corporate social responsible and return on investment...

43
Doing good to do well? Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in Sweden Master Thesis in Economics Author: Marcus Johansson Tutor: Johan Eklund and Tina Wallin Jönköping 2012

Upload: dodien

Post on 29-Mar-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

Doing good to do well?

Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in Sweden

Master Thesis in Economics

Author: Marcus Johansson

Tutor: Johan Eklund and Tina Wallin

Jönköping 2012

Page 2: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

i

Master Thesis in Economics

Title: Doing Good to Do Well? Corporate Social Responsibility Return on

Investment in Sweden

Author: Marcus Johansson

Tutor: Johan Eklund and Tina Wallin

Date: 2013-01-11

Keywords: Corporate Social Responsibility, Stakeholder Theory, Q-Theory of

Investment, marginal q

Abstract

This paper treats Corporate Social Responsibility as an investment in corporate reputation and

as such aims at investigating the return of that investment. It does so partly by estimating the

effect of being perceived as socially responsible on the firm’s ability to maximize shareholder

value and partly by estimating the effect on a more traditional accounting based measure of

financial performance. Results indicate that socially responsible firms are able to maximize

shareholder value to a greater extent than less responsible firms while at the same time not

necessarily performing better in traditional accounting terms.

Page 3: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

ii

Table of Contents

1. Introduction .................................................................................................1

1.1 Background and Problem Discussion ......................................................................................... 1

1.2 Previous Research .......................................................................................................................... 3

2 Theoretical Framework .............................................................................. 5

2.1 Stakeholder Theory ........................................................................................................................ 5

2.2 Agency Theory ................................................................................................................................ 6

2.3 Theories of Corporate Reputations ............................................................................................. 7

2.4 Q-theory of investment ................................................................................................................. 8

3 Method ........................................................................................................ 13

3.1 Measures ......................................................................................................................................... 13

3.1.2 Measure of Corporate Social Responsibility ........................................................................... 13

3.1.3 Measure of Corporate Financial Performance ....................................................................... 15

3.2 Data ................................................................................................................................................. 16

3.3 The Model ...................................................................................................................................... 18

3.4 Estimation Technique ................................................................................................................... 23

4 Empirical Results ....................................................................................... 24

5 Summary & Conclusions ......................................................................... 30

References ........................................................................................................ 31

Appendix ......................................................................................................... 34

Page 4: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

iii

List of Figures Figure 1: Shareholder Value Maximizing Investments..…………………….…………………11

Figure 2: Histograms…………………………………………………………………....…….38

List of Tables Table 1: Commonly Used Measures of Corporate Social Responsibility………………………..4

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics of CSR Data……………………...…...…………………….….16

Table 4: Median CSR-Scores by Market Capitalization………...………...…………………….17

Table 5: Variance Inflating Factors for Different Specifications………..…………………..….21

Table 5: Estimates of Marginal q …………………………………………………………..…24

Table 6: Estimates of ROA …………………………………………………………..…….....24

Table 7: Median CSR-Scores by Industry …………………………………………………….35

Table 8: Regressions Results for Different Estimation Techniques....…………..……………..36

Table 9: The Hausmann Test for Estimating ROA………………….………....……………...37

Page 5: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

1

1. Introduction

During recent years the interest in questions regarding the role of the company in society has

increased drastically. In particular, public interest in the question of corporate social

responsibility (CSR) has risen and at the same time, corporate awareness has increased as well.

In 2011, over 90% of the companies listed on the Stockholm stock exchange reported on one

or several issues related to CSR in their annual reports. In 2006, that figure was just above

70%.1 The question is why?

The obvious answer would be that firms observe the increased public interest and adapt to it

believing that it would grant them some future benefits. Commonly, these benefits are

thought to arise through positive goodwill effects from consumers and the investment

community. However, whether or not such positive effects actually exist is a question of

much debate. This paper seeks to add to that debate. Existence of positive goodwill effects

would imply that firms who are perceived as responsible are performing better than those

who are not, all else equal. If goodwill effects do not exist responsible firms would do worse

given that there are costs associated with being responsible, again all else equal.

From a shareholders point of view the question becomes whether or not engagement in CSR-

related issues is in their interest. They can choose to believe that positive effects exist and that

they are large enough to offset any costs or other negative effects in which case engagement in

CSR would be preferable. If they don’t however, engagement in CSR would be perceived as

harmful to the shareholders desire to maximize wealth and would thus constitute an agency

problem.

1.1 Background and Problem Discussion

Corporate Social Responsibility has had many different definitions and interpretations

attached to it over the years and each one of them try to address the role of the company in

society. Generally, there have been two conflicting views on what that role should be. The

first view was famously formulated by Friedman (1970) who suggested that the only

responsibility of corporations is to maximize profits for its shareholders, while obliging to the

laws of the society in which they are active.

____________________

1. Folksam Index on Responsible Business 2011 and 2006, available on:

http://www.folksam.se/testergodarad/skotersigforetagen/ansvarsfulltforetagande/1.63850

Page 6: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

2

This view is still shared by many economists2 and corporate executives today. The seconds

view is that the firm has responsibility not just towards their shareholders, but towards a set of

multiple stakeholders, often just labeled as society as a whole. The economic arguments for this

view are outlined in the theoretical framework. Proponents of stakeholder theory argue that

adhering to said responsibility would allow the firm to perform better, all else equal.

In light of these conflicting views, this paper aims at investigating whether or not socially

responsible firms are performing better than their less responsible counterparts. Engagement

in CSR is treated as an investment in corporate reputation and as such, the return of that

investment to the owners of the firm is the focus of the paper. The hypothesis of this paper is

that firms have a positive return on their investment in CSR and thus that firms who are

perceived as responsible are better prepared to deliver strong financial results than those who

are not, all else equal.

To test this hypothesis, this paper will examine whether firms that are perceived as more

socially responsible are more successful in maximizing shareholder value than firms that are

perceived as less responsible. The paper will also examine if any positive or negative effects of

CSR on financial performance exists when looking at more traditional accounting based

measures. A responsible firm is defined, in accordance with Wood (1991), as a firm that is

able to “meet or exceed the expectations of stakeholders on social issues”. The hypotheses of

this paper thus become:

H1: Firms who are perceived as socially responsible are better at maximizing shareholder value than firms who

are not.

H2: Firms who are perceived as socially responsible perform better in accounting terms than firms who are not.

The acceptance of H1 and H2 would lend support to stakeholder theory in the sense that it

would indicate that firms who adhere to their social responsibility towards society as a whole

performs better than firms who do not. Rejection however, would indicate that this is not the

case.

The paper is organized as follows: The first section provides a brief overview of previous

studies of the link between corporate social responsibility and financial performance. Section

two lays out the theoretical framework underlying the reasoning behind the hypotheses and

the testing of them. The third section describes and discusses the data and model used for

hypothesis testing. Section four present the results and provides an analysis thereof. Section

five concludes.

____________________

2.In particular, proponents of the Austrian school of economics tend to question the notion that companies have

a social responsibility. See for instance Henderson (2009) for some common arguments.

Page 7: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

3

1.2 Previous Research

Several previous studies have tried to measure the relationship between corporate social

responsibility (CSR) and corporate financial performance (CFP), with mixed results. In a

review of previous studies on the subject, Griffin & Mahon (1997) found 33 studies that

indicated a positive relationship between CSR and CFP, 9 which were inconclusive and 20

that indicated a negative relationship. Their work was later replicated by Roman et al. (1999)

who found 33 studies indicating a positive relationship, 14 inconclusive and 5 that indicated a

negative relationship. Roman et al. (1999) argued that the discrepancy between their results

and those of Griffin & Mahon (1997) were due to the fact that the latter survey included

studies whose results had been later refuted or who´s methodology was “unsound” (Roman et

al., 1999, page 120). Arlow & Gannon (1982) surveyed 7 previous studies on the subject and

found the relationship between CSR and CFP to be inconclusive.

Needless to say, previous research on the subject is both comprehensive and contradicting.

One of the reasons for this is the vast array of different variables used to measure both

financial and social performance. Griffin & Mahon (1997) lists no less than 80 different

variables used to measure financial performance in previous studies. The measures of social

performance have also varied substantially over time, mostly due to the availability of new

data. Typically, the variables used to measure financial performance is traditional accounting

based measures such as return on assets or return on equity. Examples of studies making use

of these measures are McGuire et al. (1988), Waddock & Graves (1997) and Bowman & Haire

(1975) who all found a positive link between CSR and return on assets/return on equity.

Alexander & Buchholz (1978), Soana (2011) and Nelling & Webb (2009) employed the same

measures but found no significant relationship.

To some extent, market based performance measures have been used as well by for instance

Sturdivant & Ginter (1977) who found a positive relationship between CSR and growth in

earnings per share, Herremans et al. (1993) who found that more responsible firms earned

higher abnormal stock market returns than less responsible firms, Folger & Nutt (1975) who

found no relationship between CSR and a firms price-earnings-ratio and Vance (1975) who

found a negative relationship between the price change of a stock and CSR.

The measures of corporate social responsibility has ranged between everything from the

authors own subjective opinion of a company (e.g. Moskowitz (1972) and Parker & Eillbert

(1975) who both found a positive relationship between CSR and financial performance) to

government indices (Folger & Nutt (1975), no relationship found) and rankings published by

magazines (McGuire et al. (1988), positive relationship). Table 1 below summarizes the three

most commonly used categorizes of measures of CSR, some of the more well-cited studies

using that measure and the results.

Page 8: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

4

Table 1- Commonly used Measures of Corporate Social Responsibility

Even though the data has varied substantially across previous studies, the methodology has

generally not. It has almost exclusively been that of an ordinary least squares regression of

some measures of perceived level of responsibility on a measure of financial performance.

This study offers no novelty in terms of methodology, but takes a slightly different approach

than the majority of previous studies when it comes to the measures of financial performance.

The focus is on a very specific type of financial performance, namely the ability to maximize

shareholder value. To properly measure this, a market based approach with its starting point

in the Q-theory of investment will be utilized. As will be shown later, the methodology uses

market data to measures the firm’s financial performance on the margin, an approach which

haven’t been found in any of the previous studies surveyed. This measure also account for

differences in risk across firms, something that many previous researchers have failed to

properly control for (McGuire et al., 1988). To examine if any results found would have

manifested itself had we gone in the footsteps of previous researchers and used a more

traditional, accounting based measure, such a measure will be used as well.

Measure of Corporate Social Responsibility

Example of Researchers Results

Researchers own opinion Moskowitz (1972), Parker & Eillbert

(1975) Positive Relationship

Government Indices Folger & Nutt (1975), Spicer (1978) No relationship, Positive

Relationship Reputational Indices McGuire et al. (1988), Waddock &

Graves (1997), Alexander & Buchholz (1978), Vance (1975)

Positive Relationship, No Relationship, Negative Relationship

Page 9: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

5

2 Theoretical Framework

2.1 Stakeholder Theory

Stakeholder theory was first developed by Freeman (1984) and deals with the idea that every

firm has multiple stakeholders who all have different claims on the company. Typical

examples of stakeholders include shareholders, employees, suppliers, government, trade

unions, civil society, customers and other financiers but generally a stakeholder can be said to

be anyone who has a claim, implicitly or explicitly (Cornell & Shapiro, 1987), on the company.

Stakeholder theory can be viewed as opposite to the more traditional view of the company

where the firm´s owners and their explicit claim of return on investment is the only firm-

stakeholder relationship of importance. Friedman´s (1970) famous New York Times article is

an example of this view.

One of the implications of stakeholder theory that is of particular importance for this study is

outlined by Cornell & Shapiro (1987). In their framework stakeholders can have either implicit

or explicit claims on a firm. Explicit claims are easy to identify and could typically be wage

contracts, dividend policies, required returns or bond payments. Generally put; claims that can

be explicitly priced and formulated in contracts.

Implicit claims are basically all claims which cannot be priced or explicitly regulated in a

contract. Such claims could for example be the implicit promise of a manufacturer to supply

spare parts for its products, an employer to provide a certain work environment for its

employees or a producer of a support product or service to continue to exist. An example of

the latter would be auto repair shops. Every car that is sold is sold together with an implicit

promise that if the car breaks down there would be an, often independent, mechanic around

to fix it. If all auto repair shops specialized in a specific brand of cars would go out of

business, the value of the car sold would be less for the buyer.

The implications of this reasoning is that in a situation where every firm have multiple

stakeholders and those stakeholders all have their own claims, the firm suddenly finds itself in

a situation where it needs to service (or appear to be able to do so in the future) both implicit

and explicit claims.

Page 10: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

6

Cornell & Shapiro (1987) shows us that the firm’s prospects of being able to serve these

claims are part of the overall valuation of the firm. In their framework, firms can very well

default on implicit claims without defaulting as a whole, but a default on implicit claims leads

to a decrease in market value of the firm as markets become uncertain about the ability of the

firm to service its other implicit claims in the future. A default on explicit claims such as bond

payments or wages would of course also result in a decrease in market value. Thus, given that

the failure to service an implicit or explicit claim leads to a decrease in market value, it can be

said that in the context of stakeholder theory the service of claims to all stakeholders becomes

necessary to be able to serve the traditional claim of maximized shareholder value.

In this paper, corporate social responsibility is treated as an implicit claim held by society as a

whole, on the company. It thus follows that companies that service this claim by being

perceived as socially responsible should be better at maximizing value for its shareholders

because it helps them uphold its market value (Cornell & Shapiro, 1987).

2.2 Agency Theory

While stakeholder theory focuses on the relationship between the firm and all its stakeholders,

agency theory focuses on the relationship between the management of the firm and its

owners, i.e. its shareholders, but could be extended to any principal-agent relationship.

An agency relationship arises when a contract is established between a principal and an agent,

ordering the agent to carry out some services on behalf of the principal (Jensen & Meckling,

1976). In the case of a public firm, the agency relationship is between the stockholders

(principals) that own the firm and management (the agent) that are employed to make

decisions that maximize value for the first group. However as Berle & Means (1930) was

among the first to point out, the interests of management and owners of a firm doesn’t

necessarily coincide, giving rise to principal-agent problems. We may thus observe costs associated

with the separation of ownership and control that characterizes a public company. Such costs

are known as agency costs and consist of (1) monitoring costs and (2) residual loss (Jensen &

Meckling, 1976).

Monitoring costs arises as a results of the need for the stockholder to monitor the managers of a

firm, or generally, for principals to monitor the agent. Such monitoring is undertaken as a

mean for the owners to ensure that management are indeed acting with their best interest in

mind. One way in which the owners of a firm can monitor the managers is the annual reports.

Others include setting up budget constraint and forming a compensation policy for

management that creates incentive to act in the best interest of the shareholders, such as e.g.

stock-option programs (Jensen & Meckling 1976).

Page 11: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

7

While the publication of annual reports reduce monitoring costs (Raffournier, 1995),

compensation policies may often increase them.

Residual loss is the divergence in value between the business decision that management makes,

and the business decision that would have maximized shareholder value. If management is

able to maximize shareholder value, residual loss is zero. However, agency theory predicts that

there will always be a divergence between the two (Jensen & Meckling, 1976) because the cost

of full enforcement of contracts exceeds the benefits (Fama & Jensen, 1983).

The acknowledgement of agency theory and the existence of agency costs are important for

this paper. Later on, when the firm’s ability to maximize shareholder value is examined, the

reader should bear in mind that agency costs exists and may affect the firm’s ability to

maximize shareholder value. Direct links between agency problems and CSR have also been

suggested in other studies. Friedman (1970) for instance suggests that the mere existence of

CSR practices in a firm is a sign that agency problems are present. This view is based on the

notion that investment in CSR doesn’t add any value for the shareholders and in extent that

CSR and ability to maximize value for shareholders are negatively correlated. McWilliams et al.

(2006) presents a similar view and argues that agency theory in general suggests that CSR is a

misuse of corporate resources that could have been spent on other, profit-generating projects.

One of the hypotheses of this paper is that responsible firms are better at maximizing

shareholder value than firm who do not engage in CSR practices. If that hypothesis holds

true, it would imply that the existence of CSR practices does not constitute an agency problem

since investment made in CSR would allow the firm to realize a higher risk adjusted return on

its overall investments, thereby increasing value for the shareholders.

2.3 Theories of Corporate Reputations

A company´s reputation is the measure of how it’s perceived by its current and potential

stakeholders. If a firm “treats” its stakeholders badly by, for instance, defaulting on their

claims (be they of implicit or explicit nature) the perception of that firm among its current and

potential stakeholders is likely to change for the worse – they experience a decline in

reputation.

In the framework of Dowling (1986), potential stakeholders such as customers, investors or

suppliers seldom have firsthand experience of any given company. Such potential stakeholders

thus need to rely on corporate reputations when deciding whether they will engage in business

with the company in question or not. Corporate reputations thus serve an important signaling

function to potential and current stakeholders.

Page 12: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

8

Furthermore, Fombrun & Shanley (1990) claimed that this signaling function had important

applications when firms try to differentiate themselves in a competitive market. Research also

suggests that firms who enjoy good reputations are able to charge premium prices for their

products (Shapiro, 1983) and that they have better access to capital markets (Beatty & Ritter,

1986).

The implications for this study are of course that investments in corporate social

responsibility can be viewed as investments in corporate reputation. Indeed, many studies

have treated the two as being the same and used opinion surveys of corporate reputations to

serve as a proxy for corporate social responsibility (Herremans et al. 1993). The first to do so

was Moskowitz (1972), who rated companies based on his perceptions of their degree of

social responsibility. Several subsequent studies have also employed the same methodology of

using reputations to test the relationship between corporate social responsibility and financial

performance (see for instance Cochran & Wood 1984, Alexander & Buchholz 1978 and

McGuire et al. 1988).

Thus, there seems to be strong support in the literature for the theory that actions relating to

CSR also affect the broad public notion of a company. In addition, the reputation of a

company has been shown to affect the business decisions that current and potential

stakeholders make vis-à-vis that company. Firms that enjoy a good reputation seem to be

favored over those who do not, possible due to the differentiation effect discussed by

Fombrun & Shanley (1990). In this context there are significant potential for company actions

in the area of corporate social responsibility to influence their financial performance positively

and increase value for its shareholders.

2.4 Q-theory of investment

The Q-theory of investment seeks to explain the investment behavior of firms with the use of

Tobin’s Q (Tobin, 1969).Tobin’s Q is a financial metric which measures the ratio of the

market value of assets to the replacement cost of the same assets:

(1)

Usually, the market value of installed capital is measured as the sum of the market values of

equity and debt and the replacement cost of capital as the book value of assets. Thus, Tobin’s

Q measures the ratio of the markets valuation of a company’s assets to the cost at which the

company could replace all of its current assets with new ones, at current prices.

If market prices were solely a reflection of the value of the recorded assets of a company,

Tobin’s Q would take on a value of 1.

Page 13: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

9

If Tobin’s Q takes on a value greater than 1, the market is valuing the assets at a rate above

their replacement cost implying that it believes that the firm will be able to earn a higher

future return on those assets, which will increase total firm value. A Tobin’s Q of less than 1

implies the opposite, that the market believes that the firm will not be able to earn high

returns on its assets in the future and that the value of the firm will decrease as a result. Tobin

also suggested that the ratio had important implications for the firm’s investment decisions. If

the firm should undertake more investment in capital. The logic behind this is easily

seen by looking at equation (1): If Q is above one, then an investment of 1 SEK that adds to

the current capital stock and thus increases the replacement cost of capital of the firm by 1

will, all else equal, increase the market value of the company by more than 1. This means that as

long as a firm has a Q above 1, it will continue to invest until its Q reaches 1 at which point

the firm is indifferent about investing or not investing because the increase in market value

from investing is exactly the same as the cost of investing. On the opposite end, a firm which

has a Q below 1 will not undertake any investments since their market value will increase by

less than the amount invested.

Tobin’s Q have however been criticized as a determinant of investment. The major point

being made is that Tobin’s Q is an average measure of the potential return to investment while

investment decisions should in fact be based on the potential marginal returns (Gugler &

Yurtoglu, 2003). Firms experiencing spells where they are able to realize a high return on

investment (i.e. having a high Tobin Q) may very well be encourages to overinvest if they

neglect taking into account the marginal return in their decision.

As a remedy to these problems, Gugler & Yurtoglu (2003) propose a marginal q as a

determinant of investment and as a measure of firm performance.

The methodology for deriving and calculating the marginal q used in this paper was first

developed by Mueller & Reardon (1993). Here, I will briefly go through the more

straightforward derivation as it is outlined by Gugler et al. (2004). Starting off by noting that a

firm’s investment in period t generates real cash flows equal to with present

value we have:

(2) ∑

( )

If we assume capital market efficiency and thus that the market makes an unbiased estimate of

the present value we can go on to state the following: If the real discount rate is the

same over all time periods, the investment would have the same present value if is

the pseudo-permanent return on investment.

(3)

Equation (3) implies that we can formulate a specific criteria for shareholder wealth

maximization.

Page 14: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

10

Since the firm could always increase the wealth of its shareholder by by using the funds to

repurchase stock or pay them as dividends, shareholder wealth maximization requires that

and thus that (Mueller & Reardon, 1993).We can now define the market

value of a firm in any given year as such:

(4)

Where is the depreciation of the firms total capital stock that has taken place over the

year and is the markets error in evaluating . Substituting equation (3) into equation (4)

and rearranging yields:

(5)

Given that the assumptions of market efficiency holds, ( ) . Therefore, we can set

in the equation above. From equation (5) we see that the change in market value of a

company is a function of the investments made times the marginal return of those

investments minus the depreciation of the companies’ prior market value, plus an error term.

If we divide through with we obtain the standard model used to estimate marginal q:

(6)

(

)

Qm in equation (3) and (5) is marginal q (henceforth q), the marginal rate of return on

investment in relation to cost of capital. With marginal q, a firm that maximizes shareholder

wealth only undertakes investments for which . Any investments for which is

destruction of shareholder wealth since the firm always could have increased wealth with by

using the capital available for investment to repurchase stock or pay extra dividends. This

means that only firms that exhibit are fully maximizing shareholder value since they are

investing up to the point where marginal return equals the cost of capital. This is illustrated in

Figure 1 below.

Figure 1 has cost of capital on the vertical axis and total amount invested on the horizontal

axis. In the figure, the (fictional) firm invests up until the point where its marginal return on

investments equals its cost of capital, at point C. At point C, the firm thus has a marginal q of

exactly 1. By looking at the areas ABC and BCDE we can see that the difference between the

returns generated by investing (ABC+BCDE) and the cost of doing so (BCDE) is positive

and thus that the firm enjoys a net surplus from its investment activities. It can also be seen

that investing beyond the point of C will decrease that surplus, because the marginal return

generated will be less than the cost of capital. It is also obvious that investing less than at

point C will result in a lower surplus. Point C is thus the point of value maximization.

Page 15: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

11

Figure 1. Shareholder value maximizing investments

As seen from figure 1 firms with are underinvesting, and could have increased

shareholder value even more if they had continued to invest up to the point where .

Conversely, firms that exhibit are overinvesting and are in fact destroying shareholder

value by investing beyond the point where marginal return equals cost of capital. However, a

point that is not visible in Figure 1 is that is preferable to . By looking at Figure

1, on might get the impression that at marginal q of let’s say 1,1 is as bad for shareholders as a

q of 0,9. This is not the case. It is true that the firm that has a marginal q of 1,1 is not fully

maximizing shareholder value because it could have invested more at a return above its cost

of capital. A firm that has a q of 0,9 on the other hand is not maximizing shareholder value

because it has invested too much. The difference is of course that the firm with a q of 1,1 have

retained some extra amount of capital instead of investing it, perhaps to have it available for

larger investments in the future. The firm with a q of 0,9 on the other hand have invested

more and done so at a marginal rate of return below its costs of capital. It has thus destroyed

shareholder value and spent money that otherwise could have been retained for future

investments.

For the purposes of this study, there are a couple of advantages of using marginal q rather

than Tobin´s Q or other average performance measures as a measure of firm performance.

Firstly, marginal q provides a measure of the return on investment relative to the firm’s cost of

capital (this is most easily seen by studying equation 3).This means that marginal q is a risk

adjusted performance measure since the markets perception of the risk associated with any

given company will be reflected in that firms cost of capital. The method also allows for

differences in risk across firms (Gugler et al. 2004).

Secondly, the fact that marginal q measures the return on investment on the margin rather

than on average which is the case for measures such as Tobin’s Q or return-on-assets (ROA)

Co

st o

f ca

pit

al, i

Shareholder value maximizing

investments

Marginal Return onInvestment

A

B C

D E

Page 16: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

12

is a great advantage. While Tobin’s Q is the market value of a firm divided by its capital stock,

marginal q is the change in the market value of a firm divided by the investment that created it

(Gugler et al., 2004). Lastly, Tobin Q confuses marginal and infra-marginal returns. Tobin’s Q

is the average return on capital while marginal q measures the marginal return on investment.

It is thus a much more straightforward way of measuring return on investment. Marginal q is

also less restrictive than Tobin’s Q or ROA because it uses panel data in its estimation.

Page 17: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

13

3 Method

3.1 Measures

3.1.2 Measure of Corporate Social Responsibility

Typically, studies of the relationship between CSR and firm financial performance make use

of two different methods to measure CSR (Cochran & Wood, 1984). The first of these is to

use an index on reputation. Such an index is constructed by letting knowledgeable observer’s

rate firms on one or multiple areas of CSR. Obviously, this method of measurement is very

subjective. It does however have the advantage of being internally consistent (Cochran &

Wood, 1984) since the constructor of the index is applying the same subjective criteria to each

firm in the sample. Among the early well-cited studies that use a reputational index to measure

CSR are Moskowitz (1972) (who created his own), Vance (1975) and Alexander & Buchholz

(1978).

The other commonly used measure of CSR is content analysis. Content analysis was first used

by Bowman & Haire (1975) and basically consists of measuring the extent to which CSR-

related issues are reported on. A common approach is to go through the annual reports of a

set of firms and quantify what is reported in terms of CSR. One advantage of using content

analysis is that it’s somewhat more objective than the reputational index. Once the criteria to

look for are (subjectively) decided it is quite an objective process to measure the extent on

which they are reported in the annual reports.

The measure of CSR used in this study is the Folksam index on responsible business,

published semi-annually by the mutual insurance company Folksam. For the purpose of this

study, annual data have been provided by Folksam. The Folksam index on responsible

business (henceforth called “the index”) is calculated using a form of content analysis similar

to the one discussed above. By surveying documents made public by firms the index evaluates

to what extent firms have proper managerial guidance systems in place to deal with risks

within the areas of environmental impact and human rights. The index covers all companies

listed on the Stockholm stock exchange and each company are given two grades ranging

between 0 and 7; one for their environmental work and one for their work within the area of

human rights. The result is numerical data on CSR in the form of an unbalanced panel for a

total of 340 companies over a period of 6 years.

Page 18: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

14

Aside from covering a relatively large sample, the index has other advantages that make it

suitable for this type of study. The criteria used for grading the companies are derived from

internationally agreed guidelines and standards such as those published by the OECD and the

UN, among others. These guidelines are developed through broad consultations with a wide

range of stakeholders representing civil society groups, law-makers, companies and trade

unions (OECD, 2011). The criteria are therefore likely to be in line with the expectations of

corporate behavior held by a large number of stakeholders. Given that a low score in the

index reflects a failure to meet the criteria and by extension a low level of compliance with the

guidelines, low scores in the index reflects a company´s failure to meet the expectations of

many of its stakeholders and should therefore, according to stakeholder theory, have a

negative effect on the company. This negative effect is then expected, in line with the

hypothesis of this paper, to make it harder for the firm to maximize value for its shareholders,

all else equal.

An obvious criticism of content analysis is that it will be based solely on information provided

by the company itself. Given that asymmetric information is prevalent, firms will have strong

incentives to distort the picture of their true responsiveness to CSR-issues for the better.

While this is probably true in some cases, it is hard to predict which direction, if any, the

arising bias will take. Firms that in reality are performing very poorly on these issues of course

have strong incentives to make themselves look good if they believe that their stakeholders

are expecting it. On the other hand, firms that in reality are performing well have similar

incentives, although perhaps not as strong, and may very well find themselves facing higher

expectations due to prior performances. Thus it is reasonable to assume that while the firms

in the index are likely to signal themselves as more responsible than they are, all firms will have

similarly strong incentives.

There is also a possibility that firms that are performing very poorly on CSR-issues simply

choose not to report on it at all in their annual reports. This will however not pose a problem

since firms who do not report on the issues at all receive a score of zero (the lowest possible)

in the index. Firms that are performing well on CSR-issues will always have an incentive to

report that, so the fact that failure to report result in a grade of zero, should not be a source of

bias either.

Page 19: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

15

3.1.3 Measure of Corporate Financial Performance

As mentioned earlier, the variety of performance measures used to gauge the impact of CSR

on profitability has been vast. The most common approach however, is to use some measure

of the average returns on investment for the firm such as return on assets (ROA) or return on

equity (ROE). This paper partly adopts a slightly different approach by using marginal q,

which measures the firms return on investment in relation to its cost of capital, on the margin.

The purpose of this paper is to examine whether being perceived as socially responsible is

associated with being more able to maximize shareholder wealth. In the context of

stakeholder theory, the task becomes to test if firms that are servicing the implicit claims from

society to conduct business in a responsible manner are better at also servicing the explicit

claims of value maximization. That is, is a high degree of social responsiveness associated with

a higher return on investments, measured by marginal q? To test this, marginal q will be

estimated for all firms in the sample using equation (5), modified for the purpose of

regression analysis and to include the measures of CSR. By doing so, an estimate of the effect

of CSR on marginal q will be obtained and we can thus determine if socially responsible firms

have higher q’s than less responsible ones. A positive and significant effect of CSR on

marginal q would support the hypothesis that socially responsible firms are more able to

maximize shareholder value than less responsible ones.

The estimation of marginal q makes use of both accounting data and market data. Thus, it is

necessary for the methodology to be valid that at least the conditions for semi-strong form of

market efficiency (Fama, 1970) are met. I will assume that this is the case.

To test hypothesis two, that responsible firms are more profitable in accounting terms, a more

traditional approach is adopted. The measure of financial performance will then be ROA,

which has been used extensively for this purpose by previous researchers3. ROA is an

accounting-based, average performance measure that gives an indication of how effectively a

firm utilizes its resources. It is calculated as follows:

(7)

To test if being responsible affects ROA, a regression will be performed with the measures of

CSR as the independent variables, together with commonly used control variables. The logic

behind using ROA to measure performance in accounting terms is that it allows for good

comparison against results obtained from using marginal q. As been shown previously,

marginal q measures the marginal return on investment for the firm in market terms, whilst

ROA measures the average returns in accounting returns. Looking at both marginal q and

ROA essentially means looking at the same thing from two different points of view. We will

thus be able to draw conclusions based on whether or not these two measures show similar

results. This will be elaborated upon in section 4.

____________________

3. See section 1.2 for some examples of previous research using ROA

Page 20: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

3.2 Data

Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for the data on Corporate Social Responsibility obtained

from Folksam. A couple of tendencies are directly visible when looking at Table 2. First off,

the scores have generally increased over time, with few exceptions. Secondly, no firm has ever

achieved the highest score in the index, and the majority of companies seems to have scores

in the bottom half of the scale (less than 3,5). This suggests that the distribution of the scores

might be somewhat skewed. A look at the histograms of the two variables confirms this4.

The distribution is indeed skewed to the left so that we have more observation on the bottom

half of the scale than on the upper. This suggests that the mean does a poor job of

representing the central tendency of the data. Therefor the median will be used as the measure

of average CSR performance throughout this paper.

Table 2 – Descriptive Statistics of CSR data

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Total

HR

Mean 1,771 1,876 1,931 1,998 2,171 2,146 1,979 Median 1,470 1,680 1,750 1,750 2,030 1,995 1,750 SD 1,252 1,200 1,191 1,223 1,229 1,235 1,228 Max 5,285 5,285 5,290 5,180 5,915 5,915 5,915 Min 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 n 272 272 268 257 256 255 1580

ENV

Mean 1,822 1,802 1,874 1,966 2,084 2,054 1,931 Median 1,330 1,353 1,470 1,610 1,820 1,820 1,610 SD 1,819 1,753 1,728 1,734 1,671 1,586 1,719 Max 6,463 6,557 6,560 6,557 6,557 6,557 6,560 Min 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 n 272 272 268 257 256 255 1580

Notes: HR refers to the score given to a company for their work within the area of human rights. ENV refers to the score given to a company for their environmental work.

Another possibly interesting issue is firm size. It is reasonable to assume that the benefits of

being perceived as more socially responsible is greater for firms that are closely monitored and

have a well-established brand with the public. Such firms are often large. These firms often

have a reputation to care for and being perceived as socially irresponsible may inflict damage

on that reputation. That creates an incentive for the company to make sure that it is perceived

as responsible.

____________________

4. Histograms are available in the appendix

Page 21: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

17

Furthermore, engaging in CSR-related issues and maintaining a good reputation are associated

with at least some initial costs. Larger, more mature firms are more likely to have already

borne those costs or at least to be able to afford them within a foreseeable future.

All in all large firms seem more likely to report on CSR-issues and more eager to be perceived

as responsible. This may have implications for our study: If larger firms systematically have

higher scores we will have to take that into account when constructing our model. Looking at

the data, this is confirmed.

Table 3 below gives the median CSR-scores for the companies that belong to each of the

three lists that make up the Stockholm Stock Exchange; Large Cap companies (companies

with a market capitalization above 1 billion euros), Mid Cap companies (companies with a

market capitalization between 150 million and 1 billion euros) and Small Cap companies

(companies with a market capitalization below 150 million euros).

Given the skewness of the data the Mann-Whitney U-Test5 (Mann & Whitney, 1947) is used

to calculate whether or not the medians are significantly different from each other.

Table 3 – Median CSR-Scores by market capitalization

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Total Large Cap HR 2,998†* 2,905†* 3,290†* 3,185†* 3,150†* 3,430†* 3,097†* ENV 3,500†* 3,325†* 4,18†* 4,130†* 3,803†* 3,873†* 3,780†* n 59 60 36 47 56 51 309 Mid Cap HR 1,455* 1,540* 1,960* 1,873* 2,030* 2,030* 1,820* ENV 1,796* 1,796* 2,730* 2,450* 2,287* 2,123* 2,240* n 70 68 57 64 68 62 389 Small Cap HR 1,248 1,435 1,470 1,383 1,610 1,540 1,435 ENV 0,560 0,676 0,855 0,886 1,166 1,166 0,886 n 106 112 144 120 109 121 712

Notes: †: Significantly different from mid cap companies at the 95% level. * Significantly different from small cap companies at the 95% level. Statistical differences are tested for significance using the Mann-Whitney U-Test.

____________________

5. See appendix for details on the Mann-Whitney U-test

Page 22: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

18

As seen, the difference in median between the different size-classifications is statistically

significant in every year. This implies that larger firms are being perceived as more responsible

than smaller firms. This will be important to bear in mind later on when we are estimating the

effects of being responsible on financial performance.

When it comes to our two different measures of financial performance all data used are

obtained from company records using Datastream. Data are obtained for the years 2005-2011.

3.3 The Model

This study treats CSR as an investment in company reputation and tries to gauge the effect of

it on the firm’s current ability to maximize shareholder value. What we are studying is if

previous and current investment in CSR affects the marginal return on the firm’s investments

as a whole? We are also testing if CSR have any effect on accounting profitability.

To test the relationship between corporate social responsibility, measured as the CSR-Score

given in the Folksam index on sustainable business (the index), and the firm’s ability to

maximize shareholder value measured by marginal q, regression (8) below is ran. Regression

(8) is simply equation (6) with an interaction term for CSR and control variables included. All

variables are divided by in accordance with Gugler et al. (2004). For the relationship

between CSR and financial performance in accounting terms, regression (9) will be employed.

Regression (9) contains, apart from ROA and CSR-Scores, control variables commonly used

(Beta and Debt) when estimating ROA.

(8)

(

) (

)

(9)

Where;

is the market value of the firm

is the depreciation rate of capital for the firm (and the intercept of regression (7))

is the total amount of funds available for investment

is a measure of the firms level of social responsibility, here denoted as HR for human rights

score and ENV for environmental score

is an error term which is assumed to be normally distributed with mean 0 and variance .

is return on assets, calculated as in (7)

Page 23: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

19

is the intercept of regression (8)

is the Beta of the firm

is the ratio of the firms debt to its total book value (debt-to-value ratio)

is a dummy variable that takes on a value of 1 if the firm belonged to the large cap

segment on the Stockholm Stock Exchange in the given year, and 0 otherwise.

is a dummy variable that takes on a value of 1 if the firm belonged to the small cap

segment on the Stockholm Stock Exchange in the given year, and 0 otherwise.

The market value of the firm is calculated as follows:

(10) ( )

So that the market value represents the sum of the market value of equity and the book value

of debt (book value of debt is used as a proxy for market value of debt).

Total funds available for investment are calculated (in accordance with Mueller & Reardon

(1993)) as follows:

(11)

Here, debt is yet again calculated as the difference between total assets and book value of

equity. Mueller & Reardon’s (1993) original formula contained advertising expenditures which

have been excluded in this paper due to lack of data.

Earlier in this paper I discussed the fact that CSR-Scores tends to vary with firm size. More

specifically, it was showed that the median CSR-Scores of firms were significantly different

between large, medium sized and small firms. If firm size also is correlated with the change in

market value and ROA, our dependent variables, our estimates might be biased by the fact

that we have omitted firm size from the model. To prohibit this and to account for the fact

that CSR-Scores systematically varies across the size-segments two dummy variables are

included in the regressions. One dummy is included for Large Cap companies and one for

Small Cap companies making Mid Cap firms the baseline size in the regression. Some readers

may wonder why the dummy variables aren’t allowed to interact with the investment ratio in a

fashion similar to the variables measuring CSR. Doing so would possibly have yielded

interesting results such as estimates of the effect of size on marginal q. When this approach

was tested however, interacting the dummy variables with the investment ratio gave rise to

severe statistical difficulties such as multicollinearity, making interpretation very difficult. As

such, I choose to use dummy variables in their “original form”.

Page 24: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

20

In the case of regression (9) it is also plausible to believe that ROA varies significantly across

industries due to factors such as capital needs and profit margins. Some industries may

therefore be able to consistently exhibit higher ROAs. Therefore, that model must take

industry effects into account. To achieve that purpose, a fixed-effects model using industry

specific fixed effects is employed for regression (9).

The regression model outlined in equation (8) will tell us several things. Firstly, the intercept

would normally provide us with an estimate of the depreciation rate of capital for the

companies in the sample, plus the systemic change in market valuation. However, since we

have introduced dummy variables in the regression this is not entirely true anymore. By

having one dummy for Large Cap firms and one for Small Cap firms we are effectively

making Mid Cap firms our “base-line”. This means that the intercept term will, apart from

estimating the depreciation rate and systemic change in market valuation, also estimate an

effect related to being a mid-sized firm. Normally, one would expect the intercept term to

take on a negative sign, but since being mid-sized may very well have a positive effect on the

change in market value; it may take on a positive sign. However, this estimate is not really of

interest for the purposes of this study.

Secondly, it will provide us with an estimate of marginal q. It will do so by first estimating

which will tell us the effect of one additional unit of investment on the change in market

value, which is the definition of marginal q as it is formulated by Gugler et al. (2004).

However, this is only a partial estimate of marginal q. With the inclusion of the third term in

(8) I aim to bring in the effect of the firm´s human rights and environmental scores into the

model. Since I am looking to estimate the effect of being perceived as responsible within both

fields, the intuitive way would be to include the scores in both areas as interaction terms in (8).

There is however reason to suspect that the CSR-Scores on human rights and environmental

work may be correlated with each other. Table 2 seems to support this suspicion; if the

average score on human rights is high, the average score on environmental work is high as

well, and vice versa. Scores also seem to co-vary across time. That means that we may

encounter a multicollinearity problem if we include both CSR-variables in the regression. To

test if multicollinearity is present in the data, the variance-inflating factor (VIF) is calculated

for each of the explanatory variables. VIF is calculated by regressing each of the explanatory

variables on each other. From these regressions the R2 is obtained and VIF is the calculated

as:

(12)

( )

As can be seen from (12), the VIF has a minimum value of 1, which it will take on if R2 is

zero. Therefore, a VIF of 1 implies that there is no correlation what so ever between the

explanatory variable of interest and the other explanatory variables. As R2 increase, implying a

higher degree of correlation among the explanatory variables, the VIF increases into infinity.

Generally, a is considered to imply problems relating to multicollinearity (Aczel &

Sounderpandian, 2008) but higher cut off values such as has been proposed.

Page 25: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

21

The VIFs for our explanatory variables are indeed high, ranging between 8,5 and 20,

indicating that multicollinearity is indeed present in regression (8). The VIFs for regression (9)

did not indicate a multicollinearity problem. If we were to run regression (8) in its current

form, we would thus risk estimating statistically insignificant (low t-ratios) coefficients, where

they in fact should be significant (Gujarati & Porter, 2008).

To remedy this, I consider estimating two separate regression models for the estimation of

marginal q with one CSR-variable in each so that the variable is the score on human rights

(13) and the score on environmental work (14), respectively:

(13)

(

)

and

(14)

(

)

By doing this, the multicollinearity arising from the correlation between the two CSR-variables

will be removed. Looking at the VIFs for model (12) and (13) we can see that they have

decreased significantly compared to (7):

Table 3 – Variance-Inflating Factors for different specifications

Notes: VIF-values for the Dummy Variables are excluded from this table. They were however low, with the highest value at 1,43.

Thus, the method for estimating the effect of being perceived as socially responsible on the

ability to maximize shareholder wealth will be to perform two separate regressions, (13) and

(14), for each of the measures on social responsibility. Even though no multicollinearity

problem was detected in the regression estimating the effect on ROA, I will still chose to

estimate two separate regressions there as well, with one measure of CSR in each. This will

make comparison between the results easier later on.

In the case of the estimation of marginal q this methodology will mean that will give us an

estimate of marginal q for a firm that has a score of zero (the lowest score possible in the

index) on both human rights and environmental work. is thus the marginal q for a firm

that is perceived as socially irresponsible (or just negligent to the issue as a whole) by the

(8)

(13)

(14)

Page 26: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

22

index’s standards. will then give us estimates of the impact that the CSR-score on human

rights and environmental work respectively has on a firm´s marginal q. A positive and

significant estimate of would imply that firms that are perceived as socially responsible

exhibit higher returns on investment and thus, that they are better at maximizing shareholder

wealth than their irresponsible (or negligent) counterparts.

Such a finding would support hypothesis 1 of this paper. The marginal q estimated in our

model will thus be given by the following formula:

(15)

Why this is the case is easily understood by looking at equation (8). Since the two explanatory

variables are exactly the same with the exception that the second term are multiplied with the

firms CSR-Score, the only source of additional variance introduced into the model by adding

the second term are coming from the variance in CSR-Scores. Thus, all the explanatory power

that is attributable only to the term

will be contained in and the explanatory power of

perceived social responsibility´s effect on market value will be contained in .

The interpretation of the regressions estimating the effect on ROA is very straightforward.

The variables of interest are the coefficients on the two measures of CSR, and the remaining

variables are included as controls. Positive and significant estimates of the coefficients for the

CSR variables would support hypothesis 2 of this paper that responsible firms perform better

in accounting terms.

Page 27: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

23

3.4 Estimation Technique

The regression technique for the estimation of marginal q will be a pooled OLS regression. A

fixed-effects regression technique was considered to account for the fact that there may exist

some firm and/or time specific effects other than investment (and that is uncorrelated with the

level of investment) that are affecting the market value of a firm. Fixed effects have been

introduced in models trying to assess the relationship between CSR and financial performance

before. In a recent study, Nelling & Webb (2009) used fixed-effects techniques to reject the

hypothesis that such a relationship existed and attributed previous contradicting results to

problems arising from not taking fixed effects into account. In the case of this study however,

the models using firm, time and two-ways (both time and firm specific effects) fixed effects

did not provide a different result than the pooled OLS technique. In addition to that, all

models making use of fixed effects showed lower values for adjusted , implying that

introducing fixed effects did not improve the model. It thus seems reasonable to assume that

the relationship between investment, CSR and market value is relatively constant across both

firms and time (at least in the case of our 6 year sample) and we may thus proceed with the

estimation using a pooled OLS panel data regression technique. The interested reader may

consult Table 8 in appendix for the estimated coefficients and adjusted s for all four

regression techniques.

The model that tries to estimates the relationship between CSR and accounting profitability

makes use of industry-specific fixed effects to account for the fact that ROA may vary

systematically across industries because of e.g. profit margins, competiveness and capital

requirements. A Hausman test6 (Hausman, 1978) was used to test if a random effects model

was more appropriate. The result indicated that random effects indeed were preferable but

employing such effects did not alter the results significantly. The result from both regression

techniques are given in the following chapter.

____________________

6. See Table 9 in the appendix for output.

Page 28: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

24

4 Empirical Results

The results are summarized in table 5 and 6 below:

Table 5 – Estimates of marginal q

Notes: *: Statistically significant at the 5% level. **: Statistically significant at the 1% level. †: Significantly different from 1 at the 5% level. Marginal q is calculated using the formula given in (15) where Z is the median and mean CSR-Scores, respectively.

Model

(13) 0,1080** (0,0402)

0,8224**† (0,03621)

0,0787** (0,0230)

1,75 1,98 0,960 – 0,978 -0,1288* -0,0970* 0,787 1346** 1453

(14) 0,0979** (0,0404)

0,8790**† (0,0242)

0,0834** (0,0291)

1,61 1,93 1,013 – 1,039 -0,1285* -0,090* 0,785 1342**

1453

Page 29: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

25

Table 6 – Estimates of ROA

Notes: *: Statistically significant at the 5% level. **: Statistically significant at the 1% level. Fixed effects are industry specific and estimated using the within-group (WG) estimator.

Recall equation (15):

(15)

This means that our estimates for marginal q for a firm that has a CSR-Score of zero is 0,8224

(13) and 0,879 (14). Remembering that a firm maximizes shareholder wealth if and

that

(3)

It follows that and consequently that for a firm that maximizes

shareholder wealth. In our case however (statistically significant at the 5% level)

implying that in general, firms that were listed on the Stockholm stock exchange during the

period 2006-2011 and who were perceived to have a very low level of social responsibility

were unable to maximize wealth for their shareholders. More specifically, firms with a very low

level of social responsibility are overinvesting, either by committing themselves to too many

investment projects or by choosing projects that produce an insufficient return.

The finding that firms in general are unable to invest a level that maximizes shareholder

wealth is consistent with the original findings of Mueller & Reardon (1991) and with those of

Gugler et al. (2004)7. It is also consistent with agency theory which predicts that the presence

of agency costs may prevent a public firm from fully maximizing shareholder value.

____________________

7. Gugler et.al. (2004) estimated a marginal q of 0,65 for the Swedish market, well below the condition for

shareholder wealth maximization.

Fixed Effects

0,007 (0,005)

-0,032** (0,007)

-0,149** (0,029)

0,026 -0,084* 0,066 20,04 1406

0,010* (0,004)

-0,032** (0,007)

-0,156** (0,029)

0,023 -0,079** 0,068 20,70 1406

Random Effects

0,1307** (0,026)

0,008 (0,005)

-0,032** (0,007)

-0,135** (0,028)

0,024 -0,085** 0,067 20,48 1406

0,128** (0,025)

0,011* (0,004)

-0,033** (0,007)

-0,145** (0,028)

0,021 -0,079** 0,070 21,27 1406

Page 30: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

26

The intercepts are positive and significant in both models estimating marginal q implying that

no erosion of firm’s capital stock took place over the sample period. On the contrary, the

firm’s capital stock seems to have appreciated over the sampling period. However, since we

have introduced dummies into the regressions, the intercept term contains both an estimate of

the depreciation rate of capital and of the effect of being a mid-sized firm. In this case, there

seems to be a positive effect associated with being a mid-sized firm that dominates the

depreciation effect, although we cannot be sure. However, since neither the depreciation rate

nor the estimates of size effects are of particular interest for this study, no further attention

will be paid to that issue.

The estimates for is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level of confidence for

both measures of CSR in regressions (13) and (14). This implies that being perceived by the

market as socially responsible within the fields of human rights and environmental work is

associated with a higher marginal return on investment and thus with a greater ability to

maximize shareholder wealth.

The 7th column of table 5 shows the range of estimates of marginal q calculated using

equation (14), when is the median and mean CSR-Scores within respective fields. As seen,

firms that hold the median and/or means score in the index have an estimated marginal q

very close to 1, our condition for wealth-maximization. Indeed, a test for statistically

significant difference from 1 reveals that the estimates for marginal q are not significantly

different from 1.Together with the fact that firms who exhibit a score of zero have marginal

q’s that are significantly below 1, this means that while firms with very low scores are unable

to maximize shareholder value, firms with an average score are able to so.

Table 6 indicates that being perceived as socially responsible within the field of human rights

have no significant impact on financial performance measured by ROA whilst being perceived

as responsible within the field of environmental work has. This means that although firms

with high scores on human rights exhibit higher marginal returns on investment using market

based measures, they do not exhibit higher average returns using accounting based measures.

When it comes to environmental work however, firms with high scores exhibit both higher

marginal and average returns.

For the analysis of these results we should first recall what the index on responsible business

actually measures. As is laid out in the “Method” chapter it aims to quantify “…to what extent

the firm has proper managerial guidance systems in place to deal with risks within the areas of

environmental impact and human rights”. This means that firms that have extensive

managerial guidance systems that are compliant with international standards are the ones that

will obtain the highest scores. The keyword here is “managerial”. CSR is an issue for

management, as is investment decisions. Some researchers have suggested that the process of

building the rigid managerial guidance systems required to obtain a high CSR-Score can help

managers develop other competencies such as better scanning skills, processes and

information systems (Orlitzky et al., 2003). These management skills that are acquired thru an

internal process (Orlitzky et al., 2003) could then lead to the ability to better utilize resources

thru increased productivity (Majumbar & Marcus, 2001). If this is the case, CSR would have

an important signaling function as an indication of high managerial competence, which has

Page 31: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

27

been suggested by McWilliams et al. (2006). If CSR signals managerial competence, markets

may perceive the actions of managers of responsible firms to be better than actions of

managers for less responsible firms. In such a scenario, the market may “reward” the

investment decision of a responsible firm with a larger increase in market value then if the

firm had been less responsible because it assumes by default that the managers of the more

responsible firm are more capable of making investment decisions that generate high future

returns. Responsible firms would then exhibit a higher marginal return on investment because

of the markets perception of its managers. The existence of such a signaling effect could also

explain why the evidence in favor of CSR-related activities are stronger when looking at

market based performance measures than accounting based ones. If markets do indeed

perceive managers of socially responsible firms as more competent and reward their

investment decisions with a larger increase in market value than if the firm had been perceived

as less responsible that effectively means that they are valuing the future prospects of

responsible firms higher than those of less responsible firms. This is regardless of the

accounting profits made by the firm today. If so, it is certainly possible that an increase in the

level of CSR of a firm would lead to an increase in market value (and a higher marginal q) but

not necessarily to higher accounting profits such as ROA.

Another possible explanation for the positive effect of CSR on marginal q is that responsible

firms simply make better investment decisions. For instance, a firm who maintain good

working conditions in their factories may enjoy increased worker productivity which would

increase the possibility of earning a high return on the investments made in those factories. A

similar case could be made for firms who take environmental responsibility by e.g. reducing

pollution from a factory: Such work could lead to reduced energy costs for the factory,

thereby increasing the possibility of earning a high return on the investments made in that

factory. If this is the case however, we should be able to observe a positive relationship

between CSR and financial performance not only when looking at marginal q but also when

looking at ROA. That is, the returns to being perceived as responsible should show up not

only in the markets judgment of the company’s prospects, but also in the company’s books.

Table 6 however gave us very weak evidence in favor of this theory. A weak positive

relationship seems to exist between a firm’s environmental score and ROA, but no

relationship was found when it comes to human rights. This gives some credence to the idea

that taking environmental responsibility, for instance by reducing pollution, may lead to higher

profitability through e.g. a reduction in energy costs. The same case however cannot be made

for human rights and e.g. working conditions.

Apart from the theory that CSR has a signaling function towards the market which allows

responsible firms to realize higher returns in market terms, there are several other potential

reasons for the discrepancy between the results of market and accounting based measures.

Page 32: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

28

First of all it should be noted that the validity of using accounting data to measure and

compare financial performance across firms and industry have been questioned (see for

instance Benston, 1985, Fisher & McGowan,1983 and Herremans et. al. 1993).The reason for

this is that accounting standards differ across firms (although they all must adhere to Swedish

law). Market based measures on the other hand do not, because they measure the markets

aggregated evaluation of accounting data and other firm-specific pieces of information. When

we treat the market as on single entity, we can assume that the different preferences and

interpretations of accounting data made by its individual actors are averaged out across the

population. This is equivalent to assuming that the market makes an unbiased estimate of the

available information, which in turn follows from the assumption of capital market efficiency

made in this paper. Firms may also have incentives to (legally) distort the accounting data it

presents. A high-performing firm wants to report lower than actual profits for tax reasons and

an underperforming firm may want to show itself in a more favorable light than is actually the

case. By using an accounting based measure such as ROA, both these biases may become an

issue. A market based performance measure however, under the assumption of capital market

efficiency, will be less likely to suffer from these biases because the market will take firm-

specific accounting practices into account when making its evaluation of the firm.

Another important difference between accounting-based and market-based performance

measures is the time-aspect. While accounting data presents us with a snapshot of the state of

the firm at years end, the market data used (change in market value of the firm) incorporates

all previous, present and future information and prospects of the firm (This, of course,

assumes an efficient market). If for example being perceived as socially responsible have long-

run effects on corporate images and brands (which was argued by Fombrun & Shanley, 1990)

this would be reflected in the market value of the firm but not necessarily in the firms ROA.

Taken all together, the evidence obtained seems strong enough to accept hypothesis one, that

socially responsible firms are better at maximizing shareholder value. The results given in

Table 5 shows positive and significant estimates of both measures of CSR’s effect on marginal

q and that the median (in CSR terms) firm has a marginal q very close to 1, our condition for

shareholder value maximization. As has been argued above, the fact that an equally strong

effect was not observed in accounting data does not necessarily refute these findings.

Acceptance of hypothesis one gives credence to some of the ideas put forth by proponents of

stakeholder theory but more importantly, indicates that engaging in CSR activities is

compliant with the responsibility of value maximization that the firm has towards its

shareholders. Thus, this study finds no support for the notion that engagement in CSR-

practices constitutes an agency problem.

Page 33: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

29

When it comes to hypothesis two, that firms who are responsible exhibit higher financial

performance in accounting terms the results are inconclusive at best. Being responsible with

regard to environmental issues seems to have a weak positive effect on ROA, but no such

effect exists when looking at human rights. The finding of a positive effect of CSR when

looking at market based measures and no/weak effect when looking at accounting measures is

somewhat consistent with theory which suggests that CSR may have a signaling effect that

causes the market to view the responsible firm more favorably. As mentioned earlier, such an

effect could result in the responsible firm being valued higher than the irresponsible firm,

despite not realizing higher accounting profits. The discrepancy of results may also, as

discussed above, have other reasons. Since no convincing evidence of a positive link between

CSR and accounting profits is found, I reject hypothesis two and conclude that socially

responsible firms do indeed exhibit higher marginal returns on investment and seem to be

more able to maximize shareholder value, but they do not necessarily exhibit higher

accounting profits. It follows that being perceived as socially responsible is a reputational

advantage that allows the firm’s owners to reap a higher marginal rate of return on their

investments than their irresponsible/less responsible competitors even though they might not

perform better in accounting terms. Previous and current investments in CSR have thus

placed the firm in a position where it is favored by the market.

Page 34: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

30

5 Summary & Conclusions

This paper has treated CSR as an investment in reputation, and as such has sought to

investigate the return of that investment. The findings imply that firms who invest a lot in

CSR (i.e have a high score in the index) are able to enjoy a higher marginal rate of return on

its overall investments and thus, that they are better at maximizing shareholder value

compared to firms who invest less in CSR. These findings contradict theory suggesting that

investment in CSR made by management constitutes an agency problem and supports, by

utilizing a different methodology, the findings made by many previous researchers. The

findings imply that investing in CSR is consistent with the shareholders explicit claim of value

maximization on the firm and thus that investment in CSR is justifiable in a stakeholder and

agency theory context as well as in the context of the more traditional view of the firm

advocated by e.g. Friedman (1970).

This paper also finds that even though socially responsible firms are better at maximizing

shareholder value, they do not exhibit significantly higher returns on assets. This suggests two

things:

Firstly, it suggest, in line with previous research8, that CSR has a signaling effect which causes

the market to look more favorably on socially responsible firms. Investments in CSR could

thus allow the firm to reap a higher marginal rate of return on its investments than it

previously could, all else equal.

Secondly, it suggests that the positive effects of being perceived as socially responsible may be

long-term (or at least medium-term). If that is the case, the anticipated long-term effect would

be reflected in the markets valuation of the company but not necessarily in its accounting

profits. Future research may examine more closely the nature of (if any) long-term effects, as

more data becomes available.

Lastly, the issue of causality has not been addressed in this paper. Previous studies have

investigated this to some extent and some findings suggest that financial performance is

driving CSR, rather than the other way around9. The logic behind such reasoning is that well-

performing firms have more “spare cash” to invest in CSR-projects. Furthers studies may

investigate the possibility of reverse causality in the Swedish data set.

____________________

8. E.g. McWilliams (2006), Orlitzky et. al. (2003) and Majumbar & Marcus (2001). 9.

See Nelling & Webb (2009) and McGuire et al. (1988)

Page 35: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

31

References

Aczel, D. Amir and Sounderpandian, Jayavel. (2008). Complete Business Statistics. 7th edition, McGraw-Hill Publishing Arlow, Peter and Gannon, J Martin. (1982) .Social Responsiveness, Corporate Structure and Financial Performance. The Academy of Management Review, Vol.7, No. 2, pp 235-241 Alexander, G.J and Buchholz , R.A. (1978). Corporate Social Responsibility and Stock Market Performance. Academy of Management Journal, pp 479-486 Beatty, P Randolph and Ritter, R Jay. (1986). Investment Banking, Reputation and the underpricing of initial public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics 15, pp 213-232 Benston, J George. (1985). The Validity of Profit-Structure Studies with particular reference to the FTC´s line of business data. American Economic Review, Vol.75(1), pp.37-67. Berle, A.A Jr and Means, C Gardiner. )1930). Corporations and the public investor. American Economic Review, Vol.20, No.1, pp 54-71 Bowman, E H and Haire, M. (1975). A strategic posture toward corporate social responsibility. California Management Review, Vol. 18(2), pp 49-58 Cochran, L Philip and Wood, A Robert. (1984). Corporate Social Responsibility and Financial Performance. The Academy of Management Journal, Vol.27, No.1 pp 42-56 Cornell, B and Shapiro C Alan. (1987). Corporate Stakeholder and Corporate Finance. Financial Management, Vol.16, No 1, pp 5-14 Dowling, R Grahame. (1986). Managing Your Corporate Images. Industrial Marketing Management 15, pp 109-115 Fama, F Eugene. (1970). Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work. The Journal of Finance, Vol.25, No.2, pp 383-417 Fama, F Eugene and Jensen, C Michael. (1983). Agency Problems and Residual Claims. Journal of Law and Economics, Vol.26, No.2, pp 327-349 Fisher, M Franklin and McGowan, J John. (1983). On the misuse of accounting rates of return to infer monopoly profits. American Economic Review, Vol.73(1), pp. 82-97 Freeman, R. Edward. (1984). Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach. Cambridge University Press

Friedman, M. (1970). The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase Its Profits. The New York Times Magazine, September 13

Page 36: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

Folger, H R & Nutt, F A. (1975). A note on social responsibility and stock valuation. Academy of Management Journal, Vol.18, pp. 155-160 Fombrun, C and Shanley, M. (1990). Whats in a name? Reputation Bulding and Corporate Strategy. Academy of Management Journal, Vol.33, No.2, pp 233-258 Griffin, J Jennifer and Mahon, F John. (1997). The Corporate Social Performance and Corporate Financial Performance Debate. Business and Society, Vol.36, No.1 pp 5-31 Gujarati, N Damodar and Porter, C Dawn. (2008). Basic Econometrics. 5th edition, McGraw-Hill Publishing. Gugler, Klaus, Mueller, C Dennis and Yurtoglu, B Burcin. (2004). Marginal q, Tobin’s q, Cash Flow and Investment. Southern Economic Journal, Vol 70, No. 3, pp 512-531 Gugler, Klaus and Yurtoglu, B Burcin. (2003). Average q, marginal q, and the relation between ownership and performance. Economics Letters, 78, pp 379-384 Hausman, J A. (1978). Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica, Vol. 46(6) pp 1251-1271 Henderson, David. (2009). Misguided Corporate Virtue: The Case Against CSR and The True Role of Business Today. Economic Affairs, Vol.29(4), pp 11-15 Herremans, M Irene, Akathaporn, Parporn and McInnes, Morris. (1993). An investigation of Corporate Social Reputation and Economic Performance. Accounting, Organization and Society, Vol.18, No.7/8, pp. 587-604 Jensen, C Michael. (1988). Takeovers: Their causes and consequences. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol.2(1), pp. 21-48 Jensen, C Michael and Meckling, H William. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial Behaviour, Agency Cost and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics (3), pp 305-360 Majumbar. K. Sumit and Marcus, A. Alfred. (2001). Rules versus Discretion: The Productivity Consequences of Flexible Regulation. The Academy of Management Journal, Vol.44, No.1, pp 170-179 Mann, Henry B and Whitney, Donald R. (1947). On a Test of whether one of two random variables are stochastically larger than the other. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, Vol.18(1), pp. 50-60 Mcguire, B Jean, Sundgren Alison and Schneeweis Thomas. (1988). Corporate Social Responsibility and Firm Financial Performance. The Academy of Management Journal, Vol.31, No.4 pp 854-872 McWilliams, Abagail, Siegel, S. Donald. (2001). Corporate Social Resposnsibility: A Theory of the Firm perspective. Academy of Management Review, Vol.28, No.1, pp.117-127

McWilliams, Abagail, Siegel, S. Donald and Wright, M. Patrick. (2006). Corporate Social Responsibility: Strategic Implications. Journal of Management Studies¸43:1

Page 37: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

Moskowitz, M.R. (1972). Choosing Socially Responsble Stock. Business and Society Review, pp 71-75 Mueller, C Dennis and Reardon, A Elizabeth. (1993). Rates of Return on Corporae Investment. Southern Economic Journal, 60 (2), pp 430-453. Nelling, Edward and Webb, Elizabeth. (2009). Corporate social responsibility and financial performance: the “virtuous circle” revisited. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, Vol. 32, pp 197-209 OECD. (2011). OECD Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises. OECD Publishing, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264115415-en Orlitzky, Marc. (2001). Does firm size confound the relationship between Corporate Social Responsibility Performance and Firm Financial Performance. Journal of Business Ethics, Vol.33, No.2, pp. 167-180 Orlitzky, Marc, Schmidt. L Frank and Rynes, L. Sara. (2003). Corporate Social and Financial Performance: A Meta-Analysis. Organization Studies, Vol.24(3), pp 403-441 Parket, I R and Eilbert , H. (1975). Social Responsibility: The underlying factors. Business Horizons, Vol.18(4), pp. 5-10 Raffournier, Bernard. (1995). The determinants of voluntary financial disclosure by Swiss listed companies. The European Accounting Review, Vol.4, No.2, pp 261-280 Roman, M Ronald, Hayibor, Sefa and Agle, R Bradley. (1999). The Relationship between Social and Financial Performance. Business and Society, Vol. 38, No.1, pp 109-125 Shapiro, C. (1983). Premiums for high quality products as returns to reputations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.98(4), pp 659-679 Soana, M. (2011). The Relationship Between Corporate Social Performance and Corporate Financial Performance in the Banking Sector. Journal of Business Ethics, Vol.104, pp 133-148 Spicer, H Barry. (1978). Investor, Corporate Social Responsibility and Information Disclosure: An Empiral Study. The Accountung Review, Vol. 53, No. 1, pp 94-111 Sturdivant, F.D and Ginter, J.L. (1977). Corporate social responsiveness: Management attitudes and economic performance. California Management Review, Vol.19(3), pp 30-39 Tobin, J. (1969). A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory. Journal of Money, Credit

and Banking, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp 15-29

Vance, S.C. (1975). Are socially responsible corporations good investment risks? Management

Review, Vol. 64(8), pp 18-24

Waddock, A Sandra and Graves, B Samuel. (1997). The Corporate Social Performance-

Financial Performance Link. Strategic Management Journal, Vol.18, No.4 pp 303-319

Page 38: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

Wood, J Donna. (1991). Corporate Social Responsibility Revisited. The Academy of Management

Review, Vol.16, No.4 pp 691-718

All statistical computations in this paper have been performed using R. Accordingly,

R and all packages used are cited below.

Frederic Ibanez and Philippe Grosjean & Michele Etienne <[email protected]> (2012). pastecs: Package for Analysis of Space-Time Ecological Series. R package version 1.3-11. http://CRAN.R-project.org/package=pastecs

R Core Team (2012). R: A language and environment for statistical computing. R Foundation for Statistical Computing, Vienna, Austria. ISBN 3-900051-07-0, URL http://www.R-project.org/. Richard M. Heiberger (2012). HH: Statistical Analysis and Data Display: Heiberger and Holland. R package version 2.3-17 http://CRAN.R-project.org/package=HH Yves Croissant, Giovanni Millo (2008). Panel Data Econometrics in R: The plm Package. Journal of Statistical Software 27(2). URL http://www.jstatsoft.org/v27/i02/.

Page 39: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

35

Appendix

1 The Mann-Whitney U-Test

The Mann-Whitney U-Test is a non-parametric statistical test used to determine whether one of

two samples of independent information have larger values than the other. Since it is non-

parametric, it is suitable for testing for differences when the data has a non-normal distribution.

The data to which the Mann-Whitney U-Test is applied to in this paper had a skewed

distribution, with the result that the means are a poor indicator of the central tendency in the

data. The Mann-Whitney U-Test was thus used to test for differences in the median across groups.

The null hypothesis of such a test is that the distribution of the two samples is identical, and

rejection of the null implies statistically significant differences between them. The test is

performed by combining the samples and rank the observations from smallest to largest. The

sum of the ranks from one of the population is then denoted .The large-sample test statistic

for the test is:

( )

Where,

( )

√ ( )

( )

Page 40: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

36

Tables

Table 7 – Median CSR-Scores by Industry

MSCI Industry Group

HR ENV HR ENV HR ENV HR ENV HR ENV HR ENV

Automobiles & Components 3,27 4,73 3,20 4,48 3,21 4,33 3,24 4,11 3,12 3,89 2,96 3,71

Banks 3,33 2,78 3,05 2,19 3,19 3,66 3,52 4,03 4,41 3,66 4,48 3,85

Capital Goods 1,54 2,43 1,77 2,54 1,93 2,75 2,00 2,80 2,07 2,77 1,98 2,72

Commercial & Professional Services 1,90 1,63 1,86 1,21 2,10 1,35 1,79 1,52 2,50 1,94 2,49 1,80

Consumer Durables & Apparel 1,84 1,90 1,82 1,75 2,42 2,05 2,66 1,98 2,31 2,05 2,35 1,98

Consumer Services 0,29 0,56 1,21 1,75 1,16 1,70 1,16 1,70 1,35 1,77 1,40 1,77

Diversified Financials 0,88 0,09 0,98 0,33 0,88 0,27 0,88 0,30 1,40 0,68 1,54 0,77

Energy 2,74 2,40 0,21 0,93 0,35 0,93 0,88 1,42 0,82 1,58 1,05 1,55

Food & Staples Retailing 4,46 4,25 4,27 3,94 4,27 3,94 4,38 3,94 4,24 4,18 4,38 4,08

Food, Beverage & Tobacco 4,12 3,69 2,45 3,59 2,49 3,59 1,61 2,92 2,38 3,07 2,10 2,92

Health Care Equipment & Services 1,69 0,78 1,68 0,58 1,51 0,49 2,63 0,00 1,44 0,29 1,33 0,00

Household & Personal Products 2,02 2,23 2,07 2,28 2,05 2,21 2,05 2,21 2,38 2,52 2,40 2,51

Materials 3,11 5,34 2,85 5,01 3,26 5,13 3,19 4,88 3,31 4,71 3,43 4,05

Media 0,96 0,15 1,75 0,19 1,75 0,00 1,45 0,61 2,00 1,10 2,15 1,26

Pharmaceuticals, Biotechnology & Life Sciences 1,58 0,89 1,51 0,89 1,54 0,89 1,54 1,03 1,54 1,03 1,40 0,89

Real Estate 1,75 3,31 1,54 3,10 1,65 3,10 1,86 3,01 2,03 3,01 2,03 2,52

Retailing 2,35 1,61 2,07 2,43 2,07 2,06 2,49 2,24 2,77 1,54 2,73 1,75

Software & Services 1,17 0,00 2,35 0,00 2,56 0,05 2,49 0,49 2,84 0,58 2,73 0,63

Technology Hardware & Equipment 0,93 1,30 1,02 1,35 1,02 1,56 1,19 1,66 1,61 1,75 1,45 1,80

Telecommunication Services 0,58 0,26 0,39 0,16 0,86 0,15 1,94 1,40 2,56 1,52 2,56 2,43

Transportation 1,21 2,79 1,30 2,70 1,30 2,64 1,19 2,47 1,19 3,24 1,54 3,10

Utilities NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA 0,91 1,31 0,75 1,00

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Page 41: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

37

Table 8 – Regression Results for different estimation techniques

Notes: *: Statistically significant at the 5% level. **: Statistically significant at the 1% level. All fixed effects models are estimated using within transformation.

Estimation Technique

Pooled OLS

(12) 0,8224** (0,0362)

0,0787** (0,0230)

0,78534

(13) 0,8790** (0,0242)

0,0834** (0,0291)

0,78484

Firm-Fixed Effects

(12) 0,7869** (0,0419)

0,1042** (0,0265)

0,6188

(13) 0,8734** (0,0283)

0,0950** (0,0338)

0,61773

Time-Fixed Effects

(12) 0,8196** (0,0362)

0,0795** (0,0230)

0,78219

(13) 0,8766** (0,0243)

0,0845** (0,0291)

0,78169

Firm and Time Fixed Effects

(12) 0,7850** (0,0420)

0,1044** (0,0265)

0,61575

(13) 0,8714** (0,0285)

0,0956** (0,0339)

0,61469

Page 42: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

38

Table 9 – The Hausman Test for Estimating ROA

Notes: The Hausman-test has the Chi-Square distribution. Under the null hypothesis, Random Effects model is preferable to fixed effects due to higher efficiency. Rejection of the null implies that fixed effects are more efficient.

df p-value

5,2089 5 0,3909

3,7506 5 0,5859

Page 43: Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment …hj.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:618708/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Corporate Social Responsible and Return on Investment in ... The

39

Figures

Figure 2 – Histograms

Notes: scores$ENV is the score given to a company for their environmental work. scores$HR is the score given ti a company for their work within the area of human rights.