boosting sharing economy: social welfare or revenue · pdf file ·...

13
Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang IIIS, Tsinghua Universiy, Beijing, China [email protected] Longbo Huang IIIS, Tsinghua Universiy, Beijing, China [email protected] ABSTRACT Product sharing over online platforms, or sharing economy, has become a growing trend and has the potential to mit- igate many social problems such as wasted products, idle resources, road congestions, and even greenhouse gas emis- sions. Despite its quick and successful development so far, there has been a lack of clear understanding about who is a better candidate for boosting sharing economy: government- like organizations who care about social welfare, or profit- driven entities who mainly focus on revenue? To investigate this problem, we propose a game-theoretic model among users participating in a sharing platform and analyze the social welfare under different platform pricing strategies. Specifically, we derive tight bounds of social wel- fare loss of the revenue maximization policy compared to social welfare maximization, and show that revenue maxi- mization leads to more sharing supply and ensures a better quality-of-service to users. We further conduct case studies and show the advantage of sharing over a common platform compared to separated sharing groups. Our numerical re- sults based on real data also show that, when the sharing demand/supply ratio is large, the revenue maximizing policy also achieves optimal social welfare. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to study social welfare with general user utility functions in sharing economy, and to compare the performance of different pric- ing policies. 1. INTRODUCTION Along with the rapid recent developments of internet and mobile technologies, sharing economy [1] (also known as col- laborative consumption) has emerged as an efficient way to utilize available resources. For example, Airbnb [30] for shar- ing rooms, Uber [3] and Lyft [2] for car sharing, and many bike sharing systems around the world served as part of city public transportation [29]. In fact, sharing economy attracts great amount of capital, which supports dozens of startups to chase the trend, as the revenue in the industry may reach ACM ISBN 978-1-4503-2138-9. DOI: 10.1145/1235 $3.5 billion this year according to Forbes [13]. Meanwhile, governments and many other non-profit organizations are eager to help develop sharing economy since it can “address social and economic challenges” [18], quoted from the British government’s response to the sharing economy. Among many factors that facilitates the great success of sharing economy, a very important one is that it enables ef- ficient usage of many resources that are essentially wasted: According to [27], the average time in use for cars in US and Europe is 8% and the average used time of an electric drill over its lifetime is 6-13 minutes by [6]. Data from European Environment Agency [11] also shows that the average num- ber of passengers per car is 1.58 in UK and 1.42 in Germany. One can enumerate many other kinds of resources remain idle in daily life: empty rooms, idle computing resources, etc. Due to the large quantity of these under-utilized re- sources, even a small improvement in utilization can result in great societal benefits. Indeed, UK parliament [26] es- timates that increasing the average utilization of cars to 2 passengers per car would save 17 billion tonnes of CO2. This is exactly the great potential of sharing economy. Due to its importance, there have been many works dis- cussing the definition, motivation, and development of shar- ing economy, e.g., [6], [17]. There are also concrete case studies, e.g., [23] on car sharing, phone minute sharing and bike sharing, and [30] on the impact of Airbnb to the hotel industry. Different from these prior works that mainly focus on qualitative assessments, in this paper, we try to provide an analytical framework for modeling sharing economy and for understanding how it can be effectively boosted. Specif- ically, we consider a general product-sharing system with a set of product owners and renters. The sharing platform reg- ulates sharing supply and demand by choosing an appropri- ate market price. Product owners and renters then decide on their own whether to share or rent, and determine their us- age level. Product owners receive monetary payments shar- ing their products, but spend maintenance costs, and all users obtain utility from using the products. Our goal is to understand the overall social welfare of the system and the quality-of-service (QoS) in sharing under two most common operation modes: social-welfare maximization, e.g., run by non-profit organizations, or revenue maximization, e.g., run by companies like Uber. This general framework captures various important aspects of sharing economy including user incentive, system efficiency, and QoS, a metrics that reflects both users’ satisfaction and resources utilization. Most prior works on sharing have focused on peer-to-peer (P2P) networks. For instance, [24] discusses the social wel- arXiv:1604.01627v2 [cs.GT] 6 Jul 2016

Upload: trankhanh

Post on 11-Mar-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or RevenueDriven?

Zhixuan FangIIIS, Tsinghua Universiy, Beijing, China

[email protected]

Longbo HuangIIIS, Tsinghua Universiy, Beijing, China

[email protected]

ABSTRACTProduct sharing over online platforms, or sharing economy,has become a growing trend and has the potential to mit-igate many social problems such as wasted products, idleresources, road congestions, and even greenhouse gas emis-sions. Despite its quick and successful development so far,there has been a lack of clear understanding about who is abetter candidate for boosting sharing economy: government-like organizations who care about social welfare, or profit-driven entities who mainly focus on revenue?

To investigate this problem, we propose a game-theoreticmodel among users participating in a sharing platform andanalyze the social welfare under different platform pricingstrategies. Specifically, we derive tight bounds of social wel-fare loss of the revenue maximization policy compared tosocial welfare maximization, and show that revenue maxi-mization leads to more sharing supply and ensures a betterquality-of-service to users. We further conduct case studiesand show the advantage of sharing over a common platformcompared to separated sharing groups. Our numerical re-sults based on real data also show that, when the sharingdemand/supply ratio is large, the revenue maximizing policyalso achieves optimal social welfare.

To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to studysocial welfare with general user utility functions in sharingeconomy, and to compare the performance of different pric-ing policies.

1. INTRODUCTIONAlong with the rapid recent developments of internet and

mobile technologies, sharing economy [1] (also known as col-laborative consumption) has emerged as an efficient way toutilize available resources. For example, Airbnb [30] for shar-ing rooms, Uber [3] and Lyft [2] for car sharing, and manybike sharing systems around the world served as part of citypublic transportation [29]. In fact, sharing economy attractsgreat amount of capital, which supports dozens of startupsto chase the trend, as the revenue in the industry may reach

ACM ISBN 978-1-4503-2138-9.

DOI: 10.1145/1235

$3.5 billion this year according to Forbes [13]. Meanwhile,governments and many other non-profit organizations areeager to help develop sharing economy since it can “addresssocial and economic challenges” [18], quoted from the Britishgovernment’s response to the sharing economy.

Among many factors that facilitates the great success ofsharing economy, a very important one is that it enables ef-ficient usage of many resources that are essentially wasted:According to [27], the average time in use for cars in US andEurope is 8% and the average used time of an electric drillover its lifetime is 6-13 minutes by [6]. Data from EuropeanEnvironment Agency [11] also shows that the average num-ber of passengers per car is 1.58 in UK and 1.42 in Germany.One can enumerate many other kinds of resources remainidle in daily life: empty rooms, idle computing resources,etc. Due to the large quantity of these under-utilized re-sources, even a small improvement in utilization can resultin great societal benefits. Indeed, UK parliament [26] es-timates that increasing the average utilization of cars to 2passengers per car would save 17 billion tonnes of CO2. Thisis exactly the great potential of sharing economy.

Due to its importance, there have been many works dis-cussing the definition, motivation, and development of shar-ing economy, e.g., [6], [17]. There are also concrete casestudies, e.g., [23] on car sharing, phone minute sharing andbike sharing, and [30] on the impact of Airbnb to the hotelindustry. Different from these prior works that mainly focuson qualitative assessments, in this paper, we try to providean analytical framework for modeling sharing economy andfor understanding how it can be effectively boosted. Specif-ically, we consider a general product-sharing system with aset of product owners and renters. The sharing platform reg-ulates sharing supply and demand by choosing an appropri-ate market price. Product owners and renters then decide ontheir own whether to share or rent, and determine their us-age level. Product owners receive monetary payments shar-ing their products, but spend maintenance costs, and allusers obtain utility from using the products. Our goal is tounderstand the overall social welfare of the system and thequality-of-service (QoS) in sharing under two most commonoperation modes: social-welfare maximization, e.g., run bynon-profit organizations, or revenue maximization, e.g., runby companies like Uber. This general framework capturesvarious important aspects of sharing economy including userincentive, system efficiency, and QoS, a metrics that reflectsboth users’ satisfaction and resources utilization.

Most prior works on sharing have focused on peer-to-peer(P2P) networks. For instance, [24] discusses the social wel-

arX

iv:1

604.

0162

7v2

[cs

.GT

] 6

Jul

201

6

Page 2: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

fare under assumption of linear supply and demand, andquadratic utility. [15] and [22] study the equilibrium ei-ther under quasi linear utility or simple discrete strategiesset. Outside the peer-to-peer area, a recent work [16] con-siders user’s network usage and social welfare under pricesset by a platform and focuses on the network congestionproblem. [7] studies social welfare and a sharing platform’sstrategy with linear user utility, and focuses on how usersdecide to purchase products. However, our work is differentfrom the aforementioned works in the following: (i) we con-sider a sharing platform that regulates sharing and demandvia pricing, while most previous works in network resourcessharing do not consider pricing, (ii) in our model, productowners can also benefit from personal usage of the product,whereas existing works often neglect this part, (iii) we con-sider general concave user utility functions, while prior worksoften adopt a specific form of utility functions, and (iv) wepropose a novel QoS metric for product sharing, which cap-tures the “wasted supply” of owners, e.g., Uber cars runningwithout customers, while existing works have not discussedthis aspect.

The main contributions of the paper are summarized asfollows.

• We propose a general modeling framework for study-ing the sharing economy. Our model captures variousimportant aspects including user incentive, QoS andsystem efficiency.

• Focusing on general concave user utility functions, weestablish the existence of market equilibrium and pro-vide tight bounds of social welfare loss under the rev-enue maximizing policy compared to social welfare max-imization. We also show that the revenue maximiza-tion policy guarantees more sharing supply, and en-sures a better QoS compared to social welfare maxi-mization.

• We study two classic cases where utility functions arelinear and quadratic. We show that under linear util-ity, sharing over a common sharing platform can achievea higher social welfare compared to sharing inside mul-tiple isolated groups.

• We conduct numerical simulations based on real datafrom DiDi [5], the biggest car sharing platform in China.Our results show that the social welfare loss underrevenue maximization quickly decreases to zero as therenter-owner ratio increases (scarce resource). We alsoshow that a moderate product usage cost can lead toboth high QoS and low resource idle rate. This resultimplies that a government-like organization can alsoimprove sharing by choosing a proper usage cost, e.g.,choosing tax or gasoline price for car usage.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2,we provide two examples of sharing and discuss common fea-tures of them. Section 3 introduces our system model. Sec-tion 4 provides main results of this paper, including analysisof social welfare, supply and demand properties under dif-ferent pricing policies. Section 5 studies two typical cases insharing based on the results in the previous section. Section6 provides simulation results and discussions. Conclusionscome at last in section 7.

2. EXAMPLES

Among the thriving sharing industries, we take two com-mon cases as examples. The first one is car sharing. Compa-nies like Uber, Zipcar, RelayRides provide car sharing ser-vices. Zipcar provides their own cars for sharing, while theother two match car owners and renters via online platform.In the case of Uber, car owners put their cars online for sharewhen they want to, while renters applied for cars throughUber’s platform, and rents are charged by distances or dura-tion time of use. The other example is house sharing: hostsput their available rooms online and guests can book themvia online platform, e.g., Airbnb.

The same pattern of these online sharing is that, productowner shares his products by putting some portion of them(part of the product or part of the usage time) availableonline, and he can use what is left of the product by himself.Owner’s problem is to decide how much amount of productto put online for share, e.g., a driver may share 100% usagetime of his car when the renting price is really high, or 0%if the profit is lower than his cost. He earns income bydoing so, but also pays a maintenance cost, and can facecompetitions in getting renters due to other owners’ sharingactions. As for renters, they pay as they rent the products.

3. MODEL

3.1 Owners and RentersConsider a product sharing system that consists of two

groups of users: product owners denoted by the set O, andrenters denoted by R, with NO = |O|, NR = |R| denotingthe numbers of owners and renters.

For each user i ∈ O∪R, we normalize his maximum usageof the product to be 1, e.g., product usage frequency. Then,we use ui ∈ [0, 1] to denote one’s usage of the product, e.g.,fraction of time one uses his own/rented car. If user i is aproduct owner, we also use si ∈ [0, 1] to denote the level atwhich he shares the product, e.g., drives it as a Uber car.Note that we always have ui + si ∈ [0, 1].

Note that with ui, si ∈ [0, 1], our model can be viewed asconsidering the average usage over a period of time. This isdifferent from using a realtime supply and demand model,and facilitates the quantification of long-term sharing be-havior of users in the market.

3.2 Sharing Demand and SupplyWe assume that sharing takes place over a platform, e.g.,

Uber. In this platform, renters pay the market renting pricefor using cars from owners. The market price P is set bythe sharing platform. Depending on their own usage prefer-ences, desire to share products, and the renting price, userschoose their own ui and si (si for product owners only) val-ues, which result in different demand and supply conditionsin the system.

We denote the total sharing supply S(P ) and demandD(P ) (renting demand) of the market under price P as thesum of owners’ sharing levels and the sum of renters’ usagelevels, respectively. That is,

S(P ) =∑i∈O

si(P ), D(P ) =∑i∈R

ui(P ). (1)

3.3 User UtilityFor each user i ∈ O ∪ R, we denote Ui(ui) his self-use

utility of using the product, e.g., personal satisfaction. The

Page 3: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

Ui(ui) is unrevealed to others. In this paper, we make thefollowing assumption about Ui(ui).

Assumption 1. For each i, Ui is a continuous and strictlyconcave function in ui with Ui(0) = 0. Moreover, Ui’sderivative at ui = 0 exists and is bounded.

Note that the concavity and continuity assumption is generaland is commonly adopted when studying system utilities,e.g., [28] and [21], while bounding the derivative at zero isfor the convenience of proofs without loss of generality.

In addition to usage utilities, monetary transactions onthe platform also affect users’ overall utility as follows, e.g.,product owners can profit from sharing their product whilerenters will pay for their usage.

To be specific, product owner will gain utility from bothhis self-use and the income of sharing his product, mean-while he will suffer from product’s maintenance cost, i.e.,the overall utility obtained by an owner is:

Wi(ui, si) = Ui(ui) + P min{D(P )

S(P ), 1}si − cui − csi (2)

Here Ui(ui) is i’s self-use utility and cui+csi is maintenancecost, where c is a universal constant representing the usagecost per unit, e.g., gasoline, tolls, or house keeping.

P min{D(P )S(P )

, 1}si in (2) is owner i’s sharing income. The

term min{D(P )S(P )

, 1} is introduced to captured the fact that

in practice, it is typical that a certain percentage of owner’ssharing levels will not generate any income, especially whenthe total demand is less than the supply. For instance, thetime a Uber driver spends driving around waiting for cus-tomer’s order, or the time an Airbnb room provider spends

keeping his apartment empty. In other word, min{D(P )S(P )

, 1}can be treated as the probability that an owner meets acustomer.

Interestingly, the term min{D(P )S(P )

, 1} in (2) is a also na-

ture indicator of quality-of-service (QoS) in sharing: a

lower D(P )S(P )

value implies a higher service quality to cus-

tomers, as it reflects a lower difficulty level for renters torent a product. Indeed, if we intuitively imagine that thesystem operates according to an M/M/1 queueing model,with D(P ) being the arrival rate (demand) and S(P ) beingthe service rate (supply), then the expected delay for rentersis equal to 1

S(P )−D(P ). As a result, a lower D(P )/S(P ) value

indicates a smaller service delay.1 That is to say, the item

P min{D(P )S(P )

, 1} can also be seem as the QoS-weighted mar-

ket price, i.e., when the service quality is low (D(P )S(P )

is close

to 1), the “effective price” P min{D(P )S(P )

, 1} seen by owners

becomes relatively high, and this attracts more supplies.Note that the denominator of S(P ) includes every owner’s

contribution in sharing. Due to this coupling among sharingowners, the problem becomes indeed a game among users(after the sharing price P is set).

As for renters, they have to pay the renting price P perunit usage for using the product. Hence, the overall utilitya renter obtains with product usage ui is given by

Wi(ui) = Ui(ui)− uiP. (3)

1The fraction of time the server is busy in the M/M/1 queueis exactly D(P )/S(P ).

Therefore renter i will choose his demand independently ac-cording to his own overall utility function. When total de-mand exceeds total supply, some renters may not be able toget access to products and thus obtain zero utility. Thereare three reasons that we use independent demand deci-sion instead of putting a similar “discount factor” such asmin{S(P )/D(P ), 1} in renter’s utility functions to capturethe fraction of time a renter actually gets served:

• Renters’ independence. Product owner can choosetheir self-use amount and sharing amount based onthe expected payoff when he put his product onlinefor share, while renters in real world usually apply forshared product on demand, which is independently de-cided, similar independent setting can be found in [8].

• Short term behavior. Product owner can be seenas long term participators in the sharing platform whovalue long term expected payoff. By contrast, renterscan be seen as “one shot” comers who only care aboutwhether they can get access to the product “this time”,e.g., one may immediately try taxi or subway if hecan not get served through Uber, therefore setting hisutility gained from sharing platform to be zero is moremeaningful to be a long term average.

• most importantly, using (3) does not lose any general-ity, as we will prove that in the cases of interests, i.e.,revenue maximization and social welfare maximiza-tion, supply always exceeds demand. That is, evenwe add a factor min{S(P )/D(P ), 1} in renters’ utilityfunction, we will still have min{S(P )/D(P ), 1} = 1 inthe two cases we discuss in this paper.

3.4 User’s Response and Platform’s PolicyGiven the utility functions (3) and (2), under a market

price P , each owner chooses his usage and amount of shareby maximizing his utility, i.e., choosing u∗i (P ) and s∗i (P ) bysolving the following optimization problem:

maxui,si

Wi(ui, si) (4)

s.t. ui ≥ 0, si ≥ 0, si + ui ≤ 1

and each renter choose u∗i (P ) similarly by maximizing hisutility (3).

3.5 System ObjectiveUnder a given market price P , we say that the market

reaches a Nash equilibrium when each owner is executinghis best response action, i.e., the solution of problem (4).The platform’s objective is to find an optimal market priceto maximize certain given objective function when the mar-ket is at a Nash equilibrium (if it exists). For example, amaximum social welfare policy maximizes user’s social wel-fare at the Nash equilibrium.

In this paper, we focus on two important objectives thatare commonly studied, revenue maximization and social wel-fare maximization. They represent two dominant modes un-der which sharing economy can be operated, i.e., governmentor non-profit organization driven, and revenue-driven. Weare interested in understanding how the system behaves un-der these two objectives.

3.6 Remarks

Page 4: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

A few remarks are in place for our model. First of all,the setting of fixed identities for owners and renters is basedon the assumption that users’ identities do not change fre-quently.2 Second, only assuming concavity of the utilityfunctions makes our framework and results very general. Infact, most of the main results in this paper, e.g., Theorem 3,are derived based only on this assumption and are indepen-dent of the form and parameters of each individual’s utilityfunction.

4. SHARING ANALYSISIn this section, we present our results. To facilitate read-

ing, all detailed proofs are presented in the appendices andadditional technical report [4].

4.1 Market EquilibriumWe first establish the existence of market equilibrium un-

der any fixed sharing price. This result is critical, as theexistence allows subsequent studies about the market per-formance.

Theorem 1. Nash equilibrium exists among all users inO for any given market price P .

The theorem is proved by showing that each owner’s utilityfunction is continuous in everyone’s strategy and is concavein his own strategy. Note that according to (3), renters de-cide their levels of demand to the platform independently,considering only their own utilities and the market price.That is, demand request is fixed given price P , and theoverall payoff is (3) if they get served. However, it can hap-pen that under certain equilibria (determined by P ), theresulting total supply is less than the total demand, i.e.,S(P ) < D(P ). In this case the actual utility a renter getsin practice is different from that determined by (3), as he isnot even served. Fortunately, in two cases of interest in thispaper, we show that this will never happen, i.e., for both rev-enue and social welfare maximization, we have S(P ) ≥ D(P )at the equilibria.

4.2 Social Welfare and Revenue MaximizationIn this section, we look at the aggregate social welfare un-

der two different market price mechanisms that correspondto two types of platform providers, i.e., government-like or-ganizations who care about maximizing total social welfare,and companies who are after maximum revenue. Our goalis to understand the differences of user behavior and systemperformance under these two modes.

We start with social welfare maximization. To thisend, we define the aggregate social welfare as follows:

W (P ) =∑i∈O

Wi(u∗i , s∗i ) +

∑i∈R′

W (u∗i ) (5)

Here R′ denotes the set of renters who are actually served(when D(P ) > S(P ), some renters may not be able to meetan owner). Notice here that the welfare is defined over allpossible uniform price policies. We adopt this definition to

2The assumption is reasonable: for renters, buying andmaintaining products, e.g., cars, will cost much more thanrenting, especially when the product is not frequently used;for owners, they have already paid for the cars, sharing thecars can lower their costs, as long as the price can cover theircost.

avoid unfair comparisons with welfare maximization policieswith non-uniform prices, i.e., different charges can be set todifferent users in the system, e.g., [25]. Maximum social

welfare policy is to maximize W (P ) by choosing optimal P .The revenue maximization case is to maximize the vol-

ume of trade defined as follows;

V (P ) = P min{D(P ), S(P )}. (6)

The adoption of this objective is motivated by the fact thatin many sharing systems, the platform obtains a transactionfee from each successful business event, e.g., Uber chargesits drivers 20% commission fee [19]. Thus, maximizing thetrading volume is equivalent to maximizing the companyrevenue.

We first present a few propositions to describe some basicfeatures of demand and supply in the market. They alsoserve as preliminaries for later theorems.

Proposition 1. The total demand D(P ) is non-increasingin the market renting price P and total demand eventuallybecomes 0 when P is high enough.

Proposition 1 is intuitive, since renters’ decisions are inde-pendent and are guided by objective (3). Thus, as the priceincreases, each renter will cut down his demand.

Proposition 2. There exists some 0 < Pc ≤ Pupper,such that (i) S(P ) is non-decreasing when P ≤ Pc, (ii)S(P ) ≥ D(P ), when P ∈ [Pc, Pupper], and (iii) S(P ) = 0,when P ≥ Pupper.

Some intuition about Pupper and Pc in Proposition 2 is inplace. First, if we increase P from zero, supply will con-tinue to increase as long as supply is less than demand.However, as supply increases, it eventually exceeds demandand competition among owners becomes more and more in-tense. Then when the price is higher than some thresh-

old price Pupper, resulting inPupperD(Pupper)

S(Pupper)= c, no owner

will share any more since the profit can not even cover thecost. Second, the price Pc is the lowest market clearingprice: Pc = min{P |D(P ) = S(P )}. However, establishingits existence requires showing the continuity of S(P ) at thedemand-supply intersection point and is nontrivial.

From Proposition 2, we see that when the market rentingprice is low such that D(P ) > S(P ), some renters may notbe able to rent a product, complicating the analysis of theaggregate social welfare. Fortunately, we prove in the fol-lowing proposition that both the social welfare maximizerand revenue maximizer guarantee that the supply exceedsdemand, i.e., S(P ) ≥ D(P ).

Proposition 3. Let Psw denote the market price whichmaximizes social welfare (5) and Pr denote the market pricewhich maximizes revenue (6). We have S(Psw) ≥ D(Psw)and S(Pr) ≥ D(Pr).

Proposition 3 guarantees that renters have enough supply atPr and Psw. Therefore, all renters will get served. Hence,R′ = R in (5), and that V (P ) = P ·D(P ) at Pr and Psw.

After the above propositions, we now have our first maintheorem.

Theorem 2. We have following results with respect toPsw and Pr:• lowest market clearing price P ′ maximizes aggregate

social welfare, i.e., Psw = P ′, and

Page 5: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

• maximum revenue price is higher than maximum socialwelfare prie: Pr ≥ Psw;

• The total sharing supply under revenue maximizationis no less than that under social welfare maximiza-tion, i.e., S(Pr) ≥ S(Psw), where Pr and Psw are therevenue maximizing price and the welfare maximizingprice, respectively.

It is interesting to note that revenue maximization ori-ented sharing actually encourages more supply from owners.The reason is that the pursuit of trading volume is consis-tent with owners’ interests. Thus, this objective increasestheir enthusiasm on sharing. To be specific, the “effective

price” P D(P )S(P )

seen by an owner has the numerator exactly

the form of trading volume, therefore higher trading volumemagnifies“effective price”, which stimulates supply. Anotherinteresting point is that a higher sharing amount does notimply a higher social welfare. Take car sharing as an ex-ample, a higher sharing amount at higher price may leadto more empty running cars and result in lower utility foreveryone.

Despite different prices and supply under these two cases,the following theorem bounds the social welfare loss underthe maximum revenue policy.

Theorem 3. The social welfare gap between the maxi-mum social welfare policy and a maximum revenue policyis bounded by:

0 ≤ W (Psw)− W (Pr) ≤ Pr[D(Psw)−D(Pr)S(Psw)

S(Pr)].

Moreover, the bounds are tight.

Here W (Pr) denotes the aggregate social welfare (5) underthe revenue-maximizing price Pr. Theorem 3 states thatmaximum revenue policies are “good enough,” in the sensethat their social welfare losses are bounded. One impor-tant feature of the gap is that it can be easily evaluated bythird-party organizations who are interested, e.g., govern-ment, without the necessity to know user’s private utilityfunctions, i.e., it only depends on the total demand andsupply under prices Pr and Psw. The tightness result willbe demonstrated by examples in section 5.

Our next main result is an immediate corollary of Theo-rem 3. We decide to make it a theorem due to its impor-tance.

Theorem 4. The QoS at Pr is higher than the QoS at

Psw, i.e., D(Psw)S(Psw)

≥ D(Pr)S(Pr)

.

Theorem 4 shows an interesting result that, in addition toproviding a bounded loss in social welfare, the revenue maxi-mizing approach also guarantees a better QoS for customers.

4.3 RobustnessIn this subsection, we investigate the robustness of our

results to the heterogeneity of users. Specifically, we assumethat each owner i may have different costs for sharing andpersonal usage, denoted by ci,s and ci,u, respectively, andthat users can have different preferences on sharing, e.g., the

effective price seen by an altruist maybe P ·(D(P )S(P )

+εi), ε > 0,

which is always higher than P · D(P )S(P )

. Similarly, εi < 0

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 450

50

100

150

200 Demand Supply Supply Revenue

Price

Dem

and

0

200

400

600

800

1000

Rev

enue

Pr(✏ = 0)Pr(✏ = 0.5)

(✏ = 0)(✏ = 0.5)

Figure 1: Since Pr will only be chosen in the inter-val where supply is no less than demand, under thesetting in Section 6.3, setting price at Pr(ε = 0.5) canobtain more revenue than Pr(ε = 0).

means that a user is not very willing to share.3 Therefore,an owner’s utility function becomes:

Wi(ui, si) = Ui(ui) + P (min{D(P )

S(P ), 1}+ εi)si (7)

−ci,uui − ci,ssi.

In this case, we have the following result indicating model’srobustness:

Theorem 5. Under the owner’s utility of (7), though Pr,Psw and supply may be different, all theorems above stillhold.

Theorem 5 shows that our results indeed hold for a moregeneral class of scenarios, where (i) owners can have differ-ent usage costs (captured by ci,u), due to product diversity,e.g., SUVs may cost more gasoline than sedans, (ii) own-ers can have different endurance levels to the wear and tearcosts due to renter’s use, or the moral hazard because ofrenter’s potential abusive use (captured by ci,s), as consid-ered in [20] and [7], (iii) owners have different preferencestowards sharing (captured by εi), i.e., being revenue-drivenor altruistic.

A positive ε for product owners can help lower Pr sincesupply altruists provide more supply. Note that this is cru-cial for platform to obtain higher revenue, as shown in Fig.1(with 200 renters and 120 owners, see 6.3 for detail settings),since Pr will only be chosen in the interval where supply isno less than demand, Pr(ε = 0) = Pc(ε = 0) = 13 andPr(ε = 0.5) = Pc(ε = 0) = 12, here Pc is the market clear-ing price. That is, according to the revenue curve in thisexample, a positive ε can increase supply and help platformgain more revenue.

5. CASE STUDYIn this section, we present two concrete cases to demon-

strate our results. Specifically, we consider the linear usageutility and quadratic usage utility. These two scenarios arecommonly adopted in social welfare analysis, see [7] [16].Though linear function is not strictly concave, we find thatour results also fit well here. Moreover, we show that inthese two cases, the bound in Theorem 3 is tight.

3It can also capture the case when users can have incorrectperception about the fraction of time he gets customers.

Page 6: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

5.1 Linear Usage PayoffConsider the case when each user’s payoff is linear, where

αi is the private value of user i.

Ui(ui) = αiui, ∀i ∈ O,R (8)

In this case, owners i’s best response is choosing either toshare his car all the time (si = 1) or to use his car all thetime (ui = 1), depending on whether his private value αiis lower or higher than the market price. Similarly, renter iwill choose to request either full use of a car (ui = 1) or zerodemand (ui = 0), depending on whether his private valueαi is higher or lower than the market price.

Without loss of generality, suppose no users have the sameprivate value. We label all users, including owners andrenters, ranked and labeled by their private value:

α1 > α2 > ... > αNR+NO (9)

5.1.1 Algorithm of AllocationWe now give a concrete maximum social welfare policy.

Proposition 4. The maximum social welfare price is setsuch that users (including owners and renters) of the firstNO highest private value αi get full use of the product (ui =1).

Note that this is the best possible arrangement for maximiz-ing social welfare, since all users with higher private valuesget access to products. In this case, demand equals sup-ply and none of the products are wasted, e.g., no cars arerunning empty.

Below, we also check the performance of the bound wegive in Theorem 3. Specifically, we show that the boundgiven in Theorem 3 is tight between maximum social welfareand maximum revenue policies under linear usage payoff.

We consider the following concrete example in car sharing.Suppose NR = NO = 3. Each owner’s and renter’s privatevalue is showed in Table 1.

Table 1: Example 1 of social welfare gap bound’stightness

Ranking of private value Owners Renters1 5 4 + ε > 42 2 1.53 1 0.5

From Proposition 4, let c = 0.01,the maximum social wel-fare price is Psw ∈ (1.5, 2), letting renter r1 use owner o3’scar and owners o1, o2 use their own cars. The trade vol-ume is 1 ·Psw ∈ (1.5, 2) and the social welfare is 11 + ε− 3c.Meanwhile, the maximum revenue price Pr will be 4+ε suchthat only renter r1 can rent a car and owners o2, o3 sharetheir cars all the time. The trade volume is 4 + ε and thesocial welfare is 9 + ε− 3c.

Thus, the social welfare gap between these two policies is

W (Psw) − W (Pr) = 2, and the bound given by Theorem 3

is W (Psw)− W (Pr) ≤ Pr[D(Psw)−D(Pr)S(Psw)S(Pr)

] = 2 + ε2.

Since ε is infinitely small, the bound is tight.

5.1.2 Understanding the Social Welfare Loss BoundWe further interpret the welfare loss bound in the linear

utility case. First, we rewrite the welfare loss as follows.

W (Psw)− W (Pr) ≤ Pr[D(Psw)−D(Pr)S(Psw)

S(Pr)]

=Pr[D(Psw)−D(Pr)] + PrD(Pr)

S(Pr)[S(Pr)− S(Psw)] (10)

The first item of (10) is an upper bound for the utility lossof renters, since D(Psw) − D(Pr) is exactly the number ofrenters who request for a full use of cars at Psw but de-mand nothing at Pr and Pr is the upper bound of theserenters’ private values. Similarly, the second item is the up-per bound of the utility loss of owners since S(Pr)−S(Psw)is exactly the number of owners who provide zero sharing atPsw but share all their products at Pr under risk of meeting

no renters, and PrD(Pr)S(Pr)

is the upper bound of these owners’

private values.

5.1.3 Power of AggregationHere we also discuss the platform’s contribution, by com-

paring the system to the one without the platform. In thatcase, users are separated into many groups, e.g., people livenearby group together to share with each other. Such shar-ing groups are difficult to grow since they are mainly basedon location, or relationship etc. Let J denote the set of allisolated sharing groups.

We optimistically suppose each small sharing group canreach a contract price which maximizes the social welfare in-side the group. We will show that even in this case, maximiz-ing social welfare among all users over the platform achieveshigher social welfare. To do so, let the maximum social wel-fare price of small group J ∈ J be PJ . Then, the totalsocial welfare can be computed by the sum of each isolatedsharing group’s utility, each of which is at their maximum

social welfare price, i.e., Wiso =∑J∈J

∑i∈J WJ(PJ).

The contribution of a sharing platform is to bring differentpeople into one whole group so that all renters can accessto all owner’s products. The following theorem guaranteesthat a platform can achieve a higher social welfare comparedto having multiple small isolated sharing groups.

Theorem 6. When users’ utility functions are linear, shar-ing over a common platform achieves a higher social welfare

than having isolated sharing groups, i.e., W (Psw) ≥ Wiso

This theorem is straightforward since the policy showed inProposition 4 gives the best possible social welfare, and sep-arated groups can only degenerate the performance. Forexample, consider users showed in Table 1 again. If usersare divided into two groups, group 1 includes {o1, o2, r1}and group 2 includes {o3, r2, r3}, maximum social welfare ofgroup 1 and group 2 will be 9 + ε − 2c and 1 − c, which isless than the social welfare showed in 5.1.1.

5.2 Quadratic Usage PayoffIn this subsection, we study the case when each user’s

usage utility is a quadratic function:

Ui(ui) = −aiu2i + biui, ai, bi > 0, ∀i ∈ O,R (11)

Under quadratic usage payoff, each renter’ best response de-mand is bi−P

2ai, which means the total demand is a descending

piecewise linear function.Similar to the linear utility case, we present an example

where the bound given in Theorem 3 is tight. Considerthe following example. Let NO = NR = 1 and their ai, biparameters are given in Table 2.

As proved in Proposition 3, we only consider the casewhen S(P ) ≥ D(P ). Under this setting, renter’s demand

Page 7: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

Table 2: Example 2 of social welfare gap bound’stightness

identity Ui(ui)

owner o Uo(uo) = −u2o + 2uo

renter r Ur(ur) = −u2r + ur

will be 1−P2

. As for the owner, he will have no desire toprovide supply more than the demand since there is nocompetition. Thus, demand equals supply. Let c = 0, theowner’s best responses will be to fully utilize the product,i.e., uo + so = 1. Hence, the owner’s utility function isWo = −u2

o+ 2uo+P min{D, so} and uo+ so = 1. Thereforeowner’s best response will always be choosing so = D anduo = 1− so.

A revenue maximizer will maximize the volume of trade,i.e., PD(P ) = P 1−P

2, which yields the optimal revenue price

Pr = 12. A social welfare maximizer, instead, will maximize

the total social welfare:

W = Wo +Wr

= [−(1− 1− P2

)2 + 2(1− 1− P2

) + P1− P

2] +

(1− P )2

4,

which also gives Psw = 12.

As a result, both policies use the same price, which leadsto the same demand and supply. The bound given in The-

orem 3 is Pr[D(Psw) −D(Pr)S(Psw)S(Pr)

] = 0, which is tight in

this example.

6. EXPERIMENTIn this section, we conduct numerical experiments to val-

idate the results in this paper, on both generated data andreal data. In addition, we also discuss some insights deliv-ered by simulations.

6.1 Simulation SetupIn 6.2, we conduct simulation on generated data with

quadratic usage payoff. A few different parameter settingsare examined. All user usage utility functions Ui(ui) are setto be quadratic functions here, i.e., Ui(ui) = −aiu2

i + biuiwith ai, bi > 0. This is because quadratic utilities provideboth tractability and representativeness, since quadratic func-tions can be seen as second order approximations for concavefunctions under Taylor expansion. Specifically, each user’sai, bi are uniformly chosen from (0.1, 1.2) and (0, 1).

In 6.3, we use real data from DiDi [5], the biggest car shar-ing platform in China. Data includes transaction recordson the first three weeks in January, 2016, inside a Chinesecity, including driver ID, passenger ID, starting district ID,destination district ID and fee on each ride. We choose touse data on Jan 8th randomly, which includes 395938 orderrecords.

In searching Nash Equilibrium, we use best response it-eration, which turns out to be a fast converging algorithmunder our setting.

6.2 Results on Quadratic Usage Payoff

6.2.1 Supply-Demand RelationshipHere we consider the tightness of social welfare loss bound

(Theorem 3) under different supply-demand relationship.That is, we set number of owner to be 100 and compare

1 0 0 2 0 0 3 0 0 4 0 0 5 0 0 6 0 00

2

4

6

8

1 0

Socia

l Welf

are G

ap

R e n t e r s

N u m e r c i a l R e s u l t s T h e o r e t i c a l U p p e r B o u n d

Figure 2: As the ratio of renters and owners grows,both the theoretical upper bound and simulation re-sult decrease to 0.

the social welfare gaps from numerical results and theoreti-cal bounds under different renter numbers.

It is clearly showed in Fig.2 that when the number ofrenters increases, the social welfare gap decreases to zero.There are two important implications that we want to pointout: (i) with the growth of renter population, the theoreticalbound not only provides an upper bound of actual socialwelfare loss, but also an accurate estimation, (ii) when therenter population is a few times more than owners, whichis common in real world scenarios, maximum revenue policyalso achieves maximum social welfare.

Intuitively, this is because when the resources becomescarce, a maximum social welfare policy will first satisfy theneeds of renters with higher utilities, which is the same aswhat a maximum revenue policy will do. In other words,when resources are scarce, a revenue maximization platformrun by company simultaneously guarantees maximum socialwelfare.

6.2.2 Psw and Pr

Here we compare Psw and Pr under different settings, e.g.,different cost or different degree of scarcity of the products.From Fig.3(a), Psw and Pr are stable when c is low, butalong with the cost increment, Psw increases quickly towardsPsw and eventually becomes the same when c is high enough.Compare the results in 6.3.2 and Fig.3(a), if the cost can bechosen properly, say c = 0.3, one can both keep a low priceand low wastage rate.

Different degree of product scarcity also influences Pswand Pr. When resources become scarce, as show in Fig.3(b),Psw rapidly increases towards Pr, that is because when thereis insufficient supply, a maximum social welfare policy alsoneeds to guarantee the usage of renters with higher utilities,which is the same as what a maximum revenue policy willdo. Therefore, it is reasonable that when supply is abundant(Fig.3(c)), Psw becomes much lower than Pr: a maximumsocial welfare policy wants to let more people get access toidle resources while a maximum revenue policy still focuseson high value clients.

6.3 Results on Real DataWe also conduct experiment based on real data from DiDi.

Since data are transaction records on Jan 8, 2016, we use thestatistical volume of transaction at different prices to repre-sent renters’ demand under different prices. Total demandcurve is fitted to exponential function D(P ) = αe−βPwith

Page 8: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.60.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

Price

C

P_SW P_rPsw

Pr

(a) Psw and Pr basically remain un-changed when c is low, and Psw is ap-proaching Pr when c is high. NO = 100,NR = 300,

0 200 400 600 800 10000.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

Price

Renters

P_{sw} P_rPr

Psw

(b) When resources becomes scarce, Pswtends toward Pr. NO = 100, c = 0.1.

200 400 600

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Price

Owners

P_{sw} P_rPr

Psw

(c) When resources becomes abundant,Psw will become lower than Pr. NR =500, c = 0.1.

Figure 3: Psw and Pr under different conditions.

1 0 2 0 3 0 4 0 5 0 6 00

5 0 0 0

1 0 0 0 0

1 5 0 0 0

2 0 0 0 0 H i s t o g r a m o f t r a n s a c t i o n v o l u m e

Frequ

ency

P r i c eFigure 4: Histogram of transaction volume and fit-ted exponential form demand curve.

R-square 0.9991, where α = 19190, β = 0.0832. FigIf we let each renter’s Ui(ui) take the following form,

Ui(ui) =1

β(ui + ui log(

α

Nr)− ui log ui), (12)

and plugging it into (3), we will have exactly the exponentialform of total demand mentioned above. Since (12) are basedon statistical results from real data, with out loss of general-ity, we also assume all product owners have the same form ofusage utility as (12). To balance the computation time andcredibility, we scale α and Nr to α = Nr = 1919 in compu-tation, then each renter’s demand will be e−βP ∈ [0, 1] andtotal demand will be Nre

−βP = αe−βP . Since DiDi has aminimum charge on each ride (at 10 RMB), we can reset thezero price point at the minimum charge fee.

6.3.1 Social Welfare Loss Under Exponential DemandHere we want to see the social welfare loss when DiDi

is maximizing revenue under exponential form of demandfunction listed above. We examine some practical cases:when supply are less or slightly more than demand (No =100, 500, 1000, 2000, 2500, 3000 whileNr = 1919). Fig.5 showsthat when supply is not abundant, DiDi is actually achiev-ing maximum social welfare simultaneously when it sets theprice to maximize revenue.

6.3.2 The Role of CostWe study the role of cost c here. Fig 6(a) shows demand

and supply under different cost, and Fig.6(b) is drawn under

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 30000

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

Price

Owners

P PrPsw

Pr

Figure 5: Under exponential form of real demand,when supply is not abundant, maximizing revenue isactually maximizing social welfare at the same time.

quadratic usage payoff given in 6.2 for comparison. Thesetwo settings actually shows similar results. As showed inboth two figures, cost c is the dominant factor in determin-ing the lowest price to enable sharing, i.e., there will be nosharing when price is lower than c.

In Fig.6(a), if we compare the supply curves of c = 5 andc = 10 (similar situation happens if we compare c = 0.1 andc = 0.3 in Fig 6(b) ), we also find that higher cost signifi-cantly suppresses sharing, e.g., drivers will choose their shar-ing level more conservatively if they have to pay more costwhen their cars are running empty waiting for customers’order. This shows that a properly chosen cost c can helpreduce redundant supply while maintaining an acceptableQoS. This is crucial to many social issues such as green-house gas emission, road congestion, because it is feasible toimplement such a scheme: government can carefully choosea proper c, e.g., gasoline price, instead of designing verycomplex mechanisms.

6.3.3 How can DiDi do Better?After showing the experiment results, we can also de-

rive the possible optimal revenue that the platform can get.Since trade volume is defined as (6) and by Proposition 3,P ′ = 1/β = 12 is the price which maximizes PD(P ), there-fore maximizes revenue. The platform obtains maximumrevenue when they set the price such that average chargefor each ride is P ′ plus minimum charge, under the condi-

Page 9: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

0 5 1 0 1 5 2 0 2 5 3 0 3 5 4 0 4 5 5 00

5 0 0

1 0 0 0

1 5 0 0

Dema

nd

P r i c e

D e m a n d S u p p l y : c = 1 S u p p l y : c = 5 S u p p l y : c = 1 0 S u p p l y : c = 1 5

(a) Different costs affect the startingprice of sharing and the amount of shar-ing (based on real data).

0 . 0 0 . 2 0 . 4 0 . 6 0 . 8 1 . 00

2 0

4 0

6 0

8 0

1 0 0

Dema

nd

P r i c e

D e m a n d S u p p l y : c = 0 . 0 1 S u p p l y : c = 0 . 1 S u p p l y : c = 0 . 3 S u p p l y : c = 0 . 5

(b) Different costs affect the startingprice of sharing and the amount of shar-ing (based on quadratic usage payoff,with NO = 100 and NR = 300).

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.610

11

12

13

14

15

Price

epsilon

P_sw P_rPsw

Pr

(c) Even with a 0.05 ε increase, maxi-mum revenue price can reach P ′.

Figure 6: Role of cost and ε.

tion that S(P ′) ≥ D(P ′). Meanwhile, since all data are fromactual transaction, we can calculate the average transactionprice by:

P =

∫∞0Pαe−βP∫∞

0αe−βP

=1

β(13)

which is exactly the optimal price mentioned above. That is,DiDi has already accurately chosen their price which couldgenerate best possible revenue. Nevertheless, the platformstill need to make sure there are enough supply at P ′, oth-erwise P ′ will not be the correct maximum revenue priceaccording to Proposition 3.

Given 1919 renter and 1500 owners, we know from Fig. 5that the revenue maximization price will be 12.9, which isnot at the best optimal revenue price P ′ = 12 due to the lackof supply. Actually, among all the 395938 records of orderin the data we study, there are only 43648 car driver IDs,while number of customer ID is 237800. In another word,shortage of supply is now the biggest obstacle for sharingplatform to obtain best possible revenue. There are manyways to augment supply, e.g., Uber adopt “surge price” [9]to raises the price at the area where supply is scarce in thehope of attracting more drivers.

However, under some circumstance where price is fixed,recruiting more altruistic product owners will be a betterchoice, as illustrated in 4.3. Fig 6(c) shows the impact ofrecruiting some actively sharing product owners, under thesetting of 1919 renter and 1500 owners: with only a slightlyincrease of product owner’s enthusiasm (ε = 0.05), actual Prcan be set to the best possible revenue maximization priceP ′ = 12 so that platform will gain optimal revenue. Mean-while, from social welfare maximizer’s perspective, altruisticproduct owners’ participation will also lower Psw and there-fore increase total social welfare.

7. CONCLUSIONIn this paper we consider the fundamental problem about

how to efficiently boost sharing economy. Based on a game-theoretic model, we derive various tight bounds of social wel-fare loss of the maximum revenue policy compared to max-imum social welfare pricing policy. We also show that therevenue maximization ensures higher sharing supply leveland ensures better quality-of-service to users in the shar-ing system. Our numerical results also demonstrate thatas the renter/owner ratio increases, revenue optimal policy

is also welfare optimal. Our results provide novel insightsand guidances on how to boost sharing economy towardsmaximizing social welfare by commercial power who chasesmaximum revenue.

8. REFERENCES[1] The rise of the sharing economy. Economist, 2013.

[2] Lyft. https://www.lyft.com/, 2015.

[3] Uber. https://www.uber.com, 2015.

[4] Additional technical report of this paper.https://www.dropbox.com/s/bxcagx9gh49ar16/mobihoc.pdf,2016.

[5] Didi research.http://research.xiaojukeji.com/competition/main.action?competitionId=DiTech2016,2016.

[6] R. Belk. You are what you can access: Sharing andcollaborative consumption online. Journal of BusinessResearch, 67(8):1595–1600, 2014.

[7] S. Benjaafar, G. C. Kong, X. Li, and C. Courcoubetis.Peer-to-peer product sharing: Implications forownership, usage and social welfare in the sharingeconomy. Available at SSRN: 2669823, 2015.

[8] G. P. Cachon, K. M. Daniels, and R. Lobel. The roleof surge pricing on a service platform withself-scheduling capacity. Available at SSRN, 2015.

[9] L. Chen, A. Mislove, and C. Wilson. Peeking beneaththe hood of uber. In Proceedings of the 2015 ACMConference on Internet Measurement Conference,pages 495–508. ACM, 2015.

[10] G. Debreu. A social equilibrium existence theorem.Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences ofthe United States of America, 38(10):886, 1952.

[11] EEA. Occupancy rates of passenger vehicles.http://www.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/indicators/occupancy-rates-of-passenger-vehicles/occupancy-rates-of-passenger-vehicles, 2015.

[12] K. Fan. Fixed-point and minimax theorems in locallyconvex topological linear spaces. Proceedings of theNational Academy of Sciences of the United States ofAmerica, 38(2):121, 1952.

[13] T. Geron. Airbnb and the unstoppable rise of theshare economy.http://www.forbes.com/sites/tomiogeron/2013/01/23/airbnb-and-the-unstoppable-rise-of-the-share-economy/,2013.

Page 10: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

[14] I. L. Glicksberg. A further generalization of thekakutani fixed point theorem, with application to nashequilibrium points. Proceedings of the AmericanMathematical Society, 3(1):170–174, 1952.

[15] P. Golle, K. Leyton-Brown, I. Mironov, andM. Lillibridge. Incentives for sharing in peer-to-peernetworks. In Electronic Commerce, pages 75–87.Springer, 2001.

[16] X. Gong, L. Duan, and X. Chen. When network effectmeets congestion effect: Leveraging social services forwireless services. ACM Mobihoc 15’, 1(2):3, 2015.

[17] J. Hamari, M. Sjoklint, and A. Ukkonen. The sharingeconomy: Why people participate in collaborativeconsumption. Available at SSRN 2271971, 2015.

[18] M. Hancock. Independent review of the sharingeconomy: Government response, 2015.

[19] E. Huet. Uber raises uberx commission to 25 percentin five more markets.

[20] B. Jiang and L. Tian. Collaborative consumption:Strategic and economic implications of productsharing. Available at SSRN 2561907, 2015.

[21] F. P. Kelly, A. K. Maulloo, and D. K. Tan. Ratecontrol for communication networks: shadow prices,proportional fairness and stability. Journal of theOperational Research society, pages 237–252, 1998.

[22] K. Lai, M. Feldman, I. Stoica, and J. Chuang.Incentives for cooperation in peer-to-peer networks. InWorkshop on economics of peer-to-peer systems, pages1243–1248, 2003.

[23] C. P. Lamberton and R. L. Rose. When is ours betterthan mine? a framework for understanding andaltering participation in commercial sharing systems.Journal of Marketing, 76(4):109–125, 2012.

[24] P. Maille and L. Toka. Managing a peer-to-peer datastorage system in a selfish society. Selected Areas inCommunications, IEEE Journal on, 26(7):1295–1301,2008.

[25] D. P. Palomar and M. Chiang. A tutorial ondecomposition methods for network utilitymaximization. Selected Areas in Communications,IEEE Journal on, 24(8):1439–1451, 2006.

[26] U. K. Parliament. The major road network: Eighthreport of session 2009-10.http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200910/cmselect/cmtran/505/505.pdf, 2015.

[27] D. Sacks. The sharing economy. Fast Company, 2011.

[28] S. Shakkottai, S. G. Shakkottai, and R. Srikant.Network optimization and control. Now Publishers Inc,2008.

[29] UITP. Who are the new pioneers of the sharingeconomy?http://www.uitpmilan2015.org/content/who-are-new-pioneers-sharing-economy,2015.

[30] G. Zervas, D. Proserpio, and J. Byers. The rise of thesharing economy: Estimating the impact of airbnb onthe hotel industry. Boston U. School of ManagementResearch Paper, (2013-16), 2014.

9. APPENDIXProofs of Theorem 2 and Proposition 4 are in additional

technical report [4] due the space limitation.

9.1 Proof of Theorem 1Proof. Let S = (s1, s2, ...sNo), with each component be-

ing each owner’s share level, and U = (u1, u2..., uNo+Nr ),with each component being each user’s usage.

First we notice that an owner’s strategy space is (u, s) ∈{u ≥ 0, s ≥ 0, u + s ≤ 1} and a renter’s action space isu ∈ [0, 1], both of which are compact convex sets.

Then, for renter i, it is clear that his utility function shownin (3) is continuous in S and U, and concave in ui. As forthe owners, consider Equation (2). The total demand D isfixed as long as P is set, as it only involves renters. Thetotal supply is the sum of si. Thus, owner’s utility functionis continuous in {s1, s2, ...si−1, si+1, ...sNo}, u.

Depending on D(P ) and others owners’ supplies∑j 6=i sj ,

there are three cases:

• D(P ) <∑j 6=i sj : the utility function for i becomes

Wi(ui) = Ui(ui) + P D(P )S(P )

si − cui − csi and we know

that P D(P )S(P )

si = P D(P )∑j 6=i sj+si

si is concave in si.

• D(P ) >∑j 6=i sj + 1: the utility function for i becomes

Wi(ui) = Ui(ui)+Psi−cui−csi, which is also concavein si.

•∑j 6=i sj < D(P ) <

∑j 6=i sj + 1, the utility function for

i becomes

Wi(ui) =

{U(ui) + P D(P )

S(P )si − cui − csi D(p) ≤ S(P )

Ui(ui) + Psi − cui − csi D(P ) > S(P )

and it is continuous. It is concave in si since each pieceis concave in si and at the intersection point of thesetwo pieces, the left derivative P − c is greater than the

right derivative P D(P )(S(P )−si)S(P )2

− c = P S(P )−siS(P )

− c.Hence, owner i’s utility function in above three cases arealways continuous and concave to its own strategy (ui, si).

According to [14][10][12], a pure strategy Nash equilib-rium exists since each user’s strategy space is convex andcompact, and the utility function of each user is concave inhis strategy, and continuous in S and U.

9.2 Proof of Proposition 1Proof. Under Assumption 1, for concave and continuous

Ui, and fixed P , renter has unique optimal demand u∗i (P ) ∈[0, 1] which maximizes his overall utility Wi(P ) given by (3).Suppose the market price is set to be some P0, we must have:

Wi(u∗i (P0)) =Ui(u

∗i (P0))− P0u

∗i (P0)

>Wi(ui)

=Ui(ui)− P0ui, ∀ui > u∗i (P0).

Suppose for any market price P1 > P0, we must have:

Ui(u∗i (P0))− P1u

∗i (P0)

=Ui(u∗i (P0))− P0u

∗i (P0)− (P1 − P0)u∗i (P0)

>Ui(ui)− P0ui − (P1 − P0)ui

=Ui(ui)− P1ui, ∀ui > u∗i (P0).

This implies u∗i (P1) ≤ u∗i (P0), i.e., each renter’s demand isnon-increasing in P , for otherwise by setting ui = u∗i (P1) >u∗i (P0), we get the following contradiction:

Ui(u∗i (P0))− P1u

∗i (P0) > Ui(u

∗i (P1))− P1u

∗i (P1).

Page 11: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

For any renter i, by Assumption 1, there exists mi suchthat Ui(ui) < miui, ui ∈ [0, 1]. Define Pno demand = maxi{mi}.Then, every renter has zero demand when P ≥ Pno demand.

9.3 Proof of Proposition 2Proof. Due to Assumption 1, each renter’s demand u∗i (P )

is continuous in P , so D(P ) is continuous in P . Let Pupperbe the price satisfying the equation PupperD(Pupper) = c,which means even only one owner provides production shar-ing with no competition, he can not make positive profit. Itis clear that no owner will share products at price beyondPupper. We start by proving (ii) of the proposition, and then(i) and (iii)

(ii) We first prove that there exists P ′ < Pupper such thatD(P ′) = S(P ′). By Proposition 1, total demand decreasesto 0 when market price exceeds Pupper. Thus, there mustexists some price P ′ such that D(P ′−) > S(P ′−) for P ′− =P ′ − δ and D(P+) < S(P ′+) for P ′+ = P ′ + δ, here δ > 0 isinfinite small. We only need to show that D(P ′) = S(P ′),i.e., S(P ) is continuous at the intersection point P ′. Supposethe opposite that S(P ′+)−S(P ′−) = ∆ > 0, where ∆ is somepositive constant. Then, there must exists some owner i,such that s∗i (P

′+)− s∗i (P ′−) = ∆i > 0, and the effective price

at P ′+ isP ′+D(P ′+)

S(P ′−)+∆. Since δ → 0, i share more at P ′+ while the

effective price is lower, which leads to contradiction. We canalso show that P ′ < Pupper. That is because since S(P ) =D(P ) > 0, we must have P ′ < Pupper.

Now we show that D(P ) ≤ S(P ) for P ≥ P ′. Considerowner i’s utility function at any P0 ≥ P ′ satisfying D(P0) ≤S(P0), e.g., P0 = P ′ (we have D(P0) = S(P0)):

Wi(ui) = Ui(ui) + P0si − cui − csi, (14)

and the best response is denoted by (u∗i (P0), s∗i (P0)). As-sume for contradiction that for some P1 > P0 we haveD(P1) > S(P1). Then, owner i’s utility function becomes:

Wi(ui) = Ui(ui) + P1si − cui − csi, (15)

where the best response is (u∗i (P1), s∗i (P1)). Compare equa-

tion (14) and (15), since P1 > P0D(P0)S(P0)

, we must have:

Ui(u∗i (P0)) + P0s

∗i (P0)− cs∗i (P0)− cu∗i (P0)

≥Ui(u∗i (P1)) + P0s∗i (P1)− cs∗i (P1)− cu∗i (P1) (16)

and

Ui(u∗i (P1)) + P1s

∗i (P1)− cs∗i (P1)− cu∗i (P1)

≥Ui(u∗i (P0)) + P1s∗i (P0)− cs∗i (P0)− cu∗i (P0) (17)

from (17) we have:

P1(s∗i (P1)− s∗i (P0)) ≥ Ui(u∗i (P0))− Ui(u∗i (P1))

− cs∗i (P0)− cu∗i (P0) + cs∗i (P1) + cu∗i (P1),

plugging (16) into it we have:

P1(s∗i (P1)− s∗i (P0)) ≥ P0(s∗i (P1)− s∗i (P0)) (18)

since P1 > P0D(P0)S(P0)

> 0, we have:

s∗i (P1)− s∗i (P0) ≥ 0. (19)

Since i is arbitrary, we have S(P1) ≥ S(P0), and S(P1) ≥S(P0) ≥ D(P0) ≥ D(P1) by Proposition 1, which leads tocontradiction.

Therefore let P ′ be the smallest market clearing price,P ′ = min{Pc |D(Pc) = S(Pc)}, we have S(P ) ≥ D(P ), ∀P ≥P ′.

(i)Similarly we know S(P ) is nondecreasing when P ≤ P ′,since the utility function at P < P ′ for each owner is:

Wi(ui) = Ui(ui) + Psi − cui − csi,

and each one’s si is nondecreasing when P increases.(iii)It has been proved at the beginning.

9.4 Proof of Proposition 3Proof. (i) Consider the case when the price is P0 and

D(P0) > S(P0). There exists some renters who are not ableto rent products since available products are not enough. LetR0 denote the set of renters who have successfully rented aproduct and R/R0 denotes the other renters. We know thatWi(ui) ≥ 0, ∀i ∈ R0 and Wi(ui) = 0, ui = 0, ∀i /∈ R0, i ∈R. According to Proposition 2, there exists some marketclearing price P ′ > P0 such that D(P ′) = S(P ′).

For owners, we must have each owner’s social welfareWi(ui) = Ui(ui) + P ′si − cui − csi increases compared tothe case when price is P0.

For renters in R/R0, each renter gains non-negative socialwelfare increment. For renters in R0, each renter i suffersutility lost not exceeding (P ′−P0)u∗i (P0), with u∗i (P0) beinghis best response usage at price P0. Therefore total socialwelfare lost for group R0 will be less than (P ′ − P0)S(P0).However for the owners who have served users in R0, theyhave at least (P ′−P0)S(P0) utility increment at price P ′ dueto the price increase even if they do not augments supplies.

To sum up, the social welfare at lowest market clearingprice P ′, is higher than the social welfare at any price satisfy-ing D(P ) > S(P ), i.e., Psw ≥ P ′. According to Proposition2, we always have S(Psw) ≥ D(Psw).

(ii) According to 2, let P ′ be the lowest price whenD(P ′) =D(S′). Consider any price P0 < P ′ and we have D(P0) >S(P0). The volume of trade will be P0S(P0). According toProposition 1, there exists some P1 > P ′ such that S(P0) =D(P1) and the volume of trade will be P1D(P1) = P1S(P1)and we have P1D(P1) > P0S(P0).

9.5 Proof of Theorem 2(1) We prove the first bullet in Theorem 2 here. Suppose

for some P1 > P ′, we must have Σi∈RWi(P1)−Σi∈RWi(P′) <

−(P1 − P ′)D(P1), which is the additional payment paid byrenters for demand D(P1) after price changed to P1. As forthe renters, they have earned additional payment A fromrenters:

A = P1D(P1)− P ′D(P ′)

= = (P1 − P ′)D(P1)− P ′(D(P ′)−D(P1)) (20)

where the first term in (20) is exactly the lower bound ofrenters’ loss, and we only need to prove that owners can notcompletely retrieve the loss in the second term by choosingtheir own usage. For owner i, we have:

U(u∗i (P′)) +

P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′)s∗i (P

′)− cu∗i (P ′)− cs∗i (P ′)

≥ U(u∗i (P1)) +P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′) +4sis∗i (P1)− cu∗i (P1)− cs∗i (P1)

(21)

Page 12: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

where 4si = s∗i (P1)− s∗i (P ′). Thus,

U(u∗i (P1))− cu∗i (P1)− cs∗i (P1)− U(u∗i (P′)) + cu∗i (P

′) + cs∗i (P′)

≤ P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′)s∗i (P

′)− P1D(P1)

S(P ′)s∗i (P1) (22)

summarize (22) over all owners, we have:∑i∈O

[U(u∗i (P1))− cu∗i (P1)− cs∗i (P1)

− U(u∗i (P′)) + cu∗i (P

′) + cs∗i (P′)]

<P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′)

∑i∈O

s∗i (P′)−

∑i∈O

P1D(P1)

S(P ′) +4sis∗i (P1)

=P ′D(P ′)−∑i∈O

P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′) +4sis∗i (P1) (23)

If S(P1) > S(P ′), we show that for any owner i, 4si ≥0. Suppose the contradiction that there exists some i suchthat 4si > S(P1) − S(P ′), while some j with 4sj < 0.Therefore, the effective price seen by j will be lower at P1,

i.e., P1D(P1)S(P1)

≤ P ′D(P ′)S(P ′) , otherwise j can always increase

its sharing by arbitrarily small amount beyond s∗i (P′) to

gain higher utility. Hence, we know that i can also see thedecreased effective price and decrease his sharing supply,which leads to contradiction. Thus, we have:

P ′D(P ′)−∑i∈O

P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′) +4sis∗i (P1)

< P ′D(P ′)−∑i∈O

P ′D(P ′)

S(P1)s∗i (P1)

= 0 (24)

Similarly, if S(P1) < S(P ′), we will have 4si ≤ 0 for allowner i. Since both the supply and effective price decrease

at P1, we have P ′D(P ′)S(P ′) > P1D(P1)

S(P1). So the owner will bear

the payment loss P ′D(P ′)−P1D(P1), which can be showedsimilarly as above to be irretrievable by changing self use:∑

i∈O

[U(u∗i (P1))− cu∗i (P1)− cs∗i (P1)

− U(u∗i (P′)) + cu∗i (P

′) + cs∗i (P′)]

<P ′D(P ′)−∑i∈O

P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′) +4sis∗i (P1)

<P ′D(P ′)−∑i∈O

P ′D(P ′)

S(P ′)s∗i (P1)

<P ′D(P ′)− P1D(P1) (25)

(2)By Proposition 2, 3 and results above, we must havePr ≥ Psw.

(3)The volume of trade can be represented as PrD(Pr)and PswD(Psw) by Proposition 3. Since Pr maximizes thevolume of trade, we know that PrD(Pr) ≥ PswD(Psw).

We prove by contradiction, suppose that S(Pr) < S(Psw).Let the best response of owner i at Pr and Psw is s∗i (Pr) ands∗i (Psw). Since S(Pr) < S(Psw), without loss of generality,we can assume s∗i (Pr) < s∗i (Psw) for some i. Then, as far

as i can see, the “effective” price PrD(Pr)S(Pr)

is greater than the

“effective”price PswD(Psw)S(Psw)

. Under such circumstances, i will

find that he can always increase its sharing supply, at least

by positive δ → 0, to increase his utility, as long as the total

effective price be still higher than PswD(Psw)S(Psw)

, since i’s best

response at PswD(Psw)S(Psw)

is s∗i (Psw) and i can actually share

more if price is higher. This contradicts the fact that i is atNash equilibrium and s∗i (Pr) is his best response at Pr.

9.6 Proof of Theorem 3Proof. The first inequality is trivial. From Proposition

3, we know that total supply exceeds total demand at Pswand Pr, which means each renters with positive demand canget served.

Denote W ∗i (P ) as i’s optimal utility and u∗i (P ), s∗i (P ) (fori ∈ O) as his best response at price P . Then, u∗i (Pr), s

∗i (Pr)

and u∗i (Psw), s∗i (Psw) are i’s best response usages and sharelevels (for i ∈ O) at price Pr and Psw. The total demandand total supply at price Pr and Psw are given by:

D(Pr) =∑i∈R

u∗i (Pr), S(Pr) =∑i∈O

s∗i (Pr)

D(Psw) =∑i∈R

u∗i (Psw), S(Psw) =∑i∈O

s∗i (Psw)(26)

We first consider renters’ social welfare. Renter i’s utilityat some arbitrary price P is Wi(ui) = Ui(ui) − Pui. Sinceu∗i (Pr) yields maximum utility of i at price Pr, we musthave:

Ui(u∗i (Psw))− Pru∗i (Psw) ≤ Ui(u∗i (Pr))− Pru∗i (Pr). (27)

Plugging (27) into the gap of all renters’ social welfare:∑i∈R

Wi(Psw)−∑i∈R

Wi(Pr)

=∑i∈O

U(u∗i (Psw))− Pswu∗i (Psw)− (U(u∗i (Pr))− Pru∗i (Pr))

≤(Pru∗i (Psw)− Pru∗i (Pr))− Pswu∗i (Psw) + Pru

∗i (Pr)

=(Pr − Psw)D(Psw) (28)

After bounding the renters’ social welfare, we now take alook at the owners. Since total demand is less than totalsupply, owner i’s utility function is

Wi(ui) = Ui(ui) + PD(P )

S(P )si − cui − csi. (29)

Owner group’s utility gap between two prices will be:∑i∈O

W ∗i (Psw)−W ∗i (Pr)

=∑i∈O

[Ui(u∗i (Psw))− Ui(u∗i (Pr))]

+∑i∈O

[−c(u∗i (Psw) + s∗i (Psw)) + c(u∗i (Pr) + s∗i (Pr))]

+ PswD(Psw)

S(Psw)S(Psw)− Pr

D(Pr)

S(Pr)S(Pr) (30)

Since u∗i (Pr), s∗i (Pr) is i’s best response at Pr, we must have

for all owner i:

Ui(u∗i (Pr)) + Pr

D(Pr)

S(Pr)s∗i (Pr)− cu∗i (Pr)− cs∗i (Pr)

≥Ui(u∗i (Psw)) + PrD(Pr)

S(Pr)− s∗i (Pr) + s∗i (Psw)s∗i (Psw)

− cu∗i (Psw)− cs∗i (Psw) (31)

Page 13: Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue · PDF file · 2016-12-06Boosting Sharing Economy: Social Welfare or Revenue Driven? Zhixuan Fang ... social welfare with general

Note that∑i∈O

[PrD(Pr)

S(Pr)− s∗i (Pr) + s∗i (Psw)s∗i (Psw)− Pr

D(Pr)

S(Pr)s∗i (Psw)]

= PrD(Pr)s∗i (Psw)

∑i∈O

[1

S(Pr)− s∗i (Pr) + s∗i (Psw)− 1

S(Pr)]

= PrD(Pr)

S(Pr)s∗i (Psw)

∑i∈O

s∗i (Pr)− s∗i (Psw)

S(Pr)− s∗i (Pr) + s∗i (Psw)

≥ PrD(Pr)

S(Pr)s∗i (Psw)

∑i∈O s

∗i (Pr)−

∑i∈O s

∗i (Psw)

S(Pr)−mini [s∗i (Pr)− s∗i (Psw)]

≥ 0 (32)

We have used Theorem 2 to obtain last inequality of (32).Plugging (32) into (31), we have:

Ui(u∗i (Psw))− Ui(u∗i (Pr)) ≤ Pr D(Pr)

S(Pr)s∗i (Pr)− cu∗i (Pr)

−cs∗i (Pr)− [PrD(Pr)S(Pr)

s∗i (Psw)− cu∗i (Psw)− cs∗i (Psw)]. (33)

Plugging (33) into (30), we have:∑i∈O

W ∗i (Psw)−W ∗i (Pr)

≤PrD(Pr)

S(Pr)

∑i∈O

s∗i (Pr)− PrD(Pr)

S(Pr)

∑i∈O

s∗i (Psw)

+ PswD(Psw)

S(Psw)S(Psw)− Pr

D(Pr)

S(Pr)S(Pr)

=PswD(Psw)− PrD(Pr)S(Psw)

S(Pr)(34)

Adding (34) and (28) together we have proved the theo-rem.

9.7 Proof of Theorem 5It can be verified that the proofs are the same for Theorem

1 and 2. We only need to show the differences in provingTheorem 3. Specifically, the renters utility is the same as in(28), and owner’s utility gap becomes:∑

i∈O

W ∗i (Psw)−W ∗i (Pr)

=∑i∈O

[Ui(u∗i (Psw))− ci,uu∗i (Psw)− ci,ss∗i (Psw)

− Ui(u∗i (Pr)) + ci,uu∗i (Pr) + ci,ss

∗i (Pr)

+ Psw(D(Psw)

S(Psw)+ εi)s

∗(Psw)− Pr(D(Pr)

S(Pr)+ εi)s

∗(Pr)]

(35)

Similarly to (31), since u∗(Pr) and s∗(Pr) are the best re-sponses at Pr, we have:

Ui(u∗i (Pr)) + Pr(

D(Pr)

S(Pr)+ εi)s

∗i (Pr)− ci,uu∗i (Pr)− ci,ss∗i (Pr)

≥Ui(u∗i (Psw)) + Pr(D(Pr)

S(Pr)− s∗i (Pr) + s∗i (Psw)+ εi)s

∗i (Psw)

− ci,uu∗i (Psw)− ci,ss∗i (Psw) (36)

Plugging (36) into (35), and use the similar method showedin (32), we have:∑i∈O

W ∗i (Psw)−W ∗i (Pr)

≤∑i∈O

[Psw(D(Psw)

S(Psw)+ εi)s

∗i (Psw)− Pr(

D(Pr)

S(Pr)+ εi)s

∗i (Pr)

+ Pr(D(Pr)

S(Pr)+ εi)s

∗i (Pr)− Pr(

D(Pr)

S(Pr)+ εi)s

∗i (Psw)]

= PswD(Psw)− PrD(Pr)S(Psw)

S(Pr)(37)

which is the same as (34). Therefore we have proved The-orem 3 still holds under modified owner utility of 7, andTheorem 4 again comes as a natural corollary of Theorem3. So far we have proved Theorem 5.

9.8 Proof of Proposition 4Since the social welfare under the scheme stated in the

proposition is obviously the highest possible one, we onlyneed to show that there exists such a scheme. As showed in(9), we can set the market renting price Psw ∈ (αNO , αNO+1)such that renters of first D(Psw) highest αi get access tocars provided from owners of first S(Psw) lowest αi, whilethe other owners fully use their own car. We know thatat Psw, demand equals supply, since S(Psw) = NO − (NO −D(Psw)) = D(Psw) (here (NO−D(Psw) denotes the numberof owners whose private value is higher than Psw). Underthis circumstance, we achieve maximum social welfare asstated in the proposition.