e. yasin, n. akindinova l. jakobson, a. yakovlev · 1 e. yasin, n. akindinova l. jakobson, a....

48
1 E. Yasin, N. Akindinova L. Jakobson, A. Yakovlev Is the new model of economic growth feasible for Russia? Moscow, 2013

Upload: trinhkhanh

Post on 11-Mar-2019

226 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

1

E. Yasin, N. Akindinova L. Jakobson, A. Yakovlev

Is the new model

of economic growth feasible for Russia?

Moscow, 2013

2

Table of contents

Summary ................................................................................................................ 3

1. World economy and Russia ........................................................................... 5

2. Russia’s point of departure............................................................................ 7

3. Choosing the way: scenarios for development ............................................ 15

4. New model of economic growth ..................................................................... 22

5. Drivers of new model and their activators .................................................. 26

7. Pabulum for reflection: How can we eliminate inequality and promote investment in human capital? ............................................................................ 40

Bibliography: ....................................................................................................... 47

3

Summary Hit by the crisis of 2008-2009, the world economy is now faced with new challenges. The

forthcoming decade will see global changes in the world financial system, a shifting balance of

power between developed and developing states. Russia has also exhausted its model of

economic growth based on exporting commodities against the backdrop of its current

institutional development and active involvement of the state into the economy as shown by the

dramatic slowdown in late 2012 and early 2013, with growth rates dipping below 2 %. As a

result, Russia’s share in the world economy will gradually shrink while the gap in labor

efficiency and living standards between Russia and developed countries is likely to widen. The

range of economic strategies currently being debated by the government suggests a choice

between expansive and conservative scenarios, which vary in monetary and budget parameters

but in essence mean the continuation of the current flawed institutions. However, our estimates

show that the fiscal and monetary promotion of economic growth are now limited and will not

produce a lasting impact on performance while a tough budget and monetary policy distorts the

structure of the public sector and increases uncertainty about public obligations beyond budget

limitations.

A new model of economic growth requires private enterprise, market institutions and

investments in human capital.

In this respect it is necessary to:

establish the rule of law, fostering the independence of courts

reshape the relationships between business, law enforcement and judicial agencies as a

trust building measure

reform local government, in order to promote civil society activism

promote private investment: to reform the pension system, healthcare, education and the

housing market

carry out democratization, establishing reasonable conditions for political competition

and regular regime change

The drivers of this new model of economic growth include two increasingly influential groups.

These are “new business” – a number of dynamic companies willing to grow in a market

environment but lacking incentives to invest within the current institutional framework. And the

“new bureaucracy” – progressive regional elites concerned about regional development and

federal professionals. However, the current management structure of the economy is a by-

product of a “vertical power structure” and fosters opportunism among “new businesses” and

4

“new bureaucracy”, encouraging redistribution rather that production. The transformation of this

system is beyond the scope of an individual “political will” or a small group of loyalists

(represented by “Politbureau 2.0”). It depends on the willingness and capabilities of the modern

Russian elite to reach a consensus about the “rules of the game” which they are prepared to obey

and which will not torpedo long-term economic and social objectives. At the same time, the

“voilent pressure” typical of Russia today is a waste of limited resources and could trigger

“mutual destruction” amongst the modern elite. Functional agreements on new rules of the game

can result only from a dialogue embracing interest groups representing major stakeholders. The

“right incentives” for the state machine are ensured by political competition and the pressure

exerted by an influential civil society.

5

1. World economy and Russia

Over the last five years, both the world and the Russian economy have been through dramatic

changes and need a comprehensive review. The crisis of 2008-2009 involved several stages.

After 2001, the economy boomed following the Federal Reserve System’s decision to reduce the

discount rate from 6% to 1%. As a result of the easing of monetary policy, the worldwide

economy boomed until 2008.

Table1.1. GDP growth in 2010 (year 2000 = 100)

Country GDP growth Developed countries

USA 118 Germany 109

France 112 Great Britain 115 Japan 107

Developing countries China 271 India 211 Brazil 1331) Turkey 146 Russia 159.5

Source: Federal State Statistics Service (Rosstat). Russia in Figures, 2011-1012, p. 569

1) In 2009

The fast growth of China should be noted, as it became the world leader during this

period. The development rate of India was also impressive and Brazil was very successful in this

field too. The Russian economy started to recover after a deep transformational crisis in a

favorable environment. It used its domestic reserves as well as soaring export prices (oil and

other commodities). As Table 1.1. shows, developing countries were the most successful.

Developed countries, while pushing the world forward, were growing more slowly. At that time,

the gap between developed and developing countries was impressively narrow.

6

Fig.1.1. World and Russian economy 1999-2012

Source: IMEMO, Russian Academy of Science. Russia and the World. Annual forecast. M. 2011,

p.14.

The crisis which erupted in 2008 showed that monetary easing had not had a lasting

impact. This crisis marked a new era. Its attributes so far include, along with the recession of

2008-2009, a slowdown and increased instability almost everywhere around the globe

Recovery and a new surge, which were widely expected, have not been apparent yet. A

protracted recession is looming, leading to speculation about its in-depth triggers. All major

actors, including the USA, EU, China, India, Latin America, have their own suggestions about

its roots. However, it seems that world economy is faced with an unprecedented challenge.

Experts vary in their assessment of the problem. The most frequent explanation is a lack

of regulation in the financial markets. A prominent economist1 in this respect said that tougher

control over international financial markets will eliminate independent market regulation by

market forces. Others relate global processes to an ageing population and excessive consumption

in developed countries, to an almost optimal age distribution in developing countries and a high

birthrate in poor countries unable to make savings.

One more point of view is worth considering, which states that the world is in transition

from an industrial stage of development to an innovative one. This means that during the

industrial stage there were plenty of cheap mineral raw materials and their wide use was an

important driver of high growth rates. However, now the price for non-renewable mineral

resources is rising and innovations aimed at productivity and efficiency have become the key

driver. In this respect there is a need for institutional change which encourages innovation: more

1 Deepak Lal.

-10,0

-8,0

-6,0

-4,0

-2,0

2,0

4,0

6,0

8,0

10,0

12,0

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Мир

Россия

World

Russia

7

freedom, more competition. One should not ignore the fact that if a new stage of development is

dawning, the structure and pace of business cycles should change as well. While all this is taking

shape, the economy is prone to adaptation spasms and other problems which can impede growth

and upset the balance. In the long run, the relative advantages will go to those who are able to

accumulate the largest innovation potential.

The crisis hit Russia quite badly and triggered a big recession (-7.8 % of GDP). However,

this could be amplified as the economy was overheated before. As a result, the two years of

crisis (2008-2009) were relatively easy for the country. However, later, as Fig. 1.1 and 1.2

shows, the situation in the economy changed.

Fig. 1.2. Russian GDP annual growth (100 = year 1990)

Source: Federal State Statistics Service (Rosstat), the HSE Center for Development calculations

The Russian position is in this case unique, as its economic competitiveness is lagging

behind developing countries for as long as as they have cost leadership (labor cost in the first

place) and a better price-quality ratio. They also have better innovation prospects. However,

there are several ways to narrow this gap. This is the key task of modernization. So far, Russia’s

strengths have been connected with natural resources, oil and gas. However, at the same time,

this could also be a weakness, since the country is tempted to neglect innovations and channel an

unreasonable share of resource revenues to support old sectors (for social considerations) or the

attributes of a one-time imperial power.

2. Russia’s point of departure

Macroeconomic performance: deceleration

The current state of the Russian economy and its medium-term potential are largely

determined by a recent model of growth based on the material sector and macroeconomic

Average growth in 2003-2007 (7.5% per year)

8

stability within the existing institutional framework and the active involvement of the state in the

\economy.

After the recession of 2008-2009, the Russian economy grew by 4.3-4.5% per year in

2010-2011. As a result, the actual GDP returned to the level of the middle of 2008 and

macroeconomic performance considerably improved. The 2011 Federal budget had a 0.8% GDP

surplus and the average inflation rate in the first half of 2012 plunged to 4%. All this enabled

Russia to reach a score of 22 in the competitiveness index published by the World Economic

Forum. Most experts believed that in the medium-term, Russia would be able to grow by 3-4%

annually.

Table 2.1. GDP growth as calculated for demand components2

Growth, % Contribution to GDP growth, percentage point

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

GDP 5.2 -7.8 4.5 4.3 3.4 5.2 -7.8 4.5 4.3 3.4

Including:

Final consumption 8.6 -3.9 3.5 4.9 4.8 5.7 -2.6 2.6 3.4 3.2

Households 10.6 -5.1 5.5 6.4 6.6 5.1 -2.5 3.0 3.3 3.2

State governance 3.4 -0.6 -1.5 1.2 0.0 0.6 -0.1 -0.3 0.2 0.0

NPISH (non-profit institutions serving households)

-1.4 -8.0 -0.5 -4.8 -1.0

0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0

Gross saving 10.5 -41.0 28.5 22.6 5.3 2.5 -10.5 5.4 5.1 1.3

gross fixed capital formation 10.6 -14.4 5.8 10.2 6.0 2.2 -3.2 1.3 2.2 1.3

stock changes - - - - - 0,3 -7,2 4,1 2,9 0,1

Export 0.6 -4.7 7.0 0.3 1.8 0.2 -1.5 2.0 0.1 0.5

Import 14.8 -30.4 25.8 20.3 8.7 3.2 -6.7 5.3 4.3 1.9

For reference: Domestic demand 9.1 -6.5 4.0 6.1 5.1 7.9 -5.8 3.9 5.6 4.5

Source: Federal State Statistics Service, the HSE Center for Development calculations.

However, in 2012, economic growth decelerated. This became apparent in the second

half of the year. Overall, Russia’s GDP increased by 3.4% last year, but early in 2013 the rate

fell to 1.5-2.0% year-on-year.

2 The chapter includes calculations of the THE THE HSE Center for Development researchers - Kondrashov N.V., Pukhov S.G., Tchernyavskiy A.V.

9

Fig. 2.1. GDP monthly rate as estimated by the Ministry of Economic Development of

Russia (year-on-year growth), %

Source: The Ministry of Economic Development of Russia The current slowdown has been triggered by a number of factors.

Firstly, as fossil fuel prices stopped rising and foreign fuel supplies measured by volume

stabilized, the export revenue growth rate fell from 33% in 2011 to 8% in 2012. At the same time

non-fossil exports shrank considerably last year, running counter to the hopes of a gradual

displacement of market-sensitive revenues through the expansion of other exports.

Despite oil and gas income in nominal terms reaching a historical maximum in 2012,

Russian economic agents observed its deceleration. The consensus about the world economic

performance suggests a protracted recession in the Eurozone, global disparities and budget

troubles in developed countries. Such a forecast hardly provides for a surge in fossil fuel price

or export expansion measured by volume, given that competition among gas suppliers to the

European market is becoming fiercer.

In January, 2013

10

Fig. 2.2. Export value (trend), USD bn

Source: Rosstat, the HSE Center for Development calculations

Secondly, there was a dramatic plunge of investment in 2012, triggered by external and

domestic factors. Investment rates almost halved, falling from 10.8% to 6.6%. However, even

this decrease was buffered somewhat by the low base effect in early 2011. Over the last year, the

investment rate stagnated if we exclude seasonal effects, and by 2013 the rate tended towards to

zero.

Fig.. 2.3. Construction and investment (100 = December 2010, seasonality excluded)

Source: Rosstat, the HSE Center for Development calculations

Investment rate deceleration was coupled with a continuing significant net capital

outflow. In 2012, $56.8 bn left Russia, mainly due to the non-financial sector.

Fossil export value (trend) Other exports value (trend)

Construction

Investment

11

Fig. 2.4. Net capital inflow, private sector, USD bn

Source: Rosstat, the HSE Center for Development calculations

Intense capital outflow along with plunging investment has reduced the growth rates of

investment import demand. Consequently, the balance of payments and investment rate provide

evidence that both domestic and foreign investors have become less interested in Russia.

Thirdly, slow rates of productivity (2.5% in 2012) and efficiency, which seem to be a

priority. A mere surge in investment would not be enough to promote growth if it failed to

enhance efficiency in key sectors.

Even though the investment environment in Russia had never been welcoming before, a

number of newer negative factors arose in 2012.

On the one hand, we have the unclear priorities of our economic policy. Even after the

president was elected and the government formed, these aims clashed with each other. For

example, the combination of a countercyclical budget policy with a surge in public obligations in

the areas of defense and social security.

On the other hand, the gap between the stated goals and the reality in state-business

relations has widened. The opportunity to introduce radical changes in order to encourage

business has been wasted. Instead, an even more archaic relationship between the state,

bureaucracy, law enforcement agencies and business has been revived. Steady taxation rules are

substituted by a multiple increase in premiums for the individual entrepreneur which pushes

them to the margins of legal activity. Instead of the protection of proprietary rights, business is

more and more often faced with accelerated land and building condemnation when it comes to

projects carried out by the government or affiliated agencies. Instead of easing administrative

and power pressure on business, security and law enforcement structures are even more active in

impeding business. In an environment of this kind, entrepreneurs are forced to make short-term

plans, avoiding investment, especially into efficiency-building.

12

When export and investment are shrinking, consumer demand evolves as a key driver of

growth. The overall consumption of households was 6.6% in 2012, keeping pace with 2010-

2011. This growth was ensured by a rise in the disposable income of households by 4.2% in real

terms, A pay increase in the public sector and a boost in the monetary allowances of the

“silovikis” have largely contributed to this growth. At the same time, plunging personal income

in non-budget service sector and business income shows that the private sector in Russia is

weakening.

Fig. 2.5. Structure of private earnings, %

Source: Rosstat, the HSE Center for Development calculations

Increased consumption, which exceeds income, was facilitated by expanded lending. In

2012 the share of loans to individuals compared with their income returned to the level of 2007,

at 5.3%. By the end of the year, however, the rate had considerably declined. Consumer demand

affected the GDP rate in 2012, which was largely facilitated by import stagnation. However,

serious impediments are now beginning to become apparent. Firstly, according to the Bank of

Russia, in 2013 individual borrowing rates will drop from more than 40% in 2012 to 25-30%.

Second, the growth rate halving during 2012 (from 4-5% to 2% year-on year) will inevitably

affect individual income generated by the private sector in 2013. The “business-as-usual”

scenario suggests that the final consumption rate will dip to 4-5% over the next two years.

Sustainable growth based on consumption will take place if individual income grows, promoting

Pensions

Transfers without pensions

Labor compensation fund in public sector

Monetary allowances

Labor compensation fund in non-fuel production and construction

Labor compensation fund in fuel production

Labor compensation fund in non-budget service sector

Business income

Property income

Labor compensation fund of small businesses

Undeclared income

Other

13

domestic demand, at the same time promoting investments which are sensitive not only to

profits, but also to other factors that increase investors’ interest.

However, inertia may well torpedo economic growth. Given a sustainable oil price (110-

115 USD/bbl) we suggest that economic growth will further decelerate in years to come, dipping

below 2%. Such a slowdown may widen the lag between Russia and other countries and

contribute to mounting domestic imparities, first of all, in the budget. Fig. 2.6. ”Business-as-usual” scenario of the GDP rate and the contribution of the GDP components estimated by the type of demand (growth YoY)

Source: the HSE Center for Development calculations

Macroeconomic stabilization risks: no room for budget maneuvering and vertical imbalance

The major flaws of the current budget policy include vertical imbalance and an uneven

spending pattern. In 2012, the federal budget was nearly deficit-free, although the non-fossil

deficit rose to 10.6% of GDP rather than the decrease,that had been expected. This indicates a

surge in the country’s dependency on the global environment.

Russian regions were hit by even more serious problems as they badly lacked resources

and got new obligations in 2012 according to the 7th of May Presidential decrees. Consolidated

regional budget revenues were nearly in line with the forecast of the Ministry of Finance, but

regional spending was 240 bn roubles higher than anticipated. As a result the deficit was more

than eight times higher than expected (278 bn versus 32 bn roubles).

In the medium-term this imbalance is likely to persist, despite the budget policy.

In 2013-1015, the real priorities of budgetary policy run counter to those stated by the

government. Healthcare and education spending suggested to be the fundamental objectives of

economic policy do not ensure its increase as a share of GDP in the medium-term as required by

a comprehensive reform and development of these sectors. This is likely to impede the growth of

Forecast

Inventory changes, percentage point

Import, percentage point

Foreign demand, p.p,

Domestic demand, p.p.

GDP,%

Domestic demand for domestic goods,%

14

innovation as well. Such estimates come from the Strategy 2020 project. The share of spending

on these sectors in the federal budget is gradually falling.

At the same time an increase in the monetary allowance for the military, law enforcement

and government armaments program, which costs 20 tn roubles, boosted the total military and

security spending from 5.6% of GDP in 2011 to 6.1% in 2012. It is expected that this spending

will reach 6.2-6.3% of GDP. As a result, although security spending was substituted by the loan

resources of the banks and removed beyond 2015 during the debate on the triennial budget, it

is increasing more rapidly than investment in human capital. At the same time, any “surplus”

arising from fuel revenues (National Wealth Fund) will be channeled by the Government into

infrastructure through revenue-yielding bonds.

Fig. 2.7. Budgetary spending by certain types (Fundamental Objectives of Budget Policy), % of GDP

Source: Fundamental Objectives of Budget Policy for 2013-2015 (FOBP)

In 2013, the Ministry of Finance estimates that regional budget obligations will increase

by 0.4% of GDP. At the same time, inter-budget transfers will fall by 0.7% of GDP. Any lack of

funds shall be compensated by an increase in regional tax and non-tax revenues (by 1.4% of

GDP). Taking into consideration that spending is expected to exceed the level anticipated in

2012, the real need for additional resources in 2013 is 0.4-0.5 % of GDP more than the Ministry

of suggests. Nevertheless, up to 2015 the government is going to reduce the share of the regional

budgets in GDP and simultaneously free them of deficit.

Defense and law enforcement Education Healthcare

15

According to our estimates, this puts the economy into too tough an environment, which

is especially true with regards to healthcare and education, although additional spending can be

partly financed through domestic reserves and improvements in efficiency.

Table 2.2. Regional budgets, % of GDP

2012 FOBP

2012 De facto 2013 FOBP 2014 NBP 2015 FOBP

Total revenue 12.95 12.93 13.62 13.30 13.21

Tax and non-tax revenue 10.77 10.24 11.67 11.70 11.80

Transfers 2.18 2.69 1.95 1.60 1.41 Spending 13.00 13.38 13.81 13.41 13.21

Deficit -0.05 -0.45 -0.18 -0.12 0.00 Source: Fundamental Objectives of Budget Policy for 2013-2015 (FOBP), Federal Exchequer of Russia,

HSE Center for Development calculations

The Central Bank’s policy of defeating inflation as a top priority may lead in the long run

to cheaper loans, but in the short-term it will more likely trigger a rise in interest rates simply due

to a lack of funds. At the same time, the current economic environment is hardly likely to help

curb inflation, at least comprehensively, as long as regulated tariffs and consumption taxes

(excise) used as a point of reference by the government are growing faster than income.

At the same time it is important to note that the roll call of businesses in the country is

changing. Some of them are succeeding and improving their market posture, others are fighting

for survival while trying to preserve and establish special conditions. This process is painful but

important as it will eventually define the future of the Russian economy, which may be brighter

if this process is rapid enough.

At the same time, the budget rule reflecting the focus on a tough budget and monetary

policy is double-edged. On one hand, it fosters private investment and relatively cheap loans to

balance accessibility and efficiency. On the other hand, in the current Russian business

environment, macroeconomic stability and low inflation impede growth, even at a rate of 3%,

mainly due to institutional failures. Moreover, the budget rule, which coexists with a large

number of spending obligations exceeding set limits, endangers budgetary balance and actually

boosts uncertainty.

3. Choosing the way: scenarios for development

The economic performance of the world and of Russia in the first half of 2013 shows that

growth opportunities that were present before the crisis of 2008-2009 no longer exist. A World

Bank report states that the Russian economic model was based on the assumption that the world

economy would grow and oil prices would remain high. Now it is apparent that the world growth

16

rate will be considerably lower and the demand for Russian oil production will go down as well.

In addition to this, the labor market will shrink rather than expand. We need a new model.

When market reforms were carried out in the early 1990s, most market apologists

believed that after the transformational crisis, the Russian economy should be driven by market

incentives, entrepreneurial energy and business initiative. These forces are all-powerful, but in a

favorable environment, the country could have grown faster than developed countries for 15-20

years, thereby narrowing the gap and approaching the top table in terms of productivity,

innovativeness and wealth. Naturally, state and society were expected to support it.

The reality turned out to be more complicated that these assumptions. The discrepancies

between archaic traditions and modernity in Russia proved to be extraordinary resistant to

change. Here we can speak about the transition from an entrenched feudalistic and bureaucratic

hierarchy that dominated up to the middle of the 19th century to a system of networking typical

for a market economy and political democracy. This transition started with the liberation of

peasants in 1861 along with some other reforms of Alexander II, including those connected with

local governance and the judicial system. However, progress soon stalled. Unlike the rapid

progress in industry and transportation, agricultural development was extremely slow. The

political system was also resistant to change. However, following the revolution of 1905, the

country entered WWI as a constitutional monarchy with a multiparty political system and a

functional parliament, liberating peasants from medieval obligations - a process which was

bolstered by Stolypin’s agricultural reforms. But the war itself was a tragedy for the country. The

October revolution took place in 1917 with its slogans serving as a cover for return to

overbearing bureaucracy, arbitrariness and mass repressions.

Democratic reforms and the market transition of 1989-1994 marked a new turn in

Russian history, a fresh attempt to establish a more modern society, rich in inner drivers.

However, the way forward proved to be rocky.

From the very beginning, the establishment of a market economy was dogged by the

concentration of capital and emergence of big business (oligarchy) ready to influence state

authorities and maintain their acquired benefits. A confrontation between big business and

bureaucracy broke out. In 2003, bureaucracy, including that of the security forces, triumphed. A

new era of confrontation between traditionalism and modernity dawned, when market and

entrepreneurial institutions were thwarted and previous methods returned.

The complexity of the process which has been unfolding since the beginning of this

century defies any clear conclusions about results. However, it seems that natural business

activities have decreased (for our purpose suppose that inflation is 2-3% and interest rates in real

terms are 4-6%), which was partly compensated for by rising fuel exports, with 10-12% inflation

17

and accessible foreign loans. Business activity at that time was artificial. Nevertheless, the period

between 2003 and 2008 can be seen as successful, with an annual growth of 7.3%, a productivity

rate of 5.2%, and GDP rising above that of 1990 (108%). A booming world economy bolstered

by the easing of monetary policy in the West, and the rapid growth of developing countries

contributed to Russia’s performance. It seemed as if Russia had found a new face. However, the

crisis of 2008-2009 rapidly destroyed any illusions.

After the crisis passed and recession rates were established, a debate on the scenarios for

the development of the country in the 21st century began. The first one was presented by S.Y.

Glazyev and is critical of the previous model aimed at curbing inflation.

Expansionary scenario

Even before the crisis there were voices calling for an increase in state investment and the

easing of lending to promote the growth of the national economy. Since the crisis, Glazyev and

his suporters have reiterated these demands: they claim that growth can be enhanced only

through the boosting of investment. Since private investment in Russia is growing slowly

(capital investment increased only by 1.1% as estimated for the year to January, 2013 –

D.Pichugina, 21.02.2013), the onus should be on state investment. Their scope, as it is meant,

should provide for the implementation of the stated goals - growth by 5-6%.

Glazyev opposes the recently established budget policy which requires transfers to the

Reserve Fund of oil revenues if they exceed the benchmark (estimated for a number of years) oil

price. He believes that these funds should be channeled into investment while money supply

should not be limited and interest rates should not be overpriced if compared to the profitability

of the inward-looking sectors, which is almost always lower. He says, “The key result of the

current monetary and budget policy is the orchestrated thwarting of economic growth”.

The Ministry of economy is more discreet but also leans towards this view: to reduce the

allocations in reserve from 7 to 5% of GDP, invest the surplus, and reach an annual rate of

4.1%.

It should be noted that the policy of the 2000s, generally balanced in terms of

macroeconomics, closely echoes these recommendations. Even given that the Stabilization fund

was established in the 2000s, inflation did not go below 11-12%, excluding 2006, when it fell to

a single digit rate. Foreign exchange earnings were the largest contributor to money supply. The

rate of inflation is clear evidence of the fact that money supply exceeded demand. The

macroeconomics of the 2000s can be regarded as an example of a modest approach lacking

institutional change. The proponents of this expansionary model aimed at easing monetary

restrictions, and those looking to take money from the state saw it as a standard of radical

monetarism. Institutional change (excluding tax reform and a certain reduction in administrative

18

barriers) was insufficient, and at times a policy of even tougher state regulation was pursued,

which weakened economic incentives, instead replacing them with administrative measures or

similar.

An increase in money supply as well as other short-term growth incentives is most often

effective when a slowdown or disruption in the growth rate is determined by the environment

(for example, deterioration and a sectoral crisis).

The current slowdown in Russia is taking place in a relatively stable environment and is

triggered mostly by fundamental production limitations – technological (oil production

depletion, capital consumption, technological underdevelopment, lack of professionals) and

institutional, which impede effectiveness and investment patterns (lack of competition,

bureaucratic overregulation, bad governance, high business costs, etc.).

In this context, short-term incentives should be employed only if they have a lasting

impact.

In theory, these include, for example, an increase in infrastructure investment, which is a

good incentive in both the short and long term. This example is discussed here in more detail.

The impact produced by infrastructure projects is two-sided: a surge in state investment

(in the short term) and benefits for the economy as a result of infrastructure upgrading (cost

reduction, new windows of opportunity, improved image of the country). The assessment of the

second effect, amplifying as the new infrastructure expands, is based on earlier research

(Petronevich, 2009), and suggests 0.04 p.p. of additional growth in 2013-2020. These estimates

suggest that additional investment is financed through increased spending, i.e. easing of the

budget rule.

To explore the limits of the short-term effect produced by possible fiscal incentives in

Russia we used a reference scenario with oil prices at 110 USD/bbl and spending as defined by

the budget policy. We compared this scenario to one where the share of federal spending in GDP

is the same as in 2012 (21% of GDP) but the current budget policy is abandoned. Our

calculations show that the easing of the budget guidelines and an increase in spending can

accelerate growth, but this effect is short-term and wanes rapidly. A longer lasting impact is

apparent only in the first year after the rules of spending have been changed. Indicators at the

bottom of Table 3.1 showing growth rates that depend on the increase (decrease) in spending by

1% of GDP, can be regarded as a fiscal multiplier. As the table shows, if these incentives are

employed only for one year, the multiplier is 0.74. However, it later drops.

.

19

Table 3.1. Growth rates depending on the change in spending patterns3

2013 2014 2015

Revenue if the oil price is 110 USD/bbl (% of GDP) 20.2 19.7 19.2

Hypothetical spending (% of GDP) 21.0 21.0 21.0 Hypothetical budget deficit (% of GDP) -0.8 -1.3 -1.8

Growth rates due to increased spending 0.67 0.58 0.41

Growth rates if spending increases by 1% of GDP (fiscal multipliers) 0.74 0.32 0.19

Source: the HSE Center for Development research, calculated by Tchernyavskiy A. and Kondrashov N.

Fiscal incentives are also limited by the inefficient management of state resources

apparent in the overcharging of state purchases for current consumption and investments. As an

abstract estimate to assess the effect of overpricing on macroeconomic parameters we used a

maximum of 30%, though there are even more extreme examples.

These calculations suggest a mid-term perspective between 2014 and 2016. We mean that

a tactical improvement of governance (in particular, the adjustment of legislation on state

purchase to curb corruption) hypothetically leads to a reduction of price if compared to a

reference scenario with the inertial deflators rate in state governance. The price drops by 10% in

2014 and by 20% and 30% in 2015 and 2016 respectively.

These calculations include the combined impact produced by the price reduction in

purchases for current consumption (transportation fees, connection fares, rent, property

maintenance, purchase of materials, excluding expenses for regulated tariff services) and state

investment given the same amount of purchases as in the reference scenario in nominal terms.

Table 3.2. Macroeconomic indicator rates resulting from the enhancement of state purchase

and investment efficiency (percentage points)

2014 2015 2016

A change in the growth rate of the physical quantity of state purchase 4.58 5.16 5.22

A change in the growth rate of the physical quantity of investment 1.31 1.31 1.26

A change in GDP growth rate 0.47 0.57 0.58

A change in GDP deflator -0.93 -0.61 -0.52

Source: the HSE Center for Development research, calculated by Tchernyavskiy A. And Kondrashov N.

3 The calculations involved balance and econometric model elaborated by the HSE Center for Development

20

Our estimates (Table 3.2) show that the contract discounts for purchases for current

consumption growth rate in real terms increase annually by 5 p.p. while with contract discounts

for state investment, the total investment increases by 1.3% per year. The increase of real

demand for goods and services along with a reduction in the price of state purchases by 30%

would trigger a 0.5-0.6 pp. growth in GDP in 2014-2016. All in all, a short-term effect produced

by the enhancement of state spending efficiency can be compared to one produced by fiscal

incentives, with spending increased by 1% GDP, as described above. It means that the growth

rate can be accelerated with no increase in spending, but simply due to an improvement in

efficiency.

To produce a lasting impact for infrastructure projects it is critically important to assess

the allocation on a case-by-case basis. The return on investment is just one of the aspects.

Excessive construction represented by certain ambitious projects means that feedback is weaker

than it could be. Russian Railways and Gazprom could finance their investment programs

without extra allocations, merely through the use of internal reserves. At the same time

additional funds could help to mitigate the lack of infrastructure investment in the regions.

As far as monetary incentives are concerned (an increase in money supply), which was

widely used in the 2000s, the practice shows that banks do not use all the funds allocated by the

Central Bank to expand lending. From 9/1/2011 to 9/1/2012 the Central Bank provided

commercial banks with an additional two trillion roubles. Table 3.3 shows the main directions in

which banks used these funds.

Table 3.3. The share of banks which used the funds allocated by the Central Bank

between 9/1/2011 to 9/1/2012 as estimated for the major lines of activity

Share of banks (%)

Share of banks which raised their claims to the

CB in assets (correspondent accounts, deposits,

Bank of Russia bonds)

38.1

Share of banks which expanded their lending

portfolio

47.0

Share of banks which raised the balance on

correspondent accounts in non-resident banks

59.1

Source: banker’s books, research of the HSE Center for Development, calculated by D. Miroshnichenko

On balance, over this period more than one third of the banks enhanced their liquidity

with the help of the Central Bank of Russia. Nearly half of the banks (47%) expanded their

lending portfolio for businesses. However, the balance on correspondent accounts in non-

21

resident banks was boosted by two thirds of Russian banks. This means that an increase in

money supply in the current environment encourages mainly capital outflow and only promotes

lending as a secondary result. It means that an increase in money supply as a growth incentive is

far from efficient. It also means that the expansionary policy prescribed by S. Glazyev would

logically lead to capital controls, not to say a closed economy.

The main problem with fiscal or monetary growth promotion through investment is the

return of “soft restrictions”, which should be eliminated by budget guidelines. Consequently,

inflation is likely to rise and private investment is likely to fall.

Scenarios for the development of the Russian economy presented by the Ministry of

Economic Development of Russia are also currently a subject for heated debate. They are

described in the Ministry’s estimate up to 2030 and include conservative, innovative and

accelerated (target) scenarios.

A conservative or “business-as-usual” scenario essentially means the prolongation of

the current policy based on technological drivers of modernization. Unlike Glazyev’s scenario,

this variant suggests macroeconomic stability and rejects the risk of a deficit or an increase in the

supply of money, and follows the stated budgetary policy, including savings in the Reserve fund

that amount to 7% of GDP. However, there is no institutional change.

An innovative scenario suggests institutional reforms aimed at the enhancement of the

investment climate, promotion of entrepreneurship and better governance. Though we prefer this

variant it should be noted that the scope of the institutional change needed must be correctly

assessed: these are either measures similar to subordinate technological changes or alternatively,

guiding actions. The latter are the core of the policy and embrace key legal and political

complications. It is clear that the Ministry has defined responsibilities, but we believe that a

tangible result can be yielded only under these conditions. In other words, new institutions

should be the focal point. We cannot conclude this from the present Ministry’s estimate.

An accelerated scenario is full of optimistic targets as well as uncertainties: it suggests a

macroeconomic imbalance, a considerable increase in gross savings (up to 30-33% of GDP

against the current 20%) and job cuts, ensuring no efficiency increase. (Mau V.A. Between

Modernization and Stagnation: Economic Policy in 2012. The Issues of Economy, №12, p.18).

The authors claim that this scenario encompasses all the institutional reforms from the innovative

variant. However, their compatibility with the accelerators described above is uncertain.

We should note that the first scenario is close to the conservative one and, oddly enough,

to the accelerated as all three scenarios are focused on technological shifts. Political decisions

lacking an institutional basis along with increasing state spending are the key drivers here. There

is room for budget deficit and an active policy of printing money if production growth is

22

expected to make up for spending. Falling interest rates should make the loans cheaper,

contributing to the anticipated improvement in private investment in the long run.

In practice, such a policy provides for the relatively low efficiency of state spending. The

increase in savings will be nullified by a decrease in efficiency. A surge in money supply lacking

business incentives, including competition, would not trigger the equivalent growth of money

demand and would spur inflation. This case is solid enough to firmly reject these scenarios.

Only the innovative scenario of the Ministry regards institutional change as a core

assumption. It is clear that the macroeconomic differences typical of other scenarios are minor.

They would be important if there were no pressing need for new institutions. However, at the

present time, the core of the economic and social policy has been shifted to institutions and their

transformation. Consequently, we believe the other scenarios to be invariants of the conservative

scenario since they suggest no institutional change.

However, even the monetary scenario will fall short of expectations if we only focus on

its macroeconomic specifics. The reserves ensure a certain stability in case of a deteriorating

environment. Inflation can be leveled to figures typical of natural business activity. However,

business activity per se is not triggered by inflation, the latter shows the balance between money

demand and supply. Business initiative and entrepreneurial drive are generated by political and

economic institutions, their credibility and market forces. These are the forces the bureaucratic

hierarchy lacks or suppresses. Nevertheless, they are inherent for the network market model

which reemerged in Russia in the 1990s and can successfully grow now, serving as a key driver.

Reforms that will trigger it were incorporated to the Gref’s program but stopped as oil prices

ballooned. They should be brought back to finish their task. Institutional change provides the

backdrop for innovation. This is an innovative scenario in contrast to the “business-as-usual”

one. The focus is on those institutional differences that encourage development rather than

microfinance. If they reach the necessary scope, growth and productivity rates can exceed those

of developed countries. It is a criterion for successful modernization.

However, it ought to be understood that institutional reforms are time-consuming while

their results are not always immediately apparent. Institutions change slowly as the process

involves the shaping of individual habits, along with wide-scale adoption of the rules and norms

that make new institutions functional.

4. New model of economic growth

As mentioned above, the drivers that ensured the recovery of the Russian economy after

the transformational crisis in the 2000s are now exhausted. We need to activate new factors and

institutions that can reinvigorate driving forces.

23

The need for institutional change

Most experts believe that it is the unfavorable environment that is the key impediment

to economic growth in Russia today. Figures illustrate that the impact produced by institutional

change is comparable to the effects of fiscal and monetary stimulation, and could even exceed

them.

Bad institutions triggered a capital outflow, which started in the autumn of 2011, as well

as low foreign investment. A drop in net capital outflow from the current 4.5% of GDP to zero

would increase the rate of savings (the share of investments in GDP) by 2-4 p.p. (in 2011 it was

19.4%). It would accelerate investment growth rates in real terms while the rate of savings is on

the rise. As a result, the GDP growth rate would increase in both the short and long term.

The investment rate is just part of the story. Research carried out (Petronevich,

Aleksashenko, Akindinova, 2011) provides a more complex quantitative estimate of the

institutional impact on growth rates. The results show that a better performance of the key state

institutions4 by a mere one point (estimated by a ten-point scale used by the Vienna institute of

management IMD) would facilitate ceteris paribus an annual GDP growth of 0.3%. This is a

tangible effect when we take into account that Russia has 3-4 fewer points than developed

countries in this respect. (p.16, Volume 24).

In Chapter 3 (Table 3.3) we showed that a quality increase of public administration in

state purchases and investment can accelerate growth rates by 0.5-0.6 p.p. of GDP in the short

term.

According to research carried out by the Russian Presidential Academy of National

Economy and Public Administration in 2012, losses stemming from insufficient competition and

potential economic impact produced by institutional change can amount to 2.5% of GDP.

The impact would be more rapid and longer lasting if coupled with an effective

credibility building measure, boosting the credibility of the state and its institutions It can be, for

example, a declaration on easing the pressure on business followed by a large-scale amnesty of

“economic prisoners”, punishment of the “siloviki” involved in the illegal prosecution and

killing of business people. However, we now see the opposite: law enforcement agencies and

the judicial system have their own rules of the game which leave much to be desired in

connection with economic growth in the current environment. 4 The calculations employ the competitiveness index used by IMD. Though this database embraces less countries than the WEF (56 states against 139), it contains comparable data since 1995, i.e. covers the whole period under our scrutiny. We took 10 indicators out of the IMD stock which reflect the rate of development of main public institutions, including: legal and regulatory framework; adaptability of government policy; transparency; bureaucracy, government decisions; competition; bribing and corruption; justice; ease of doing business, personal security and private property.

24

The key attributes of a new model

The report for the 23rd April conference, held in 2012 (Yasin E. ‘Long-term Scenarios

for Russia’) suggests three other scenarios – modernization “from above”, “resolute

breakthrough” and “evolution”.

Modernization from above suggests a highly centralized decision-making process and

tough state control over the economy and public life. Its content is close to the one we called

conservative or “business-as-usual”. Institutional change is impossible as it suggests a certain

initiative from the bottom and interaction between agents outside the hierarchy. The results of its

implementation are likely to be poor.

The other two scenarios seem to combine all the variants contrasting with the first one.

For our purpose it can be called modernization “from the bottom” (democratic) or an innovative

scenario, as the Ministry of Economy suggests. Institutional change here is the core of the policy

though it can be implemented at various speeds. It is important in the case of institutional

development, as institution building is not only a formality but also a policy which can rapidly

change public attitudes (e.g. “perestroika”) or evolution with consideration given to the

difficulties of change.

The above-mentioned details split the ‘modernization from the bottom’ scenario into

two versions which differ in pace and the number of institutional changes over a given period of

time.

A “resolute breakthrough” suggests that most of the critical steps will be taken in the

very beginning to promote the impetus for reform. However, the risk of complications and

backsliding persists.

“Evolution” puts the emphasis on slower progress enabling society to adopt changes,

discuss its content and pace, resolve conflicts and take concerted action. Its implementation can

include interrelated complementary institutions encouraging mutual promotion and the

mobilization of society. (Yasin E. ‘Scenarios’, 2012, p. 39).

We opted for the last scenario as it seems to be the most relevant to the current

economic performance and the state of society.

It should be emphasized that the new model of economic growth suggests a complex

implementation of institutional change which would be better at revitalizing human potential and

the unique attributes of human capital currently waiting to be employed. These powers are

connected with freedom, competition and those laws which put freedom and competition into a

rational framework.

25

Here we list the most important vectors for the implementation of a new model.

Up to now, development has followed a “business-as-usual” scenario which has not

been promising at all. A new stage of reform requires critical decisions to be made. Here we list

the most important of these decisions.

1. To establish the rule of law, fostering the independence of courts, eliminating power

abuse and selfish decisions driven by short-term advantage.

2. To reshape the relationships between business, law enforcement and judicial agencies

as a critical step in the establishment of the rule of law. This is required to enhance the

credibility of the state and its agencies. Without it, there will be no economic boost.

3. To reform local government, including the expansion of its authority in taxation

and charging. To promote civil society activism based on local governance.

4. Social sector: pension reform, healthcare, education and the real-estate market.

This is a sector of individual investment that was virtually absent in the USSR. All the costs

were borne by the state or employers, while people were robbed of critical human functions. This

cannot be carried over into the future society, citizens should have a chance to choose, save and

enhance their efficiency. Demographic trends should be also taken into consideration: the

number of children in families is unlikely to rise and nor will the ratio between the working

population and those who are retired. Money flow will be transformed. Pensions will be saved as

a long-term investment along with medical insurance at the cost of an increased salary.

This chapter aims to start a debate on these issues, and to shape changes aimed at lasting

institutional decisions rather than dragging our feet while the situation continues to deteriorate.

5. To introduce democratization and establish reasonable conditions for political

competition and periodic regime change. This involves a gradual process including the

implementation of a modern electoral system, taking into consideration the current political and

social and economic environment. This system shall reduce to minimum the ability of the ruling

elite to manipulate the system for their own ends. Democratization also means full-scale freedom

of speech, sustainable plurality of political parties and a true separation of powers.

Though we strongly believe that institutional and bureaucratic barriers should be

eliminated as soon as possible, we would like to caution against excessive optimism. The impact

produced by these changes will not become apparent immediately as the reforms themselves are

gradual. The best-case scenario (if all the parties concerned – experts, businessman and civil

servants attempt this task in good faith) suggests that the situation will improve in three or four

years, once the majority of technical measures have been implemented and the upgraded

institutions accepted by those meant to use them.

26

We should understand that reforms are time-consuming and the amount of time is

comparable to that needed to establish and foster institutions, including their adoption by the

general public.

5. Drivers of new model and their activators In practice, the launch of a new model depends on the question of who is going to support

the institutional reforms mentioned above, and why they will do so. We can identify a number of

such “groups of interest”.

The first group can be called “new businesses”. The 2000s sent oil prices skyrocketing,

triggering the launch of “national projects”, the establishment of state corporations and ambitious

construction projects in Vladivostok and Sochi. The social and political stability of the 2000s and

the rapid growth of consumer demand encouraged many companies targeting the domestic

market..

According to research by Expert magazine, prior to the 2008 crisis, there were some 5000

medium sized businesses in Russia (those with a turnover exceeding $10 million per year) which

generated average annual sales growth at 20% and higher (Vin’kov et al., 2008). Such firms

were especially visible in construction and retail, although in fact, they existed in all sectors. At

the same time, the share of rapidly growing companies (“gazelles”) in Russia was much higher

than that in developed countries (Yudanov, 2010).

These results were in line with data produced by a joint project between the HSE and the

WB based on a survey of 1000 firms in 2005-2006 which showed a deep non-homogeneity in the

manufacturing sector. On one hand, the calculations of the WB experts confirmed that the

average labor productivity in the Russian manufacturing sector at that time was three times lower

than in South Africa, half that of Brazil and Poland and only slightly better than China. (Desai &

Goldberg, 2007, p.17-22). On the other hand, the calculations of Russian team of this project

based on the same data showed that the average numbers covered very large gaps in labor

productivity in terms of value added among companies of the same sector. Thus, in transport

machine building, the gap between the top 20% and bottom 20% of businesses in terms of

success was eleven fold, in the textile and garment industry it was sixteen fold, and in timber and

the food industry, it differed by a factor of 24 (The HSE, 2007).

In other words, even back in 2005, and given the low average indicators of efficiency in

every large sector, some companies were still able to compete in global markets. These

successful companies with long-term planning used a favorable market conditions for business

development (including investment, technical retooling, new markets expansion, attraction of

foreign partners) and in fact contributed to the economic growth of the 2000s. Nowadays such

27

companies, familiar with Russian market, financially stable and run by professional managers,

can be the foundation for a new model of economic growth. However, they should have plenty

of incentives to invest in Russia. Here we are faced with a traditionally bad investment climate in

Russia.

The fact that the business environment in Russia leaves mush to be desired has been

widely known for a long time. There has been plenty of work published on the subject (Hellman

et al, 2003; Yasin, Yakovlev, 2004; Djankov et al, 2006; BEEPS, 2009; Doing Business; 2012).

At the same time, the BEEPS survey, carried out by the EBRD and the WB in emerging markets,

confirmed that the business environment in Russia was stagnating in the 2000s. While in 2005

half of the institutional indicators received from the top management of Russian companies had a

higher than average score, by 2009 16 out of 18 indicators were worse than the average score for

28 transition economies (Kuznetsov et al, 2011).

However, before the crisis of 2008-2009, high business costs in Russia were balanced by

high returns on operations in the domestic markets. Given the social and political stability of the

mid to late 2000s (when many people rejected state capitalism with a Russian face, but economic

policy was regarded as predictable and prudent) this combination encouraged considerable

investment, mainly foreign. After the crisis, the situation changed dramatically: high margins

disappeared, barriers remained and an uncertainty in economic policy (mainly involving

apparent discrepancies between announced commitment and the decreasing financial potential

of the government) led to additional challenges for new investment. As a result, capital rapidly

left Russia. This exodus started during the crisis and has not stopped yet. Domestic investment

has also shrunk, as mentioned above.

Such a response can be explained in terms coined by Albert Hirschman, one of the

classical political scientists; it is an example of an “exit” strategy5. However, it should be noted

that the majority of successful medium sized businesses which rode the wave of high demand in

the 2000s can succeed only in Russia and to them, “exit” means closing the window of

opportunity. After the crisis at least some of the business community came to realize this and felt

it necessary to take collective action aimed at the transformation of the environment (or use of

“voice” strategy, according to A. Hirschman). In should be noted that it is the “Business Russia”

5 See Hirschman (1970). According to Hirschman, the “exit” strategy suggests that an agent (a firm, an employee, a household or a voter), dissatisfied with the current market environment, quits (“votes with feet”). The “voice” strategy suggests that the agent is willing to make the market change the “rules of the game” and bring them in line with his interests. The second choice, on the hand, is closely related to the “exit” costs, on the other – depends on the cost of collective action.

28

association that become most vocal in this respect. It represents medium sized and big “non-

oligarchical” business.

We believe that the recent attempts by the government to change the investment

environment are a response to mounting business pressure and reflect the understanding that only

economic growth based on private investment can trigger a surge in individual income and

uphold social stability nowadays. However, a real change in the investment environment

stemming from declarations is highly dependent on the quality of governance.

The current model of the Russian state machine can be concisely described as a “vertical

power structure”. This model initially suggested a distance between the government and business

as well as power redistribution in favor of the federal center. It evolved as a response to the

decentralization of the 1990s which empowered certain social groups while widening inequality

and triggering the destabilization of society.

The “vertical power structure” played its role in the recovery of the country early in the

2000s. Many of the steps Putin and his supporters made at that time were in line with the

interests and expectations of a large part of the market players. For example, the reestablishment

of the united economic space as a result of “taming” the heads of the regions, was beneficial for

most businesses. Constraints on the influence of big business on economic policy were initially

regarded as a positive sign since businessmen were generally opposed to the “Seven Bankers’

Rule” of 1996-1998 when economic policy was clearly shaped by the interests of a handful of

market leaders. Improvements in the civil service as a result of an inflow of professionals

improved the quality of governance. The tax reform of 2000-2001 and improvement of tax

administration is the most illustrative example. It dramatically eased the taxation burden6. . As a

result while in the 1990s, legislation was widely neglected, in the 2000s the enhanced state

machine regained control over the observance of law on the part of the citizens and businessmen.

Better fiscal performance combined with tax redistribution in favor of the federal center brought

considerable funds to the federal budget and facilitated the launch of a number of ambitious

social and infrastructure projects.

At the same time, the state which was being consolidated within the “vertical power

structure” was faced with consequences of a different kind. In particular, it suggested

considerable expansion of the state machine and its authority in economic regulation. It led to 6 The WSJ once called it a “tax revolution” – see “The Putin Curve”. The Wall Street Journal, November 26, 2002

.

29

soaring corruption, which is still one of the most pressing social problems in Russia.

Centralization of power and regulation of the work of the state machine were regarded as the

main instruments in the fight against corruption.

These measures are based on some simple assumptions. In a big hierarchical system,

rules and regulations enable top management to control their subordinates (especially when there

is no clear and transparent assessment of their productivity) and limit arbitrariness and “rent-

seeking” of an individual civil servant. Detailed reporting provides top management with all the

necessary managerial data. At first sight, such formality establishes a system of universal

impersonal rules regarded by Douglas North and his counterparts as one of the most important

pre requisite conditions of social development (North et al, 2009).7

However, in practice, the bigger the hierarchy, the more centralized and non-transparent

it is (there is lack of information about the performance of its components), and the more

sophisticated the regulations and accountable figures are. Consequently, more effort is needed to

observe the rules and prepare reports than is needed for work-related duties. At the same time the

system which undermines initiative at the bottom with set procedures inevitably shifts

responsibility to the top. As a result, top management is more and more absorbed with routine

regulation instead of strategic planning, while middle management upgrades its manipulation

techniques and capacities. Unwilling to implement its mission as an order from above, it gets

involved in filibustering. A qualified civil servant in Russia clearly understands that tasks set by

his superiors should be fulfilled formally rather than substantially. Only those tasks which are in

line with the interest of the agency are subject to a thorough review.

Moreover, detailed regulation of the routine (instead of devolution and productivity

assessment) impedes the urgent need to resolve economic and social problems. Most of them

requires creativity and awareness about local specifics which do not fit universal regulations set

by the government. As a result, while declaring commitment to the regulations, top-level

management repeatedly evades the rules (as, for example, the legislation on public procurement

is regularly evaded when it comes to “strategic projects”). Thus it has to handle problems

through ‘manual control” which per se is a breeding ground for corruption.

7 Exploring historic cases, North and his colleagues show that the rule of law was enforced from the above in England, France and the USA – when the key stakeholders within the elite reached a consensus on the transition from personal privilege to impersonal rights and established a set of rules to regulate inter-elite dynamics. Initially it was the rule of law for the elite rather than citizenry. Later it embraced larger social groups. However, the establishment of impersonal rules and their observance by the elite was an important step on the road to the “rule of law”.

30

In other words, the nature of the “vertical power structure” leads to large-scale conflicts

of interest within the state machine. Loyalty to duty confronts the abuse of power. So the internal

costs of conflict management mount. It ought to be noted that examples of the rejection of

innovation, high operational costs and sharp differences in the incentives for civil servants within

the administrative hierarchy are numerous in literature and the Soviet past. Such a model is more

or less functional in cases when there is a resource surplus (when goals can be achieved at any

cost) but it fails if the budget constraints are tight and there is a need to counter internal and

external challenges. This was true of the USSR in the 1980s and, we believe, is also the case in

modern Russia after the crisis of 2008-2009, where we have mounting social obligations and

soaring uncertainty about the future of global markets.

All in all, we have attempted to show that the launch of a new economic model based on

flourishing medium-sized business which emerged in the 2000s should be facilitated by change

in the institutional environment and a more friendly investment climate. So the “right incentives”

for the state machine are needed. Thus the state administration should be dramatically altered.

What direction should these changes follow and what social base can they rest on?

In developed democracies, the “right incentives” for the state machine are triggered by

political competition and the pressure of a strong civil society. In Russia both factors are weak.

However, inter-regional competition can ensure pressure within the state machine and provide

incentives to facilitate change. In this respect we can use the experience of China where flawed

market institutions and rampant corruption have coexisted with high growth rates for over thirty

years. (see Box 1).

Box 1. U-form and M-form organizational structures The difference in the track and results of market transformation in Russia and the PRC

can be explained through the comparative analysis of the Soviet and Chinese models of economic regulation. According to (Maskin et al, 2000) , the Soviet economy was administered by more than 60 industry sectoralministries and was structurally close to the Ford corporation (the first to use an assembly line). Its structure had been unitary up to WWII (Alfred Chandler, one of the authors of classical reading on the theory of management termed it the “U-form”). In particular, the management in the Ford corporation was built according to the principle of functionality: production department, sales department, purchase department etc. Every department had its own mission. All in all, they were complementary though different in substance and incomparable.

Unlike the Soviet model, the Chinese planned economy was closer to the “M-shape” pattern invented by General Motors. In General Motors, the internal structure was split into independent automobile companies producing various brands (Chevrolet, Pontiac, Oldsmobile etc.).

As the theoretical model suggested by Eric Maskin and his colleagues showed, such multidivisional structure facilitates productivity comparison for the middle-level management

31

and ensures more effective incentives for managers. The history of the automobile industry in the USA between 1930 and1950 showed that such a structure became a competitive advantage for General Motors and enabled the company to outperform Ford which had been the market leader.

The parallels between the Chinese economy and the “M-shape” rest on Maskin’s assumption that unlike the USSR and other socialist countries, they used decentralized planning in China - distributing the products and resources among 27 large provinces. Mao Zedong’s conviction that either the USA or the USSR would inevitably invade China and occupy a part of this territory contributed to this model. Taking into consideration the guerilla fight against Japanese occupation, it was important to establish relatively autonomous and self-sufficient “support bases” to ensure the army could continue to fight. As a result China, unlike the USSR, was split into ten districts where parallel industries were deliberately established (Qian, 1999).

Such a structure of economy combined with a high role of regional organizations within The Communist Party of China laid the foundation for a unique model of governance established in the course of Deng Xiaoping’s reforms. This model included political centralization and fiscal federalism. At the same time, as Qian and Roland showed (Qian & Roland, 1998; Roland, 2000, Chapter 11), tough budget constraints enforced by the federal center triggered competition for resources which, in its turn, enhanced governance. Empirical research carried out later (Li & Zhou, 2005; Fan et al, 2009) confirmed that the promotion of a civil officer in China was closely linked to the economic performance of the provinces they administered.

All in all, as we see it, decentralization is able to introduce changes essential to the

establishment of the “right incentives”. It does not imply, however, automatic allocation of

additional funds to close the deficit in regions and local governments. It suggests a real

expansion of regional and local autonomy, i.e. a return to federalism. It should be noted that if

these steps are not taken, a return to the election of governors will make relations even more

strained and fuel criticism of the president and the government. Apart from the reduction of

excessive functional burden, the return to federalism will give the federal center more room for

adequate decision-making in tackling social and economic problems through regional

experiments and pilot projects.

Shifts in the structure of the regional elites in the 2000s could contribute to this process.

In particular, according to an analysis of regional elites carried out by HSE International Center

for the Study of Institutions and Development (ICSID), only 16% of those governors who were

in charge of the regions in 2000 remained in office by 2011. Vice-governors and key regional

ministers underwent an even more radical clearout: by 2011 only 8% of officials who had been

working in 2001 remained in office. The average age of a governor in 2011 was 54 (as opposed

to 64 in 2000). Vice-governors are now, on average, two years younger than that - they are

typically 46 years old. At the same time, a new generation of the regional elite are embracing

more ex-businessmen (every fifth governor and every third vice-governor has experience in

business) and professional bureaucrats (nearly 40% of governors and 35% of vice-governors).

32

On balance, it is obvious that a “new bureaucracy” has emerged. It is comprised of

qualified and well-paid professionals who have a good grasp of the market economy, are often

aware of modern methods of governance and are ambitious when it comes to their career.

Nowadays, these type of bureaucrats works in the regions as well as in federal agencies.

However, it is their activity in the regions that can serve as an illustration of their productivity.

There they also have more opportunities to tell their own “success story” – as happened, for

example, in Kaluga or Ulyanovsk, where regional authorities have succeeded in attracting

investors.

These shifts in the motivation of regional leaders can be traced not only through case

studies but also by a broader empirical analysis. Regression analysis of the results of the above-

mentioned survey among 1000 manufacturing companies showed that large-scale investment

projects launched in 2005-2008 were an important facilitator of the regional authorities’ decision

to allocate additional funds. For example, regional government supported 36.5% of “active

investors” in 2007-2008, compared to 25% of “non-regular investors” and 17% of companies

without investment.8

However, until last year such positive regional shifts in Russia were occasional rather

than regular, as they were not based on rational identification and encouragement of best

practices by the federal center. Effective bureaucrats could not be promoted against clear and

measurable assessment criteria. Professional training was traditionally conducted by the

educational entities which originated early in the 1990s and was based on former Higher Party

Schools of KPSU “inheriting” their staff.

All in all, we can conclude that the stability of the 2000s (traditionally related to the

“vertical power structure”) has produced two large social groups, both of which are skilled and

can afford to be involved in long-term planning.

However, economic and social regulation patterns stemming from the “vertical power

structure” foster opportunism of the “new business” and “new bureaucracy”, and encourage

redistribution rather than production. The question remains: who can change it and how?

Despite conventional wisdom, it is not a matter of an individual’s “political will” or the

will of a small group of loyalists (represented by “Politbureau 2.0”). It depends on the

willingness and capacity of the new Russian elite to reach a consensus on the “rules of the game”

which they are ready to comply. These rules should not impede long-term economic and social

8 It should be noted that federal support was less dependent on investment activities; state participation, keeping employment, the date of establishment before 1991 and location in an underdeveloped regions were more important for federal authorities (Yakovlev, 2011).

33

objectives. At the same time, the “violent pressure” typical of Russia today is a waste of limited

resources and can trigger “mutual destruction” among the modern elite.

As noted above, the specifics of the current system suggests that the top elite feel free

from any rules. It seems that the rule of law should be established from the bottom rather than

from the top (as has been established in modern liberal democracies). Rules, norms and

obligations that are publicly declared for all citizens must include the elite as well.

The “bottom-top” vector is in line with the pressure put on the government by different

social groups - from drivers locked in jammed streets due to the ever-growing number of

“government” cars with traffic privileges to businessmen fighting illegal takeovers and

“bullying” at the hands of law enforcement agencies. A tougher budget puts external pressure on

the elite as it cannot merely bribe the displeased.

However, pressure per se does not result in adequate trouble-shooting. Functional

agreements on new “rules of the game” can be produced only by a dialogue embracing those

groups which represent the interests of key stakeholders. The current rules of the game were

established by the bureaucratic elite, the “siloviki” and big business, loyal to the regime, as a

response to the crisis of 1998 and the challenges of the 1990s in general. After the ‘Yukos

affaire” the structure of the ruling coalition changed and big business found itself in the role of

the junior partner. Now, new parties - “new business” and regional elites - should be invited to

debate the new “rules of the game”. As we have attempted to show above, it is these two groups

that can be the drivers of the new model of economic growth. Moreover, the negotiations should

embrace professional elites (teachers, doctors, professors, researchers) who represent the public

sector since its performance is important for sustainable economic growth.

HSE research shows that the business community is the most active when it comes to

self-organization. For example, before the crisis of 2008-2009, along with the “big four” (RSPP,

Chamber of Commerce and Industry, “Business Russia” and “OPORA Rossii”), there were more

than 300 functioning sectoral business associations (Yakovlev, Govorun, 2011). At the same

time, as Table 5.1 shows, the associations included more active businesses.

Table 5.1 Share of enterprises with different levels of investment activity among members and non-members of business associations (BA) in 2009*

2005-2008 Members of BA Non-members of BA

No investments 19% 36%

Low investments 30% 30%

34

Large investments 51% 34%

*) According to a survey of 1002 businesses in the manufacturing industry, conducted by the HSE in February-June 2009.

However, even advanced associations representing the collective interest of business

have, so far, tended to tackle problems through “vertical links”. Such an approach may be

effective in the short term, but it is unsustainable for long-term purposes. A tougher budget and

soaring uncertainty mean that the regime cannot ensure its commitment to certain social groups.

Only those decisions which are in line with the interests of major stakeholders will be put into

practice. In this respect it is essential to develop horizontal cooperation, which will curb

uncertainty per se, enhance credibility and put interests into perspective. In this case the result

(new satisfactory decisions) is as important as the process which facilitates any change in the

environment.

The urgent social and economic problems which Russia now faces frequently call for

creative solutions. In Chapter 7 we present one possible solution aimed at leveling social

inequality and the promotion of investment in human capital. However, we do not underestimate

our expertise - such ideas should be generated by stakeholders who will then go on to participate

in their implementation. Experts can make solutions more formal; build arguments and assess

the potential consequences.

In this respect, any dialogue on the new “rules of the game” largely depends on the

lobbying groups able to offer constructive solutions and take into consideration the interests of

other social groups while defending the interest of their own group. It has to be understood that

the search for new solutions will take a long time and they will have to be found by trial and

error. Consensus building in this respect is essential. However, it is advanced civil society

institutions that ensure sustainable and adequate decision-making for development.

6. The role of civil society in shaping a new growth model

Only the future will show how much Russian elites are ready to try to reach a consensus on

the basis of long-term interests as opposed to a situational share of administrative and economic

resources. In this regard, the medium term, especially the run-up to the next parliament and

presidential elections, will become critically important. Also, only a highly developed civil

society can become the basis for institutional change, thereby encouraging economic growth, at

least in its post-industrial form.

35

In Russia the state has traditionally been the driver of change. Its policy was at best

determined by competition between the elite and at worst – by the interests and favors of

individuals. The wider population only could execute decisions and criticize the authorities.

Often these two roles became intertwined since they assumed something like the mindset of a

child, who is sure that the life of the family is shaped not by him, but by his parents, and who

demands things from his parents, is sometimes grateful, often rebellious, but seldom thinking of

himself as of an independent and responsible individual. Undoubtedly, this situation did not stem

from the free will of most of the people, but was determined by the conditions in which society

and state evolved.

But the nature of the economy of the 21st century implies a multifaceted and diverse

interaction between many subjects, who are distinguished precisely by a high degree of

independence and responsibility. It is difficult to match a full-scale manifestation of such traits in

the economic sphere with either servility or blind rebellion against the authorities.

Can we overcome the tradition where the state is more of a master and mentor to the society

than an agent? We do not agree with the two well-known points of view, according to which a

tradition is either determined by the genotype of a nation and cannot be changed or alternatively,

can be eliminated almost instantaneously after uncompromising democrats come to power. We

believe that both an evolving culture and the mastering of the skills of civil self-organization

play a key role.

In previous works it was shown that not only is market self-organization emerging in the

country, but also a non-market and a not-for-profit one. From the early 2000s it has started to

become stronger in society, which was prepared, on one hand, by the appearance of new

economic opportunities along with the growth of the middle class, and, on the other hand, by the

previous development phases of Russian civil society, from the activities of Soviet dissidents to

the intensive import of NGO resources and learning from foreign counterparts in the 1990s.

(Jakobson, Sanovish, 2009). The present phase is often underestimated for two reasons: firstly,

Due to a number of circumstances, not analyzed here, the development only partly corresponds

to the quantitative growth of registered NGOs. Second, the “widening” of the nonprofit sector

was naturally characterized by the convergence of the features of NGOs’ partisipants with the

features of a typical Russian citizen. This disappoints those experts who see civil society only as

a composition of politically active groups, inspired by liberal values. Indeed, Russia is similar to

most other countries in that the most common group is the non-political self-organization, aimed

at mutual assistance and philanthropy, spending joint leisure time together etc.

36

For instance, in a survey of 1005 NGOs, conducted in 2012 by the HSE, 41% of the

respondents, when answering a question about the social and political orientation of their

organization, said it was neutral, 20% said they were committed to liberal values, 16% to social-

democratic and 11% to conservative values. 16% said they were adherents of other views,

among which the most common were communist (5%) and nationalist (3%). 9 The same

respondents were asked to assess whether most Russian NGOs would like to take part in

bringing about serious political change in the country. 8% said they “would definitely like”, 22%

“would quite like”, while more than a half of the respondents gave a negative answer (16%

didn’t know).

A lack of close correlation between two aspects of its development is typical of the current

situation in Russian civil society. This includes, on one hand, the shaping of a network of

sustainable self-organization groups, that can be registered as NGOs or act for a longer period of

time without registration, and, on the other hand, the organization of mass actions, mostly

protests. The aforementioned survey of NGO leaders showed that only 7% of respondents took

part in protests, rallies or strikes.

The fact that mass actions are not rooted in the day-to-day activities of registered and non-

registered NGOs makes most of those actions ad hoc events in response to the actions of the

authorities. Such a situation is clearly more preferable than one that happens in an even less

developed civil society. We mean passivity as wel as spontaneous riots “for everything good,

against everything bad”, which, time and again, bring about regime change in third world

countries. Despite this, the current state of Russian civil society does not ensure a continuous,

relatively unidirectional and efficient pressure on the elite.

At the same time, although they are often overlooked, there are situations when civil self-

organization is mainly seen within the framework of its political means and consequences.

Primarily, in recent years a distinct need for NGO participation in what has been previously

regarded as a state monopoly has formed in our country.

The data in Fig. 6.1, showing the results of a representative survey conducted by the HSE and

the Public Opinion Foundation in 2012 seems significant in relation to this.

9 The research was conducted by a quota sample, developed by I.Mersiyanowa in a way to reflect the variety of NGO types, the number of years they exist, the type of the population aggregates and such regional characteristics as the urbanization level and per capita gross regional product values and the number of registered NGOs. Field study conducted by OOO “MarketUp”

37

Fig. 6.1 Replies to the question: “How could non-profit organizations and civic initiatives to help improve the situation in the social sphere?” (in percent)

The specific character of these times is characterized by the fact that the request is already

there, but still unusual and only moderately satisfied. Also, as the analysis shows, there are

already many (although separate) examples of successful initiatives. The authorities, for the its

part, are gradually beginning to understand that they cannot solve urgent social problems alone.

The relationship between NGOs and the state is far from ideal, but the population is no longer

indifferent to how this relationship is formed and has made a conscious choice in favor of a real

partnership. This can be seen in Fig 6.2., where you can see answers to the question of how the

relationship between the authorities and NGOs and civil initiatives should be and how it actually

is.

фото

фото

фото

Санкт-

3

Attract voluntary donations into the branch

Attract voluntary labour of love

Inform population on services quality

Control authorities’ work

Protect the rights of...

3723

1721

0 10 20 30 40

Public healthEducation

CultureSocial security

3417

1115

0 10 20 30 40

2125

2322

15 20 25 30

3632

3936

0 10 20 30 40 50

4149

35 40 45 50

Students Patients

Actively work in the social sphere

27

29

44

59

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70

To get engaged in the sphere of education, render educational services to the people

To get engaged in the sphere of public health, render medical services to the people

To get engaged in the sphere of culture, render services to the people

identify the real needs of vulnerable social groups and inform the authorities on it

Public healthEducation

CultureSocial security

Public healthEducation

CultureSocial security

Public healthEducation

CultureSocial security

38

Fig. 6.2 Replies to questions on the desired and actual nature of interactions (in percent)

Second, non-political self-organization, participation in different associations, even if

established to solve private problems, is, according to Alexis de Tocqueville, a “school of

democracy” (R.Putnam 1993, 2000). In Russia this “school” has been functioning freely for a

little over two decades and has been “attended” by many people for about ten years only. Of

course one should not expect extraordinary success from this “school”. Comparison of the data

of the HSE-survey among NGO leaders and public surveys shows that the former not only have

a much more distinct attitude towards connecting with other people for joint action (88% vs.

63%), but have also an impressively higher level of overall trust: 52% of them believe that one

can trust most people, while the average rate is 17%. Meanwhile the level of trust plays a key

role in establishing horizontal relations beyond family and close friends.

Overall, from the civil society monitoring data obtained by the HSE and a number of

sociological centers, one can draw the following conclusions. There really are processes in the

country involving relatively broad and diverse self-organization. Citizens rely less on the state

and see the possibility and desirability of its accountability to civil structures quite clearly. There

are more and more examples of free, organized and responsible joint actions in various areas of

public life. All this refutes the idea of the “innate statehood” of a nation. Moreover, given the

short period of time during which civil activity in Russia was been able to exist without harsh

repression, its current level gives us reason to expect that Russia will be able to quickly walk

along the path that some other countries have been traveling for centuries.

8

11

16

14

2

29

1

34

14

36

11

47

1

7

1

15

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

Helping authorities with their projects

elaboration and implementation of socially important programs with the authorities

Using authorities to solve their problems

protection of citizens' interests before the authorities

Hindering authorities

Do their own thing, trying not to interact with the authorities without need

other

Don’t know

How to your mind should NGOs, noncommercial organizations and initiatives interact with the authorities (Card, two answers maximum)

How to your mind do NGOs, noncommercial organizations and initiatives interact with the authorities (Card, two answers maximum)

39

However, while civil self-organization is no longer perceived as an underground activity

or an “exotic foreigner”, the skills needed for it to be effective are only now emerging. The

number and diversity of NGOs is not insignificant, but most organizations are economically and

administratively weak, and not all of them play fair. Self-organizing cells are usually small,

fragmented and have no distinct need for consolidation. There are relatively few horizontal links

between social structures, and their mutual “kinship” is most often perceived as a mere

coincidence in areas of activity, i.e. they work “parallel” to each other. It is notable that precisely

such a coincidence was recognized by 53% of the abovementioned NGO leaders, who took the

survey, agreeing with the phrase “your organization has a lot in common with another.” At the

same time, only 5% saw a connection through common principles, world outlook, goals and

tasks. 6 % spoke of joint action as the definition of the aforementioned phrase. In turn, practical

cooperation is characterized mostly by different mutual information formats. In the same survey

58% of respondents cited experience exchange as one of the results of interacting with other

organizations, 37% mentioned the formation of a positive image of the organization, 33% spoke

about access to information and methodological resources, while 34% mentioned the additional

possibilities of solving social problems, but only 20% talked about an increase in influence on

authorities.

Most NGOs are not attracted to the idea of being initiators and supporters of mass

actions. This means that, on the whole, they tend to act depending on the situation. The state

policy in relation to public structures can be described as “carrot and stick”. Ultimately it makes

no sense, because it is by definition impossible to manipulate a free self-organization, and a

simulated or corrupt self-organization is ineffective. However, there are such attempts, and that,

of course, discourages many NGOs. At the same time, there are many organizations that have

learned to cooperate with the authorities, without compromising their independence or dignity.

There are also those who knowingly exploit the poor judgment of these structures, as well as

those who act as tools or even as agents of the authorities.

The available empirical evidence gives us moderate optimism about the prospects for

Russian civil society. It would seem that its development is irreversible. However, there is no

reason to expect that the pressure of the civil society on the elite and the state in the near future

will be a decisive factor for change in those institutions that are fundamentally important for

economic growth. Too much still depends on relationships among the elite. This reduces the

predictability of the political and economic process. However, the increase in public activity,

clearly seen at the end of 2011, reduces policy choices available to the elite and, ceteris paribus,

it leads to its greater caution and concern for the long-term future.

40

With the formation of a network of self-organizing cells reflecting a real range of

interests, values, views and requests in Russian society, citizens gradually cease to be content

with their limited role as “fans” for this or that elite team. Of course, this applies in different

ways to different segments of the population. The leaders are, among others, the professional

community of lawyers, doctors, teachers, and especially businessmen.

7. Pabulum for reflection: How can we eliminate inequality and promote investment in human capital?

Income and spending inequality is one of the stumbling blocks on the road to a fully-

fledged civil society and its consolidation around common values. The current gap is too high for

a developed country. This inequality partly stems from the structural imbalance of the Russian

economy, particularly underdevelopment of those sectors which ensure investment in human

capital.

In this chapter we present some solutions. While it is less detailed than previous chapters,

we decided to open a public debate on our ideas since we believe that a full-scale public

discussion is a critical part of strategic deliberations.

This new model of economic growth will be based on human capital in the long-term.

Effective economic mechanisms encouraging state and private investment in human capital

facilitate the feasibility of this model. Education, healthcare and retirement insurance are the

main channels for investment. Furthermore, investment in the environment depends on the

affordability of real estate and the quality of housing and public utility services. We believe that

a reduction in inequality and a more responsible approach by individuals towards their own

investment in human capital for are the only ways to facilitate a breakthrough in these directions.

As a result of the rapid economic growth of the 2000s, income and consumer spending in

real terms increased 2.5 times. However, the change in the structure of consumer spending and

individual savings was uneven. The share of non-food products grew as opposed to food

expenses, and organized savings were generally reduced to bank deposits. At the same time, in

the 2000s the share of fee-based services fluctuated around 14-16% of the income achieved in

the late 1990s. Over the decade the share of medical expenses and tourism grew only slightly -

from 1.2 to 1.3% of income while the share of fee-based educational services after a period of

volatility stabilized at 1%. Pension contributions through savings did not exceed a statistical

discrepancy during the whole period. Thus, though income has been rising throughout the

41

decade, the structure of spending is still far from the pattern that can be seen in developed

countries. Consequently, the share of individual transfers in the structure of investment into

human capital remains low.

The share of education and healthcare in GDP has been nearly the same over the last

decade. It has followed budget spending in these sectors while private financial services have

been reduced to banking. It seemed that a “resource curse” at that time should have not impeded

the above-mentioned non-tradable sectors. The lag persisted as a result of the incomplete reforms

of the public service and state pension systems which did not grow, but instead created an

illusion that they provided the population with their services. In addition to this, a high level of

inequality caused by insufficient income in the public sector impeded the growth of investment

in human capital.

Our hypothesis suggests that narrowing the salary imbalance between public services and

other sectors would increase the share of fee-based services in the structure of consumption. This

assumption is indirectly confirmed by the sharp increase in the salary of public sector employees

in late 2001. As a result, salaries in education and healthcare grew by 60% in 2002 against an

average rise of 35%. This increase coincided with a considerable growth in the share of fee-

based services in the structure of spending (including education and healthcare). This effect

lasted until the early 2010s.

Table 7.1. Consumer spending, % from income

2001 2002 2011 Purchase of goods and service payments 74.6 73.3 73.5 Purchase of goods 59.8 57.3 56.4 Service payments, including 14.8 15.9 15.6 Education payments 1.0 1.1 1.0 Recreation costs, tourism and healthcare services 1.1 1.4 1.3

Source: Federal State Statistics Service

We suggest that the mobilization of additional resources and the growth of income of

employees in education and healthcare are required for the development of these sectors.

However, we need to change the incentives of both producers and consumers in order to drive

these sectors into a new orbit. To this end, public services should be assessed in market terms,

employees should get competitive compensation while consumers should have the resources and

a set of real options and responsibility. As a result, such sectors as healthcare, education, funded

42

retirement insurance, housing and public utilities will emerge as fully-fledged elements of the

market economy. Needless to say, this process will be time-consuming.

What should be done to achieve this goal? In fact, the first step has already been outlined

in plans to increase salaries in public sector for the majority of employees and to maintain them

so that they do not dip below the average level across the region. For some categories of teachers

and doctors, salaries are expected to be higher than average. Unfortunately, given the current

slowdown in the economy and different priorities in federal budget spending, there are not

sufficient funds to guarantee these plans. Even if the number of employees in the public sector

were reduced by 15% by 2018, this increase in salaries would require extra costs of at least 15%

of GDP year on year.

The leveling of the structural disproportion in income in the public sector and other

sectors will reduce inequality. Since this growth in the key producers of investment in human

capital require their inclusion into the market, financial flows should be redefined in order to

trigger market incentives, positive selection and enhancement of quality as well as to attract

extra-budgetary funds into these sectors.

In developed European countries employees pay, as a rule, up to half of their pension

contributions. The rest is paid by their employer. The share of private spending on medical

insurance is also higher than in Russia. We suggest that salaries should be increased in a way

that enables employees to make regular contributions to healthcare and funded pension

insurance. Thus the volume and the structure of spending and savings in this category can be

substantially transformed. It will also encourage an increase in the supply of these services and

can be gradually expanded to employees in the private sector. Healthcare and the pension system

are the top priorities as they suffer more than others when it comes to a lack of funding and

underdeveloped insurance mechanisms. Later this pattern - providing support for additional

spending - can be expanded to education, housing and public utility services and affordable real

estate.

We have preliminarily assessed the required resources and mapped the redistribution of

financial flows. Being aware of the importance of different aspects, we decided to take into

consideration only key factors. So our calculations are approximate. All the figures are

estimated as of 2012 and are based on statistics for 2010-2012. We did not pursue long-term

scenario building, in order to avoid making forecasts about a wide range of parameters.

43

In 2012 the total number of employees in the public sector was 14.1 million. 12 million

are employed in three major sectors – education, healthcare and public administration. These

sectors account for up to 6.5% of GDP as salaries and some 2% of GDP as social expenditure.

Table 7.2. Key parameters of pay and employment in the public sector

Assessment

as of 2012 % of GDP Average pay in the public sector, ths. of roubles/month 23.9 Employment in the public sector, mn. ppl. 14.1 Labor compensation fund year10, bn roubles 4048 6.5 Labor compensation fund incl. transfers (30%)11, bn roubles 5263 8.4 transfers to the Pension Fund of the Russian Federation (22%) 891 1.4 transfers to the compulsory medical insurance (5.1%) 206 0.3 transfers to the Social Insurance Fund (2.9%) 117 0.2

Source: Federal State Statistics Service, the HSE Center for Development calculations

To assess the resources required to transform the financial flow in healthcare we suggest

that an increase in the salary of one employee in the public sector will be equivalent to medical

insurance at the market price for one employee and a member of his family. Given the average

price of a VHI – 25-30 roubles per year (at 2012 price), the estimated increase in the salary of

one public sector employee (insurance bonus) is 5300 roubles per month, including income tax.

Additional flat budget costs are 1.4% of GDP. At the same time, additional expenditure of the

employers (0.5% of GDP) will go into the Pension Fund, compulsory medical insurance agencies

and the Social Insurance Fund.

Table 7.3. Change in financial flows in healthcare

Assessment as of 2012

% of GDP

Number of running VHI contracts, mn. 4.3 VHI premiums, bn. of roubles 120 Average VHI assurance cost, ths. of roubles/year 27.9

Full cost of health insurance for two ppl./year, ths. of roubles 55.8 Same including income tax 64.1 Same per month 5.3 Additional budget expenditures for salaries (w/o transfers), bn. of roubles 905.2 1.4 additional transfers to the Pension Fund of the Russian Federation (22%) 199.2 0.3 additional transfers to the compulsory medical insurance (5.1%) 46.2 0.1 additional transfers to the Social Insurance Fund (2.9%) 26.3 0.04

10 Budget transfers and income-generating activities 11 Excluding recourse

44

Additional budget expenditures with transfers, bn. of roubles 1177 1.9 Source: Federal Financial Markets Service, the HSE Center for Development calculations

To calculate the resources required by the defined contribution pension system, we

suggest that all employees in the public sector get an increase in salary which makes up for the

cost of the first annual fee for one participant. The period for accumulating a pension is 40 years

and the payment period is 20 years. According to a conservative scenario, the annual growth of

salary will be 7% per year in nominal terms. The average annual return for the whole period is

6% in nominal terms and 3% in real terms. An accumulated pension should ensure 50% of the

average income over the working period (or 17% of final salary). We do not consider the

survival probability normally used in actuarial calculations. 12 Such method results in the

overpricing of pension transfers against the baseline. However, it is reasonable to use this if

pension savings can be inherited (this is the best way to enhance the credibility of the system).

To avoid discrimination we suggest that all gender and age groups will get an increase in salary,

though savings will be financially reasonable only for those who will be able to accumulate

savings for more than 20 years. Senior citizens can relocate the above-mentioned funds as

additional transfers to a pay-as-you-go part of the pension system. It will mitigate the deficit and

reduce the vertical imbalance of the budget.

The estimated increase in salary of one employee in the public sector required to pay the

first annual fee is 2900 roubles per month, income tax included. The additional budget cost of

labor compensation is 1% of GDP, with all expenditures included.

Table 7.4. Change in cash flow in the pension system

Assessment as of 2012

% of GDP

Average annual pay growth rate, % 7.0% Average return, % 6.0% Premium due date, yrs 40 Endowment period, yrs 20 Average pay during pension accumulation, ths. of roubles/month 119.3 Pension amounting to 50% average earnings (17% of final salary), ths. of roubles/month 59.6 Pension capital, ths. of roubles 14311.2 Cost of the annual fee in the first year, ths. of roubles 30.5 Same including income tax 35.1 Same per month 2.92 Additional budget expenditures for salaries (w/o transfers), bn. of roubles 495.3 0.8 additional transfers to the Pension Fund of the Russian 109.0 0.2

12 As we noticed, a number of the biggest Russian non-state pension funds do the same.

45

Federation (22%) additional transfers to the compulsory medical insurance (5.1%) 25.3 0.04 additional transfers to the Social Insurance Fund (2.9%) 14.4 0.02 Additional budget expenditures with transfers, bn. of roubles 644 1.0

Source: the HSE Center for Development calculations

The above-mentioned changes in health and funded pension insurance should encourage

employees in the public sector to generate additional financial flows in these sectors, shape

demand for better medical services and establish a source of long-term investment as an

upgraded component of the defined contribution pension system.

Table 7.5. General Results

Assessment as of 2012

% of GDP

Average pay in the public sector, ths. of roubles 32.2 Changes to the expenditure budget Additional expenditures for salaries 1401 2.2 Additional transfers 420 0.7 Total additional expenditures, bn. of roubles 1821 2.9 Changes to the revenue side of the budget Additional transfers to the Pension Fund of the Russian Federation 803 1.3 through payments of employers 308 0.5 through payments of workers 495 0.8 into the PAYG part 248 0.4 into the cumulative part 248 0.4 Additional transfers to the compulsory medical insurance 977 1.6 through payments of employers 71 0.1 through payments of workers 905 1.4 Additional transfers to the Social Insurance Fund 41 0.1 Total additional income, bn. of roubles 1821 2.9 Funds to cover the current deficit of the Pension Fund of the Russian Federation, bn. of roubles 556 0.9 Flow of resources into medical insurance and the cumulative part of the pension insurance, bn. of roubles 1265 2.0

Source: Federal State Statistics Service, Federal Financial Markets Service, the HSE Center for Development calculations

The price of the change is an increase in budget spending on labor compensation and

expenditures by 2.9% of GDP. The total amount of resources required for change is smaller than

the National Wealth Fund. At the same time, most of the funds will immediately return to the

budget due to additional transfers to non-budget funds. However, since labor compensation in

the public sector is financed mainly by regional budgets, the regions will need additional

transfers for this period of transition. As the service sector matures and the regional budgets get

additional revenues, the need for transfers will decrease, so our proposal is generally in line with

46

the concept of decentralization. Inflation will be almost unaffected since any additional resources

will not directly influence the consumer goods market.

The biggest risks and problems stem from the need to expand this upgraded system to

employees in the private sector. If they immediately have to pay medical insurance and pension

fees for themselves without any compensation, it could result in a growing poverty rate in those

households where no one works in the public sector13. The margin for increase in salaries in the

public sector can be slightly higher than that required by expenditure so that this “award”

promotes aggregate demand. The gradual adaptation of the economy and an increasing supply of

high-quality services and expanding resources will need time for transition (approx. 5-7 years).

Citizens will favor the new system if the difference between standard services in

compulsory health insurance and high-quality services at market price (for example, the choice

between a public health center and a private or ministerial one) is obvious. The upgraded defined

contribution pension system should include credibility building measures to ensure the safety of

savings and high returns. One possible solution suggests that the process can be launched in

those regions with best performance, where income is higher and there are already various

medical centers and financial institutions. The supply of high-quality services will increase and

be comparable to demand if medical centers attached to governmental agencies are included in

this insurance system since they currently provide services to employees in public administration

which is a non-market access restriction.

Increased competition in the labor market and pressure for higher salaries from

employees in the private sector will be the most important result of this transition to a market

with investment in human capital. In this context, the private sector will have to enhance its

efficiency and labor productivity (by rationalizing staff or using technological advances). So the

changes described above can only be carried out as a part of a full-scale institutional

transformation.

13The authors would like to thank L.N.Ovcharova and the Independent institution of social policy staff who helped to assess the consequences with the use of microdata.

47

Bibliography: Vinkov A., Gurova T., Polunin Y., Yudanov A. To run medium business, Expert. 2008. № 10.

SU HSE (2007) Russian industry at the crossroads: what impedes the competitiveness of our businesses: the report SU-HSE // Economic Issues. 2007. № 3

NRU HSE. Will the states do on their own? NGOs’ role in tackling social problems. М.: NRU HSE, 2012.

Petronevich M.V., Aleksashko S.V., Akindinova N.V., Petronevich A.V. How much do dysfunctional institutions cost? Economic Issues, 2011. № 8.

Petronevich M.V. The impact of the modernization of the network of federal roads on the growth of certain macroeconomic parameters of the region. HSE Economic Magazine., 2009. Volume13.№2. p.295-322.

The Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration. The fruit of weak competition: quantitative estimates and policy implications (analytical report), Economic policy, 2012, № 6.

Yudanov A.Y. The conquerors of the “blue oceans” (“gazelles” in Russia), Modern Competition. 2010. № 2.

Jakobson, Lev and Sergey Sanovich (2009). The Changing Model of the Russian Third Sector: Import Substitution Phase // Journal of Civil Society, Vol. 6, No 3, 278-300.

Yakovlev Andrei. State-Business Relations in Russia in the 2000s: From the Capture Model to a Variety of Exchange Models? BOFIT Discussion Paper No. 10/2011

Yakovlev Andrei and Govorun Andrei. Industrial Associations as a Channel of Business-Government Interactions in Imperfect Institutional Environment: The Russian Case. UCL SSEES Centre for Comparative Economics Working Paper No. 116, 2011

Yasin E.G. Long-term scenarios for Russia. New push after two decades down the road. 2012, NRU HSE

Desai R. M., I. Goldberg (eds.) Enhancing Russia’s Competitiveness and Innovative Capacity. World Bank, 2007.

Kuznetsov, B., Dolgopyatova, T., Golikova, V., Gonchar, K., Yakovlev, A. & Yasin, Y., “Russian Manufacturing Revisited: Industrial Enterprises at the Start of the Crisis,” Post-Soviet Affairs, Vol.27, 2011, Issue 4, p.366-386.

Djankov Simeon, Gerard Roland, Yingyi Qian, Ekaterina Zhuravskaya (2006). Entrepreneurship in China and Russia compared // Journal of the European Economic Association, April-May 2006, 4 (2-3), p.352-365.

48

Fan Joseph P.H., Jun Huang, Randall Morck & Bernard Yeung (2009) The Visible Hand behind China’s Growth. Paper prepared for the Joint NBER-CUHK Conference on Capitalizing China. December 2009.

Li Hongbin & Li-An Zhou (2005) Political turnover and economic performance: the incentive role of personnel control in China // Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 89 (2005), p.1743–1762.

Maskin Eric, Yingyi Qian & Chenggang Xu (2000) Incentives, Information, and Organizational Form // The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 67, No. 2 (Apr., 2000), pp. 359-378

Shleifer Andrei and Robert W. Vishny (1993). Corruption // The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108, No. 3 (Aug., 1993), pp. 599-617

Roland Gerard (2000). Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms. The MIT Press, 2000.

R. Putnam. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, 1993

R. Putnam. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York, 2000.

Qian Yingyi and Gérard Roland (1998). Federalism and the Soft Budget Constraint // American Economic Review, 88 (5), p.1143-1162,

Qian, Yingi (1999). “The Process of China’s Market Transition (1978-1998): Evolutionary, Historical and Institutional Perspectives.” Paper prepared for the Journal of Institutional and The oretical Economics symposium on “Big-Bang Transformation of Economic Systems as a Challenge to New Institutional Economics,” June 9-11, 1999, Wallerfangen/Saar, Germany.