economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

24
This article was downloaded by: [Yonsei University] On: 05 March 2013, At: 17:47 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Economy and Society Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/reso20 Economies of contagion: financial crisis and pandemic Robert Peckham Version of record first published: 14 Jan 2013. To cite this article: Robert Peckham (2013): Economies of contagion: financial crisis and pandemic, Economy and Society, DOI:10.1080/03085147.2012.718626 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03085147.2012.718626 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms- and-conditions This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub- licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

Upload: man-go

Post on 13-Apr-2015

32 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

DESCRIPTION

1

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

This article was downloaded by: [Yonsei University]On: 05 March 2013, At: 17:47Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH,UK

Economy and SocietyPublication details, including instructions for authorsand subscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/reso20

Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemicRobert PeckhamVersion of record first published: 14 Jan 2013.

To cite this article: Robert Peckham (2013): Economies of contagion: financial crisis andpandemic, Economy and Society, DOI:10.1080/03085147.2012.718626

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03085147.2012.718626

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes.Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expresslyforbidden.

The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make anyrepresentation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up todate. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should beindependently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liablefor any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damageswhatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connectionwith or arising out of the use of this material.

Page 2: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

Economies of contagion:financial crisis andpandemic

Robert Peckham

Abstract

The outbreak of an influenza A (H1N1) pandemic in 2009 coincided with a severeglobal financial downturn (2007�8). This paper examines the use of ‘contagion’ as amodel for assessing the dynamics of both episodes: the spread of infection and thediffusion of shock through an intrafinancial system. The argument is put that adiscourse of globally ‘emerging’ and ‘re-emerging’ infection helped to shape a theoryof financial contagion, which developed, particularly from 1997, in relation tofinancial crises in ‘emerging markets’ in Southeast Asia. Conversely, concerns aboutthe economic impact of a global pandemic have been influential in shaping publichealth responses to communicable diseases from the early 1990s. The paper arguesthat tracing the conceptual entanglement of financial and biological ‘contagions’ isimportant for understanding the interconnected global environment within whichrisk is increasingly being evaluated. The paper also considers the consequences ofthis analogizing for how financial crises are understood and, ultimately, howresponses to them are formulated.

Keywords: contagion; emerging markets; emerging infections; networks; analogies;risk.

Introduction: models of contagion

This paper investigates the interconnectedness of two global events: the 2007�8

‘Credit Crunch’ and the 2009 pandemic of swine-origin influenza A (H1N1)

Robert Peckham, The University of Hong Kong, Centre for the Humanities and Medicine,

B926, 9/F, Run Run Shaw Tower, Centennial Campus, Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong. E-mail:

[email protected]

Copyright # 2013 Taylor & Francis

ISSN 0308-5147 print/1469-5766 online

http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03085147.2012.718626

Economy and Society 2013 pp. 1�23, iFirst article

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 3: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

strain (S-OIV), a hybrid of human, pig and avian influenza first identified in

Mexico (Zimmer & Burke, 2009).1 In 2008, during the height of the financial

crisis, commentators drew heavily and explicitly on the vocabulary of infectious

disease and imported concepts from epidemiology to explain the spillover of

volatility and the diffusion of distress through an intrafinancial system

characterized by its ‘complexity’ (Caballero & Simsek, 2009, p. 2). Both

events � financial ‘crunch’ and pandemic � were invariably construed by media

commentators, public health officials, policy-makers and a range of ‘experts’ as

crises caused by destabilized and destabilizing global processes. Both events

brought to the fore debates about the need for a re-evaluation of risk in relation

to the threats posed by emerging infections, as well as the cross-institutional

perturbations and cascading bank failures within the financial ‘ecosystem’

(Haldane & May, 2011; May et al., 2008).

In 2007, after a prolonged fall in US property prices, sub-prime mortgage

defaults increased, prompting investors to reassess the risks of high-yield

securities (Mizen, 2008, pp. 533�50). The economist Robert J. Shiller

commented on the ‘infectious exuberance’ which had characterized the

subprime housing market, observing that ‘financial bubbles are like

epidemics � and we should treat them both the same way’ (Shiller, 2008).

Similarly, Timothy Geithner, US Secretary of the Treasury, observed in early

2008, following the loan defaults and the Federal Reserve’s bailout of Bear

Stearns, the brokerage firm and investment bank: ‘Contagion spreads,

transmitting waves of distress to other markets’ (Geithner, 2008). To many

economists and financial theorists, the global spread of the US ‘financial flu’

held out the real prospect of a ‘pandemic’ (Roubini, 2008). As Roubini and

Mihm asserted: ‘History confirms that crises are much like pandemics: they

begin with the outbreak of a disease that then spreads, radiating outwards’

(2010, p. 8). Analogies of disease, infection and contagion pervade their

account of the 2008 financial downturn, even though the authors themselves

concede: ‘Much of our framing and understanding of the worst financial

crisis in generations derives from a set of assumptions that, while not always

wrong, have nonetheless prevented a full understanding of its origins and

consequences’ (Roubini & Mihm, 2010, p. 5).

The focus, in this paper, is on the ways in which financial crises have been

analogized with contagious disease. Specifically, it addresses the following

questions: how, why and when did equations of financial distress with virulent

infection come about? What are the consequences of this analogizing for how

risk is understood, evaluated and communicated? To what extent does the

language of contagion in economics and financial theory influence how

governments, financial institutions and the public respond?

Notwithstanding the experiences of 2007�8, and ongoing debates about

financial contagion in relation to the sovereign debt crisis in the Eurozone, to

date little attention has been paid to the manner in which financial downturns

have been analogized by diverse actors across institutions (including news

media outlets, government agencies, financial organizations and academia) as

2 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 4: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

forms of ‘contagion’, or to the incorporation of financial models into public

health approaches to epidemics (Roberts, 2006).2 Analogies of contagion, and

the appropriation of related ‘disease’ metaphors into financial theory, this

paper suggests, do not simply serve to elucidate processes; increasingly such

conceptual formulations are defining how financial systems are viewed and

understood, and accordingly how policy is devised.3 Today, the extent to which

epidemiological models impinge on financial theory tends to pass unnoticed.

When rhetorical resources are taken for granted in this way, their explanatory

force diminishes, and they may even distort the phenomena they purport to

explain. As Mirowski has argued in his analysis of the adoption of a ‘static

physics model of equilibrium’ into neoclassical economics � ‘term for term

and symbol for symbol’ � it is important to highlight the mistranslation

that underpin these analogies, which may lead to critical distortions (Mirowski,

1989, p. 3).

The aim, then, is not to argue that financial crises are directly linked to ‘real’

pandemics � although the state of an economy will undoubtedly affect the

prevalence of infection and the burden of disease (Roberts, 2006, p. 7)4 � but,

rather, to examine the underlying logic of an increasingly pervasive

epidemiological language in financial theory and, in so doing, to consider

the conceptual and empirical implications of such recombinations. What is at

stake when a theoretical model and technical language from one domain

(epidemiology and public health) migrate to another (economics and financial

theory), and vice versa?

The paper engages with these issues by focusing on three key areas: the

development of financial theories of contagion in relation to ‘emerging

markets’; the evolution of theories of ‘emerging disease’; and the formulation

of ‘ecological’ approaches to financial systems during the 2007�8 financial

crisis and its aftermath. First, the paper argues that, in their responses to both

events between 2007 and 2009 (financial downturn and pandemic), economists,

policy-makers and other actors drew on antecedents of ‘contagion’ and a

discourse of ‘emergence’ which had developed from the 1980s and 1990s. This

section charts the rise of ‘emerging markets’ in the 1980s and then examines

theories of financial contagion in the late 1990s, which were evolved to explain

the mechanisms or ‘vectors’ of shock transmission.

Prior to the global crisis triggered by the currency devaluation in Thailand

in July 1997, the term ‘contagion’ was seldom applied to crises in the

international financial markets. As Claessens and Forbes have commented,

before 1997 a Lexis-Nexis search for contagion ‘finds hundreds of examples in

major newspapers, almost none of which refer to turmoil in international

financial markets’ (2001, p. 3).5 After 1997, however, studies began to

investigate how and why certain financial markets � particularly those in

emerging market countries � were more susceptible than others to financial

contagion (Lowell et al., 1998).6 The complex global interdependencies of

trade and finance revealed in the mid to late-1990s put pressure on existing

economic and financial models, exacerbating what Bell and Kristol had earlier

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 3

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 5: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

termed a ‘crisis in economic theory’ (1981). Global interdependencies and

network ‘spillovers’ underscored the imperative for developing novel inter-

pretative frameworks, drawing on models from biological systems, along with

network theories in sociology and engineering. The emphasis was on

elucidating transmission dynamics within complex networks with the aim of

formulating effective strategies for preventing and managing future episodes,

as well as creating a resilient network architecture to bolster stability (Cohen-

Cole et al., in press, p. 2; Sheng, 2011 [2010], pp. 84�6).

Second, the paper considers how the concept of ‘emerging markets’

provided a critical framework for conceptualizing ‘emerging infections’, a

term which gained currency from 1989. While economic models and

techniques were applied to the evaluation of biological threats, providing a

rationale for intervention (Roberts, 2006),7 epidemiological models of risk

management and disease containment fundamentally shaped economic and

financial thinking, with some commentators arguing that foreign speculation

triggered ‘capital outflows’ that functioned in a manner ‘analogous to a medical

epidemic’ (Lowell et al., 1998, p. 1). As Claessens and Forbes noted,

comparisons between the spread of a lethal ‘medical disease such as Ebola’

and financial crises ‘can be useful on a number of levels’ (2001, p. 4).

Third, having tracked these antecedents, the paper turns to the conflated

idioms of financial meltdown and pandemic between 2007 and 2009, examining

the ways in which both events were conceptually equated within an increasingly

influential network and complex-systems paradigm. Here, the dynamics of

banking ‘ecosystems’ and the propagation of ‘shock’ were explained through

analogy with the networks within which infectious diseases spread in order to

shed light on risks within financial networks (Haldane & May, 2011). The

explicit aim of such work was to apply models from ecology and epidemiology

to suggest how stability might be achieved within the banking system following

the crisis of 2007�8. As we shall see, the publication of a paper in Nature on the

pricing of derivatives and system stability by Haldane and May (2011) � an

expert in banking and an expert in theoretical ecology8 � reflects the rise of

financial ecology as a new field of research.

The conflated language of financial crisis and pandemic raises important

issues about how financial systems are conceived and represented, and what the

consequences of such conceptions and representations may be. While

McCloskey (1998 [1985]) has examined the rhetorical devices deployed within

economics, including metaphors, Ruccio (2008, p. 7) has argued that different

representations within economics reflect often divergent understandings of the

role of economics, its scope and modus operandi. Finally, construing banking

as an ‘ecosystem’ raises numerous questions, including the role of human

agency in the crisis and the extent to which human actors are able to manage or

control risk (and, indeed, are liable when untoward events occur). Examining

the connections and interactions between conceptual models, which are

increasingly taken for granted, thus has important empirical implications for

how future episodes are responded to, as well as the ways in which policy is

4 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 6: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

formulated to deal with global instabilities caused by proliferating commu-

nication networks, intensifying economic and biological contact, and changing

patterns of human behaviour (Waters, 2001, p. 80).

‘Emerging markets’ and theories of economic contagion

The term ‘emerging markets’ was coined by the International Finance

Corporation (IFC) of the World Bank Group in 1981 as an alternative to

the term ‘Third World’ (Agtmael, 2007, p. 5). ‘Emerging markets’ denoted a

transitional phase between developing and developed economic status, with the

largest emerging markets identified as China, India, Brazil and Mexico. The

Center for Knowledge Societies’ 2008 Emerging economy report characterizes

emerging economies as ‘regions of the world that are experiencing rapid

informationalization under conditions of limited or partial industrialization’.9

While emerging markets are deemed to yield greater profits for investors,

less ‘developed’ nations are also seen as less secure, carrying risks associated

with political instability, corruption, a partial judiciary and ineffective law

enforcement.

Whereas the term ‘emerging markets’ gained currency in the 1980s, the

widespread application of ‘contagion’ as a model for understanding financial

crises developed primarily in the 1990s, and particularly following the Asian

financial debacle. The so-called ‘Asian Flu’, as it was dubbed by the

international news media, began with the devaluation of the Thai baht in

July 1997 and then spread to Malaysia, Indonesia, Korea and Japan � with the

Hong Kong stock market crashing in October 1998 (Jackson, 1999). The crisis

in Southeast Asia subsequently migrated to Russia (leading to a loan default)

and Brazil, affecting Europe and North America, and resulting in the collapse

of the US hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management (Claessens & Forbes,

2001, p. 3).

In the 1990s, financial contagion was linked to a discourse of emerging

markets and, as a theoretical model, it was used to shed light on ‘co-movements

in creditworthiness not explained by movements in fundamentals’ (Valdes,

2000 [1997], p. 2.). Although the term ‘contagion’ had been employed before

1997, it was generally within the context of banking illiquidity and in relation

to the flow (and quality) of information on a given bank’s assets that

determined how investors and depositors interpreted risk (Park, 1991; Valdes,

2000 [1997], pp. 5�6).10 After 1997, contagion � conceptually tethered to

‘emergence’ � increasingly became a conceptual framework for analysing

cross-border financial relations and volatility in a global environment.11 As

Krugman has remarked of the 1997 financial crisis: ‘At the time, I thought of it

this way: it was as if bacteria that used to cause deadly plagues, but had long

been considered conquered by modern medicine, had reemerged in a form

resistant to all the standard antibiotics’ (2008, p. 5).

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 5

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 7: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

Since the 1990s, economists and policy-makers have striven to analyse the

intermediaries of financial shock and to isolate the alternative ‘channels

through which disturbances are transmitted from one country to another’

(Hernandez & Valdes, 2001, p. 3). As Rigobon has noted, the emphasis has

tended to be on addressing two overriding questions: ‘is the transmission of

shocks intensified during crises, and what is explanation behind the

propagation mechanism?’ (2003, p. 279). Within this extensive literature,

contagion has been defined in many different ways, and it has been attributed

to a range of causes, while numerous empirical methods of measurement and

testing have been hypothesized, and different channels of transmission

suggested (Cheung et al., 2009). In the broadest, macro-definition of the

term, the World Bank has stated: ‘Contagion is the cross-country transmission

of shocks or the general cross-country spillover effects.’12

A key emphasis in studies of contagion has been on trade linkages (in the

‘real’ economy) and on financial interconnections (including common creditors

and lenders), as well as on ‘microeconomic similarities’ between markets

(Cheung et al., 2009, pp. 4�6; Hernandez & Valdes, 2001, pp. 3�6). Other

more or less ‘broad’ and ‘restrictive’ definitions of contagion have focused on

incomplete or ‘asymmetric’ information and herding behaviour, on the impact

of shifting expectations that may result from a shock in another country and on

the so-called ‘wake-up call’, when ‘a crisis elsewhere provides new information

about the seriousness of problems in the home economy’ (Cheung et al., 2009,

p. 4). Moreover, channels of contagion have been sub-classified into, for

example, international ‘monsoons’, or global disturbances that affect all or

most countries (such as the oil shocks in the 1970s), and shocks deriving from a

related country’s ‘spillovers’ (Masson, 1999). Post-2008, as Ogum has noted,

the ‘ripple-effect’ and interconnections ‘between emerging market economies

(EME) and advanced economies (specifically the US) have become a major

topic of debate’ (2010, p. 3).

Epidemiological ideas of contagion have been adopted in the notion that

contagion is identifiable when ‘any disease or event occurs in clear excess of

normal expectancy’ (Last, 2001, cited in Gerstman, 1998, p. 2). Drawing

explicitly on epidemiological models, economists have applied conceptual

frameworks from research in epidemiological modelling, including Anderson

and May’s (1991) influential work on infectious disease and population

dynamics, making use of concepts and technical terms such as ‘transmission

coefficient’ and ‘endemic equilibrium’ as a way of elucidating the transmission

mechanisms of financial shock. Anderson and May had brought together

ecological and medical methods, developing mathematical models as public

health tools for managing micro- and macro-parasitic infections, with a focus

on the dynamics of parasitic interaction with host populations. As Sell has

noted in his account of financial contagion:

It is worthwhile learning from epidemiology basic terms and mechanisms of

infection and the transmission of infectious diseases before applying these

6 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 8: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

notions to problems in the field of international finance and monetary

economics. This, however, is only a first step and there are a huge variety of

possible ‘adaptations’, ‘translations’ and so on from epidemiology to economics.

(Sell, 2001, p. 120)

Different epidemiological approaches to finance over the last decade have had a

significant impact on rethinking interactions within financial systems. A 2010

Bank of England report by Gai and Kapadia, for example, citing Anderson and

May (1991), as well as Newman (2002) and Meyers (2007), among others,

proposed analytic models for evaluating contagion in complex, increasingly

interdependent financial networks (particularly with the advent of credit

default swaps, collateralized debt and other sophisticated financial products),

drawing explicitly on the literature of complex networks as they have been

applied to the epidemiology of infectious disease.

The literature on financial contagion seeks to ascertain the causes of global

market volatility in order, ultimately, to elaborate strategies for containing

crises and minimizing susceptibility to cross-border shocks. Debates on the

nature of contagion tend to centre on the extent to which capital mobility

should be regulated, and on addressing two critical questions: what factors

determine the course of a crisis and its potential to spread? Is shock propagated

through existing channels or along new pathways created by crises? Despite the

lack of consensus over the definition of ‘contagion’, and notwithstanding the

reservations expressed by some economists about the appositeness of the term

(Favero & Giavazzi, 2002, p. 245), ‘contagion’ continues to remain an

important theoretical framework for interpreting the transmission of financial

crises.

Disease emergence and microbial threats

Financial contagion was, from the outset, principally linked to emerging

markets � that is to say, the chief sources of ‘infection’ were located in less-

developed, often former colonial settings. These geographical contexts � and

specifically Southeast Asian countries and Latin America � were precisely the

environments singled out as battlegrounds in the war against virulent

‘emerging diseases’. The relationship between these two forms of ‘emergence’

was underscored by the term ‘Asian Flu’ used to describe the 1997 financial

crisis and by an outbreak of H5N1 avian flu in Hong Kong in 1997 in which

18 people were hospitalized, six of whom died. As a consequence, two notions

of risk � biological and economic � became increasingly intertwined. Indeed,

the socio-political contexts of the so-called ‘emerging markets’ were precisely

the risk factors that contributed to both public health and financial crises, even

though they provided potential for substantial profits.

The HIV/AIDS epidemic which followed the World Health Organization’s

(WHO) promotion of smallpox’s eradication in 1977, and antimicrobial

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 7

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 9: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

resistant strains in infectious diseases, focused international attention from the

1980s on newly identified and re-emerging communicable diseases. In a

systematic literature survey it was found that 87 of the 1,399 known human

pathogens were first reported after 1980, the majority of these new species

being viruses with a global distribution and associated largely with animal

reservoirs (Woolhouse & Gaunt, 2007). The term ‘emerging’ infection to

describe these newly identified pathogens appears to have been coined in 1989

by the virologist Stephen S. Morse, who convened a conference on ‘emerging

viruses’ with Joshua Lederberg, organized by the National Institutes of Health

and Rockefeller University. As a concept, ‘emergence’ gained further currency

with the publication of the 1992 report Emerging infections: Microbial threats to

health in the United States edited by Lederberg and others, while the term

became institutionally entrenched with the launch of the journal Emerging

Infectious Diseases in 1994 and the establishment of WHO’s Division of

Emerging and Other Communicable Diseases Surveillance and Control, which

sought to address ‘the elusive, continuous, evolving, and global nature’ of new

and renewed infectious diseases.13

As King has argued, the ‘emerging diseases worldview’, which was reflected

in these initiatives, came ‘equipped with a moral economy and historical

narrative, explaining how and why we find ourselves in the situation that we do

now, identifying villains and heroes, ascribing blame for failures and credit for

triumphs’. The ‘emerging diseases worldview’ emphasized the risks posed by

infections to public health, national security, development and international

finance, and thereby ‘recapitulated the previous century’s dominant logics of

international health policy’ (King, 2002, pp. 763�4, 767).

Like ‘emerging markets’, ‘emerging diseases’ were viewed as the con-

sequences of increasing globalization (Knobler et al., 2006) � accelerated and

intensified migration facilitated by mass transportation systems, new multi-

national agribusiness and an exploding world population:

As the human immunodeficiency virus (HIV) pandemic surely should have

taught us, in the context of infectious diseases, there is nowhere in the world

from which we are remote and no one from whom we are disconnected.

Consequently, some infectious diseases that now affect people in other parts of

the world represent potential threats to the United States because of global

interdependence, modern transportation, trade, and changing social and cultural

patterns.

(Lederberg et al., 1992, p. v)14

Such anxieties were further linked to environmental change and increasing

global contact, ideas disseminated in popular culture, including the writings of

Richard Preston (1994), Laurie Garrett (1995), Jared Diamond (1997) and

others. A spate of much-publicized disease outbreaks in the late 1990s,

including Ebola in Zaire (from 1997 the Democratic Republic of the Congo),

Bovine spongiform encephalopathy (BSE or ‘mad cow disease’) in Western

8 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 10: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

Europe and the West Nile Virus in the US reinforced latent concerns about

security threats posed to the West by highly pathogenic diseases originating in

the developing world (Wald, 2008, pp. 29�67). The trans-boundary movement

of people, animals and trade continues to be identified as a key driver of future

emerging disease threats, necessitating ‘new systems for disease detection,

identification and monitoring’ (Brownlie et al., 2006, p. 2).

The ‘emerging diseases’ worldview overlapped in significant ways with the

economic discourse of ‘emerging markets’. While disease was equated with

economic underdevelopment, inadequate healthcare and the potential diffusion

of pandemic infections provided a rationale for ‘Western’ intervention to tackle

the threat ‘at source’. Moreover, such interventions entailed the absorption of

‘emerging’ countries into international (US-led) global economic and public

health institutions. Financial contagions, like disease outbreaks, were con-

strued, in this sense, as ‘phantasms of consequences’: incarnations of the

developing world ‘leaking into the metropolises of the First World’ (Wald,

2008, p. 45). It was precisely this nexus which was emphasized in the Institute

of Medicine’s report, America’s vital interest in global health: Protecting our

people, enhancing our economy, and advancing our national interests, which

articulated the notion of ‘enlightened self-interest’ and integrated national

economic interests within a global health agenda. Published at the same time as

the Asian financial crisis, the report declared of US policy abroad: ‘Our

considered involvement can serve to protect our citizens, enhance our

economy, and advance US interests abroad’ (IOM, 1997, p. vi). Biological

threats and economic interests were construed as intertwined, necessitating

comprehensive preparedness plans and a global network of surveillance to

monitor cross-border flows. Hygienic modernization and economic develop-

ment were, in effect, understood as part and parcel of the same project. A key

concern was the amplification of risk that was one consequences of ‘the

liberalization of international trade’, which had ‘greatly increased the exchange

of goods and people across borders’, leading to greater instability and diffusion

of disease (IOM, 1997, p. 111).

Within this context, public health professionals and policy-makers sought to

develop public health models by drawing on the examples of financial

institutions. The international response to the Asian financial crisis in 1997

provided an example, for some, of the ways in which international financial

institutions could develop efficient mechanisms to mitigate risk. According to

this argument, the existence of central banks, such the Federal Reserve Bank of

New York, allowed for the generation of credible information about potentially

damaging developments and served as a model for the ‘central bank’ role which

the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) was destined to play

(Levine, 2006), just as the 1997 report on infectious diseases had cited the

World Bank (which was growing in influence and had issued loans for health in

1996 for US$ 2.5 billion, over twice the total budget of the WHO) as an

example of what the WHO needed to become (IOM, 1997, pp. 42�3). The

proceedings of a forum held in April 2002 on emerging infections in

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 9

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 11: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

Washington DC for clinicians, researchers and public policy-makers called for

the establishment of an international public health ‘bank’. The suggestion was

made for public health to adopt a ‘market-like architecture’ that:

would be operable on a global level and would allow the movement of resources

across political barriers. The establishment of some type of public health

‘currency’ would facilitate the sharing of resources and provide a conduit

through which the developed and developing world could exchange experience

and information.

(Knobler et al., 2006, p. 102)

Here, the financial system becomes a model for disease exchange and

prophylactic strategies, just as disease transmission and public health

surveillance became models in financial theory for rethinking networks and

risk. In the passage above, financial discourse is incorporated into the heart of

public health, while the integration of public health into a global economy has

not superseded a territorial, boundary-oriented and ‘contagion’-centred

epidemiology, but rather reaffirmed it.

A tension underscores the conceptual equation of financial crisis with

communicable disease, one that lies at the heart of the idea of the ‘risk society’

developed by Beck (1992) and Giddens (1999), precisely at the moment when

the risks posed by ‘emerging infections’ and ‘financial crises’ were coming into

focus.15 On the one hand, the notion that toxic financial products are biological

‘agents’, akin to contaminating viruses, for example, suggests that they need to

be understood in terms of biological processes. In short, they constitute a form

of natural hazard, rather than a ‘man-made’ risk. On the other hand, within

public health there is an increasing tendency to understand emerging

infections, not simply as biologically produced threats, but, to an extent, as

‘man-made’ risks, generated by human agency. According to such views,

changing human behaviour and activities are contributing substantially to the

emergence, re-emergence and spread of infections through, for example,

environmental degradation, human migration and war. In this context, biology

becomes, at least in part, framed as a ‘manufactured risk’, which Giddens �drawing on Beck � understands as a fundamental transformation wrought by

science and technology on nature:

For hundreds of years, people worried about what nature could do to us �earthquakes, floods, plagues, bad harvests and so on. At a certain point,

somewhere over the past fifty years or so, we stopped worrying so much about

what nature could do to us, and we started worrying more about what we have

done to nature.

(Giddens, 1999, p. 3).

The biologization of the financial crisis, which is implicit in pervasive analogies

of cascading financial shocks with ‘contagion’, reclaims risk as a natural hazard

10 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 12: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

or, at the least, as a form of ‘external risk’. The association of this risk with

semi-industrialized, ‘emerging market’ settings is not fortuitous since, as

Giddens argues, ‘external risk’ dominated ‘the first two hundred years of the

existence of industrial society’ (1999, p. 4). However, the integration of

economic models into public health, recasts natural hazards or external risks as

a form of ‘manufactured risk’ which, for Giddens, heralds ‘the end of nature’

(1999, p. 3).16

Rethinking financial networks: ecology and infection

In 2009, different aspects of the interrelationship between the financial crisis

and the H1N1 pandemic were evoked by economists, policy-makers, public

health officials and other actors. Margaret Chan, Director-General of the

WHO, herself made a connection between the two events in an address to the

World Health Assembly in May 2009, where she pointed to ‘a world out of

balance’, in which ‘radically increased interdependence among nations, their

financial markets, economies, and trade systems’ was responsible for

producing crises. This was a view expressed earlier by critics of global

capitalism, who had drawn links between the ‘viral apocalypse’ of twenty-first-

century emerging diseases and the financial system. According to Davis

(2005), for example, the spread of H5N1 across Southeast Asia, which first

infected humans in Hong Kong in 1997, was in large part the result of

burgeoning slums, agribusiness and the fast food industry, as well as the

skewed commercial priorities of Big Pharma. Tackling ‘emerging diseases’,

such as the H5N1 influenza or Severe acute respiratory syndrome (SARS),

was thus as much about reconfiguring financial and economic systems as it was

about global health resources.

In addition, the cost of the 2009 pandemic was much discussed, as was the

extent to which the fallout from the pandemic would exacerbate the global

recession. Economic policy was also identified as a factor in the amplification

of the crisis into a pandemic. For example, some commentators argued that the

restructuring of the Mexican economy in response to financial crises in the

1980s and 1990s was responsible for the Mexican government’s public health

failure in monitoring the transmission of the disease. According to such

arguments, Mexico’s integration into the global market and a neoliberal

development agenda to balance its public finances had led to the decentraliza-

tion and privatization of the health sector. As a result, the central government

lacked the ability to collect data about the new virus with sufficient speed

(Kuepfer Thakkar, 2009).

Noticeable in public health responses and media coverage were ‘twin

impulses’, particularly in the US (King, 2002, p. 772). On the one hand, there

was a territorial impulse to locate the ‘origins’ of disease ‘outside’ the nation,

making use of epidemiological models premised on securing borders. On the

other hand, there was an integrationist, non-territorial impulse, which

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 11

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 13: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

conceptualized the dissemination of disease and prophylactic strategies in terms

of network systems. As King has argued, the ‘emerging disease worldview’

combined an ‘obsession with boundaries’, mapping and territoriality, with

‘an increasing emphasis on information and commodity exchange networks’. In

short, it perpetuated an ‘ideal of territoriality while simultaneously seizing on

de-territorialization as a response’ (King, 2002, pp. 763, 772).

Given that ‘modern financial systems exhibit a high degree of interdepen-

dence’, networks function as a convenient ways of representing ‘a collection of

nodes and the links between them’ (Allen & Babus, 2009 [2008], pp. 367�8).

As previously discussed, from the global spillover of the Asian crisis in the late

1990s, there has been increasing interest in developing a network framework

for explaining and evaluating these economic phenomena. Network analysis,

for example, as Allen and Babus have suggested, ‘may help address two types

of questions: the effect of the network structure and the process of network

formation’ (2009, p. 369). In April 2009, as the first instances of influenza were

being reported in the US and Mexico, Andrew Haldane, Executive Director of

the Bank of England, delivered a speech in Amsterdam on ‘Rethinking the

financial network’.17 He began by drawing a detailed equivalence between

the outbreak of SARS in Guangdong Province, China, in November 2002 and

the Lehman Brothers filing for Chapter 11 bankruptcy in a New York

courtroom in September 2008. For Haldane, both crises revealed fundamental

aspects of adaptive global networks under stress. First, they accentuated the

role of the 24/7 contemporary media and communication systems in

transmitting fear. Second, they pointed to the ‘adaptive’ nature of networks

which ‘are driven by interactions between optimizing, but confused, agents’

(Haldane, 2009, p. 3). Adopting a form of complex network theory, and the

analysis of financial systems in terms of dynamic ecosystems prone to flip

through ‘tipping points’ into states of instability (May et al., 2008), Haldane

extended his comparison with other epidemics, including HIV/AIDS, drawing

connections between historical responses to pestilence (quarantine and flight),

which determine rates of transmission, and responses to financial crises (the

hoarding of liquidity and the flight from infected assets):

In the present financial crisis the flight is of capital, not humans. Yet the scale

and contagious consequences may be no less damaging. This financial epidemic

may endure in the memories long after SARS has been forgotten. But in halting

the spread of future financial epidemics, it is important that the lessons from

SARS and from other non-financial networks are not forgotten.

(Haldane, 2009, p. 31)

Haldane observed that, within interconnected networks, risk is shared

through diversification, until the system tilts ‘the wrong side of the knife-

edge’, at which point interconnections serve as shock-amplifiers, rather than

dampeners. Risk-spreading, which leads to fragility, then prevails, highlighting

the ‘small world’ feature of networks which intensify local shocks across the

12 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 14: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

system (Haldane, 2009, pp. 9�10). Haldane suggested that the WHO’s Global

Outbreak Alert and Response Network (GOARN) � a technical collaboration

of institutions and networks established in 2000 to pool human and technical

resources for the rapid identification, confirmation and response to disease

outbreaks � could serve as a model for how the risks of a financial crisis might

be identified and managed.18

More recently, Haldane, collaborating with May, has sought to develop these

ideas further by exploring the interplay between complexity and stability in

‘banking ecosystems’, specifically in relation to the pricing of derivatives and

the management of risk. Haldane and May seek to build upon earlier work,

including the conference organized in May 2006 by the US National

Academies, the National Research Council and the Federal Reserve, to

reconsider risk within complex adaptive systems. This conference brought

together experts from the financial sector with those working within science,

including biology (Kambhu et al., 2007; May et al., 2008). In the wake of 2007,

Haldane and May’s purpose is to draw further lessons for the ways in which

bank failure is generated within an intrafinancial system by using models

developed to explain, for example, the networks within which infectious

diseases spread and ecological food webs, with the ultimate purpose of

minimizing systemic risk. They suggest that economic thinking continues to

assume a natural ‘equilibrium’ and has much to learn from the shift that took

place within ecology where, in the 1970s, a ‘balance of nature’ approach gave

way to a more complex model of stability and instability within a network

structure of interactions (Haldane & May, 2011, p. 351).

Acknowledging the ‘deliberately over-simplified’ nature of the models they

are proposing for the propagation of bank failures or ‘shock’, Haldane and May

also highlight ‘major differences between ecosystems and financial systems’:

For one thing, today’s ecosystems are the winnowed survivors of long-lasting

evolutionary processes, whereas the evolution of financial systems is a relatively

recent phenomenon. Nor have selective pressures been entirely dispassionate,

with the hand of government a constant presence shaping financial structures,

especially among institutions deemed ‘too big to fail’. In financial ecosystems,

evolutionary forces have often been survival of the fattest rather than the

fittest.

(Haldane & May, 2011, p. 351)

Even as they point to differences and analogic limitations, however, Haldane

and May argue for the usefulness of these ‘over-simplified’ ecological models

for understanding the dynamic response to perturbations within banking.

Citing the study of epidemiological networks in Anderson and May’s Infectious

diseases of humans: Transmission and control (1991), they evoke the concept of

the ‘super-spreader’, applied to infectious diseases such as HIV/AIDS, as a

focus for preventive action ‘to limit the potential for system-wide spread’.

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 13

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 15: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

Alluding to the failure of Lehman Brothers in October 2008, they note how

‘super-spreaders’ are a source of ‘system-wide risk’, further commenting:

If anything, this same logic [of super-spreaders] applied with even greater force

in banking. There has been a spectacular rise in the size and concentration of the

financial system over the past two decades, with the rapid emergence of ‘super-

spreader institutions’ too big, connected or important to fail.

(Haldane & May, 2011, p. 354)

While the authors recognize the simplified approximations of such analogies

between networks of infectious disease and financial systems � conceding the

shortcomings of their model, which is focused on ‘theoretical concepts’ and

requires ‘improvements’ in order ‘to be more realistic’ � nonetheless, these

analogies are progressively literalized, so that, in effect, the one becomes the

other. The point is not to argue, here, as Johnson does, for example, in his

critique of Haldane and May, that ‘standard models of ecological food webs,

disease spreading and networks’ do not provide sufficiently flexible or

calibrated models for evaluating financial-market risk within a dynamic regime

‘in which the character of both the links and nodes can change on the same

timescale’ (Johnson, 2011, p. 302). Rather, the issue is whether selected parts

of one model can ever be meaningfully extrapolated and appropriated, given

that it is precisely the complex interactions between individual agents on a

micro-scale and the collective repercussions of those actions across networks

that define complex non-linear systems. There is, in short, a significant

difference between deep analogies of complex adaptive systems and the kinds

of general macro-scale comparisons between epidemics and financial panic,

public health measures to quarantine infection and regulatory efforts to

decouple ‘contagious’ elements within financial networks.

Conclusion: contagion, shock and risk

It might be argued that analogies and metaphors ‘not only help to make science

and technology comprehensible to nonspecialists, they can also guide scientific

work’ (Wyatt, 2004, p. 244). Hodgson (1993, pp. 18�21) contends that

metaphors perform an important function in economics, where they help to

extend ‘knowledge of poorly understood phenomena by means of those that are

better understood’ (Miller, 1996, p. 218). Analogies may provide original

perspectives on familiar problems, producing novel analyses that challenge

narrow assumptions. Bronk (2009) argues that a broader ‘analytic repertoire’

that draws on literature and the humanities is required to model the

complexity and non-rational aspects of the markets.

Yet analogical mapping between two phenomena (biological and financial

systems) and the ‘adaptations’ and ‘translations’ involved when concepts and

technical terms from epidemiology are integrated into economics (Sell, 2001,

14 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 16: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

p. 120) have practical consequences. By way of conclusion, the aim in the

final section of this paper is to consider the implications for policy and

public debate of applying epidemiological models to elucidate financial

interactions.

Post-2008, as we have seen, there has been considerable debate about how to

estimate the propagation of financial distress and the ways to evaluate network

influences. In a recent paper on systemic risk in financial networks, for

example, Cohen-Cole et al. point out that different approaches developed

within financial theory have so far been unable ‘to capture the precise cascade in

behavior that occurs between interconnected agents’ (in press, p. 3) during a

shock. It is in the context of the limitations in existing financial risk models

that the authors make use of risk-modelling in the epidemiological literature

which focuses on system-wide effects and interactions between network

properties and the dynamics of the processes within those networks. As Cohen-

Cole et al. observe, ‘These kind of studies are particularly useful to define

suitable procedures to stop the propagation of epidemics . . . the corollary of

which in financial crisis is obvious’ (in press, p. 4).

In what sense, however, is the diffusion of a disease an ‘obvious’ corollary of

a financial shock? Communicable diseases can be clearly classified and have

specific aetiologies; they are caused by pathogenic agents (such as viruses or

bacteria) and, depending on the agent, are spread in a number of ways,

including through vector organisms, body fluids or airborne inhalation. How

can different shocks be thus differentiated? Is the shock itself the pathogenic

agent? Or is the infective agent the cause of the shock? These basic but

essential questions are obscured by a corollary that appears to Cohen-Cole

et al. not only ‘obvious’ but ‘intellectually compelling’.

Yet, even as they seek to integrate two empirical risk models (epidemiolo-

gical and financial), they acknowledge that they are borrowing from ‘seemingly

unrelated’ fields and they note the critical differences between biomedical and

financial channels: ‘Even though the channels of propagation of financial

distress are different from those of medical diseases, those models may be

helpful to understand the dynamics of the financial system, as well as to devise

efficient and fast actions for the protection of financial networks against

shocks’ (Cohen-Cole et al., in press, pp. 4�5).

Thus, while the argument that they develop is ‘highly technical’ in nature,

involving equation-based computations of systemic risk, their central argument

is parenthesized by a series of equivocations about the value of analogical

mapping and concessions about the fundamental discrepancies between the two

risk models. They conclude their paper by conceding that to understand

networks and systemic risk in financial markets would require a type of ‘analysis

that is specific to the actual network structure of the market and reflects the

incentives present in the market’ (Cohen-Cole et al., in press, p. 24). It would

also need much more exact information, they note, including the identification

of systemically important institutions, further data on the constitutive influence

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 15

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 17: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

of regulatory interventions on market structure and an understanding of the

impact of central bank policy on market prices and liquidity.

The paper by Cohen-Cole et al. exemplifies a number of theoretical

manoeuvres that characterize analyses of financial markets, particularly post-

2008. First, there is the admission of the inadequacy of financial models;

second, ‘useful’ models are identified from the epidemiological literature of

infectious disease with implications for market policy-makers; third, the

differences between these models are acknowledged, even as these differences

are obscured by ‘highly technical’ arguments; last, the limitations of the model

are recognized, given the particularities of market networks and the absence of

relevant and sufficient data.

Although they draw on epidemiological models in their Bank of England

report, Gai and Kapadia, too, see fundamental differences between biological

contagion and financial distress, pointing to the fact that, whereas in

epidemiological models higher connectivity creates more pathways for disease

to spread, in financial systems greater connectivity provides a counteracting

risk-sharing benefit (Gai & Kapadia, 2010, p. 9).19 Similarly, despite the

recurrence of biomedical analogies in their account of the 2008 crisis, Roubini

and Mihm acknowledge that there are complications in transferring informa-

tion between disciplines, remarking that ‘the contagion metaphor, so

frequently invoked, does not fully explain the crisis’ (2010, p. 116).

Notwithstanding this admission, Roubini and Mihm (2010) structure a

critical section of their argument around such concepts as ‘pandemic’ and

disease ‘vector’, alluding to the ripple effect of shock through channels that

‘[infect] otherwise healthy sectors of other countries’ economies’. There is

considerable confusion in their argument between terms such as ‘contagion’,

‘disease’, ‘infection’ and between an understanding of the causal agent and of

the mechanisms of transmission.20 Analogue terms which carry precise

technical meanings in their ‘original’ context are distorted. The blurring of

critical focus exposes the limitations of the epidemiological analogy in their

financial analysis, confirming McCloskey’s observation that ‘unexamined

metaphor’ can become ‘a substitute for thinking’ (1998 [1985], p. 46).

Epidemiological risk modelling ‘defined as the formal, quantitative estima-

tion of the probability of specified adverse effects from defined hazards’ (Vose,

2008, quoted in Woolhouse, 2011, p. 2048) is clearly of interest to financial

theorists because its findings have been successfully integrated into public

health policy and proven highly effective in the control, management and

prevention of infectious disease. However, as we have noted above, infectious

disease is by no means an ‘obvious’ corollary of financial shock, while the

control and prevention of specific infections cannot be compared with

regulatory interventions in the market, given that the cause and nature of

the shock remains ambiguous.

By the same token, translations of epidemiological models into analyses of

financial markets tend to ignore ongoing debates in epidemiology about the

disadvantages of non-linear event-specific forms of modelling work, including

16 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 18: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

agent-based or individual-based computational models of human and animal

disease. As Woolhouse (2011, p. 2049) argues, when geared to specific events,

such models lack generality and are therefore difficult to ‘translate’ to different

settings; individual-based models are complex, hard to parametrize and require

a large amount of detailed data.

Conceptualizing financial shock as a form of ‘contagion’ creates fear and

expectations in the public and therefore influences policy. There is a danger, as

Yago (2003 [1999], pp. 94�5) has suggested, that fear displaces critical analysis.

In both the 1997 Asia crisis and the ‘Credit Crunch’ of 2008 the language of

contagion and an emotive narrative of lethal disease emergence and diffusion

predicated on ‘super-spreaders’, ‘hot zones’ and virulent ‘micro-agents’ served

to constrain thinking and responses. Amplified in popular culture, where the

‘pandemic thriller’ has become an established genre, the construction of market

turbulence as a form of contagion fuelled panic with its implicit equivalence of

death by microbe and financial ruin.21 As an editorial in the New York Times

(‘Global markets’ lethal magic’, 1999b) remarked in the context of the alarm

trigged by the spectre of ‘deadly’ financial contagion in the late 1990s, ‘there

needs to be greater understanding of the broad social and political implications

of economic theory’.

On the one hand, then, the notion of financial distress as contagion triggers

panic and volatility. On the other hand, the analogy also gives rise to

expectations that, as in public health, tools exist to tackle the spread of market

turbulence. The pressure to find solutions is increasingly feeding back into

academic discourse from the mainstream media. As models in epidemiology

and public health have proven effective in the past to manage and prevent

pandemics, it is perhaps no wonder that economists are turning to

epidemiology to look for ways of containing ‘infection’. Yet, as this paper

has sought to show, arguments about the contagious nature of financial shock

are made even in the face of evidence that non-linear epidemiological models

have clear limitations for extrapolated use in other than highly specific disease

settings.

In addition, contagion reframes financial instability as a form of pathogeni-

city, thereby re-inscribing socio-cultural and economic relationships as biology.

At a time when there is considerable public focus on the behaviour of bankers

and on the culture of bonuses and incentives in the financial service sector, as

well as on issues of corporate governance and accountability, the idea of

‘contagion’ removes human agency and therefore culpability. Perturbations are

the result of pathogenic causal agents � and do not involve the interplay of

human actions, determined by specific motivations. Further, analogizing

distress as shock suggests that ‘those who fall prey to financial crises do so

through no fault of their own’, whereas, on the contrary, ‘speculators appear

to discriminate in choosing the countries they attack’ (Dungey & Tambakis,

2003, p. 1).

Finally, identifying emerging infectious diseases with ‘emerging markets’

as spheres of high return but higher risk effectively recasts biology in

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 17

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 19: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

politico-economic terms. As Wald has argued, the discourse of ‘emerging

disease’, like the ‘outbreak narrative’, represents a form of ‘thirdworldifica-

tion’ (2008, p. 270) and a continuation of the ‘epidemiological cartography’ of

the post-Second World War CDC which imagined the world in terms of a

binary opposition between the modern and the pre-modern, the clean and

the dirty, the hygienic and the infectious (Ostherr, 2005).

Within contagion theory, globalization is construed in terms of fragmenta-

tion and threat, therein implicitly � if not explicitly � re-affirming the salutary

coherence of national space as a necessary antidote.22 This discourse of

emergence identifies East Asia, Latin America and Africa as the weak links in

an interdependent world � projecting them as high-risk, high-profit places in

which disease, poverty and financial corruption ‘emerge’ to destabilize the

First World. A challenge to this model was the fact that the financial crisis of

2008 had little to do with ‘emerging markets’. On the contrary, it was the result

of a bubble in the US sub-prime mortgage market. Similarly, the ‘emerging

disease’ was not an importation from Southern China, which, according to

Newsweek ‘delivers new flu viruses to the world most years’ (quoted in Wald,

2008, p. 5). On the contrary, it was a mutation that took place in the US’s ‘back

yard’.

A recurrent theme in accounts of the 2008 financial crisis is the obligation to

rethink inherited views as a prerequisite to finding new solutions for dealing

with risk and the instabilities produced within an intrafinancial system.

Reflecting on the ‘Credit Crunch’, Stiglitz has expressed a hope that the ‘Great

Recession’ might ‘lead to changes in the realm of policies and in the realm of

ideas’ (2010, p. xiii). This paper has argued that such changes ‘in the realm of

ideas’ must entail a re-examination of the analogical reasoning that has shaped

financial thinking over the last 30 years, and, more specifically, since the Asian

financial crisis of 1997. In particular, it must involve a questioning of

the increasingly widespread use of epidemiological models in financial theory

to elucidate the dynamics of � and systemic risk posed by � turmoil in the

markets. Such models, this paper has suggested, obscure more than they

illuminate, while setting up fears and expectations that are increasingly

constraining the parameters of public debate.

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank my colleagues in the Journalism and Media Studies

Centre at the University of Hong Kong for co-sponsoring the panel

‘Constructing pandemics’ as part of the international conference ‘One year

into the pandemic: Perspectives on risk and crisis communication’. I am

grateful, in particular, to Thomas Abraham, Charles L. Briggs and Lisa

Cartwright for participating in the conversation, and also to Maria Sin. Finally,

I am grateful to the three anonymous reviewers who read earlier drafts of this

paper and offered helpful suggestions.

18 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 20: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

Notes

1 The term ‘Credit Crunch’ was included in the Oxford Concise Dictionary in 2008;see Mizen (2008, p. 531). The influenza outbreak was declared a ‘pandemic’ in June2009. See Margaret Chan’s (2009) statement: http://www.who.int/mediacentre/news/statements/2009/h1n1_pandemic_phase6_20090611/en/index.html2 For an account of the ‘contagiousness’ of the contagion metaphor in criticaldiscourse across the humanities, the medical sciences and the social sciences, seeMitchell (forthcoming).3 On the normative aspect of ‘metaphors’ in economics, see Wyatt (2004, pp. 246�7).4 See also WHO (1996).5 See also Edwards, who notes: ‘A search of the EconLit data set for 1969�February2000, yielded 147 entries that had the word ‘‘contagion’’ in either the title or in theabstract. Of these, only 17 corresponded to works published before 1990’ (2000, p. 1).6 On the history of economic crises analogized as disease, as well as the equation ofsickness with economic ‘disturbances’ and ‘contagionist’ debates, see Besomi (2011).7 Smith (2006) considers the role played by risk � and particularly the perception ofrisk � in the economic fallout from Severe acute respiratory syndrome (SARS) in 2003.The epidemic had an estimated global macro-economic impact of US$30 to 100 billion,a far higher economic shock than anticipated given the health impact.8 Robert May was formerly Chief Scientific Advisor to the UK government and Headof the Office of Science and Technology (1995�2000).9 See http://www.emergingeconomyreport.com10 For an historic perspective on banking failure in this context, see Calomiris (2007).11 See the articles that appeared in the New York Times on the ‘contagion effect’under the heading ‘Global contagions: A narrative (networked economies, stuntedlives)’ (1999a).12 See the different definitions of ‘contagion’ on the World Bank website: http://www.worldbank.org13 See http://wwwnc.cdc.gov/eid/pages/background-goals.htm14 For further commentary on this passage and the origins of the ‘emerging diseasesworldview’, see King (2002, p. 767).15 Giddens (1999, p. 1) opens his paper ‘Risk and responsibility’ by suggestingconnections between the outbreak of BSE, the Lloyds insurance crisis and the collapseof Barings Bank in the early to mid-1990s.16 The confusion between ‘manufactured’ and biological hazards is also evident in thecontemporary equation of terrorist attacks with pandemics: both are increasingly beingframed as ‘security threats’ that jeopardize the operations of the state. See, for example,Mun (2005), Muntean (2009) and Weiss (2009).17 On Haldane, who is executive director of financial stability and the Bank ofEngland’s ‘radical house intellectual’, see Pryke (2011).18 See: http://www.who.int/csr/outbreaknetwork/en/19 See, however, the argument presented by Battiston et al. (2009), who questionwhether the diversification of risk leads to a more stable financial situation.20 On the confusion between contagion and the evidence of contagion, see Kolb(2011, p. 4) and on the tension between disease and mechanism of transmission, seeClaessens and Forbes, who also note that analogies between the spread of infectiousdisease and financial crises ‘are often overdone’ (2001, p. 4).21 This is a coalescence which Wald has termed the ‘outbreak narrative’ (2008). Forexamples of popular narratives that conflate financial loss, social disorder and pandemic,see Steven Soderbergh’s 2011 movie Contagion.22 See, however, the argument against so-called ‘viral sovereignty’ presented byHolbrooke and Garrett in The Washington Post (2008).

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 19

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 21: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

References

Agtmael, A. V. (2007). The emergingmarkets century: How a new breed of world-class companies is overtaking the world. NewYork: Simon & Schuster.Allen, F. & Babus, A. (2009 [2008]).Networks in finance. In P. R. Kleindorfer,Y. Wind & R. E. Gunther (Eds), Thenetwork challenge: Strategy, profit, and riskin an interlinked world (pp. 367�82).Upper Saddle River, NJ: WhartonBusiness Publishing/Pearson Education.Anderson, R. M. & May, R. M. (1991).Infectious diseases of humans: Dynamics andcontrol. Oxford and New York: OxfordUniversity Press.Battiston, S., Gatti, D. D., Gallegati,M., Greenwald, B. C., & Stiglitz, J. E.(2009). Liaisons dangereuses: Increasingconnectivity, risk sharing, and systemicrisk. NBER Working Paper, 15611.Cambridge, MA: National Bureau ofEconomic Research. Retrieved fromhttp://www.nber.org/papers/w15611Beck, U. (1992). Risk society: Towards anew modernity. London: Sage.Bell, D. & Kristol, I. (Eds.). (1981). Thecrisis in economic theory. New York: BasicBooks.Besomi, D. (2011). Crises as a disease ofthe body politick: A metaphor in thehistory of nineteenth-century economics.Journal of the History of Economic Thought,33(1), 67�118.Bronk, R. (2009). The romantic economist:Imagination in economics. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.Brownlie, J., Peckham, C., Waage, J.,Woolhouse, M., Lyall, C., Meagher, L.,et al. (2006). Foresight: Infectious diseases:Preparing for the future: Future threats.London: Office of Science andInnovation.Caballero, R. J. & Simsek, A. (2009).Complexity and financial panics. NBERWorking Paper, 14997. Cambridge, MA:National Bureau of Economic Research,May� June. Retrieved from: http://www.nber.org/papers/w14997Calomiris, C. W. (2007). Bank failuresin theory and history: The GreatDepression and other ‘contagious’ events.

NBR Working Paper, 13597. Cambridge,MA: National Bureau of EconomicResearch. Retrieved from: http://www.nber.org/papers/w13597Chan, M. (2009). Concern over flupandemic justified. Speech to the 62ndWorld Health Assembly, Geneva, 18 May.Retrieved from http://www.who.int/dg/speeches/2009/62nd_assembly_address_20090518/en/index.htmlCheung, L., Tam, C. & Szeto, J. (2009).Contagion of financial crises: A literaturereview of theoretical and empiricalframeworks. Hong Kong MonetaryAuthority. Research Note, 02/2009, 8 June.Retrieved from http://www.hkma.gov.hk/media/eng/publication-and-research/research/research-notes/RN-02-2009.pdfClaessens, S. & Forbes, K. (2001).International financial contagion: Anoverview of the issues and the book. InS. Claessens & K. Forbes (Eds),International financial contagion (pp. 3�18). Dordrecht and London: Kluwer.Cohen-Cole, E., Kirilenko, A. &Patacchini, E. (in press). Strategicinteractions on financial networks for theanalysis of systemic risk. In J-P. Fouque &J. Langsam (Eds), Handbook of systemicrisk. Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress. Draft available at: http://www.rhsmith.umd.edu/doit/docs/CohenColeEtAl.pdfDavis, M. (2005). The monster at our door:The global threat of avian flu. New York:New Press.Diamond, J. (1997). Guns, germs, andsteel: The fates of human societies. NewYork: Norton.Dungey, M. & Tambakis, D. (2003).International financial contagion: What dowe know? Working Paper, 9. Cambridge:Cambridge Endowment for Research inFinance, Judge Institute of Management,University of Cambridge. Retrievedfrom http://www-cfap.jbs.cam.ac.uk/publications/index.htmlEdwards, S. (2000). Contagion. Revisedversion of the World Economy Lecture,University of Nottingham, 28 October1999. Retrieved from http://www.ander-

20 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 22: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

son.ucla.edu/faculty/sebastian.edwards/world_economy5.pdfFavero, C. A. & Giavazzi, F. (2002). Isthe international propagation of financialshocks non-linear? Evidence from theERM. Journal of International Economics,51(1), 231�46.Gai, P. & Kapadia, S. (2010).Contagion in financial networks. WorkingPaper, 383, March. London: Bank ofEngland. Retrieved from http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/workingpapers/wp383.pdfGarrett, L. (1995). The coming plague:Newly emerging diseases in a world out ofbalance. London and New York: Penguin.Geithner, T. (2008). Actions by the NewYork Fed in response to liquiditypressures in financial markets. Testimonybefore the US Senate Committee onBanking, Housing and Urban Affairs,Washington, DC, delivered 3 May.Federal Reserve Bank of New York.Retrieved from http://www.newyorkfed.org/newsevents/speeches/2008/gei080403.htmlGerstman, B. B. (1998). Epidemiologykept simple: An introduction to traditionaland modern epidemiology. New York: Wiley.Giddens, A. (1999). Risk andresponsibility. Modern Law Review, 62(1),1�10.Global contagions: A narrative(networked economies, stunted lives.(1999). New York Times, 15�18 February.Global markets’ lethal magic:Editorial. (1999). New York Times, 21February.Haldane, A. G. (2009). Rethinking thefinancial network. Speech delivered at theFinancial Student Association,Amsterdam, 28 April. Retrieved fromhttp://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2009/speech386.pdfHaldane, A. G. & May, R. M. (2011).Systemic risk in banking ecosystems.Nature, 469(7330), 351�5.Hernandez, L. F. & Valdes, R. O.(2001). What drives contagion: Trade,neighbourhood, or financial links? IMFWorking Paper, 01/29. InternationalMonetary Fund. Retrieved from http://

www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2001/wp0129.pdfHodgson, G. M. (1993). Economics andevolution: Bringing life back into economics.Ann Arbor, MI: University of MichiganPress.Institute of Medicine (IOM) (1997).American’s vital interest in global health:Protecting our people, enhancing oureconomy, and advancing our nationalinterests. Washington, DC: NationalAcademies Press.Jackson, K. D. (Ed.) (1999). Asiancontagion: The causes and consequences of afinancial crisis. Boulder, CO: WestviewPress.Johnson, N. (2011). Proposing policy byanalogy is risky. Nature, 469(7330), 302.Kambhu, J., Weidman, S. & Krishnan,N. (Eds.). (2007). New directions forunderstanding systemic risk. Washington,DC: National Academies Press.King, N. B. (2002). Security, disease,commerce: Ideologies of postcolonialglobal health. Social Studies of Science,32(5�6), 763�89.Knobler, S., Mahmoud, A. & Lemon,S. (2006). The impact of globalization oninfectious disease emergence and control:Exploring the consequences and opportunities.Washington, DC: National AcademiesPress.Kolb, R. W. (2011). Financial contagion:The viral threat to the wealth of nations.New York: Wiley.Krugman, P. (2008). The return ofdepression economics and the crisis of 2008.London and New York: Penguin.Kuepfer Thakkar, S. (2009).Globalization goes viral. InternationalRelations and Security Network, 26August.Last, J. M. (Ed.) (2001). A dictionary ofepidemiology (4th edn). Oxford and NewYork: Oxford University Press.Lederberg, J., Shope, R. E., & OaksS. C. (Eds.) (1992). Emerging infections:Microbial threats to health in the UnitedStates. Washington, DC: NationalAcademies Press.Levine, R. (2006). Commentary: A curefor the Asian flu. Biosecurity andBioterrorism: Biodefense Strategy, Practice,and Science, 4(3), 228�30.

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 21

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 23: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

Lowell, J., Tong D. & Neu, C. R. (Eds.)(1998). Financial crises and contagion inemerging market countries. Santa Monica,CA: Rand.Masson, P. (1999). Contagion:Monsoonal effects, spillovers and jumpsbetween multiple equilibria. In P. Agenoret al. (Eds), The Asian financial crisis:Causes, contagion and consequences (pp.265�83). Cambridge and New York:Cambridge University Press.May, R., Levin, S. A. & Sugihara, G.(2008). Complex systems: Ecology forbankers. Nature, 451(7181), 893�5.McCloskey, D. N. (1998 [1985]). Therhetoric of economics. Madison, WI:University of Wisconsin Press.Meyers, L. A. (2007). Contact networkepidemiology: Bond percolation applied toinfectious disease prediction and control.Bulletin of the American MathematicalSociety, 44(1), 63�86.Miller, A. (1996). Insights of genius:Imagery and creativity in science and art.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Mirowski, P. (1989). More heat than light:Economics as social physics, physics asnature’s economics. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.Mitchell, P. (forthcoming). Contagiousmetaphor. London and New York:Continuum.Mizen, P. (2008). The credit crunch of2007�2008: A discussion of thebackground, market reactions, and policyresponses. Federal Reserve Bank of St.Louis Review, 90(5), 531�67. Retrievedfrom: http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/08/09/Mizen.pdfMun, K. C. (2005). Contagion andimpulse response of international stockmarkets around the 9-11 terroristattacks. Global Finance Journal, 16(1),48�68.Muntean, N. (2009). Viral terrorism andterrifying viruses: The homologicalconstruction of the ‘war on terror’ andthe avian flu pandemic. InternationalJournal of Media and Cultural Politics,5(3), 199�216.Newman, M. E. J. (2002). The spread ofepidemic disease on networks. PhysicalReview E, 66(1).

The New York Times. (1999a). Globalcontagions: A narrative (networkedeconomies, stunted lives). 15�18February.The New York Times. (1999b). Globalmarkets’ lethal magic: Editorial. 21February.Ogum, G. (2010). Equity volatilitytransmission and contagion between theUS and emerging stock markets: The roleof the US subprime crisis. Paper presentedat the Southwestern Finance AssociationMeeting, Dallas, Texas, 2�6 March,pp. 1�13. Retrieved from http://southwesternfinance.org/conf-2010/G5-2.pdfOstherr, K. (2005). Cinematicprophylaxis: Globalization and contagion inthe discourse of world health. Durham, NC:Duke University Press.Park, S. (1991). Bank failure contagion inhistorical perspective. Journal of MonetaryEconomics, 28(2), 271�86.Preston, R. (1994). The hot zone. NewYork: Random House.Pryke, M. (2011). Introducing AndrewHaldane. Journal of Cultural Economy,4(4), 365�9.Rigobon, R. (2003). On the measurementof the international propagation ofshocks: Is the transmission stable?Journal of International Economics, 61(2),261�83.Roberts, J. (Ed.) (2006). The economics ofinfectious disease. Oxford and New York:Oxford University Press.Roubini, N. (2008). The coming financialpandemic. Foreign Policy, 165(March�April), 44�8.Roubini, N. & Mihm, S. (2010). Crisiseconomics: A crash course in the future offinance. London: Penguin.Ruccio, D. F. (2008). Introduction: Whatare economic representations and what’sat stake? In D. F. Ruccio (Ed.), Economicrepresentations: Academic and everyday (pp.1�32). London and New York: Routledge.Sell, F. L. (2001). Contagion in financialmarkets. Aldershot and Lyme, NH:Edward Elgar.Sheng, A. (2011 [2010]). Financial crisisand global governance: A networkanalysis. In M. Spence & D. Leipziger(Eds), Globalization and growth

22 Economy and Society

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3

Page 24: Economies of contagion:financial crisis and pandemic

implications for a post-crisis world (pp. 69�94). Washington, DC: World Bank.Shiller, R. J. (2008). Infectiousexuberance. The Atlantic (July�August).Retrieved from http://www.theatlantic.com/magazine/archive/2008/07/infectious-exuberance/6839/Smith, R. D. (2006). Responding toglobal infectious disease outbreaks:Lessons from SARS on the role of riskperception, communication andmanagement. Journal of Social Science andMedicine, 63(12), 3113�23.Stiglitz, J. E. (2010). Freefall: America,free markets, and the sinking of the worldeconomy. New York: Norton.Valdes, R. (2000 [1997]). Emergingmarkets contagion: Evidence and theory.Working Papers, Central Bank of Chile,March. Retrieved from http://www.bcentral.cl/eng/studies/working-papers/007.htmVose, D. (2008). Risk analysis: Aquantitative guide (3rd edn.). Chichester:Wiley.Wald, P. (2008). Contagious: Cultures,carriers, and the outbreak narrative.Durham, NC: Duke University Press.The Washington Post. (2008).‘Sovereignty’ that risks global health. 10August.Waters, W. F. (2001). Globalization,socioeconomic restructuring, andcommunity health. Journal of CommunityHealth, 26(2), 79�92.

Weiss, N. E. (2009). Banking andfinancial infrastructure continuity:Pandemic flu, terrorism, and otherchallenges. CRS Report for Congress, 4May. Congressional Research Service7-5700; www.crs.gov. RL31873.Woolhouse, M. (2011). How to makepredictions about future infectious diseaserisks. Philosophical Transactions of theRoyal Society, 366(12 July), 2045�54.Woolhouse, M. & Gaunt, E. (2007).Ecological origins of novel humanpathogens. Critical Reviews ofMicrobiology, 33(4), 231�42.World Health Organization (WHO).(1996). Removing obstacles to healthydevelopment. Retrieved from http://www.who.int/infectious-disease-report/pages/textonly.htmlWyatt, S. (2004). Danger! Metaphors atwork in economics, geophysiology, and theinternet. Science, Technology, & HumanValues, 29(2), 242�61.Yago, G. (2003 [1999]). Private capitalflows, emerging economies, andinternational financial architecture. InW. Russell Mead & S. R. Schwenninger(Eds), The bridge to a global middle class:Development, trade and internationalfinance (pp. 85�124). Boston, MA, andDordrecht: Kluwer.Zimmer, S. M. & Burke, D. S. (2009).Historical perspective: Emergenceof influenza A (H1N1) viruses.New England Journal of Medicine, 361(3),279�85.

Robert Peckham is co-Director of the Centre for the Humanities and

Medicine at the University of Hong Kong, where he teaches in the Department

of History. He has held research fellowships at the university of Cambridge and

University of Oxford, and has been a visiting fellow at the London School of

Economics and Political Science. Forthcoming publications include the co-

edited volume Imperial contagions: Medicine, hygiene, and cultures of planning in

Asia, and the edited volume Disease and crime: A history of social pathologies and

the new politics of health. He is currently completing a monograph, Infective

economies, supported by a major award from the Research Grants Council of

Hong Kong.

Robert Peckham: Economies of contagion 23

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Yon

sei U

nive

rsity

] at

17:

47 0

5 M

arch

201

3