earnings management and the accruals anomaly: the role of ...correlated during times of...

54
Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of industry-specific discretionary accruals Atif Ikram Wayne State University Ranjan D’Mello Wayne State University This Version: September 1, 2013 Keywords: Accruals, earnings management, market efficiency, methodology JEL Classification: G12, G14, G30, M41 Atif Ikram School of Business Administration, Wayne State University, Prentis Building, 5210 Cass Avenue, Detroit, MI 48202, USA. Email: [email protected] Telephone: 313-577-7837 Ranjan D’Mello School of Business Administration, Wayne State University, Prentis Building, 5210 Cass Avenue, Detroit, MI 48202, USA. Email: [email protected] Telephone: 313-577-7828

Upload: others

Post on 21-Jan-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The

role of industry-specific discretionary accruals

Atif Ikram

Wayne State University

Ranjan D’Mello

Wayne State University

This Version: September 1, 2013

Keywords: Accruals, earnings management, market efficiency, methodology

JEL Classification: G12, G14, G30, M41

Atif Ikram

School of Business Administration, Wayne State University, Prentis Building, 5210 Cass Avenue, Detroit,

MI 48202, USA.

Email: [email protected]

Telephone: 313-577-7837

Ranjan D’Mello

School of Business Administration, Wayne State University, Prentis Building, 5210 Cass Avenue, Detroit,

MI 48202, USA.

Email: [email protected]

Telephone: 313-577-7828

Page 2: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

Abstract

We motivate and implement a methodology that decomposes a firm’s discretionary accruals

into a firm-specific and an industry-specific component. We find that the “accruals anomaly”

(Sloan 1996) – the finding that firms with high discretionary accruals subsequently earn

negative abnormal returns – is driven by the firm-specific component of discretionary accruals.

Moreover, although industry-specific discretionary accruals do not contribute directly towards

the anomaly, we find that it is precisely when industry-specific discretionary accruals are high

that firms with large firm-specific discretionary accruals subsequently earn negative abnormal

returns. The results suggest firms use income-increasing discretionary accruals to manipulate

earnings primarily when other firms in the industry also have high discretionary accruals. A

likely explanation for this finding is that industry-wide use of high discretionary reduces

investors’ incentives to distinguish between manipulative and value-relevant discretionary

accruals, and that firms internalize this reduced probability of detection in deciding to

manipulate earnings. The finding also has an important bearing on the earnings management

literature that uses discretionary accruals to proxy for earnings manipulation.

Page 3: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

1

1. Introduction

The information content and potential manipulation of accruals continues to

attract the attention of academics and the investing community. Accruals stem from

mismatch in the timing of cash and economic transactions and can help managers convey

value-relevant information about the firm (Dechow 1994). At the same time, given the

discretion enjoyed by managers in accounting for accruals, managers can potentially also

use accruals to manipulate reported earnings (Jones, 1991; Kasanen, Kinnunen and

Niskanen, 1996). Such discretion and the potential for manipulation imply that it is likely

to be difficult for investors to extract the information content (if any) embedded in

reported accruals.

Accordingly a number of studies have explored the relationship between reported

accruals and capital market outcomes. Several results are considered to be anomalous.

For instance Sloan (1996) finds that firms with high (low) accruals subsequently earn

negative (positive) abnormal returns. Bradshaw, Richardson and Sloan (2001) and

Ahmed, Nainar and Zhou (2005) show that even sophisticated investors like sell-side

analysts tend to be optimistic and do not incorporate the predictable earnings declines

associated with high accruals. Xie (2001) decomposes accruals into a discretionary and

non-discretionary component and finds that investors tend to misprice the discretionary

component of accruals, i.e. the component more susceptible to earnings manipulation.

Subsequent research has shown that this “accruals anomaly” can primarily be attributed

to the mispricing of large, income-increasing discretionary accruals (Beneish and Vargus,

2002; Desai, Rajgopal and Venkatachalam, 2004; Kothari, Loutskina and Nikolaev,

2006; Mashruwala, Rajgopal and Shevlin, 2006; Lev and Nissim, 2006). The finding

Page 4: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

2

suggests that firms use (high) discretionary accruals to manipulate earnings and that

market participants fail to detect this earnings manipulation. Indeed a large strand of

earnings management literature has used high discretionary accruals to proxy for earnings

manipulation in a variety of settings (e.g. Rangan, 1998; Teoh, Welch and Wong,

1998a,b; Teoh and Wong, 2002; Bergstresser and Phillipon, 2006; Cornett, McNutt and

Tehranian, 2009).

In this paper we develop and implement a methodology that decomposes a firm’s

discretionary accruals into a firm-specific (FSDA) and an industry-specific (ISDA)

component. We define firm-specific discretionary accruals as the difference between a

firm’s reported accruals and those expected of it at a specific point in time within its

industry. This captures the idea that a part of firm’s discretionary accruals is

idiosyncratic. The industry-specific component, on the other hand, measures those

discretionary accruals that arise when contemporaneous expected level of accruals

deviate from those expected of the firm in the long-run. This captures the idea that

sometimes an entire industry can be experiencing a high/low ‘discretionary accruals

wave’ and thus firms in the same industry could be sharing a common component of

discretionary accruals. A firm’s total discretionary accruals (TDA) are hence defined as

the sum of its firm-specific and industry-specific components.

In most existing related literature, researchers have used some variant of the

cross-sectional Jones (1991) model to calculate discretionary accruals. In these models a

firm’s reported accruals are regressed (cross-sectionally, at the industry level) against a

set of explanatory variables, and the residuals obtained from these models are classified

as discretionary (e.g. Kothari, Leone and Wasley, 2005). Such an approach implicitly

Page 5: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

3

assumes that a firm’s time-t expected accruals (measured using contemporaneous Jones

model parameter estimates) do not contain a component of discretionary accruals that is

common to all firms within the industry. Under certain situations such a presumption may

not be reasonable.

For instance, Jeter and Shivakumar (1999) argue that discretionary accruals are

likely to be correlated when an industry is enjoying favorable economic conditions and

firms are trying to ‘smooth’ reported earnings. Kang, Liu and Qi (2010) suggest that

discretionary accruals can be correlated if firm managers time the aggregate equity

market and increase discretionary accruals after sensing an increase in next-period’s

market risk premium. Similarly a decrease in discount rates can result in an industry-wide

increase in discretionary accruals as firms optimally adjust investments in response to

discount rate changes (Wu, Zhang and Zhang, 2010). Cheng (2010) suggests that in

certain situations the use of high discretionary accruals at one firm can “spillover” to

other firms in the industry. Relatedly (Bagnoli and Watts, 2000) argue that managers’

relative performance evaluation concerns within an industry can cause manipulative

discretionary accruals to emerge as Nash equilibrium. Discretionary accruals can also be

correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to

manipulate earnings upwards in order to sustain their overvaluation (Jensen 2005;

Kothari et al. 2006). Residuals from variants of the cross-sectional Jones (1991) model

cannot, by construction, capture such correlated discretionary accruals.

Accordingly, we contend that residuals obtained from cross-sectional Jones model

only measure the firm-specific component of discretionary accruals. In order to measure a

firm’s total discretionary accruals one must also estimate the industry-specific

Page 6: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

4

component, i.e. the component shared by all firms in the industry. To that end, We

augment the application of the Jones model: we use the arithmetic average of the

parameters obtained from estimating the model in each year and industry to calculated a

firm’s long-run non-discretionary accruals (LRNDA), and calculate industry-specific

discretionary accruals as the difference between a firm’s short-run non-discretionary

accruals (SRNDA), i.e. firm’s time-t expected accruals (estimated using

contemporaneous Jones model parameter estimates) and its long-run non-discretionary

accruals.1 Defining and decomposing discretionary accruals in this manner can allow for

a more incisive examination of the information content and manipulability of accruals,

their role in price discovery, and the source of the documented accrual anomalies. For the

purpose of this paper we focus the lens of this accruals decomposition on the original

anomaly documented by Sloan.

Using a sample of COMPUSTAT firms from 1970 – 2006, we confirm that

Sloan’s accruals anomaly is driven by the discretionary component of accruals. When we

sort firms into decile portfolios based on fiscal year-end TDA, we find that firm-years in

the top TDA decile earn an average annualized abnormal return of -3.84% the following

year. On the other hand, neither the highest- nor the lowest-LRNDA decile earns

abnormal returns in the year following portfolio formation. Additionally, we find that

mispricing of discretionary accruals is driven by the firm-specific component. When we

sort firms based on fiscal year-end FSDA and ISDA we find that firm-years in the top

1 Effectively, our point of departure from prior studies is with respect to the definition of non-discretionary

accruals. Prior studies define non-discretionary accruals as accruals estimated using contemporaneous Jones model parameter estimates. In the context of this paper, the term is misleading because non-

discretionary accruals (measured this way) can contain a correlated component of discretionary accruals.

Therefore, (for the lack of a better word) we refer to these time-t expected accruals as short-run non-

discretionary accruals and distinguish them from a firm’s long-run non-discretionary accruals. The

difference between the two measures the correlated, industry-specific component of discretionary accruals.

Page 7: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

5

FSDA decile subsequently earn an annualized abnormal return of -3.60%; in contrast,

firms in the highest ISDA decile do not earn significant abnormal returns subsequent to

portfolio formation. These results suggest that compared to FSDA, ISDA (on average)

are not manipulative and convey value-relevant information to investors.

Moreover, although industry-specific accruals do not directly contribute towards

the accruals anomaly, we find that it is precisely when industry-specific discretionary

accruals are high that firms with high firm-specific discretionary accruals subsequently

earn negative abnormal returns. Specifically, when we divide the top FSDA decile into

subgroups based on member firms’ respective ISDA decile ranking, we find that the

highest-FSDA-highest-ISDA portfolio (i.e. the set of firm-years both in the top FSDA

and ISDA decile) earns an annualized abnormal return of -8.16% in the year following

portfolio formation. In contrast, the highest-FSDA-lowest-ISDA portfolio (i.e. the set of

firm-years in the top FSDA decile and the bottom ISDA decile) does not earn such

negative abnormal returns. The results suggest the accruals anomaly is not merely driven

by the mispricing of high FSDA, but specifically by the mispricing of those high FSDA

that are associated with high ISDA.

The mispricing of high (discretionary) accruals is anomalous in that it questions

the efficiency of capital markets. Accordingly, academics have offered different

explanations for why this mispricing occurs. Sloan (1996) argues that investors misprice

accruals because they naively fixate on earnings without realizing the lower persistence

of accruals compared to cash flows. Fairfield, Whisenant and Yohn (2003) argue that

firms with high accruals subsequently earn negative returns due to diminishing returns to

new investments. Desai et al. (2004) suggest that accrual anomaly is merely a

Page 8: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

6

manifestation of the well-documented glamour stock phenomenon. Recently Wu, Zhang

and Zhang (2010) have put forth a q-theory hypothesis for the anomaly according to

which firms optimally adjust their accruals in response to changes in discount rates. Of

all these explanations, Sloan’s ‘earnings-fixation’ hypothesis has received the most

attention (and support) in the literature.2

The findings of this paper suggests that an alternative (though not necessarily

mutually exclusive) explanation for the accruals anomaly could be that industry-wide use

of high discretionary accruals increases the search costs that investors have to incur in

order to detect earnings manipulation. When most firms in the industry have high (value-

relevant) discretionary accruals, a firm whose high discretionary accruals are

manipulative is able to ‘blend in’ more easily compared to when most firms in the

industry have low discretionary accruals. As a result, industry-wide use of value-relevant,

high discretionary accruals can camouflage firms whose high discretionary accruals are

manipulative in nature. For investors, distinguishing between value-relevant and

manipulative discretionary accruals during such times can be time-consuming and

potentially associated with greater information gathering costs. As long as such search

costs are reasonably high, investors may have an incentive to price all high discretionary

accruals as value-relevant, including those that are manipulative.

Relatedly, the use of high discretionary accruals by most firms in the industry can

also act as a credible signal to investors that firms have high discretionary accruals for

‘good’ (i.e. value-relevant) reasons. As a result, investors can become less likely to

subject a given firm’s high discretionary accruals to scrutiny, and/or to deem them

2 Dechow, Khimich and Sloan (2011) provide a comprehensive overview of the potential explanations for

the accrual anomaly as well as evidence supporting the superiority of earnings-fixation hypothesis.

Page 9: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

7

manipulative. In some sense, industry-wide use of high discretionary accruals can give

investors reason to be ‘credulous’ of earnings manipulation (Teoh and Wong, 2002),

causing them to overlook firms whose high discretionary accruals are manipulative.

The paper makes notable contributions to the accounting and finance literature.

First, it develops and implements a methodology that augments a widely-used

econometric technique (namely, the cross-sectional Jones model) to measure a firm’s

discretionary accruals. Several academics (e.g. Jeter and Shivakumar, 1999) have argued

that residuals from cross-sectional estimation of the Jones model can produce biased

estimates of discretionary accruals if discretionary accruals are correlated across firms in

the industry. The (discretionary) accruals decomposition motivated in this paper directly

addresses this concern by explicitly measuring this industry-specific component of

discretionary accruals and hence, at the very least, produces a less biased estimate of

discretionary accruals.

Secondly, the paper advances our understanding of the information content

embedded in discretionary accruals. The finding that neither high nor low ISDA

subsequently earn abnormal returns suggests that correlated discretionary accruals tend

not to be manipulative.3 Moreover, the finding that mispricing of high FSDA is driven

specifically by the subset of firms which also has high ISDA suggests that even high

FSDA are not always manipulative. In particular, the results imply that when most firms

in the industry have low discretionary accruals, firms use high FSDA to convey value-

relevant information to investors. The implication potentially has an important bearing on

the earnings management literature that has used residuals from variants of cross-

3 The evidence hence casts doubt on the possibility of industry-wide earnings manipulation (e.g. Bagnoli

and Watts, 2000).

Page 10: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

8

sectional Jones model to measure discretionary accruals and classified all firms with high

discretionary accruals as earnings manipulators. This probably helps explain why some

academics find variants of cross-sectional Jones model prone to misspecifying high

discretionary accruals as manipulative (McNichols 2000; Badertscher, Collins and Lys

2012).4 Relatedly, the paper adds to the growing body of literature that has found industry

and market conditions to be particularly important in studying earnings management

(Park, 1999; Jiao, Mertens and Roosenboom, 2007).

Finally, the paper adds to the growing body of literature looking to explain why

investors overprice firms with high discretionary accruals. The results indicate that only

firms with high FSDA and high ISDA subsequently earn negative abnormal returns. This

suggests that a potential explanation for why investors fail to detect earnings

manipulation could be that industry-wide use of high discretionary accruals makes it

difficult/costly for them to distinguish between high discretionary accruals that are value-

relevant and those that are manipulative.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the

research methodology used to define and decompose discretionary accruals. Section 3

describes the data used to implement the accruals decomposition. Section 4 presents the

main results of the paper. Section 5 provides details on alternative specifications used to

test the robustness of results. Finally Section 6 provides a brief summary of the main

findings and identifies potential areas for future research.

4 It is worth stressing that this implication is based on results obtained for the general accruals anomaly

documeneted by Sloan (1996) and Xie (2001). It is quite possible that industry-specific discretionary

accruals do not play any role in explaining earnings manipulation prompted by firm-specific events or

factors such as equity issuance (Teoh et al. 1998a,b), high equity compensation of CEOs(Bergstresser and

Phillipon 2006), poor corporate governance (Cornett, McNutt and Tehranian 2009) etc.

Page 11: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

9

2. Research Methodology

The methodology we use to decompose discretionary accruals into firm-specific

and industry-specific components is similar to the one used by Rhodes-Kropf, Robinson

and Viswanathan (2005, hereafter RKRV) in assessing the impact of misvaluation on

merger activity. Under the pretext that high market-to-book ratios (M/B) indicate

overvaluation, RKRV propose that a firm’s M/B should be broken into two components:

market value-to-true-value, M/V, and true value-to-book value, V/B. Thus, M/B can be

expressed as:

( ) ( ) [1]

where m is market value, b is book value, and v is some measure of fundamental value,

all expressed in logarithms. The authors argue that captures the part of ln(M/B)

that is associated with misvaluation, positive in times of overvaluation and negative in

times of undervaluation.

RKRV further argue that a firm’s misvaluation should be broken down into two

components: a firm-specific component and an industry-specific component. The authors

contend that the firm-specific component captures part of the misvaluation that is unique

to the firm, while the industry-specific component captures the part that is common to all

firms in the industry ( due to an entire industry being misvalued at a given point in time).

Thus, for a given firm i in industry j at time t, the authors decompose as:

( )⏟

( ) ( )⏟

( ) ⏟

[2]

Page 12: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

10

In equation [2], RKRV estimate v by expressing it as a function of firm-specific

accounting information at a point in time, , and a vector of conditional accounting

multiples, . The key difference in the ( ) expressions is that (in a given industry j)

time-t multiples are represented as while long-run multiples are represented by .

Thus, the first term (labeled firm-specific) indicates the difference between a firm’s

market value and fundamental value conditional on time t and industry j valuation effects.

The authors call this firm-specific error/misvaluation because the v term captures all

deviations common to a sector at a point in time. The second component (labeled sector-

specific) measures the firm’s time-t fundamental value relative to its long-run value. The

authors call this time-series sector error because the function ( ) captures sector-

specific valuation that does not vary over time; the parameters in capture the long-run

multiples for industry j. Finally, the last component (labeled long-run) measures the

difference between long-run value and book value.

In a manner analogous to RKRV, we decompose a firm’s total accruals (AC) into

three components: firm-specific discretionary accruals (FSDA), time-series industry-

specific discretionary accruals (ISDA), and long-run non-discretionary accruals

(LRNDA). The firm-specific component captures the difference between a firm’s

observed accruals and its predicted level of accruals based on time-t accounting

fundamentals. We call these short-run non-discretionary accruals (SRNDA). The

industry-specific component measures the difference between a firm’s SRNDA and

LRNDA. The sum of firm-specific and industry-specific components equals total

discretionary accruals (TDA), and measures how much a firm’s total accruals deviate

from its LRNDA.

Page 13: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

11

Mathematically, if ( ) denotes the ith

firm’s accruals as a function of firm-

specific accounting information, , and a vector of conditional parameter estimates,

then the accrual decomposition can be expressed as:

{ ( )}⏟

{ ( ) ( )}⏟ ⏟

( )⏟

[3]

In equation [3], the first bracketed term on the right (labeled FSDA) measures

firm-specific discretionary accruals as it reflects the difference between a firm’s accrual

measure and its short-run non-discretionary accruals based on time-t accounting

fundamentals and industry j accrual effects, ( ). If economic conditions are

good and all firms in the industry are smoothing reported earnings then this will get

reflected in and consequently in firm’s SRNDA, ( ). Similarly if most firms

in the industry have high discretionary accruals due to better-than-average industry

performance (Kothari, Leone and Wasley 2005) then this too will get reflected in and

hence in ( ). More generally, any component of discretionary accruals

correlated across firms within the industry will be captured by ( ).

The second bracketed term on the right reflects the difference between time-t

expected accruals ( ) and long-run expected accruals ( ). As in RKRV,

the main difference between the two functions is that short-run parameter estimates are

represented by while long-run parameter estimates are represented by . Thus

( ) ( ) captures the industry-specific component of discretionary

accruals because compared to ( ), ( ) measures that part of a firm’s

Page 14: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

12

expected accruals that does not vary with time. Finally, the last term in equation [3]

(labeled LRNDA) measures the firm’s long-run non-discretionary accruals.

It is worth noting that each of these three components varies at the firm-level and

involves parameter estimates that vary across industries and overtime. Thus ( )

varies overtime at the firm level as accounting information changes (i.e. varies over t

holding i constant), and also varies across firms within an industry as their accounting

data differ (i.e. varies over i holding t constant).

Equation [3] can be re-written to express a firm’s (total) discretionary accruals as

the sum of firm-specific and industry-specific discretionary accruals:

( )⏟

{ ( )}⏟

{ ( ) ( )}⏟

[4]

The breakdown of discretionary accruals naturally depends on a reliable measure

of expected accruals, ( ). A large body of literature has used some variant of the

Jones model to estimate these expected accruals. In these models a firm’s accruals are

regressed on accounting variables that are considered important determinants of accruals

(e.g. sales, PP&E etc.) and the resulting parameter estimates – or “accrual multiples” –

are used to predict the firm’s time-t expected accruals. In this paper we use the cross-

sectional, (performance-adjusted) modified Jones model to calculate these expected

accruals. There are two main reasons for using this particular specification. First,

compared to time-series versions of the Jones model the cross-sectional variants usually

result in larger samples and are less likely to suffer from survivorship bias (McNichols,

2000). The cross-sectional specifications also tend to have more explanatory power

Page 15: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

13

compared to their time-series counterparts (Bartov, Gul and Tsui, 2000).5 Additionally,

literature suggests that within the class of cross-sectional variants, the performance-

adjusted modified Jones model is preferred (Ronen and Yaari, 2008) because it adjusts

for the effect of credit sales (Dechow, Sloan and Sweeney, 1995) and operating

performance (Subramanyam 1996; Kothari et al. 2005) on accruals.

Second, industry-level cross-sectional estimation of expected accruals is aptly

suited to the purpose of this paper because it explicitly accounts for the possibility that

firm’s expected accruals vary overtime and across industries. Hence the regression

coefficients obtained from this procedure can be interpreted as time-varying accrual

multiples and can be used to calculate time-series industry-specific discretionary accruals

in the manner outlined above.

The exact specification of the modified Jones model we use in this paper can be

expressed as:

( )

In equation [5], AC denotes a firm’s reported total accruals, AT denotes total

assets, SALE denotes sales, REC denotes receivables, PPE denotes gross property, plant

and equipment, and NI denotes net income. To generate estimates of (lag-asset weighted)

( ) and ( ) we follow RKRV’s methodology and use fitted values from

equation [5] above:

5 This is also perhaps why a large strand of accounting and finance literature has used cross-sectional Jones

model to measure discretionary accruals.

Page 16: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

14

( )

( )

for each firm. Equation [6] yields a firm’s short-run non-discretionary accruals. To obtain

( ) i.e. a firm’s long-run non-discretionary accruals, we average over time to

obtain ⁄ ∑ for each set of parameters { }, and then calculate:

( )

( )

3. Data and Sample Selection

My initial sample consists of all firms for which data are available on

COMPUSTAT Fundamentals Annual and CRSP Monthly Stock Return files from 1968 –

2006. We define each firm’s industry based on its 2-digit SIC code. We drop financials

(SIC codes 6000 – 6999) due to the difficulty involved in interpreting their accruals, and

utilities (SIC codes 4900 – 4999) due to their different regulatory reporting requirements.

We limit our analysis to firms listed on NASDAQ, NYSE and AMEX and to firms whose

shares correspond to common equity (i.e. closed-end funds, units, ADRs and REITs are

excluded from the sample). We also confine our attention to firms incorporated in the US,

to firms with fiscal year-end in December, and to firms with non-missing values for any

of the modified Jones (1991) model variables shown in equation [5].

Page 17: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

15

In order to obtain reliable estimates from the cross-sectional Jones model

(equation [5]), we require all industries to have at least 10 firms in a given fiscal year.6

Moreover, in order to obtain reliable estimates of i =1,…,4 in equation [7], we also

limit our sample to firms which have non-missing values for FSDA in at least eight of the

sample years.7 The final sample with non-missing values for TDA, FSDA and ISDA

consists of 55,208 firm-years between 1970 and 2006. We Winsorize all continuous

variables at 1% and 99% to remove the effect of outliers.

At the end of each fiscal year we rank sample firm-years based on the magnitude

of their accrual components, and use these rankings to construct AC, TDA, FSDA ISDA

and NDA decile portfolios. The assignment of firm-years across their respective deciles

remains fixed throughout the analysis.

The measurement of required variables proceeds as follows: for each firm i at

time t we calculate accruals ( ) using the balance-sheet approach (see, for example,

Koathri et al. 2006) as:

( ) ( ) [6]

where is change in current assets (COMPUSTAT item ACT), is change

in cash and cash equivalents (COMPUSTAT item CHE), is change in current

liabilities (COMPUSTAT item LCT), is the change in debt in in current

6 A minimum number of observations are required to obtain ‘reasonable’ parameter estimates from the

cross-sectional Jones (1991) model. According to Ronen and Yaari (2008), the customary minimum

(median) cutoff number is eight (ten). 7 Thus, we require that each industry has a minimum of 10 firms in at least 8 of the sample years between

1968 and 2006.

Page 18: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

16

liabilities (COMPUSTAT item DLC), is the change in income taxes payable

(COMPUSTAT item TXP), and is the depreciation expense (COMPUSTAT item

DP). Where necessary we define earnings as income before extraordinary items

(COMPUSTAT item IB) and cash flows as the difference between earnings and accruals.

All these variables are scaled by beginning-of-year total assets (COMPUSTAT item AT)

to ensure compatibility across firms in the sample.

To estimate equation [5] we measure as the change in sales revenue

(COMPUSTAT item SALE), as change in accounts receivable (COMPUSTAT

item RECT), as gross property, plant and equipment (COMPUSTAT item

PPEGT), and as net income (COMPUSTAT item NI).

As in Kothari et al. (2006) we calculate abnormal portfolio returns by annualizing

monthly Jensen’s alphas obtained from estimating the Fama and French (1993) three

factor model.8 To ensure that there is sufficient time for financial statement data to reflect

in market prices we measure portfolio returns starting in April, four months after the end

of the fiscal year. The monthly portfolio alphas are calculated by regressing monthly

equally-weighted portfolio returns on the three Fama-French factors (market, size and

book-to-market respectively). In the event a firm delists, we replace its returns by its

delisting return in the month of delisting and reinvest the liquidating proceeds in the

value-weighted market portfolio for the remainder of the year (Xie, 2001).

4. Results

4.1 Descriptive Statistics

8 The calculation of alphas requires that sample firms be aligned in calendar time. All firm-years in our

sample have fiscal year-end in December and hence meet this requirement.

Page 19: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

17

Conditional on firm-specific accounting information , the magnitude of ISDA

depends on the difference between the contemporaneous and average Jones model

parameter estimates, and , respectively. Therefore as a first step we examine the

summary statistics of the parameter estimates obtained from cross-sectionally estimating

equation [5]. These statistics are reported in Table I. Each row shows the industries in my

final sample (as defined using 2-digit SICs), and the three columns labeled Col 1, Col 2

and Col 3 show the summary statistics of , and .9 The mean values of parameter

estimates in each of these columns correspond to , and used in equation [7].

Table I shows that signs of all parameter estimates are, on average, consistent

with expectations. For instance is negative in all industries since PPE captures the

magnitude of depreciation expense. Likewise almost all industries have a positive

average value for which is consistent with the notion that net working capital accruals

are positive for firms whose sales exceed their expenses.10

Positive average values of

are also consistent with the idea that operating accruals tend to increase with firm

performance (Healy 1996).

Additionally Table I suggests considerable heterogeneity across industries in

terms of firms’ average sensitivity to each of explanatory variables in the Jones model.

For instance the median value of is quite high in the Leather and leather products

industry (0.171) and in the Electronic equipment industry (0.160), but considerably lower

in the Eating and drinking industry (-0.036) Likewise, firms’ average sensitivity to last

9 Table I does not report the summary statistics of , the coefficient on inverse-assets (1/At-a) which

appears as one of the regressors in equation [5]. Inverse-assets are included in the model to control for

hetroscedasticity across firms within the same industry. 10 Nonetheless, sensitivity to net working capital accruals can be negative. For further discussion of this

issue, see Chapter 10 of Ronen and Yaari (2008).

Page 20: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

18

year’s return on assets is considerably high in Textile mill products industry ( = 0.303)

and Furniture and fixtures industry ( = 0.240), but much lower in other industries like

Oil and gas extraction ( = -0.008). These inter-industry differences suggest that

industry membership and nature of business operations are an important determinant of

accruals.

More importantly, Table I suggests that values of these parameter estimates vary

considerably overtime within industries. In most industries, each parameter estimate

exhibits a large inter-quartile range as well as a high standard deviation relative to the

mean. This is especially true for estimates of and . For instance in the Furniture and

fixtures industry is 0.038, its interquartile range is 0.235 and its standard deviation is

0.158. Similarly in the Metal Mining industry the standard deviation of (0.262) is

more than three times its mean (median) value of 0.045 (0.045). Although these

parameters fluctuate more in some industries than in others, the fact that they do fluctuate

suggests that at any given point a firm is likely to have non-zero correlated discretionary

accruals.

In Table II we report the summary statistics of accrual components and key firm

characteristics. Consistent with earlier studies (Subramanyam 1996; Xie 2001) Panel A

shows that average accruals are negative with a mean (median) of -3.81% (-4.17%). Both

SRNDA and LRNDA form a significant fraction of these accruals (on average) as

reflected by their means (medians) of -3.34% (-3.19%) and -3.52% (-3.28%) respectively.

This is to be expected since FSDA are residuals from the cross-sectional Jones model

and, statistically, must add up to zero. ISDA must also add up to zero since SRNDA are

distributed around LRNDA in a similar fashion. Indeed Panel A shows that, on average,

Page 21: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

19

all components of discretionary accruals are approximately zero.11

Nonetheless, Panel A

indicates that discretionary accruals are more volatile than non-discretionary accruals:

TDA have a standard deviation of 9.76% whereas LRNDA have a standard deviation of

5.14%. This finding is also consistent with prior literature (e.g. Xie 2001) and highlights

the ‘discretionary’ nature of TDA. Finally, Panel A shows that most of the variation in

TDA comes from variation in the firm-specific component of discretionary accruals –

FSDA have a standard deviation of 8.85%, whereas ISDA have a standard deviation of

merely 4.10% in comparison.

Panel B in Table 1 shows the (Pearson) correlations among accrual components.

The Panel shows that total accruals are more strongly correlated with discretionary

accruals compared to non-discretionary accruals: the correlation between AC and TDA is

approximately 88%. The Panel also shows that AC and TDA have a high positive

correlation with FSDA (81.4% and 90.7% respectively), which again suggests that firm-

specific discretionary accruals cause most of the fluctuation in total accruals and

discretionary accruals. Additionally, the correlation between SRNDA and LRNDA is

0.753 which, though positive and statistically significant, is less than 1. This suggests that

about 25% of the variation in a firm’s SRNDA occurs due to correlated discretionary

accruals. Finally, Panel B shows a zero correlation between FSDA and ISDA, implying

that industry-wide use of high/low discretionary accruals doesn’t influence firm-level

discretion over accruals.

In Table III we report means and median of accrual component and key firm

characteristics across discretionary accruals decile portfolios. Panel A reports the means

11 FSDA, ISDA and TDA are not exactly equal to zero because the Jones model (equation [5]) does not

include an intercept term.

Page 22: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

20

and medians of these components across TDA decile portfolios. Panel B and Panel C

does the same for FSDA and ISDA decile portfolios respectively. Viewing sample

descriptive statistics in this manner helps highlight the potentially different nature of

firms with extreme discretionary accruals.

Consistent with prior evidence (e.g. Kothari et al. 2006), Table III suggests that

firms with extreme discretionary accruals tend to be relatively small, growth firms with

relatively low accounting performance. For instance Panel A shows that firms in the top

and bottom TDA decile have considerably lower average assets and higher market-to

book ratios compared to firms in other TDA decile portfolios. Additionally, average

earnings (scaled by beginning-of-year assets) in the lowest-TDA and highest-TDA

deciles are -12.06% and -5.80% respectively, both of which are significantly lower than

average earnings in other TDA deciles. Panels B and C suggest that firms with extreme

FSDA and ISDA (respectively) display similar characteristics.

Table III also shows that a large part of firms’ total discretionary accruals are

composed of the firm-specific component. For instance, mean TDA and FSDA in the

lowest-TDA decile are -17.67% and -15.49% respectively, and the mean TDA and FSDA

in the highest-TDA decile are 18.08% and 14.44% respectively. In contrast, mean ISDA

in these lowest- and highest-TDA deciles are only -1.69% in and 3.67% respectively.

Nonetheless, Table III shows that both average FSDA and ISDA increase monotonically

with TDA. Moreover, looking at mean ISDA as a fraction of mean TDA in each decile

suggests that ISDA consistently account for about 10% - 25% of a firm’s total

discretionary accruals.12

In the lowest TDA decile, ISDA account for about 12.28% of

TDA (-2.17/-17.67) while in the highest ISDA decile they account for 20.13% of TDA

12 Computing this ratio using median value of ISDA and TDA reduces the range to about 8% - 15%.

Page 23: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

21

(3.64/18.08). Overall these statistics suggest that ISDA, though small in comparison to

FSDA, form a non-trivial component of a firm’s total discretionary accruals.

Interestingly, both Panel B and Panel C hint towards a non-linear relationship

between FSDA and ISDA. For instance, Panel C shows that while average FSDA steadily

decrease from an average of 0.43% in the lowest-ISDA decile to an average of -1.44% in

the second-highest-ISDA decile, they jump up to an average -0.13% going from the

second-highest to the highest-ISDA decile. Similarly Panel B shows that mean ISDA are

0.51% in the top FSDA decile, and that they decrease monotonically to -0.31% till the

second-highest FSDA decile before increasing sharply to an average of 0.60% in the

highest FSDA decile. Both panels seem to suggest that firms’ use of FSDA is not

insensitive to industry-wide use of discretionary accruals.

To gain further insight into this potential non-linear relationship, we examine the

distribution of firm-years across FSDA decile ranks within each ISDA decile portfolio.

That is, we examine how firm-years are distributed across their respective FSDA decile

rankings conditional on their ISDA ranking. The results from this examination are

reported in Table IV. The top half of the Table shows the percentage of firms-year in

each FSDA (and TDA) decile in the bottom five ISDA deciles while the bottom half of

the table shows these percentages in the top five ISDA deciles. By construction, summing

across FSDA and TDA ranks (respectively) within each ISDA decile equals 100%.

Likewise summing across ISDA deciles for a given FSDA (or TDA) rank also equals

100%.13

Each decile contains approximately 5,500 firm-years.

The results in Table IV display a peculiar interplay between FSDA and ISDA

whereby firms’ use of large FSDA – both income-increasing and income-decreasing–

13 Not all sums add up to exactly 100% due to rounding-off errors.

Page 24: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

22

tends to be particularly high both when ISDA are extremely low and when ISDA are

extremely high. For instance, Table IV shows that in the lowest ISDA decile 13.74% of

firm-years have the lowest FSDA. As ISDA increase this percentage decreases, dropping

to about 7% in ISDA Decile 5. Thereafter however, the percentage of firms with low

FSDA starts to increases steadily with ISDA, reaching its highest of 16.36% in the

highest ISDA decile. A similar pattern is observed with respect to firms’ use of large

income-increasing FSDA. When ISDA are extremely low (ISDA Decile 1), 16.68% of

firm-years have the highest FSDA. This percentage steadily declines to a low of 6.87% in

ISDA Decile 6 and thereafter begins to increase. The greatest increase occurs moving

from the second-highest- to the highest-ISDA decile where the percentage of firms with

the highest FSDA increases from 9.64% to 18.34%, an increase of almost 100%.

The results in Table IV offer a different perspective to the zero correlation

observed between FSDA and ISDA earlier (in Table II). At first blush, Table II suggested

that firm’s use of FSDA is orthogonal to the industry-wide use of discretionary accruals.

If this were true however, then one would have observed a (more or less) uniform

distribution of firm-years across their respective FSDA ranks within each ISDA decile. In

other words, the percentage of firm-years in each FSDA decile rank would have been

roughly 10% within an ISDA decile.14

The results in Table IV show that this is not the

case, and instead suggest a U-shaped relationship whereby extreme ISDA are associated

with an increased tendency by firms to use extreme FSDA.

In the next section we explore the implications of discretionary accruals and its

components towards market returns. Additionally, in light of the descriptive statistics

14 For the same reason, the percentage of firm-years in a fixed FSDA rank across ISDA deciles should have

been roughly 10% as well.

Page 25: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

23

above, we also assess the seemingly differential impact of extreme ISDA on firms’ use of

extreme FSDA in order to gain insight into Sloan’s accrual anomaly.

4.2 The Accruals Anomaly

As a first step, we check whether accruals anomaly exists in our sample. To that

end we compute the abnormal portfolio returns earned by discretionary and (long-run)

non-discretionary accrual decile portfolios. As outlined in Section 3, we calculate these

portfolio returns using the Fama-French three factor model. The results are reported in

Table V. Each column shows the monthly abnormal returns earned by portfolio firms

through years t-3 to t+3 where t represents the time of portfolio formation.15

Table V confirms the presence of accruals anomaly in my sample. Specifically,

Panel A shows that the set of firm-years in the top TDA decile earn an annualized

abnormal return of -3.84% (-0.32% x 12) in year t+1. In contrast, the lowest-TDA decile

does not earn any abnormal returns in the years following portfolio formation. The

finding is consistent with the literature which finds that accruals anomaly is driven by the

mispricing of large, income-increasing discretionary accruals (Beneish and Vargus, 2002)

and suggests that compared to high discretionary accruals, low discretionary accruals are

not manipulative (Kothari et al., 2006). A hedge portfolio short in the highest-TDA

portfolio and long in the lowest-TDA portfolio subsequently earns an annualized

abnormal return of 5.88% (0.49% x 12). This hedge portfolio yields significantly positive

abnormal returns even in the second and third year following portfolio formation.

Moreover, Panel B shows that neither the highest- nor the lowest-LRNDA portfolio earns

15 Accrual anomaly pertains to market returns subsequent to portfolio formation. The reason why we

examine market returns prior to portfolio formation is to consider prior overvaluation as a potential

explanation for the accrual anomaly (Kothari et al. 2006). The details are provided in Section 4.4.

Page 26: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

24

significant abnormal returns subsequent to portfolio formation. This suggests that, like

low discretionary accruals, (long-run) non-discretionary accruals also convey value-

relevant information to investors.

To see how firm-specific and industry-specific discretionary accruals individually

contribute towards this accrual mispricing, we next examine the monthly abnormal

returns earned by FSDA and ISDA decile portfolios. The results are shown in Table VI.

Panel A shows the monthly abnormal returns for FSDA decile portfolios while Panel B

shows the monthly abnormal returns for ISDA decile portfolios.

Panel A shows that firms in the top FSDA decile earn a significantly negative

annualized abnormal return of -3.60% (-0.30% x 12) one year subsequent to portfolio

formation. Like the top TDA decile, the highest-FSDA decile continues to earn negative

abnormal returns in the second and third year following portfolio formation.

Additionally, firms with the lowest FSDA do not earn such abnormal returns. A hedge

portfolio short in the highest-FSDA portfolio and long in the lowest-FSDA portfolio

earns significantly positive annualized abnormal returns of 6.72% (0.56% x 12), 4.20%

(0.35% x 12), and 2.76% (0.23% x 12) in years t+1, t+2, and t+3 respectively. In

contrast, Panel B shows that neither the highest- nor the lowest-ISDA decile earns

significant abnormal returns subsequent to portfolio formation. The finding suggests that

the mispricing of discretionary accruals is driven by the firm-specific component of

discretionary accruals; industry-specific discretionary accruals, on average, convey value-

relevant information to investors and are not manipulative.

4.3 The Role of Industry-Specific Discretionary Accruals

Page 27: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

25

Results from the previous section suggest that the accruals anomaly occurs as a

result of investors mispricing large, income-increasing FSDA. At the same time however,

summary statistics in Table IV suggested that firms’ use of high FSDA varies with

industry-wide use of discretionary accruals. In order to see whether these variations have

implications towards the information content and/or mispricing of large FSDA, we

examine the abnormal returns earned by the highest-FSDA portfolio at varying levels of

ISDA. To do this we divide firms in the top FSDA decile into ten subgroups based on

member firms’ ISDA decile ranking, and then examine the monthly alphas earned by the

resulting portfolios.16

This way the highest-FSDA decile gets subdivided into ten groups

with each group corresponding to firms with a specific ISDA decile ranking.17

Panel A in

Table VII reports the monthly alphas earned by these ISDA-conditioned portfolios. Each

row represents a portfolio with a specific ISDA decile rank. As before the columns show

the monthly alphas of these portfolios from year t-3 to year t+3, where t represent the

year in which the portfolios are formed.

The results in Panel A suggest that the magnitude of ISDA has a direct impact on

the mispricing of high FSDA. In particular Panel A shows that among firms with the

highest FSDA, the subset which has the highest ISDA subsequently earns an annualized

abnormal return of -8.16% (-0.68% x 12). On the other hand, none of the other subgroups

earn such negative abnormal returns. In particular, firms with the highest FSDA but the

16 Arguably, the lowest-FSDA decile warrants a similar subdivision given that firms’ tendency to use low

FSDA also varies with ISDA. Nonetheless, we don’t focus on the lowest-FSDA decile because evidence

suggests that firm use low FSDA to convey value-relevant information to investors. The motivation behind

subdividing the highest-FSDA decile is to see whether the magnitude of ISDA has a differential impact on

the accruals anomaly. 17 Notice that firm-years are not equally distributed across the resulting portfolios. The exact distribution of

firm-years is determined by percentages shown in Table IV. With approximately 5,500 firm-years in each

FSDA decile, Table IV suggests that there are approximately 1,010 firm-years in the highest-FSDA-

highest-ISDA portfolio (18.34% of 5,500), and about 920 firm-years in the highest-FSDA-lowest-ISDA

portfolio (16.68% of 5,500). There are at least 378 firm-years in each of the remaining portfolios.

Page 28: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

26

lowest ISDA do not earn significantly negative abnormal returns the following year.

Moreover, returns earned by the highest-FSDA-highest-ISDA portfolio are considerably

higher than those earned by the unconditioned highest-FSDA portfolio (in Table VI,

Panel A); the difference is both statistically and economically significant. Hence, a hedge

portfolio which shorts firms in the highest-FSDA-highest-ISDA portfolio and takes a

long position in firms with the lowest-FSDA earns an annualized abnormal return of

11.28% (0.92% x 12) one year after portfolio formation. These returns are almost 70%

higher than those earned by the hedge portfolio that shorts the highest-FSDA portfolio

and longs the lowest-FSDA portfolio.

In Panel B, we report the results from repeating the exercise with FSDA and

ISDA quintiles. That is, we first sort firms into quintiles based on their FSDA quintile

ranking, and then subdivide firm-years in the top FSDA quintile based on member firms’

ISDA quintile ranking. We do this to ameliorate the potential concern that subdividing

the highest FSDA decile (i.e. 10% of the entire sample) into ten subgroups leads to “too

few” observations in any one resulting portfolio. Panel B shows that the tenor of results

remains unchanged in response to this modification. In particular, firm-years with the

highest FSDA and highest ISDA (as identified by their respective quintile rankings) still

earn an annualized abnormal return of -4.32% (-0.36% x 12) subsequent to portfolio

formation. In contrast, firms with the highest FSDA do not earn any negative abnormal

returns when their ISDA quintile rankings are lower. Overall, these results suggest that

the accruals anomaly is not merely driven by mispricing of firms with high FSDA but

specifically by the mispricing of those firms whose high FSDA that are accompanied by

high ISDA.

Page 29: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

27

A likely explanation for the above finding is that firms use large FSDA to convey

value-relevant information to investors when most similar firms in the industry have low

discretionary accruals, and to manipulate earnings when most similar firms in the

industry have high discretionary accruals. A possible reason for this asymmetry could be

that firms face greater relative performance evaluation (RPE) concerns when ISDA are

high than when they are low. Research indicates that discretionary accruals tend to be

positively correlated with contemporaneous/lagged firm performance (Healy 1996;

Kothari et al. 2005). Hence it is plausible that high ISDA are associated with unusually

high industry performance and thereby increase firms’ incentive to manipulate earnings

due to RPE concerns (Bagnoli and Watts, 2000; Cohen and Zarowin, 2007) and/or to

meet inflated analyst expectations (Burghstaler and Eames, 2003). In contrast, such

perverse incentives to manipulate earnings are unlikely to exist when industry-specific

discretionary accruals (and hence industry performance) are low. As a result, firms are

more likely to have high FSDA due to value-relevant reasons. The U-shaped relationship

observed between ISDA and firms’ use of high FSDA also supports this view.

Specifically, Table IV shows that for high levels of ISDA the percentage of firms with

high FSDA increases as ISDA increase. This pattern is consistent with industry-wide use

of high discretionary accruals inducing some firms to manipulate earnings upwards.

Moreover, the result also suggests that a likely reason for why investors overprice

high FSDA is that industry-wide use of high discretionary accruals makes it difficult for

them to detect earnings manipulation. When most firms in the industry have high

discretionary accruals, firms whose high discretionary accruals are value-relevant can

camouflage those firms whose high discretionary accruals are manipulative. During such

Page 30: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

28

times, detecting earnings manipulation may be time-consuming and/or associated with

greater information gathering costs. As long as these search costs are reasonably high,

investors may be inclined to price all high discretionary accruals as value-relevant,

including those that are manipulative. Relatedly, it is also plausible that the systematic,

industry-wide use of high discretionary accruals acts as a credible signal to investors that

all firms in the industry have high discretionary accruals for ‘good’ (i.e. value-relevant)

reasons. As a result, investors can end up overpricing firms whose high discretionary

accruals, though manipulative, are ‘reasonable’ given the high discretionary accruals

wave in the industry.

4.5 Discretionary accruals and earnings management

The above interpretation of results suggests that high ISDA have a differential

impact on both the information content and the mispricing of large FSDA. Nonetheless,

an alternative possibility consistent with the findings is that all large income-increasing

FSDA are actually manipulative but that investors price such high FSDA fairly when

concurrent ISDA are low. In other words, it is possible that industry-wide use of high

discretionary accruals only impacts investors’ ability to price large FSDA fairly, and not

necessarily the information content of high FSDA. This possibility is perfectly consistent

with the (potential) explanation forwarded above for why investors misprice high FSDA.

When most firms in the industry have high discretionary accruals, investors may face

high search costs to distinguish between value-relevant and manipulative large FSDA,

and may also have ‘good’ reason to be credulous of earnings manipulation. In contrast,

firms with high (manipulative) FSDA are likely to be more conspicuous when most firms

Page 31: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

29

in the industry have low discretionary accruals, making it easier for investors to detect

earnings manipulation. This notion is consistent with Coles, Hertzel and Kalpathy (2006)

who find that investors are able to see through earnings manipulation in more transparent

settings.18

In order to reflect on this possibility, we examine the abnormal returns earned by

portfolio firms prior to portfolio formation. These pre portfolio formation returns are

reported in Tables V through VII. Kothari et al. (2006) have shown that compared to

firms with low discretionary accruals, firms with high discretionary accruals experience

significantly positive risk-adjusted returns in the year(s) leading up to portfolio

formation. The authors cite this as evidence in support of Jensen’s (2005) agency costs of

overvalued equity as an explanation for the accruals anomaly. Specifically, the authors

argue that firms use high discretionary accruals to manipulate earnings (upwards) in order

to sustain their prior overvaluation, and that the subsequent negative returns experienced

by these firms reflects the correction of this overvaluation.

If Kothari et al.’s argument is true, then to the extent that high FSDA are

manipulative only when concurrent ISDA are high as well, one should expect the highest-

FSDA-highest-ISDA portfolio to exhibit signs of significant overvaluation prior to

portfolio formation. In contrast, firms with high FSDA but relatively low ISDA should

not display such signs of prior overvaluation since their high FSDA convey value

relevant information to investors. On the other hand, if ISDA do not have a differential

18 Revisiting the results in Table IV also offers some perspective to this argument. The table shows that more than one-third (35.61%) of the firms have the highest TDA in the highest ISDA decile. It seems likely

that the set of firms with the highest FSDA (about 18%) is less likely to be scrutinized by investors in such

a case. In contrast, the percentage of firms with the highest TDA is less than 6% in the lowest ISDA decile.

In this case, firms with high FSDA (about 16%) are likely to be relatively more conspicuous and hence

more susceptible to investors’ scrutiny.

Page 32: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

30

impact on the information content of large FSDA, then one should expect all firms with

high FSDA to be significantly overvalued prior to portfolio formation, regardless of the

magnitude of concurrent ISDA.

In Table VII, both Panel A and Panel B show that in year t-1 all firms with the

highest FSDA earn significantly positive abnormal returns regardless of the magnitude of

concurrent ISDA. In particular, Panel A shows that the highest-FSDA-highest-ISDA

portfolio earns an annualized return of 19.44% (1.62% x 12) whereas the highest-FSDA-

lowest-ISDA portfolio earns an annualized abnormal return of 11.04% (0.92% x 12) in

the year preceding portfolio formation. Panel B shows very similar results with respect to

FSDA-ISDA quintile portfolios. Notably, the highest-FSDA-highest-ISDA portfolio

exhibits signs of greater overvaluation compared to firms in the highest-FSDA-lowest-

ISDA portfolio: the difference between the two portfolios’ abnormal returns is both

statistically and economically significant in all three years prior to formation.

Nonetheless, to the extent that prior overvaluation is not specific to the highest-FSDA-

highest-ISDA decile, the results seem to suggest that all firms with high FSDA consist of

overvalued firms who have an incentive to manipulate earnings.

Although the above results seem to undermine the possibility that high FSDA are

value-relevant when ISDA are low, it is worth bearing in mind that the above

interpretation of pre portfolio-formation returns strictly depends on the extent to which

prior overvaluation is indicative of earnings manipulation! In other words, the

interpretation assumes that Kothari et al.’s claim is correct and that negative post-

portfolio formation returns are only experienced by firms which are significantly

overvalued and have incentive to manipulate earnings.

Page 33: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

31

To assess the validity of this claim we also examine pre-portfolio formation

returns in Tables V and VI. Panel A in Table V shows that compared to firms with the

lowest TDA, firms with the highest TDA experience significantly positive abnormal

returns in the three years leading up to portfolio formation. In the year immediately

preceding portfolio formation, the highest TDA portfolio earns an annualized alpha of

15.85% (1.32% x 12); in contrast, the lowest-TDA portfolio earns no such abnormal

returns. Similarly, Panel A in Table VI shows that where the highest FSDA portfolio

earns an annualized risk-adjusted return of 15.26% (1.28% x 12), the lowest FSDA

portfolio does not earn positive abnormal returns prior to portfolio formation. These

results are similar to those found by Kothari et al. and seem to lend support to their

argument that firms with high discretionary accruals consist of earnings manipulators

looking to sustain their prior overvaluation. By the same token, low discretionary

accruals convey value-relevant information to investors.

Nonetheless, an examination of pre-portfolio formation returns in Panel B of

Table V and Table VI undermine agency costs of overvalued equity as an (only)

explanation for the accruals anomaly. Specifically Panel B in Table V shows that even

firms with the highest LRNDA experience significantly positive abnormal returns in the

three years prior to portfolio formation.19

Interestingly, in terms of magnitude firms with

the highest LRNDA experience higher positive returns prior to portfolio formation

compared to firms with the highest TDA and firms with the highest FSDA.20

Kothari et

al.’s argument would suggest that the highest-LRNDA portfolio comprises of firms that

have incentives to manipulate earnings upwards to sustain this overvaluation. This seems

19 In their paper, Kothari et al. (2006) only report the monthly abnormal returns earned by firms sorted into

total and discretionary accrual portfolios, and not for firms sorted into non-discretionary accrual portfolios. 20 In untabulated results we find the difference to be both statistically and economically significant.

Page 34: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

32

unlikely given that LRNDA capture the component of discretionary accruals that is less

susceptible to earnings manipulation and more likely to contain value-relevant

information. Indeed, the fact that highest LRNDA portfolio does not experience negative

abnormal returns subsequent to portfolio formation casts doubt on agency costs of

overvalued equity as the only explanation for the accruals anomaly.2122

Similarly, Panel B in Table VI shows that the highest-ISDA portfolio experiences

significantly positive abnormal returns in the three years leading up to portfolio

formation. The fact that this portfolio also does not experience negative returns

subsequent to portfolio formation suggests that prior overvaluation is not necessarily

suggestive of earnings manipulation. By extension, the evidence suggests that it is likely

that firms use high FSDA to convey value-relevant relevant information to investors

when their concurrent ISDA are low – the fact that these firms show signs of prior

overvaluation is not necessarily indicative of their high FSDA being manipulative.

4.6 Robustness Checks

In this paper we have used the performance-adjusted modified Jones (1991)

model to estimate the various components of discretionary accruals. One potential

problem with this specification is that it causes all the effect of a change in accounts

receivable to be placed in discretionary accruals. As a result, the model is likely to

overestimate discretionary accruals for firms experiencing high sales growth and

21 In their paper, Kothari et al. (2006) use SRNDA as a proxy for non-discretionary accruals. In untabulated results, we find that the highest-SRNDA portfolio exhibits similar signs of prior overvaluation. 22 Of course, the argument assumes that cross-sectional Jones model do a good job at measuring non-

discretionary accruals. In that respect, we take the efficacy of Jones model as a given. Moreover, the fact

that Kothari et al. (2006) use a similar specification to measure discretionary and non-discretionary accruals

allows a meaningful comparison of our results with theirs.

Page 35: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

33

underestimate them for firms with poor performance (Coles et al. 2006). Although

including return on assets as an additional regressor in the model is likely to ameliorate

this problem to a certain extent, we nonetheless repeat all our tests using the standard

Jones (1991) model, i.e. one in which change in revenue is not computed net of change in

accounts receivables.23

Additionally, to draw parallel with most prior literature we also

redo all our tests using the modified Jones model without lagged ROA as an additional

regressor (Dechow et al., 1995; Kothari et al., 2006). The tenor of our main results

remains unchanged in response to these specifications. Specifically, Panel A in Table

VIII shows that using the standard Jones model does not influence the finding that

accruals anomaly is driven by the mispricing of firms whose high FSDA are

accompanied by high ISDA. Panel B shows that using Dechow et al.’s modified Jones

model (without adjustment for firm performance) also yields similar results.

Another potential concern with the findings of this paper is that they are based on

the balance sheet measure of current accruals. Collins and Hribar (2002) have argued that

this balance sheet approach is prone to measurement error and instead recommend using

cash flow from operations (as determined under SFAS 95) to calculate accruals. For

robustness we replicate our tests using this alternative measure of accruals and find

qualitatively similar results.24

In particular, mispricing of high FSDA continues to be

23 In the standard Jones model, total accruals are regressed on change in sales and gross PP&E. That is, the

model does not adjust for the effect of performance on discretionary accruals. 24

As in Xie (2001), we measure accruals using the cash flow method as the difference between income

before extraordinary items (COMPUSTAT item IB) and cash flows. We measure cash flow as net cash flow from operating activities (COMPUSTAT item OANCF). For fiscal years prior to 1988, we measure

cash flow as the difference between fund flow from operations (COMPUSTAT item FOPT) and the

difference between change in current assets (COMPUSTAT item ACT) net of cash and cash equivalents

(COMPUSTAT item CHE) and change in current liabilities (COMPUSTAT item LCT) net of debt in

current liabilities (COMPUSTAT item DLC).

Page 36: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

34

driven by the subset with high ISDA. These results are not reported for the sake of

brevity.

The mispricing of accruals is a joint test of market efficiency and the

appropriateness of the asset pricing model (Subramanyam, 1996). Hence one may argue

that there is potentially a risk-based explanation for the findings of this paper. While

recent evidence casts doubt on risk-based explanations for the accrual anomaly (e.g.

Hirshleifer, Hou and Teoh 2012), for robustness we replicate our main tests using the

four-factor model which enhances Fama-French three factor model by including

‘momentum’ as an additional risk factor (Jegadeesh and Titman 1993).

The monthly alphas obtained from estimating the four-factor model are shown in

Table IX. Panel A shows these alphas for bottom, middle, and bottom FSDA deciles.

Panel B reports alphas for the set of top-FSDA decile firms which lie in the bottom,

middle, and top ISDA deciles respectively. Finally Panel C reports alphas for the set of

firms in the top-FSDA quintile which lie in the bottom, middle, and top ISDA quintiles

respectively. In the spirit of Mashruwala et al. (2006), we estimate the four factor model

using firm-years with fiscal year-end prior to 1997.25

The results in Table IX suggest that the main conclusions of the paper remain

unchanged even after controlling for momentum. Specifically, while Panel A shows that

firms in the top FSDA decile earn significantly negative abnormal returns subsequent to

portfolio formation, Panel B shows that these negative returns are primarily driven by the

25 Mashruwala et al., (2006) show that for the sample of firms between 1976 and 2001, the momentum factor considerably reduces the magnitude and significance of Jensen’s alphas of firms with high

discretionary accruals. The authors attribute this result (in part) to the technology-stocks related bull market

of the late 1990s. Upon confining their sample to firms between 1976 and 1997, the authors find that the

statistical significance of negative alphas following high discretionary accruals is restored. The authors thus

conclude that accrual anomaly is robust to momentum.

Page 37: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

35

mispricing of those firms whose high FSDA are accompanied by high ISDA. Panel C

reports similar results with respect to FSDA and ISDA quintiles.26

5. Conclusion

In this paper we augment the cross-sectional Jones (1991) model to define and

decompose discretionary accruals into a firm-specific and an industry-specific

component. Many studies have employed variants of the Jones model to measure

discretionary accruals, particularly in the study of earnings management. Nonetheless,

several academics have suggested that there are industry trends beyond those captured by

these models which can influence the use and information content of discretionary

accruals broadly across all firm in the industry. The accruals decomposition motivated in

this paper specifically addresses this concern by explicitly measuring the industry-

specific component of discretionary accruals. This allows for a more incisive examination

of the information content and manipulability of accruals, their role in price discovery,

and the source of accruals anomaly.

My findings indicate that the accruals anomaly is driven by the firm-specific

component of discretionary accruals, and that industry-specific discretionary accruals, on

average, convey value-relevant information to investors. More importantly, we find that

firms with high firm-specific discretionary accruals are overpriced specifically when

industry-specific discretionary accruals are high as well. The evidence suggests that firms

use high (firm-specific) discretionary accruals to manipulate earnings primarily when

26 Interestingly, both Panel B and Panel C show that while momentum reduces the significance of pre-

portfolio formation returns earned by the highest-FSDA-lowest-ISDA portfolio, it does not do reduce the

significance of pre portfolio-formation returns earned by the high-FSDA-high-ISDA firms. The evidence

bolsters the argument that high FSDA accompanied by low ISDA are likely to be value-relevant.

Page 38: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

36

most firms in the industry also have high discretionary accruals and that investors

overlook or fail to detect this earnings manipulation.

Prior literature has offered several explanations for why the accruals anomaly

occurs. The findings of this paper suggest that an additional (though not necessarily

mutually exclusive) explanation could be that industry-wide use of high discretionary

accruals increases the search costs that investors have to incur in order to detect earning

manipulation. When most firms in the industry have high discretionary accruals due to

value-relevant reason, they can camouflage those firms whose high discretionary accruals

are manipulative. As a result investors can face difficulty distinguishing between the two

types of firms. At the same time, the systematic use of high discretionary accruals can act

as a credible signal to investors that firms have high discretionary accruals for value-

relevant reasons. This can increase investors’ tolerance for high discretionary accruals

and can hence cause them to be credulous of those discretionary accruals that are

manipulative.

The results of the paper are at odds with most prior earnings management

literature which has classified all firms with high discretionary accruals as potential

earnings manipulators. The finding that firms with the highest-FSDA earn negative

abnormal returns only when concurrent ISDA are high suggests that when most firms in

the industry have low discretionary accruals, firms use high (firm-specific) discretionary

accruals to convey value-relevant information to investors. If true, the implication

potentially has an important bearing on the earnings management literature which has

unconditionally used high (firm-specific) discretionary accruals to proxy for earnings

manipulation. The fact that some academics have found large discretionary accruals to be

Page 39: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

37

a poor predictor of actual cases of fraud and earnings manipulation (e.g. Badertscher et

al. 2012) also suggests that at least some firms use such discretionary accruals for value-

relevant purposes.

Overall, the paper suggests that industry-specific discretionary accruals

(indirectly) help the accruals anomaly. In doing so, the paper identifies several lines of

inquiry for future research. For instance, although the results are consistent with industry-

wide use of high discretionary accruals having a differential impact on the information

content of high (firm-specific) discretionary accruals, an alternative possibility is that all

high FSDA are manipulative but that investors are able to detect this manipulation when

most firms in the industry have low discretionary accruals. we find some evidence which

suggests that the latter possibility is unlikely. Nonetheless, the evidence is not conclusive

and warrants further investigation. Relatedly, it is also not clear why firms would have an

increased incentive to manipulate earnings when most firms in the industry have high

discretionary accruals. One possibility is that managers’ RPE concerns are higher during

such times. Another possibility is that firms internalize investors’ (potentially) decreased

ability and/or incentives to detect earnings manipulation when industry-specific

discretionary accruals are high, and hence manipulate earnings because of a greater

likelihood that such manipulation will go unnoticed by investors. It is also possible that

high industry-specific discretionary accruals are correlated with other variable(s) that

induce earnings manipulation. More research is needed to understand why, if at all, firms

use manipulative discretionary accruals specifically when most firms in the industry also

have high discretionary accruals.

Page 40: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

38

Moreover, a deeper understanding is required of factors that result in investors’

failure to detect earnings manipulation. Regardless of whether or not high ISDA have a

differential impact on the information content of high FSDA, results suggest that they do

have a differential impact on the pricing of high FSDA. While a likely explanation for

this mispricing is that investors face increased search costs to detect manipulation during

these times, further research is required to establish the validity of this claim and also to

shed light on the nature of these search costs. Additionally, a related possibility is that

high industry-specific discretionary accruals increase investors’ tendency to be credulous

of earnings manipulation. In this respect, future research can look into whether industry-

wide use of high discretionary accruals increases investors’ tendency to ‘fixate’ on

earnings. High industry-specific discretionary accruals could also be related to low

industry-wide discount rates (Wu et al., 2010), in which case the differential impact of

high ISDA on the mispricing of high FSDA could have a more ‘rational’ explanation.

Finally, the accruals decomposition developed in this paper can be used to revisit

and reflect on prior literature on the accruals anomaly and earnings management. The

scope of this paper is limited in that it only applies the accruals decomposition to address

the original anomaly documented by Sloan. We leave it for future research to examine

the role of industry-specific discretionary accruals (if any) in identifying earnings

manipulation and in explaining anomalous capital market outcomes in other settings.

Page 41: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

39

References

Anwer S. Ahmed, S. M. Khalid Nainar, and Jian Zhou. 2005. Do analysts’ earnings

forecasts fully reflect the information in accruals? Canadian Journal of

Administrative Science, 22 (4), 329-342.

Badertscher, B., Collins, D., Lys, T., 2012. Discretionary accounting choices and the

predictive ability of accruals with respect to future cash flows. Journal of Accounting

and Economics, 53(1-2), 330-352

Bagnoli, M., Watts, S., 2000. The effect of relative performance evaluation on earnings

management: a game-theoretic approach. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 19,

377-397.

Bartov, E., Gul, F., Tsui, J., 2000. Discretionary accruals models and audit qualifications.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30, 421-452.

Beneish, M., Vargus, M., 2002. Insider trading, earnings quality and accrual mispricing.

The Accounting Review, 77 (4), 755-791.

Bergstresser, D., Phillipon, T., 2006. CEO incentives and earnings management. Journal

of Financial Economics, 80 (3), 511-529.

Bradshaw, M., Richardson, S., Sloan, R., 2001. Do analysts and auditors use information

in accruals? Journal of Accounting Research, 39, 45-74.

Burgstahler, D., Eames, M.J., 2003. Earnings management to avoid losses and earnings

decreases: Are analysts fooled? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24(1), 99-126.

Cheng, I., 2011. Corporate governance spillovers. Working paper, University of

Michigan, Ross School of Business. Available at SSRN:

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1299652

Cohen, D.A., Zarowin, P., 2007. Earnings management over the business cycle. Working

paper, New York University. Available online:

http://w4.stern.nyu.edu/emplibrary/EM_08_23_07FINAL.pdf

Coles, J., Hertzel, M., Kalpathy, S., 2006. Earnings management around employee stock

option reissues. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 41(1-2), 173-200.

Collins, D., Hribar, P., 2002. Errors in estimating accruals: Implications for empirical

research. Journal of Accounting Research, 40 (1), 105-134.

Cornett, M., Marcus, A., Tehranian, H., 2008. Corporate governance and pay-for-

performance. The impact of earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics,

87 (2), 357-373.

Dechow, P., 1994. Accounting earnings and cash flows as measures of firm performance:

The role of accounting accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 18, 3-42.

Dechow, P., Khimich, N., Sloan, R., 2011. The accrual anomaly. Working Paper.

Available at SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1793364

Dechow, P., Sloan, R., Sweeney, A., 1995. Detecting Earnings Management. The

Accounting Review, 70, 193-225.

Desai, H., Rajgopal, S., Venkatachalam, M., 2004. Value-glamour and accrual

mispricing: One anomaly or two. The Accounting Review, 79, 355-385.

Fairfield, P., Whisenant, S., Yohn, T., 2003. Accrued earnings and growth: Implication

for future profitability and market mispricing. The Accounting Review, 78, 353-371.

Fama, E., French, K., 1993. Common risk factors in returns on stocks and bonds. Journal

of Financial Economics, 33 (1), 3-56.

Page 42: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

40

Healy, P., 1996. Discussion of market-based evaluation of discretionary accrual models.

Journal of Accounting Research, 34 (3), 107-115.

Hirshleifer, D., Hou, K., Teoh, S., 2012. The Accrual Anomaly: Risk or Mispricing?

Management Science, 58(2), 320-335.

Jegadeesh, N., Titman, S., 1993. Returns to buying winners and selling losers:

Implications for stock market efficiency. Journal of Finance, 48, 65-91.

Jensen, M., 2005. Agency costs of overvalued equity. Financial Management, 34, 5-19.

Jeter, D., Shivakumar, L., 1999. Cross-sectional estimation of abnormal accruals using

quarterly and annual data. Effectiveness in detecting event-specific earnings

management. Accounting and Business Research, 29 (4), 299-319.

Jiao, T., Mertens, G., Roosenboom, P., 2007. Industry-valuation driven earnings

management. Working paper, ERASMUS University, ERASMUS Research Institute

of Management.

Jones, J., 1991. Earnings management during import relief investigations. Journal of

Accounting Research, 29, 193-228.

Kang, Q., Liu. Q., Qi, R., 2010. Predicting stock market returns with aggregate

discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting Research, 48(4), 815-858.

Kasanen, E., Kinnunen, J., Niskanen, J., 1996. Dividend-based earnings management:

Empirical evidence from Finland. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 22, 283-312.

Kothari, S., Leone, A., Wasley, C., 2005. Performance-matched discretionary accrual

measures. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39, 163-197.

Kothari, S., Loutskina, E., Nikolaev, V., 2006. Agency theory of overvalued equity as an

explanation for the accrual anomaly. CentER Discussion Paper Series No. 2006-103.

Available at SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=871750

Lev, B., and Nissim, D., 2006. The persistence of the accruals anomaly. Contemporary

Accounting Research, 23(1), 193-226.

Mashruwala, C., Rajgopal, S., Shevlin, T., 2006. Why is the accrual anomaly not

arbitraged away? The role of idiosyncratic risk and transaction costs. Journal of

Accounting and Economics, 42 (1-2), 3-33.

McNichols, M.F., 2000. Research design issues in earnings management studies. Journal

of Accounting and Public Policy, 19, 313-345

Park, M., 1999. Industry earnings performance and firms’ accrual decisions. Working

paper, Purdue University.

Rangan. S., 1998. Earnings management and the performance of seasoned equity

offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 50 (1), 101-122.

Rhodes-Kropf, M., Robinson, D., Viswanathan. S., 2005.Valuation waves and merger

activity: The empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 77 (3), 561-603.

Ronen, J., Yaari, V., 2008. Earnings management: Emerging insights in theory, practice

and research. Springer Series in Accounting Scholarship.

Sloan, R., 1996. Do stock prices fully reflect the information in accruals and cash flows

about future earnings? Accounting Review, 71, 289-316.

Subramanyam, K.., 1996. The pricing of discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting

and Economics, 22 (1-3), 249-281.

Teoh, S., Welch, I., Wong, T., 1998a. Earnings management and the long-run

underperformance of seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 50,

63-100.

Page 43: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

41

Teoh, S., Welch, I., Wong, T., 1998b. Earnings management and the long-run

underperformance of initial public offerings. Journal of Finance, 53, 1935-1974.

Teoh, S., Wong, T., 2002. Why new issues and high-accrual firms underperform: The

role of analysts’ credulity. Review of Financial Studies, 15 (3), 869-900.

Wu, J., Zhang, L., Zhang, X., 2010. The q-theory approach to understanding the accrual

anomaly. Journal of Accounting Research, 48(1), 177-222.

Xie, H., 2001. The mispricing of abnormal accruals. The Accounting Review, 76, 357-

373.

Page 44: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

42

Table I

Descriptive Statistics of Jones Model Parameter Estimates across Industries The table presents the descriptive statistics of parameter estimates obtained from estimating the performance-adjusted cross-sectional modified Jones (1991) model expressed in equation

[5]. The model is estimated at the industry level using 2-digit SIC codes to classify firm-years into industries. Col 1 shows the descriptive statistics of (coefficient on

), Col 2 shows the summary statistics of (coefficient on PPE) and Col 3 shows the summary statistics of (coefficient on NI). P25 and P75 refer to the 25th percentile and 75th

percentile respectively. Std. refers to the standard deviation. The regression is estimated yearly for all US firms that are present on the COMPUSTAT and CRSP monthly returns file between 1970 and 2006 that do not correspond to financials or utilities, have fiscal year-end in December (FYR = 12), have shares corresponding to common equity, and have non-

missing data for accruals, and its discretionary and non-discretionary accrual components. All continuous variables are Winsorized at 1% and 99%.

Industry

Col 1

Change in Sales - Change in Receivables

Col 2

Gross Property, Plant and Equipment

Col 3

Lag Net Income

Mean Median P25 P75 Std. Mean Median P25 P75 Std. Mean Median P25 P75 Std.

Amuse. & Recreation -0.129 -0.112 -0.269 0.010 0.204 -0.059 -0.055 -0.067 -0.043 0.018 0.076 0.024 -0.087 0.278 0.234

Apparel & Other Text. 0.113 0.124 0.018 0.209 0.150 -0.070 -0.091 -0.131 -0.004 0.103 0.191 0.309 -0.100 0.487 0.382

Business Services 0.079 0.073 0.026 0.114 0.086 -0.107 -0.095 -0.123 -0.078 0.043 0.070 0.069 0.009 0.123 0.134

Chemicals 0.075 0.080 0.015 0.119 0.077 -0.059 -0.060 -0.070 -0.049 0.017 0.109 0.074 0.026 0.148 0.133

Communication -0.020 -0.045 -0.081 0.042 0.116 -0.078 -0.079 -0.094 -0.059 0.022 0.059 0.073 -0.039 0.128 0.147

Eating & Drinking -0.036 -0.039 -0.080 -0.015 0.075 -0.067 -0.067 -0.079 -0.052 0.018 0.017 0.049 -0.115 0.104 0.153

Electronic Equipment 0.160 0.164 0.129 0.199 0.073 -0.086 -0.088 -0.110 -0.068 0.034 0.155 0.113 0.075 0.201 0.139

Engineering Services 0.026 0.034 -0.020 0.073 0.077 -0.080 -0.079 -0.113 -0.044 0.044 0.080 0.050 -0.031 0.166 0.145

Fabricated Metal Prod. 0.133 0.138 0.093 0.173 0.071 -0.069 -0.070 -0.086 -0.047 0.026 0.208 0.208 0.046 0.329 0.228

Food & Kindred Prod. 0.075 0.055 0.042 0.129 0.075 -0.057 -0.062 -0.072 -0.048 0.020 0.041 0.036 -0.058 0.191 0.199

Food Stores 0.022 0.005 0.021 0.041 0.075 -0.074 -0.074 -0.086 -0.062 0.027 0.080 0.106 -0.040 0.214 0.190

Furniture & Fixtures 0.038 0.040 -0.071 0.164 0.158 -0.082 -0.087 -0.122 -0.029 0.067 0.240 0.253 0.022 0.530 0.439

Gen. Build. Contractors 0.048 0.042 0.014 0.071 0.140 -0.070 -0.060 -0.092 -0.033 0.054 0.238 0.276 -0.071 0.555 0.583

Health Services 0.044 0.009 -0.058 0.102 0.151 -0.080 -0.083 -0.107 -0.047 0.039 0.087 0.076 0.008 0.128 0.137

Hotels& Other Lodging -0.054 -0.020 -0.140 0.097 0.217 -0.052 -0.054 -0.061 -0.042 0.022 0.085 0.046 -0.084 0.289 0.312

Industrial Machinery 0.132 0.137 0.096 0.174 0.060 -0.069 -0.071 -0.088 -0.055 0.033 0.174 0.147 0.071 0.234 0.141

Instruments 0.142 0.155 0.095 0.189 0.063 -0.072 -0.075 -0.088 -0.059 0.026 0.214 0.118 0.044 0.335 0.240

Leather & Leather Prod. 0.171 0.196 0.046 0.279 0.129 -0.054 -0.132 -0.171 0.042 0.216 -0.078 -0.108 -0.338 0.326 0.495

Lumber Products 0.018 0.033 -0.066 0.115 0.163 -0.070 -0.073 -0.096 -0.049 0.045 0.231 0.232 -0.039 0.485 0.481

Metal Mining 0.002 0.030 -0.116 0.135 0.227 -0.042 -0.052 -0.070 -0.015 0.045 0.045 0.045 -0.146 0.193 0.262

Misc. Retail 0.044 0.082 -0.051 0.126 0.133 -0.068 -0.073 -0.113 -0.043 0.090 0.126 0.101 -0.033 0.365 0.349

Misc. Manufacturing 0.167 0.162 0.097 0.252 0.171 -0.075 -0.078 -0.125 -0.047 0.062 0.181 0.156 0.051 0.316 0.251

Page 45: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

43

Table I (cont.)

Industry

Col 1

Change in Sales - Change in Receivables

Col 2

Gross Property, Plant and Equipment

Col 3

Lagged Net Income

Mean Median P25 P75 Std. Mean Median P25 P75 Std. Mean Median P25 P75 Std.

Oil and Gas Extract 0.006 0.018 -0.093 0.094 0.121 -0.069 -0.072 -0.076 -0.059 0.016 -0.008 0.001 -0.058 0.084 0.134

Paper and Allied Prod. 0.077 0.069 0.023 0.164 0.133 -0.053 -0.053 -0.063 -0.042 0.017 0.043 0.041 -0.093 0.145 0.250

Petroleum and Coal 0.034 0.038 -0.005 0.088 0.083 -0.059 -0.062 -0.069 -0.047 0.015 0.104 0.090 -0.000 0.212 0.293

Primary Metal 0.134 0.128 0.081 0.201 0.085 -0.043 -0.042 -0.051 -0.034 0.014 0.074 0.080 -0.062 0.195 0.222

Printing & Publishing 0.106 0.103 0.034 0.188 0.128 -0.083 -0.077 -0.111 -0.060 0.037 0.071 0.109 -0.085 0.220 0.203

Railroad Transportation -0.105 -0.089 -0.202 0.040 0.240 -0.030 -0.030 -0.041 -0.022 0.019 0.160 0.070 -0.103 0.317 0.527

Rubber and Misc. Prod. 0.114 0.122 0.024 0.204 0.122 -0.066 -0.067 -0.081 -0.050 0.027 0.059 0.025 -0.097 0.139 0.213

Stone, Clay & Glass 0.116 0.099 0.031 0.187 0.134 -0.050 -0.049 -0.062 -0.042 0.029 0.060 0.055 -0.073 0.186 0.217

Textile Mill Prod. 0.099 0.153 0.005 0.174 0.123 -0.056 -0.065 -0.081 -0.037 0.056 0.303 0.178 0.084 0.349 0.471

Transportation Equip. 0.113 0.126 0.064 0.168 0.073 -0.073 -0.072 -0.088 -0.053 0.030 0.169 0.168 -0.006 0.283 0.221

Transportation By Air -0.077 -0.068 -0.142 0.001 0.127 -0.070 -0.069 -0.087 -0.060 0.024 0.150 0.093 -0.015 0.363 0.276

Trucking & Warehouse 0.058 0.054 0.012 0.108 0.088 -0.095 -0.103 -0.110 -0.079 0.020 0.004 -0.007 -0.096 0.103 0.195

Water Transportation 0.039 0.004 -0.109 0.141 0.214 -0.052 -0.048 -0.063 -0.037 0.021 0.093 -0.023 -0.150 0.127 0.426

Wholesale – Durable 0.145 0.131 0.103 0.168 0.065 -0.081 -0.083 -0.117 -0.051 0.048 0.230 0.199 0.097 0.375 0.247

Wholesale – Nondurable 0.062 0.069 0.028 0.098 0.053 -0.071 -0.068 -0.093 -0.044 0.037 0.110 0.129 -0.022 0.277 0.284

Page 46: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

44

Table II

Descriptive Statistics and Correlations of Accrual Components and Key Firm Characteristics The table presents the descriptive statistics [Panel A] and Pearson correlations [Panel B] of accrual components and key firm characteristics

for the sample of firms between 1970 and 2006. Accruals (AC) are calculated using the balance sheet approach as difference between non-

cash current assets and change in current liabilities (exclusive of short-term debt and taxes payable), less depreciation expense, all divided by

lagged assets. Firm-specific discretionary accruals (FSDA) are residuals obtained from estimating the performance-adjusted cross-sectional

Jones model presented in equation [5]. Short-run non-discretionary accruals (SRNDA) are estimated using equation [6] and long-run non-

discretionary accruals (LRNDA) are calculated using equation [7]. Total discretionary accruals (TDA) are calculated as the difference between accruals AC and LRNDA. Industry-specific discretionary accruals (ISDA) are calculated as the difference between SRNDA and

LRNDA. Earnings (EARN) are defined as operating income after depreciation, divided by lagged assets. Cash flow (CFO) is the difference

between EARN and AC. In Panel A the descriptive statistics of AC, SRNDA, LRNDA, TDA, FSDA, ISDA, CFO and EARN are all reported

as percentage of lagged assets. Market-Book ratio is calculated as the sum of assets and fiscal year-end market capitalization, less common

equity and deferred taxes, divided by assets. The sample consists of all US firms that are present on the COMPUSTAT and CRSP monthly

returns file between 1970 and 2006 that do not correspond to financials or utilities, have fiscal year-end in December (FYR = 12), have shares

corresponding to common equity, and have non-missing data for accruals, and its discretionary and non-discretionary accrual components.

All continuous variables are Winsorized at 1% and 99%.

Panel A: Descriptive Statistics

Obs. Mean Median Min. Max. Deviation

AC 55,208 -3.81 -4.17 -38.45 35.23 10.65

SRNDA 55,208 -3.34 -3.19 -41.13 41.16 6.19

LRNDA 55,208 -3.52 -3.28 -48.18 25.51 5.14

TDA 55,208 -0.29 -0.34 -57.87 68.69 9.76

FSDA 55,208 -0.47 -0.37 -51.54 56.66 8.85

ISDA 55,208 0.18 -0.04 -39.17 59.82 4.10

CFO 55,208 2.63 7.29 -107.20 39.08 21.66

EARN 55,208 -1.07 4.21 -111.88 30.31 21.30

Assets (000s) 55,208 1,182.86 127.14 2.12 25,199 3,553.68

Market-Book 53,309 1.77 1.26 0.53 9.57 1.49

Panel B: Pearson Correlation Coefficients

AC SRNDA LRNDA TDA FSDA ISDA CFO EARN

AC 0.557*** 0.408*** 0.877*** 0.814*** 0.331*** -0.254*** 0.261***

SRNDA

0.753*** 0.212*** -0.029*** 0.567*** -0.036*** 0.261***

LRNDA

-0.082*** -0.037*** -0.115*** 0.181*** 0.399***

TDA

0.907*** 0.422*** -0.373*** 0.074***

FSDA

0.002 -0.281*** 0.131***

ISDA

-0.281*** -0.105***

CFO

0.843***

EARN

Page 47: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

45

Table III

Summary Statistics of Accrual Components and Key Firm Characteristics Across Discretionary Accrual

Decile Portfolios The table presents the mean (median) values of discretionary accrual components and key firm characteristics for the sample of firms

between 1970 and 2006. Panel A reports statistics across total discretionary accruals (TDA) decile portfolios, while Panel B and Panel C

reports the statistics for firm-specific discretionary accruals (FSDA) and industry-specific discretionary accruals decile (ISDA) portfolios

respectively. Firm-specific discretionary accruals (FSDA) are residuals obtained from estimating the performance-adjusted cross-sectional

Jones model presented in equation [5]. Short-run non-discretionary accruals (SRNDA) are estimated using equation [6] and long-run non-

discretionary accruals (LRNDA) are calculated using equation [7]. Total discretionary accruals (TDA) are calculated as the difference

between accruals AC and LRNDA. Industry-specific discretionary accruals (ISDA) are calculated as the difference between SRNDA and

LRNDA. Earnings (EARN) are defined as operating income after depreciation, divided by lagged assets. Cash flow (CFO) is the difference

between EARN and accruals. Accruals (AC) are calculated using the balance sheet approach as difference between non-cash current assets

and change in current liabilities (exclusive of short-term debt and taxes payable), less depreciation expense, all divided by lagged assets. All

descriptive statistics are reported as percentage of lagged assets. Market-Book ratio is calculated as the sum of assets and fiscal year-end

market capitalization, less common equity and deferred taxes, divided by assets. The sample consists of all US firms that are present on the COMPUSTAT and CRSP monthly returns file between 1970 and 2006 that do not correspond to financials or utilities, have fiscal year-end in

December (FYR = 12), have shares corresponding to common equity, and have non-missing data for accruals, and its discretionary and non-

discretionary accrual components. All continuous variables are Winsorized at 1% and 99%.

Panel A: Total Discretionary Accrual (TDA) Decile Portfolios

Lowest

Decile 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Highest

Decile

TDA

-17.67 -7.74 -4.56 -2.62 -1.10 0.29 1.78 3.69 6.91 18.08

(-15.74) (-7.62) (-4.53) (-2.65) (-1.11) (0.26) (1.75) (3.64) (6.74) (15.13)

FSDA -15.49 -7.00 -4.05 -2.27 -0.93 0.22 1.44 3.11 5.78 14.44

(-14.20) (-6.90) (-4.01) (-2.23) (-0.89) (0.28) (1.57) (3.22) (5.99) (12.87)

ISDA -2.17 -0.74 -0.51 -0.35 -0.17 0.07 0.34 0.58 1.12 3.64

(-1.17) (-0.60) (-0.40) (-0.34) (-0.19) (-0.02) (0.13) (0.37) (0.72) (2.10)

LRNDA -2.69 -2.67 -2.98 -3.33 -3.57 -3.85 -4.16 -4.17 -4.17 -3.63

(-2.66) (-2.42) (-2.78) (-3.08) (-3.37) (-3.65) (4.00) (-4.00) (-3.86) (-3.03)

EARN -12.06 -1.68 1.25 1.81 2.04 2.36 1.68 0.80 -1.18 -5.80

(-1.13) (3.43) (4.40) (4.78) (4.84) (4.86) (4.58) (4.44) (4.34) (4.38)

CFO 8.18 8.66 8.79 7.76 6.70 5.94 4.04 1.33 -3.88 -21.33

(15.18) (12.47) (11.37) (10.26) (9.21) (8.22) (6.83) (4.57) (0.80) (-10.96)

ASSETS 462.01 814.08 1204.97 1735.84 1898.29 1951.40 1662.24 1196.31 587.47 310.62

(45.25) (98.33) (159.64) (227.79) (286.90) (274.40) (214.78) (145.37) (85.95) (47.15)

MB 2.00 1.72 1.66 1.66 1.61 1.57 1.59 1.68 1.83 2.31

(1.31) (1.24) (1.23) (1.25) (1.22) (1.21) (1.21) (1.22) (1.27) (1.49)

Page 48: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

46

Table III (Continued)

Panel B: Firm-Specific Discretionary Accrual (FSDA) Decile Portfolios

Lowest

Decile 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Highest

Decile

TDA

-16.18 -7.14 -4.09 -2.23 -0.95 0.28 1.53 3.32 6.15 16.38

(-14.68) (-7.04) (-4.21) (-2.39) (-1.08) (0.15) (1.41) (3.08) (5.87) (13.91)

FSDA -16.69 -7.57 -4.52 -2.58 -1.09 0.27 1.70 3.51 6.46 15.78

(-14.69) (-7.40) (-4.44) (-2.53) (-1.06) (0.26) (1.67) (3.44) (6.28) (13.37)

ISDA 0.51 0.43 0.43 0.36 0.14 0.02 -0.16 -0.20 -0.31 0.60

(0.3) (0.30) (0.21) (0.15) (0.00) (-0.10) (-0.29) (-0.46) (-0.47) (0.00)

LRNDA -2.99 -2.96 -3.03 -3.43 -3.72 -3.90 -4.15 -4.09 -3.83 -3.12

(-2.81) (-2.68) (-2.83) (-3.17) (-3.46) (-3.65) (-4.01) (-3.81) (-3.54) (-2.74)

EARN -12.47 -2.77 -0.27 0.78 1.80 1.83 1.53 0.75 0.42 -2.38

(-1.27) (3.26) (4.09) (4.61) (4.63) (4.69) (4.61) (4.64) (4.63) (4.79)

CFO 6.49 7.33 6.85 6.43 6.45 5.39 4.18 1.51 -1.95 -16.48

(13.93) (11.82) (10.41) (9.78) (9.12) (8.27) (7.02) (5.15) (1.97) (-8.00)

ASSETS 441.90 773.80 1,111.59 1,666.74 1,910.23 1,830.08 1,680.26 1,274.97 747.67 386.12

(47.91) (94.94) (148.62) (206.16) (254.89) (265.08) (214.95) (145.13) (96.05) (54.74)

MB 2.02 1.75 1.70 1.71 1.59 1.62 1.63 1.71 1.77 2.15

(1.32) (1.27) (1.24) (1.26) (1.20) (1.22) (1.21) (1.25) (1.27) (1.40)

Panel C: Industry-Specific Discretionary Accrual (ISDA) Decile Portfolios

Lowest

Decile 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Highest

Decile

TDA

-5.81 -2.30 -1.46 -1.15 -0.87 -0.54 -0.30 0.49 1.45 7.55

(-4.19) (-1.83) (-1.13) (-0.83) (-0.63) (-0.43) (-0.03) (0.37) (1.38) (5.55)

FSDA 0.43 0.24 0.05 -0.31 -0.58 -0.77 -1.11 -1.11 -1.44 -0.13

(1.12) (0.57) (0.29) (-0.10) (-0.41) (-0.69) (-0.79) (-1.17) (-1.55) (-1.00)

ISDA -6.24 -2.54 -1.51 -0.83 -0.29 0.23 0.81 1.60 2.89 7.68

(-5.08) (-2.46) (-1.47) (-0.82) (-0.31) (0.17) (0.74) (1.54) (2.82) (6.15)

LRNDA -3.05 -3.32 -3.26 -3.22 -3.21 -3.19 -3.19 -3.55 -3.84 -5.40

(-3.44) (-3.30) (-3.01) (-2.96) (-2.81) (-2.86) (-2.94) (-3.47) (-4.14) (-5.62)

EARN -3.71 1.49 2.79 2.50 2.15 1.71 0.60 -0.99 -4.00 -13.31

(3.29) (4.79) (5.12) (4.73) (4.53) (4.37) (4.17) (4.07) (3.66) (1.80)

CFO 5.26 7.12 7.49 6.87 6.20 5.34 4.01 1.95 -1.75 -16.29

(9.44) (9.47) (9.06) (8.56) (7.85) (7.72) (7.06) (6.38) (5.16) (-3.32)

ASSETS 709.40 1,200.44 1,510.04 1,152.14 1,637.62 1,549.18 1,387.50 1,156.54 798.78 362.79

(54.75) (139.20) (185.06) (196.05) (222.55) 211.92 (163.77) (131.71) (90.12) (34.68)

MB 1.96 1.72 1.65 1.58 1.55 1.55 1.58 1.66 1.90 2.48

(1.34) (1.24) (1.23) (1.20) (1.21) (1.21) (1.20) (1.23) (1.31) (1.55)

Page 49: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

47

Table IV

Distribution of Firm-Years across FSDA and TDA Ranks within ISDA Decile Portfolios The table shows the distribution of firm-years across firm-specific (FSDA) and total discretionary accrual (TDA) decile ranks within each

industry-specific discretionary accrual (ISDA) decile portfolio for the sample of firms between 1970 and 2006. The top half shows the

percentage of firm-years in each of the ten FSDA and TDA rankings for the bottom five ISDA decile portfolios, while the bottom half

shows the percentage of firm-years in each of the ten FSDA and TDA rankings for the top five ISDA decile portfolios. FSDA are

residuals obtained from estimating the performance-adjusted cross-sectional Jones model presented in equation [5]. TDA are calculated as

the difference between accruals and LRNDA. Accruals are calculated using the balance sheet approach as difference between non-cash current assets and change in current liabilities (exclusive of short-term debt and taxes payable), less depreciation expense. ISDA are

calculated as the difference between SRNDA (equation [6]) and LRNDA (equation [7]). TDA, FSDA and ISDA decile ranks are

determined based on their respective fiscal year-end values. The sample consists of all US firms that are present on the COMPUSTAT

and CRSP monthly returns file between 1970 and 2006 that do not correspond to financials or utilities, have fiscal year-end in December

(FYR = 12), have shares corresponding to common equity, and have non-missing data for accruals, and its discretionary and non-

discretionary accrual components. All continuous variables are Winsorized at 1% and 99% respectively.

Decile

ISDA Decile 1

(Lowest) ISDA Decile 2

ISDA Decile 3

ISDA Decile 4

ISDA Decile 5

Rankings FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

Lowest 13.74 28.53

9.23 13.15

6.90 8.60

7.55 8.27

6.92 6.81

2 8.63 14.59

8.29 13.31

8.56 12.05

8.32 10.55

9.75 10.69

3 7.12 11.28

7.91 12.62

8.63 12.00

10.17 12.20

10.44 10.82

4 5.87 8.69

8.15 11.64

9.52 12.49

10.39 12.29

11.31 12.12

5 6.21 7.31

8.94 10.68

10.75 11.78

11.20 11.20

11.94 12.57

6 7.25 6.16

10.12 9.45

11.06 10.24

11.24 11.56

11.34 11.60

7 8.92 5.58

10.83 7.73

11.75 10.53

12.43 10.55

12.25 11.32

8 10.87 5.96

13.11 7.97

13.18 9.48

11.33 9.16

9.24 9.19

9 14.70 6.11

12.80 7.44

11.60 7.58

9.54 8.27

9.73 9.24

Highest 16.68 5.80

10.61 6.01

8.05 5.23

7.84 5.95

7.08 5.64

100.00 100.00

100.00 100.00

100.00 100.00

100.00 100.00

100.00 100.00

Decile ISDA Decile 6

ISDA Decile 7

ISDA Decile 8

ISDA Decile 9

ISDA Decile 10

(Highest)

Rankings FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

FSDA% TDA%

Lowest 7.69 6.82

9.02 7.19

9.69 6.90

12.61 7.58

16.36 5.88

2 9.85 9.68

10.39 9.04

11.67 7.95

12.50 7.47

12.08 4.70

3 11.15 10.52

11.04 9.47

11.87 9.01

11.86 7.29

9.86 4.87

4 12.00 11.76

11.59 10.07

11.51 9.37

11.83 7.27

7.92 4.38

5 12.42 12.05

11.51 10.85

11.45 10.53

8.77 8.27

6.74 4.70

6 11.84 12.96

11.88 12.15

10.64 10.62

8.70 9.66

5.99 5.65

7 9.99 10.50

10.41 13.03

9.34 12.88

7.85 10.96

6.39 7.08

8 9.94 10.66

8.88 11.10

7.39 12.54

8.45 13.64

7.59 10.26

9 8.40 8.98

8.46 10.03

8.41 10.85

7.80 14.78

8.73 16.87

Highest 6.73 6.06

6.81 7.19

8.01 9.35

9.64 13.09

18.34 35.61

100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00

Page 50: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

48

Table V

Monthly Alphas from Fama and French Three-Factor Model for TDA and NDA Decile Portfolios The table presents the monthly alphas for total discretionary accrual (TDA) and long-run non-discretionary accrual (LRNDA) decile

portfolios, Panels A and B respectively. The portfolios are constructed by ranking firms in each year t based on their magnitude of TDA

and LRNDA, respectively. The monthly alphas are estimated from calendar time regression based on Fama-French’s three factor model

using monthly returns: ttHtSftmtmftpt HMLSMBRRRR )( where Rpt is the return on the accrual portfolio in month

t; Rmt is the return on the CRSP value-weighted index in month t; Rft is the 3-month T-bill yield in month t; SMBt is the return on small

firms minus the return on large firms in month t; and HMLt is the return on high book-to-market stocks minus the return on low book-to-

market stocks in month t. For companies in each accrual decile in year t, we report monthly returns earned three years prior and three

years subsequent to portfolio formation. Monthly returns are included starting 4 months after the beginning and 4 months after the end of

each year. LRNDA are calculated using equation [7] and TDA are calculated as the difference between total accruals and LRNDA.

Accruals are calculated using the balance sheet approach as difference between non-cash current assets and change in current liabilities

(exclusive of short-term debt and taxes payable), less depreciation expense. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

Deciles

Panel A: Monthly Alphas (%) for TDA Decile Portfolios

Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.43*** 0.29* -0.04 0.02 0.17 0.01 0.17

2 0.25** 0.05 -0.01 0.02 0.40*** 0.25** 0.28**

3 0.23** 0.11 -0.14 0.09 0.24*** 0.12 0.17

4 0.17*** 0.00 -0.08 0.08 0.25*** 0.19** 0.27

5 0.07 0.11 -0.08 0.13 0.15** 0.20** 0.14

6 0.15** 0.12 0.06 -0.04 0.17** 0.09 0.1

7 0.08 0.15* 0.12 0.03 0.08 0.13 0.08

8 0.23*** 0.31** 0.25*** 0.07 0.01 0.22** 0.15*

9 0.37** 0.57*** 0.41*** 0.23** -0.02 0.06 0.25**

10 (Highest) 0.60*** 0.72*** 1.32*** 0.72*** -0.32** -0.22* -0.12

Highest – Lowest 0.17*** 0.22*** 1.35*** 0.70*** -0.49*** -0.23** -0.33**

Deciles

Panel B: Monthly Alphas (%) for LRNDA Decile Portfolios

Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.25 0.28 0.05 0.13 -0.02 -0.04 0.06

2 -0.05 -0.04 -0.17 -0.02 0.07 0.22* 0.14

3 0.06 -0.17 -0.36*** -0.06 0.13 0.11 0.18

4 0.04 -0.21** -0.42*** -0.10 0.13 0.17* 0.10

5 0.01 -0.16 -0.28** -0.13 0.17* 0.10 0.17

6 0.17* -0.04 -0.19** -0.04 0.23*** 0.17** 0.14

7 0.18** 0.08 0.01 0.04 0.20** 0.21** 0.24***

8 0.38*** 0.45*** 0.28** 0.07 0.20** 0.35 0.21**

9 0.60*** 0.78*** 0.83*** 0.44*** 0.17* 0.13 0.17*

10 (Highest) 0.97*** 1.48*** 2.09*** 1.02*** -0.10 -0.10 0.09

Page 51: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

49

Highest – Lowest 0.72*** 1.20*** 2.04*** 0.89*** -0.08 -0.06 0.03

Table VI

Monthly Alphas from Fama-French’s Three-Factor Model for Firm-Specific Discretionary Accrual (FSDA)

and Industry-Specific Discretionary Accrual Decile (ISDA) Portfolios The table reports the monthly alphas for firm-specific discretionary accrual (FSDA) decile portfolios [Panel A], and industry-specific

discretionary accrual (ISDA) decile portfolios [Panel B]. The portfolios are constructed by ranking firms in each year t based on their

magnitude of FSDA and ISDA, respectively. The alphas are estimated from calendar time regression based on Fama-French’s three factor

model using monthly returns: ttHtSftmtmftpt HMLSMBRRRR )( where Rpt is the return on the accrual portfolio in

month t; Rmt is the return on the CRSP value-weighted index in month t; Rft is the 3-month T-bill yield in month t; SMBt is the return on

small firms minus the return on large firms in month t; and HMLt is the return on high book-to-market stocks minus the return on low book-to-market stocks in month t. Monthly returns are included starting 4 months after the beginning and 4 months after the end of each

year. FSDA are residuals obtained from estimating the performance-adjusted cross-sectional Jones model presented in equation [5]. ISDA

are calculated as the difference between SRNDA (equation [6]) and LRNDA (equation [7]). ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5%

and 10% respectively.

Panel A: Monthly Alphas (%) for FSDA Decile Portfolios

Deciles Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.33** 0.24* -0.05 0.05 0.26 0.10 0.15

2 0.38*** 0.10 -0.03 0.10 0.36*** 0.20* 0.27**

3 0.26*** 0.08 -0.03 0.03 0.32*** 0.02 0.21**

4 0.27*** 0.21** -0.02 0.11 0.17** 0.19** 0.18**

5 0.07 0.08 0.01 0.07 0.20** 0.13 0.25***

6 0.11 0.11 0.04 0.09 0.09 -0.20** 0.08

7 0.09 0.25*** 0.09 -0.03 0.06 0.11 0.10

8 0.26*** 0.27*** 0.12 0.17* 0.03 0.29*** 0.18*

9 0.32*** 0.39*** 0.44*** 0.12 -0.01 0.07 0.20**

10 (Highest) 0.44*** 0.70*** 1.28*** 0.64*** -0.30** -0.25* -0.09

Highest – Lowest 0.11** 0.46*** 1.33*** 0.59*** -0.56*** -0.35** -0.23**

Panel B: Monthly Alphas (%) for ISDA Decile Portfolios

Deciles Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.25* 0.28* 0.37** 0.20 -0.11 -0.06 -0.07

2 0.18* 0.44*** 0.20* 0.07 0.09 0.09 0.22**

3 0.24** 0.24** 0.11 0.00 0.22** 0.22** 0.28***

4 0.20** 0.10 -0.10 -0.04 0.20** 0.06 0.25***

5 0.20** 0.07 -0.02 0.06 0.23*** 0.20** 0.13

6 0.21** 0.23*** 0.05 0.05 0.16 0.26*** 0.16

7 0.12 0.05 0.07 0.00 0.24*** 0.18** 0.12

8 0.28*** 0.14 0.16 0.02 0.04 0.09 0.16*

9 0.31*** 0.22 0.35*** 0.37*** 0.18 0.12 0.25**

10 (Highest) 0.58*** 0.66*** 0.62*** 0.61*** -0.09 -0.11 -0.04

Highest – Lowest 0.33*** 0.38*** 0.25*** 0.41*** 0.02 -0.05 0.03

Page 52: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

50

Table VII

Monthly Alphas from Fama-French’s Three-Factor Model for Firms with the Highest FSDA The table reports the monthly alphas for the portfolio of firms with the highest firm-specific discretionary accrual (FSDA). Panel A

reports these alphas for firms in top FSDA decile across ISDA deciles, while Panel B reports these results for firms in top FSDA quintile

across ISDA quintiles. The portfolios are constructed by ranking firms based on the magnitude of their FSDA and ISDA decile and

quintile rankings respectively at the end of each year t. The alphas are estimated from calendar time regression based on Fama-French’s

three factor model using monthly returns: ttHtSftmtmftpt HMLSMBRRRR )( where Rpt is the return on the accrual

portfolio in month t; Rmt is the return on the CRSP value-weighted index in month t; Rft is the 3-month T-bill yield in month t; SMBt is the

return on small firms minus the return on large firms in month t; and HMLt is the return on high book-to-market stocks minus the return

on low book-to-market stocks in month t. Monthly returns are included starting 4 months after the beginning and 4 months after the end of

each year. Firm-specific discretionary accruals (FSDA) are residuals obtained from estimating the performance-adjusted cross-sectional

Jones model presented in equation [5]. Industry-specific discretionary accruals (ISDA) are calculated as the difference between SRNDA

(equation [6]) and LRNDA (equation [7]). ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

ISDA Deciles

Panel A: Monthly Alphas (%) for Decile Portfolios

Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.34 0.32 0.92*** 0.77*** -0.39 -0.29 -0.30

2 0.21 0.93*** 0.88*** 0.56** -0.24 -0.36 0.06

3 0.01 0.82*** 1.10*** 0.41* 0.11 -0.22 0.38

4 0.40 0.58** 1.08*** 0.12 0.05 -0.08 -0.25

5 0.22 0.88*** 0.82*** 0.23 -0.19 -0.19 -0.38

6 -0.14 0.96*** 1.31*** 0.41 -0.23 -0.03 -0.39

7 0.88** 0.62** 0.86*** -0.15 -0.46 0.26 -0.01

8 0.81** 0.36* 1.79*** 0.92*** -0.33 -0.21 0.19

9 0.81** 0.61** 1.84*** 0.69*** -0.15 -0.49* 0.23

10 (Highest) 0.71** 1.03*** 1.62*** 1.14*** -0.68*** -0.48* -0.20

Highest – Lowest 0.37*** 0.71*** 0.72*** 0.37*** -0.29** -0.19 0.10

ISDA Quintiles

Panel B: Monthly Alphas (%) for Quintile Portfolios

Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.20 0.39*** 0.66*** 0.31** -0.14 -0.07 0.04

2 1.03*** 0.55*** 0.60*** 0.12 -0.01 -0.06 0.21

3 0.22 0.61*** 0.71*** 0.20 0.00 0.03 -0.18

4 0.51*** 0.46*** 0.92*** 0.27* -0.22 0.12 0.34**

10 (Highest) 0.70*** 0.80*** 1.34*** 0.88*** -0.36** -0.32* -0.03

Highest – Lowest 0.50*** 0.41*** 0.68*** 0.57*** -0.22** -0.25* -0.07

Page 53: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

51

Table VIII

Monthly Alphas from Fama-French’s Three-Factor Model for Highest-FSDA Decile Using Alternative

Jones Model Specifications The table reports the monthly alphas for the portfolio of firms with in the top decile of firm-specific discretionary accruals (FSDA) which

lie in the bottom, middle, and top deciles of industry-specific discretionary accruals (ISDA) respectively. In Panel A, FSDA and ISDA are

measured using the standard Jones model which regresses accruals on change in sales and gross property, plant and equipment. In Panel

B, FSDA and ISDA are measured using the modified Jones model which regresses accruals on change in sales net of change in

receivables and gross property, plant and equipment without lag ROA as an additional regressor in the model. The portfolios are

constructed by ranking firms based on the magnitude of their FSDA and ISDA decile rankings respectively at the end of each year t. The

alphas are estimated from calendar time regression based on Fama-French’s three factor model using monthly returns:

ttHtSftmtmftpt HMLSMBRRRR )( where Rpt is the return on the accrual portfolio in month t; Rmt is the return on

the CRSP value-weighted index in month t; Rft is the 3-month T-bill yield in month t; SMBt is the return on small firms minus the return

on large firms in month t; and HMLt is the return on high book-to-market stocks minus the return on low book-to-market stocks in month

t. Monthly returns are included starting 4 months after the beginning and 4 months after the end of each year. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

Panel A: Monhtly Alphas (%) for Highest-FSDA Decile Using Standard Jones

ISDA Deciles Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.18 0.56** 0.97*** 0.51** -0.29 -0.33 -0.34

5 0.53* 0.91*** 1.30**** -0.37 -0.34 0.38 -0.08

10 (Highest) 0.66** 0.68** 1.97*** 0.90*** -0.69*** -0.87*** -0.28

Highest – Lowest 0.48* 0.12** 1.00*** 0.39*** -0.40** -0.55*** 0.06

Panel B: Monthly Alphas (%) for Highest-FSDA Decile Using Modified Jones Without Lag ROA

ISDA Deciles Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.25 0.63*** 1.01*** 0.59** -0.13 -0.34 -0.39*

5 0.13 1.09*** 1.53*** -0.05 -0.37 -0.38 0.05

10 (Highest) 0.61* 0.89*** 2.14*** 1.09*** -0.93*** -0.74*** -0.59**

Highest – Lowest 0.36 0.26*** 1.13*** 0.60*** -0.80*** -0.40*** -0.20*

Page 54: Earnings management and the accruals anomaly: The role of ...correlated during times of industry-wide overvaluation as overvalued firms attempt to manipulate earnings upwards in order

52

Table IX

Monthly Alphas from Fama-French’s Four-Factor Model The table reports monthly Jensen’s alphas using the Fama-French four factor model for the period 1970 – 1996. Panel A reports these

alphas for firms in the bottom, middle, and top FSDA deciles, Panel B reports these alphas for firms in the top FSDA decile in the lowest,

middle, and top ISDA deciles, and Panel C reports these alphas for firms in the top FSDA quintile in the lowest, middle, and top ISDA

quintiles respectively. The portfolios are constructed by ranking firms in each year t based on their magnitude of FSDA and ISDA decile

and quintile rankings respectively. The alphas are estimated from calendar time regression based on Fama-French’s four factor model

using monthly returns: ttUtHtSftmtmftpt UMDHMLSMBRRRR )( where Rpt is the return on the accrual portfolio

in month t; Rmt is the return on the CRSP value-weighted index in month t; Rft is the 3-month T-bill yield in month t; SMBt is the return on

small firms minus the return on large firms in month t; HMLt is the return on high book-to-market stocks minus the return on low book-to-

market stocks in month t; and UMDt is the difference between returns on portfolios of past winners and losers. Monthly returns are

included starting 4 months after the beginning and 4 months after the end of each year. Firm-specific discretionary accruals (FSDA) are

residuals obtained from estimating the performance-adjusted cross-sectional Jones model presented in equation [5]. Industry-specific

discretionary accruals (ISDA) are calculated as the difference between SRNDA (equation [6]) and LRNDA (equation [7]). ***, ** and *

denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

FSDA Deciles

Panel A: Monthly Alphas (%) for FSDA Decile Portfolio

Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.05 -0.03 -0.36** -0.10 0.35** 0.17 0.25*

5 -0.03 0.14* 0.07 0.17** 0.24*** 0.20** 0.23**

10 (Highest) 0.27* 0.49*** 0.95*** 0.40*** -0.32** -0.21* -0.04

Highest – Lowest 0.22* 0.52*** 1.31*** 0.50*** -0.67*** -0.38** -0.29*

ISDA Deciles

Panel B: Monthly Alphas (%) for Highest FSDA Decile Portfolio

Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.01 -0.19 0.23 0.60** -0.42 -0.33 -0.10

5 0.25 0.82** 0.88*** 0.29 0.03 -0.03 0.18

10 (Highest) -0.70** 0.74*** 1.51*** 0.66** -0.89*** -0.38 -0.26

Highest – Lowest -0.71** 0.93*** 1.28*** 0.06 -0.47*** -0.05 -0.16

ISDA Quintiles

Panel C: Monthly Alphas (%) for Highest FSDA Quintile Portfolio

Year With Respect to Portfolio Formation

t = -3 t = -2 t = -1 t = 0 t = +1 t = +2 t = +3

1 (Lowest) 0.07 -0.00 0.13 0.24 -0.04 -0.11 0.19

3 0.40*** 0.58*** 0.63*** -0.00 -0.00 0.04 0.15

5 (Highest) 0.56*** 0.64*** 1.32*** 0.65*** -0.46*** -0.28 -0.09

Highest – Lowest 0.49*** 0.64*** 1.19*** 0.41*** -0.42*** -0.17 -0.28*