leaping and learning: strategies for taking agricultural ... · pdf fileleaping and learning:...

36
1 Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to Scale in Sub-Saharan Africa Workshop on linking farmers to markets in East Africa Nairobi, Wednesday 11 July 2012

Upload: dothuy

Post on 25-Mar-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

1

Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to Scale in Sub-Saharan Africa

Workshop on linking farmers to markets in East Africa

Nairobi, Wednesday 11 July 2012

Page 2: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

2

Contents

Introduction 3

Presentation from distinguished guest: Dr Wilson Songa, Agriculture Secretary, Ministry of

Agriculture, Government of Kenya 4

A framework for linking smallholders to market, Steve Wiggins, ODI 6

Case Study: Stephanie Hanson, One Acre Fund 10

Case Study: Agribusiness Value Chain Financing -The Case of Equity Bank 12

What works in linking smallholders to markets? 17

Summary of feedback and discussion from the first round of café tables 17

What needs to be done to promote links from smallholders to markets? Summary of feedback

and discussion from the first round of café tables 23

Summarising the day 26

Annex A: List of participants 28

Annex B Linking smallholders to markets: the issues 29

Page 3: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

3

Introduction

Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to Scale

Agriculture for Impact (A4I), the Overseas Development Institute (ODI), Firetail, and

the Glasshouse Partnership are working together on the project ‘Leaping and Learning:

Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to Scale’ funded by the Bill & Melinda Gates

Foundation and the UK’s Department for International Development.

The aim of the programme is to provide development partners with access to independent,

evidence-based recommendations that set out practical policy options and approaches for

scaling up smallholder agricultural development in sub-Saharan Africa to ensure food and

nutrition security and poverty reduction.

Our approach

A key challenge for agricultural development is how to link small-scale, family farmers to

providers of financial services, inputs, technical advice and marketing; thereby allowing

smallholders to innovate, invest and enjoy better livelihoods. Many government agencies, non-

governmental organisations, or private firms are working to facilitate such links. But there is

much to learn. This programme is reviewing such experiences, to distil good practice.

Stakeholder Evaluation

At the start of the project A4I commissioned Firetail to interview stakeholders who represented

the intended users of the Leaping and Learning project outputs both in OECD countries and

Sub-Saharan Africa. The purpose of these discussions was to explore how the materials could

be developed to ensure they were of maximum value to stakeholders and the sector as a

whole. 25 interviews were conducted between 2nd February and 9th March 2012. The Firetail

report findings have influenced our approach; you can read them at www.ag4impact.org.

Consultation

A4I and ODI are working with Food, Agriculture and Natural Resources Policy Analysis Network

(FANRPAN) to hold regional workshops in Johannesburg (9th July), Nairobi (11th July) and Accra

(13th July) to gather more evidence and seek feedback from agricultural development

practitioners in sub-Saharan Africa.

For more information please contact:

Liz Wilson, Deputy Director, Agriculture for Impact

[email protected]

www.ag4impact.org

Funded by

Page 4: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

4

Presentation from distinguished guest: Dr Wilson Songa, Agriculture Secretary, Ministry of Agriculture, Government of Kenya

This workshop comes at a good time.

It is a time when we are telling our small scale

producers that farming is no longer going to be

just a way of life: farming has to be a business.

And we cannot have farming as a business

without the markets.

In whatever small way, some marketing systems

are now undergoing rapid transformation.

Traditional market channels are being replaced

by much more coordinated links between

farmers, processors, and others.

This has been made possibly primarily by consumers. They are becoming more demanding

about food quality, safety, and changes in feeding habits — such as the younger generation in

Kenya that now prefers rice more than what used to be traditional foods like maize and beans,

partly because it takes less time and fuel to make rice. Most of the linkages with the farmers

have been established mainly by the buyers of farm produce, with little or no assistance from

agribusiness. To date, there has not been much emphasis on the need for activities to make

these linkages work; but things are now changing. Any farmer producing now has a market in

mind; aware of where the surplus will go. Even small-scale producers are now producing

surpluses owing to increases in productivity, coming from technological change — new seed,

fertiliser, and analysis of soil type. This makes the small-scale producer begin to play an active

role in the markets.

How do we ensure success? Linkages do not just happen: there are some requirements. Need

to ensure commitment from buyers. There has to be increased demand for coordinating the

productive process. So we are moving to a rather complex situation – how to achieve this?

Efficiency is one element. A value chain is as good as its weakest point. One of the weakest

points to date has been the marketing.

For buyers and producers, want to ensure that costs of production are lowered as much as

possible. Kenya is sending teams to learn from Ethiopian dairying, which is coming up very

efficiently using small scale production. Capacity building is required all along the value chain.

For small-scale producers this is an enormous task.

Agriculture should be driven essentially by non-state actors or the private sector. We will need

to have strategies to see that the production, processing, and the final market requirement are

met with a view to ensure sustainability.

Moreover, the challenge is not a one-off. We can have an excellent system one year, but our

experience here is that the next year then may be very different. So how do we then build in

the necessary resilience that is crucial for this kind of farming system?

So to ensure that food security is assured, we need also to ensure that production is as

diversified as possible. In most areas where food security has been achieved, there is

diversified production. In many communities where poverty has been overcome, this has been

a result of moving from mono-cropping to a much more diversified production — by spreading

risk, not merely depending on one commodity.

Which would be the success factors for linkages?

We expect that for producers to be successful, for buyers to be successful, we will have to

identify the appropriate skills for these groups. And this goes for the entire value chain. When

Page 5: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

5

it comes to capacity building, we must also bear in mind that agricultural cannot operate in

isolation. We must find a link to the other sectors; most importantly education, health, and

infrastructure. In the past agriculture linked well with health, but not with the others. Imagine

if from day one they had borne in mind nutrition, where would they be now?

If they had developed closely with the infrastructure sector—when the Ministry of Roads is

planning, we have to be in communication so roads are also planned for areas where we are

promoting crop production and investing in irrigation. That is how we enhance efficiency in the

whole system.

As for now I think in the public sector, we have come to acknowledge that we have not done

very well in aiding the private sector. Hence we are now in the process of seeing how to

facilitate non-state actors to play a more significant role.

One area where we are actually going quite far is the area of provision agricultural extension

service. This service need not be only provided by the public sector. A good example is

floriculture in Kenya, a flourishing export industry, where public extension is not significant.

This is to be expected in an industry where growers must respond immediately in a

competitive environment: they cannot wait for an extension officer to come and visit at home.

Therefore, extension service needs to be graduated; only those farmers who cannot afford it

should be provided with public extension service. As much as possible, let us move out of that

expectation of waiting to be given that free service.

We have only one day for this important workshop. It is up to us to make the best of it. When

you see Sir Gordon and Steve here you know this is serious business.

It is through linkages that we manage to achieve more.

It is true now there is some light coming from the African continent. It is up to us to make that

light shine brighter, or to have it remain as it is. We cannot afford to have it remain as it is.

Page 6: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

6

A framework for linking smallholders to market, Steve Wiggins, ODI

Powerpoint slides. Annex B gives a more detailed and revised account of the framework.

Development Aims

• Reduce poverty & hunger, MDG #1

• Smallholder development: highly effective [in

Low Income C]

No secrets for agricultural development!

• Rural Investment Climate

• Doesn’t have to be perfect!

• Rural Public Goods

• Roads, power, irrigation, etc.

• Education, Health, Water

• Research & Extension

• Link SF to markets for Produce, Inputs, Tech Assist, Finance

• [Overcome failures in rural markets]

Linking SF to Market

• Then: Parastatals

• Too often: High Cost, Inefficient, Politicised

• Now: Market

• Farmer groups & associations

• Private firms, agri-business

• NGOs

• Private foundations

• Gov’t agencies

So much learn from the diversity of experiences

Leaping & Learning

Review Lit.

Consult Stakeholders

Synthesise cases

[Report: Nov 2012]

Cases & Lit: Working Propositions

5 Key Issues

1. Right Environment

Private action struggles when:

(a) state failings

(b) shocks from outside world

— example of the collapse of

Page 7: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

7

cashew prices on world markets in 2004 that hit Mozambique processors

Opportunities can arise with reforms — see case of Rwanda: coffee when it was possible

from the mid-1990s to operate coffee as a business again without undue political

appropriation of profits

Policy implications?

Scan environment

Advocacy, but how to make case?

2. Right Markets

Demand: critical … moving target

Exports: great ... here is the case of Rwanda and the recovery of its exports, with rising unit

value as more coffee is sold as a premium, from former position of producing low quality

coffee.

BUT

Domestic markets > Exports

Larger

Growing Faster

Less Demanding & Less Risky

o Certification: is this a high cost trap?! Examples of smallholders being squeezed

out of export markets by GlobalGap requirements in Kenya, Senegal

o Ghana pineapples: gorwers hit hard when European market switched to MD2

variety that began to arrive from Costa Rica

But all is not necessarily lost. Coming Home: Kenya’s Green Beans — where an increasing

fraction of produce is destined for Nairobi and other domestic markets.

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Rwanda's coffee exports

Export Quantity (1000 tonnes)Export Value (Millions…

Page 8: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

8

How to keep track of demand?

When?

To change focus?

To diversify markets?

To move up from basics to higher value?

3. Right Focus

Important to focus on critical limits in the system: may be in production or marketing; may be

about trying to maximise output, quality or price; or about reducing risks in production and

marketing.

Maximise Output, Quality Limit Risk

Produce Produce more

Lower unit costs

Risks from weather, pests, disease

Diversify production

[may limit commercial prod’n]

Versatile varieties

Crop protection

Selling Sell for higher price

Higher quality that can

access premium markets

Risks from fluctuating prices, quality required,

traceability

Diversify markets, channels

[Hedge]

Right focus: questions

How to decide on what to focus?

When to reconsider, re-plan?

Sequences?

4.325

30.543

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

451990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Exports (thousands of tonnes)

Production minus exports

Production (thousands of tonnes)

Page 9: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

9

4. Right Grouping of smallholders

Information costs real & high

Aggregators essential, many models possible

Zambia: Dunavantcotton distributors: 65 SF each

Uganda: Mukwanooilseed industry farmer groups = 54k SF

Uganda: Kabale potato farmer association

What works? Why

But: few self-sustaining co-operatives!

Why not more?

Groups: social dilemma

Large firms work 1st with better-off SF

Dilemma: functioning groups, collectives may exclude poorest

A: Jobs on & off farm

Kenya SF green bean 15 jobs/ha

Burkina Fasoshea factory: 1,500 workers

Mozambique cashew factories, jobs in an area of high unemployment, with links to rest

of local economy, etc.

5. Right Approach

Build capacity, competence, change behaviour

Facilitate, Enable …

... Don’t substitute for private or collective action

But how to

pass learning thresholds?

Meet donor demands for visible results, next year, targets ticked?

Page 10: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

10

Case Study: Stephanie Hanson, One Acre Fund

Target farmers: the smallholders at the very base of the pyramid, living on under $2 USD per day.

One Acre serves over 130,000 smallholder

farmers in Kenya, Rwanda, and Burundi.

The organization focuses primarily on maize

and beans; although in Rwanda we are

beginning to work with coffee as well.

One Acre has a four-part service model:

1. Distribution of farm inputs within 2

kilometres of where farmers live

2. Financing

3. Extension

4. Market facilitation

Individual farmers obtain seed and fertiliser, financing, and information through a field officer.

These are not university trained agronomists, but they are local farmers themselves. There are

700 field officers from rural areas working in Kenya, Rwanda, Burundi, each serving about 225

farmers. They are full-time, salaried staff.

One Acre Fund farmers pay for extension services; they are part of the privatisation of

extension. Lessons are delivered to small groups of 30 to 50 farmers. Farmers are asked to

practice methods for their field officer during training sessions in the demonstration area to see

if they are adopting correctly.

Staple crops are the focus: we want to turn farmers from net food buyers to net food sellers,

so the focus is on surplus. Most farmers have never had a surplus. So when they produce

more, they need to store the surplus: keeping maize or beans in storage for up to 9 months.

Farmers might keep it for 5, 6, 7 months, then sell at higher prices, rather than having to sell

directly after harvest when the price is lowest.

Main benefit seen from the operating model is income generation: typically US$120 more in

income per year, or a doubling of farm income per planted acre. Compared to something like

horticulture it doesn’t seem like much, but for a farmer growing staple food crops this is a

significant increase in income. It allows them to diversify and mitigate risk.

What challenges does One Acre face? Staple food crops themselves: these are only one step

forward, they do not allow most farmers to make a business out of farming. When farmers

start saying they want to grow onions, raise poultry and so on, we have to link them to others

in the area who already have the expertise, or One Acre Fund has to develop the expertise

themselves.

Questions about operating model for One Acre

Q: In Rwanda are they associated with warehouse receipt systems?

A: No, One Acre not involved, but are interested.

Q: What kind of partnerships do you have across these 3 countries?

A: In Rwanda One Acre partners with the Ministry of Agriculture on a few different projects,

including fertilizer subsidy, a World Bank-funded land & water husbandry programme that

rebuilds terraces using a technique called radical terracing.

Also partners with Technoserve on coffee farmers. About 3 years ago they approached One

Acre saying they did a lot of work about optimal fertilizer use. One Acre did soil testing that led

Page 11: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

11

to success with fertiliser so that about 10% of their clients, about 5,000 farmers are using the

fertiliser.

Q: One Acre, understand farm for one acre, so what about larger farms? And what exit

strategies do you have?

A: Name is a bit of a misnomer because we work with farmers with more than one acre. Our

clients have aspirations to buy land and become a “super farmer,” one with enough land to

feed family and produce for markets. Any farmer who plants more than 2 acres with One Acre

Fund in Kenya is a “super farmer.” For any farmer to have someone in the community to look

up, as a role model, is great.

Q: What is the exit strategy for One Acre?

A: Much depends on environment working in. Currently the Fund is about 83% financially

sustainable. We are driving for full financial sustainability; to demonstrate that smallholder

farmers present a viable market for the private sector.

Page 12: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

12

Case Study: Agribusiness Value Chain Financing -The Case of Equity Bank

Florence Kariuki, Equity Bank

Our purpose

We exist to transform the lives and

livelihoods of our people socially and

economically by availing to them modern,

inclusive financial services.

Our Vision

To be the champion of the social-economic

prosperity of the people of Africa

Our mission

We offer inclusive, customer focused

financial services that socially and

economically empower our clients and other

stakeholders

Why agri-business?

Constitutes a Large “underserved” market –the Bottom Of the Pyramid (BOP)

To promote economic empowerment by redistribution of wealth through access to financial

resources

Enabling micro enterprises (farmers, processors, transporters etc) to contribute to the

economy and be part of the financial system

A Social responsibility to avail financial services to the lower segment majority of our

rural community

Financing agri-business through the value chain

Value chain financing concept allows integration of the various players in agriculture

production, processing and marketing.

It defines the various roles of players while at the same time, scope and purpose of

partnerships that can be established.

It enhances synergy through forward and backward linkagesvaluechain actors

Who is involved?

Page 13: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

13

Financing value chain model

Our interventions

Farmer friendly remittance account

Research on customers needs and aspirations

encourage Savings even if inmodest amounts

develop credit productsrelevant to needs.

Maintain repayment rates that are sustainable

Support the clients’ businesses through training etc

Encourage groups to generate critical volumes for market (exporters)

Seasonal loans with bullet payments

Irrigation and micro insurance to mitigate weather based risks

Market linkages e.g. World Food Programme, EABL etc

Financial Model That Encourages Savings and Supports Borrowing Affordable

Account opening balance-Nil

Minimum Operating balance - Nil

No ledger fee/No maintenance fee

Accessible

No appointment on seeing the managers

135 licensed branches in Kenya

Page 14: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

14

Flexible

Tailored to the individual needs

Appraisal ability to pay based vis-à-vis collateral based

Flexible Securities/collateral

Prompt disbursement

Challenges facing farming as a business

For majority small scale farmers farming is an occupation not business

Dependency on rain fed agriculture

Lack of access to Agric-credit

Lack of market information

Low quality products

Huge production costs

Poor infrastructure

Case of KilimoBiashara

KilimoBiashara-$ 50million (Ksh 3b)Partnership between Equity Bank, AGRA and

IFAD through Ministry of Agriculture

Objective: To increase food security and household income for farmers

An initiative to support the commercialization of agricultural activities.

So far loan disbursed in over Ksh 2.3billion to over 45,000 direct beneficiaries

Target

Small scale producers: support in purchase of farm inputs such as seeds,

fertilizers and chemicals.

Large scale producers: supports for acquisition of farm input, farm machinery

and other farm development needs.

Agri-businesses: This includes suppliers of farm inputs, transporters, food

processors and other agribusinesses that promote grain sub-sector. Provision of

working capital and other operational needs.

Warehouse receipt financing

It enhances post harvest management

The certified warehouse receipt is a title document stating a precise quantity of

known quality, held in a known store

Page 15: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

15

Pilot tested through partnership with East Africa Grain Council, Lesiolo Grain

Handlers, Kenya Maize Development Programme/USAID

Case of sorghum farming as a business

Sorghum has for a long time been considered as an orphan crop

Through partnership with EU, KARI-MOA, Africa Harvest , buying agents like EABL

and World Food Program the crop has been transformed to a commercial crop in

arid areas

Has generated and developed business services providers –bulkbuyers and others

like threshers, packaging materialsetc

The impact

Farmers’ appreciation of the need to change from subsistence farming to

commercial farming

Arid land/abandoned scheme reclaimed for grain production with the MoA giving

infrastructural support to the farmers e.g. Bura irrigation scheme in NEP

Farmers have been able to adopt modern methods of farming aimed at improved

production e.g. in Bura, yields rose by 300%(from average of 11bags to 32 bags

per acre)

Agro-dealers are able to consistently supply inputs without challenges of working

capital

So far close to $20m to about33,000 small scale farmers despite adverse weather

condition during the first season

Email: [email protected]

Web site: www.equitybank.co.ke

Questions about Equity Bank

Q: With regard to the product financing the farmers: what is the interest rate?

A: On the pricing, Equity tries as much as possible to have lower interest rates than the

market rate, thanks to social responsibility ethic and also because want to increase uptake.

Currently offering credit to farmers at 12% per annum.

Q: What about the World Food Programme’s Purchase for Progress (P4P): contracts signed

earlier and farmers can’t benefit from prices that are in the markets

A: Haven’t seen this pricing challenge. At the time of sale, the farmers will give to better

buyers whether there’s a contract or not – that has been the major challenge.

Q: Can you share successes with youth / women?

A: With the youth and women, are working with them also in collaboration with the

government through the youth fund or the women fund.

Q: And what kind of security /guarantee will people give you to be able to qualify.

Page 16: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

16

A: Also in group funding—for those who have a challenge of collateral they encourage to be in

groups, this is often the case for women and youths.

On security, surprisingly enough for the lower end market they use social security. They will

visit a client, assess what they have at home — see their cows, chairs, tables. It’s not because

the Bank could get much for this security, but at the back of their mind, the people know the

bank has attachment to their property.

Q: Example of Bura irrigation scheme. Very impressive. I visited2 years ago, the farmers had a

problem though: they had a 300% production increase, but they were not free to sell to the

market, and the grain board was waiting for them and trying to make them sell at a lower

price.

A: The initial reason for not selling, on doing the tests, was that the maize had high qualities of

aflatoxin. Seed multiplication now is mostly done under the irrigation scheme: already have a

good market and seeds fetch a higher price.

When Equity set up the Kilimo Biashara project, Government with IFAD and AGRA came out

with a credit guarantee – 10%, not more, but hoped that that is enough to help Equity, and

banks like that will liberate ten times more to give to the farmers. Leverage effect has never

been realized. Why are farmers not being forthcoming to take up this credit? [Don’t give credit

in an election year!]

Page 17: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

17

What works in linking smallholders to markets?

Summary of feedback and discussion from the first round of café tables

Broad issues that set the frame for making links

Enabling

environment

A good enabling environment: important to have an enabling environment

with the government policies

Favourable policy framework—this will allow integration, enabling

environment, support and enforce rules / regulation.

Transport One problem area is infrastructure/transport

There are things that are beyond our reach here: inputs have to get from

point A to point B, if there is no bridge, people are not going to lift inputs with

a helicopter. Hence physical infrastructure is necessary. Poor infrastructure is

real, we can’t wish it away, especially that last 30km from village to market,

costs so much.

We need to talk about …One out of 2 ha to maize, very politically important,

market very distorted, need open discussions about how this should move.

Linking

policy

across

sectors

In Kenya have 6 or 8 ministries involved in agriculture … talk of splitting up

marketing and co-operative development (one under trade, one under finance

Very important is nutrition: the story of green beans is good, but do have a

better nutritional content. If we have difficulty with the agricultural bits of the

different ministries being so spread out, how can we marry the health issues

to this?

Quantity and quality, linking health— nutrition—water. With climate change

need to think about water in a better way than we are today, from human

health as well as productivity.

Farmer

strategy

In favour of diversification

Farmers should diversify – from experience people are discussing this – where

there are mono-crops the food security aspect is forgotten.

In areas where there is a food sec problem then promoting diversification is

good.

Benefits of specialising

In Rwanda, farmers say: first, ‘show us the market’; then ‘show us the

technology’, and then they are interested in inputs. They want money in their

pocket, not only the food in the house.

We don’t produce food, we buy from the market. Why can’t a farmer produce

coffee and buy his food from the market?

One investor says that he views his money as soldiers, and he sends out his

soldiers to war, and what he expects back is prisoners of war, which is more

money.

Promote specialization so that every farmer has a cash crop, makes money.

Encourage people to do what they do best.

Paradox of diversity: raise food productivity to allow specialist crops

for market

Even in areas known for cash crops, such as Central province Kenya with its

Page 18: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

18

tea and coffee, surveys show farmers not putting much more than 25% to

cash crops; rest is food crops – maize, beans, etc.

The challenge is to improve food crop productivity so can feed family from

smaller area, and then have more room for the higher value crops.

Importance of reducing cost of product per unit area: must keep concentrating

on increasing production per unit area because of ever increasing land

pressure.

Environment Real problem for the whole region is water – agriculture consumes 70%. Map

of 2025/2030, Kenya will be water stressed. Kenya will go orange to bright

red earlier than the others.

In agriculture we are not dealing with industrial systems we are talking about

cropping systems, and maize, after maize after maize depletes the soil, so we

can’t just focus on something that deals with only one crop.

Prices Farmers are always risk averse. They are producing 10,000L of milk per day,

but from the 10,000L they will rather sell on the open market b/c that is

where they are getting better prices

Making the links to market: approach, groups, arrangements

Approach &

principles

Adopt a value chain approach – clear understanding of all the actors – every

actor appreciates what the other does, and by so doing there’s a win-win

situation.

Market approach – success found with this approach – here you can only

produce what you can sell (not sell what you can produce).

Talked about getting the system in place before the smallholders are involved

(example: warehouse receipts), but they don’t have 200 years to wait.

Must be private-sector driven

Strategic partnerships – going through value chain there are different players

so good to have ones who will build synergy, added value.

Working as a team, private-public partnerships the most important.

More specifically in markets, quality, quantity, timeliness and need to

aggregate.

Exit strategies must be addressed from the beginning – time, budgets,

sustainability

Seeds, inputs, important, extension services: there’s a feeling they should be

paid for, either through embedded services or directly by the people. In our

opinion, extension shouldn’t be for free because we’re talking about farming

as a business.

If the public extension isn’t there, they should have the option to pay for

private extension. Means need privatization of extension services

Groups Organising or aggregating farmers into groups is the key focus area – and also

focusing on one commodity

Reduce transaction cost

Form association, federation, cooperatives…

Aggregation – group approach has worked very well – access to training,

Page 19: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

19

marketing services, inputs, finances – as a group that is possible and it has

worked.

One of the things working with the suppliers is having village agglomerates –

somewhere the small farmer can have access to these inputs.

With group guarantee, also easier to access finance.

Also saw that strong social structures at that SHF level are very necessary for

taking farmers to the market, especially org structures and issues of

leadership and governance

Next one ; 2 issues – aggregation – talking about projects, but 10 years later

those aggregates are not working. Do we have the real features that we need

to look at for certain ones to work – be sustainable… at all levels, because you

can see, x coop contributes 13% of milk, but at very small scale level, what

other things do you want to consider?

Women very important in the groups, have better financial controls

Capacity&

extension

Group development sustainability – capacity building for groups—they could

be grouped but don’t have knowledge, once they have received capacity

training, could progress

Capacity building easier with structures (strong & solid social structures) –

bargaining power, reduction of costs

The farmer field school works very well, an experiential method, farmers learn

with each other, and helps build that network. If supported by public

interventions, it works very well.

People learn best if they learn themselves: if they are not force fed!

Extension services: wondering about after the project, how do you ensure that

those service providers are able to learn the emerging technologies and are

able to support farmers on the ground so it becomes a sustainable

framework?

Organising

links

Organised market – what they mean is a contract already established, there

would be room for other stakeholders to come in like microfinance and the

like.

Strategic partnerships—these have also worked where you have the buyers

coming together with the producers and service providers, and financial

service providers at the same time. Because especially for small scale farmers

where collateral has been an issue, here they have an arrangement, they can

leverage on that arrangement and access inputs and finance.

FIP – East African Farm Input Promotion: their model has advisors at the very

grassroots level; it is working, and could be up-scaled over other area. They

also say ministries, line ministries, part of the people who should be sharing

this knowledge among the small farmers, also came up with banking, table

banking, have large and small banks

Example of dairy value chain has managed to achieve through East African

Dairy Development Project, funded by the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation.

Dairy hub model, they put in various localities a cooling hub: farmers bring

their milk to these when have surplus. Banks provide capital.

Contracting Contract farming: some question marks here. In some places it has worked, in

some places a lot of issues arise — especially side-selling because contracts

don’t come with good prices, and where farmers are selling in the open

Page 20: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

20

market, they are able to make more money.

Example from Ethiopia – contract farming facilitated about a month ago. Local

company, small produces about 10k pieces of injeraa day; supplies big hotels

in Addis, retails to consumers, and exports to Washington about 3x a week,

exports US$70-80k a month. Started a contract with Fermi agriculture, a co-

operative producing Teff for making injera. In the contract, the farmers coop

will supply at least 750 tonnes to the company, and the company agreed to

pre-finance seed and fertilizer and also crop insurance. Other advantage is, it

agreed to a phased delivery, and instead of buying all the produce at harvest

time at low prices, it buys the teff at 3 intervals at the market price. Initially

after harvest it gives 50% up front so the farmer isn’t tempted to sell

elsewhere.

Since prices are rising, the company agreed to pay prevailing market prices at

time of delivery, and if the farmers meet three quality requirements (for

instance, farmers wash the grains), it offers a 100 Birr premium over the

prevailing price: good incentive for farmers not to sell to anyone else.

So, the company gets a steady supply of raw material, and reduces its

transactions costs, instead of procuring from many suppliers. It also doesn’t

incur costs from cleaning the cereal, delivering quality product.

EATA was able to act as a neutral party between the two groups, facilitated

the contract arrangement, got feedback from both parties, and brought some

government agencies to monitor the contract mechanism. Will be publishing

and sharing their experience in the future.

Certification Certification: though this creates a few questions, it’s an investment, and if it’s

an investment, in some of the places where we have worked, people have not

been able to link that with the overall results – they just do it because it’s a

requirement, but they don’t take time to analyse how they will benefit later

on.

Catalysts,

Value-chain

enablers

traders

Who? Should be doing the coordination?

One Acre’s example of village based advisors – embedding in the village

ACDI/VOCA have something similar except they – set them up for 6 to 8

months, give them a salary, and later on they can become an advisor in their

own right (withdraw salary)

Brokers— developed a very bad name ‘he makes you broke’ — but he has a

very important function. Laws are weak and don’t recognize him: we need to

engage him or her, and see that working together him, us, and the farmer, we

are better off—win-win.

Specific technical and other issues that arise in linking

Information Market, strategy – up to date information to farmers – support to link to

information

Access to information. Real time information, market information, trend

analysis, awareness, coordination, intermediary, complete package. Here we

have quite a lot of models – ex SMS in Kenya. Mobile phone penetration in

Kenya 50%.

Info

technology

Other things not exploited, mobile technology – not exploited enough.

Heifer said E-cow is already working; the other one is that in information

sharing they have seen village-based advisors, working equally well.

Page 21: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

21

ICT in agriculture – very effective, especially in livestock. Maasai in Tanzania:

now most of them have mobile phones to monitor sales of livestock, so they

are changing, building houses owning property, motorbikes etc. because they

don’t sell at a loss.

If Tele-centres could be available for other crops, farmers could monitor prices

for other crops and livestock.

Youth often have ICT skills

Financing In the area of finance – need to attach shame to removal of collateral – not

the collateral itself, social pressures could help.

Warehouse

receipts

Warehouse Receipt system – if well aggregated, and if have good

intermediaries, and then can access the market.

Warehouse receipts– someone says smallholders don’t use, but some do

(small %)

Lusiolo warehouse: small-scale farmers have used it together with traders, but

it’s only a small part of their warehouse stock.

Banks giving credit against inventories, but some banks didn’t understand that

the inventory was collateral!

Insurance Insurance against climate: could be out of the box thinking, with climate

change and what they are going through, could have lessons learned from

those who have done it. One person shared about Kilimo Salama insurance

from Syngenta foundation

Also example of working with the Maasai livestock insurance, when the area

was with drought, they stopped a lot of pastoralists from going to zero and

dropping out as pastoralists.

ILRI: Insurance scheme in Northern Ethiopia, typically a food insecure area.

Oxfam America is partnering, and in this scheme farmers contribute work to

fix up some of the local environment as the premium.

One of the interesting observations from this scheme was that it encouraged

farmers to use more purchased inputs — seed and fertiliser, has allowed them

to invest in their farms

On the downside, premium has been really high, about 70%, so if they had to

pay from their pocket wouldn’t do that, but in a way it has contributed to

improving environment in the area.

In the case of Kenya, 10 or 12% premium on the commodity/inputs, basically

they will supply credit on the inputs and if there is a weather problem, they

can get their seeds / fertiliser replaced – in a bad year they lost quite a lot of

money (Syngenta) now working with UAP, the Agricultural inputs and

veterinary stockists get a replacement if it doesn’t work. So they’re prepared

to put the time in for the stockists. Downside: limited to seeds and fertiliser ...

if it was non selective it would be even better.

Current size? Scalable? Objective? Not sure. At least farmer has support for

inputs- 12% premium. If wanted to add crop support, the premium would go

to 30% = too much.

Seasonality How do you address the issues of seasonality in terms of supplies, because

that is a challenge across most of the other value chains.

Seasonality – depends on commodity – ex cashew seasonal – used to work in

Page 22: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

22

cashew, had to link finance with entrepreneur so could bulk, so could sell to

processor throughout the year.

Processing Value addition: for example crop like mangoes – perishable fruit, post-harvest

losses very high, had experiences like supporting a co-operative society to be

able to install a processing unit through a credit guarantee, and now they are

processing pulp which they are selling to Del Monte, they have a contract, and

at the same time they are selling fresh mangoes, to address the issues of

post-harvest losses.

Gordon Conway comments

Very important to stress the point that although yields very low, potential is enormous. I saw a

missionary place in Zimbabwe getting 16 tonnes per ha, of course it was a missionary place so

there was another hand involved in the process. Seen bananas 100 tonnes / ha, milk etc.

The trick is not to get plant breeders to produce these varieties, the trick is to have reliability

in input and output markets. Once you start getting those, a virtuous circle emerges.

There’s no reason why in Africa we can’t be producing the same sort of yields as they do in the

United States—except— starting to get this virtual circle right. How do start to get the virtual

circle – can you start at certain places, do you have to do everything at once? On the other

hand, as we know, if we can only do one thing, it will collapse.

Three or four things that will start this virtuous circle round: what are the 3 or 4 places you

act?

Page 23: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

23

What needs to be done to promote links from smallholders to markets? Summary of feedback and discussion from the first round of café tables

Broad issues that set the frame for making links

Context Importance of transport. Dependence on Kenyan infrastructure for the region:

petroleum comes through Mombasa with supplies for Burundi, Rwanda, South

Sudan, Uganda

Policy Several comments to the effect that it is difficult to work when policy is not

clear, is absent, or about to change — with examples in Kenya on cereals,

urban and per-urban agriculture, pyrethrum, etc.

Government needs to come up with a policy that will spark innovation and it

also has to create mechanisms that will absorb the outcome (effective demand)

Regional

differences

Important to recognise regional differences:

Different approaches needed for different areas: approach to dry areas should

be different from that in high potential areas.

Farmers engaging in crops that cannot be sustained in that environment. You

need zoning: zones for particular crops so that farmers begin to look at crops

as commercial entities.

Using partners. If a partner is focused on a particular crop, they are region-

specific, and they always stick to that region, and that research doesn’t help so

much, because there are difficulties in replicating except outside a similar

environmental zone.

Making the links to market: approach, groups, arrangements

Approach Development partners should either play a rural provider or a facilitator – when

they move out there is a big gap it can lead to food insecurity.

The government should not just sit and draft / implement policies: it should

strengthen public-private partnerships

Need public facilitation to help farmers produce for some niche markets.

Example: Pepsi Cola has contracted farmers in Ethiopia to grow chick pea that

are for sale in Middle East & North Africa.

The NGO role should be facilitative. Let smallholders lead the processes, own

them, invest up front, they just should be shown the linkages with financiers,

input suppliers and own the processes where agreements, contracts, MOUs are

spelt out and the farmers are taking leadership roles. As we enable the farmers

to take leadership roles in all these processes,

Let’s strengthen the public-private partnerships, remembering that farmers are

part of the private in this.

Begin with end in mind incorporate exit strategies from the beginning

Repeated concerns that whole government and NGOS support initiatives, when

the project ends they collapse. Facilitation is like a dating agency: you bring

people who have no opportunity to meet together, and then you let them

continue. You’re not going to manage all their private business – facilitation is

like that, you identify opportunities which the private sector cannot identify by

themselves. You create an environment where they can form a business

contract.

Page 24: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

24

To be sustainable, it has to be a market-based approach.

If there’s any money to give anyone, give it to the business man.

Value chains Understand value chains: look for synergies or lack of them. Understand

configuration of actors. Set objectives for short and longer terms.

Financing along the value chain: important to understand all the different

financing mechanisms —where are they working, how, for who, mapping them

to work effectively.

Look for synergies of the finance mechanisms and the attendant insurance

Contract farming: important that contracts are made in a transparent way and

understood.

Co-

ordination

platforms

Should have coordination platforms for scaling up and replication. Unless we

share what we have; unless we have a platform of sharing, we lose what we

have.

Catalysts In all there is a champion – a person taking leadership – persons who are

spanning boundaries and enabling people to act.

Empower individuals – people that come between producers / consumer.

Not sure if these brokerage persons or firms should be governed: seen

situations where projects collapse when that leadership (coordination

mechanism) ends.

How to

group small-

scale

farmers?

The quality, quantity, volumes are not there. If you are linking to markets, you

cannot expect a business person to run around with his trucks looking for

product.

When it comes to accessing of agricultural inputs, if co-ops can be facilitated to

source these inputs in bulk, the cost of production goes down and the benefits

to farmers increases.

Continue supporting developing capacity of SHF groups

Empowerment of the farmer org to engage: although talking about

aggregation, they need to engage; not just become loose coalitions. If their

capacity is built, they will be able to engage, with government or other

partners.

Personal accountability within the group – so group not accountable.

As long as facilitators support the attitude that coops are not a business entity

with a clear business mandate, then they will not succeed.

Failings of co-operatives

One of the efforts which appeared with regularity was aggregation. But if it is

so good, why is it not working? This all points to a failure: inadequate

enforcement of rules and regulation. What are the consequences of breaking

the rule? More importantly, what do you do to someone who breaks the rule?

Is law enforcement blind?

For aggregation to work, need to look at the whole issue of governance. Who is

going to throw the first stone? That is a big challenge in this country.

Do a bit of research and come up with those things. In so doing, realise that

we need to aggregate the farmers, but have problems with the coops — poor

governance — people are stealing from the farmers and going Scot-free with

Page 25: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

25

impunity. If these people are not charged and farmers are not paid they will

stop farming all together.

To say we have bad contracts and that’s why they’re not honoured – not true.

As long as we have impunity, we can have the best contracts and they still will

not work.

Limit the time for support

Need to know what is the number of years need to spend with the groups until

they can govern themselves, have good organisational development skills,

leadership, social management… we are talking about incorporating exit

strategies from inception.

Need to develop a checklist if we know we are going to spend a certain amount

of years with the community; on the checklist. What is it that we need to attain

from inception to enable us to leave the smallholders to continue on their own?

Specific technical and other issues that arise in linking

Storage Market structures themselves: warehouse / storage. Small scale farmers don’t

have storage at their level. See warehousing as a future, but has to begin with

simple storage.

Adding

value

Brand our produce, as for example with tea, pyrethrum that are well branded

for Kenya. Maybe we can do something different and make something out of it.

Let’s look at value addition in a new light – sell quality in everything we

produce.

Transformation not just industrial processing but all farm processing – capture

geographic differences & seasonality.

Technical

and market

knowledge

Advisors should know what to grow where. They need gross margins calculated

so they can advise the farmer on the most profitable crops.

Environment Water harvesting – now it’s dry again, all the water has gone to waste, need

dams not water pans. This can even reduce conflict between communities.

Learning Dissemination: need to get information on the various actions that they are

taking part in; need effective dissemination of technologies, lessons.

Publicise successes and failures: need to publicise the success stories and what

the public should do

People can learn from success stories – learn, upgrade, adopt.

Share and Absorb Adoption & Adaptation of best practices

Page 26: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

26

Summarising the day

Steve Wiggins

Things that impressed me:

Big challenge of how do we get effective groups, associations, people we can work with,

people whose capacity we can build?

How do we get finance into the system? – not just investment, also to do with

seasonality and taking out certain marketing behaviour.

Standards. Includes the question of how do you get a system where all the maize

circulating is free from aflatoxin, contaminating the whole market.

But these arise within a dynamic context marked by two points.

One, hugely impressed by amount of demand for agricultural output. For example, Pepsico

arranging chick pea production in Ethiopia for the Middle Eastern markets. Pigeon peas being

loaded onto export in Dar es Salaam. Burgeoning cities and opportunities. No lack of demand:

instead a plethora of opportunities.

Two, there has been frequent mention of the politics, that arise with groups, with financial

systems. How do we deal with the political pressures? Take all the politics out of policy? No,

that is not possible. It is more a question of understanding the political economy,

understanding what needs to be there to regulate and guard the public interest; to distinguish

this from that which is rent-seeking, populist, or plain misguided.

Another clear challenge is that of knowledge management. We need to document, learn and

share experiences. Those of us who are researchers have the challenge of drawing on this to

produce frameworks, middle-level theory, so when we hear a story of success or failure, we

understand if we’re hearing about general case, something that may be imitated, or something

that is exceptional and unlikely to succeed in other cases.

Finally, we’ve heard an awful lot of different things today, with many different ideas and

examples. When you look at it reality seems extraordinarily complex. But back in London I’m

engaged in repeated struggles with people who despair when agriculture is presented as

complicated and complex. But just because reality is so, does not mean that policy and

programmes have to be complicated and complex. On the contrary, some simple interventions

— blunt instruments, if you will — can do an awful lot of good. Think, for example, of rural

roads.

Gordon Conway

I have a framework, as follows:

In the middle we have farmers, men, women or women alone and their farms, organized into

farmer associations / co-ops, contract farm groups or whatever;

Out here they have a source of inputs, usually agro-dealers with fertiliser, credit, and seed

from seed companies, certified, high quality. Fertilizers hopefully they’re getting high quality.

Microcredit they get from Equity Bank and the like.

On the other side, there’s aggregators, buying the product. They in turn are linked to

warehouses, processors, they understand the nature of demand.

They’re all private sector components.

But they all need finance and in many ways it is private-public partnerships that provide the

finance. Most important, they’re contained within an enabling environment. Part of that‘s

Page 27: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

27

infrastructure – hard, like roads, partly soft infrastructure like mobile phones / ICT, which also

connect, an environment consisting of extension, education, better health.

All of that is a kind of engine, you can think of it as an engine, all those wheels, etc. working

together.

Three big drivers can be seen. One of course is money. Second thing is people – particularly

entrepreneurial / innovate people – farmers, SME runners, novel processors. And thirdly

you’ve got policies in the way that Steve has described: policies of good governance – we

mean government policies informed by a full political economy.

The engine can be seen as a single or cluster of value chains.

Problem is it seems very complicated; and even then many things have been left out.

But the trick is to find the two, three, or four, points of intervention that will make this engine

go round for a particular value chain in a particular place. That’s what being smart is.

Page 28: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

28

Annex A: List of participants

Name Organisation

Beatrice Okeyo Swedish Cooperative Centre & Vi Agroforestry

Beatrice Ouma Future-Agricultures Consortium

Bernadette Majebelle Consultant EAC export

Crispin Mwatate Heifer International

Daniel Rukazambuga National University of Rwanda

Daphne Gatwiri KENFAP

David Juma Fwamba ARDAP

Elijah Mbwavi RegioDev Africa

Florence Kariuki Equity Bank

Furgassa Bedhadha Farm Africa Ethiopia

Gem Argwings Kodhek AECF

George Mazuri USTADI

Gordon Conway Agriculture for Impact

Hannington Odame CABE-Africa

Iris Krebber DFID

Jean Jaques Franc de Ferrière AbSS

Joachim Weber GIZ

Joseph Ngugi ACT Kenya

Josephine Thome Welthungerlife

Karin Francis Tegemeo

Kenneth Ayuko Agriculture policy Development Coordination

Liz Wilson Agriculture for Impact

Lucy Muchoki Pan-African Agribusiness Consortium

Lydia Kimani PANAAC

Mary M Kitheka Ministry of Livestock Development, Kenya

Mary Njoroge FOSCA, AGRA

Mellyne Ongang’o AGRA Markets program

Monicah Nyang FARM Africa

Nega Wubeneh EATA

Norman Clark

Patrick Chege PSDA

Peterson Marira ACT

Sharada Keats ODI

Stephanie Hanson One Acre Fund

Stephen Kagio Egerton University

Steve Collins ACDI/VOCA

Steve Wiggins ODI

Wilson Songa Agriculture Secretary

Page 29: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

29

Annex B Linking smallholders to markets: the issues

No secrets for agricultural development

In truth, government does not need to do much most of the time. Farming, and most of the

supporting industry upstream and downstream in input supply, marketing, storage, processing

and so on, is largely private enterprise. Most of the investment and innovation will be private.

Government, however, has to make that possible, and encourage it. In broad terms

governments need to do three things:

Establish an encouraging rural investment climate: law and order; macro-economic stability,

including inflation under control, a competitive exchange rate, relatively low interest rates;

business regulations that do not deter investors; taxes modest in impact but broadly shared;

and clear property rights, etc.;

Provide public goods in rural areas: physical infrastructure — rural roads, electricity, perhaps

large-scale irrigation and drainage where applicable; human development — education, water

and sanitation, health; and, public knowledge through agricultural research and extension;

The first two sets of policies are overwhelmingly important: get these broadly right, and

government has largely done its job. It is not important that the rural investment climate be

ideal, that investments in rural public goods be optimal —nice though these would be. No, the

important point is to remove the more egregious obstacles to investment, such as rampant

inflation, insecurity, threats of expropriation, red tape, or very high taxation.

Similarly, investments have to be made so that rural roads are not impassable thereby pushing

transport costs sky high; so that rural populations can read and carry out simple sums, that

they do not suffer from repeated bouts of illness, or that rural women have to bear many

children because too many die in infancy; so that improved technologies for local farming

systems are developed and disseminated.

Why are these so important? Simply this: that when developing country governments pay

attention to these fundamentals, farming prospers. Look at Ghana after 1983, China after

1978, where agricultural growth accelerated: policies were not perfect, but reforms had

corrected the really big mistakes of previous regimes.

The good news is that these policies are generally straightforward and well understood.

The third challenge is more difficult:

Remedy failures in rural markets. Farmers and rural businesses often face difficulty in

obtaining inputs and credit from commercial providers, since transactions costs can be high.

Some intermediaries in rural areas also have monopoly power by which they extract undue

returns. Each of these can mean that investment and innovation does not take place, even

when it would be profitable. Remedying these failures may involve promotion of institutions

such as contract farming; co-operation by farmers to reduce transactions costs; or even direct

state action to replace the market where it does not function.

Framework for thinking about links from smallholders to market

What has to happen so that small-scale farmers can be linked to markets for produce, inputs,

finance and know-how? How can such links be made effective, efficient, fair and inclusive?

Reviews of existing literature and studies of documented cases, suggest that success involves

three interacting elements: formulating an appropriate1 business case; taking an appropriate

approach to intervention; and getting an appropriate organisation.

1 In earlier drafts ‘appropriate’ was replaced by ‘right’. While the latter term makes for a compelling message, it over-

simplifies and can deceive: the aim is to get a good fit, not some optimal solution.

Page 30: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

30

Three elements in linking smallholders to markets

So what are these elements, and what are the implications for those setting policy and those

working with smallholders to make the links?

Formulating an appropriate business case

It should go without saying, but unless there are returns to capital, labour and land that justify

investment and innovation, then there is no case to link small-scale farmers to market. Three

things influence whether there is a business case that promises returns to both farmers and

those they work with in supply chain: working within a conducive economic environment and

rural public goods; producing for the most appropriate market; and, focusing on the most

critical elements for farmers, be they in production or marketing, in maximising returns or

reducing risks.

First, the economic environment or investment climate has to be adequate. There has to

be peace and security; respect for property rights — especially those of poor farmers; a stable

macro-economy without undue inflation; a competitive exchange rate; reasonable and fair

levels of tax; and government policies that are predictable, without sudden shifts that

dramatically and unforeseeably change prices, trading rules, property rights, and so on. When

these conditions do not apply, private enterprise will struggle: and especially enterprises that

are small and therefore highly exposed to changes in the economic environment.

This should not be taken to imply that the rural investment climate needs to be perfect. No:

experience suggests that avoiding the worst failings, providing an adequate environment is all

that is needed to allow private actors, including small farmers, to get on with their livelihoods

and businesses. The reforms China made in 1978 were far from ideal, but they remedied some

gross failings and liberated private endeavour remarkably. [Bromley & Yang 2006, China-DAC

Study Group 2010, Rodrik 2003, 2004] These are not only matters for domestic policy:

external shocks can be equally if not more significant. When cashew prices fell by 40% in

Mozambique in 2001, processing plants rapidly went into the red and closed down.

When poor business environments improve, of course, there can be new opportunities.

Rwanda is a case in point. When in 1996 peace was restored, the coffee sector that previously

had been taxed heavily and treated as a cash cow to generate funds for politics, was allowed

to develop as a normal business so that returns to exporting became once again an incentive

to produce and raise quality.

Business Case

Check economic environment

Think about market for

produce

Select focus for working with

SF; production or marketing;

maximising returns or

reducing risk

Approach

Enable, Facilitate: don’t replace

Considering inclusiveness

Exit strategy

Learning & overcoming unforeseen obstacles

Organisation

Grouping SF to

overcome

diseconomies of small-

scale units

Find champions, catalysts

Page 31: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

31

Similarly, government has to supply rural public goods: those goods and services that will

not be provided by private firms since they cannot recoup their investments. These include

physical infrastructure — rural roads, electricity, perhaps large-scale irrigation and drainage

where applicable; human development — education, water and sanitation, health care; and

public knowledge through agricultural research and extension.

What do these considerations imply for policy makers and agricultural development

programme managers? Two things stand out. One, since the environment changes, especially

external conditions, the environment needs to be scanned and key changes detected as early

as possible. It may not be possible to change external conditions, but recognising what may

affect a business is better than being unaware.

Two, some domestic policies may unwittingly undermine the business environment. In such

cases, advocacy may be effective in correcting such policies.

Second, since linking smallholders to markets almost always concerns selling produce, then

the question of what to produce and for which market becomes central. Smallholders have

to understand what output markets demand from them, what possibilities exist, and what

standards are necessary to gain access to particular markets.

The questions raised over markets are most striking when considering the advantages and

drawbacks of producing for export markets. Exporting allows smallholders to serve markets

that are much larger than domestic markets, where prices are often far higher than those

possible at home. Moreover, some of the more specialised export markets for high-value

produce, or for organic or fairly-traded items, promise premium prices. It would be foolish to

overlook these possibilities. Many thousands of farmers in Africa produce for traditional export

markets in beverages (cocoa, coffee, and tea), cotton, sugar, groundnuts, rubber and so on: a

smaller but growing number supply non-traditional exports of fruit, vegetables, flowers, fish

and even wine. Markets in Asia are opening up for exports of oilseeds and pulses.

But the potential of export markets should not be overstated, for three reasons. One, export

markets can be highly demanding in quality, consistency, traceability and certification. The last

can be highly costly for smallholders: meeting GlobalGap certification that allows export to

leading European supermarket chains can cost US$580 [Ashraf et al. 2008, for Kenya] a farm

— an enormous overhead for a small farm. This is why in some sectors, such as horticulture,

increasingly exports from Africa come from large farms and not smallholdings. [Ashraf et al.

2008, Maertens & Swinnen 2009] Some donors and non-governmental agencies may be guilty

of having encouraged small farmers to achieve standards at high cost. [Jaffee et al. 2011]

Two, export markets can be more risky than domestic markets. Competition exists for

premium export markets. Innovations by barely perceived competitors can suddenly change

prospects for other exporters. During the 1990s, for example, Ghana developed exports of

fresh pineapple from smallholdings to Europe. At the time, it seemed the main competition

came from neighbours such as Côte d'Ivoire. Given the turmoil in that country, Ghanaian

exporters felt little competition. In 2005, however, an unexpected change undermined Ghana’s

position. Del Monte developed a pineapple variety in Costa Rica called MD2 that was suitable

for long-range shipping, presenting an attractive fruit on delivery in distant Europe. Ghana’s

Smooth Cayenne variety might have competed, but producers and exporters failed to get the

quality and consistency in shipped pineapple to match the MD2.

Markets were thus lost. After few years, Ghana reacted, but in so doing the industry

restructured as production shifted heavily to plantations owned by large companies. Some

smallholders still grow on contract, but conditions are stringent and few are able to take

advantage. [Barrett et al. 2012, Whitfield 2008]

Three, domestic and regional markets are large and growing rapidly with urbanisation and

rising incomes. In Africa it is expected that agricultural exports may be worth US$20 billion in

2030, up from US$11 billion in 2000; while domestic and regional agricultural markets will

expand from US$50 to 150 billion. Kenya green beans are a case in point. During the 1990s

and early 2000s, export production increased with contracted smallholdings supplying a good

Page 32: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

32

share of the exports. But when GlobalGap came into effect in the mid-2000s, many

smallholders found themselves unable to export. But this was not the end of the story. Nairobi

has a booming demand for fresh vegetables, so today the overwhelming amount of green

beans and other vegetables grown on smallholdings in central Kenya are destined for the

capital city. Most exports, on the one other hand, now come from larger holdings that can

afford the costs of certification and traceability.

Figure A: Green beans exports from Kenya

Source: Constructed using FAOSTAT data

Third, those working with small farmers need focus on the critical issues for those farmers:

they need an appropriate focus, between production and marketing, between

maximising and reducing risks — see Figure B. This presents choices along these two

dimensions to produce the four quadrants shown.

Figure B: Different emphases when working with smallholders

Maximise Returns Reduce Risk

Production Produce more Lower unit costs

Reduce risks from weather, pests, disease Diversify production [may limit commercial production] Use versatile and resilient varieties and methods Crop protection Crop insurance

Marketing Sell for higher price — better information for negotiation with traders, using more direct channels that cut out intermediaries, etc. Higher quality, more consistency, certification with norms that can access

premium markets

Reduce risks from fluctuating prices, changing market demands Diversify production Seek alternative markets Contracting Hedge on commodity exchanges [future

option]

The top-left quadrant is about improving production on farm: raising yields, increasing

productivity and reducing unit costs. The top-right sector concerns combating risks in

production arising from weather, pests and disease. It comprises diversification of production

— that may limit specialisation in crops for sale; adopting varieties and methods that are

resilient to physical challenges — again, this may trade off against maximising production;

protecting crops using chemicals or biological defences; and insuring crops against loss. This

4.325

30.543

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Exports (thousands of tonnes)

Production minus exports

Production (thousands of tonnes)

Page 33: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

33

last is rarely an option for smallholders in Africa, but there are pilot schemes offering insurance

against indices of weather, so it may become more of an option in the future.

Marketing occupies the lower half of the table. The bottom-left cell includes strategies to sell

for higher prices — through better informed negotiation, or by using more direct channels; as

well as raising quality, improving consistency, and certifying production that may allow access

to premium markets. The lower-right quadrant depicts ways to reduce risks in marketing from

variations in prices or rapid changes in product specifications that may exclude current

production. Responses to these may lie in diversifying production, or seeking additional and

alternative markets so that exposure to any one product and market is reduced. Contracting

where prices and specifications are agreed before production is another way to reduce risk. In

the future there may be opportunities to hedge against price risks on the commodity

exchanges that are gradually emerging across the continent.

The point here is to be aware that the most effective actions may lie in any of the four

quadrants, or some combination of them. The points of emphasis, moreover, may shift

through time as external conditions move, or as programmes move sequentially from dealing

with the most pressing issues to the next most pressing. Value chain analyses can be helpful in

identifying critical points for intervention, especially when they have the participation of key

stakeholders.

Finding an appropriate approach

The principles for appropriate and effective intervention are not hard to state. The starting

point considers the diversity of circumstances, the private or collective nature of enterprise;

and the need to create links that are sustainable without external support.

The range of circumstances that define what may be effective is immense: varying by physical

location and connections to market; agro-ecological conditions; the nature of the crops and

farm enterprises; and the economic and social conditions of the smallholders. Making links,

moreover, involves the actions of multiple private or collective actors who cannot be directed,

since they are free and independent actors who can accept or reject whatever advice or

support is offered. Lastly, whatever links are created, the mechanisms have at some point to

be sustained without external support, if they are to persist and if the model is to be replicated

or scaled up.

Progress will thus rarely be made by intervening with a ready-made solution: effective links

will more likely be built by careful adaptation to circumstances and the capacities of the key

players, reinforced by learning and adjustment. For these reasons, interventions need to

facilitate and enable rather than to intervene with ready-made, planned solutions. Commercial

relations between private firms and collectives — including, of course, smallholders individually

or in groups — should not be replaced by project activities by those agencies trying to make

the links.

Furthermore, enabling processes of working with smallholders and other actors in the supply

chain will involve some learning on the job; indeed, they will encounter unforeseen and

unforeseeable obstacles. Learning and overcoming such hurdles imply additional and

unplanned efforts: there has to be flexibility in operating systems in time, staff and budgets to

allow for such learning and responding.

Some efforts, moreover, will be frustrated, they will fail. The rate of failure of new businesses,

especially small ones, is high. Interveners need to be prepared, then, to abandon some

endeavours. In business, this is painful; but less painful than piling up losses as the business

fails. In public agencies, both government and non-governmental, it may be possible to persist

pointlessly; especially when admission of failure is seen, as it often is in hierarchical

organisations, as tantamount to an admission of professional incompetence.

While it is easy to state these conditions for an appropriate approach, three challenges arise in

practice: the dilemma of offering support but not creating dependency; the need to work

Page 34: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

34

within the norms dictated by most funding agencies; and the extent to which initiatives are

inclusive.

Dilemma: supporting but not replacing

Although a principle of facilitation is that interveners should not take the place of commercial

actors and should not provide unsustainable support, in the early stages smallholders may

need temporary support to allow them to learn or to underwrite new initiatives. Such support

may take the form of training, advice and technical information, facilitating meetings between

farmers and buyers who have not done business before, provision of capital grants to allow

initial investments in production, storage, processing or transport, or underwriting novel

schemes with the intervener guaranteeing to buy back unsold inventory, to cover (some) bad

debt, to support prices should they prove lower than expected, and so on.

The danger is that any such support creates expectation and dependence; that it becomes

tempting for well-funded and well-meaning interveners to argue for another year of support,

since they fear that to leave at this point would mean all the efforts to date being lost. Hence it

is not surprising that practitioners stress the need for a clear strategy at the outset, and exit

strategy, for when the intervener will withdraw.

Programming facilitation with learning

These principles for effective intervention may not, moreover, fit easily with many

organisations need for programming, budgeting and monitoring. Enabling and facilitation are

processes that are not readily programmed in advance. It is hard to be sure just what the

needs will be in a year’s time. It is also difficult to be confident about how much progress will

be made. Those engaged in such processes are unanimous that one or two year’s actions will

rarely be enough: that thinking of five to ten years may be more realistic. Fitting these

requirements to the typical operating systems of most formal agencies is thus a challenge,

since these agencies have to prepare quite precise budgets and plans detailed to within one

year — sometimes to half-years or quarters, to specify short-term objectives and to define

targets against which progress can be monitored. How can this be done in a way that does not

lock the process into a straitjacket?

Intervening agencies may be able to cope with these issues by having a diverse portfolio of

initiatives, proceeding at different speeds; with these jointly programmed so that staff time

and resources can be switched from one initiative to another as and when needed. A diverse

portfolio also allows some endeavours to be dropped, in the reasonable expectation that other

initiatives will bear fruit and justify the overall effort made.

How inclusive can interventions be?

A repeated observation from cases is that when large firms link to small-scale farmers, or

when smallholders combine to make the links, that links work best with those smallholders

who have above average land, capital, equipment and education. There may well then be a

trade-off between having effective farmer groups and having inclusive ones: at least for the

purposes of production and marketing.

Organisational models for linking smallholders to market in practice may not always be

inclusive: they may leave marginal farmers out, without access to contracts, unable to

participate in farmer associations.

If that is so, then what is the fate of the more marginal smallholders? For them, better options

than direct participation may arise in jobs created within more successful supply chains. Small-

scale growers of green beans in Kenya generate the equivalent of fifteen jobs for every hectare

they plant. A shea butter processing factory in southern Burkina Faso employs 1,500 staff.

Cashew nut processing plants in coastal Mozambique, in zones where there is very little work

to be had, provide employment — and as people gain incomes from this, their spending

generates additional jobs in local services. [Paul 2008]

Finding an organisational model

Last but not least, there is the organisation that forms the links between smallholders and

other actors in the supply chain.

Page 35: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

35

Much has been written about the various ways in which farmers may deal with those buying

their produce, supplying inputs, providing financial services or technical advice. At one end of

the spectrum is the free market with multiple actors in competition, where deals are mainly

spot transactions. At the other end are integrated relations, with contracts tightly specifying in

advance quantity, quality and price of goods and services exchanged. In between are all

manner of combinations.

This is not the place to review the possibilities, their advantages and disadvantages. The key

point is that are several possibilities; that no model is ideal in all conditions, since each needs

tailoring to contexts that include the nature of the crop — perishability, quality variations,

needs for processing; the frequency of transactions; the extent to which undertaking an

activity means investing in assets that have no other use; the experience of farmers; the

strength of existing institutions including weights and measures, respect for contracts; and

existing social capital that may help underpin new commercial relations.

Two insights repeatedly apply in most situations, however. One is that rarely can large-scale

firms in supply chains — manufacturers of inputs, processors, large wholesalers, retail chains,

banks, etc. —deal directly with individual small-scale farmers. The costs are usually too high,

not just in administering many small deals, but also, and often more important, in ensuring

that farmers who are party to deals are competent and trustworthy.2 Hence there has to be

some point in the organisation of the chain where the farmers are aggregated, either directly

as in a farmer group, association or co-operative; or indirectly through the intermediation of

local input dealers or appointed distributors, lead farmers, bank agents, and so on.

The other is that the acid test of functioning links is not the model itself, but whether the

model respects and works with the capacity and competence of the different actors, and

whether sufficient trust can be developed in the relations between actors. It is this that

probably explains why so often farmer co-operatives have functioned badly or failed outright.

Co-operatives have too often taken on functions beyond their capacity and competence,

involving relations that have strained existing levels of trust.

Of course, if capacity, competence and trust are the defining characteristics of any model, then

these will not necessarily be static, since with time and repeated experience, capacity,

competence and trust can develop and deepen and hence arrangements can evolve as well.

Finally, there is the matter who takes the initiative to form links. For simple spot transactions

there may be no other requirement than traders and farmers meeting. But for more complex

arrangements, especially when there are deferred transactions, in almost cases there is a

champion or a catalyst who takes the initiative. But who are these actors, and what is their

incentive?

Two sets of actors stand out. In deals arranged within the supply chains, it is usually a large

firm — a processor, exporter, or retail chain — who takes the initiative to set up the links.

Rarely does this come from a smaller operator, still less from farmers themselves. The

incentive in these cases is commercial gain; more specifically, the large firm looking to get a

source of supply for a profitable outlet. They turn to smallholders when there is no other

convenient supply or when it seems smallholders may be able to supply at lower cost than the

alternative. In practice, this last criterion translates to comparing supply from local small-scale

farmers to that from imports. Occasionally it may be that smallholders can deliver better

quality than larger operations, as applies with crops that require hand-picking.

The other set of actors comprises public agencies, government, NGOs, foundations, who have

a mandate to promote links. Their incentive is simply that this is what they have entrusted to

do. In many cases, the public agency operates by facilitating arrangements between

smallholders and larger firms, ultimately handing over the operation of the links created to

2 These latter costs are those of information: they can be very high when the formal, large-scale provider has little

experience of rural areas, when some or many farmers may be illiterate or innumerate, and when language and culture differ. In technical terms the costs are called ‘transactions costs’: the costs of doing business with confidence. These may not matter much for spot deals, but they do for any deferred transaction, such as credit.

Page 36: Leaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... · PDF fileLeaping and Learning: Strategies for Taking Agricultural ... Strategies for Taking Agricultural Successes to

36

private operators. Hence in these cases they effectively replace the private firm as the

temporary champion of the links.

There are other possibilities for catalysts and champions. In some cases, often after prodding

by a public agency, a stakeholder forum for a particular chain may be formed and encouraged

to initiate changes. The forum itself may then become the champion.

References Ashraf, Nava, Xavier Giné& Dean Karlan, 2008, ‘Finding Missing Markets (and a disturbing epilogue): Evidence from an

Export Crop Adoption and Marketing Intervention in Kenya’, Center Discussion Paper No. 967, Economic Growth Center, Yale University, P.O. Box 208629, New Haven, CT 06520-8269, http://www.econ.yale.edu/~egcenter/

Barrett, Christopher B., Maren E. Bachke, Marc F. Bellemare, Hope C. Michelson, Sudha Narayanan, Thomas F. Walker, 2012, ‘Smallholder Participation in Contract Farming: Comparative Evidence from Five Countries,’ World Development,40 (4), 715–730 10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.09.006.

Bromley, Daniel W. & Yang Yao, 2006, ‘Understanding China’s economic transformation. Are there lessons here for the developing world?,’ World Economics, 7 (2), 73–95

China-DAC Study Group, 2010, Agricultural Transformation, Growth and Poverty Reduction, Beijing: International Poverty Reduction Center in China (IPRCC) & Paris: OECD http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/25/27/46767135.pdf

Jaffee, S., Henson, S. and Diaz Rios, L. (2011) Making the grade: smallholder farmers, emerging standards and development assistance programs in Africa. Washington DC: The World Bank.

Maertens, Miet& Johan F.M. Swinnen, 2009, Trade, Standards, and Poverty: Evidence from Senegal, World Development, 37 (1), 161–178

Paul, Brad, 2008, ‘Factories in the field. Rural Transformation and the Organization of Work in Mozambique’s Cashew Triangle’, Technoserve,

Rodrik, Dani,2003, In Search of Prosperity, Princeton University Press

Rodrik, Dani, 2004, ‘Getting institutions right’, Mimeo, Harvard University, April 2004

Whitfield, Lindsay, 2010, ‘Developing Technological Capabilities in Agro-Industry: Ghana’s experience with fresh pineapple exports in comparative perspective’, Danish Institute for International Studies (DIIS) Working Paper 2010:28, Copenhagen: DIIS