regulating banking agents - world...

20
A major obstacle to financial inclusion is cost—not only the cost incurred by banks in servicing low- value accounts and extending banking infrastructure to underserved, low-income areas, but also the cost incurred by poor customers (in terms of time and expense) in reaching bank branches. Achieving financial inclusion therefore requires innovative business models that dramatically reduce costs for everyone and thus pave the way to profitable extension of financial services to the world’s poor. This is why banking agents are part of an increasingly potent model for financial inclusion. 1 Take, for example, Kareem. Kareem stands behind the counter of a small general store on a bustling roundabout in the heart of Karachi. Although he sells a variety of toiletries and other products, the largest sign outside his shop advertises his role as an agent for Easypaisa, the mobile telephone funds transfer product of Tameerbank. Kareem is one of Tameerbank’s 8,000 active agents—effectively serving as an extension of the bank’s network by providing cash-in and cash- out services and other financial services to Easypaisa customers. All parties benefit. The bank saves the cost of building expensive branches and hiring staff, enabling it to reach low-income people with financial services. Kareem earns a transaction fee from Tameerbank to supplement his sales. And customers save on transportation time and expense because Kareem’s shop is close by, and they also enjoy the generally lower cost of the service. More and more banks (and occasionally nonbank financial service providers) around the world—from Brazil to Mali, to India and the Philippines—are using agents like Kareem. This branchless banking model is evolving, with regulation assuming a central role in enabling—and sometimes limiting—its spread. Regulators struggle with how to promote financial inclusion through profitable, lower cost, delivery models while simultaneously protecting consumers and the integrity of financial services. This Focus Note reviews global regulation of the use of agents by banks (and where noted, nonbank service providers) and focuses on four questions related to the safe and scalable use of agents: 1. Who can be an agent? 2. What roles can agents play in the provision of financial services? 3. On what commercial terms can banks engage agents? 4. What is the extent of bank liability for agents? This Focus Note concludes that regulators can safely permit the use of bank agents to offer financial services and verify customer identity for know-your-customer purposes with minimal restrictions on agent eligibility, compensation, and structuring—provided that regulators hold banks liable for the provision of financial services by their agents. (See Table 1 for selected bank agent regulatory provisions from around the world.) Who can be an agent? Regulators want to ensure that agents, as extensions of the banking system, are able to provide professional customer service, keep records, handle cash, and manage liquidity. As a result, one of the primary questions regulators grapple with is who can act as an agent. Legal Form Many countries permit a wide range of individuals and legal entities to be agents for banks. Other countries limit the list of eligible agents on the basis of legal form. For example, India permits a wide variety of eligible agents, such as certain nonprofits, post offices, kirana shop owners, 2 retired teachers, and most recently, for- profit companies, including mobile network operators (MNOs). 3 Explicitly excluded, however, are the largest microfinance institutions (MFIs) registered as nonbank finance companies (NBFCs). Kenya takes a different approach, requiring agents to be for-profit actors and Regulating Banking Agents No. 68 March 2011 FOCUS NOTE Michael Tarazi and Paul Breloff 1 The use of the term “agent” in this Focus Note is not necessarily a reference to an agent in the traditional legal sense of a party authorized by a principal to act on the principal’s behalf and for whom such principal is liable with respect to activities taken by the agent within the scope of its agency relationship or contract. 2 Kirana shops are the traditional, sole-proprietorship “mom and pop” shops popular in India; they account for a large percentage of India’s retail market. 3 RBI/2005-06/288, DBOD.No.BL.BC. 58/22.01.001/2005-2006 (25 January 2006), as subsequently amended. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Upload: phungdieu

Post on 22-Aug-2019

212 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

A major obstacle to financial inclusion is cost—not

only the cost incurred by banks in servicing low-

value accounts and extending banking infrastructure

to underserved, low-income areas, but also the

cost incurred by poor customers (in terms of time

and expense) in reaching bank branches. Achieving

financial inclusion therefore requires innovative

business models that dramatically reduce costs

for everyone and thus pave the way to profitable

extension of financial services to the world’s poor.

This is why banking agents are part of an increasingly

potent model for financial inclusion.1 Take, for

example, Kareem. Kareem stands behind the counter

of a small general store on a bustling roundabout in

the heart of Karachi. Although he sells a variety of

toiletries and other products, the largest sign outside

his shop advertises his role as an agent for Easypaisa,

the mobile telephone funds transfer product of

Tameerbank. Kareem is one of Tameerbank’s 8,000

active agents—effectively serving as an extension of

the bank’s network by providing cash-in and cash-

out services and other financial services to Easypaisa

customers.

All parties benefit. The bank saves the cost of building

expensive branches and hiring staff, enabling it to reach

low-income people with financial services. Kareem earns

a transaction fee from Tameerbank to supplement his

sales. And customers save on transportation time and

expense because Kareem’s shop is close by, and they

also enjoy the generally lower cost of the service.

More and more banks (and occasionally nonbank

financial service providers) around the world—from

Brazil to Mali, to India and the Philippines—are using

agents like Kareem. This branchless banking model

is evolving, with regulation assuming a central role

in enabling—and sometimes limiting—its spread.

Regulators struggle with how to promote financial

inclusion through profitable, lower cost, delivery

models while simultaneously protecting consumers

and the integrity of financial services.

This Focus Note reviews global regulation of the

use of agents by banks (and where noted, nonbank

service providers) and focuses on four questions

related to the safe and scalable use of agents:

1. Who can be an agent?

2. What roles can agents play in the provision of

financial services?

3. On what commercial terms can banks engage

agents?

4. What is the extent of bank liability for agents?

This Focus Note concludes that regulators can safely

permit the use of bank agents to offer financial services

and verify customer identity for know-your-customer

purposes with minimal restrictions on agent eligibility,

compensation, and structuring—provided that

regulators hold banks liable for the provision of financial

services by their agents. (See Table 1 for selected bank

agent regulatory provisions from around the world.)

Who can be an agent?

Regulators want to ensure that agents, as extensions

of the banking system, are able to provide

professional customer service, keep records, handle

cash, and manage liquidity. As a result, one of the

primary questions regulators grapple with is who can

act as an agent.

Legal Form

Many countries permit a wide range of individuals and

legal entities to be agents for banks. Other countries

limit the list of eligible agents on the basis of legal form.

For example, India permits a wide variety of eligible

agents, such as certain nonprofits, post offices, kirana

shop owners,2 retired teachers, and most recently, for-

profit companies, including mobile network operators

(MNOs).3 Explicitly excluded, however, are the largest

microfinance institutions (MFIs) registered as nonbank

finance companies (NBFCs). Kenya takes a different

approach, requiring agents to be for-profit actors and

Regulating Banking Agents

No. 68March 2011

foc

us

no

te

Michael Tarazi

and Paul Breloff

1 the use of the term “agent” in this focus note is not necessarily a reference to an agent in the traditional legal sense of a party authorized by a principal to act on the principal’s behalf and for whom such principal is liable with respect to activities taken by the agent within the scope of its agency relationship or contract.

2 Kirana shops are the traditional, sole-proprietorship “mom and pop” shops popular in India; they account for a large percentage of India’s retail market.

3 RBI/2005-06/288, DBoD.no.BL.Bc. 58/22.01.001/2005-2006 (25 January 2006), as subsequently amended.

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

WB456286
Typewritten Text
82563

2

disallowing nonprofit entities (like nongovernment

organizations [NGOs], educational institutions, and

faith-based organizations).4 In another example,

Brazil permits any legal entity to act as an agent, but

prevents individuals from doing so.5

These different approaches reflect the different

concerns of regulators in each country. In India,

regulators originally excluded for-profit entities from

the list of eligible agents reportedly due to a sense that

for-profits would be inclined to exploit poor clients. In

Kenya, by contrast, regulators reportedly felt that acting

as agents could steer NGOs away from their social

mission. In Brazil, the regulator felt that preventing

individuals from acting as agents would reduce

fraud, facilitate supervision, and promote consumer

confidence, though in practice, it has been difficult to

prevent individuals from operating as agents.

While these varying limits may be reasonably

motivated, they may unintentionally restrict the

involvement of actors who may be the most

promising agents due to their existing network

of retail locations and their capacity to manage

decentralized operations. As global experience

deepens, some countries have relaxed initial

restrictions. The Reserve Bank of India, for example,

initially restricted agents to nonprofits, post offices,

and cooperatives—a restriction that contributed to a

sluggish launch of branchless banking. But revisions in

2009 extended eligibility to small-scale retailers and

other well-placed actors, and revisions in 2010 further

extended eligibility to most for-profits,6 resulting in

a number of bank–MNO partnerships. Regulators

are now trending toward liberalizing agent eligibility

requirements, recognizing that overly restrictive

policies can conflict with financial inclusion.

Broad eligibility rules alone, however, do not

guarantee successful agency models. For instance,

Colombia’s 2006 decree on agent banking permits

any type of legal entity, including savings and credit

cooperatives, to be a banking agent.7 Nevertheless,

banks have been slow to engage agents—to date,

only two Colombian banks have a significant number

of agents.8

Location

Some countries also restrict the location of agents,

though such restrictions are sometimes eased when

regulators recognize that the regulations create

obstacles to financial inclusion. For example, due to

concerns that agents could threaten bank branches,

Brazilian regulation originally allowed agents only in

municipalities that did not have bank branches. To

facilitate customer access to government transfers,

this restriction was lifted in 2000,9 enabling the

expansion of agents as a lower cost and more

convenient alternative to branch banking, even in

places already served by bank branches.

Indian regulators initially required agents to be

located within 15 kilometers of a “base branch” of the

appointing bank in rural areas, and within 5 kilometers

in urban areas. This policy, intended to ensure adequate

bank supervision of its agents, limited the use of agents

by banks with only a few branches. Consequently,

regulators have since expanded the distance to 30

kilometers, and banks can seek exemption from this

requirement in areas with underserved populations

where a branch would not be viable.10

Experience has shown that overly restrictive location

requirements can complicate the business case for

viable agent-based banking and ultimately work

against financial inclusion goals. In addition, the

real-time nature of most agent services has enabled

remote supervision, thereby obviating one of the

central arguments for location restrictions. Countries

such as Mexico appear to be taking their cue from the

experience of other countries and although originally

having considered location-based restrictions,

ultimately decided against them.

4 Guideline on Agent Banking—cBK/PG/15, section 4.2.5 Resolution cMn 3110/03, Article 1 (July 2003), as amended by Resolution cMn 3156/03 (December 2003).6 RBI/2010-11/217 DBoD.no.BL.Bc.43 /22.01.009/2010-11, Art. 3 (28 september 2010). However, nBfcs, the corporate form of the

largest MfIs, are still expressly prohibited from acting as agents due to concerns over the possibility of comingling customer funds with intermediated funds.

7 Decree 2233 (July 2006), as amended by Decree 1121 (March 2009).8 see cGAP (2010).9 Resolution cMn 2707/00 (2000).10 RBI/2007-2008/295 (24 April 2008).

3

Agent Due Diligence: The “Fit and Proper” Test

Regulations often impose some form of “fit and

proper” requirements, mandating a form of agent

due diligence that requires financial institutions to

verify that would-be agents have good reputations,

no criminal records, and no history of financial

trouble or insolvency. Fit-and-proper tests sometimes

go beyond these requirements to specify other

qualifications, such as citizenship, literacy, minimum

age, or technical or operational capability. Such

regulations are deemed important as a way to ensure

appropriate customer service, security, and reliability.

Regulators should nevertheless be mindful of

unwittingly creating costly burdens that threaten

the business models they are regulating. While fit-

and-proper criteria listed in regulation often are not

problematic, providers and agents have occasionally

argued that compliance with particular details can

impose significant cost, particularly with respect

to gathering documentation. For example, while

requiring a clean credit history may seem reasonable,

many countries do not possess credit registries

or, if they do, such registries would not include

information about small retail establishments likely

to act as agents. Even when credit registries do exist,

obtaining a credit history may be costly and time-

consuming, posing a particular challenge for remote

retailers most likely to reach the underbanked.

Recommendations

• Tailor fit-and-proper restrictions narrowly so as to

enable best placed actors to be agents:

Permit organizations with large distribution

networks to play an active role in serving as (or

managing) agents—e.g., MNOs, chain retailers,

etc.

Avoid location-based restrictions, as the costs

of such restrictions unduly limit the spread of

agents and ultimately limit financial access.

• Frame fit-and-proper requirements in a proportionate

manner, paying particular attention to the potential

costs and practicality of demonstrating fitness (e.g.,

credit reports, etc.) and complying with ongoing

requirements (e.g., periodic recertifications).

What roles can an agent play?

Agents may be able to play a role in a broad range

of services, including account opening, cash-in and

cash-out services (including cash disbursement of

bank-approved loans and repayment collection),

payment and transfer services (including international

remittances and person-to-person domestic

transfers), and perhaps even credit underwriting.11

Regulation, however, often sets limits on the role

agents can play in providing financial services,

reflecting concerns over the reliability, security, and

competence of such third parties. Some regulators

are even considering different categories of agents

based on the services offered—with less stringent

eligibility standards for those agents offering only

basic services, such as cash-in and cash-out services.

Cash-in and Cash-out Services

Most regulations permit agents to process cash-in

(deposit) and cash-out (withdrawal) transactions. This

enables customers to conveniently store and access

cash in areas underserved by traditional branch or

automated teller machine (ATM) channels. It also

makes commercial sense for institutions: migrating

low-value transactions to cheaper channels helps the

business case for offering basic accounts, and may

serve to decongest crowded bank branches.12

In some contexts, however, this basic functionality

has been compromised by legacy “outsourcing” or

other banking regulations that restrict cash-handling

outside of branches. A common obstacle is regulation

that deems cash-in services as “deposit” taking, an

activity that is limited to banks or that otherwise

requires licensing (such as a money remittance

11 to date, with rare exception, agents have not been permitted to play a role in making decisions to extend credit on behalf of financial institutions; regulators believe this kind of technical judgment raises not only prudential concerns but also consumer protection concerns, particularly if agent fees are linked to the amount of any credit. nevertheless, agents sometimes play a role in evaluating credit applications even though final decisions on credit extension are taken by bank employees.

12 for a brief discussion on cost reductions associated with branchless banking, see Ivatury and Mas (2008).

4

license). Such licenses are often burdensome to

obtain and keep for smaller agents. For example,

in Indonesia, agents providing cash-out services

require separate licensing as a “money remitter,”

and the process and requirements of such license

(such as risk management mechanisms and proof of

operational readiness) are impractical for small retail

agents. Indeed, Indonesian regulators recognize

that this requirement has effectively blocked the

development of viable agent networks.13

Recommendation

Regulators should permit cash-in and cash-out

services at agent locations. In particular, regulators

should understand that when transactions are real

time and transacted against the agent’s own account,

cash-in and cash-out services do not present more

risk than bank deposits. (See Box 1.)

Verifying Customer Identity

One of the biggest challenges many regulators

face is what role, if any, to permit agents to play in

conducting customer due diligence (CDD) measures

required for account opening and other transactions.

Permitting customer verification at remote locations

through agents (who likely have no experience in CDD

measures and are one step removed from the financial

institutions well versed in CDD) could impede anti-

money laundering and combating financing of terrorism

(AML/CFT) efforts. Nevertheless, the potential financial

inclusion benefits could be significant.

The Financial Action Task Force (FATF) is the

international body responsible for developing and

promoting national and international standards

and policies to combat money laundering and

terrorist financing. It requires that financial service

providers identify “and verify” customer identity

using “reliable, independent” documentation,

though FATF does not expressly mandate the forms

of such documentation.14 In an effort to comply

with this requirement, national governments have

sometimes insisted on documentation, such as

specific identification cards or proof of address, that

are beyond the reach of many unbanked poor. In

addition, some have even required biometric data

that are not only too difficult to obtain for poor

customers but also require infrastructure (such as

eye scanners or fingerprint readers) that is too costly

or technologically incompatible with the realities

of local agent locations. Pakistani regulations, for

example, require fingerprint scans as a condition of

account registration, but the technology required for

accurate fingerprinting makes it too costly for many

smaller agents to operate in low-traffic areas. Aware

of the negative impact on financial inclusion, Pakistani

regulators have issued temporary exemptions to this

requirement to enable the spread and adoption of

branchless banking services through agents.

13 for a discussion on the use of agents in Indonesia, see cGAP (2010b).14 fAtf 40 Recommendations, Recommendation 5.

Box 1. How Agents Commonly Provide Cash-In/Cash-Out Services

While agents can provide a wide array of financial

services, agents are most often used as cash-in/cash-

out points where customers may deposit funds into

their account and redeem electronic value for cash.

These agents often operate, particularly when the

mobile telephone channel is used, by first opening

and funding their own account with the bank,

and all transactions with customers are transacted

against this personal agent account. For example,

when a customer wishes cash to be credited to her

electronic account, the agent accepts the cash and

transfers electronic value from the agent’s account

to the customer’s account. Conversely, when a

customer wishes to redeem electronic value for

cash, the customer transfers electronic value to the

agent’s account, and the agent gives the customer

the corresponding amount from the agent’s cash

reserves. These agents are sometimes viewed as

“cash merchants”—retailers who engage in the

business of transferring value between electronic and

physical forms. Since these cash merchants transact

against their own accounts—and because transactions

are typically conducted in real time, permitting the

customer to confirm receipt of electronic funds—the

risks involved (such as systemic or consumer protection

risks) may be less than sometimes assumed.

5

Agents (in the traditional legal sense)15 are viewed by

FATF as simply an extension of the financial services

provider, and consequently, the conduct of CDD by

these agents is treated as if conducted by the principal

financial institution. FATF also permits third parties to

perform CDD, provided the financial institution (i )

remains liable for such third-party compliance with

applicable money laundering and terrorist financing

requirements and (ii ) “satisfies itself” that CDD

information will be made readily available to it and

that the third party is regulated and supervised.16 This

last requirement can be problematic in the context of

small retailers conducting CDD since such retailers,

if considered third parties by FATF, may not be

adequately “regulated and supervised.”

It is unclear how FATF views the difference between

an agent and a third party if the bank is liable in

either case. Unsurprisingly, FATF is in the process

of reviewing its recommendations and clarifying the

role of agents and third parties. Recognizing that the

supervision requirement de facto limits the types of

entities who can act as agents, FATF is considering

giving countries more discretion regarding the types

of third parties permitted to engage in CDD, provided

they are supervised or monitored.17 In addition, FATF

is considering adopting a new standard for CDD

verification by other parties—with a central factor

being whether such parties apply their own CDD

procedures or simply implement the procedures of

the bank, subject to the bank’s control.18

Many countries are comfortable in permitting agents

to conduct CDD. Throughout Latin America (such

as in Peru, Colombia, Mexico, and Brazil) banking

agents routinely verify customer identity. In India,

banks “may, if necessary, use the services of the

Business Correspondent for preliminary work relating

to account opening formalities” provided that the

bank remains ultimately liable for observance of AML/

CFT requirements. In Fiji, retail agents may conduct

CDD on behalf of MNOs offering mobile financial

services. In the Philippines, regulators permit licensed

remittance agents (RAs) to verify customer identity,

provided such RAs undergo training, retain records

for five years, and report suspicious transactions.19

Some countries have taken a different path with

respect to the use of agents in CDD—permitting

agents to conduct CDD only with respect to

financial products viewed as lower risk for money

laundering and terrorist financing. In Pakistan, for

example, the 2008 branchless banking regulations

permit banking agents to open Level 1 accounts,

which carry relatively low balance and transfer

limits.20 Similarly in Mexico and Peru, banking

agents may conduct CDD with respect to low-

transactional, low-risk, or basic accounts subject to

deposit and transactional limits.

Regulators are realizing the wisdom of leveraging

the reach of retail agent networks to play a role in

verifying customer identity for account opening and

transactional purposes. The common denominator,

however, is ultimate bank liability for agent

compliance with applicable AML/CFT regulations.

(See “Liability for Agents.”)

Recommendations

• Enable agents to verify customer identity for AML/

CFT purposes.

• Ensure that forms of required identification are

reasonable in light of technical and infrastructural

realities of agent locations.

• Hold financial institution liable for agent compliance

with AML/CFT measures.

15 In a traditional legal sense (and not as most commonly used in branchless banking regulations and in this focus note), an “agent” is a party authorized by a principal to act on the principal’s behalf and for whom such principal is liable with respect to activities taken by the agent within the scope of its agency relationship or contract. Liability can also sometimes extend to agent actions reasonably assumed by customers to be within the scope of the agency.

16 fAtf 40 Recommendations, Recommendation 9.17 fAtf consultation Paper, the Review of the standards—Preparation for the 4th Round of Mutual evaluations, p. 9. (october 2010)18 Ibid.19 Bangko sentral ng Pilipinas, circular 471, series of 2005. It should be noted that such RAs are licensed financial services providers

themselves and are, from a legal perspective, agents of the customer, not agents of another financial services provider. nevertheless, these RAs are often used by other financial services providers to expand outreach of cash-in and cash-out services to customers in areas without a bank branch.

20 state Bank of Pakistan, Branchless Banking Regulations, section 4 (March 2008).

6

On what commercial terms can agents be engaged?

Beyond questions of who can be an agent and what

the agent can do, the business potential for agent

networks can be facilitated or limited by a number

of other critical issues related to how agents are

regulated. These issues include (i) how agents may be

compensated, (ii) whether agents may be engaged

on an exclusive basis, and (iii) how agents can be

managed by an agent network manager (ANM).

Agent Compensation: Fees and Revenue

The spread of branchless banking depends on agents

making an attractive return, whether directly (such

as through transaction fees paid to the agent) or

indirectly (such as in the form of increased footfall,

brand building, customer loyalty, etc.) (Flaming,

McKay, and Pickens 2011). While most regulatory

approaches leave the issue of agent revenue to free

negotiations between the agent and the financial

institution, nearly all countries prohibit the agent from

charging customers directly for agent services, and

some countries even restrict how much a bank can

charge customers for agent transactions. Such well-

meaning regulations, aimed at protecting customers

from excessive fees, can endanger the spread of

branchless banking models if they leave participants

unable to make an acceptable return in light of the

unique challenges and costs of reaching the poor.

In India, for example, agent regulation initially denied

banks and agents the ability to charge customers for

using agents. Recognizing the adverse impact of this

approach on the viability of agent banking models,

the Reserve Bank of India lifted this prohibition in

November 2009,21 and now banks are permitted to

charge reasonable fees under policies approved by

the bank’s board. Regulators may be reassured to

know that, in some cases, market forces moderate

prices even without regulation. For example, Latin

American countries generally permit banks to charge

for agent transactions, although banks do not always

apply such charges due to competitive or affordability

concerns—and often because it is in a bank’s interest

to shift low-value transactions toward agents and

away from more expensive bank branches.

Regulations also sometimes specify that agents

cannot modify charges to customers unless cleared

through the bank—this is the case in Pakistan, for

example, where agents cannot alter the fee structure

set by the bank in any way.22

Even in places where banks are permitted to charge

customers for using agents, regulations often still

require banks to collect these fees directly from

customer accounts (rather than permit agents to

charge customers directly). These regulations are

intended to mitigate the risk of agents using the

collection process to unfairly charge customers

for their services, particularly in locations with few

available agents.

In rare cases, agents have been permitted to set their

own fees (sometimes within a range defined by the

service provider). In Tanzania, agents of one bank

were permitted to establish their own fees on the

assumption that competition in urban areas would

drive fees down, while increased costs of liquidity

management in remote areas would necessitate higher

agent fees. However, a free market approach carries

its own risks. In the case of the Philippines, RAs can

exercise some discretion in setting their own pricing.

One electronic money service provider permits RAs

to charge up to 3 percent of the transaction amount

(even though they are encouraged by the provider

to charge only 1 percent). The lack of uniform fees

has led to some customer confusion and a lack of

a consistent marketing message—factors that may

have contributed to limited customer adoption of

branchless banking services.

Recommendations

• Permit service providers and agents to freely

negotiate fees paid to agents.

• Permit service providers to freely set retail prices,

subject to prevailing consumer protection norms,

such as transparent pricing disclosure.23

• In situations where agents are permitted to set

their customer fees and charge customers directly,

21 RBI/2009-10/238, DBoD.no.BL.Bc. 63 /22.01.009/2009-10 (30 november 2009).22 state Bank of Pakistan, Branchless Banking Regulations, section 6.1 (March 2008).23 for a fuller discussion of consumer protection in the branchless banking context, see Dias and McKee (2010).

7

monitor such pricing for signs of exploitation or

customer confusion.

Agent Exclusivity

Regulations often prohibit banks from contracting

agents on an “exclusive” basis in order to promote

commercial viability, financial inclusion, and

competition. First, the viability of an agent business

depends on sufficient transaction volume, and agents

in low-traffic areas may need to process transactions

on behalf of multiple banks and other service

providers to generate attractive revenues. Second,

in areas facing a deficit of suitable agents, some

regulators believe “no exclusivity” provisions will

increase the chances that multiple banks will penetrate

into remote areas, promoting competition and

outreach and preventing banks from monopolizing

the choicest agents and locations. Regulations in

Kenya for example prohibit agent exclusivity, but

do require each service provider to have a separate

agreement with each agent for supervision and

liability purposes.24 In Fiji, regulators prohibited agent

exclusivity as a condition to launching two mobile

payments platforms—though operators there have

suggested that they pressure agents to favor their

services over those of their rival. For example, an

agent that does not undertake an adequate number

of transactions on behalf of a specific operator may

find her contract cancelled.

In some markets, rather than simply prohibiting

exclusivity, regulators go a step further to promote

sharing. In Pakistan, the Branchless Banking Guidelines

explicitly contemplate the adoption by banks of an

“open architecture” that would enable agents to

serve multiple banks without separate contracts with

each bank. In rare situations, regulators have also

considered mandating “agent interoperability”—in

other words, requiring that an agent, once signed

up by one bank, can be used by customers of any

bank to process transactions. In the Maldives, the

Monetary Authority currently plans to require any

agent, once signed up by one bank, to be able to

process transactions on behalf of customers of any

bank participating in the payments system.

In other cases, regulators permit exclusivity, believing

it improves incentives for providers to invest in

agent banking. Without exclusivity, competitors can

piggyback off of the investment of first movers—

taking advantage of a first mover’s investment in

identifying, vetting, and training potential agents.

While agent regulations in Brazil, Colombia, and Peru

are silent on the question of agent exclusivity, exclusive

arrangements are common in these countries. Other

jurisdictions, such as Nigeria, clarify that agents

are permitted to represent more than one financial

institution, but technically allow agents to enter into

exclusive arrangements should they choose to.

The situation in India is more complicated. While

Indian regulations permit an agent (as in the case

of a large retail chain or other agent with multiple

outlets) to represent more than one bank, “a retail

outlet or a sub-agent of a[n agent] shall represent

and provide banking services of only one bank.”25

Consequently, at the point of customer interface,

exclusivity is the norm—though, as with ATMs, it is

assumed that banks may negotiate with other banks

to arrive at pricing and other terms by which other

bank customers could use the exclusively branded

point of customer interface. This policy is ostensibly

intended to promote clarity for the end user and

ensure clear bank accountability for each location,

though it may make it difficult for banks to compete

in areas facing a deficit of suitable agents. Also, as

a practical matter, this regulation may be difficult to

enforce: industry experts suggest that individuals or

family members working from the same storefront

could sign separate agreements with different banks

and likely escape detection.

The question of agent exclusivity goes beyond

balancing first mover incentives against increased

points of access to maximize short-term financial

inclusion. As markets develop and more actors enter

the sector, the question of exclusivity broadens into a

question of competition policy. (See Box 2.)

Recommendation

Permit temporary agent exclusivity, particularly in the

early stages of sector development, to provide banks

24 Guideline on Agent Banking. section 6.1. As mentioned, Kenya’s regulation applies only to banks, and not to Mnos such as safaricom.25 RBI/2010-11/217 DBoD.no.BL.Bc.43/22.01.009/2010-11, Art. 3 (28 september 2010).

8

with short-term incentives to invest in building agent

networks, while enabling other providers to compete

effectively in the long term in areas with few suitable

agents.

Agent Network Management

While banks are used to managing branches, they

often find that identifying, training, and managing

agents is a different and challenging undertaking.

Consequently, they are increasingly turning to ANMs

to play this role. There are a variety of ANM models

but typically ANMs are (i ) specialized third parties

who contract with banks for outsourced agent

management services, but who do not operate as

agents themselves; (ii) large retailers (such as grocery

chains) or other entities with a large, proprietary

outlet network who sign a single agency agreement

with the bank and who then manage agent functions

at each of their retail outlets; or (iii) third parties

(such as MNOs) who sign a single agency agreement

with the bank but who then subcontract other legal

entities or individuals as agents.

ANMs are often critical for the development

of banking agent networks. Not only do they

simplify the use of agents for banks, but they also

play an important role in managing risk. Due to

their specialized management services and daily

interaction with agent outlets, ANMs are often better

positioned and capitalized to assume liability for their

subagents and indemnify banks for bank payments

made as a result of agent liability. (See “Liability for

Agents.”)

Regulation sometimes restricts ANM models by

preventing agents from subcontracting or otherwise

delegating their agent duties. Kenya’s 2010 Guideline

on Agent Banking, for example, explicitly provides

that an agent shall not “subcontract another entity

Kenya hosts the largest mobile phone-based

branchless banking service in the world. In 2007, MNO

Safaricom launched M-PESA, a money transfer service.

M-PESA now has nearly 13 million customers serviced

by more than 20,000 agents. These agents serve

Safaricom on an exclusive basis, meaning they cannot

provide similar financial services on behalf of other

providers, including banks. After the Kenyan Guideline

on Agent Banking was issued in 2010 (which does not

apply to MNO Safaricom), commercial banks sought to

scale their own agent networks. But now some banks

are crying foul, complaining that the Guideline does

not permit banks to pursue exclusive agent contracts

(putting them at a competitive disadvantage vis-a-vis

Safaricom) and Safaricom’s headstart has allowed it

to use exclusivity provisions to tie up the supply of

potential agents. (Banks are also arguing that agent

qualification criteria and approval processes applicable

to bank agents are unduly burdensome in light of the

lack of similar criteria and processes for MNOs.)

So what’s the regulator to do? Some have argued

that the lack of a level playing field is justified since

banking agents can offer far more than the cash-in/

cash-out services of Safaricom agents and financial

inclusion considerations weigh against permitting

this fuller array of services to be monopolized by

one actor through the use of exclusive contracts.

But realistically, it is the cash-in/cash-out services

that banking agents also provide that would be of

most immediate value to many unbanked poor. So,

is the answer to allow banks exclusivity with respect

to agents providing the same cash-in/cash-out

services provided by Safaricom? Or is it now time for

Safaricom’s exclusive arrangements to be reviewed

for possible anti-competitive impact? Should

Safaricom’s exclusive agent arrangements now be

prohibited since they have already benefitted from

their first mover advantage—and if so, what signal

would that send to first movers in other countries

wondering to what extent their initiative will be

rewarded? On what basis should regulators evaluate

bank claims that the market of potential agents has

been tied up already? Should banks be forced to

affirmatively prove this claim and, if so, how?

Kenyan regulators, including those from the Central

Bank and the Monopolies and Prices Commission,

are struggling to develop a regulatory approach

that promotes competition and financial inclusion,

while simultaneously respecting the free market and

providing incentives to first actors.

Box 2. Agent Exclusivity and Competition Policy: Kenya’s Dilemma

9

to carry out agent banking on its behalf.” Such

prohibitions are often intended to ensure greater bank

involvement down to the “last mile” agent locations.

While such regulations prohibiting subcontracting

may still permit banks to engage intermediaries to

help manage agent locations, these arrangements

are more costly and complex because the bank must

still bear the expense and hassle of signing separate

agreements with every agent location.

In most cases, regulators recognize the benefits of

ANMs and permit subcontracting, so long as the bank

remains liable for the provision of financial services.

For example, in Mexico, regulation enables third

parties, including MNOs and retailers, to set up and

manage agent networks for banks. In Pakistan, the

branchless banking regulations expressly contemplate

a role for “superagents,” which may be organizations

with existing retail outlets or a distribution setup,

including fuel distribution companies, Pakistan

Post, courier companies, and chain stores.26 These

superagents would be responsible for managing and

controlling subagents, and agreements between

subagents and superagents would have to be similar

in form and substance to the agreement between the

superagent and the bank. In Brazil, recent regulations

permit only one level of subcontacting. Regulators

there believe that several levels of subcontracting

created too much distance between the bank and

the frontline agents for whom they were liable. Banks

were not able to effectively supervise their agents,

resulting in poor customer service and fraud.

Recommendation

Permit agent subcontracting, provided bank is

ultimately liable for the financial services rendered.

Liability for Agents

Imposing liability on banks for acts of their agents is

often the key factor in giving regulators the comfort

needed to permit the use of agents.27 Imposing bank

liability for agent noncompliance with regulations

forces providers to ensure professional agent behavior

and agent compliance with CDD norms (see “Verifying

Customer Identity”) and ultimately alleviates many

regulator concerns about the use of agents.

Based on the countries reviewed for this publication,

all countries that permit bank agents also impose

bank liability for these agents. Brazil, a country with

perhaps the most widespread use of banking agents,

requires banks to be “fully responsible for the services

rendered by its agents.”28 Similarly, India requires

that “all agreements/contracts with the customer

shall clearly specify that the bank is responsible to

the customer for acts of omission and commission

of the [agent].”29 Interestingly, Pakistan imposes

bank liability but states that the bank may “take

steps it deems necessary to safeguard itself against

liabilities arising out of the actions of its agents….”30

This clause suggests that banks should enter into

indemnification agreements with their agents—a

protection that could steer banks toward large and

well-capitalized agents capable of indemnifying the

bank while forgoing agent relationships with smaller

retailers who may nevertheless be better positioned

to serve low-income population segments.31

However, despite the widespread imposition of

liability for agents, financial inclusion goals would

benefit from limiting provider liability to those actions

or omissions related to the provision of financial

services.32 A failure to do so potentially increases

costs to the financial services provider who may have

to pay out damages for agent actions unrelated to

the purpose of the agency. These costs could have a

market chilling effect, negatively impacting not only

the emergence of viable business models but also the

ease and speed by which such models reach scale.

Some countries more clearly limit the extent of liability

in banking agency to the financial services provided.

For example, Kenya’s banking agent guidelines

impose liability on banks for agent actions “even if

not authorized in the [agency] contract so long as

26 Branchless Banking Regulations, section 6.2.27 Indeed, in common law jurisdictions, liability is imposed as a matter of law.28 Resolution cMn 3110, Art. 3 (July 2003).29 RBI circular January 2006, as restated september 2010, section 10(iv)30 state Bank of Pakistan, Branchless Banking Regulations, section 5 (March 2008).31 the practice in Brazil and other Latin American countries is to rely on indemnification by AnMs or sometimes even insurance.32 the question of what act or omission is related to the provision of financial services will ultimately be based on the facts and circumstances

of any particular incident.

10

they relate to banking services or matters connected

therewith” (emphasis added).33 This language is

reflected almost verbatim in Haiti’s recently issued

Branchless Banking Guidelines.34

See Box 3 for a discussion on liability and M-PESA.

Recommendations

• Regulation should impose bank liability for agent

actions but clearly limit the extent of such liability to

the provision of financial services on the bank’s behalf.

• Where the bank is ultimately liable for agent actions,

regulators should feel more comfortable in minimizing

restrictions on agent eligibility, location, and agent

due diligence. (See “Who Can Be an Agent.”)

Looking Forward

There is no one-size-fits-all regulatory solution for the

provision of financial services through agents, and

markets may experiment with a number of approaches

before finding one that works. As a result, some

regulators have adopted a test-and-learn35 approach,

permitting private sector experimentation, monitoring

the market, and ultimately developing regulations

based on identified market needs. In the Philippines,

for example, regulators showed great flexibility in the

early stages of development, following the market

and regulating informally through letter arrangements.

Other countries, such as Fiji, are following a similar test-

and-learn approach as they watchfully permit industry

experimentation in anticipation of regulation.36 Even

when regulators establish comprehensive frameworks,

many of them have actively listened to feedback from

the field and have revised regulations to promote

market development.

Regulators are aware that business reasons often drive

providers to behave in a manner consistent with the

best interests of customers—since ensuring a superior

customer experience, promoting transparency, and

acting in the interests of long-term business sustainability

often align the incentives of service providers with the

interests of customers. Consequently, most regulators

have generally agreed that issues such as liquidity

management at agent locations or physical security

safeguards are best left to free negotiation between the

parties—though regulators sometimes require these

issues to be addressed in some form in the contract

between the agent and the financial services provider.

Nevertheless, while the free market might produce

results consistent with customer interests, regulators

The Kenyan success story of M-PESA is sometimes heralded as a counter-example to the general principle of bank liability for agent actions. In Kenya, MNO Safaricom launched and scaled the successful M-PESA product, which now has more than 13 million customers. Since Safaricom is an MNO, it is not subject to Kenya’s banking agency regulations. Safaricom, however, claims no liability for its agents, and indeed, the M-PESA terms and conditions customers sign expressly state that “Agents are independent contractors and Safaricom shall not be liable for the acts or omissions of M-PESA Agents.”a Nevertheless, the service has so far been well-received with relatively few complaints, suggesting that market forces (i.e., incentives to protect brand reputation and other business benefits) may be sufficient to ensure security and service quality.

This argument is a red herring. Safaricom’s disclaimer, while perhaps taken at face value by Safaricom customers, is legal posturing common to many standard contracts between big business and individual consumers. Representatives of the Central Bank of Kenya have adopted the position that Kenyan common law principles of agent liability apply to Safaricom, and if the question ever went before Kenyan courts, Safaricom would be deemed liable as a matter of law. (A number of factors would support the argument that Safaricom’s M-PESA distributors are legally agents, including M-PESA branding requirements, exclusivity arrangements, and the commission structure.) The legal likelihood of Safaricom’s liability no doubt provides some added incentive to Safaricom to ensure appropriate agent behavior—regardless of its disclaimer.

Box 3. M-PESA and the Question of Liability

a M-PesA customer terms and conditions, section 18.11. While regulation has still not been issued with respect to e-money issuers such as safaricom (an Mno), banks are held liable for their agents under the Banking Agent Guidelines. some have justified this differential treatment on the basis that bank agents engage in a broader array of financial services than M-PesA agents.

33 Guideline on Agent Banking—cBK/PG/15, section 5.1.1.34 Banque de la République d’Haïti, Lignes Directrices Relatives à La Banque à Distances, section 5.1 (september 2010)35 first coined by the GsM Association, the term “test and learn” was later adopted by the G-20 in its “Principles for Innovative financial

Inclusion” (toronto, 27 June 2010).36 see tarazi (2010).

(continued on page 20)

11

Tab

le 1

: Ag

ency

Reg

ulat

ions

: Glo

bal

Ap

pro

ache

s

Co

untr

y W

ho c

an b

e an

ag

ent?

Wha

t ar

e o

ther

ag

ent

elig

ibili

ty

req

uire

men

ts?

Wha

t ca

n an

ag

ent

do

?R

estr

icti

ons

on

fees

ch

arg

ed b

y ag

ents

?C

an a

n ag

ent

sub

cont

ract

?Is

ag

ent

excl

usiv

ity

per

mit

ted

?P

rinc

ipal

liab

ility

fo

r ag

ents

Bra

zil

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

31

10, J

uly

2003

, as

am

end

ed b

y R

eso

luti

on

CM

N

3156

, Dec

emb

er

2003

; Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

365

4,

Dec

emb

er 2

008

and

R

eso

luti

on

CM

N

3954

, Feb

ruar

y 20

11)

“Onl

y en

trep

rene

uria

l co

mp

anie

s an

d

asso

ciat

ions

(as

def

ined

by

Law

10

,406

of

2002

) and

p

rovi

der

s o

f no

tary

an

d r

egis

try

serv

ices

(a

s d

efin

ed b

y La

w

8,93

5 o

f 19

94) c

an

be

hire

d a

s ag

ents

.”

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

39

54, A

rt. 3

).

Fina

ncia

l ins

titu

tio

ns

and

oth

er in

stit

utio

ns

that

are

par

t o

f th

e na

tio

nal f

inan

cial

sy

stem

can

be

hire

d

as a

gen

ts. (

Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

395

4, A

rt. 3

, III)

Exc

ept

for

acti

viti

es

such

as

(i) r

ecei

ving

an

d f

orw

ard

ing

p

rop

osa

ls f

or

cred

it

and

(ii)

pay

men

ts a

nd

elec

tro

nic

tran

sfer

, it

is p

rohi

bit

ed

to h

ire

an e

ntit

y w

hose

pri

ncip

al o

r so

le a

ctiv

ity

is t

he

pro

visi

on

of

agen

t se

rvic

es.

No

te: I

ndiv

idua

ls m

ay

not

act

as a

gen

ts.

In t

he c

ase

of

agen

ts

who

off

er c

red

it

op

erat

ions

, the

y m

ust

pas

s a

cert

ifica

tio

n ex

amin

atio

n ca

rrie

d

out

by

a re

cog

nize

d

enti

ty w

ith

the

tech

nica

l cap

acit

y.

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

39

54, A

rt. 1

2) T

he

cert

ifica

tio

n m

ust

incl

ude

tech

nica

l as

pec

ts o

f o

per

atio

ns,

app

licab

le r

egul

atio

n,

cons

umer

pro

tect

ion,

et

hics

, and

aud

itin

g.

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

39

54, A

rt. 1

2, II

)

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-o

ut: A

gen

ts m

ay

per

form

dep

osi

ts a

nd

wit

hdra

wal

s an

d b

ill

pay

men

ts. (

Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

311

0, A

rt. 1

)

Ver

ify

Cus

tom

er

Iden

tity

fo

r A

cco

unt

Op

enin

g P

urp

ose

s:

Co

rres

po

nden

ts m

ay

rece

ive

and

fo

rwar

d

acco

unt

op

enin

g

app

licat

ions

.

Oth

er: A

gen

ts

may

, int

er a

lia, (

i)

rece

ive

and

fo

rwar

d

app

licat

ions

fo

r cr

edit

/ cr

edit

car

ds,

(ii

) han

dle

rec

eip

ts,

pay

men

ts, a

nd

elec

tro

nic

tran

sfer

s fo

r cr

edit

or

deb

it

to c

usto

mer

dep

osi

t ac

coun

ts, a

nd

(iii)

ext

raju

dic

ial

colle

ctio

n se

rvic

es.

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

39

54, A

rt. 8

)

Ag

ents

are

pro

hib

ited

fr

om

“ch

arg

ing

, on

its

ow

n in

itia

tive

, any

fe

e co

nnec

ted

wit

h th

e p

rovi

sio

n o

f th

e se

rvic

es t

o w

hich

th

e co

ntra

ct r

efer

s.”

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

31

10, A

rt. 4

, IV

(c)

and

Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

39

54, A

rt. 1

7)

Sub

cont

ract

ing

is

per

mis

sib

le w

ith

pre

vio

us c

ons

ent

of

the

finan

cial

in

stit

utio

n.

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

31

10, A

rt. 4

, III)

Onl

y o

ne le

vel o

f su

bco

ntra

ctin

g

is a

llow

ed if

co

ntra

ct a

llow

s fo

r th

is p

oss

ibili

ty.

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

39

54, A

rt. 7

)

No

t ex

plic

itly

m

enti

one

d in

the

re

gul

atio

n, b

ut in

p

ract

ice,

exc

lusi

ve

arra

ngem

ents

do

ex

ist.

“The

pri

ncip

al is

ful

ly

resp

ons

ible

fo

r th

e se

rvic

es r

end

ered

b

y it

s ag

ents

.”

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

31

10, A

rt. 3

)

“An

agen

t ac

ts

for

and

und

er t

he

gui

del

ines

of

the

hiri

ng in

stit

utio

n,

whi

ch a

ssum

es f

ull

resp

ons

ibili

ty f

or

the

serv

ices

pro

vid

ed

to c

lient

s an

d

user

s th

roug

h th

e ag

ent,

and

whi

ch

shal

l gua

rant

ee

the

inte

gri

ty,

relia

bili

ty, s

ecur

ity

and

co

nfid

enti

alit

y o

f th

e tr

ansa

ctio

ns

cond

ucte

d t

hro

ugh

the

Ag

ent…

.”

(Res

olu

tio

n C

MN

39

54, A

rt. 2

) (co

ntin

ues)

12

Co

untr

y W

ho c

an b

e an

ag

ent?

Wha

t ar

e o

ther

ag

ent

elig

ibili

ty

req

uire

men

ts?

Wha

t ca

n an

ag

ent

do

?R

estr

icti

ons

on

fees

ch

arg

ed b

y ag

ents

?C

an a

n ag

ent

sub

cont

ract

?Is

ag

ent

excl

usiv

ity

per

mit

ted

?P

rinc

ipal

liab

ility

fo

r ag

ents

Co

lom

bia

Dec

ree

2233

(Jul

y 20

06),

Dec

ree

1121

(M

arch

200

9)

Any

typ

e o

f le

gal

en-

tity

, inc

lud

ing

sav

ing

s an

d c

red

it c

oo

per

a-ti

ves,

may

wit

h p

rio

r Su

per

inte

nden

cia

Fina

ncie

ra d

e C

olo

m-

bia

aut

hori

zati

on

act

as a

co

rres

po

nden

t.

Ind

ivid

uals

may

als

o

act

as a

gen

ts, p

ro-

vid

ed t

hat

they

co

n-d

uct

som

e b

usin

ess

acti

vity

in a

fix

ed e

s-ta

blis

hmen

t. (D

ecre

e 22

33, A

rt. 5

)

The

finan

cial

inst

i-tu

tio

n is

req

uire

d

to a

sses

s th

e co

r-re

spo

nden

t’s m

ora

l in

teg

rity

, phy

sica

l an

d t

echn

ical

infr

a-st

ruct

ure,

and

hum

an

reso

urce

s.(D

ecre

e 22

33, A

rt. 5

)

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-o

ut:

Ag

ent

may

per

form

ca

sh d

epo

sits

and

w

ithd

raw

als

for

chec

king

, sav

ing

s,

or

tim

e d

epo

sits

as

wel

l acc

ept

cash

loan

p

aym

ents

and

dis

-b

urse

loan

am

oun

ts.

Ag

ents

may

als

o a

c-ce

pt

pay

men

ts.

Ver

ify

Cus

tom

er

Iden

tity

fo

r A

cco

unt

Op

enin

g P

urp

ose

s:

”Co

rres

po

nden

ts

may

act

as

auth

o-

rize

d t

hird

par

ties

fo

r ca

rryi

ng o

utth

e ne

cess

ary

pro

-ce

dur

es […

], su

ch

as t

he in

terv

iew

s re

qui

red

fo

r ac

cep

-ta

nce

of

clie

nts.

” (D

ecre

e 11

21, T

hird

p

arag

rap

h)

Oth

er: B

alan

ce in

qui

-ri

es a

nd s

tate

men

ts

for

chec

king

/sav

ing

s ac

coun

ts.

Co

llect

ion

and

su

bm

issi

on

of

do

cu-

men

ts.

Pro

mo

tio

n an

d a

d-

vert

isin

g o

f se

rvic

es.

Do

mes

tic

mo

ney

tran

sfer

s in

Co

lom

-b

ian

curr

ency

wit

hin

the

nati

ona

l ter

rito

ry.

(Dec

ree

2233

, Art

. 2)

Co

rres

po

nden

ts c

an-

not

char

ge

extr

a fe

es

(Dec

ree

2233

, Art

. 3,

3)

Sub

cont

ract

ing

is

per

mis

sib

le w

ith

pre

-vi

ous

co

nsen

t o

f th

e fin

anci

al in

stit

utio

n.

No

t ex

plic

itly

men

-ti

one

d in

the

reg

ula-

tio

n b

ut in

pra

ctic

e,

excl

usiv

e ar

rang

e-m

ents

do

exi

st.

The

finan

cial

inst

i-tu

tio

n is

“d

irect

ly

resp

ons

ible

fo

r p

rovi

din

g s

ervi

ces

thro

ugh

the

corr

e-sp

ond

ent”

(Dec

ree

2233

, Art

. 3, 1

).

Tab

le 1

: Ag

ency

Reg

ulat

ions

: Glo

bal

Ap

pro

ache

s (c

ont

inue

d)

13

Ind

iaB

C C

ircul

ars

and

am

end

men

ts (J

anu-

ary

2006

, Mar

ch

2006

, Ap

ril 2

008,

A

pri

l 200

9, N

ove

m-

ber

200

9, S

epte

mb

er

2010

)

”NG

Os/

MFI

s se

t up

un

der

So

ciet

ies/

Trus

t A

cts,

So

ciet

ies

reg

is-

tere

d u

nder

Mut

ually

A

ided

Co

op

erat

ive

Soci

etie

s A

cts

or

the

Co

op

erat

ive

Soci

et-

ies

Act

s o

f St

ates

, se

ctio

n 25

co

mp

a-ni

es,

… a

nd P

ost

Of-

fices

” (J

anua

ry 2

006,

Se

ctio

n 3.

1)

Late

r ad

ded

: “re

tire

d

ban

k em

plo

yees

, ex

-ser

vice

men

and

re

tire

d g

ove

rnm

ent

emp

loye

es.”

(Ap

ril

2008

)

Late

r ad

ded

:“(

i) in

div

idua

l kir

ana/

med

ical

/fai

r p

rice

sh

op

ow

ners

(ii)

A

gen

ts o

f Sm

all S

av-

ing

s sc

hem

es o

f G

ov-

ernm

ent

of

Ind

ia/

Insu

ranc

e C

om

pan

ies

(iv) i

ndiv

idua

ls w

ho

ow

n P

etro

l Pum

ps

(v) R

etire

d t

each

ers

and

(vi)

Aut

hori

zed

fu

ncti

ona

ries

of

wel

l ru

n Se

lf H

elp

Gro

ups

(SH

Gs)

link

ed t

o

ban

ks.”

(Sec

tio

n 2,

N

ove

mb

er 2

009)

Loca

tio

n: “

The

dis

-ta

nce

bet

wee

n th

e p

lace

of

bus

ines

s o

f a

BC

and

the

bas

e b

ranc

h, o

rdin

arily

, sh

oul

d n

ot

exce

ed

15 K

ms

in r

ural

, sem

i-ur

ban

and

urb

an

area

s. In

met

rop

oli-

tan

cent

res,

the

dis

-ta

nce

coul

d b

e up

to

5

kms.

” (A

pri

l 200

8)

Late

r ex

pan

ded

: BC

p

lace

of

bus

ines

s m

ust

be

wit

hin

30

kilo

met

ers

of

the

“bas

e b

ranc

h” o

f th

e b

ank.

(Ap

ril 2

009)

Due

dili

gen

ce m

ay

be

carr

ied

out

on

po

-te

ntia

l BC

s. S

uch

due

d

ilig

ence

exe

rcis

e m

ay in

clud

e as

pec

ts

such

as

“(i)

rep

uta-

tio

n/m

arke

t st

and

ing

, (ii

) fin

anci

al s

oun

d-

ness

, (iii

) man

age-

men

t an

d c

orp

ora

te

go

vern

ance

, (iv

) cas

h ha

ndlin

g a

bili

ty a

nd

(v) a

bili

ty t

o im

ple

-m

ent

tech

nolo

gy

so-

luti

ons

in r

end

erin

g

finan

cial

ser

vice

s.”

(Sep

tem

ber

201

0)

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-o

ut:

BC

s m

ay e

ngag

e in

(i) d

isb

ursa

l of

smal

l-val

ue c

red

it, (

ii)

reco

very

of

pri

ncip

al/

colle

ctio

n o

f in

ter-

est,

and

(iii)

rec

eip

t an

d d

eliv

ery

of

smal

l va

lue

rem

itta

nces

/o

ther

pay

men

t in

-st

rum

ents

.”(J

anua

ry 2

006,

Sec

-ti

on

3.2)

Ver

ify

Cus

tom

er

Iden

tity

fo

r A

cco

unt

Op

enin

g P

urp

ose

s:

“The

ban

ks m

ay, i

f ne

cess

ary,

use

the

se

rvic

es o

f th

e B

C

for

pre

limin

ary

wo

rk

rela

ting

to

acc

oun

t o

pen

ing

fo

rmal

itie

s.

Ho

wev

er, e

nsur

ing

co

mp

lianc

e w

ith

KY

C a

nd A

ML

norm

s un

der

the

BC

mo

del

co

ntin

ues

to b

e th

e re

spo

nsib

ility

of

ban

ks.”

(Sep

tem

ber

20

10, S

ecti

on

5)

Oth

er: B

Cs

may

als

o

eng

age,

inte

r al

ia, i

n (i

) id

enti

ficat

ion

of

bo

rro

wer

s, (i

i) c

olle

c-ti

on

and

pre

limin

ary

“The

ban

ks m

ay p

ay

reas

ona

ble

co

m-

mis

sio

n/fe

e to

the

B

C, t

he r

ate

and

q

uant

um o

f w

hich

m

ay b

e re

view

ed

per

iod

ical

ly. T

he

agre

emen

t w

ith

the

BC

sho

uld

sp

ecifi

-ca

lly p

rohi

bit

the

m

fro

m c

harg

ing

any

fe

e to

the

cus

tom

ers

dire

ctly

fo

r se

rvic

es

rend

ered

by

them

on

beh

alf

of

the

ban

k.

The

ban

ks (a

nd n

ot

BC

s) a

re p

erm

itte

d

to c

olle

ct r

easo

nab

le

serv

ice

char

ges

fro

m

the

cust

om

ers

in a

tr

ansp

aren

t m

anne

r”

(Jan

uary

200

6, a

s re

stat

ed S

epte

mb

er

2010

)

Per

mit

ted

by

imp

lica-

tio

n an

d r

efer

ence

d

in P

arag

rap

h 3

of

Sep

tem

ber

201

0 ci

rcul

ar. S

ee c

olu

mn

to r

ight

.

“Whi

le a

BC

can

be

a B

C f

or

mo

re t

han

one

ban

k, a

t th

e p

oin

t o

f cu

sto

mer

in

terf

ace,

a r

etai

l out

-le

t o

r a

sub

-ag

ent

of

a B

C s

hall

rep

rese

nt

and

pro

vid

e b

anki

ng

serv

ices

of

onl

y o

ne

ban

k.”

(Sep

tem

ber

20

10, P

ara.

3)

“[A

]ll a

gre

emen

ts/

cont

ract

s w

ith

the

cust

om

er s

hall

clea

rly

spec

ify t

hat

the

ban

k is

res

po

nsib

le

to t

he c

usto

mer

fo

r ac

ts o

f o

mis

sio

n an

d

com

mis

sio

n o

f th

e B

usin

ess

Faci

litat

or/

C

orr

esp

ond

ent.

” (J

anua

ry 2

006,

as

rest

ated

Sep

tem

ber

20

10, S

ecti

on

10(iv

))

”The

out

sour

c-in

g o

f an

y ac

tivi

ty

by

ban

k d

oes

no

t d

imin

ish

its

ob

liga-

tio

ns, a

nd t

hose

of

its

Bo

ard

and

sen

ior

man

agem

ent,

who

ha

ve t

he u

ltim

ate

resp

ons

ibili

ty f

or

the

out

sour

ced

act

iv-

ity“

(Gui

del

ines

on

Man

agin

g R

isks

and

C

od

e o

f C

ond

uct

in O

utso

urci

ng o

f Fi

nanc

ial S

ervi

ces

by

Ban

ks, A

nnex

, 4.)

(co

ntin

ues)

14

Tab

le 1

: Ag

ency

Reg

ulat

ions

: Glo

bal

Ap

pro

ache

s (c

ont

inue

d)

Co

untr

y W

ho c

an b

e an

ag

ent?

Wha

t ar

e o

ther

ag

ent

elig

ibili

ty

req

uire

men

ts?

Wha

t ca

n an

ag

ent

do

?R

estr

icti

ons

on

fees

ch

arg

ed b

y ag

ents

?C

an a

n ag

ent

sub

cont

ract

?Is

ag

ent

excl

usiv

ity

per

mit

ted

?P

rinc

ipal

liab

ility

fo

r ag

ents

Ind

iaB

C C

ircul

ars

and

am

end

men

ts (J

anu-

ary

2006

, Mar

ch

2006

, Ap

ril 2

008,

A

pri

l 200

9, N

ove

m-

ber

200

9, S

epte

mb

er

2010

)

Late

r ad

ded

:“a

ny o

ther

ind

ivid

ual

incl

udin

g t

hose

op

-er

atin

g C

om

mo

n Se

rvic

e C

entr

es”

an

d “

Co

mp

anie

s re

gis

tere

d u

nder

the

In

dia

n C

om

pan

ies

Act

,195

6 w

ith

larg

e an

d w

ides

pre

ad r

e-ta

il o

utle

ts, e

xclu

din

g

No

n B

anki

ng F

inan

-ci

al C

om

pan

ies.

(Sep

tem

ber

201

0)

pro

cess

ing

of

loan

ap

plic

atio

ns in

clud

-in

g v

erifi

cati

on

of

pri

mar

y in

form

atio

n/

dat

a, (i

ii) c

reat

ing

aw

aren

ess

abo

ut

savi

ngs

and

oth

er

pro

duc

ts a

nd e

duc

a-ti

on

and

ad

vice

on

man

agin

g m

one

y an

d d

ebt

coun

selin

g,

(iv) p

roce

ssin

g a

nd

sub

mis

sio

n o

f ap

pli-

cati

ons

to

ban

ks, a

nd

(v) s

ale

of

mic

ro in

-su

ranc

e/m

utua

l fun

d

pro

duc

ts/p

ensi

on

pro

duc

ts/o

ther

thi

rd

par

ty p

rod

ucts

.

Ken

yaG

uid

elin

e o

n A

gen

t B

anki

ng—

CB

K/

PG

/15

(May

201

0)

Larg

e ra

nge

of e

nti-

ties:

lim

ited

liab

ility

p

artn

ersh

ips,

sol

e p

rop

rieto

rshi

ps,

par

t-ne

rshi

ps,

soc

ietie

s,

coop

erat

ive

soci

etie

s,

stat

e co

rpor

atio

ns,

trus

ts, p

ublic

ent

ities

, an

d a

ny o

ther

ent

ity

whi

ch t

he C

entr

al

Ban

k m

ay p

resc

ribe.

(S

ectio

n 4.

2.3)

A p

rinc

ipal

inst

itu-

tio

n m

ust

esta

blis

h th

at a

po

tent

ial

agen

t ha

s “

exis

ting

wel

l est

ab-

lishe

d c

om

mer

cial

ac

tivi

ty w

hich

has

b

een

op

erat

iona

l fo

r at

leas

t ei

ght

een

mo

nths

… h

as n

ot

bee

n cl

as-

sifie

d a

s a

def

icie

nt,

do

ubtf

ul, o

r no

n-p

er-

form

ing

bo

rro

wer

by

an in

stit

utio

n in

the

la

st 1

8 m

ont

hs…

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-ou

t:

Perm

issi

ble

activ

ities

in

clud

e ca

sh d

epos

it an

d ca

sh w

ithdr

awal

, ca

sh d

isbu

rsem

ent

and

cash

repa

ymen

t of

loan

s, c

ash

paym

ent

of b

ills,

cas

h pa

ymen

t of

retir

emen

t and

so

cial

ben

efits

, cas

h pa

ymen

t of s

alar

ies,

tr

ansf

er o

f fun

ds.

Veri

fy C

usto

mer

Id

enti

ty f

or A

ccou

nt

Op

enin

g P

urp

oses

: A

gen

ts m

ay c

olle

ct

and

forw

ard

cus

tom

er

doc

umen

ts in

rela

tion

to a

ccou

nt o

pen

ing

.

Ag

ents

sha

ll no

t

“[c]

harg

e an

y fe

es d

i-re

ctly

to

cus

tom

ers.

” (S

ecti

on

4.4.

1(iii

))

An

agen

t sh

all n

ot

“sub

cont

ract

ano

ther

en

tity

to

car

ry o

ut

agen

t b

anki

ng o

n it

s b

ehal

f.”

(Sec

tio

n 4.

4.1

(xiv

))

“No

co

ntra

ct b

e-tw

een

an in

stit

utio

n an

d a

n ag

ent

shal

l b

e ex

clus

ive.

An

agen

t m

ay p

rovi

de

serv

ices

fo

r ag

ent

ban

king

to

mul

tip

le

inst

itut

ions

pro

vid

ed

that

the

ag

ent

has

sep

arat

e co

ntra

cts

for

the

pro

visi

on

of

such

ser

vice

s w

ith

each

inst

itut

ion

and

p

rovi

ded

fur

ther

tha

t th

e ag

ent

has

the

ca-

pac

ity

to m

anag

e th

e tr

ansa

ctio

ns f

or

the

diff

eren

t in

stit

utio

ns”

(Sec

tio

n 6.

1)

“The

inst

itut

ion

is

who

lly r

esp

ons

ible

an

d li

able

fo

r al

l ac-

tio

ns o

r o

mis

sio

ns o

f th

e ag

ent.

Thi

s re

-sp

ons

ibili

ty e

xten

ds

to a

ctio

ns o

f th

e ag

ent

even

if n

ot

au-

tho

rize

d in

the

co

n-tr

act

so lo

ng a

s th

ey

rela

te t

o b

anki

ng s

er-

vice

s o

r m

atte

rs c

on-

nect

ed t

here

wit

h.”

(Sec

tio

n 5.

1.1)

15

The

follo

win

g c

anno

t b

e ag

ents

: ent

ities

th

at a

re fa

ith-b

ased

or

non

pro

fit, n

ong

ov-

ernm

enta

l org

aniz

a-tio

ns, e

duc

atio

nal

inst

itutio

ns, f

orei

gn

exch

ang

e b

urea

us,

and

any

oth

er e

nti-

ties

not

per

mitt

ed

to c

arry

on

for-

pro

fit

activ

ities

. (Se

ctio

n 4.

2.4)

Ind

ivid

uals

are

no

t ex

pre

ssly

per

mit

ted

to

act

as

agen

ts b

ut

are

oft

en a

pp

rove

d

as in

form

al s

ole

pro

-p

riet

ors

hip

s (S

ecti

ons

4.

2.3

(ii),

in c

oo

rdi-

nati

on

wit

h Se

ctio

n 3.

27).

and

po

sses

ses

ap-

pro

pri

ate

phy

sica

l in

fras

truc

ture

and

hu

man

res

our

ces

to

be

able

to

pro

vid

e th

e se

rvic

es w

ith

the

nece

ssar

y d

egre

e o

f ef

ficie

ncy

and

sec

u-ri

ty.”

(Sec

tio

n 3.

1.1)

A p

rinc

ipal

inst

itu-

tio

n m

ust

also

ass

ess

the

mo

ral,

bus

ines

s an

d p

rofe

ssio

nal

suit

abili

ty o

f th

e so

le p

rop

riet

or

or

par

tner

s (a

nd in

the

ca

se o

f co

rpo

rati

ons

, th

e C

EO

and

off

icer

re

spo

nsib

le f

or

agen

t o

per

atio

ns) o

f an

y p

ote

ntia

l ag

ent.

In

eval

uati

ng s

uch

suit

-ab

ility

, the

fo

llow

ing

w

ill b

e co

nsid

ered

: cr

edit

his

tory

, cri

mi-

nal r

eco

rds,

rep

uta-

tio

n (a

s ev

iden

ced

b

y tw

o r

efer

ence

s),

bus

ines

s ex

per

ienc

e,

sour

ces

of

fund

s,

bus

ines

s re

cord

, and

“a

ny o

ther

mat

ter

whi

ch n

egat

ivel

y o

r p

osi

tive

ly im

pac

ts o

n th

e p

erso

n”. (

Sect

ion

3.2.

5)

Oth

er:

Perm

issi

ble

ac

tiviti

es in

clud

e b

al-

ance

enq

uiry

; gen

-er

atio

n an

d is

suan

ce

of m

ini b

ank

stat

e-m

ents

; col

lect

ion

of

doc

umen

ts in

rel

atio

n to

loan

ap

plic

atio

ns,

cred

it an

d d

ebit

card

co

llect

ion,

col

lect

ion

of d

ebit

and

cre

dit

card

s; a

gen

t m

obile

b

anki

ng s

ervi

ces;

ch

eck

boo

k re

que

st

and

col

lect

ion

by

cus-

tom

ers;

col

lect

ion

of

ban

k m

ail/

cor

resp

on-

den

ce fo

r cu

stom

ers;

an

y ot

her

activ

ity

pre

scrib

ed b

y C

entr

al

Ban

k. (

Sect

ion

4.4.

1)

Exp

ress

ly P

rohi

bit

ed

Act

ivit

ies:

Ag

ents

sh

all n

ot,

inte

r al

ia,

op

en a

cco

unts

, gra

nt

loan

s, o

r ca

rry

out

an

y ap

pra

isal

fun

c-ti

on

for

pur

po

ses

of

op

enin

g a

n ac

coun

t o

r g

rant

ing

of

a lo

an

or

any

oth

er f

acili

ty,

und

erta

ke c

heck

de-

po

sit

or

enca

shm

ent

of

chec

ks, t

rans

act

in f

ore

ign

curr

ency

; p

rovi

de

cash

ad

-va

nces

. (Se

ctio

n 4.

4.1(

ix)-

(xii)

)

(co

ntin

ues)

16

Tab

le 1

: Ag

ency

Reg

ulat

ions

: Glo

bal

Ap

pro

ache

s (c

ont

inue

d)

Co

untr

y W

ho c

an b

e an

ag

ent?

Wha

t ar

e o

ther

ag

ent

elig

ibili

ty

req

uire

men

ts?

Wha

t ca

n an

ag

ent

do

?R

estr

icti

ons

on

fees

ch

arg

ed b

y ag

ents

?C

an a

n ag

ent

sub

cont

ract

?Is

ag

ent

excl

usiv

ity

per

mit

ted

?P

rinc

ipal

liab

ility

fo

r ag

ents

Mex

ico

(Ban

king

Circ

ular

, 12

/200

9 an

d a

men

d-

men

ts; L

aw o

n C

red

it

Inst

itut

ions

, 199

9 an

d

amen

dm

ents

)

Any

leg

al e

ntit

y, e

x-ce

pt

finan

cial

inst

itu-

tio

ns w

hose

exc

lusi

ve

bus

ines

s is

co

nduc

t-in

g a

uxili

ary

cred

it

acti

viti

es a

s d

efin

ed

in la

w (L

aw o

f A

uxil-

iary

Cre

dit

Act

ivit

ies

and

Org

aniz

atio

ns,

1985

and

am

end

-m

ents

), su

ch a

s b

roke

rs a

nd d

eale

rs.

Fina

ncia

l ins

titu

tio

ns

can

be

agen

ts o

nly

if al

low

ed b

y th

eir

ow

n b

ylaw

s, a

nd

exch

ang

e ho

uses

can

b

e ag

ents

fo

r ce

rtai

n ty

pes

of

serv

ices

. P

awnb

roke

rs a

nd

sim

ilar

enti

ties

can

-no

t b

e ag

ents

. (B

ank-

ing

Circ

ular

, Cha

pte

r X

I, Se

ctio

n 2,

art

icle

32

5).

Ind

ivid

uals

can

be

agen

ts o

nly

if th

ey

have

a b

usin

ess

and

a

per

man

ent

esta

b-

lishm

ent

whe

re t

hey

cond

uct

such

bus

i-ne

ss. (

Ban

king

Circ

u-la

r, A

nnex

57,

3)

Ag

ents

sho

uld

(i)

have

a p

erm

anen

t es

tab

lishm

ent

and

su

ffic

ient

cap

acit

y to

pro

per

ly o

per

ate

elec

tro

nic

dev

ices

, (ii

) hav

e th

e ne

ces-

sary

infr

astr

uctu

re

to p

roce

ss b

anki

ng

op

erat

ions

, and

(iii)

d

emo

nstr

ate

go

od

re

put

atio

n an

d c

red

it

hist

ory

, inc

lud

ing

la

ck o

f p

revi

ous

civ

il an

d c

rim

inal

co

n-d

emna

tio

n an

d in

-ve

stig

atio

ns f

rom

the

B

anki

ng C

om

mis

sio

n.

The

req

uire

men

ts

of

go

od

cre

dit

his

-to

ry a

nd p

erm

anen

t es

tab

lishm

ent

can

be

wai

ved

if a

n A

NM

fu

lfils

the

m. (

Ban

king

C

ircul

ar, A

nnex

57)

.

Ag

ents

sho

uld

hav

e a

dep

osi

t ac

coun

t w

ith

the

cont

ract

ing

b

ank

agai

nst

whi

ch

all t

rans

acti

on

will

be

cond

ucte

d, e

xcep

t w

hen

a ne

two

rk

man

ager

is u

sed

. (B

anki

ng C

ircul

ar,

Cha

pte

r X

I, Se

ctio

n 2,

Art

icle

322

, I)

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-o

ut:

wit

hdra

wal

s an

d d

e-p

osi

ts f

rom

/to

ban

k ac

coun

ts b

y th

e ac

-co

unt

hold

er

Ver

ify

Cus

tom

er

Iden

tity

fo

r A

cco

unt

Op

enin

g P

urp

ose

s:

may

co

nduc

t C

DD

in

the

co

ntex

t o

f o

pen

ing

“lo

w t

rans

-ac

tio

nal”

and

“lo

w

risk

” ac

coun

ts—

ac-

coun

ts s

ubje

ct t

o

dep

osi

t an

d t

rans

ac-

tio

nal l

imit

s.

Oth

er: (

i) P

aym

ents

(in

clud

ing

loan

re-

pay

men

ts) u

sing

cr

edit

and

deb

it

card

s, c

heck

s, a

nd

cash

, (ii)

tra

nsfe

rs b

e-tw

een

ban

k ac

coun

ts

incl

udin

g o

f o

ther

b

anks

, (iii

) bal

ance

in

qui

ries

, (iv

)che

ck

cash

ing

, and

(v)

term

dep

osi

ts (o

nly

thro

ugh

exch

ang

e ho

uses

tha

t ha

ve a

ca

pit

al a

deq

uacy

ra

tio

of

at le

ast

12%

). (B

anki

ng C

ircul

ar,

Cha

pte

r X

I, Se

ctio

n 2,

art

icle

319

).

Ag

ents

are

pro

hib

-it

ed f

rom

cha

rgin

g

add

itio

nal f

ees

that

w

ere

not

pre

vio

usly

se

t b

etw

een

ban

k an

d t

he c

lient

(Ban

king

Circ

ular

, C

hap

ter

X, S

ecti

on

2,

arti

cle

324,

VIII

).

Ag

ents

can

not

sub

-co

ntra

ct t

o t

hird

par

-ti

es (B

anki

ng C

ircul

ar,

Cha

pte

r X

, Sec

tio

n 2,

ar

ticl

e 32

4, V

III(d

)).

Ban

ks c

an n

one

the-

less

hire

ag

ents

th

roug

h ag

ent

netw

ork

man

ager

s.

(Ban

king

Circ

ular

, C

hap

ter

X, S

ecti

on

2,

arti

cle

322,

I).

Ban

ks c

anno

t hi

re e

n-ti

ties

tha

t ha

ve b

een

acti

ng a

s ex

clus

ive

agen

ts t

o a

noth

er

ban

k in

the

pas

t 12

m

ont

hs a

nd a

gen

ts

cann

ot

sig

n ex

clus

ive

agen

cy a

gre

emen

ts

to c

ond

uct

pay

men

ts

of

nonb

ank

serv

ices

an

d c

red

it c

ard

p

aym

ents

(Ban

king

C

ircul

ar, C

hap

ter

XI,

Sect

ion

2, A

rtic

le

324)

.

Usi

ng a

gen

ts d

oes

no

t ex

emp

t th

e b

ank,

the

ir m

anag

-er

s, e

mp

loye

es, a

nd

leg

al r

epre

sent

ativ

es

fro

m c

om

ply

ing

wit

h th

e p

rovi

sio

ns o

f th

e La

w o

n C

red

it

Inst

itut

ions

. Ag

ents

ar

e su

bje

ct t

o a

d-

min

istr

ativ

e, c

ivil

and

cr

imin

al c

harg

es f

or

infr

ing

ing

ap

plic

able

le

gis

lati

on.

(Law

on

Cre

dit

In-

stit

utio

ns, 1

999

and

am

end

men

ts, A

r-ti

cles

46

Bis

1 a

nd 2

, an

d B

anki

ng C

ircul

ar,

Cha

pte

r X

I, Se

ctio

n 2,

Art

icle

s 32

9-33

1)

Ban

ks le

gal

ly r

esp

on-

sib

le f

or

the

acts

of

thei

r ag

ents

(Law

on

Cre

dit

Inst

itut

ions

, A

rtic

le 4

6 B

is 1

, §2)

.

17

Che

ck c

ashi

ng a

nd

wit

hdra

wal

s ar

e lim

-it

ed t

o 1

,500

UD

Is

per

clie

nt p

er d

ay.

Dep

osi

ts a

re li

mit

ed

to 1

0,00

0 U

DIs

per

cl

ient

per

day

, and

p

er a

gen

t to

25%

of

the

aver

age

mo

nthl

y g

ross

dep

osi

ts o

f th

e b

ank,

as

ob

serv

ed in

th

e la

st 1

2 m

ont

hs.

(Ban

king

Circ

ular

, C

hap

ter

XI,

Sect

ion

2, A

rtic

le 3

23)

Nig

eria

(Reg

ulat

ory

Fra

me-

wo

rk f

or

Mo

bile

P

aym

ent

Syst

ems

in

Nig

eria

, 200

9)

May

be

ind

ivid

u-al

s o

r le

gal

ent

itie

s.

(Sec

tio

ns 5

.2.1

.3 a

nd

5.2.

1.4

by

imp

lica-

tio

n.)

Serv

ice

pro

vid

er

mus

t ca

rry

out

ag

ent

due

dili

gen

ce

mea

sure

s, in

clud

ing

fin

ger

pri

ntin

g (i

n th

e ca

se o

f in

div

idua

ls)

and

ver

ifyin

g r

egis

-tr

atio

n (in

the

cas

e o

f le

gal

ent

itie

s). (

Sec-

tio

n 5.

2.1.

2)

Ag

ents

mus

t no

t m

aint

ain

a ti

ll ex

-ce

edin

g N

100,

000

(ap

pro

x $6

55).

(Sec

-ti

on

5.2.

2)

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-o

ut:

Serv

ice

pro

vid

ers

may

ap

po

int

agen

ts

to f

acili

tate

“d

epo

sit

and

wit

hdra

wal

/ca

sh-o

ut.”

(Sec

tio

n 5.

2.1.

1)

Ver

ify

Cus

tom

er

Iden

tity

fo

r A

cco

unt

Op

enin

g P

urp

ose

s:

Serv

ice

pro

vid

ers

may

ap

po

int

agen

ts

to f

acili

tate

“en

rol-

men

t o

f cu

sto

mer

s”

tho

ugh

uncl

ear

to

wha

t ex

tent

thi

s p

er-

mit

s ag

ents

to

ver

ify

iden

tity

fo

r ac

coun

t o

pen

ing

pur

po

ses.

(S

ecti

on

5.2.

1.1)

Uns

tate

dE

-mo

ney

issu

ers

may

ap

po

int

agen

ts a

nd

sub

agen

ts. (

Sect

ion

5.1.

1)

The

“ag

ents

are

no

t re

stri

cted

to

any

one

sc

hem

e o

per

ato

r (t

hey

can

serv

e as

ag

ents

to

mul

tip

le

op

erat

ors

).” (2

009,

Se

ctio

n 5.

2.26

)

No

t cl

earl

y sp

ecifi

ed

but

co

mm

on

law

as-

sum

pti

on

of

liab

ility

fo

r ag

ent

whe

n ac

t-in

g u

nder

the

au-

tho

rity

of

its

agen

cy

agre

emen

t. (co

ntin

ues)

18

Tab

le 1

: Ag

ency

Reg

ulat

ions

: Glo

bal

Ap

pro

ache

s (c

ont

inue

d)

Co

untr

y W

ho c

an b

e an

ag

ent?

Wha

t ar

e o

ther

ag

ent

elig

ibili

ty

req

uire

men

ts?

Wha

t ca

n an

ag

ent

do

?R

estr

icti

ons

on

fees

ch

arg

ed b

y ag

ents

?C

an a

n ag

ent

sub

cont

ract

?Is

ag

ent

excl

usiv

ity

per

mit

ted

?P

rinc

ipal

liab

ility

fo

r ag

ents

Pak

ista

nB

ranc

hles

s B

ank-

ing

Reg

ulat

ions

fo

r Fi

nanc

ial I

nsti

tuti

ons

D

esiro

us t

o U

n-d

erta

ke B

ranc

hles

s B

anki

ng (3

1 M

arch

20

08)

No

t sp

ecifi

ed. I

n p

ract

ice

may

be

leg

al

enti

ty o

r in

div

idua

l (p

rovi

ded

suc

h in

di-

vid

ual i

s th

e p

rop

ri-

eto

r o

r o

per

ates

a

bus

ines

s).

Fina

ncia

l ins

titu

tio

ns

“sho

uld

cle

arly

de-

fine

vari

ous

ag

ent

typ

es a

nd m

inim

um

agen

t se

lect

ion

cri-

teri

a fo

r ea

ch t

ypes

. [T

hey]

sho

uld

ens

ure

that

ag

ents

are

wel

l es

tab

lishe

d, e

njo

ying

g

oo

d r

eput

atio

n an

d

havi

ng c

onf

iden

ce

of

the

loca

l peo

ple

.”

(Sec

tio

n 6.

3)

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-o

ut:

Ag

ents

may

eng

age

in c

ash-

in, c

ash-

out

serv

ices

, in

clud

ing

co

llect

ing

cas

h fo

r b

ill

pay

men

ts (i

nclu

din

g,

with

res

pec

t to

util

ity

pay

men

ts, f

rom

bot

h re

gis

tere

d a

nd w

alk-

in c

usto

mer

s) a

nd

loan

dis

bur

sem

ent

and

rep

aym

ent.

(Sec

-tio

n 6.

1)

Ver

ify C

usto

mer

Id

enti

ty f

or

Acc

oun

t O

pen

ing

Pur

po

ses:

Fo

r Le

vel 1

acc

ount

s (a

ccou

nts

held

by

ind

ivid

uals

sub

ject

to

b

alan

ce a

nd t

rans

ac-

tion

cap

s) a

gen

ts m

ay

faci

litat

e op

enin

g b

y co

llect

ing

pho

toco

py

of n

atio

nal I

D c

ard

, b

iom

etric

fing

erp

rint

scan

and

dig

ital

pho

to a

nd fo

rwar

din

g

such

doc

umen

tatio

n to

fina

ncia

l ins

titu-

tion.

(Sec

tion

4)

“Ag

ents

may

no

t al

ter/

chan

ge

char

ges

/fee

s st

ruc-

ture

pro

vid

ed b

y th

e b

ank

in a

ny w

ay. A

ll ch

arg

es h

ave

to b

e p

re-a

gre

ed b

etw

een

the

ban

k an

d t

he

agen

t an

d s

houl

d

be

clea

rly

com

mun

i-ca

ted

to

the

cus

tom

-er

s.”

(Sec

tio

n 6.

1)

Ag

ent

sub

cont

ract

-in

g a

llow

ed a

nd d

if-fe

rent

ag

ent

leve

ls

refe

renc

ed (S

uper

A

gen

ts, D

irect

A

gen

ts, a

nd S

ub

Ag

ents

.) (S

ecti

on

6.2)

“One

Ag

ent

can

pro

-vi

de

serv

ices

to

mul

-ti

ple

ban

ks p

rovi

ded

he

(the

ag

ent)

has

a

sep

arat

e se

rvic

e le

vel

agre

emen

t w

ith

each

b

ank.

” (S

ecti

on

6.1)

“The

ult

imat

e re

-sp

ons

ibili

ty f

or

bra

nchl

ess

ban

king

lie

s w

ith

the

Fina

ncia

l In

stit

utio

n. T

he F

I m

ay, h

ow

ever

, tak

e st

eps

it d

eem

s ne

c-es

sary

to

saf

egua

rd

itse

lf ag

ains

t lia

bili

-ti

es a

risi

ng o

ut o

f th

e ac

tio

ns o

f it

s ag

ents

, se

rvic

e p

rovi

der

s o

r p

artn

ers.

” (S

ecti

on

5)

“All

agre

emen

ts/

cont

ract

s w

ith

the

cust

om

er s

hall

clea

rly

spec

ify t

hat

the

ban

k is

res

po

nsib

le

to t

he c

usto

mer

fo

r ac

ts o

f o

mis

sio

n an

d

com

mis

sio

n o

f th

e ag

ent.

” (S

ecti

on

9.1)

19

Sout

h A

fric

a(B

anks

Act

No

. 94

of

1990

; Ban

ks A

ct

Gui

dan

ce N

ote

3/

2008

on

out

sour

c-in

g o

f fu

ncti

ons

w

ithi

n b

anks

)

Any

“p

erso

n” c

an

act

as a

ban

k ag

ent.

(B

anks

Act

). Th

ere

is

no p

rovi

sio

n re

stri

ct-

ing

oth

er t

hird

-par

ty

out

sour

ces

alth

oug

h th

e cl

ear

imp

licat

ion

of

Gui

dan

ce N

ote

3

(whi

ch c

ove

rs o

nly

out

sour

cing

arr

ang

e-m

ents

tha

t im

pac

t th

e ri

sk p

rofil

e o

f th

e b

ank,

aff

ect

the

ban

k›s

syst

ems

and

co

ntro

ls, a

re c

lass

i-fie

d b

y th

e b

ank›

s m

anag

emen

t as

of

stra

teg

ic im

po

rtan

ce

or

have

imp

licat

ions

fo

r SA

RB

›s s

uper

vi-

sio

n) is

tha

t th

e o

ut-

sour

cee

is a

bus

ines

s.

Ther

e ar

e no

elig

ibil-

ity

req

uire

men

ts f

or

agen

ts o

r o

utso

ur-

cees

. H

ow

ever

, the

b

ank

mus

t no

tify

SA

RB

in a

dva

nce

of

any

out

sour

cing

ar-

rang

emen

t co

vere

d

by

Gui

dan

ce N

ote

3.

In g

ener

al, b

anks

m

ay o

utso

urce

sp

ecifi

c se

rvic

es,

pro

vid

ed t

hat

such

se

rvic

es a

re c

on-

duc

ted

in a

cco

rdan

ce

wit

h th

e b

ank’

s in

ter-

nal p

olic

ies

and

sta

n-d

ard

s an

d m

oni

tore

d

by

the

ban

k.

Cas

h-in

/Cas

h-ou

t. A

b

ank

may

con

trac

t ag

ents

”to

rece

ive

on it

s b

ehal

f fro

m it

s cl

ient

s an

y d

epos

its,

mon

ey d

ue t

o it

… o

r to

mak

e p

aym

ents

to

su

ch c

lient

s on

its

be-

half“

(Ban

ks A

ct,

Def

-in

ition

of “

agen

cy”)

.

Ver

ify

Cus

tom

er

Iden

tity

fo

r A

cco

unt

Op

enin

g P

urp

ose

s.

No

t sp

ecifi

cally

ad

dre

ssed

. No

t ex

-p

ress

ly p

erm

itte

d o

r p

rohi

bit

ed.

Oth

er: A

gen

ts m

ay

rece

ive

app

lica-

tio

ns f

or

loan

s o

r ad

vanc

es. (

Ban

ks

Act

, def

init

ion

of

“ag

ency

”) A

sid

e fr

om

the

def

init

ion

of

agen

cy, t

here

is n

o

exp

licit

sta

tem

ent

re-

gar

din

g w

hat

agen

ts

may

or

may

no

t d

o.

Ther

e ar

e no

pro

vi-

sio

ns r

estr

icti

ng f

ees

char

ged

by

agen

ts,

tho

ugh

this

wo

uld

ty

pic

ally

be

a to

pic

o

f co

ntra

ctua

l ag

ree-

men

t b

etw

een

pri

nci-

pal

and

ag

ent.

Ther

e is

no

sta

tuto

ry

bar

on

sub

cont

ract

-in

g b

y ag

ents

. H

ow

-ev

er, a

gen

ts w

ill b

e ab

le t

o s

ubco

ntra

ct

onl

y if

per

mit

ted

un

der

the

ag

reem

ent

wit

h th

e b

ank.

If

an

agen

t o

r o

utso

urce

e d

oes

sub

cont

ract

, th

e b

ank

will

nee

d t

o

ensu

re m

anag

emen

t o

f, a

nd c

ont

rol o

ver,

the

func

tio

ns p

er-

form

ed b

y th

e su

b-

agen

t/su

bco

ntra

cto

r.

Ther

e is

no

sta

tuto

ry

rest

rict

ion

on

agen

t ex

clus

ivit

y. H

ow

ever

, an

y su

ch a

rran

ge-

men

t w

ill b

e su

bje

ct

to t

he c

om

pet

itio

n la

w.

Co

mm

on

law

ren

der

s th

e p

rinc

ipal

liab

le

for

acts

of

its

agen

ts

(but

no

t o

utso

urce

s,

alth

oug

h a

ban

k co

uld

be

so li

able

p

ursu

ant

to c

on-

trac

t).

*Thi

s Ta

ble

is b

ased

in p

art

on

uno

ffic

ial E

nglis

h tr

ansl

atio

ns o

f re

leva

nt r

egul

atio

n. It

is n

ot

inte

nded

as

leg

al g

uid

ance

or

op

inio

n, a

nd r

efer

ence

sho

uld

alw

ays

be

mad

e to

the

ori

gin

al t

ext.

should view this as an argument supporting a light

touch regulatory approach, not a presumption that

regulation is unnecessary.

Finally, new regulatory challenges to the use of agents

are emerging. Agent exclusivity is now beginning to

raise questions about how best to promote competition

while maximizing financial inclusion (see Box 2).

Questions are also emerging as to how agents can be

practically supervised—and in Egypt and Jordan for

example, the question is not just about how to regulate

agents, but also who should regulate them: Is it the

financial regulator or the telecommunications regulator?

Policy makers have endeavored to create fertile

contexts for experimentation and financial inclusion,

but the evolution of branchless banking remains a work

in progress. What is clear is that the business case for

agent banking depends significantly on the promise of

lower costs—both to service existing customers and

reach new segments and geographies. Cost savings in

turn depend on proportional regulations that address

the real risks of banking agents in the least burdensome

manner possible, enabling agent networks to scale

safely and sustainably and ultimately promoting access

to financial services for the world’s poor.

References

CGAP. 2010a. “Update on Regulation of Branchless

Banking in Colombia.” http://www.cgap.org/

gm/document-1.9.42397/Updated_Notes_On_

Regulating_Branchless_Banking_Colombia.pdf

CGAP. 2010b. “Update on Regulation of Branchless

Banking in Indonesia.” Sections 3.1.2 and 3.2. http://

www.cgap.org/gm/document-1.9.42399/Updated_

Notes_On_Regulat ing_Branchless_Banking_

Indonesia.pdf

Dias, Denise, and Katharine McKee 2010.

“Protecting Branchless Banking Consumers: Policy

Objectives and Regulatory Options.” Focus Note 64.

Washington D.C.: CGAP. http://www.cgap.org/gm/

document-1.9.47443/FN_64_Rev.pdf

Flaming, Mark, Claudia McKay, and Mark Pickens.

2011. “Agent Management Toolkit: Building a Viable

Network of Branchless Banking Agents.” Technical

Guide. Washington, D.C.: CGAP. http://www.cgap.org/

gm/document-1.9.49831/AgentManagement_TG.pdf

Ivatury, Gautam, and Ignacio Mas. 2008. “The Early

Experience with Branchless Banking.” Focus Note 46.

Washington, D.C.: CGAP. http://www.cgap.org/gm/

document-1.9.2640/FN46.pdf

Tarazi, Michael. 2010. “Branchless Banking: The Test

and See Approach.”Blog post. http://technology.

cgap.org/2010/02/09/branchless-banking-the-test-

and-see-approach/

The authors of this Focus Note are Michael Tarazi and Paul Breloff. The authors would like to thank the following for their review and commentary: Tilman Ehrbeck, Stephen Rasmussen, Timothy Lyman, Chris Bold, Kate Lauer, Yanina Seltzer, Denise Dias, Sarah Fathallah, Emiko Todoroki (World Bank Financial Integrity Team), and Paul

Leishman (GSMA). The Technology Program at CGAP works to expand financial services for the poor using mobile phones and other technologies and is co-funded by the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, CGAP, and the U.K. Department for International Development (DFID).

The suggested citation for this Focus Note is as follows:Tarazi, Michael, and Paul Breloff. 2011. “Regulating Banking Agents.” Focus Note 68. Washington, D.C.: CGAP, March.

No. 68March 2011

Please share thisFocus Note with yourcolleagues or request

extra copies of thispaper or others in

this series.

CGAP welcomesyour comments on

this paper.

All CGAP publicationsare available on the

CGAP Web site atwww.cgap.org.

CGAP1818 H Street, NW

MSN P3-300Washington, DC

20433 USA

Tel: 202-473-9594Fax: 202-522-3744

Email:[email protected]

© CGAP, 2011