chapter 36 public goods

97
Chapter 36 Public Goods

Upload: zacharee-horn

Post on 31-Dec-2015

29 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

DESCRIPTION

Chapter 36 Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition. A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. Nonexcludable -- all consumers can consume the good. Nonrival -- each consumer can consume all of the good. Public Goods -- Examples. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Chapter 36Public Goods

Page 2: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Public Goods -- Definition

A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption.Nonexcludable -- all consumers can

consume the good.Nonrival -- each consumer can consume

all of the good.

2

Page 3: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Public Goods -- Examples

Broadcast radio and TV programs. National defense. Public highways. Reductions in air pollution. National parks.

3

Page 4: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Reservation Prices

A consumer’s reservation price for a unit of a good is his maximum willingness-to-pay for it.

Consumer’s wealth is Utility of not having the good is Utility of paying p for the good is

Reservation price r is defined by

U w( , ).0w.

U w p( , ). 1

U w U w r( , ) ( , ).0 1

4

Page 5: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Reservation Prices: An ExampleConsumer’s utility isU x x x x( , ) ( ).1 2 1 2 1

Utility of not buying a unit of good 2 is

V wwp

wp

( , ) ( ) .0 0 11 1

Utility of buying one unit of good 2 atprice p is

V w pw pp

w pp

( , ) ( )( )

.

1 1 12

1 1

5

Page 6: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Reservation Prices; An ExampleReservation price r is defined by

V w V w r( , ) ( , )0 1 I.e. by

wp

w rp

rw

1 1

22

( )

.

6

Page 7: Chapter 36 Public Goods

When Should a Public Good Be Provided? One unit of the good costs c. Two consumers, A and B. Individual payments for providing the

public good are gA and gB.

gA + gB c if the good is to be provided.

7

Page 8: Chapter 36 Public Goods

When Should a Public Good Be Provided? Payments must be individually

rational; i.e.

and

U w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , ).0 1

8

Page 9: Chapter 36 Public Goods

When Should a Public Good Be Provided? Payments must be individually

rational; i.e.

and

Therefore, necessarily and

U w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , ).0 1

g rA A g rB B .

9

Page 10: Chapter 36 Public Goods

When Should a Public Good Be Provided? And if

and

then it is Pareto-improving to supply the unit of good

U w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , )0 1

10

Page 11: Chapter 36 Public Goods

When Should a Public Good Be Provided? And if

and

then it is Pareto-improving to supply the unit of good, so is sufficient for it to be efficient to supply the good.

U w U w gA A A A A( , ) ( , )0 1

U w U w gB B B B B( , ) ( , )0 1

r r cA B

11

Page 12: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Private Provision of a Public Good? Suppose and . Then A would supply the good even if

B made no contribution. B then enjoys the good for free; free-

riding.

r cA r cB

12

Page 13: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Private Provision of a Public Good?

Suppose and . Then neither A nor B will supply the

good alone.

r cA r cB

13

Page 14: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Private Provision of a Public Good?

Suppose and . Then neither A nor B will supply the

good alone. Yet, if also, then it is

Pareto-improving for the good to be supplied.

r cA r cB

r r cA B

14

Page 15: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Private Provision of a Public Good?

Suppose and . Then neither A nor B will supply the

good alone. Yet, if also, then it is

Pareto-improving for the good to be supplied.

A and B may try to free-ride on each other, causing no good to be supplied.

r cA r cB

r r cA B

15

Page 16: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Suppose A and B each have just

two actions -- individually supply a public good, or not.

Cost of supply c = $100. Payoff to A from the good = $80. Payoff to B from the good = $65.

16

Page 17: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Suppose A and B each have just

two actions -- individually supply a public good, or not.

Cost of supply c = $100. Payoff to A from the good = $80. Payoff to B from the good = $65. $80 + $65 > $100, so supplying

the good is Pareto-improving.

17

Page 18: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding

-$20, -$35 -$20, $65

$100, -$35 $0, $0

Buy

Don’tBuy

BuyDon’tBuy

Player A

Player B

18

Page 19: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding

-$20, -$35 -$20, $65

$100, -$35 $0, $0

Buy

Don’tBuy

BuyDon’tBuy

Player A

Player B

(Don’t’ Buy, Don’t Buy) is the unique NE.19

Page 20: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding

-$20, -$35 -$20, $65

$100, -$35 $0, $0

Buy

Don’tBuy

BuyDon’tBuy

Player A

Player B

But (Don’t’ Buy, Don’t Buy) is inefficient.20

Page 21: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Now allow A and B to make

contributions to supplying the good. E.g. A contributes $60 and B

contributes $40. Payoff to A from the good = $40 >

$0. Payoff to B from the good = $25 >

$0.

21

Page 22: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding

$20, $25 -$60, $0

$0, -$40 $0, $0

Contribute

Don’tContribute

ContributeDon’tContribute

Player A

Player B

22

Page 23: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding

$20, $25 -$60, $0

$0, -$40 $0, $0

Contribute

Don’tContribute

ContributeDon’tContribute

Player A

Player B

Two NE: (Contribute, Contribute) and (Don’t Contribute, Don’t Contribute).23

Page 24: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding

So allowing contributions makes possible supply of a public good when no individual will supply the good alone.

But what contribution scheme is best? And free-riding can persist even with

contributions.

24

Page 25: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities E.g. how many broadcast TV

programs, or how much land to include into a national park.

25

Page 26: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities E.g. how many broadcast TV

programs, or how much land to include into a national park.

c(G) is the production cost of G units of public good.

Two individuals, A and B. Private consumptions are xA, xB.

26

Page 27: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities Budget allocations must satisfyx x c G w wA B A B ( ) .

27

Page 28: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities Budget allocations must satisfy

MRSA & MRSB are A & B’s marg. rates of substitution between the private and public goods.

Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is

x x c G w wA B A B ( ) .

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

28

Page 29: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities Pareto efficiency condition for public

good supply is

Why?

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

29

Page 30: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities Pareto efficiency condition for public

good supply is

Why? The public good is nonrival in

consumption, so 1 extra unit of public good is fully consumed by both A and B.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

30

Page 31: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities Suppose MRSA is A’s utility-preserving

compensation in private good units for a one-unit reduction in public good.

Similarly for B.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

31

Page 32: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities

is the total payment to A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is lowered by 1 unit.

MRS MRSA B

32

Page 33: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities

is the total payment to A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is lowered by 1 unit.

Since , making 1 less public good unit releases more private good than the compensation payment requires Pareto-improvement from reduced G.

MRS MRS MCA B ( )G

MRS MRSA B

33

Page 34: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities Now suppose

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

34

Page 35: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities

Now suppose is the total

payment by A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is raised by 1 unit.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

MRS MRSA B

35

Page 36: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities

Now suppose is the total

payment by A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is raised by 1 unit.

This payment provides more than 1 more public good unit Pareto-improvement from increased G.

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

MRS MRSA B

36

Page 37: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities

Hence, necessarily, efficient public good production requires

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

37

Page 38: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Variable Public Good Quantities

Hence, necessarily, efficient public good production requires

Suppose there are n consumers; i = 1,…,n. Then efficient public good production requires

MRS MRS MCA B ( ).G

MRS MCii

nG

1

( ).

38

Page 39: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case Two consumers, A and B. U x G x f G ii i i i( , ) ( ); , . A B

39

Page 40: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case Two consumers, A and B. Utility-maximization requires

U x G x f G ii i i i( , ) ( ); , . A BMRS f G ii i ( ); , .A B

MRSpp

f G p iiG

xi G ( ) ; , .A B

40

Page 41: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case Two consumers, A and B. Utility-maximization requires

is i’s public good demand/marg. utility curve; i = A,B.

U x G x f G ii i i i( , ) ( ); , . A BMRS f G ii i ( ); , .A B

MRSpp

f G p iiG

xi G ( ) ; , .A B

p f GG i ( )

41

Page 42: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

MUA

MUB

pG

G

42

Page 43: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

pG

G

43

Page 44: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences CasepG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G

44

Page 45: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

45

Page 46: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

pG*

46

Page 47: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

pG*

p MU G MU GG* ( *) ( *) A B

47

Page 48: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Efficient Public Good Supply -- the Quasilinear Preferences Case

G

pG

MUA

MUB

MUA+MUB

MC(G)

G*

pG*

p MU G MU GG* ( *) ( *) A B

Efficient public good supply requires A & Bto state truthfully their marginal valuations.48

Page 49: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited When is free-riding individually

rational?

49

Page 50: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited When is free-riding individually

rational? Individuals can contribute only

positively to public good supply; nobody can lower the supply level.

50

Page 51: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited When is free-riding individually

rational? Individuals can contribute only

positively to public good supply; nobody can lower the supply level.

Individual utility-maximization may require a lower public good level.

Free-riding is rational in such cases.

51

Page 52: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited

Given A contributes gA units of public good, B’s problem is

subject to

max,x gB B

U x g gB B A B( , )

x g w gB B B B , .0

52

Page 53: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

53

Page 54: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0is not allowed

54

Page 55: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0is not allowed

55

Page 56: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0is not allowed

56

Page 57: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Free-Riding Revisited

G

xB

gA

B’s budget constraint; slope = -1

gB 0

gB 0is not allowedgB 0(i.e. free-riding) is best for B

57

Page 58: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation

A scheme that makes it rational for individuals to reveal truthfully their private valuations of a public good is a revelation mechanism.

E.g. the Groves-Clarke taxation scheme.

How does it work?

58

Page 59: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation N individuals; i = 1,…,N. All have quasi-linear preferences. vi is individual i’s true (private)

valuation of the public good. Individual i must provide ci private

good units if the public good is supplied.

59

Page 60: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation ni = vi - ci is net value, for i = 1,

…,N. Pareto-improving to supply the

public good ifv ci i

i

N

i

N

11

60

Page 61: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation ni = vi - ci is net value, for i = 1,

…,N. Pareto-improving to supply the

public good ifv c ni i i

i

N

i

N

i

N

0

111.

61

Page 62: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation

If and

or and

then individual j is pivotal; i.e. changes the supply decision.

nii j

N

0 n ni j

i j

N

0

nii j

N

0 n ni j

i j

N

0

62

Page 63: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation

What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others?

63

Page 64: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation

What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others?

If then is the loss.ni

i j

N

0,

nii j

N0

64

Page 65: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation

What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others?

If then is the loss.

If then is the loss.

nii j

N

0,

nii j

N0

nii j

N

0, ni

i j

N

0

65

Page 66: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation

For efficiency, a pivotal agent must face the full cost or benefit of her action.

The GC tax scheme makes pivotal agents face the full stated costs or benefits of their actions in a way that makes these statements truthful.

66

Page 67: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation

The GC tax scheme: Assign a cost ci to each individual. Each agent states a public good net

valuation, si. Public good is supplied if

otherwise not.

sii

N

01

;

67

Page 68: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation A pivotal person j who changes the

outcome from supply to not supply

pays a tax of sii j

N.

68

Page 69: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation A pivotal person j who changes the

outcome from supply to not supply

pays a tax of

A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from not supply to supply

pays a tax of

sii j

N.

sii j

N.

69

Page 70: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Note: Taxes are not paid to other

individuals, but to some other agent outside the market.

70

Page 71: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Why is the GC tax scheme a

revelation mechanism?

71

Page 72: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Why is the GC tax scheme a

revelation mechanism? An example: 3 persons; A, B and C. Valuations of the public good are:

$40 for A, $50 for B, $110 for C. Cost of supplying the good is $180.

72

Page 73: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Why is the GC tax scheme a

revelation mechanism? An example: 3 persons; A, B and C. Valuations of the public good are:

$40 for A, $50 for B, $110 for C. Cost of supplying the good is $180. $180 < $40 + $50 + $110 so it is

efficient to supply the good.

73

Page 74: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60.

74

Page 75: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60. B & C’s net valuations sum to

$(50 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $40 > 0.

A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(40 - 60) + $40 = $20 > 0.

75

Page 76: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60. B & C’s net valuations sum to

$(50 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $40 > 0.

A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(40 - 60) + $40 = $20 > 0. So A is not pivotal.

76

Page 77: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what

net valuation sA should A state?

77

Page 78: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what

net valuation sA should A state?

If sA > -$20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $20 to him, more likely.

78

Page 79: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what

net valuation sA should A state?

If sA > -$20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $20 to him, more likely.

A prevents supply by becoming pivotal, requiring sA + $(50 - 60) + $(110 - 60) < 0;I.e. A must state sA < -$40.

79

Page 80: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Then A suffers a GC tax of

-$10 + $50 = $40, A’s net payoff is

- $20 - $40 = -$60 < -$20.

80

Page 81: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Then A suffers a GC tax of

-$10 + $50 = $40, A’s net payoff is

- $20 - $40 = -$60 < -$20. A can do no better than state the

truth; sA = -$20.

81

Page 82: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60.

82

Page 83: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60. A & C’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $30 > 0.

A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(50 - 60) + $30 = $20 > 0.

83

Page 84: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60. A & C’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(110 - 60) = $30 > 0.

A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(50 - 60) + $30 = $20 > 0. So B is not pivotal.

84

Page 85: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation What net valuation sB should B

state?

85

Page 86: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation What net valuation sB should B

state? If sB > -$10, then B makes supply of

the public good, and a loss of $10 to him, more likely.

86

Page 87: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation What net valuation sB should B state?

If sB > -$10, then B makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $10 to him, more likely.

B prevents supply by becoming pivotal, requiring sB + $(40 - 60) + $(110 - 60) < 0;I.e. B must state sB < -$30.

87

Page 88: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Then B suffers a GC tax of

-$20 + $50 = $30, B’s net payoff is

- $10 - $30 = -$40 < -$10. B can do no better than state the

truth; sB = -$10.

88

Page 89: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60.

89

Page 90: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60. A & B’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(50 - 60) = -$30 < 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > 0.

90

Page 91: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation Assign c1 = $60, c2 = $60, c3 =

$60. A & B’s net valuations sum to

$(40 - 60) + $(50 - 60) = -$30 < 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > 0. So C is pivotal.

91

Page 92: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C

state?

92

Page 93: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C

state? sC > $50 changes nothing. C stays

pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$(40 - 60) - $(50 - 60) = $30, for a net payoff of $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > $0.

93

Page 94: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C state?

sC > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$(40 - 60) - $(50 - 60) = $30, for a net payoff of $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > $0.

sC < $50 makes it less likely that the public good will be supplied, in which case C loses $110 - $60 = $50.

94

Page 95: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation What net valuation sC should C state?

sC > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$(40 - 60) - $(50 - 60) = $30, for a net payoff of $(110 - 60) - $30 = $20 > $0.

sC < $50 makes it less likely that the public good will be supplied, in which case C loses $110 - $60 = $50.

C can do no better than state the truth; sC = $50.

95

Page 96: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation GC tax scheme implements

efficient supply of the public good.

96

Page 97: Chapter 36 Public Goods

Demand Revelation GC tax scheme implements

efficient supply of the public good. But, causes an inefficiency due to

taxes removing private good from pivotal individuals.

97