regional economist - oct. 2014

Upload: federal-reserve-bank-of-st-louis

Post on 01-Jun-2018

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    1/24

    3 17 9 3 2 7 9 3 3 7 9 

    P r e m i u m 

    P l u s 

    R e g u l a r 

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9

     3 3 7 9

     P r e m i u m

     P l u s

     R e g u l a r

     3 1 7 9 3 2 7

     9

     3 3 7 9

     P r e m i u m

     P l u s

     R e g u l a r

    3189

    3289

    3389PremiumPlus

    Regular $ 1 0 5

    $ 9 4 

    3 1 7  9 3 2 7  9 3 3 7  9 

    P  r e m i u m 

    P  l u s 

    R e g u l a r 

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9 3 3 7

     9

     P r e m i u m

     P l u s R e g u

     l a r

     A Quarterly Reviewof Business andEconomic Conditions

    Vol. 22, No. 4

    October 2014

    THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

    CENTRAL TO AMERICA’S ECONOMY®

    errorismTe oll It akes

    on Developing Countries

    China and the U.S.Why Teir Food Prices

    Now Move Along Similar

    “Rockets and Feathers”Why Don’t Gasoline Prices

    Always Move in Sync with Oil Prices?

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    2/24

    C O N T E N T S

    Gas and Oil Prices Don’t Always Move in SyncBy Michael Owyang and E. Katarina Vermann

    Given that Americans still spend a considerable portion o their budget

    on gasoline (just under 4 percent in 2012), it’s important to understand

    why gas prices don’t always move in sync with oil prices. Te latter are

    determined in a more-or-less centralized market, but the market or gas

    is ofen local, with prices affected by location, season and taxes, among

    other actors.

    4

    THE REGIONAL

    ECONOMISTOCTOBER 2014 | VOL. 22, NO. 4

    The Regional Economist  is published

    quarterly by the Research and Public Affairs

    divisions of the Federal Reserve Bank

    of St. Louis. It addresses the national, interna-

    tional and regional economic issues of

    the day, particularly as they apply to states

    in the Eighth Federal Reserve District. Views

    expressed are not necessarily those of the

    St. Louis Fed or of the Federal Reserve System.

    Director of Research

    Christopher J. Waller

    Senior Policy Adviser 

    Cletus C. Coughlin

    Deputy Director of Research

    David C. Wheelock

    Director of Public Affairs

    Karen Branding

    Editor 

    Subhayu Bandyopadhyay

    Managing Editor 

    Al Stamborski

    Art Director 

    Joni Williams

    The Eighth Federal Reserve District includes

    all of Arkansas, eastern Missouri, southern

    Illinois and Indiana, western Kentucky and

    Tennessee, and northern Mississippi. The

    Eighth District offices are in Little Rock,

    Louisville, Memphis and St. Louis.

    Please direct your commentsto Subhayu Bandyopadhyay

    at 314-444-7425 or by email at

    [email protected].

    You can also write to him at the

    address below. Submission of a

    letter to the editor gives us the right

    to post it to our website and/or

    publish it in The Regional Economist  

    unless the writer states otherwise.

    We reserve the right to edit letters

    for clarity and length.

    Single-copy subscriptions are free

    but available only to those with

    U.S. addresses. To subscribe, go to

    www.stlouisfed.org/publications.

    You can also write to The Regional

    Economist , Public Affairs Office,

    Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,

    P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166-0442.

     3 PRE S I D E N T ’ S M E S S A G E

    10 Terrorism Is a Threat

    to Foreign Investment

    By Subhayu Bandyopadhyayand Javed Younas

    Developing countries that are

    struck by terrorists lose not

    only lives and property but a lso

    potential or economic growth,

    studies show. Fearul companies

    shit t heir operations elsewhere,

    or example, taking with them

    their capital and technology.

    12  Noncorporate BusinessesFind Credit Is Still Tight

     

    By Juan M. Sánchez 

    Since the inancial crisis o

    2008, credit has loosened up

    or corporations but not nearly

    as much or noncorporate busi-

    nesses. Both types are still having

    trouble getting credit rom

    banks; corporations, however,

    have the ability to issue shares

    in the stock market a nd borrow

    by issuing bonds.

    14 Inflation in China, U.S.

    Following Similar Paths

     

    By Maria A. Arias and Yi Wen  

    A look at ood prices in t he two

    countries helps to explain the

    increasing correlation in their

    inlation patterns. One reason

    why their ood prices are mov-

    ing together is the increased

    trade between the countries.

    16 MET RO PRO F IL E

      Manufacturing Shares the

    Stage with Service Sectors

    By James D. Eubanksand Charles S. Gascon

    oday, Jackson, enn., the center

    o activity in the largely rural area

    between Memphis and Nashville,

    depends less on manuacturing

    and more on such service-

    oriented employers as health care

    and local government.

    1 9 E C O N O M Y A T A G L A N C E

    20 D I S T R I CT O VE RV I E W

      Minimum Wage’s Impac

    Varies across Country

    By Charles S. Gascon

    Because cost-o-living die

    ences vary across and withistates, the ederal mini mum

    wage goes urther i n some p

    than in others. Mississippi

    Oregon are examples o the

    mer, while Hawaii and New

    are two o t he latter. Meanw

    some parts o the country a

    raising their minimum wag

    ar above the current edera

    requirement o $7.25 an hou

    22 N A T I O N A L O VE RV I E W

      Optimism Prevailsas GDP Snaps Back

    By Kevin L. Kliesen

    Improvements in auto sales

    corporate proits, job grow

    and housing sales have con

    tributed to the rising opti m

    among both consumers and

    businesses. Analysts are als

    saying that the rebound in

    in the second quarter had le

    do with the irst qua rter’s b

    weather than irst thought.

    2 3 R E A D E R E X C H A N G E

    ONLINE EXTRARead more at www.stlouisfed.org/publications/re.

    3 17 9 3 2 7 9 3 3 7 9 

    P r e m i u m 

    P lu s 

    R e g u la r 

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9

     3 3 7 9

     P r em iu m

     Plu s

     Re gu lar

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9

     3 3 7 9

     P re m i u m

     P l u s

     R e g u l a r

    318 9

    328 9

    338 9PremiumPlus

    Regular $ 1 0 5

    3 1 7  9  3 2 7  9  3 3 7  9  

    P  r e m i  u m 

    P  l  u s 

    R e g u l  a r 

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9

     3 3 7 9

     P  re m  i u m

     P  l us

     R eg u  la  r

     AQuarterlyReviewofBusinessandEconomicCondi tions

    Vol.22,No.4

    October2014

    THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST.LOUIS

    CENTRAL TO AMERICA’S ECONOMY®

    errorismTeollItakeson

    DevelopingCountries

    ChinaandWhyTeirFoo

    MoveAlongS

    “Rockets and Feathers”Why Don’t Gasoline Prices

    Always Move in Sync with Oil Prices?

    Looking at Recessions through a Different Lens

    By David G. Wiczer 

    raditionally, research about recessions ocused on the big picture—how the overall economy was perorming. But recent economicstudies have looked at the impact on specific groups. One othe interesting findings is that the highest earners are, by somemeasures, the most affected by recessions. Teir gains during goodtimes, however, more than make up or their recession losses.

    2  The Regional Economist | October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    3/24

    By conventional metrics, the U.S. econ-omy is approaching normal conditionsin terms o the two main macroeconomic

    goals assigned to the Federal Reserve—price

    stability and maximum sustainable employ-

    ment. Te monetary policy stance o the

    Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC),

    however, has not yet begun to normalize.

    Current policy settings are ar rom normal,

    and the normalization process will take a

    long time. Tereore, normalizing may need

    to begin sooner rather than later i macroeco-

    nomic conditions continue to improve at the

    current pace.1

    Over the past five years, U.S. unemployment

    has been high, although it has generally beenimproving since it reached 10 percent in Octo-

    ber 2009. In September 2014, the unemploy-

    ment rate stood at 5.9 percent, down rom

    7.2 percent a year earlier. Inflation was surpris-

    ingly low rom the second quarter o 2013

    through the first quarter o 2014, but recent

    readings have moved closer to the FOMC’s

    2 percent target. Te inflation rate, as mea-

    sured by the year-over-year percent change in

    the personal consumption expenditures price

    index, was 1.5 percent in August.

    In recent years, the FOMC has used twomain tools to achieve its dual mandate—

    A Mismatch: Close to Macroeconomic Goals,

    Far from Normal Monetary Policy

    P R E S I D E N T ’ S M E S S A G E

    short-term interest rate policy (the ederal

    unds rate) and quantitative easing (QE).

    Te target or the ederal unds rate has

    remained near zero since December 2008.

    Meanwhile, the Fed’s balance sheet is still

    large and increasing, although the current

    asset purchase program (QE3) is winding

    down. Te size o the balance sheet, at more

    than $4 trillion, is roughly 25 percent o U.S.

    nominal gross domestic product (GDP).

    Te figure illustrates a measure o how

    ar the economy’s perormance has been

    rom the FOMC’s macroeconomic goals

    since 1975 and a measure o how ar the

    stance o monetary policy has been rom

    normal. Te ormer, based on inflation andunemployment, currently shows a low value

    that is close to precrisis levels.2 Te latter,

    based on the ederal unds rate and the size

    o the balance sheet relative to GDP, shows

    the opposite. In other words, the macroeco-

    nomic goals are close to being met, whereas

    monetary policy settings have a long way to

    go beore being close to normal.

    While this mismatch is not causing mac-

    roeconomic problems today, it may cause

    problems in the years ahead as the economy

    continues to expand. One risk is that infla-tion would return. I that does happen, the

    FOMC would have to adjust policy aster

    and more aggressively than it usually does,

    as inflation tends to be difficult to get under

    control. Te other main risk is that financial

    market bubbles could develop. Macropru-

    dential policies alone are probably not su-ficient to keep a bubble under control; these

    policies must be combined with monetary

    policy that is consistent with financial sta-

    bility, as well as our macroeconomic goals.

    Up to now, relatively low inflation and

    relatively weak labor markets have suggested

    a later start to normalizing monetary policy

    but stronger-than-expected data may change

    this calculus in the months and quarters

    ahead. Over the next ew years, the objective

    will be to execute monetary policy normal-

    ization without creating excessive inflationor substantial financial stability risks.

     James Bullard, President and CEO

    Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

    E N D N O T E S

      1  Tis column is based on my presentation onJuly 17, 2014, “Fed Goals and the Policy Stance.”

    See http://research.stlouised.org/econ/bullard/

    ed-goals-and-the-policy-stance.  2  For a broader measure o the labor market, one

    could use the labor market conditions index rom

    staff at the Federal Reserve Board. However, the

    results would be similar because there is a high

    correlation between this index and the unemploy-

    ment rate. See Chung, Hess; Fallick, Bruce;

    Nekarda, Christopher; and Ratner, David.

    “Assessing the Change in Labor Market Condi-

    tions,” FEDS Notes, May 22, 2014.

    SOURCES: Federal Reserve Board, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics and author’s calculations; data obtained from FRED and Haver Analytics.

    NOTES: Details on the functions used to measure these distances can be found in my presentation on July 17, 2014. The figure, which is an updated version of a

    chart from that presentation, shows the square root of the function values from January 1975 to June 2014.

    For these calculations, the normal policy stance refers to historical averages for the federal funds rate and the size of the balance sheet relative to GDP. The

    macroeconomic goals refer to the FOMC’s inflation target and the midpoint of the central tendency of the longer-run projection for unemployment, as of the FOMC’s

    September Summary of Economic Projections.

    Distance from Goals vs. Distance from Normal Policy

     Jan. ’75 Jan. ’80 Jan. ’85 Jan. ’90 Jan. ’95 Jan. ’00 Jan. ’05 Jan. ’10

    20

    18

    16

    14

    12

    10

    8

    6

    4

    2

    0

    Distance of policy stance from normal

    Distance from macroeconomic goals

        D

        i   s    t   a   n   c   e

        (   s   q   u   a   r   e

       r   o   o    t    )

    The Regional Economist  |  www.stlouisfed.org  3

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    4/24

    Why Don’t Gasoline Pric

    3 17 9 3 2 7 9 3 3 7 9 

    P r e m i u m 

    P l u s 

    R e g u l a r 

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9

     3 3 7 9

     P r e m i u m

     P l u s

     R e g u l a r

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9

     3 3 7 9

     P r e m i u m

     P l u s

     R e g u l a r

    31893289

    3389PremiumPlus

    Regular $ 1 0 5

    $ 9 4 

     $ 9 4

    3 1 7  9 3 2 7  9 3 3 7  9 

    P  r e m i u m 

    P  l u s 

    R e g u l a r 

     3 1 7 9

     3 2 7 9

     3 3 7 9

     P r e m i u m

     P l u s

     R e g u l a r

    4  The Regional Economist | October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    5/24

    By Michael Owyang and E. Katarina Vermann

    Always Move in Sync with Oil Prices?

    he U.S. Energy Inormation Administrationreported last year that American consum-ers spent, on average, just under 4 percent o their

    pretax income on gasoline in 2012—nearly $3,000

    per household.

    1

     In the previous 30 years, thispercentage was this high only once beore—in 2008.

    Given the impact on the average American’s

    budget, it is important to understand how gasoline

    prices are affected by fluctuations in oil prices.

    A number o economists have studied the mannerin which changes in oil prices affect changes in gas

    prices—the so-called pass-through. Te prevailing

    The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org  5

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    6/24

    sentiment is that the pass-through is not

    symmetric: Te speed at which gas prices

    change differs depending on whether the

    price o gasoline is relatively high or rela-

    tively low compared with the price o oil.

    Both casual and industry observers say

    that gas prices adjust to changes in oil pricesaster when gasoline prices are relatively

    low compared with oil than when gasoline

    prices are relatively high compared with

    oil. Tis uneven pass-through can be seen

    when oil prices rise afer being steady or

    some time—gasoline prices shoot up

    quickly. In contrast, when oil prices all

    afer being steady or some time, gasoline

    prices retreat slowly. In the gasoline indus-

    try, this phenomenon is known as “rockets

    and eathers.”

    Although crude oil prices are determinedin a more-or-less centralized market, retail

    gasoline prices vary by season and by

    location, depending on supply, demand,

    inventories, regulations and—in particu-

    lar—taxes. Te ormulation or gasoline

    can also vary over time, across seasons and

    across locations, depending on environmen-

    tal regulation and the average temperatures

    during the winter and summer. Tereore,

    the sensitivity o gas prices to oil prices may

     vary across cities and over the seasons.

    We reviewed some o the academic workmeasuring pass-through when gasoline

    prices were high relative to oil prices and

     vice versa, and we investigated whether

    oil price pass-through to national gasoline

    prices was different in these cases. We also

    considered how the pass-through changes

    across the seasons by assessing whether

    gasoline prices change more rapidly dur-

    ing certain months o the year. Finally, we

    considered how the pass-through varies

    across the country and whether location can

    alter the degree o asymmetry in gasoline’s

    responsiveness to oil prices.

    Asymmetric Pass-through

    Crude oil—the main component o

    gasoline—makes up nearly 70 percent o the

    pump price o regular gasoline.2 Tereore,

    it is not surprising that the per gallon price

    o retail gasoline ollows a similar pattern

    to the price o crude oil. Figure 1 shows the

    monthly national average price o regular

    unleaded gasoline per gallon in dollars

    (lef axis) rom January 1995 to July 2014,

    along with the price o oil per barrel in

    dollars (right axis). We plotted the price o

    Brent crude instead o the more amiliar

    price o West exas Intermediate (WI)

    because the two series recently diverged (see

    sidebar) and gasoline prices—particularly,

    the national average—appear to have been

    more closely tied to Brent.

    Figure 1 demonstrates the co-movement

    between the two series. Fluctuations in oil

    prices are closely mimicked in the retail gas-

    oline market with a common upward trend

    in both series, suggesting that the prices

    o oil and gas are related in the long run.

    Despite this long-run relationship, the two

    prices can independently move around their

    long-run ratio in the short run. We estimate

    that a $10 rise in the price o a barrel o oil

    is correlated with an approximately 25-centincrease in the price o a gallon o gasoline

    adjusted or taxes and markups, which are

    (relatively) constant over time. I the ratio

    between the adjusted price o gasoline to the

    crude oil price (25 cents per $10) al ls too

    out o line with this long-run relationship,

    gasoline prices will tend to adjust to return

    to this ratio.

    Although oil and gas prices appear to move

    together, the speed at which changes in the

    upstream price (oil) affects the downstream

    price (gasoline) can vary.3

     Te adjustmentprocess back to the long-run relationship may

    depend on whether gasoline prices are above

    or below their long-run ratio with oil prices.

    Economists who have studied gasoline prices

    have generally ound that gasoline prices

    adjust aster when they are low relative to oil

    prices than when they are high relative to

    oil prices. According to economists Severin

    Borenstein, A. Colin Cameron and Richard

    Gilbert, two major actors cause asymmetric

    FIGURE 1

    Oil and Gas Prices

    SOURCE: U.S. Energy Information Administration and The Wall Street Journal .

    1995 2000 2005 2010

    5

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

    160

    140

    120

    100

    80

    6040

    20

    0

    Retail Gasoline Price($/Gallon of Regular Gasoline)

    Brent Oil Price ($/Barrel)

        D   o    l    l   a   r   s

        P   e   r    G   a    l    l   o   n

        D   o    l    l   a   r   s

        P   e   r    B   a   r   r   e    l

     July 2014

    6  The Regional Economist  |  October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    7/24

    pass-through: seller market power and supply

    chain shocks.

    Seller market power implies that retail

    gasoline markets are not perectly com-

    petitive: Opportunities exist or retailers to

    take advantage o price changes to main-

    tain a higher overall profit. For example,

    Borenstein, Cameron and Gilbert noted

    that retailers increased gasoline prices as

    oil prices rose to keep a constant margin.

    When prices ell, retailers adjusted prices

    downward slower because consumers were

    already accustomed to the higher prices.

    One actor that influences market power

    is market concentration: Gas stations that

    are physically close together have less

    market power than do gas stations that are

    arther apart. o illustrate, a 2008 study o

    the Southern Caliornia gasoline market by

    economist Jeremy A. Verlinda ound that

    a rival gas station in “immediate proxim-ity” reduced the difference in the size o the

    response o gas prices to positive vs. negative

    changes in oil prices. Economist Matthew

    Lewis suggested that asymmetric pass-

    through is possible because o consumers’

    slow processing o gasoline price inorma-

    tion. Since people do not tend to observe

    gasoline prices until they are ready to reuel

    their gas tanks, consumer expectations may

    be slow to adjust to pricing changes, allow-

    ing prices to remain relatively high.

    Supply chain disruptions, such as Hur-ricane Katrina’s effect on refining in the Gul

    o Mexico, can also affect oil price pass-

    through because refineries can use pricing

    to control their inventories. Because gasoline

    has a finite supply, refineries can accommo-

    date anticipated gasoline shortages by raising

    prices in order to cut consumption. For

    example, in a 2011 study o weekly national

    data, economists Stanislav Radchenko and

    Dmitry Shapiro ound that retail gasoline

    prices increased 0.52 percent within the first

    week o an anticipated increase o 1 percentin oil prices, while they ell 0.24 percent

    within the first week o an anticipated

    decrease o 1 percent in oil prices.4 

    We measured the asymmetric response

    o gasoline prices to fluctuations in the

    pass-through by considering separately

    the months in which the adjusted average

    national retail gasoline price to oil price

    ratio was either above or below 25 cents to

    $10. Consistent with much o the literature,

    we ound a small difference in the speed at

    which gasoline prices were attracted to the

    long-run ratio depending on whether prices

    were above or below this ratio.

    Pass-through during Different Seasons

    Gasoline prices vary seasonally. Anec-

    dotal evidence suggests gasoline prices in

    the United States rise during the spring, up

    until Memorial Day weekend. Afer that

    point, they remain higher throughout the

    summer, typically spike again beore Labor

    Day weekend and then retreat in the all.

    For example, between 1995 and 2014, retail

    gasoline prices rose, on average, 0.4 percent

    (1 cent per gallon) during the two weeks

    prior to Memorial Day and 1.6 percent

    (3 cents per gallon) during the two weeks

    prior to Labor Day.

    While much o these price changes can

    be attributed to increased demand rom

    summer driving, gasoline prices may exhibit

    some seasonality because o a change in

    the cost o production due to changes incomposition: Te gasoline used in many

    areas is cheaper in the winter because it

    is, essentially, a different product. Average

    winter and summer temperatures dictate

    some o the changes in gasoline ormula-

    tion; environmental regulation is another

    determinant. Some areas allow alternative

    ingredients in the winter that are cheaper

    to produce, but contribute more to pollu-

    tion. During the summer, the use o these

    alternative ingredients is more restricted.

    During the summer in warmer areas,gasoline sometimes requires additives that

    reduce the vapor pressure and make the

    gasoline less volatile, as well as less suscep-

    tible to evaporation in the gas tank. Because

    summer gasoline is more costly to produce,

    the prices during the spring and summer,

    when these products are used, will naturally

    be higher.5 

    We examined whether the pass-through

    asymmetry varies over the seasons. o this

    Anecdotal evidence suggests gasoline prices in theUnited States rise during the spring, up until Memorial

    Day weekend. After that point, they remain higher

    throughout the summer, typically spike again before

    Labor Day weekend and then retreat in the fall.

    The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org  7

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    8/24

    end, we separated the data into observa-

    tions occurring during the months o Octo-

    ber to March and observations occurring

    during the months o April to September.6 

    We calculated asymmetry or each sample,

    thus letting the asymmetry differ both

    when gas was above/below the long-run

    ratio and across seasons.

    By splitting the sample into summer and

    winter months, we ound more

    evidence o asymmetry. During

    the winter, the rate at which

    gas prices are pulled down

    by oil prices appeared to be

    higher than it was during

    the summer. Moreover,

    splitting the sample by

    season appeared to

    ampliy the asymmetry,

    which appeared to

    be higher during thehigh-demand summer season

    and when the cost o gasoline production

    was higher.

    Pass-through across Cities

    Gasoline prices differ by location or

    a number o reasons. Variation in taxes

    accounts or a substantial portion o the

    difference. Differences in supply can vary

    because o the costs o moving gasoline

    rom the refinery to the retail location.

    Demand can vary because o commutingpatterns, a city’s population density, the

    quality and use o public transportation,

    total population, and other actors. We

    suggested above that production costs can

    cause pricing differentials; thus, variations

    in weather—in particular, average summer

    and winter temperatures—across cities can

    cause differences in the price o gasoline.

    In a 2012 paper, economist Matthew

    Chesnes studied 27 cities and confirmed

    the existence o asymmetric pass-through

    in the gasoline market. He ound that thetype o uel used in each city was impor-

    tant or determining the magnitude o the

    asymmetry: Cities selling predominantly

    conventional gasoline (St. Louis and Lou-

    isvil le, Ky., or example) were less asym-

    metric in adjusting to the long-run ratio

    than were other cities where reormulated

    gasoline was sold.

    Te sensitivity o gas prices to oil prices

    may also vary across cities depending on

    West Texas Intermediate and Brent:

    Two Benchmarks for the Price of Crude Oil

    In the United States, there are two main benchmark measures of crude oil prices.One is the price of West Texas Intermediate (WTI), which is a grade of crude oil thatis both low in density and low in sulfur. It is often referred to as Texas sweet light

    crude. The low sulfur content of WTI allows more oil to be extracted from the crude.

    WTI crude is both sourced and refined in the United States; its price is used as abenchmark only in the United States. Futures contracts for WTI are traded on the New

    York and Chicago Mercantile exchanges, among other exchanges, and are settled

    in Cushing, Okla.

    The second important benchmark price for crude

    oil is Brent. Brent oil was originally sourced from 15 oil

    fields in the North Sea but has become the international

    benchmark for pricing crude oil. It is much more widely

    used than is the price of WTI as a benchmark, especially

    outside of the United States. There are slight differences

    in the density and sulfur content between Brent and

    WTI, but the differences are relatively small.

    Prior to 2011, the two spot oil prices moved almostin lockstep. This is perhaps not surprising because

    WTI and Brent crude oil are essentially the same

    product. Standard economic models of commodity

    pricing would predict that arbitrage would eliminate price differentials

    between the two oil prices. If the price of a commodity is higher in one market

    (say, market A) than another (market B), one could, in principle, buy the good

    in market B and resell it in market A. This would yield a profit if the two prices

    were different. It would also put upward pressure on the price in B and down-

    ward pressure on the price in A, making the two prices eventually converge. In

    practice, the two prices may not completely converge because of, for example,

    the cost of transporting the commodity from B to A. However, after 2011, the

    two spot oil prices diverged. The explanation for their divergence might lie in

    how—or perhaps where—the two prices are determined.

    In early 2011, Cushing reached its storage capacity, causing a difference

    between the two spot oil prices that could not be eliminated by arbitrage. In

    September 2011, for example, the Brent spot price was $27.31 per barrel higher

    than the WTI spot price. This differential is large considering that, prior to 2011,

    a typical differential was on the order of $1.37. No arbitrage opportunity existed

    because of the inability to move oil from Cushing to another location in the Gulf

    Coast where it could be sold for prices closer to the settlement price of Brent

    crude. This also meant that the regional variation in gas prices increased; oil

    prices (and, thus, gasoline prices) near the coasts were more closely tied to

    Brent, while prices in the Midwest were more closely tied to WTI.

    Recently, however, the difference between the two spot oil prices has declined.

    The decline was due, in part, to the reversal of the oil flow in the Seaway Pipeline,

    which normally moves oil from the Gulf Coast to Cushing. The reversal allowed oil

    to travel from Cushing to the Gulf Coast, where it could be sold at the Brent price.

    During the summer of 2013, the difference between the two spot prices had

    declined substantially, to about $3.30 in July 2013. Since then, the difference

    peaked at $13.93 in November 2013 and drifted back to $3.18 in July 2014.

    These differences are still considerably less than $17, the average difference from

    the beginning of 2011 and the end of 2012. In August 2014, the price differential

    was $5.07.

        ©     T

        H    I    N    K    S    T    O

        C    K

    8  The Regional Economist  |  October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    9/24

    E N D N O T E S

      1  See www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.

    cm?id=9831.  2  See www.eia.gov/petroleum/gasdiesel.  3  Te total effect o oil price fluctuations on gasoline

    prices cannot vary lest the long-run relationship

    between the two prices breaks down.  4  Te evidence or asymmetr y is by no means con-

    clusive. In two studies, one by economists Lance J.

    Bachmeier and James M. Griffen and the other by

    economist Christopher C. Douglas, no evidencewas ound that gasoline prices adjust back to the

    long-run relationship asymmetrically.  5  See http://blog.gasbuddy.com/posts/A-crash-

    course-on-seasonal-gasoline/1715-401024-239.

    aspx or a good summary o the differences in the

    composition o gasoline across the seasons.  6  Tese cutoffs are airly arbitrary and may not

    reflect the true differences in the seasonality.  7  Te St. Louis metro area includes parts o South-

    ern Illinois. As such, taxes have been removed

    using a weighted average o the tax rates across the

    states and local municipalities.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Bachmeier, Lance J.; and Griffen, James M. “New Evi-

    dence on Asymmetric Gasoline Price Responses.”

    Te Review of Economics and Statistics, August

    2003, Vol. 85, No. 3, pp. 772–76.

    Borenstein, Severin; Cameron, A. Colin; and Gilbert,

    Richard. “Do Gasoline Prices Respond Asym-

    metrically to Crude Oil Price Changes?” Te

    Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1997,

    Vol. 112, No. 1, pp. 305-99.

    Chesnes, Matthew. “Asymmetric Pass-through in

    U.S. Gasoline Prices.” U.S. Federal rade Commis

    sion Bureau o Economics Working Paper No. 302

    September 2012.

    Deltas, George. “Retail Gasoline Price Dynamics and

    Local Market Power.” Te Journal of Industrial

    Economics, September 2008, Vol. 56, No. 3,

    pp. 613-28.

    Douglas, Christopher C. “Do Gasoline Prices Exhibi

    Asymmetry? Not Usually!” Energy Economics, July 2010, Vol. 32, No. 4, pp. 918–25.

    Lewis, Matthew S. “Asymmetric Price Adjustment

    and Consumer Search: An Examination o the

    Retail Gasoline Market.” Journal of Economic s

    and Management Strategy, Summer 2011, Vol. 20,

    No. 2, pp. 409-49.

    Radchenko, Stanislav; and Shapiro, Dmitry.

    “Anticipated and Unanticipated Effects o Crude

    Oil Prices and Gasoline Inventory Changes on

    Gasoline Prices.” Energy Economics, July 2011,

    Vol. 33, No. 5, pp. 758- 69.

    Verlinda, Jeremy A. “Do Rockets Rise Faster and

    Feathers Fall Slower in an Atmosphere o Local

    Market Power? Evidence rom the Retail Gasoline

    Market.” Te Journal of Industrial Economics, 

    September 2008, Vol. 56, No. 3, pp. 581-612.

    market power (or concentration). In a 2008

    study, economist George Deltas argued that

    states with higher average seller margins on

    gasoline (which implies ewer sellers) had

    more asymmetric pass-through in levels

    and a slower speed o adjustment to the

    long-run ratio.

    We calculated pass-through across 162

    cities using weekly pretax retail gasoline

    prices and the Brent oil price rom 2005-

    2013. Because taxes are ofen assumed to

    be the principal source o the variation in

    gasoline prices across cities, we constructed

    the pretax retail price o gasoline to measure

    pass-through at the city level. Tus, our

    local retail gasoline price series excludes

    national, state and local gasoline-specificexcise taxes, as well as local environmental

    regulation ees and sales taxes imposed on

    gasoline. Figure 2 shows the time series

    o pretax gasoline prices or three cities in

    our sample: New York, San Diego and

    St. Louis.7 Te cities were chosen to high-

    light the regional differences in gasoline

    price dynamics. As one might expect, the

    gasoline prices in different cities had similar

    fluctuations, induced, or the most part, by

    fluctuations in oil prices. However, there

    were also notable differences: Even aferadjusting or taxes, San Diego and New York

    had higher prices than cities in the Midwest

    (e.g., St. Louis) possibly due to differences

    in proximity to Cushing, Okla., (the source

    or WI crude oil) or due to differences in

    gasoline composition.

    When we analyzed the relationship

    between retail gasoline prices and crude oil

    prices at the city level, we ound two main

    differences. First, the long-run relationship

    between gasoline and oil could vary across

    cities. Second, the effect o changes in oil

    prices on gasoline could vary across cities.

    As to the ormer, we ound relatively similar

    long-run relationships between gasoline

    and oil across cities. Te main difference

    across cities was in how gasoline prices were

    adjusted or different taxes in the long-run

    ratio. Cities exhibited a variety o degrees

    o asymmetry; among the most asymmetric

    were Anchorage, Alaska; Bakersfield, Cali.;

    and Colorado Springs, Colo. In addition, the

    responsiveness o gas prices in the various

    cities differed. For example, Sacramento,

    Cali., was about three times aster to adjust

    to the long-run ratio than was Boise, Idaho.

    Conclusion

    Te market or gasoline is local, with vari-

    ations in market concentration, demand,

    regulation and taxation. Tus, it may not be

    surprising that we ound more asymmetry

    at the local level than at the national level.

    What does the presence o the asymmetry

    mean or consumers and policymakers?

    Awareness o the apparent asymmetry can

    help consumers better orecast (and budget

    or) gasoline expenditures. Further study

    is needed to understand the origin o theasymmetry and its consequences or the

    overall welare o the economy.

     Michael Owyang is an economist and E. KatarinaVermann is a senior research associate, both atthe Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For moreon Owyang’s work, see http://research.stlouis- fed.org/econ/owyang.

    FIGURE 2

    Gas Prices across Select Cities

    SOURCES: The  Wall Street Journal , Gas Buddy and author’s calculations.

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    0    5

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    0    5

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    0    6

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    0    6

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    0    7

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    0    7

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    0    8

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    0    8

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    0    9

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    0    9

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    1    0

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    1    0

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    1    1

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    1    1

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    1    2

        S   e   p    t .

        ’    1    2

        M   a   r   c    h    ’    1    3

    5

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

    160

    140

    120

    100

    80

    6040

    20

    0

    San DiegoSt. Louis

        D   o    l    l   a   r   s    P   e   r    G   a    l    l   o   n

        D   o    l    l   a   r   s    P   e   r    B   a   r   r   e    l

    New York City

    Brent August 2013

    The Regional Economist  |  www.stlouisfed.org  9

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    10/24

    errorism around the world is a problemor oreign direct investment (FDI). Forexample, a multinational corporation based

    in the U.S. may find a location in India to

    be attractive or setting up a plant because

    o the abundance o cheap and well-trained

    labor there. However, i that area is also apotential location or insurgency and ter-

    rorism, the multinational will have to weigh

    the benefits rom lower wage costs against

    the possibility o loss o plant, manpower

    and equipment rom terrorist attacks. On

    aggregate, a higher incidence o terrorism(as perceived by potential investors) will

    tend to reduce their willingness to invest in

    a terrorism-inested area.1

    Let us consider the case o Colombia,

    which was notorious or drug violence and

    terrorism in the 1980s and 1990s. In more

    recent years, Colombia has seen significant

    declines on these ronts. Te figure shows

    that as terrorism has allen, FDI has risen.

    Without careul analysis, we cannot sug-

    gest this apparent relationship as causal;

    however, a link is possible. Fortunately,the literature in this area includes careul

    studies on the link between terrorism and

    FDI, studies that have employed rigorous

    economic theory and econometric methods.

    Te rest o this article provides a sample o

    this research.

    Impact in Spain, Greece

    A 1996 study by economists Walter

    Enders and odd Sandler is one o the first

    to quantiy the effect o terrorism on FDI.

    Teir study investigated how transnational

    terrorism had affected FDI flows into Spain

    and Greece.2 Using net annual oreign direct

    investment (NFDI) data rom the mid-1970s

    through 1991, they ound that terrorist inci-

    dents reduced NFDI in Spain by 13.5 percentand in Greece by 11.9 percent. Te authors

    noted that these reductions amounted to

    7.6 percent and 34.8 percent o annual gross

    fixed capital ormation or Spain and Greece,

    respectively. Clearly, this means that terror-

    ism had a major negative effect on capitalormation in these nations and, in turn, on

    their potential or economic growth.

    Impact on FDI from the U.S.

    A large number o transnational terrorist

    attacks on the U.S. are conducted against

    U.S. interests in oreign nations. Tis is

    likely to raise the risks or U.S. corpora-

    tions doing business abroad. In a 2006

    study, Enders, Sandler and ellow economist

    Adolo Sachsida investigated how terror-

    ism in other nations may have affectedFDI rom the U.S. into these nations. Tey

    ound that terrorist attacks lowered U.S.

    FDI by 1 percent in nations that belong to

    the Organization or Economic Coopera-

    tion and Development (OECD) but had

    no statistically significant effect in non-

    OECD nations. Greece and urkey (OECD

    members) suffered relatively large damages,

    amounting to U.S. FDI reductions o

    5.7 percent and 6.5 percent, respectively.

    Diversion of FDI

    Some studies have argued that terrorist

    attacks usually destroy only a small raction

    o the capital stock o a nation and, there-

    ore, are unlikely to cause major economic

    damage. A 2008 study by economists

    Alberto Abadie and Javier Gardeazabal

    ound otherwise. Tey showed that even

    when the direct damage to a nation’s capital

    stock is not large, the eventual, overall

    impact may be large because, or example,

    earul oreign investors divert their money

    to other nations. Tis diversion can result in

    a large loss o investment. Using a cross-

    sectional study, the economists ound that

    a one-standard-deviation increase in the

    intensity o terrorism in a particular nation

    can reduce the net FDI position o that

    nation by approximately 5 percent o itsGDP, a large impact.

    Threat to Developing Nations

    FDI is considered to be a major source o

    oreign capital and technology to support

    economic growth in developing countries.

    I terrorism reduces FDI flows into these

    nations, their growth and development

    can be stymied. Tis poses a challenge

    or economists who provide policy advice

    to international donor agencies like U.S.

    Agency or International Development andthe World Bank.

    In their 2014 study on this issue, econo-

    mists Subhayu Bandyopadhyay, Javed

    Younas and the aorementioned Sandler

    ocused on 78 developing countries over the

    period 1984-2008. Te authors ound that

    both domestic and transnational terrorism

    significantly depressed FDI in develop-

    ing countries. A one-standard-deviation

    increase in domestic terrorist incidents per

    Terrorism: A Threat

    to Foreign Direct Investment

    D O I N G B U S I N E S S A B R O A D

    By Subhayu Bandyopadhyay and Javed Younas

    Many of the terrorism-afflicted nations are poor and lack vital

    resources that can be used for counterterrorism. This problem

    can be partly alleviated by foreign aid.

    10  The Regional Economist  |  October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    11/24

    E N D N O T E S

     1  Among others, a 2008 paper by economists Abadie

    and Gardeazabal shows that a greater intensity

    o terrorism increases the variance o the return

    to investment while reducing its mean. Clearly,

    a lower average rate o return to investment in a

    nation will tend to reduce potential FDI into that

    nation.

     2  When a terroris t incident in a certain country

    involves citizens or property o another country, it

    is considered to be transnational terrorism.

     3  Te Bandyopadhyay et al. analysi s presents a

    theoretical model in which aggregate aid has

    unconditional aid and aid tied to counterterrorism

    as its two components. Te theoretical analysis

    shows that tied aid can reduce the adverse effect

    o terrorism on FDI. Te econometric analysis

    motivated by this model finds significant benefits

    o oreign aid in terms o reducing the damages to

    FDI rom terrorism.4  For details on securit y concerns as a donor

    motive, see the 2013 study by Bandyopadhyay

    and Vermann.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Abadie, Alberto; and Gardeazabal, Javier. “errorism

    and the World Economy,” European Economic

    Review, January 2008, Vol. 52, No. 1, pp. 1-27.

    Bandyopadhyay, Subhayu; Sandler, odd; and

    Younas, Javed. “Foreign Direct Investment,

    Aid, and errorism,” Oxford Economic Papers,

    January 2014, Vol. 66, No. 1, pp. 25-50.

    Bandyopadhyay, Subhayu; Vermann, E. Katarina.

    “Donor Motives or Foreign Aid,” Federal Reserve

    Bank o St. Louis Review, July/August 2013,

    Vol. 95, No. 4, pp. 327-36.

    Enders, Walter; Sachsida, Adolo; and Sandler, odd.

    “Te Impact o ransnational errorism on U.S.

    Foreign Direct Investment,” Political Research

    Quarterly,  December 2006, Vol. 59, No. 4,

    pp. 517-31.

    Enders, Walter; and Sandler, odd. “errorism and

    Foreign Direct Investment in Spain and Greece,”

    Kyklos, August 1996, Vol. 49, No. 3, pp. 331-52.

    100,000 people reduced net FDI between

    approximately $324 million and $513 mil-

    lion or the average sample country, whose

    GDP totaled $70 billion. A one-standard-

    deviation increase in transnational  terroristincidents per 100,000 people reduced net

    FDI between approximately $296 million

    and $736 mil lion at the same level o GDP.

    Te loss o FDI, however, was much smaller

    when it was calculated at the median value

    o GDP ($10.4 bill ion) in the sample.

    Many o the terrorism-afflicted nations

    are poor and lack vital resources that can be

    used or counterterrorism. Tis problem can

    be partly alleviated by oreign aid. Bandyo-

    padhyay et al. ound in their study earlier

    this year that oreign aid can help in thisregard and that the evidence suggests sig-

    nificant terror-mitigating effects on FDI.

    For example, the aorementioned lower

    estimate o FDI loss rom domestic terror-

    ism o $324 million is reduced to about

    $113 million or the average aid-receiving

    nation, while the lower estimate or trans-

    national terrorism is reduced to about

    $45 million rom $296 million.3 

    As the World Shrinks

    In an integrated global economy, ter-rorism presents policy challenges both at

    home and abroad. Te July 2014 downing

    over Ukraine o a Malaysian jet carrying

    Dutch passengers (or the most part) was a

    stark reminder o this interconnectedness.

    Accordingly, U.S. policymakers involved

    with counterterrorism remain vigilant

    about terrorism in the U.S. and abroad.

    By ocusing on the existing literature on

    FDI and terrorism, we can see that policy

    efforts targeted at reducing terrorism can

    provide substantial economic benefits to the

    terrorism-afflicted nations.

    Te literature also points to the impor-

    tant role that oreign aid may play in termso containing terrorism and boosting the

    growth potential o developing nations. Te

    literature on oreign aid has increasingly

    ocused on security concerns rather than

    on a recipient nation’s economic need as a

    motive behind giving oreign aid.4 Along

    similar lines, the aorementioned 2014

    study by Bandyopadhyay et al. suggests that

    oreign aid may be motivated by, among

    other things, substantial economic benefits

    in terms o greater FDI flows to nations with

    reduced terrorism.

    Subhayu Bandyopadhyay is an economist at theFederal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, and JavedYounas is an associate professor of economics at American University of Sharjah, United ArabEmirates. For more on Bandyopadhyay’s work,see http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/bandyo- padhyay.

    Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and Terrorism in Colombia

    NOTE: Data are averaged over six-year nonoverlapping periods from 1988 to 2011, which gives us four time periods. Terrorism incidents include domestic,

    transnational and other acts of terrorism that cannot be unambiguously assigned to either of these two categories.

    SOURCES: FDI-World Development Indicators (2013); Terrorism-Global Terrorism Database, University of Maryland, College Park.

    1988-1993 1994-1999 2000-2005 2006-2011

    6

    5

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

        F    D    I ,    T   e   r   r   o   r    i   s   m

    Terrorism incidents (hundreds) FDI as % of GDP

    The Regional Economist  | www.stlouisfed.org  11

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    12/24

    Firms use credit to finance production,working capital, investment in physicalcapital, and research and development. All

    these activities are important or the unc-

    tioning o the economy. In act, as argued in

    recent research, there is a strong connection

    between the development o credit marketsand that o the economy.1

    On June 5, the Board o Governors o the

    Federal Reserve System published the Finan-

    cial Accounts o the United States or the first

    quarter o 2014. Tis article uses data rom

    that publication to analyze the use o credit

    by nonfinancial businesses since the financial

    crisis o 2008. Te main finding is that the

    evolution o outstanding liabilities has been

     very different or corporate and noncorporate

    businesses, with a remarkable stagnation in

    credit to noncorporate businesses.Figure 1 displays the value o outstand-

    ing liabilities o corporate and noncorporate

    businesses. Since their previous peak (during

    the financial crisis), liabilities o corporate

    businesses increased about 20 percent,

    while liabilities o noncorporate businesses

    increased only 4 percent. Tese patterns may

    be important to understand the strength

    o the recovery i we take into account the

    well-established connection between the

    unctioning o credit markets and that o the

    aggregate economy. Recent research showsthat disturbances in financial markets may

    be an important cause o business-cycle

    fluctuations.2

    Corporations are distinguished rom

    noncorporations in two critical ways: (i) the

    financial sources to which they have access

    (corporations can issue shares in the stock

    market and can borrow and lend by issuing

    bonds, while noncorporations can’t do either)

    and (ii) the ownership and control structure

    (a corporation is owned by shareholders but

    is typically run by a separate group o man-

    agers, while noncorporations are typically

    owned by one or two individuals who alsoperorm as managers).3 Te first element is

    important to understand the differences in

    the type o liabilities available or these two

    groups o firms.

    Te main components o liabilities or both

    corporate and noncorporate businesses are

    credit instruments (e.g., commercial paper,

    corporate bonds, depository institution loans

    and mortgages). Tey represent about 60

    percent and 70 percent o the liabilities o

    corporations and noncorporations, respec-

    tively. Te rest are trade payables, which areliabilities owed to suppliers or purchases or

    services rendered; tax payables, which are

    taxes that a company owes as o the balance

    sheet date; and others.

    Figure 2 displays the evolution o credit

    market instruments. Te difference between

    corporations and noncorporations is quite

    striking. Since the financial crisis, corpora-

    tions increased the value o outstanding

    credit market instruments by 27 percent,

    while the same variable increased by only

    3 percent or noncorporations.

    o understand the evolution o credit mar-

    ket instruments, consider their composition,as shown in Figure 3. For noncorporate busi-

    nesses, most o the debt is composed o mort-

    gages (69 percent) and loans rom depository

    institutions (27 percent). In contrast, 68

    percent o the credit market liabilities o cor-

    porations are corporate bonds, which are not

    available to noncorporate businesses.

    Te table displays the growth o loans

    rom depository institutions, mortgages and

    corporate bonds. Recall that the first two are

    the most important credit instruments used

    by noncorporate businesses, while the lastone is available only or corporations. Te

    trend in loans rom depository institutions

    and in mortgages since the financial crisis

    is very sluggish or both types o businesses.

    Actually, or these two instruments, growth

    was negative or corporate businesses and

    slightly positive or noncorporate businesses.

    Te key difference is that noncorporate busi-

    nesses rely on these instruments, while these

    instruments are much less important or

    2006:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 2011:Q1 2012:Q1 2013:Q1 2014:Q1

    Noncorporate (Right Axis)

    Corporate (Left Axis)

        B    i    l    l    i   o   n   s

       o    f    D

       o    l    l   a   r   s

    6500

    6000

    5500

    5000

    4500

    4000

        B    i    l    l    i   o   n   s

       o    f    D

       o    l    l   a   r   s

    17000

    16000

    15000

    14000

    13000

    12000

    11000

    10000

    FIGURE 1

    Total Liabilities of Nonfinancial Businesses

    SOURCE: Financial Accounts of the United States, published by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    Credit to Noncorporate

    Businesses Remains Tight

    P O S T - F I N A N C I A L C R I S I S

    By Juan M. Sánchez 

    12  The Regional Economist  |  October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    13/24

    FIGURE 3

    Components of Credit Market Liabilities, by Instruments, 2013

    SOURCE: Financial Accounts of the United States, published by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    For Nonfinancial Noncorporate Business For Nonfinancial Corporate Business

    Mortgages

    Depository institution loans

    Other loans and advances

    Corporate bonds

    Municipal securities

    Commercial paper

    Mortgages

    Depository institution loans

    Other loans and advances

    69%

    27%

    4%

    68%11%

    6%

    2%

    corporations, as shown in Figure 3. Actually,

    the strong recovery o credit or corporationsis due to the ast growth o corporate bonds;

    their growth has increased at an average

    annual rate o 10 percent since 2008:Q4.

    Overall, credit to noncorporate businesses

    remains tight. Tis phenomenon is mostly

    accounted or by the sluggish recovery o

    loans rom depository institutions and mort-

    gages, which are very important or this type

    o business. ight credit may be affecting

    the day-to-day operations o noncorporate

    E N D N O T E S

      1  See, or example, Greenwood, Sánchez and Wang.  2  See Shourideh and Zetlin-Jones.  3  See Magill and Quinzii, Chapter 6, Section 31, or

    a thorough discussion.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Greenwood, Jeremy; Sánchez, Juan M.; and Wang,

    Cheng. “Quantiying the Impact o Financial

    Development on Economic Development,” Review

    of Economic Dynamics, January 2013, Vol. 16,

    No. 20, pp. 194-215.

    Magill, Michael; and Quinzii, Martine. Teory of

    Incomplete Markets, Vol. 1. Cambridge: MI

    Press, 1996.

    Shourideh, Ali; and Zetlin-Jones, Ariel. “External

    Financing and the Role o Financial Frictions over

    the Business Cycle: Measurement and Teory.”

    Working Paper, University o Pennsylvania’s

    Wharton School, December 2012.

    businesses since credit is important or

    growth. Future research should ocus ontrying to find out the reasons or the weak

    recovery o lending by banks and other

    depository institutions.

     Juan M. Sánchez is an economist at the FederalReserve Bank of St. Louis. For more on hiswork, see http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/ sanchez. Lijun Zhu, a technical research associ-ate at the Bank, provided research assistance.

    SOURCE: Financial Accounts of the United States, published by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    Corporate Noncorporate

    Depository institution loans –3.3% 1.5%

    Mortgages –7.3% 0.2%

    Corporate bonds 10.3% n.a.

    Growth Rates of Key Credit Instruments since 2008:Q4, Annualized

    2006:Q1 2007:Q1 2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 2011:Q1 2012:Q1 2013:Q1 2014:Q1

    Noncorporate

    Corporate    I   n    d   e   x

        (    1    0    0  =

        2    0    0    6  :    Q

        1    )

    170

    160

    150

    140

    130

    120

    110

    100

    90

    80

    FIGURE 2

    Value of Outstanding Credit Market Instruments

    SOURCE: Financial Accounts of the United States, published by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    7%

    6%

    The Regional Economist  | www.stlouisfed.org  13

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    14/24

    Food Prices and Inflationin China and the U.S.

    Are Following Similar PathsBy Maria A. Arias and Yi Wen

    I N T E R N A T I O N A L T R A D E

    Inflation, as measured by growth in theconsumer price index (CPI), has beenrelatively stable during the past two years

    in both the U.S. and China. Both countries

    also shared a period o price volatility in the

    years beore and afer the Great Recession—

    a time when commodity prices werefluctuating around the globe. Beore 2000,

    however, prices in China and the U.S. did

    not always behave similarly. (See Figure 1.)

    Food prices, an important component

    in the CPI, can help explain the relation-

    ship between the two countries’ overall

    price co-movements. Fluctuations in ood

    prices in China started to become more

    strongly correlated to those in the U.S. afer

    China joined the World rade Organization

    (WO) in 2001. Between 1994 and 2001, the

    correlation1

     was 41 percent; between 2002and 2013, it rose to 62 percent. (See Figure 2

    and the table.)

    But what drives the co-movement in ood

    prices o the two countries? Are there expla-

    nations other than this co-movement or

    the increased synchronization o inflation

    in China and the U.S.? Let’s look at some

    possible answers to these questions.

    World Food and Commodity Prices

    Some people think that prices in general

    and ood prices in particular are highly cor-related in the U.S. and China because both

    sets o prices are affected by some world-

    wide actors, such as movements in world

    ood prices. Data show that this is true or

    China, but not or the U.S.

    China’s ood prices were strongly cor-

    related with world ood prices between 2002

    and 2013 (80 percent correlation), while U.S.

    ood prices during the same period were not

    that highly correlated to world ood prices

    (34 percent). Similarly, Chinese ood prices

    were strongly and significantly correlated

    with the S&P Goldman Sachs CommodityIndex between 2002 and 2013 (49 percent),

    while the correlation between U.S. ood

    prices and the S&P GSCI was low (10 per-

    cent) and not statistically significant.

    Exchange Rates and Money Supply

    Looking at ood prices rom a monetary

    standpoint, another likely explanation could

    be related to currency exchange rates. China

    has a targeted floating exchange rate with

    the dollar; so, higher money supply in the

    U.S. should lead to higher money supply

    in China. I this were true, CPI inflationin China and the U.S. should fluctuate in

    similar patterns.2 

    Te data are not conclusive regarding this

    explanation. Te correlation between CPI

    inflation in the U.S. and China more than

    doubled, rom 24 percent between 1994 and

    2001 to 57 percent between 2002 and 2013.

    But the correlation between M1 money sup-

    ply in the U.S. and China is negative, and it

    weakened rom –59 percent between 1994

    FIGURE 1

    CPI Inflation

    SOURCES: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED).

    1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004

    United States

    China

    2006 2008 2010 2012

    30

    25

    20

    15

    10

    5

    0

    –5

        P   e   r   c   e   n    t    C    h   a   n   g   e    f   r   o   m     Y

       e   a   r    A   g   o

    U.S. Recessions

    China Joined WTO

    FIGURE 2

    Food Price Growth

    SOURCES: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED).

    1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004

    U.S. Recessions

    China Joined WTO

    United StatesChina

    2006 2008 2010 2012

    45

    35

    25

    15

    5

    –5

    –15

        P   e   r   c   e   n    t    C    h   a   n   g   e    f   r   o   m     Y

       e   a   r

        A   g   o

    14  The Regional Economist  |  October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    15/24

    E N D N O T E S

     1  Correlation is a measure o the statistical relation-

    ship between two random variables. I they are

    perectly synchronized in movements, the correla-

    tion is 1; i they have no relationship or similaritie

    at all, then the correlation is 0.

     2  I the money supply in the U.S. increases, there

    is more money chasing the same amount o

    goods, putting upward pressure on U.S. prices.

    Tereore, China’s money supply has to increase

    in order to maintain the same exchange rate level,

    which should also lead to higher prices in China.

    Troughout this article, we use M1 money stock as

    a measure o the money supply; M1 includes notes

    and coins in circulation, traveler’s checks, demand

    deposits and checkable deposits.

     3  Even though U.S. ood prices are not as highly

    correlated with international soybean prices, the

    correlation strengthened in the period afer 20 02.

    and 2001 to –28 percent between 2002 and

    2013. Moreover, there has not been any sig-

    nificant shif in monetary and exchange rate

    policy toward closer policy coordination. I

    anything, China has relaxed the yuan’s link

    to the U.S. dollar in recent years.

    Agricultural Trade Volumes

    Given that the price correlations are

    markedly stronger afer China joined the

    WO, and since the other two possible

    explanations are not very conclusive, the

    structural change can likely be explained

    by the strong increase in trade, particularly

    agricultural trade, between China and the

    U.S. From 1991 until 2001, when China

     joined the WO, agricultural exports rom

    the U.S. to China grew 168 percent and agri-

    cultural imports grew 146 percent. During

    the 10 years afer China joined the WO,

    agricultural exports rom the U.S. to China

    and imports rom China to the U.S. grew

    874 percent and 388 percent, respectively.

    (See Figure 3.)

    In 2013 alone, about 18 percent o total

    U.S. agricultural exports went to China

    ($25.9 bill ion), including $13.4 bill ion in

    soybeans, $4.7 billion in grain and eed

    cereal, $3.7 billion in livestock and ani-

    mal products, and $2.2 billion in cotton.

    However, only about 4 percent o U.S.

    agricultural imports in 2013 came rom

    China ($4.4 bil lion), including $1.7 billionin ruit and vegetable products, $0.6 billion

    in livestock and animal products, and

    $0.5 billion in grain and eed cereal, in addi-

    tion to $2.7 bil lion o fish (which is consid-

    ered a nonagricultural commodity).

    Soybean trade is particularly interest-

    ing. International prices or soybeans are

    highly correlated with ood prices around

    the world. Te correlations strengthened

    afer 2002 or China, the U.S. and the entire

    world.3 (See the table.) Since the early 2000s,

    soybeans have accounted or 40 to 60 per-cent o U.S. agricultural exports to China,

    peaking at 70 percent in 2009. Soybeans

    drove most o the surge in agricultural trade

    between both countries afer 2002.

    Intersecting Needs

    Agricultural trade between China and

    the U.S.—the two largest economies in the

    world—is substantial and has been increas-

    ing rapidly and steadily, making not only

    China’s ood prices sensitive to those in the

    U.S., but also vice versa. Urbanization and

    higher incomes have helped shif Chinese

    people toward more protein-based diets,

    thus ueling demand or eed cereal and live-

    stock and putting upward pressure on U.S.

    agricultural products. Te heavy reliance by

    Americans on consumer goods rom China

    may also make the U.S. cost o living sensi-

    tive to that in China, and Chinese produc-

    tion costs, especially wages, have been rising

    rapidly in recent years. Such developments

    can only imply stronger cross-country cor-

    relations in ood prices and CPI inflation

    between the two countries.

    Yi Wen is an economist and Maria A. Arias is aresearch associate, both at the Federal ReserveBank of St. Louis. For more on Wen’s work, seehttp://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/wen.

    FIGURE 3

    Agricultural Trade between China and the U.S.

    SOURCES: U.S. Census Bureau, U.S. Department of Agriculture Foreign Agricultural Service.

        1    9    9    1

        1    9    9    2

        1    9    9    3

        1    9    9    4

        1    9    9    5

        1    9    9    6

        1    9    9    7

        1    9    9    8

        1    9    9    9

        2    0    0    0

        2    0    0    1

        2    0    0    2

        2    0    0    3

        2    0    0    4

        2    0    0    5

        2    0    0    6

        2    0    0    7

        2    0    0    8

        2    0    0    9

        2    0    1    0

        2    0    1    1

        2    0    1    2

        2    0    1    3

    U.S. Recessions

    China Joined WTO

    Exports to China (Left Axis)

    Imports from China (Right Axis)

    30

    25

    20

    15

    10

    5

    0

        B    i    l    l    i   o   n   s

       o    f    D   o    l    l   a   r   s

    6

    5

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

        B    i    l    l    i   o   n   s

       o    f    D   o    l    l   a   r   s

     Food Prices inU.S. and China

     CPI in

    U.S. and China

    International Soybean Prices

    U.S. Food Prices China Food Prices World Food Prices

    1994-2001 0.41 0.24 0.25 0.14 0.45

    2002-2013 0.62 0.57 0.38 0.65 0.76

    Selected Correlations

    SOURCES: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, International Monetary Fund, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations,Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) and Haver Analytics.

    NOTE: The first two columns in the table show the correlation in food price fluctuations, as well as that of CPI inflation, in both countries (columns) during therespective periods (rows). Likewise, the right-hand side of the table shows the correlation between international soybean prices and food prices in each of thethree regions during the respective periods. (See endnote 1 for an explanation of correlation.)

    The Regional Economist  | www.stlouisfed.org  15

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    16/24

    Jackson experienced a manuacturingboom in the 1990s that set the stage oreconomic growth in the ollowing decade

    and beyond. From 1990 to 2000, manu-

    acturing employment in the two largest

    counties in the area—Chester and Madi-son—increased by more than a third, even

    as manuacturing employment nationwide

    ell slightly. Both population and nonarm

    payrolls in Jackson grew aster than the

    national average during this period.

    Jackson’s road and rail connections, as

    well as its low rates o unionization and

    numerous state and local incentives, made

    it an attractive location or manuacturers;

    Jackson’s position on Interstate 40 between

    Memphis and Nashville gives local com-

    panies access to the logistics and distribu-tion network in Memphis and the growing

    markets and industrial base o the Nashville

    area. While manuacturing is still vital to

    Jackson’s economy, in recent years the city

    has emerged as the center or services in this

    otherwise rural area.

    Te Jackson metropolitan statistical area

    (MSA), which now includes Chester, Crock-

    ett and Madison counties, has a population

    o about 130,650 people and a labor orce o

    about 63,190. Between 2000 and 2013, the

    population o the MSA increased 7 per-

    cent, slower than the growth rates in both

    ennessee (13.9 percent) and the nation

    (15.6 percent). Chester County, home to

    13.3 percent o the MSA’s population, grewthe astest (11.6 percent), ollowed by Madi-

    son County (7.2 percent), where the majority

    o the Jackson-area population resides.

    Crockett County registered growth o just

    0.3 percent.

    Te borders o Jackson’s MSA are in flux.

    Last year, the U.S. Office o Management

    and Budget added Crockett County to the

    area based on its increasing economic ties

    to Jackson. However, the Bureau o Labor

    Statistics (BLS) has yet to make the change,

    still considering the MSA to be made up o just Chester and Madison counties. Unless

    otherwise indicated in this article, the use

    o Jackson reers to the three-county area.

    In 2013, Jackson’s gross metropolitan

    product was $5.77 billion, about 8.5 percent

    o the size o the nearby Memphis economy

    and 5.7 percent o the size o the Nash-

     ville economy. Per capita personal income

    in Jackson grew 41.4 percent to $36,721

    between 2002 and 2012, aster than the

    37.6 percent growth rate or the nation.

    Although per capita personal income in

    Jackson is 16 percent lower than the national

    average, the cost o living is 18 percent lower.

    In Madison County, 23.8 percent o

    those 25 and older hold a bachelor’s degreeor higher. In Chester and Crockett coun-

    ties, 15.4 and 12.3 percent hold a bachelor’s

    degree or higher, respectively. Te average

    or the U.S. is 28.5 percent.

    Economic Drivers

    In 2000, manuacturing was the largest

    sector (by employment) in Madison and

    Chester counties, employing more than

    20 percent o workers.1 oday, manuactur-

    ing is the third-largest sector by employ-

    ment in this area and makes up 13.3 percento total employment. (Still, the percentage

    is higher than the nation’s 8.7 percent.)

    Manuacturers Delta Faucet, Kellogg,

    Pinnacle Foods, and Stanley Black and

    Decker are among the 10 largest employers

    in Madison County. Te area continues to

    attract investment in manuacturing: Te

    Jackson Chamber o Commerce reports that

    there was more than $1 billion in industrial

    investment between 2003 and 2013.

    M E T R O P R O F I L E

    ManufacturingShares the Stagewith Service Sectorsin Jackson, Tenn.

    By James D. Eubanks and Charles S. Gascon

    In western ennessee, the area around Jackson has leveraged

    its manuacturing base to evolve into a center or services in

    the largely rural stretch between Memphis and Nashville.

    West Tennessee Healt

    employs more than 5,0

    PHOTO COURTESY OF WEST TENNESS

    16  The Regional Economist  |  October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    17/24

    Te education and health services sector

    has become increasingly important to the

    local economy. In late 2009, this sector

    surpassed manuacturing to become the

    largest private sector by employment in

    Madison and Chester counties. Te major-

    ity o employees in this sector work in

    health care and social services. Jackson’s

    health care providers have grown to serve

    the entire region between Memphis and

    Nashville: Te Jackson chamber reports

    that more than 60 percent o the patients

    at Jackson’s largest hospital are not rom

    Madison County, where Jackson is the

    county seat. Te largest employer by ar

    in Madison County is West ennessee

    Healthcare, which employs more than

    5,000. Other top-10 employers in Madison

    County include Union University and the

    Regional Hospital o Jackson.

    Although the rising importance oeducation and health care reflects Jack-

    son’s emergence as the hub or services in

    the area, it is also part o a national trend.

    Between 2003 and 2013, the sector grew

    28 percent in Jackson’s two largest counties

    and 25.6 percent nationwide. Te sector

    accounts or about the same share o

    employment in the area (15.9 percent)

    as in the U.S. (15.5 percent).

    Meanwhile, the public sector has been

    an important source o employment in

    Jackson or decades. Government becamethe largest sector by employment in Mad-

    ison and Chester counties in late 2003,

    largely because o declines in manuact-

    uring employment rather than increases

    in government employment. At the start

    o the recession in late 2007, government

    employment was 12,300; in March 2014,

    it was 12,700. Te majority o government

    employees in the area work or local gov-

    ernment. Tree o the 10 largest employers

    in Madison County are in the public sector:

    the city o Jackson, Madison County gov-

    ernment and the Jackson-Madison County

    School System. Te ennessee Supreme

    Court’s courthouse or West ennessee is

    also located in Jackson.

    Current Conditions

    At 7.8 percent in July 2014, the unem-

    ployment rate in the three-county MSA

    is higher than the nation’s (6.2) and en-

    nessee’s (7.1). However, the rate has allen

    more quickly in Jackson than in the nation

    as a result o both increasing employmentand a declining labor orce. Between May

    2013 and May 2014, Jackson’s rate declined

    rom 8.9 percent to 7.0 percent, while the

    U.S. rate declined rom 7.5 percent to

    6.3 percent. Te unemployment rate in

    Jackson increased during the summer as the

    labor orce grew aster than employment.

    Nonarm payrolls in Jackson’s two largest

    counties grew much more quickly than the

    national average rom October 2010 to Febru-

    ary 2013. Most jobs added during this time

    were in the proessional and business servicessector. Te education and health services

    sector also steadily added jobs during this

    time, as did the wholesale trade sector. Later

     Jackson, Tenn. 

    Population 130,645

    Labor Force 63,190

    Unemployment Rate 7.8%

    Personal Income (per capita) $36,721

    Gross Metropolitan Product $5.77 billion

    MSA Snapshot

    LARGEST LOCAL EMPLOYERS

    1. West Tennessee Healthcare 5,368

    2. Jackson-Madison County School System 2,019

    3. Delta Faucet 880

    4. Union University 835

    5. Kellogg 735

    Retail Trade Manufacturing

    Wholesale Trade

    Other Services and

    Information

    Professional and

    Business Services

    Financial Activities 3%Construction, Natural

    Resources and Mining

    Leisure and

    Hospitality Education and

    Health Services

    Government

    10%

    13%

    16%

    20%5%

    5%

    9%

    12%

    4%

    Transport, Warehousing

    and Utilities 3%

    NONFARM EMPLOYMENT BY SECTOR

    For a long time, manufacturing drove the economy of the Jackson area, thanks to the area’sroad and rail connections, low rates of unionization, and numerous state and local incentives.The sector is still important, what with major employers such as Delta Faucet, Kellogg, PinnacleFoods, and Stanley Black and Decker, and productivity is still rising. However, employment inthis sector is declining.

    Today, more people in the area work in service sectors than in manufacturing. The governmentsector is No. 1 in employment, largely because of declines in manufacturing employment ratherthan increases in government workers. The majority of these employees work for local governmentincluding the city of Jackson, Madison County and the Jackson-Madison County School System.The private sector that employs the most is education and health services.

    PHOTO COURTESY OF DELTA FAUCET PHOTO COURTESY OF TENNESSEE COURT

    The Regional Economist  | www.stlouisfed.org  17

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    18/24

    2004 2006   2008   2010 2012 2014

    101

    100

    99

    98

    97

    96

    9594

    93

    92

    91

     Jackson

    U.S.

    Tennessee    I   n    d   e   x ,

        D   e   c   e   m    b   e   r    2    0    0    7  =

        1    0    0

     July

    FIGURE 3

    Nonfarm Payrolls

    2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

    160

    150

    140

    130

    120

    110

    100

    90

    80

    70

    60

    Real Manufacturing Output

    Manufacturing Employment

    Output per Employee

        I   n    d   e   x ,

        2    0    0    1  =

        1    0    0

    FIGURE 4

     Jackson Manufacturing Productivity

    NOTE: Real manufacturing output is the dollar value of manufacturing output in inflation-adjusted terms. Output per employee is real manufacturing outputdivided by the number of employees in manufacturing.

    To see these charts with the latest data, as well as to see other data on the Jackson MSA, check out our data dashboard at

    http://research.stlouisfed.org/dashboard/872. In each of the four charts above, the gray bars represent recessions. The Bureau

    of Labor Statistics was a source for data in all four charts; in addition, Figure 4 used data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis.Employment data from the BLS Establishment Survey do not cover Crockett County.

    in 2013, nonarm payroll growth slowed to the

    national rate and has since dropped below that

    rate. otal employment has not quite recov-

    ered to its prerecession peak: In July 2014, tota

    nonarm employment was 0.3 percent below

    its level in December 2007.

    Manuacturing employment in Chester

    and Madison counties has declined in year-

    over-year terms or the past six years. Tis

    mirrors the national trend. Te declines in

    manuacturing employment could partly be

    a result o increases in efficiency: Jackson’s

    manuacturing output in real terms in

    2012 was only 2.4 percent below its level in

    2001, when manuacturing employment

    in Jackson was near its peak. Although

    manuacturing employment has decreased

    significantly, Jackson continues to attract

    industrial businesses. According to figures

    rom the Jackson chamber, new investment

    rom existing industry in 2012 was aboveits 2003-2012 average. wo manuacturing

    companies have recently announced plans

    to expand or open new acilities in Jack-

    son. Still, total business investment, which

    includes investment by newly recruited

    companies, has allen over the past decade.

    Te education and health services sector

    experienced sustained growth between 2010

    and 2012, but this growth has since slowed

    considerably. West ennessee Healthcare

    has announced plans to cut positions, offer

    early retirement packages to hundreds oemployees and reduce paid time off.

    Going Forward

    Te diversification o Jackson’s economy

    since 2000 has positioned it or moderate

    growth over the next 10 years, with the

    majority o employment growth likely to

    come rom service industries.

    Employment in Jackson’s second-largest

    sector, education and health services, is

    expected to continue to grow nationally.

    Te Bureau o Labor Statistics projectseducation services employment to grow by

    1.9 percent and health care and social assis-

    tance employment to grow by 2.6 percent

    rom 2012 to 2022. Over the past decade,

    Jackson’s growth in these sectors has been

    consistently higher than national growth. I

    this trend continues, these sectors will pro-

     vide many o the new jobs in Jackson over

    the next 10 years.

    FIGURE 1

    Manufacturing Employment

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

    150

    140

    130

    120

    110

    100

    90

    80

    70

    60

    50

     JacksonU.S.

    Tennessee    I   n    d   e   x ,    J   a   n   u   a   r   y    1    9    9    0  =

        1    0    0

     July 2014

    1990 1995   2000   2005 2010

    26

    24

    22

    20

    18

    16

    14

    12

    10

    8

    Manufacturing

    Education and Health Services    P   e   r   c   e   n    t   o    f    T   o    t

       a    l    J   a   c    k   s   o   n    E   m   p    l   o   y   m   e   n    t

    Government

     July 2014

    FIGURE 2

     Jackson Employment Shares

    18  The Regional Economist  |  October 2014

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - Oct. 2014

    19/24

    Eleven more charts are available on the web version of this issue. Among the areas they cover are agriculture, commercialbanking, housing permits, income and jobs. Much of the data are specific to the Eighth District. To see these charts, go towww.stlouisfed.org/economyataglance.

    U . S . A G R I C U L T U R A L T R A D E AVERAGE LAND VALUES ACROSS THE EIGHTH DISTRICT

    ’09 ’10 ’11 ’12 ’13 ’14

    90

    75

    60

    45

    30

    15

    0

    NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

    Exports

    Imports

     JulyTrade Balance

        B    I    L    L    I    O    N    S

         O    F

        D    O    L    L    A    R    S

    2013:Q2 2013:Q3 2013:Q4 2014:Q1 2014:Q2

    7,000

    6,000

    5,000

    4,000

    3,000

    2,000

    1,000

    0

        D    O    L    L    A    R    S

         P    E    R

         A    C    R    E

    Quality Farmland   Ranchland or Pastureland

    SOURCE: Agricultural Finance Monitor .

    C I V I L I A N U N E M P L O Y M E N T R A T E I N T E R E S T R AT E S 

    ’09 ’10 ’11 ’12 ’13 ’14

    11

    10

    9

    8

    7

    6

    5

    4

             P         E         R         C         E         N         T

    September

    ’09 ’10 ’11 ’12 ’13 ’14

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

    10-Year Treasury

    Fed Funds Target

    August1-Year Treasury

             P         E         R         C         E         N         T

    NOTE: On Dec. 16, 2008, the FOMC set a target range for

    the federal funds rate of 0 to 0.25 percent. The observations

    plotted since then are the midpoint of the range (0.125 percent).

    I N F L A T I O N - I N D E X E D T R E A S U R Y Y I E L D S P R E A D S R AT ES ON FE DE RA L F UN DS FU TU RE S O N S EL EC TE D D AT ES

    3.00

    2.75

    2.50

    2.25

    2.00

    1.75

    1.50

    1.25

    1.00

    NOTE: Weekly data.

    5-Year

    10-Year

    20-Year

             P         E         R         C         E         N         T

    Sept. 26

    ’10 ’11 ’12 ’13 ’14   1st-ExpiringContract

    3-Month 6-Month 12-Month

    0.50

    0.45

    0.40

    0.35

    0.30

    0.25

    0.20

    0.15

    0.10

    0.05

    0.00

    CONTRACT SETTLEMENT MONTH

             P         E