chapter 2 the market for foreign exchange international monetary and financial economics third...

57
Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose © South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Upload: victor-gordon

Post on 25-Dec-2015

237 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

Chapter 2

The Market for Foreign

Exchange

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Third Edition

Joseph P. DanielsDavid D. VanHoose

Copyright © South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Page 2: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

2

The Foreign Exchange Market

• Exchange Rate– The value of one currency relative to another

currency as the number of units of one currency required to purchase one unit of the other currency.

• Foreign-Currency-Denominated Financial Instrument– A financial asset, such as a bond, a stock, or a bank

deposit, whose value is denominated in the currency of another nation.

Page 3: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

3

Spot Market Characteristics

• It is the oldest and largest financial market in the world:– Has no central trading floor where buyers and sellers meet.– Is open twenty-four hours a day, except for short gaps on weekends.– The spot market is a market for immediate delivery (2 to 3 days).

• Primarily an interbank market, which is the trading of foreign-currency-denominated deposits between large banks.– Global banks account for about two-thirds of the market volume, while

foreign exchange brokers and dealers account for approximately 20 percent.

• Approximately $US1.4 - 1.6 trillion daily in global transactions.

Page 4: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

4

A Foreign Exchange Transaction

• Toshiba receives a dollar denominated payment from Best Buy, which they present to Fuji Bank.

• To exchange the dollar payment for the yen equivalent, Fuji Bank may contact another bank, such as Citigroup, or contact a FX broker.

Page 5: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

5

Currency Trading Tables

• Typical FX tables in a daily business publication provide spot and forward rates.

• US $ equivalent or US $ per currency is the dollar price of a unit of foreign currency (eg., $/€).

• Currency per US $ is the foreign currency price of one US dollar (eg., €/$).

Page 6: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

6

Some Additional Terminology:Direct - Indirect Quotes

• Direct quote is the home currency price of a foreign currency.

• Indirect quote is the foreign currency price of the home currency.

Page 7: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

7

Appreciating and Depreciating Currencies

• A currency that has lost value relative to another currency is said to have depreciated.

• A currency that has gained value relative to another currency is said to have appreciated.

• These terms relate to the market process and are different from devaluation and revaluation (Chapter 3).

Page 8: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

8

Appreciating and Depreciating Currencies

• We use the percentage change formula to calculate the amount of appreciation or depreciation.

• Example, suppose on Monday the Mexican peso traded at 11.3855 MXN/USD, whereas on Tuesday it traded at 11.1245 MXN/USD.

• The peso has appreciated, as it now takes fewer pesos to purchase each dollar.

• The amount of appreciation is:

[(11.1245 – 11.3855)/11.3855] •100 = -2.29%

Page 9: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

9

Cross-Rates: Unobserved Rates

• A cross-rate is an unobserved rate that is calculated from two observed rates.

• For example, the spot rate for the Canadian dollar is 1.3176 C$/$, and the spot rate on the euro is 1.2153 $/€. What is the Canadian dollar price of the euro (C$/€)?

• Note that (C$/$)·($/€) = C$/€.• In this example, (1.3176)· (1.2153) = 1.6013

C$/€.

Page 10: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

10

Bid - Ask Spreads

• The bid is the price the bank is willing to pay for the currency, e.g., 1.2148 $/€ is the bid on the euro in terms of the dollar.

• The ask is what the bank is willing to sell the currency for, e.g. 1.2158 $/€, is the ask on the euro in terms of the dollar.

• The typical rate quoted in a daily publication is the midpoint of these two values, e.g., 1.2153.

Page 11: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

11

Bid - Ask Spread and Margin

• The bid - ask spread of a currency reflects, in general, the cost of transacting in that currency.

• It is calculated as the difference between the ask and the bid. • For example, 1.2158 – 1.2148 = 0.001.• The bid - ask spread can be converted into a percent to

compare the cost of transacting among a number of currencies.

• The margin is calculated as the spread as a percent of the ask.

(Ask - Bid)/Ask * 100• Example, (1.2158 – 1.2148)/1.2158 * 100 = 0.082%.

Page 12: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

12

Real Exchange RatesReal Measures

• Nominal variables, such as an exchange rate, do not consider changes in prices over time.

• Real variables, on the other hand, compensate for price changes.

• A real exchange rate, therefore, accounts for relative price changes, or in other words, for differences in inflation between the two nations.

Page 13: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

13

Real Exchange Rates

• A nominal exchange rate indicates the rate of exchange between one nation’s currency with the currency of another nation.

• Real exchange rates indicate the purchasing power of a nation’s residents for foreign goods and services relative to their purchasing power for domestic goods and services.

• A real exchange rate is an index. Hence, we compare its value for one period relative to its value in another period, or the change in the index from one period to another.

Page 14: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

14

Real Exchange RatesAn Example

• In 1990 the spot rate between the dollar and the peso was 2.9454 (MXN/$).

• In 1995 the rate was 7.6425.• Hence, the peso depreciated relative to the dollar by

159.5 percent {[(7.6425-2.9454)/2.9454]*100}.• Based on this alone, the purchasing power of US

residents for Mexican goods and services (relative to US goods and services) rose by 159 percent.

Page 15: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

15

Example: Continued

• In 1990 the Mexican CPI was 100 and the US CPI was 100. In 1995, the CPI’s were 224.5 and 116.8 respectively.

• Based on this, Mexican prices rose 124.5 percent while US prices rose 16.8 percent, a 107.7 difference.

• Since the prices of Mexican goods and services rose faster than the prices of US goods and services, there was a decline in purchasing power over Mexican goods and services relative to the purchasing power over US goods and services.

Page 16: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

16

Combining the Two Effects

• A real exchange rate combines these two effects - the gain in purchasing power of US residents due to the nominal depreciation of the peso and the decline in relative purchasing power due to Mexican prices rising at a faster rate than US prices.

• To construct a real exchange rate, the spot rate, as it is quoted here, is multiplied by the ratio of the US CPI to the Mexican CPI.

(MXN/$) • (CPIUS/CPIMX)

Page 17: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

17

Combining the Two Effects

• 1990 Real Rate = 2.9454 x (100/100) = 2.9454.

• 1995 Real Rate = 7.6425 x (116.8/224.5) = 3.9761.

• The real depreciation of the peso was

34.99 percent.

Page 18: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

18

Conclusion

• The nominal exchange rate change resulted in a 159.5 percent gain in the purchasing power of Mexican goods and services for US residents.

• The difference in price changes resulted in a 107.7 percent loss of purchasing power of Mexican goods and services relative to US goods and services for US residents.

• Note how the 159.5 percent gain was partially offset by the 107.7 loss, resulting in an overall 35 percent gain in purchasing power.

Page 19: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

19

Effective Exchange Rates

• On any given day, a currency may appreciate in value relative to some currencies while depreciating in value against others.

• An effective exchange rate is a measure of the weighted-average value of a currency relative to a select group of currencies.

• Thus, it is a guide to the general value of the currency.

Page 20: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

20

Weighted Average Value

• To construct an EER, we must first pick a set of currencies we are most interested in.

• Next, we must assign relative weights. In the following example, we weight the currency according to the country’s importance as a trading partner.

Page 21: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

21

Weights

• Suppose that of all the trade of the US with Canada, Mexico, and the UK, Canada accounts for 50 percent, Mexico for 30 percent, and the UK for 20 percent.

• These constitute our weights (0.50, 0.30, and 0.20).

• Now consider the following exchange rate data.

Page 22: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

22

Exchange Rate Data

Currency 2004 Value 2003 Value

Canadian Dollar 1.31 $C/$ 1.39

Mexican Peso 11.4 P/$ 10.9

British Pound 0.56 £/$ 0.64

Page 23: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

23

Calculating the EER

• The EER is calculating by summing the weighted values of the current period rate relative to the base year rate.

• The weighted-average value is calculated as:

Σ[(Weight i)(current exchange value i)/(base exchange value i)]

Where i represents each individual country included in the weighted average.

Page 24: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

24

Calculating the EER

• Commonly this sum is multiplied by 100 to express the EER on a 100 basis.

• As we shall see next, the base-year value of an index measure is 100.

• The index, therefore, is useful is showing changes in the weighted average value from one period to another.

Page 25: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

25

Example

• Let 2003 be the base year.

• The effective exchange rate for 2003 was:[(1.39/1.39)•0.50 + (10.9/10.9)•0.30

+ (0.64/.64)•0.20]•100

= 100.

• As with any index measure, the base year value is 100.

Page 26: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

26

Example

• The value of the EER for 2004 is:[(1.31/1.39)•0.50 + (11.4/10.9)•0.30

+ (0.56/0.64)•0.20] • 100

• Or 96.0

• The dollar, therefore, has experienced a 4 percent depreciation in weighted value.

Page 27: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

27

Effective Exchange Measures

• There are a number of effective exchange measures available in the popular press. Some common measures are:

• Bank of England Index: The Economist and Financial Times.

• J.P. Morgan: The Wall Street Journal.

• International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics.

Page 28: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

28

Effective Exchange RatesJapan, United Kingdom, United States

Between 1985 and 1995, the average value of the

U.S. dollar and the British pound declined, while the

average value of the Japanese yen increased.

This trend reversed in 1995, but began anew in

2002.

SOURCE: Data from the Bank of England.

Page 29: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

29

Arbitrage:Consistency of Cross Rates

• Arbitrage is the simultaneous buying and selling to profit (as opposed to speculation).

• The ability of market participants to arbitrage guarantees that cross rates will be, in general, consistent.

• If a cross rate is not consistent, the actions of currency traders (arbitrage) will bring the respective currencies in line.

Page 30: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

30

Spatial Arbitrage

• Spatial Arbitrage refers to buying a currency in one market and selling it in another.

• Price differences arise from geographical (spatial) dispersed markets.

• Due to the low-cost rapid-information nature of the foreign exchange market, these prices differences are arbitraged away quickly.

Page 31: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

31

Triangular Arbitrage

• Triangular arbitrage involves a third currency and/or market.

• Arbitrage opportunities exist if an observed rate in another market is not consistent with a cross-rate (ignoring transaction costs).

• Again, profit opportunities are likely to be arbitraged away quickly, meaning that cross-rates are, for the most part, consistent with observed rates.

Page 32: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

32

Triangular Arbitrage: Example

• The US dollar is trading for 1.7936 ($/£) and the Polish zloty for 6.5492 (Z/£) in London, while the zloty is trading for 3.7826 (Z/$) in New York.

• The cross-rate in London is:6.5492/1.7936 = 3.6514 (Z/$)

• Hence, an arbitrage opportunity exists.

Page 33: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

33

Example Continued

• A trader with £1, could buy $1.7936 in London. • The $1.7936 would purchase Z6.7845 in New

York.• The Z6.7845 purchases £1.0359 in London.

This is a profit of £0.0359 or 3.59 percent profit on the transaction.

• To understand the arbitrage opportunity, remember “buy low, sell high.”

Page 34: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

34

Triangular Arbitrage

Buy $ in London

Purchase Z in New YorkPurchase £ in London

Page 35: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

35

The Demand for a Currency

• The demand for a currency is a derived demand. That is, the demand for the currency is derived from the demand for the goods, services, and financial assets the currency is used to purchase.

• If, for example, foreign demand for European goods and services increases, the demand for the euro increases.

Page 36: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

36

The Demand Curve is Downward Sloping

• If, for example, the euro depreciates, European goods, services, and financial assets become less expensive to foreign residents. Foreign residents will increase their quantity demanded of the euro to purchase more European goods, services, and financial assets.

• The downward slope of the demand curve shows the negative relationship between the exchange rate and the quantity demanded.

Page 37: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

37

The Demand Curve

The downward slope of the demand curve shows the negative relationship between the exchange rate and the quantity demanded.

Page 38: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

38

Important Note

• It is vital to construct and label supply and demand diagrams properly.

• Note here we are diagramming the market for the euro. Hence, it is crucial to represent the correct exchange rate on the vertical axis.

• The correct exchange rate is one that reflects the “price” of the euro. That is, it must be an indirect quote.

Page 39: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

39

An Increase in Demand

• Consider an increase in the demand for the euro.• Suppose, for example, that savers desire euro-

denominated financial assets relative to dollar-denominated financial assets because of a change in economic conditions.

• The demand for the euro rises as savers desire more euros to purchase greater amounts of European financial assets.

Page 40: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

40

An Increase in the Demand for the Euro

The demand for the euro rises as savers desire more euros to purchase greater amounts of European financial assets.

Page 41: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

41

The Supply of a Currency

• The supply of one currency is derived from the demand for another currency.

• Consider the demand schedule for the dollar. If the dollar depreciates relative to the euro, there is an increase in the quantity demanded of dollars.

• As more dollars are purchased, the quantity of euros supplied in the foreign exchange market increases.

Page 42: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

42

The Supply of the Euro

Consider the demand schedule for the dollar. If the dollar depreciates relative to the euro, there is an increase in the quantity demanded of dollars. As more dollars are purchased, the quantity of euros supplied in the foreign exchange market increases.

Page 43: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

43

An Increase in the Supply of the Euro

An increase in the demand for the U.S. dollar by German residents leads to an increase in the supply of the euro.

Page 44: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

44

Equilibrium

• The market is in equilibrium when the quantity supplied of a currency is equal to the quantity demanded.

• The equilibrium rate of exchange is also referred to as the market clearing exchange rate because there is neither a surplus nor a shortage of the currency.

Page 45: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

45

Market Equilibrium

At exchange rate Sb the quantity supplied of the euro exceeds the quantity demanded and the euro will depreciate.At exchange rate Sc, the quantity of euros demanded exceeds the quantity supplied and the euro will appreciate.

Page 46: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

46

Increase in the Demand for the Euro

An increase in U.S. consumers’ demand for German goods results in an increase in the demand for the euro. The euro appreciates relative to the dollar.

Page 47: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

47

Central Bank Intervention

• Suppose a nation’s policymakers desire to keep the value of the currency stable (relative to the currency of an important partner).

• They may request the central bank to intervene in foreign exchange (FX) markets.

• Basically, FX intervention entails the buying and selling of foreign reserves (foreign currency denominated financial instruments).

Page 48: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

48

FX Intervention - Continued

• Let’s continue with the previous example and assume that there is an increase in the demand for the euro.

• As shown, the demand curve for the euro shifts to the right, resulting in an appreciation of the euro relative to the dollar.

Page 49: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

49

FX Intervention - Continued

• Now let’s suppose that the European Central Bank (ECB) desires to maintain the value of the euro at Se rather than the market determined rate S'.

• The ECB would need to accommodate the increase in demand for the euro with an equivalent increase in the quantity of euros supplied.

Page 50: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

50

Buying and Selling Foreign Reserves

• Suppose the ECB buys dollar-denominated deposits from commercial banks. (In effect, the ECB is removing these dollars from circulation.)

• The ECB must pay the banks for the dollar-denominated financial instruments it bought from them.

• The ECB pays the banks with euro-denominated deposits – increasing the quantity of euros supplied.

Page 51: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

51

FX Intervention

The ECB accommodates the increase in the demand for the euro by increasing the quantity supplied of the euro via a purchase of dollar-denominated financial instruments.

Page 52: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

52

FX Intervention - Conclusion

• The increase in the quantity of euros supplied accommodates the increase in the demand for the euro.

• The exchange rate remains at Se.• The quantity transacted, however, rises to Q2.• The amount (euro value) of the intervention is

given by difference between Q‘d and Qe.

Page 53: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

53

Over and Under-Valued Currencies

• If a currency’s value is market determined, how can it be over- or under-valued?

• A currency is said to be over- or under-valued if the market exchange rate is different from the rate that a model or individual predicts to be the “correct” rate.

• In other words, the individual believes the market “has it wrong.”

Page 54: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

54

Undervalued

• Suppose your predicted spot value, Sb, lies above the market determined rate, Se.

• Hence, you believe it should take a greater amount of dollars to buy each euro. You would conclude, therefore, that euro is undervalued.

Page 55: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

55

Purchasing Power ParityAbsolute or the Law of One Price

• Suppose The Economist magazine sells for £2.50 in the UK and $3.95 in the US.

• Arbitrage, therefore, should guarantee that the exchange rate between the dollar and the pound to be s = 3.95/2.50 = 1.580 ($/£).

• In words, the dollar price of The Economist in the UK should equal the dollar price of the Economist in the US (ignoring transportation costs).

Page 56: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

56

Absolute PPP

• Absolute PPP is expressed as P = P*×S, where P is the domestic price, P* is the foreign price, and S is the spot rate, expressed as domestic to foreign currency units.

• Often it is rearranged as: S = P/P*.

• The previous slide was an example of absolute PPP.

Page 57: Chapter 2 The Market for Foreign Exchange INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Third Edition Joseph P. Daniels David D. VanHoose Copyright ©

57

Relative PPP

• Rearrange APPP to S = P/P*. • Often economists will take the log of this expression

to obtain: S = - *.• In words, domestic inflation less foreign inflation

should equal the change in the spot rate.• Relative PPP implies that the higher inflation country

should see its currency depreciate.• This is the version that economists would test.