s earnings

announcements suggests that analysts only slowly incorporate implications of current

earnings for future earnings into their forecasts over time, again consistent with the “delayed

response” explanation for market underreactions.

A more striking result emerges when I estimate the model for the two types of analysts

separately. Columns (2) and (3) in Table 5 show that for non-responsive analysts, the

autocorrelation is as high as 0.844, while for responsive analysts, it is only 0.369, less than

half of that for non-responsive analysts. The R-squared is also in sharp contrast: it is almost

21% for non-responsive analysts, more than double that for responsive analysts (8.61%). This

result suggests that the responsive analysts’ prompt forecast revisions significantly mitigate

the correlation of their forecast errors immediately after the earnings announcements.

I next estimate the model after adding the interaction terms of FEi,j,t with RESPi,j,t, and

subsequently, the interaction terms of FEi,j,t with EXPi,j,t and NUMANAj,t respectively. The

results appear in the last two columns in Table 5. Consistent with expectations, the coefficient

on the interaction term of FEi,j,t and RESPi,j,t is significantly negative, with or without the

control variables. When the model controls for the effects of analysts’ firm-specific

experience and analysts’ coverage, non-responsive analysts’ forecast errors have a serial

correlation of 0.809, in comparison to 0.327 (=0.809-0.482) for responsive analysts. In other

words, immediately (i.e., two trading days) after the earnings announcements, the serial

correlation in forecast errors for responsive analysts’ is only 40% of that for non-responsive

11 For example, Abarbanell and Bernard (1992) report a coefficient of 0.18 while Mikhail et al. (2003) report a coefficient of 0.14.

Page 24: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

22

analysts, suggesting responsive analysts’ forecasts better incorporate the implications of

current earnings for future earnings. Regarding the control variables, inconsistent with

Mikhail et al. (2003a), the coefficient on FEi,j,t × EXPi,j,t is significantly positive.12 In addition,

the effect of NUMANAj,t on the degree of underreaction is negative, albeit insignificant.

The above analyses are performed at the analyst level; that is, the unit of observation

is analyst-firm-quarter specific. Since the post-earnings-announcement drift is necessarily

examined at the firm level, I also repeat the analyses above using firm level data. Specifically,

I estimate the following regression:

MFEj,t+1 = β0 + β1MFEj,t + β2MFEj,t × FRESPj,t + β3FRESPj,t + β4MFEj,t × FEXPj,t

+ β5FEXPj,t + β6MFEj,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (3)

where MFEj,t is the firm-quarter mean of FEi,j,t (MFEj,t+1 is calculated likewise). Following

Mikhail et al. (2003b), FEXPj,t is the firm-quarter median of EXPi,j,t, where EXPi,j,t is as

defined previously. FRESPj,t and NUMANAj,t are as defined previously.

The results, presented in Panel B of Table 5, are generally consistent with those

reported in Panel A. In Column (1), before the inclusion of the interaction terms, MFEj,t has a

positive coefficient of 0.722 for the pooled sample. In Columns (2) and (3), without or with

control variables respectively, the coefficient on the interaction term of MFEj,t and FRESPj,t is

significantly negative. The results suggest that at the firm level, the autocorrelation in mean

analyst forecast errors after the earnings announcements decreases as the percentage of

responsive analysts following the firm increases. In fact, based on Column (3), for firms

12 There are at least two differences in sample selection and research design between the Mikhail et al. paper and the current paper. First, Mikhail et al. use analyst forecast information from Zacks while I use analyst forecast information from I/B/E/S. Second, they measure the serial correlation in analyst forecast errors immediately before the next quarter’s earnings announcements while I measure the serial correlation immediately after current quarter’s earnings announcements.

Page 25: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

23

followed by responsive analysts only, the autocorrelation in analyst forecast errors is only

42% of that for firms followed by non-responsive analysts only. Finally, the effect of

experience on the autocorrelation at the firm level is insignificantly positive, and the effect of

analyst coverage is significantly positive.

4.2. Analysts’ Responsiveness and Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift

The results presented in the previous subsection indicate that in comparison to non-

responsive analysts, responsive analysts underreact to earnings announcements to a lesser

extent. In other words, their forecasts at the end of two trading days after the earnings

announcements better reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings. To the

extent that analyst forecasts mirror market expectations for future earnings and that the post-

earnings-announcement drift is caused by investors’ failure to promptly incorporate the

implications of current earnings for future earnings into stock prices (e.g., Bernard and

Thomas 1990), this result implies that the post-earnings-announcement drift would be lower

for firms followed by responsive analysts. I now explicitly test this prediction.

To be consistent with my definition of the event window, the post-earnings-

announcement period starts from the third trading after the earnings announcements.

Following prior studies (e.g., Liang 2003; Mikhail et al. 2003b), I focus on stock returns over

the sixty-trading-day period after the earnings announcements and measure stock returns over

this period using size-adjusted buy-and-hold returns (SARj,t), where the adjustment is based

on equally-weighted returns of NYSE / AMEX / NASDAQ firm size decile to which the firm

belongs at the beginning of the calendar year.

Page 26: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

24

I estimate the following regression to examine the effect of analysts’ responsiveness

on the magnitude of the post-earnings-announcement drift.

SARj,t = β0 + β1RMFEj,t + β2RMFEj,t × FRESPj,t + β3FRESPj,t + β4MFEj,t × FEXPj,t

+ β5FEXPj,t + β6MFEj,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (4)

To minimize problems associated with outliers as well as non-linearity, I follow prior

literature to use deciles of MFEj,t, namely, RMFEj,t, as opposed the raw MFEj,t, in the

regression (e.g., Bernard and Thomas 1990; Bartov, Radhakrishnan, and Krinsky 2000; Doyle

et al. 2003). Specifically, I rank MFEj,t by fiscal quarters into ten deciles indexed from 0 to 9

and then divide the index by 9 so that RMFEj,t, the ranked surprise, ranges between 0 and 1.

Thus, the coefficient on RMFEj,t can be readily interpreted as the size-adjusted return one can

earn by taking a long position in the highest decile and a short positive in the lowest decile.

Other variables are as defined in the previous sections.

The results are presented in Table 6. Column (1) reports the pooled regression with the

base model which regresses SARj,t on RMFEj,t. The coefficient on RMFEj,t is 0.048,

indicating that on average, one can earn about 4.8% size-adjusted return during the sixty

trading days after the earnings announcements by taking the “post-earnings-announcement

trading strategy” with the sample used in this paper. The next column allows the coefficient

on RMFEj,t to vary with the percentage of responsive analysts that follow the firm. The

coefficient on RMFEj,t is significantly positive at 0.055, whereas that on RMFEj,t × FRESPj,t

is significantly negative at -0.022. This suggests that for firms that are followed by responsive

analysts only, the post-earnings-announcement drift is about 40% lower than for firms that are

followed by non-responsive analysts only.

Page 27: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

25

The last column confirms that this result is not subsumed by the effects of analysts’

firm-specific experience or analyst coverage. The results suggest that after controlling for

these effects, while the drift for firms that are followed by non-responsive analysts only can

be as high as 6.2%, it is more than one third lower if all analysts who follow the firm are

responsive to the earnings announcements in revising their forecasts. In terms of the control

variables, unlike the results presented in previous sections regarding EXPi,j,t or FEXPj,t, here

FEXPj,t has a significantly negative effect on the magnitude of the post-earnings-

announcement drift, consistent with the results in Mikhail et al. (2003b). Similarly,

NUMANAj,t also has a significantly negative effect, suggesting that the post-earnings-

announcement drift is smaller when the firm has a greater number of analysts following.

In sum, the results in Table 6 show that the post-earnings-announcement drift

decreases as the percentage of responsive analysts following the firm increases. This finding

supports the hypothesis that delayed responses by investors and/or analysts contribute to the

post-earnings-announcement drift.

5. Conclusion

Recently, a number of studies provide behavioral explanations for market

underreactions or overreactions. A common view of the behavioral explanations for

underreaction anomalies such as post-earnings-announcement drift proposes that investors are

slow in updating their expectations upon receiving information, i.e., the “delayed response”

hypothesis. Few studies, however, have provided direct evidence to support this view.

This study addresses this issue by focusing specifically on the speed at which analysts

respond to quarterly earnings announcements in revising their earnings forecasts for future

Page 28: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

26

quarters. To directly test the validity of the “delayed response” hypothesis as an explanation

for market underreaction, I also examine the effects of analysts’ responsiveness on market

underreaction to earnings announcements. The results show that more than half of analysts do

not react to earnings surprises instantaneously as the efficient market hypothesis predicts.

Further, analysts’ responsiveness mitigates both the extent of the positive serial correlation in

analyst forecast errors after the earnings announcements and the extent of the post-earnings-

announcement drift. Together, these results provide direct support for the “delayed response”

hypothesis and suggest it is indeed possible that investors’ cognitive incompetence leads to

underreaction anomalies such as the post-earnings-announcement drift.

Given the sophistication levels of security analysts, it is somewhat surprising that a

considerable number of analysts do not promptly adjust their earnings expectations upon the

earnings announcements. Additional analyses in this study suggest that the lack of prompt

reaction by the non-responsive analysts is not because they have information advantage over

the responsive analysts. On the contrary, they seem to in general have lower ability to forecast

accurately and to understand the implications of current earnings for future earnings. This

result sheds light on the importance to examining the responsiveness aspect of analysts

information processing, suggesting that analysts’ responsiveness can potentially be a good

indicator of their overall forecasting abilities. Future work could investigate economic factors

as well as behavioral factors that drive analysts’ responsiveness.

Page 29: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

27

REFERENCES

Abarbanell, Jeffery S., 1991, Do analysts’ forecasts incorporate information in prior stock price changes? Journal of Accounting and Economics 14, 147-165.

Abarbanell, Jeffery S., and Victor L. Bernard, 1992, Tests of analysts’ overreaction/ underreaction to earnings information as an explanation for anomalous stock price behavior, Journal of Finance 47, 1181-1207.

Bagnoli, Mark, Stanley, Levine, and Susan G. Watts, 2004, Analyst estimate revision clusters and corporate events. Working paper, Purdue University.

Ball, Ray, and Phillip Brown, 1968, An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers, Journal of Accounting Research 6, 159-178.

Barberis, Nicholas, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, 1998, A model of investor sentiment, Journal of Financial Economics 49, 307-343.

Bartov, Eli, Suresh Radhakrishnan, Itzhak Krinsky, 2000, Investor sophistication and patterns in stock returns after earnings announcements, The Accounting Review 75, 43-63.

Bernard, Victor L., and Jacob K. Thomas, 1989, Post-earnings-announcement drift: Delayed price response or risk premium? Journal of Accounting Research 27, 1-36.

Bernard, Victor L., and Jacob K. Thomas, 1990, Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings, Journal of Accounting and Economics 13, 305-340.

Chan, Louis K. C., Narasimhan Jegadeesh, and Josef Lakonishok, 1996, Momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 51, 1681-1713.

Conrad, Jennifer, Bradford Cornell, and Wayne R. Landsman, 2002, When is bad news really bad news? The Journal of Finance 57, 2507-2532.

Cooper, Rick A., Theodore E. Day and Craig M. Lewis, 2001, Following the leader: A study of individual analysts’ earnings forecasts, Journal of Financial Economics 61, 383-416.

Doyle, Jeffrey, Russell Lundholm, and Mark Soliman, 2003, The extreme future stock returns following extreme earnings surprises, Working paper, University of Michigan.

Easterwood, John C., and Stacey R. Nutt, 1999, Inefficiency in analysts’ earnings forecasts: Systematic misreaction or systematic optimism? Journal of Finance 54, 1777-1797.

Elgers, Pieter T., May H. Lo, and Ray J. Pfeiffer Jr., 2001, Delayed security price adjustments to financial analysts’ forecasts of annual earnings, The Accounting Review 76, 613-632.

Page 30: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

28

Fama, Eugene F., 1998, Market efficiency, long-term returns, and behavioral finance, Journal of Financial Economics 49, 283-306.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth French, 1997, Industry costs of equity, Journal of Financial Economics 43, 153-193.

Foster, George, Chris Olsen, and Terry Shevlin, 1984, Earnings releases, anomalies, and the behavior of securities returns, The Accounting Review 59, 574-603.

Francis, Jennifer, Katherine Schipper, and Linda Vincent, 2002, Expanded disclosures and the increased usefulness of earnings announcements, The Accounting Review 77, 515-546.

Fried, Dov, and Dan Givoly, 1982, Financial analysts' forecasts of earnings: A better surrogate for market expectations, Journal of Accounting and Economics 4, 85-107.

Hong, Harrison, Terence Lim, and Jeremy C. Stein, 2000, Bad news travels slowly: Size, analyst coverage, and the profitability of momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 55, 265-295.

Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein, 1999, A unified theory of underreactions, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets, Journal of Finance 54, 2143-2184.

Ivković, Zoran, and Narasimhan Jegadeesh, 2004, The timing and value of forecast and recommendation revisions, Journal of Financial Economics 73, 433-463.

Jiang, Guohua, Charles M. C. Lee, and Grace Y. Zhang, 2004, Information uncertainty and expected returns, Working paper, Peking University and Cornell University.

Liang, Lihong, 2003, Post-earnings-announcement drift and market participants’ information processing biases, Review of Accounting Studies 8, 321-345.

Mendenhall, Richard R., 1991, Evidence on the possible underweighting of earnings-related information, Journal of Accounting Research 29, 170-179.

Mikhail Michael B., Beverly R. Walther, and Richard H. Willis, 1997, Do security analysts improve their performance with experience? Journal of Accounting Research 35, 131-157.

Mikhail Michael B., Beverly R. Walther, and Richard H. Willis, 2003a, The effect of experience on security analyst underreaction, Journal of Accounting & Economics 35, 101-116.

Mikhail Michael B., Beverly R. Walther, and Richard H. Willis, 2003b, Security analyst experience and post-earnings-announcement drift, Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 18, 529-550.

Page 31: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

29

Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West, 1987, A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix, Econometrica 55, 703-708.

Richardson, Scott, Siew Hong Teoh, and Peter D. Wysocki, forthcoming, The walkdown to beatable analyst forecasts: The roles of equity issuance and insider trading incentives, Contemporary Accounting Research.

SAS Institute Inc., 1989. SAS/STAT User’s Guide (SAS Institute Inc., Cary, NC.).

Schipper, Katherine, 1991, Analysts’ forecasts, Accounting Horizons 5, 105-121.

Stickel, Scott E., 1989, The timing of and incentives for annual earnings forecasts near interim earnings announcements, Journal of Accounting and Economics 11, 275-292.

Page 32: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

30

Figure 1. Timeline of information events. Ej,t is the actual earnings per share for firm j quarter t. Fi,j,t is analyst i’s most recent forecast for firm j quarter t before the corresponding earnings announcement. Fi,j,t+1

a is analyst i’s most recent forecast for firm j quarter t+1 issued before the announcement of Ej,t. Fi,j,t+1

b is analyst i’s first forecast for firm j quarter t+1 issued after the announcement of Ej,t. Ej,t+1 is the actual earnings per share for firm j quarter t+1.

Latest Forecast for Quarter t: F i,j,t

Latest Forecast before day 0 for Quarter t+1: F i,j,t+1

a

First Forecast after day 0 for Quarter t+1: F i,j,t+1

b

Day 0: Earnings Announcement for Quarter t: E j,t

Earnings Announcement for Quarter t+1: E j,t+1

Page 33: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

31

0

20

40

60

80

100

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

Number of Calendar Days After the Earnings Announcements

Cum

ulat

ive

Perc

enta

ge

Figure 2. Timing of first forecast revision after the earnings announcements.

Page 34: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

32

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics

The sample includes 327,084 analyst-firm-quarters with fiscal period ending between 1988 and 2002, representing 103,681 firm-quarters. FEi,j,t=( Ej,t - Fi,j,t)/P and REVi,j,t+1=(Fi,j,t+1

b - Fi,j,t+1a)/P, where P is

firm j’s stock price at the end of fiscal quarter t. See Figure 1 for timeline and definitions of Ej,t, Fi,j,t, Fi,j,t+1

b, and Fi,j,t+1a.

# calendar days

[Ej,t, Fi,j,t+1b]

FEi,j,t × 100 REVi,j,t+1 × 100 Year # analyst- firm-quarter Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median

1988 4,485 33.18 27 -0.12 0.00 -0.11 -0.03 1989 5,531 30.41 23 -0.23 -0.06 -0.28 -0.11 1990 7,210 30.02 23 -0.22 -0.04 -0.40 -0.13 1991 9,807 30.17 24 -0.13 -0.02 -0.30 -0.10 1992 11,494 27.21 20 -0.09 0.00 -0.19 -0.06 1993 12,465 25.33 17 -0.08 0.00 -0.17 -0.06 1994 19,024 26.45 16 0.00 0.04 -0.12 -0.03 1995 21,763 24.01 13 -0.03 0.03 -0.17 -0.05 1996 23,547 23.61 11 -0.02 0.03 -0.19 -0.04 1997 27,196 22.73 8 0.00 0.03 -0.16 -0.04 1998 33,430 20.59 6 -0.03 0.02 -0.26 -0.06 1999 35,489 17.64 4 0.02 0.04 -0.18 -0.02 2000 36,236 17.02 3 0.03 0.04 -0.20 -0.03 2001 42,091 13.88 3 0.01 0.03 -0.26 -0.09 2002 a 37,316 12.69 2 0.05 0.05 -0.19 -0.05 Over All 327,084 20.32 7 -0.01 0.03 -0.21 -0.05

a Year 2002 has observations for three quarters only, due to the requirement for quarter t+1 information.

Page 35: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

33

Table 2. Analysts’ Responsiveness to Earnings Announcements

The sample includes 327,084 analyst-firm-quarters with fiscal period ending between 1988 and 2002, representing 103,681 firm-quarters. FEi,j,t=( Ej,t - Fi,j,t)/P, where P is firm j’s stock price at the end of fiscal quarter t. RESPi,j,t equals 1 if Fi,j,t+1

b is issued within two trading days after the announcement of Ej,t and 0 otherwise. FRESPj,t is the percentage of analysts with RESPi,j,t=1 among all analysts following firm j for the quarter t. See Figure 1 for timeline and definitions of Ej,t, Fi,j,t, Fi,j,t+1

a, and Fi,j,t+1b. Industries are

classified in accordance to Fama and French (1997). Panel A: Descriptive Statistics of Number of Calendar Days between Et and Ft+1

Mean Median STD P25 P75 All observations 20 7 25 2 31 Excluding obs. w/ FEi,j,t=0 20 7 24 2 30 Panel B: Analysts’ Responsiveness to Earnings Announcements—Analyst Level

RESPi,j,t=1 RESPi,j,t=0 All observations 43.67% 56.33% Excluding obs. w/ FEi,j,t=0 43.82% 56.18% Industries with highest percentage of responsive analysts a Electronic Equipment (8.29%) 56.01% 43.99% Measuring and Control Equipment (1.54%) 52.65% 47.35% Business Services (12.54%) 51.33% 48.67% Electrical Equipment (2.34%) 50.73% 49.27% Industries with lowest percentage of responsive analysts Chemicals (2.36%) 34.50% 65.50% Trading (3.49%) 37.51% 62.49% Automobiles and Trucks (1.72%) 37.72% 62.28% Food Products (1.37%) 38.15% 61.85%

Panel C: Analysts’ Responsiveness to Earnings Announcements—Firm Level FRESPj,t=1 0<FRESPj,t<

1FRESPj,t=0

All observations 18.42% 35.17% 46.41% a Only industries with at least one percent of analyst-firm-quarters in the sample that have highest or lowest percentage of responsive analysts are reported. Numbers in parentheses are the percentage of observations represented in the corresponding industries.

Page 36: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

34

Table 3. Descriptive Statistics Conditional on Analysts’ Responsiveness

The sample includes 327,084 analyst-firm-quarters with fiscal period ending between 1988 and 2002, representing 103,681 firm-quarters. FEi,j,t=(Ej,t - Fi,j,t)/P, AFEi,j,t=Abs(FEi,j,t), AFEi,j,t+1

a=Abs(Ej,t+1 - Fi,j,t+1

a)/P, and AFEi,j,t+1b=Abs(Ej,t+1 - Fi,j,t+1

b)/P, where P is firm j’s stock price at the end of fiscal quarter t. RESPi,j,t equals 1 if Fi,j,t+1

b is issued within two trading days after the announcement of Ej,t and 0 otherwise. EXPi,j,t is the number of quarters that analyst i has been following firm j by quarter t. AGEj,t is the number of years firm j has been included in the CRSP database as of the end of quarter t. LOGMVj,t is the log of market value of firm j as of the end of quarter t. NUMANAj,t is the number of analysts following firm j for quarter t. See Figure 1 for timeline and definitions of Ej,t, Fi,j,t, Fi,j,t+1

a, and Fi,j,t+1

b. Numbers in parentheses are two-sided p-values. For means, it is from t-test; for medians, it is from Wilcoxon test.

Mean Median RESPi,j,t=1 RESPi,j,t=0 RESPi,j,t=1 RESPi,j,t=0 # calendar days [Et, Ft+1

b] 2.50 34.13 2.00 27.00 (0.00) (0.00) AFEi,j,t 0.0025 0.0030 0.0010 0.0011 (0.00) (0.00) AFEi,j,t+1

a 0.0065 0.0075 0.0023 0.0027 (0.00) (0.00) AFEi,j,t+1

b 0.0045 0.0050 0.0013 0.0014 (0.00) (0.00) FEi,j,t 0.0002 -0.0004 0.0004 0.0002 (0.00) (0.00) EXPi,j,t 8.51 7.62 5.00 5.00 (0.00) (0.00) AGEj,t 15.64 16.12 11.00 13.00 (0.00) (0.00) LOGMVj,t 14.42 13.98 14.35 13.91 (0.00) (0.00) NUMANAj,t 7.60 5.56 6.00 4.00

(0.00) (0.00)

Page 37: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

35

Table 4. Analysts’ Responsiveness and Forecast Revisions

The sample includes 327,084 analyst-firm-quarters with fiscal period ending between 1988 and 2002, representing 103,681 firm-quarters. FEi,j,t= (Ej,t - Fi,j,t)/P and REVi,j,t+1=(Fi,j,t+1

b - Fi,j,t+1a)/P,

where P is firm j’s stock price at the end of fiscal quarter t. RESPi,j,t equals 1 if Fi,j,t+1b is issued

within two trading days after the announcement of Ej,t and 0 otherwise. EXPi,j,t is the number of quarters that analyst i has been following firm j by quarter t. NUMANAj,t is the number of analysts following firm j for quarter t. See Figure 1 for timeline and definitions of Ej,t, Fi,j,t, Fi,j,t+1

a, and Fi,j,t+1b. All regressions are estimated after deleting observations with absolute

studentised residuals greater than 2. Numbers in parentheses are two-sided p-values. They are based on t-statistics adjusted using the Newey and West (1987) procedure with six lags.

REVi,j,t+1 = β0 + β1FEi,j,t + β2 FEi,j,t × RESPi,j,t + β3RESPi,j,t + β4 FEi,j,t × EXPi,j,t + β5EXPi,j,t + β6 FEi,j,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (1)

Predicted Sign

(1) Pooled

(2) RESP=1

(3) RESP=0

(4) Pooled

(5) Pooled

Intercept -0.001 (0.00)

-0.001 (0.00)

-0.002 (0.00)

-0.002 (0.00)

-0.002 (0.00)

FEi,j,t + 0.486 (0.00)

0.528 (0.00)

0.457 (0.00)

0.458 (0.00)

0.402 (0.00)

FEi,j,t × RESPi,j,t + 0.071 (0.00)

0.047 (0.00)

RESPi,j,t ? 0.000 (0.00)

0.000 (0.00)

FEi,j,t × EXPi,j,t + 0.001 (0.24)

EXPi,j,t ? -0.00 (0.80)

FEi,j,t × NUMANAj,t + 0.013 (0.00)

NUMANAj,t ? 0.00 (0.45)

Adj. R-Squared 25.06% 28.93% 22.44% 25.25% 25.45%

Page 38: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

36

Table 5. Analysts’ Responsiveness and Analyst Underreaction

The sample includes 327,084 analyst-firm-quarters with fiscal period ending between 1988 and 2002, representing 103,681 firm-quarters. FEi,j,t= (Ej,t - Fi,j,t)/P, where P is firm j’s stock price at the end of fiscal quarter t. RESPi,j,t equals 1 if Fi,j,t+1

b is issued within two trading days after the announcement of Ej,t and 0 otherwise. FEi,j,t+1= (Ej,t+1 - Fi,j,t+1)/P, where Fi,j,t+1 equals Fi,j,t+1

b if RESPi,j,t equals 1 and Fi,j,t+1a

otherwise. EXPi,j,t is the number of quarters that analyst i has been following firm j by quarter t. NUMANAj,t is the number of analysts following firm j for quarter t. MFE j,t and MFE j,t+1 are firm-quarter means of FEi,j,t and FE i,j,t+1 respectively. FRESPj,t is the percentage of analysts with RESPi,j,t=1 among all analysts following firm j for the quarter t. FEXPj,t is median of EXPi,j,t for firm j quarter t. See Figure 1 for timeline and definitions of Ej,t, Ej,t+1, Fi,j,t, Fi,j,t+1

a, and Fi,j,t+1b. All regressions are

estimated after deleting observations with absolute studentised residuals greater than 2. Numbers in parentheses are two-sided p-values. They are based on t-statistics adjusted using the Newey and West (1987) procedure with six lags.

Panel A: Analyst Level Analysis

FEi,j,t+1 = β0 + β1FEi,j,t + β2FEi,j,t × RESPi,j,t + β3RESPi,j,t + β4FEi,j,t × EXPi,j,t + β5EXPi,j,t + β6FEi,j,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (2)

Predicted Sign

(1) Pooled

(2) RESP=1

(3) RESP=0

(4) Pooled

(5) Pooled

Intercept -0.002 (0.00)

-0.001 (0.00)

-0.003 (0.00)

-0.003 (0.00)

-0.002 (0.00)

FEi,j,t + 0.820 (0.00)

0.369 (0.00)

0.844 (0.00)

0.850 (0.00)

0.809 (0.00)

FEi,j,t × RESPi,j,t - -0.470 (0.00)

-0.482 (0.00)

RESPi,j,t ? 0.002 (0.00)

0.002 (0.00)

FEi,j,t × EXPi,j,t - 0.002 (0.00)

EXPi,j,t ? -0.000 (0.09)

FEi,j,t × NUMANAj,t - 0.006 (0.00)

NUMANAj,t ? -0.00 (0.16)

Adj. R-Squared 7.06% 8.61% 20.84% 19.73% 19.75%

Page 39: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

37

Panel B: Firm Level Analysis

MFEj,t+1 = β0 + β1MFEj,t + β2MFEj,t × FRESPj,t + β3FRESPj,t + β4MFEj,t × FEXPj,t + β5FEXPj,t + β6MFEj,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (3)

Predicted Sign

(1) Pooled

(2) Pooled

(3) Pooled

Intercept -0.002 (0.00)

-0.003 (0.00)

-0.003 (0.00)

MFEj,t + 0.722 (0.00)

0.849 (0.00)

0.767 (0.00)

MFEj,t × FRESPj,t - -0.423 (0.00)

-0.442 (0.00)

FRESPj,t ? 0.002 (0.00)

0.002 (0.00)

MFEj,t × FEXPj,t - 0.003 (0.23)

FEXPj,t ? -0.000 (0.65)

MFEj,t × NUMANAj,t - 0.036 (0.00)

NUMANAj,t ? -0.000 (0.25)

Adj. R-Squared 16.03% 17.63% 17.77%

Page 40: Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market …...Analysts’ Responsiveness and Market Underreaction to Earnings Announcements Yuan Zhang 611 Uris Hall, 3022 Broadway Columbia Business

38

Table 6. Analysts’ Responsiveness and Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift

The sample includes 327,084 analyst-firm-quarters with fiscal period ending between 1988 and 2002, representing 103,681 firm-quarters. SARj,t is size-adjusted buy-and-hold returns over sixty trading days since the 3rd trading day after the earnings announcement of firm j for quarter t. FEi,j,t= (Ej,t - Fi,j,t)/P, where P is firm j’s stock price at the end of fiscal quarter t. RMEFt is the decile of MFEt ranked by quarter and ranges from 0 to 1, where MFE j,t is firm-quarter means of FEi,j,t. FRESPj,t is the percentage of analysts with RESPi,j,t=1 among all analysts following firm j for the quarter t, where RESPi,j,t equals 1 if Fi,j,t+1

b is issued within two trading days after the announcement of Ej,t and 0 otherwise. FEXPj,t is median of EXPi,j,t for firm j quarter t, where EXPi,j,t is the number of quarters that analyst i has been following firm j by quarter t. NUMANAj,t is the number of analysts following firm j for quarter t. See Figure 1 for timeline and definitions of Ej,t, Fi,j,t, Fi,j,t+1

b, and Fi,j,t+1a. All regressions are

estimated after deleting observations with absolute studentised residuals greater than 2. Numbers in parentheses are two-sided p-values. They are based on t-statistics adjusted using the Newey and West (1987) procedure with six lags.

SARj,t = β0 + β1RMFEj,t + β2RMFEj,t × FRESPj,t + β3FRESPj,t + β4MFEj,t × FEXPj,t + β5FEXPj,t + β6MFEj,t × NUMANAj,t + β7NUMANAj,t (4)

Predicted Sign

(1) Pooled

(2) Pooled

(3) Pooled

Intercept -0.037 (0.00)

-0.041 (0.00)

-0.047 (0.00)

RMFEj,t + 0.048 (0.00)

0.055 (0.00)

0.062 (0.00)

RMFEj,t × FRESPj,t - -0.022 (0.00)

-0.021 (0.00)

FRESPj,t ? 0.014 (0.00)

0.014 (0.00)

RMFEj,t × FEXPj,t - -0.004 (0.01)

FEXPj,t ? 0.001 (0.00)

RMFEj,t × NUMANAj,t - -0.001 (0.34)

NUMANAj,t ? -0.001 (0.01)

Adjusted R-Squared 0.74% 0.77% 0.88%