self-selection of emigrants: theory and evidence on ... · analysis and derives theoretical...

60
George J. Borjas Ilpo Kauppinen Panu Poutvaara Self-Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance in Observable and Unobservable Characteristics VATT INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH VATT Working Papers 67

Upload: others

Post on 23-Oct-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • George J. BorjasIlpo KauppinenPanu Poutvaara

    Self-Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance in Observable and Unobservable Characteristics

    VATT INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH

    VATT Working Papers 67

  • VATT WORKING PAPERS

    67

    Self-Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance

    in Observable and Unobservable Characteristics

    George J. Borjas Ilpo Kauppinen Panu Poutvaara

  • George J. Borjas, Harvard Kennedy School, NBER and IZA.

    Ilpo Kauppinen, VATT Institute for Economic Research.

    Panu Poutvaara, University of Munich and Ifo Institute, CESifo, CReAM and IZA.

    We thank participants at Norface Migration Network Conference, Journées Louis-André Gérard-Varet, EEA and CEMIR Junior Economist Workshop in 2013, the Alpine Population Conference, UCFS Workshop, CESifo ESP area conference and VfS annual conference in 2015 and seminars at UC Irvine, ETH Zurich, Labour Institute for Economic Research, VATT, University of Linz, and University of Salzburg for valuable comments. Financial support from Leibniz Association (SAW-2012-ifo-3) is gratefully acknowledged.

    ISBN 978-952-274-163-9 (PDF) ISSN 1798-0291 (PDF) Valtion taloudellinen tutkimuskeskus VATT Institute for Economic Research Arkadiankatu 7, 00100 Helsinki, Finland Helsinki, April 2016

  • Self-Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance in Observable and Unobservable Characteristics

    VATT Institute for Economic Research VATT Working Papers 67/2016 George J. Borjas – Ilpo Kauppinen – Panu Poutvaara

    Abstract

    We show that the Roy model has more precise predictions about the self-selection of migrants than previously realized. The same conditions that have been shown to result in positive or negative selection in terms of expected earnings also imply a stochastic dominance relationship between the earnings distributions of migrants and non-migrants. We use the Danish full population administrative data to test the predictions. We find strong evidence of positive self-selection of emigrants in terms of pre-emigration earnings: the income distribution for the migrants almost stochastically dominates the distribution for the non-migrants. This result is not driven by immigration policies in destination countries. Decomposing the self-selection in total earnings into self-selection in observable characteristics and self-selection in unobservable characteristics reveals that unobserved abilities play the dominant role. Key words: international migration, Roy model, self-selection JEL classes: F22, J61

  • 1

    1.IntroductionAcentralfindingintheeconomicliteratureoninternationalmigrationisthatemigrantsarenotrandomlyselectedfromthepopulationofthesourcecountries.Thenatureofthenon‐randomselectionaffectsthelevelandthedistributionofwelfarethroughtwomajorchannels.First,theskilldistributionofmigrantsaffectsthewagestructureinbothsendingandreceivingcountries(Borjas2003).Asecondeffecttakesplacethroughthepublicsector.Immigrationcreatesafiscalsurplusinthereceivingcountryifandonlyifthenetpresentvalueofthetaxpaymentsofimmigrantsexceedsthenetpresentvalueofthecoststheyimpose.Boththeimmigrationofnetrecipientsandtheemigrationofnetpayersposeachallengetothepublictreasury(Wildasin1991;Sinn1997).BeginningwithBorjas(1987),therehasbeenagreatdealofinterestinderivingandempiricallytestingmodelsthatpredicthowmigrantsdifferfromnon‐migrants.ManyofthesestudiesrelyonanapplicationoftheRoymodelofoccupationalself‐selection.Aslongasskillsaresufficientlytransferableacrosscountries,thesortingofpersonsacrosscountriesismainlydeterminedbyinternationaldifferencesintherateofreturntoskills.AcountryliketheUnitedStateswouldthenattracthigh‐skilledworkersfrommoreegalitariancountries(i.e.,countriesofferingrelativelylowratesofreturntoskills)andlow‐skilledworkersfromcountrieswithgreaterincomeinequality(i.e.,countriesofferinghigherratesofreturntoskills).Theevidenceindeedsuggestsanegativecross‐sectioncorrelationbetweentheearningsofimmigrantsintheUnitedStatesandincomeinequalityinthesourcecountries.1AlthoughtheexistingliteratureonimmigrantselectionfocusesmainlyontheU.S.contextoronmigrationflowsfrompoortorichcountries,therearealsosizablemigrationflowsbetweenrichcountries.AccordingtotheUnitedNations(2013),21.9millionpersonsfrom

    1Relatedcross‐countrystudiesincludeCobb‐Clark(1993)andBratsberg(1995).GroggerandHanson(2011)examinetheselectionofmigrantsacrossabroadrangeofcountriesusinganalternativetheoreticalframeworkwhereindividualsmaximizelinearutilityandmigrationisdrivenbyabsoluteearningsdifferencesbetweenhighandlow‐skilledworkers.

  • 2

    EU15countriesnowliveoutsidetheirbirthplace,with42percentofthesemigrantslivinginotherEU15countriesandanadditional13percentlivingintheUnitedStates.2Thispaperexaminestheself‐selectionofemigrantsfromDenmark,oneoftherichestandmostredistributiveEuropeanwelfarestates.In2013,overaquartermillionDaneslivedoutsideDenmark(correspondingtoabout5percentoftheDanish‐bornpopulation),with50percentofthemigrantslivinginotherEU15countriesand13percentintheUnitedStates(UnitedNations,DepartmentofEconomicandSocialAffairs2013).BecausethereturnstoskillsinDenmarkarerelativelylow,thecanonicalRoymodelpredictsthattheemigrantsshouldbepositivelyselectedinthesensethattheexpectedearningsofthemigrantsexceedtheexpectedearningsofthestayers.3However,therehavebeenfewsystematicstudiesoftheself‐selectionofmigrantsfromarelativelyegalitariancountrytoseewhetherthisisindeedthecase.4Ourtheoreticalanalysisshowsthatthecanonicalframeworkdoesnotonlyhavepredictionsaboutthedifferencebetweentheexpectedearningsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants,whichisthebasisforthestandarddefinitionofpositiveornegativeselectionintheliterature,butalsoaboutthestochasticorderingofthetwoearningsdistributions.Weshowthatthesameconditionsthatpredictthatmigrantsarepositivelyself‐selectedinthesenseofadifferenceinexpectedincomesalsopredictthattheincomedistributionofthemigrantswillfirst‐orderstochasticallydominatetheincomedistributionofthenon‐migrants.Thetheoryalsodistinguishesbetweenselectioninobservableandselectioninunobservablecharacteristics.2TheEU15countriesrefertothememberstatesoftheEuropeanUnionpriortotheexpansiononMay1,2004.3ForcomparisonsofgrosswagepremiafromtertiaryeducationacrosscountriesseeBoariniandStraus(2010).ArecentpaperstudyingreturnstocognitiveskillsisHanusheketal.(2015).Thestudyfindssignificantcross‐countrydifferences.Moreover,thereturnsarerelativelylowinDenmarkaswellasinotherNordiccountries,andhighintheUnitedStates,GermanyandtheUnitedKingdom,whichalsoareamongthemostpopulardestinationsofDanishmigrants.4StudiesoftheselectionofmigrantsacrossdevelopedcountriesincludeLundborg(1991),Pirttilä(2004),Klevenetal.(2014),andJungeetal.(2014).Manystudiesalsoexamineselectionissuesinahistoricalcontext;seeWegge(1999,2002),AbramitzkyandBraggion(2006),Abramitzky,Boustan,andEriksson(2012),Ferrie(1996),andMargo(1990).

  • 3

    OurempiricalanalysisusestheDanishfullpopulationadministrativedatatoanalyzehowmigrantsandnon‐migrantsdifferintheirpre‐emigrationearningsandotherobservablecharacteristics.Toshedlightontheroleofunobservablecharacteristicsintheselectionprocess,weinvestigatehowmigrantsandnon‐migrantsdifferintermsofunobservableearningsability,asmeasuredbyresidualsfromMincerianearningsregressions.Ourempiricalresultsareinlinewiththepredictionsofthemodel:Danishemigrantsareindeedpositivelyself‐selectedbothintermsofearningsandintermsofresidualsfromthewageregressions.FollowingourreframingofthecanonicalRoyframeworkintermsoftheconceptofstochasticdominance,ourstudyspecificallytestsforwhethertheearningsdistributionoftheemigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofthestayers(aswouldbepredictedbythemodel).Theevidenceconfirmsthisstrongtheoreticalpredictionovermostofthesupportoftheearningsdistribution.OurstudyisrelatedtotheflurryofrecentpapersthatexaminetheselectionofmigrantsfromMexicototheUnitedStates.ThepioneeringanalysisofChiquiarandHanson(2005)mergedinformationfromtheU.S.censusonthecharacteristicsoftheMexicanmigrantswithinformationfromtheMexicancensusonthecharacteristicsoftheMexicannon‐migrants.Becausethemergeddatadidnotreporttheearningsofmigrantspriortothemove,pre‐migrationearningswerepredictedbasedonobservablecharacteristicsofthemigrants.This“counterfactual”empiricalexercisesuggestedthatMexicanemigrantswerelocatedinthemedium‐highrangeoftheMexicanwagedistribution.ThefindingofintermediateselectionintheMexicancontextdoesnotseemconsistentwiththebasicimplicationsoftheRoymodelbecausetherateofreturntoskillsisfarlargerinMexicothanintheUnitedStates.MorerecentstudiesbyFernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)andKaestnerandMalamud(2014)usesurveydatathatreporttheactualpre‐migrationearningsandfindevidenceofnegativeselection.Theyalsoconcludethatpartofthenegativeselectioncanbetracedtotheunobservablecharacteristicsthatdetermineamigrant’searnings.Theimportantroleplayedbyunobservablecharacteristicsimpliesthatconstructingacounterfactualearningsdistributionforthemigrantsbasedonobservablecharacteristics

  • 4

    cangreatlybiasthenatureoftheselectionrevealedbythedata.Ourfindingssuggestthattheuseofsuchacounterfactualdistributionwilltendtounderstatethetrueselectioninearnings,sothattheselectionimpliedbythecounterfactualdistributionisfarweakerthanthetrueselection—regardlessofwhetherthereispositiveornegativeselection.ThenumericalbiasthatresultsfromusingthecounterfactualestimationissizableintheDanishcontext:morethanhalfofthedifferencebetweentheexpectedearningsofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsarisesbecauseofdifferencesinunobservedcharacteristics.Thepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section2sketchestheeconomictheoryunderlyingtheanalysisandderivestheoreticalpredictionsconcerningtheself‐selectionofemigrants,usingthenotionofstochasticdominanceasaunifyingconcept.Section3introducesanddescribestheuniquepopulationdatathatweuseandreportssomesummarystatistics.Sections4and5presentthemainempiricalfindings.Insection4,weexaminetheselectionintermsofobservedpre‐migrationearnings.Wepresentastatisticalmethodfortestingthetheoreticalimplicationthattheearningsdistributionoftheemigrantsshouldstochasticallydominatethecorrespondingdistributionofthenon‐migrants.Section5extendstheempiricalworkbyexaminingtheselectionthatoccursintheunobservedcomponentofearnings.Section6evaluatesthebiasthatresultsfrompredictingthepre‐migrationearningsofemigrantsfromtheearningsdistributionofnon‐migrants.Section7examineswhethertheselectionofpersonsmovingtootherEU15countriesdiffersfromtheselectionofmigrantsmovingtocountrieswhereimmigrationrestrictionscomeintoplay.Wefindthatimmigrationrestrictionshavelittleeffectontheselectionofemigrants.Finally,Section8summarizesthestudyanddrawssomelessonsforfutureresearch.2.Theoreticalframework

    Previousliteratureontheself‐selectionofmigrantshasfocusedontheconditionalexpectationsofearningsdistributionsamongmigrantsandstayers.Inthissection,wederiveanovelresult:theRoymodelimpliesthatundercertainconditions,theearningsdistributionofmigrantsfirst‐orderstochasticallydominates,orisstochasticallydominatedby,theearningsdistributionofstayers.Inabivariatenormalframework,itturnsoutthat

  • 5

    theconditionsrequiredforstochasticdominanceareidenticaltotheconditionsthatdeterminethenatureofself‐selectionintermsofexpectedearnings.Wealsodecomposeself‐selectionintotwocomponents,onethatisdeterminedbydifferencesinreturnstoobservableskillsbetweensourceandhostcountry,andonethatisdeterminedbydifferencesinreturnstounobservableskills.Thedistinctionbetweenobservableandunobservableskills,ofcourse,dependsontheempiricalframeworkandonthedatathatisbeingused;observableskillsincludethevariablesexplainingearningsthatareincludedinthedata,whilethecomponentofearningsthatisleftunexplainedbythedataistheunobservableskillcomponent.Eventhoughthecontentofthetwocomponentsdiffersamongdatasets,itislikelythatamajorpartofmigrantself‐selectionisdeterminedbytheunobservablecomponentsimplybecause“observables”tendtoexplainarelativelysmallfractionofthevarianceinearnings.Wetakeasourstartingpointthemigrationdecisionfacedbypotentialmigrantsinatwo‐countryframework,inlinewithBorjas(1987)andsubsequentliterature.Residentsofthesourcecountry(country0)considermigratingtothedestinationcountry(country1),andthemigrationdecisionisassumedtobeirreversible.Tosimplifythepresentation,wefocusonasingleobservedskillcharacteristicsandsuppressthesubscriptthatindexesaparticularindividual.Forconcreteness,thevariablescanbethoughtofasgivingtheworker’syearsofeducationalattainment,butitincludesallthecharacteristicsaffectingindividual’sincomethatareobservedinagivensetofdata.Residentsofthesourcecountryfacetheearningsdistribution:(1) log

    wherew0givesthewageinthesourcecountry;r0givestherateofreturntoobservableskills;andtherandomvariable0measuresindividual‐specificproductivityshocksresultingfromunobservedcharacteristicsandisnormallydistributedwithmeanzeroandvariance .Thedistributionofobservableskillsinthesourcecountry’spopulationis 02

  • 6

    givenbys=s+s,wheretherandomvariablesisalsoassumedtobenormallydistributedwithmeanzeroandvariance . Iftheentirepopulationofthesourcecountryweretomigrate,thispopulationwouldfacetheearningsdistribution:(2) log

    wheretherandomvariable1isnormallydistributedwithmeanzeroandvariance12 .Foranalyticalconvenience,weassumethatCov(0,s)=Cov(1,s)=0,sothattheindividual‐specificunobservedproductivityshocks(i.e.,the“residuals”fromtheregressionline)areindependentfromobservablecharacteristics.5Thecorrelationcoefficientbetween0and1equals01.Itisalsoworthnotingthattherandomvariablesisindividual‐specificandhasthesamevalueforthesameindividualinbothcountries,whereas0and1arebothindividual‐andcountry‐specific. Equations(1)and(2)completelydescribetheearningsopportunitiesavailabletopersonsborninthesourcecountry.AssumethatthemigrationdecisionisdeterminedbyacomparisonofearningsopportunitiesacrosscountriesnetofmigrationcostsC.Definetheindexfunction:(3) log ∆ ,

    5Amorerealisticassumptionwouldbethatthecorrelationbetweenobservedandunobservedskillsispositive.However,allowingforpositivecorrelationdoesnotchangethequalitativepredictionsofthemodel.

    s2

  • 7

    wheregivesa“time‐equivalent”measureofmigrationcosts(=C/w0).Thecross‐countrydifferenceinearningsnetofthetime‐equivalentmigrationcostforanindividualwithaverageobservedandunobservedcharacteristicsisgivenby=[(1–0)+(r1–r0)s–].Thedifferenceinearningsattributabletoindividualdeviationfromaveragecharacteristicsisgivenby ,wherevi=(ris+i)for∈ 0,1 .ApersonemigratesiftheindexI>0,andremainsintheorigincountryotherwise.

    Migrationcostsvaryamongpersons—butthesignofthecorrelationbetweencosts(whetherindollarsorintime‐equivalentterms)andskills(bothobservedandunobserved)isambiguousanddifficulttodetermine.Theheterogeneityinmigrationcostscanbeincorporatedtothemodelbyassumingthatthedistributionoftherandomvariableinthesourcecountry’spopulationisgivenby=+,whereisthemeanlevelofmigrationcostsinthepopulation,andisanormallydistributedrandomvariablewithmeanzeroandvariance .However,Borjas(1987)andChiquiarandHanson(2005)showthattime‐equivalentmigrationcostsdonotplayaroleinthealgorithmthatdeterminestheselectionofemigrantsifeitherthosecostsareconstant(sothat2 =0),orifthecostsareuncorrelatedwithskills.Foranalyticalconvenience,weassumethattime‐equivalentmigrationcostsareconstant,sothat=.6Theoutmigrationratefromthesourcecountryisthengivenby:(4) 0 ∗ ∆ ∗ 1 ∆ ∗ ,

    wherev*=(v1v0)/visastandardnormalrandomvariable;*=/v;v2 =Var(v1–v0);andisthestandardnormaldistributionfunction.76If werenegativelycorrelatedwithskills,thenegativecorrelationwouldtendtoinducethemoreskilledtomigrate,creatingapositivelyselectedmigrantflow.Thiswouldstrengthenpositiveself‐selection,andweakennegativeself‐selection.7Itisstraightforwardtostudyequation(4)toconfirmthatthemigrationraterises,whenmeanincomeinthesourcecountryfalls,meanincomeinthehostcountryrises,returnstoobservedskillsinthesourcecountryfall,returnstoobservedskillsinthehostcountryrise,time‐equivalentmigrationcostsfallandwhenmeanobservedskillsriseifr1>r0orfallifr1<r0.

    2

  • 8

    Inadditiontoidentifyingthedeterminantsoftheoutmigrationrateinequation(4),theRoymodelletsusexaminewhichpersonsfinditmostworthwhiletoleavethesourcecountry.8Inthefollowing,weexaminetheself‐selectionofemigrantsalongtwodimensions:selectionintermsofobservableskillssandselectionintermsofunobservableskills0,whichtogethercombineintoselectionintermsoftotalproductivityorearnings,asmeasuredbylogw0.LetFM(z)andFN(z)representthe(cumulative)probabilitydistributionsofskillsorearningsformigrantsandnon‐migrantsinthesourcecountry,respectively,wherezdenotesaparticularmeasureofskills(e.g.,observableorunobservablecharacteristicsorincome).Bydefinition,theprobabilitydistributionofmigrantsFM(z)first‐orderstochasticallydominatesthatofstayersFN(z)if:(5) ∀ ,andthereisatleastonevalueof forwhichastrictinequalityholds.9Fromnowon,wheneverwerefertostochasticdominance,wemeanfirst‐orderstochasticdominance.Equation(5)impliesthatalargerfractionofthemigrantshaveskillsaboveanythresholdz*.Putdifferently,foranylevelofskillsz*,thepopulationdescribedbytheprobabilitydistributionFMismoreskilledbecausealargerfractionofthegroupexceedsthatthreshold.Themigrants,inshort,arepositivelyselected.Negativeselection,ofcourse,wouldoccurifthereversewastrueand z,withastrictinequalityholdingforatleastonevalueof .8Throughouttheanalysis,weassumethat*isconstant.Themigrationflowiseffectivelyassumedtobesufficientlysmallthattherearenofeedbackeffectsonthelabormarketsofeitherthesourceordestinationcountries.

    9Analternativeandperhapsmoreintuitivedefinitionofstochasticdominanceisintermsofquantiles.Let and bethequantilefunctionsoforder oftheskilldistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants.FM(z)stochasticallydominatesFN(z)ifandonlyif forall0 1andthereisatleastonevalueof forwhichastrictinequalityholds.

  • 9

    Iftheskilldistributionofmigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrants,thestochasticdominancethenalsoimpliesthetypicaldefinitionofpositiveselectionthatisbasedonconditionalexpectations:(6) | 0 | 0 ,sothatmigrants,onaverage,aremoreskilledthanstayers.Conversely,iftheprobabilitydistributionofstayersstochasticallydominatesthatofmigrants,andtherewasnegativeselection,itwouldalsofollowthat | 0 | 0 .Theconverse,however,isnottrueforageneraldistribution:Aclaimofpositiveselectioninexpectations,asdefinedbyequation(6),doesnotimplythattheskilldistributionofmigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrants.Toderivethestochasticorderingoftheskilldistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants,letf(x,v)beabivariatenormaldensityfunction,withmeans(x,v),variances ( x2 ,v2 ) andcorrelationcoefficient.Further,lettherandomvariablevbetruncatedfrombelowatpointaandfromaboveatpointb.Arnoldetal.(1993,p.473)showthatthe(marginal)momentgeneratingfunctionofthestandardizedrandomvariable(x‐x)/x,giventhetruncationofv,isgivenby:(7) / ,where=(a–v)/v;and=(b–v)v. Intermsofthemigrationdecision,thetruncationintherandomvariablev=v1–v0inthesampleofmigrantsisfrombelowandimpliesthat=–*=k,and=,wherekisthetruncationpoint.Inthesampleofstayers,thetruncationinvisfromabove,andthetruncationpointsare=–and=k.Bysubstitutingthesedefinitionsintoequation(7),it

  • 10

    canbeshownthatthemomentgeneratingfunctionsfortherandomvariablegivingtheconditionaldistributionsofskillcharacteristicxformigrantsandstayersreduceto:(8)

    1 Φ1 Φ

    and(9)

    ΦΦ .

    ConsideranytwodistributionfunctionsF(z)andG(z).Thistle(1993,p.307)showsthatFwillstochasticallydominateGifandonlyif:(10) , ∀ 0,wheremFisthemomentgeneratingfunctionassociatedwithdistributionF;mGisthemomentgeneratingfunctionassociatedwithG.Therankingofthemomentgeneratingfunctionsinequation(10)implieswecandeterminethestochasticrankingofthetwodistributionsbysimplysolvingfortherelevantcorrelationcoefficient,andcomparingequations(8)and(9).Suchacomparisonimpliesthat:(11) , 0 , 0.

  • 11

    Inotherwords,migrantsarepositivelyselectedif>0,andarenegativelyselectedotherwise.Considerinitiallythestochasticrankinginobservablecharacteristics.Therandomvariablex=s,andtherelevantcorrelationcoefficientisdefinedby:(12) , 1 .Equation(12)showsthatthestochasticorderingofthedistributionsofobservableskillsofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsdependsonlyoninternationaldifferencesintherateofreturntoobservableskills.Theskilldistributionofmigrantswillstochasticallydominatethatofstayerswhentherateofreturntoskillsishigherabroad.Conversely,theskilldistributionfornon‐migrantswillstochasticallydominatethedistributionformigrantsiftherateofreturntoobservableskillsislargerathome.Considernextthestochasticorderingintheconditionaldistributionsofunobservableskills0.Therelevantcorrelationfordeterminingthistypeofselectionisgivenby:(13) , 1 .Itfollowsthatthedistributionofunobservableskillsformigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatfornon‐migrantswhen 1.Notethatthenecessaryconditionforpositiveselectionhastwocomponents.First,theunobservedcharacteristicsmustbe“transferable”acrosscountries,sothat01issufficientlyhigh.Second,theresidualvarianceinearningsislargerinthedestinationcountrythaninthesourcecountry.Theresidualvariances02 and1

    2 ,ofcourse,measurethe“price”ofunobservedcharacteristics:thegreatertherewardstounobservedskills,thelargertheresidualinequalityinwages.10Aslongasunobserved

    10Thisinterpretationofthevariancesfollowsfromthedefinitionofthelogwagedistributioninthehostcountryintermsofwhatthepopulationofthesourcecountrywouldearniftheentirepopulationmigratedthere.Thisdefinitioneffectivelyholdsconstantthedistributionofskills.

  • 12

    characteristicsaresufficientlytransferableacrosscountries,emigrantsarepositivelyselectedwhentherateofreturntounobservableskillsishigherinthedestination.Finally,considerthestochasticrankingin“total”productivity.Theearningsdistributioninthesourcecountrygivenbyequation(1)canberewrittenas:(14) log 0 α0 0μs 0ε ε0 α0 0μ 0,wherethenormallydistributedrandomvariablev0hasmeanzeroandvariancev02 .Therelevantcorrelationfordeterminingthestochasticrankingoftheearningsdistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsis:(15) , 1 1 1 ,where ⁄ and1 ⁄ .Thesignofthecorrelationinequation(15),whichdeterminesthenatureoftheselectioninpre‐migrationearnings,dependsonthesignofaweightedaverageoftheselectionthatoccursinobservableandunobservablecharacteristics.Interestingly,theweightisthefractionofthevarianceinearningsthatcanbeattributedtodifferencesinobservableandunobservablecharacteristics,respectively.Ifthereispositive(negative)selectioninboth“primitive”typesofskills,therewillthenbepositive(negative)selectioninpre‐migrationearnings.If,however,therearedifferenttypesofselectioninthetwotypesofskills,theselectionineachtypeisweightedbyitsimportanceincreatingthevarianceoftheearningsdistribution.Itiswellknownthatobservablecharacteristics(suchaseducationalattainment)explainarelativelysmallfractionofthevarianceinearnings(perhapslessthanathird).Asaresult,equation(15)impliesthatitistheselectioninunobservablesthatismostlikelytodeterminethenatureoftheselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofemigrants.Thisimplicationplaysan

  • 13

    importantroleinexplainingwhytheevidencereportedinFernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)andKaestnerandMalamud(2014)conflictswiththatofChiquiarandHanson(2005).Asmentionedearlier,thestochasticdominanceresultsnecessarilyimplyselectionintermsofconditionalexpectations.Inthecaseofbivariatenormaldistributions,itfollowsthattheexpectationoftheearningsdistributionofmigrantsE(logw0|v*>*)isgivenby:(16) | ∗ Δ ∗ 1 Δ ∗ 1 Δ ∗ ,where*)=(*)/[1(*)]>0,andisthedensityofthestandardnormaldistribution.Ascanbeseenbyexaminingequation(16),theconditionsthatdeterminetheself‐selectionintermsofexpectationsarethesameastheconditionsthatdeterminethestochasticorderingoftheskilldistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants.InthenormaldistributionframeworkthatunderliesthecanonicalRoymodel,stochasticdominanceimpliesselectioninexpectations,andviceversa.Inempiricalapplications,however,thepredictionofstochasticdominanceislikelytobemuchlessrobustthanthepredictionsconcerningexpectationsbecausetestingforstochasticdominancewillrequireamorerigoroustestthansimplycomparingtheaverageincomesorskillsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants.Ifonejustcomparestheaveragestofindouthowmigrantsareself‐selected,thefindingscanbecompatiblewiththepredictionsoftheRoy‐modelevenifalargenumberofindividualsinthedatabehaveagainstthestochasticdominancepredictionsofthemodel.Asaresult,establishinganempiricalpatternofstochasticdominanceprovidesverystrongevidencethatdifferencesinskillpricesareindeedimportantinmigrationdecisions.

  • 14

    3.Data

    OuranalysisusesadministrativedatafortheentireDanishpopulationfrom1995to2010.ThedataismaintainedandprovidedbyStatisticsDenmarkanditderivesfromtheadministrativeregistersofgovernmentalagenciesthataremergedusingauniquesocialsecuritynumber.11Foreachyearbetween1995and2004,weidentifiedallDanishcitizensaged25‐54wholivedinDenmarkduringtheentirecalendaryear.12Werestricttheanalysistopersonswhoworkedfulltime.13Migrationdecisionsofpart‐timeworkersorofworkersoutsidethelaborforcemaybedrivenbydifferentfactors,andtheobservedincomeoftheseworkersmaynotbeindicativeoftheirtrueearningspotential.Theincomevariableforeachyearisconstructedbyaddingtheworker’sannualgrosslaborincomeandpositivevaluesoffreelanceincome.14Wemergedthisinformationwithdatafromthemigrationregisterfortheyears1995through2010.Themigrationregisterreportsthedateofemigrationandthecountryofdestination.EventhoughitispossibleforDanishcitizenstoemigratewithoutregistering,weexpectthatthenumbersofpersonswhodosoissmallasitisalegalrequirementfor

    11AllresidentsinDenmarkarelegallyrequiredtohaveasocialsecuritynumber.Thisnumberisnecessarytomanyactivitiesindailylife,includingopeningabankaccount,receivingwagesandsalariesorsocialassistance,obtaininghealthcare,andenrollinginschool.12Aperson’sageismeasuredasofJanuary1sttheyearafterthereferenceyear.13Theadministrativedataallowsthecalculationofavariablethatmeasurestheamountof“workexperiencegained”duringthecalendaryear.Themaximumpossiblevalueforthisvariableis1,000.Werestrictoursampletoworkerswhohaveavalueof900orabove,sothatoursampleroughlyconsistsofpersonswhoworkedfulltimeatleast90percentoftheyear.Inordertomeasuretheworkexperiencegainedduringagivenyear,wesubtractthevaluefromthepreviousyearfromthecurrentvalueofthevariable.Personswhohadamissingvalueforworkexperienceineitherofthetwoyearsweredroppedfromthesample.Missingvaluesinthisvariabletypicallyindicatethatthepersonspenttimeabroad.14Theinformationonearningsistakenfromthetaxrecordsforeachcalendaryear.ThisvariableisconsideredtobeofhighqualitybyStatisticsDenmark.Somepersonsalsoreportnegativevaluesforfreelanceincome.Thesenegativevaluesarelikelytobeduetolossesarisingfrominvestmentsanddonotreflecttheproductivecharacteristicsoftheindividual.

  • 15

    Danishcitizenstoreportemigration.Danishtaxlawsprovidefurtherincentivesformigrantstoregisterwhentheyemigrate.Afteridentifyingthepopulationofinterest,wedeterminedforeachpersonwhetherheorsheemigratedfromDenmarkduringthefollowingcalendaryear.Ifwefoundthataparticularpersonemigrated,wesearchedforthepersoninthemigrationregisterforsubsequentyearstodetermineifthemigrantreturnedtoDenmarkatsomepointinthefuture,andrecordedthedateofpossiblereturnmigration.Themigrationregisterincludesnear‐completeinformationonreturnmigration,asregistrationinDenmarkisrequiredforthereturnmigranttobeeligibleforincometransfersandtobecoveredbynationalhealthinsurance.Tofocusonmigrationdecisionsthatarepermanentinnature,werestricttheanalysistomigrationspellsthatareatleastfiveyearslong.15Wedefineamigrantasanindividualwhoisfoundinoneofthe1995‐2004cross‐sections,whoemigratesfromDenmarkduringthefollowingyeartodestinationsoutsideGreenlandortheFaroeIslands,andwhostaysabroadforatleastfiveyears.16Individualswhoemigratedforlessthanfiveyearswereremovedfromthedata,andtherestofthepopulationisthenclassifiedasnon‐migrants.17Theanalysisofbothmigrantsandnon‐migrantsisfurtherrestrictedtoonlyincludeDanishcitizenswhodonothavean“immigrationbackground.”18

    15Havingstayedabroadforfiveyearspredictslongermigrationspells.Forexample72%ofmenand71%ofwomenwholeftDenmarkin1996andwerestillabroadafterfiveyearswerealsoabroadaftertenyears.16GreenlandandtheFaroeIslandsareautonomousregionsbutstillpartofDenmark.WehaveexcludedthesedestinationsasmanyofthesemigrantscouldhaveoriginatedinGreenlandortheFaroeIslands,andmanywouldactuallybereturninghomeratherthanemigratingfromDenmark.Theexactdurationrequirementswere1,825daysorlongerforlong‐termmigrants. 17Wealsoexaminedtheselectionofshort‐termmigrantsandthequalitativeresultsaresimilartothosereportedbelow,althoughtheintensityofselectionisweaker.18StatisticsDenmarkdefinesapersontohave“noimmigrantbackground”ifatleastoneoftheparentswasborninDenmarkandthepersonis/wasaDanishcitizen.Wesearchedthepopulationregistersfrom1980to2010fortheparentsofthepersonsinoursample,andifaparentwasfoundheorshewasrequiredtobeaDanewithnoimmigrantbackgroundaswell.

  • 16

    Table1reportssummarystatisticsfromtheDanishadministrativedata.Thepaneldatasetcontainsover6.4millionmaleand5.1millionfemalenon‐migrants.Theconstructionofthedataimpliesthatnon‐migrantsappearinthedatamultipletimes(potentiallyonceineachcross‐sectionbetween1995and2004).Wewereabletoidentify7323maleand3436femalemigrants.Byconstruction,thesemigrantsarepersonswhowefirstobserveresidinginDenmarkandwholeftthecountryatsomepointbetween1996and2005.AsTable1shows,theDanishemigrantsareyoungerthanthenon‐migrants,regardlessofgender.Despitetheagedifference,theemigrantsearnedhigherannualincomesintheyearpriortothemigrationthanthenon‐migrants.Weconstructasimplemeasureof“standardizedearnings”thatadjustsfordifferencesinage,gender,andyeareffects.Standardizedearningsaredefinedbytheratioofaworker’sannualgrossearningstothemeangrossearningsofworkersofthesameageandgenderduringthecalendaryear.19Table1showsthatemigrantsearnmorethannon‐migrantsintermsofstandardizedearnings.Inparticular,maleemigrantsearnabout30percentmorethannon‐migrants,andfemaleemigrantsearnabout20percentmore.Table2reportsthenumberofemigrantsmovingtodifferentdestinations.ThelargestdestinationsforbothmenandwomenaretwootherNordiccountries,SwedenandNorway,aswellastheUnitedStates,theUnitedKingdomandGermany.20Thesefivecountriesaccountfor57percentofallemigration.Finally,itisalsointerestingtosummarizethelinkbetweeneducationandemigration.Table3reportstheeducationdistributionsfornon‐migrantsandmigrants.Itisevidentthatthemigrantstendtobemoreeducatedthanthenon‐migrants,amongbothmenandwomen.Forexample,50percentofDanishmalenon‐migrantshaveavocationaleducation,ascomparedtoonly30percentofmigrantstonon‐Nordicdestinations.Similarly, the 19Bothmigrantsandnon‐migrants,aswellasshorter‐termmigrants,areincludedinthesecalculations.20Ifwerelaxtheconstraintsonlabormarketstatusandagetoenterthesample,theUnitedKingdomemergesasthelargestdestinationbecauseofthelargenumberofDanishstudentswhopursuetheireducationthere.

  • 17

    fraction of male migrants to non-Nordic destinations with a Master’s degree is 24 percent,

    whereas only 7 percent of male non-migrants have a Master’s degree.

    In order to add time dimension, the evolution of the emigration rate is presented in figure 1a for

    men and in figure 1b for women separately for the whole population and for those with higher

    education and without higher education. As we are looking at long-term migration, the

    emigration rates are small, but there is an upward trend. The rate is higher for men and for those

    with higher education. We also computed the difference between the average of the log

    standardized earnings, or a degree of selection, for migrants and non-migrants for each year from

    1995 to 2004 for men and women separately. The results are reported in figures 2a and 2b. There

    is a downward trend in the difference for both men and women. The finding makes sense: when

    the migrants are positively self-selected and the emigration rate gets bigger the average

    standardized earnings of migrants should get smaller. However, the variation across years is

    small, so that pooling the data is justified.

    Tosummarize,thedescriptivefindingssuggestastrongdegreeofpositiveselection—atleastasmeasuredbyeducationanddifferencesintheconditionalmeansofearnings.

    4.Selectioninpre‐migrationearnings

    Thissectionpresentsempiricalevidenceontheself‐selectionofemigrantsfromDenmarkintermsofstandardizedpre‐emigrationearnings.Themainempiricalfindingisthatlong‐termemigrantsfromDenmarkwere,ingeneral,muchmoreproductivepriortotheirmigrationthanindividualswhochosetostay.Ofcourse,thesummarystatisticsreportedinTable1alreadysuggestpositiveselectionamongemigrantsbecausetheirstandardizedearningsexceededthoseofnon‐migrants.However,differencesinconditionalaveragescouldbemaskingsubstantialdifferencesbetweentheunderlyingprobabilitydistributions.Ourtheoreticalframeworkpredictsthatthedistributionofearningsformigrantsshouldstochasticallydominatethatofnon‐migrants.Asaresult,ourempiricalanalysiswillmainlyconsistofcomparingcumulative

  • 18

    distributionsofstandardizedearningsbetweenmigrantsandnon‐migrants.Anadvantageofsimplygraphingandexaminingthecumulativedistributionsisthattheanalysisdoesnotrequireanytypeofkerneldensityestimation,andthatwedonotneedtoimposeanystatisticalassumptionsorparametricstructureonthedata.Wewillalsopresentkerneldensityestimatesoftheearningsdensityfunctionsasanalternativewayofpresentingthekeyinsights.Finally,wewillderiveandreportstatisticalteststodetermineifthedatasupportthetheoreticalpredictionofstochasticdominance.Figure3aillustratesthecumulativeearningsdistributionsformalemigrantstoNordiccountries,malemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountries,andformalenon‐migrants.Thevaluesofthestandardizedearningsaretruncatedat‐2and2tomakethegraphsmoretractable.21Thefigureconfirmsthatmigrantswerepositivelyselectedduringthestudyperiod.ThecumulativedistributionfunctionofstandardizedearningsofmigrantstodestinationsoutsidetheNordiccountriesisclearlylocatedtotherightofthecorrespondingcumulativedistributionfornon‐migrants,aswouldbethecaseifthecumulativedistributionofmigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrants.ThefigurealsoshowsthatthedistributionfunctionformigrantstootherNordiccountriesislocatedtotherightofthatfornon‐migrants.However,theselectionofthemigrantstoNordiccountriesseemsweaker.ThisweakerselectionmayarisebecausetherateofreturntoskillsinNordiccountriesisrelativelylowwhencomparedtothatinotherpotentialdestinations.22Figure3bpresentscorrespondingevidenceforwomen.23Themainfindingsarequalitativelysimilar,butthepositiveselectionseemsweaker.

    21Thetruncationdoesnotaltertheresultsconsiderablyasthesharesofobservationsbelowthelowerandabovetheuppertruncationpointsaresmall.Further,thefollowinganalysisofdifferencesbetweencumulativedistributionfunctionsdoesnotusetruncation.0.07%ofnon‐migrants,0.19%migrantstootherNordiccountriesand0.11%ofmigrantstootherdestinationsliebelowthelowertruncationpoint.Correspondingly,0.03%ofnon‐migrantsand0.21%ofmigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountrieslieabovetheuppertruncationpoint.TherearenomigrantstootherNordiccountriesabovetheuppertruncationpoint.22Moreover,someDanesmayliveinsouthernSwedenbutworkinDenmark.AsthistypeofmigrationisnotrelatedtoreturnstoskillsinthedestinationcountrythisshoulddecreasetheestimatedselectiontoNordiccountries.

  • 19

    Figure4apresentsthecorrespondingkernelestimatesofthedensityfunctionsofthelogarithmofstandardizedearningsformen,whileFigure4bpresentstherespectivegraphsforwomen.24ThedensityfunctionsagainrevealthepositiveselectionofmigrantsmovingoutsidetheNordiccountries,bothformenandwomen.Asisevidentfromthefigures,Kolmogorov‐Smirnovtestscomparingtheearningsdistributionsfordifferentgroupsrejectthehypothesisthattheunderlyingearningsdistributionsarethesameatahighlysignificantlevel.Inadditiontoshowingthatthecumulativedistributionsaredifferent,itisalsoimportanttodetermineiftheevidencestatisticallysupportsthetheoreticalpredictionthatthecumulativedistributionfunctionofmigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrants.Statisticaltestsforfirst‐orderstochasticdominancearehighlysensitivetosmallchangesintheunderlyingdistributions,makingitdifficulttorankdistributionsinmanyempiricalapplications.25AsnotedbyDavidsonandDuclos(2013),itmaybeimpossibletoinferstochasticdominanceoverthefullsupportofempiricaldistributionsifthedistributionsarecontinuousinthetails,simplybecausethereisnotenoughinformationinthetailsformeaningfultestingofanystatisticalhypothesis.Itwouldthenmakesensetofocusontestingstochasticdominanceoverarestrictedrangeofthedistribution.Weapplyanapproachthatcharacterizestherangeoverwhichthevalueofthecumulativedistributionfunctionfornon‐migrantsisstatisticallysignificantlylargerthanthatofnon‐migrants.Inparticular,wecalculatethedifferencebetweenthecumulativedistributionfunctionswithconfidenceintervals.Tocalculatetheconfidenceintervalsweusetoolsthatwere

    23Forwomen,0.06%ofnon‐migrantsliebelowthelowertruncationpointand0.00%ofnon‐migrantslieabovethehighertruncationpoint.Therearenomigrantslyingbelowthelowerorabovethehighertruncationpoint.24FollowingLeibbrandtetal.(2005)andFernandes‐HuertasMoraga(2011),weuseSilverman’sreferencebandwidthmultipliedby0.75topreventover‐smoothing.Thesamebandwidthisusedalsoinallthekerneldensityestimatesreportedinsubsequentcalculations.25Thiscanleadtodifficultiesinempiricalwork,andlessrestrictiveconceptssuchasrestrictedfirstorderstochasticdominance(Atkinson,1987)andalmoststochasticdominance(LeshnoandKevy,2002)havebeenproposed.

  • 20

    introducedinAraar(2006)andAraaretal.(2009).26Moreformally,wetestthefollowingnullhypothesisforeach ∈ ,where isthejointsupportofthetwodistributions:(17) H0:F(w))=FN(w)–FM(w) 0,againstthealternativehypothesis(18) H1:F(w))=FN(w)–FM(w) 0

    andcharacterizeanyrelevantrangeof whereweareabletorejectthenull.Let bethestandarddeviationoftheestimator∆ w ,andletz()bethe(1–)thquantileofthestandardnormaldistribution.27DavidsonandDuclos(2000)showthattheestimator∆ w isconsistentandasymptoticallynormallydistributed.Wecanthendefinethelowerboundforaone‐sidedconfidenceintervalfor∆ as:28(19) ∆ ∆ w .WeestimatethestandarderrorsusingaTaylorlinearizationandallowforclusteringattheindividuallevel.Wethenimplementtheprocedurebycalculatingthelowerboundsoftheconfidenceintervalsfortheestimate∆ w definedinequation(19).Table4reportsthesharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantswhoseearningsareoutsidetherangeoverwhichthemigrantdistributionstochasticallydominatesata95percentconfidencelevel.Considerfirstthedistributionsofnon‐migrantmenandmenmigratingtodestinationsoutsidetheNordiccountries.Althoughitisnotclearlyvisiblefromfigure3a,26ThecalculationsareimplementedusingtheDASPStatamodulepresentedinAraarandDuclos(2013).27Theasymptoticvarianceof∆ isderivedinAraaretal.(2009).28Chow(1989)provedthetheoremforthecaseofindependentsamples.DavidsonandDuclos(2000)showthattheresultsalsoextendtothecaseofpairedincomesfromthesamepopulation.

  • 21

    thecumulativedistributionfunctionscrossnearthelowertailsofthedistributions.Figure5adepicts∆ w andlowerandupperboundsfora95%confidenceinterval.29Thelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositiveonmostoftherangecoveringthesupportsofthedistributions.Only2.0percentofthemigrantsand3.4percentofthenon‐migrantsliebelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,whereasthesharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsabovetheupperboundoftherangeare0.1and0.0percent.Putdifferently,theearningsofalmost98percentofmalemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountriesareontherangewherethecumulativedistributionfunctionfornon‐migrantsisstatisticallysignificantlyabovethefunctionformigrants.

    Figure5bdepicts∆ w andtheboundsfora95%confidenceintervalfornon‐migrantwomenandwomenmigratingtodestinationsoutsideNordiccountries.Only2.8percentofthemigrantsand4.1percentofthenon‐migrantshaveearningsbelowtherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,andanevensmaller0.2percentofthemigrantsand0.0percentofthenon‐migrantshaveearningsabovethisrange.WeinterpretthesefindingsassupportforthestochasticdominancepredictionforbothmenandwomenmigratingoutsideNordiccountries.Figures6aand6bandthebottompanelofTable4presentacorrespondinganalysisbycomparingthecumulativedistributionsofpersonswhomigratetootherNordiccountrieswiththatofnon‐migrants.Almost12percentofmalemigrantsand16percentofmalenon‐migrantshaveearningsthatliebelowtherangewhere ∆ ispositive,andanother1.5percentofthemigrantsand0.7percentofthenon‐migrantshaveearningsabovetherange.Putdifferently,about87percentofthemalemigrantstoNordiccountrieshaveincomesontherangewhere ∆ ispositive.Forwomen,itcanbeseeninTable4thatalmost95percentofthemigrantsgoingtoNordiccountrieshaveearningsontherangewhere

    ∆ ispositive.Tosumup,thefindingsoffersupporttothestochasticdominance

    29Theupperboundsarecalculatedsimilarlytothelowerbounds.

  • 22

    predictionformaleandfemalemigrantsregardlessoftheirdestination,althoughtheevidenceisweakerformenwhomigratedtoNordiccountries.AdditionalsupportforourtheorycomesfromMexico.OurtheorypredictsthattheearningsdistributionofmigrantsfromMexicototheUnitedStatesshouldbestochasticallydominatedbytheearningsdistributionofnon‐migrants.Fernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)presentsthesedistributionsformen.Althoughhedoesnotpresentconfidenceintervalsaswedo,thefiguressuggestapatternthatmirrorswhatwefindforDenmark,reversingthecurvesformigrantsandnon‐migrants.InMexico,thewagedistributionofnon‐migrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofmigrants,apartfromanoverlapforafewpercentatthebottomandconvergingatthetop.5.Selectioninunobservedcharacteristics

    Intheprevioussection,wedocumentedtheselectionthatcharacterizesthemigrantsusingthetotalpre‐migrationearnings(afteradjustingforageandyear).Wenowexamineaspecificcomponentofearnings,namelythecomponentduetounobservedcharacteristics.Inparticular,wenowadjustfordifferencesineducationalattainmentbetweenmigrantsandnon‐migrants(aswellasotherobservablevariables)byrunningearningsregressions,anddeterminewhetherthedistributionoftheresidualsdiffersbetweenthetwogroups.30Byconstruction,theresidualsfromaMincerianwageregressionreflectthepartofearningsthatisuncorrelatedwiththeobservedmeasuresofskill.Obviously,thedecompositionissomewhatarbitrarybecauseitdependsonthecharacteristicsthatareobservedandcanbeincludedasregressorsinthewageequation.Nevertheless,thestudyofemigrantselectionintermsofwageresidualsisimportantforanumberofreasons.

    30Intheearningsregressionsweusenon‐standardizedannualearningsasthedependentvariable.Weincludeageandyearfixedeffectsandruntheregressionsseparatelyformenandwomen.

  • 23

    First,selectionintermsofunobservablecharacteristicsshedslightontheimportanceofthequalityofjobmatchesrelativetotheskillcomponentthatisinternationallytransferable.Thetheorypredictsthatthenatureoftheselectioninunobservablecharacteristicsdependsonthemagnitudeofthecorrelationcoefficientmeasuringhowthesourceanddestinationcountriesvaluethesetypesofskills.Aslongasthiscorrelationisstronglypositive(sothatunobservedcharacteristicsareeasilytransferableacrosscountries),Danishemigrantswouldbepositivelyselectedinunobservables.Afterall,thepayofftothesetypesofskillsislikelytobegreaterinthedestinationcountries.However,itcouldbearguedthatthecorrelationbetweenthewageresidualsinDenmarkandabroadmaybe“small”.Forexample,theresidualsfromthewageregressionmaybelargelyreflectingthequalityoftheexistingjobmatchintheDanishlabormarket,ratherthanmeasuringtheworker’sinnateproductivity.Totheextentthatthequalityofthejobmatchplaysanimportantroleingeneratingtheresidual,thecorrelationinthisresidualacrosscountrieswouldbeexpectedtobeweak(infact,apurerandommatchingmodelwouldsuggestthatitwouldbezero).Asaresult,therewouldbenegativeselectioninunobservedcharacteristicssimplybecauseDanishworkerswithgoodjobmatches(andhencehighvaluesoftheresidual)wouldnotmove.Second,thetheoryalsosuggeststhatthenatureoftheselectioninpre‐migrationearningsdependsonaweightedaverageoftheselectionthatoccursinobservableandunobservablecharacteristics,withtheweightsbeingthefractionofearningsvarianceattributabletoeachtypeofskill.Becauseobservablecharacteristicsplayonlyalimitedroleinexplainingthevarianceofearningsinthepopulation,itiscrucialtopreciselydelineatethenatureofselectioninunobservablecharacteristics.Table5reportstheMincerianwageregressionsthatweusetocalculatetheresiduals.Thesampleincludesthewholepopulationofprimeagedfulltimeworkerspooledovertheentire1995‐2004period.Inadditiontovectorsoffixedeffectsgivingtheworker’sageandeducationalattainment,wealsoincludetheworker’smaritalstatusandnumberofchildren.Theregressionsareestimatedseparatelyformenandwomen.

  • 24

    Figure7apresentsthecumulativedistributionsofwageresidualsformalemigrantstoNordiccountries,malemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountries,andmalenon‐migrants.Thevaluesoftheresidualsaretruncatedat‐2and2,arangethatcoverspracticallyallofthepopulation.31ThecumulativedistributionfunctionofresidualsforemigrantswhomovedoutsidetheNordiccountriesislocatedtotherightofthecumulativedistributionformigrantstoNordiccountries,whichinturnislocatedtotherightofthecumulativedistributionofthenon‐migrants.Thevisualevidence,therefore,providesastrongindicationthatmigrantsarepositivelyselectedintermsofunobservedcharacteristics.Figure7bpresentstheanalogousevidenceforwomen.32Thefigureshowsthatfemalemigrantsarealsopositivelyselectedintermsofwageresiduals.Aswasthecasewhencomparingthemeasureofpre‐migrationearningsintheprevioussection,theselectioninunobservedcharacteristicsislesspronouncedforwomenthanformen.Oneexplanationforthiscouldbethatmenaretypicallyprimaryearnersincouples.WealsoperformedKolmogorov‐Smirnovtestsonthedistributionsofresidualsfornon‐migrantsandmigrantstootherNordiccountriesandformigrantstootherdestinations(separatelyformenandwomen).Allthetestsclearlyrejectedthenullhypothesis,confirmingthatthedistributionsofresidualsindeeddifferamongthegroups.33Theevidenceonthepositiveselectionofmigrantsinunobservedcharacteristicsobviouslyimpliesthattheselectioninpre‐migrationearningsdocumentedintheprevioussectioncannotbeattributedsolelytothefactthatmigrantsaremoreeducated.Instead,wefindthatthereispositiveselectionwithineducationgroups.Thisresultalsohasimplicationson

    31Formen,0.05%ofnon‐migrants,0.19%ofmigrantstootherNordiccountriesand0.11%ofmigrantstootherdestinationsliebelowthelowertruncationpoint.Correspondingly,0.03%ofnon‐migrantsand0.23%ofmigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountrieslieabovetheuppertruncationpoint.TherearenomigrantstootherNordiccountriesabovetheuppertruncationpoint.32Forwomen,0.05%ofnon‐migrantsliebelowthelowertruncationpointand0.00%ofnon‐migrantslieabovethehighertruncationpoint.Therearenomigrantslyingbelowthelowerorabovethehighertruncationpoint.33Thep‐valueforthetestbetweenwomenmigratingtootherNordiccountriesandtootherdestinationswas0.015andalltheotherp‐valueswere0.000,sothatalltestsclearlyrejectthehypothesisthattheobservationsaredrawnfromthesamedistribution.

  • 25

    theinterpretationofearningsregressionresidualsingeneral.Theresidualsfromwageregressionsaresometimesinterpretedasreflectingthevalueofthejobmatchbetweentheworkerandtheemployer.Ifahighvaluefortheresidualonlyreflectsagoodmatch,wewouldthenexpecttofindthatworkerswithlargeresidualswouldbelesslikelytochangejobsandlesspronetomigrate.Ourfindingsclearlyrejectthisinterpretation.Comparingresultsontheself‐selectiontootherNordiccountriesandtherestoftheworldsuggeststhatsearchforabetterjobmatchtothosewhohaveabadjobmatchinDenmarkismorepronouncedamongmigrantstootherNordiccountries.34Asintheprevioussection,wealsocalculatedthedifferencebetweenthecumulativedistributionfunctionswithconfidenceintervalstodeterminewhetherempiricalevidencesupportsthestochasticdominanceprediction.ThetestresultsaresummarizedinTable6.Figure8adepicts∆ w andthelowerandupperboundsfora95%confidenceintervalforthecomparisonbetweennon‐migrantmenandmenmigratingtodestinationsoutsideNordiccountries.Thelowerboundofthe95%confidenceintervalispositiveontherangeofresidualscoveringmostofthesupportofthetwodistributions.9.9percentofthemigrantsand15.2percentofthenon‐migrantshavewageresidualsbelowthelowerboundofthisrange,whereasthesharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsabovetheupperboundoftherangeare0.1and0.0percent.35Figure9adepicts∆ w andtheboundsfora95%confidenceintervalfornon‐migrantmenandmenmigratingtootherNordiccountries.A13percentshareofmigrantsand15percentofnon‐migrantshavevaluesofthewageresidualthatarebelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundofthe95%confidenceintervalispositive,andsharesof2percentand1percentofmigrantsandnon‐migrantshavevaluesoftheresidualthat34Forthisgroup,returnstounobservedproductivityarenotasimportantacriterionforself‐selectionasamongmigrantstotherestoftheworld,simplybecausedifferencesinreturnstoskillsbetweenDenmarkandotherNordiccountriesareminor.Asaresult,themechanismofsearchingforabettermatchqualityismorepronounced.35Forwomen,20percentofmigrantsand25percentofnon‐migrantshaveearningsresidualsbelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,andsharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsabovetherangearelessthanonepercent.

  • 26

    wouldplacethemabovethisrange.Putdifferently,theresidualsofover84percentofmalemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountriesareontherangewherethecumulativedistributionfunctionfornon‐migrantsisstatisticallysignificantlyabovethefunctionformigrants.36Interestingly,thereisasizableareainthelefttailofthedistributionofresidualswheretheupperboundoftheconfidenceintervalisnegative.37Weconcludebysummarizingtheevidenceasfollows:thereisstrongpositiveselectioninunobservablecharacteristicsinthesampleofmigrantsthatmovedoutsidetheNordiccountriesandweakerevidenceofpositiveselectioninthesampleofmigrantswhomovedtootherNordiccountries.6.Biasincounterfactualpredictions

    Thefactthatemigrantsareself‐selectedintheirunobservedcharacteristicsimpliesthatusingtheobservablecharacteristicsofmigrantstopredicttheircounterfactualearningshadtheychosennottomigratewillleadtobiasedresults.Duetodataconstraints,thisispreciselytheempiricalexerciseconductedbyChiquiarandHanson(2005),whoadoptthemethodologyintroducedbyDiNardo,Fortin,andLemieux(1996)andbuildacounterfactualwagedensityofwhattheMexicanimmigrantswouldhaveearnedinMexicohadtheystayed.TheactualwagedensityofMexican“stayers”isthencomparedtothecounterfactualdensityformigrants.Byconstruction,thisapproachignorestheroleofunobservablecharacteristicsintheestimationofthecounterfactualwagedistribution.AclearadvantageoftheDanishadministrativedataisthattheearningsofemigrantscanbeobservedbeforetheyemigrate,sothereisnoneedtobuildacounterfactualdensity.Onejustneedstocomparetheearningsdistributionofnon‐migrantstotheactualdistribution36Forwomen,20percentofmigrantsand25percentofnon‐migrantshaveearningsresidualsbelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,andsharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsabovetherangeare3percentand2percent.37A2percentshareofmigrantsand2percentshareofnon‐migrantshaveresidualsinthisarea,andtheinterpretationwouldbethatmalemigrantstootherNordiccountriesarenegativelyselectedintermsofresidualsinthelefttailofthedistribution.

  • 27

    offuturemigrants,aswehavedoneintheprecedinganalysis.Theadministrativedata,however,allowsustopreciselymeasuretheextentofthebiasresultingfromcarryingoutthecounterfactualexerciseinChiquiarandHanson(2005).Inparticular,wecancontrastthepredictedcounterfactualwagedistributionofmigrantshadtheynotmovedtotheactualwagedistributionofmigrantspriortotheirmove.WecarryoutthisexercisebypreciselyreplicatingthevariousstepsintheChiquiar‐Hansoncalculations.Itisworthemphasizingthatthistypeofbiaswillarisenotonlyinstudiesthatexaminetheselectionofmigrants,butinanystudythatreliesonobservablestopredictacounterfactualwagedistribution.Let representthelogarithmofstandardizedannualearningsasdefinedearlier(i.e.earningsadjustedforage,gender,andyeareffects).Let | bethedensityfunctionofwagesinDenmark,conditionalonasetofobservablecharacteristics .Also,let beanindicatorvariableequaltooneiftheindividualmigratesthefollowingyearandequaltozerootherwise.Definefurther | 0 astheconditionaldensityofobservedcharacteristicsamongworkersinDenmarkwhochoosenottomigrate,and | 1 bethecorrespondingconditionaldensityamongmigrants.Theobservedwagedensityforthenon‐migrantsis(20) | 0 | , 0 | 0 .Similarly,theobserveddensityforthemigrantsis(21) | 1 | , 1 | 1 .

    Uptothispoint,theanalysisreportedinthispaperconsistsofdirectlyestimatingandcomparingthedistributionfunctionsassociatedwiththedensitiesinequations(20)and(21).Supposethatthepre‐migrationearningsdensityfornon‐migrantswerenotavailable.Wewouldinsteadattempttoestimateitfromtheobservablecharacteristicsofthemigrants.Theimpliedcounterfactualdistributionis:

  • 28

    (23) | 1 | , 0 | 1 .Equation(23)correspondstothedensityofincomefornon‐migrants,butitisinsteadintegratedoverthedensityofobservablecharacteristicsformigrants.Notethatthecounterfactualdensityin(23)canberewrittenas:(24)

    | 1 | , 0 | 0 | 1| 0

    | , 0 | 0 , where || .Tocompute ,weuseBayes’lawtowrite:(25) | | and

    | | ,

    where istheunconditionaldensityofobservedcharacteristics.Wecanthencombinethesetwoequationstosolvefor:(26)

    1|1 1|

    01 .

    TheproportionPr(I=0)/Pr(I=1)isaconstantrelatedtotheproportionofmigrantsinthedata.Itcanbesettooneinkerneldensityestimationwithoutlossofgenerality.Theweightweuseintheestimationisthengivenby:

  • 29

    (27) 1|

    1 1| .AsinChiquiarandHanson(2005),theindividualweightsearecalculatedbyestimatingalogitmodelwherethedependentvariableindicatesifapersonemigrated.Theregressorsincludeavectorofagefixedeffects,avectorofschoolingfixedeffects,variablesindicatingwhethertheworkerismarriedandthenumberofchildren(andaninteractionbetweenthesetwovariables),andavectorofyearfixedeffects.38Table7reportsthelogitregressionsestimatedseparatelybygender.Thecoefficientsarethenusedtocomputetheweightsforeachnon‐migrantpersoninthesample.39Figures10aand10bpresenttheresultingcounterfactualdensityfunctionsofthelogarithmofstandardizedearningsaswellastheactualdistributionsformigrantsandnon‐migrants.40Thedifferencebetweentheactualdensityfornon‐migrantsandthecounterfactualdensityformigrantsreflectsthepartofself‐selectionthatisduetoobservablecharacteristics.Similarly,thedifferencebetweenthecounterfactualandactualdensitiesformigrantsreflectsthepartofselectionthatisduetounobservedcharacteristics(i.e.,allthosevariablesthatcouldnotbeincludedinthelogitmodel).Onesimplewayofquantifyingthesedistributionaldifferencesistocomputetheaveragesofthevariousdistributions.ThesecalculationsarereportedinTable8.Considerinitiallytheresultsinthemalesample.Thedifferencebetweenthemeanoftheactualdistributionsformigrantsandnon‐migrantsis0.245logpoints,butthedifferencebetweenthecounterfactualdistributionandthedistributionfornon‐migrantsis0.073.Thisimpliesthatonlyabout30percentofthepositiveselectioninpre‐migrationearningscanbeattributed38Wealsotriedspecificationswithage,agesquaredandinteractionsofexplanatoryvariables,butwedonotreporttheseanalysesastheresultingcounterfactualdistributionsdidnotpracticallydifferfromthedistributionsresultingfromthissimplerspecification.39Asearlier,weuseSilverman’sreferencebandwidthmultipliedby0.75.40Toconductthecounterfactualanalysiswepoolthesampleofallmigrants(regardlessofwhethertheymovedtoNordiccountriesornot).

  • 30

    totheobservablecharacteristicsincludedinthelogitmodel,whileabout70percentisattributabletounobservabledeterminantsofproductivity.Thecalculationsinthefemalesampleyieldadifferenceof0.157logpointsbetweenthemeansoftheactualdistributionsformigrantsandnon‐migrantsandadifferenceof0.074pointsbetweenthecounterfactualdistributionandthedistributionfornon‐migrants.Asaresult,observableandunobservablecharacteristicseachaccountforabouthalfofthepositiveself‐selectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofwomen.41Thekeylessonisclear:selectioninunobservablecharacteristicsplaysacrucialroleindeterminingtheskillcompositionofemigrants.Thedistinctroleofobservablesandunobservablesindeterminingtheselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofmigrantsisevidentifwereturntotheRoymodelandequation(16),whichpresentstheconditionalexpectationE(logw0|v*>*).Equation(16)yieldsaninterestingandpotentiallyimportantinsight.Thenatureoftheselectioninpre‐migrationearnings,ofcourse,isgivenbythesumoftheselectioninobservablesandtheselectioninunobservables.Note,however,thateachoftheseselectiontermshasaweightingcoefficientthatrepresentsthevarianceinearningsattributabletoobservablecharacteristics( r02S2)ortounobservablecharacteristics(02 ).Asnotedearlier,observablecharacteristicsexplainarelativelysmallfractionofthevarianceinearnings.Putdifferently,equation(16)impliesthatitistheselectioninunobservablesthatismostlikelytodeterminethenatureoftheselectionthatcharacterizestheemigrantsample.Totheextentthatbothtypesofselections(i.e.,inobservablesandunobservables)workinthesamedirection,thecounterfactualexercisedescribedinthissectionwillinevitablyunderestimatethetrueextentofpositiveselectioninpre‐migrationearnings.Conversely,41Thecomponentofself‐selectionthatisduetounobservablecharacteristicsplaysasomewhatsmallerroleforwomen.Onereasoncouldbethatwomenaremoreoftentiedmigrants,andthemigrationdecisionmaybemainlybasedontheskillsofthespouse.Thevarianceinincomeisalsosmallerforwomen,whichalsomakestheselectionbothintermsofobservableandunobservablecharacteristicsweaker.

  • 31

    thecounterfactualexercisewillalsoattenuatetheextentof“true”negativeselectionifthereisnegativeselectioninbothcomponentsofskills.Infact,Fernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)presentsacorrespondinganalysisusingsurveydatafromMexicoandfindsthatcounterfactualestimatesgreatlyunderestimatetheextentofnegativeselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofMexicanswhomovetotheUnitedStates.Putdifferently,thecounterfactualexercisemayleadtoqualitativelyrightconclusionsaboutthenatureoftheselection,butitmayalsogenerateasizablebias,greatlyunderestimatingthetrueextentofeitherpositiveornegativeselection.7.Selectionandimmigrationrestrictions

    Asappliedintheimmigrationliterature,theRoymodelfocusessolelyontheeconomicfactorsthatmotivatelaborflowsacrossinternationalborders.Themodelingtypicallyignoresthefactthattheseflowsoccurwithinapolicyframeworkwheresomereceivingcountriesenactdetailedrestrictionsspecifyingwhichpotentialmigrantsareadmissibleandwhicharenot.WecanusetheadministrativedatafromDenmark,combinedwiththeuniquepoliticalcircumstancesthatguaranteefreemigrationwithinEurope,topartiallyaddressthequestionofwhetherimmigrationpolicyaffectsselectionallthatmuchintheend.Specifically,wecansubdividethegroupofmigrantswhomovedoutsideNordiccountriesintotwogroups:thosewhomovedtoacountryintheEU15ortoSwitzerland,andthosewhomovedtoacountryoutsidetheEU15andSwitzerland.MovementoflaborwasunrestrictedbetweenDenmarkandotherEU15countriesandSwitzerlandintheperiodunderstudy,butwasobviouslyrestrictedbyimmigrationregulationstodestinationsoutsidetheEU15,suchastheUnitedStates.ItturnsoutthatthesedifferentimmigrationpoliciespursuedbytheEU15andSwitzerlandandtherestoftheworldbarelymatterindeterminingtheselectionofDanishemigrants.Figure11adepictsthecumulativedistributionfunctionsofthelogarithmofstandardizedannualincomeformenandfigure11bforwomen.Itisevidentthatthedistribution

  • 32

    functionsofstandardizedearningsareverysimilarforthetwogroupsofmigrants.42Wealsoconductedtheanalysisusingthewageresiduals(notshown),andthedistributionsofresidualsarealsosimilarbetweenthetwogroups.Thereisanimportantsenseinwhichthesepolicyrestrictionscannotmattermuch.Suppose,forexample,thatareceivingcountryenactsapolicythatlimitsentryonlytohigh‐skillimmigrants.Ifthehigh‐skillimmigrantsfromasendingcountrydonotfinditoptimaltomove,thepolicycannotforcethosehigh‐skillworkerstomigrate.Allthepolicycandoisessentiallycutthemigrationflowfromthatparticularsendingcountrydowntozero.Thelow‐skillworkerswouldliketomovebutarenotadmitted,andthehighskillworkersareadmissiblebuttheydonotwanttomove.Insum,thepositiveself‐selectionthatissoevidentintheDanishemigrantdatacannotbeexplainedbyimmigrationrestrictions.EventhoughlaborflowstotheEU15andSwitzerlandwereunrestricted,thereisnoevidenceofweakerpositiveselectiontothesecountriesthantotherestoftheworld.Our results also have tentative implications for the question of whether migration patterns reflect differences in rate of returns or migration costs.

    Although it is plausible that migration costs are higher when moving to other continents, our

    results suggest that such differences do not play a significant role in the sorting of emigrants

    between Europe and other continents, most notably North America.

    8.Conclusion

    ThispapershowsthattheRoymodelhasmoredramaticpredictionsontheself‐selectionofemigrantsthanpreviouslyexamined.Thesameconditionsthathavebeenshowntoresultinemigrantsbeingpositively(negatively)self‐selectedintermsoftheiraverageearningsactuallyimplythattheearningsdistributionofemigrantsfirst‐orderstochasticallydominates(orisfirst‐orderstochasticallydominatedby)theearningsdistributionofnon‐

    42Forwomen,aKolmogorov‐Smirnovtestisnotabletorejectthenull‐hypothesisthattheobservationsforthetwogroupsofmigrantscomefromthesameunderlyingdistribution.

  • 33

    migrants.Ourtheoreticalanalysisalsodistinguishesbetweenselectioninobservableandselectioninunobservablecharacteristics.OurempiricalanalysisusestheDanishfullpopulationadministrativedatatoanalyzetheself‐selectionofemigrants,intermsofeducation,earningsandunobservableability,measuredbyresidualsfromMincerianearningsregressions.Theresultsareinlinewiththetheory;themigrantsarebettereducatedandbothpre‐emigrationearningsandwageregressionresidualsofmigrantsstochasticallydominatethoseofnon‐migrantsovermostofthesupportofthedistributions.Consider,forexample,thecaseoffull‐timeworkersaged25‐54.For98percentofmenand97percentofwomenwhomigrateoutsideotherNordiccountriesthecumulativeearningsdistributionintheyearbeforeemigrationstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrantswitha95%confidenceinterval.Thedifferencebetweenthecumulativedistributionsisnotstatisticallysignificantlydifferentineitherdirectionfortheremaining2to3percent.Decomposingtheself‐selectionintotalearningsintoself‐selectioninobservablecharacteristicsandself‐selectioninunobservablecharacteristics(asmeasuredbyresidualsfromMincerianwageregressions),revealsthatunobservedabilitiesplaythedominantrole.Formen,about70percentofthepositiveself‐selectioninpre‐migrationearningsisattributabletounobservabledeterminantsofproductivity.Forwomen,thefractionisabout50percent.Thissuggeststhatrelyingoncounterfactualdistributions,basedonobservedcharacteristics,wouldstronglyunderestimatepositiveself‐selection.ThisresultcomplementstheFernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)findingthatcounterfactualestimatesalsogreatlyunderestimatetheextentofnegativeselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofMexicanswhomovetotheUnitedStates.Inshort,theuseofcounterfactualearningsdistributionsbasedonobservablecharacteristicsgreatlyunderstatethetrueextentofselectionintotalearnings.Strongpositiveself‐selectioninresidualsalsosuggeststhatunobservedabilitiesplayamuchbiggerroleinmigrationdecisionsthanmatchquality.Ourfindingsalsohaveimplicationsforimmigrationpolicies.Receivingcountriescanonlybasetheiradmissionpoliciesonskillvariablesthatareobserved,whereasmuchofthe

  • 34

    selectionofimmigrantsis“hidden”intheirunobservedcharacteristics.Itcanbeexpectedthatmigrantswillbeself‐selectedintermsofunobservedcharacteristicsevenwhenadmissionrestrictionsareapplied,andtheself‐selectionamongthosefulfillingadmissioncriteriacanbeexpectedtoreflectrelativeskillprices.Thisraisesaquestionabouttheeffectivenessofpointsystemsthatarenecessarilybasedonobservablecharacteristics.Theimportanceofrelativeskillpricesisalsosupportedbyourseparateanalysesofself‐selectionofDanesmigratingtothecountriesbelongingtocommonEuropeanlabormarket(excludingotherNordiccountriesthathaveskillpricessimilartoDenmark)andnothavinganyimmigrationrestrictions,andtheself‐selectiontotherestoftheworld.Thereisvirtuallynodifferenceintheself‐selectiontothesedestinationareas.

  • 35

    ReferencesAbramitzky,R.,L.Boustan,andK.Eriksson(2012).“Europe’sTired,Poor,HuddledMasses:Self‐SelectionandEconomicOutcomesintheAgeofMassMigration.”AmericanEconomicReview102(5):1832–56.Abramitzky,R.andF.Braggion(2006).“MigrationandHumanCapital:Self‐SelectionofIndenturedServantstotheAmericas.”JournalofEconomicHistory66(4):882–905.Araar,A.(2006).“Poverty,InequalityandStochasticDominance,TheoryandPractice:TheCaseofBurkinaFaso.”CahiersderecherchéPMMA2007‐087,PEP‐PMMA.Araar,A.andJ.Y.Duclos(2013).“UserManualforStataPackageDASP:Version2.3.”UniversitéLavalPEP,CIRPÉEandWorldBank.Araar,A.,J.Y.Duclos,M.Audet,andP.Makdissi(2009).“TestingforPro‐poornessofGrowth,withanApplicationtoMexico.”ReviewofIncomeandWealth55(4):853–881.Arnold,B.C.,R.Beaver,R.A.GroeneveldandW.Q.Meeker(1993).“TheNontruncatedMarginalofaTruncatedBivariateNormalDistribution.”Psychometrika58(3):471–488.Atkinson,A.B.(1987).“OntheMeasurementofPoverty.”Econometrica55:749–764.Boarini,R.andH.Strauss(2010).“WhatisthePrivateReturntoTertiaryEducation?:NewEvidencefrom21OECDCountries.”OECDJournal:EconomicStudies,Vol.2010/1.Borjas,G.J.(1987).“Self‐SelectionandtheEarningsofImmigrants.”AmericanEconomicReview77:531–553.Borjas,G.J.(2003).“TheLaborDemandCurveisDownwardSloping:ReexaminingtheImpactofImmigrationontheLaborMarket.”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics118(4):1335–1374.Bratsberg,B.(1995).“TheIncidenceofNonReturnAmongForeignStudentsintheUnitedStates.”EconomicsofEducationReview14(4):373–384.Chiquiar,D.andG.H.Hanson(2005).“InternationalMigration,Self‐Selection,andtheDistributionofWages:EvidencefromMexicoandtheUnitedStates.”JournalofPoliticalEconomy113(2):239–281.Chow,K.V.(1989).“StatisticalInferenceforStochasticDominance:aDistributionFreeApproach.”Ph.D.Thesis,UniversityofAlabama.Cobb‐Clark,D.(1993).“ImmigrantSelectivityandWages:TheEvidenceforWomen.”AmericanEconomicReview83:986–93.

  • 36

    DavidsonR.andJ.Y.Duclos(2000).“StatisticalInferenceforStochasticDominanceandfortheMeasurementofPovertyandInequality.”Econometrica68:1435–64.DavidsonR.andJ.Y.Duclos(2013).“TestingforRestrictedStochasticDominance.”EconometricReviews32:84–125.DiNardo,J.,N.M.Fortin,andT.Lemieux(1996).“LaborMarketInstitutionsandtheDistributionofWages,1973–1992:ASemiparametricApproach.”Econometrica64(September):1001–44.Fernández‐HuertasMoraga,J.(2011).‘‘NewEvidenceonEmigrantSelection.’’ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics93(1):72–96.Ferrie,J.(1996).“ANewSampleofMalesLinkedfromthePublicUseMicroSampleofthe1850U.S.FederalCensusofPopulationtothe1860U.S.FederalCensusManuscriptSchedules.”HistoricalMethods29:141–56.Grogger,J.andG.H.Hanson(2011).“IncomeMaximizationandtheSelectionandSortingofInternationalMigrants.”JournalofDevelopmentEconomics95(1):42–57.HanushekE.A.,G.Schwerdt,S.Wiederhold,andL.Woessmann(2015).“ReturnstoSkillsaroundtheWorld:EvidencefromPIAAC.”EuropeanEconomicReview73:103–130.Junge,M.,M.D.Munk,andP.Poutvaara(2014).“InternationalMigrationofCouples.”CESifoWP4927.Kaestner,R.andO.Malamud(2014).“Self‐SelectionandInternationalMigration:NewEvidencefromMexico,”TheReviewofEconomicsandStatistics,96(1):78–71.Kleven,H.J.,C.Landais,E.Saez,andE.Schultz(2014).“MigrationandWageEffectsofTaxingTopEarners:EvidenceoftheForeigners’TaxSchemeinDenmark.”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics129:333–78.Leibbrandt,M.,J.Levinsohn,andJ.McCrary(2005)."IncomesinSouthAfricasincetheFallofApartheid."NBERworkingpaperno.11384.Leshno,M.andH.Kevy(2002).“PreferredbyAllandPreferredbyMostDecisionMakers:AlmostStochasticDominance.”ManagementScience48:1074–1085.Lundborg,P.(1991).“DeterminantsofMigrationintheNordicLaborMarket.”TheScandinavianJournalofEconomics93(3):363–375.Margo,R.A.(1990).RaceandSchoolingintheSouth,1880–1950:AnEconomicHistory.Chicago:UniversityofChicagoPress.

  • 37

    Pirttilä,J.(2004).“IsInternationalLabourMobilityaThreattotheWelfareState?EvidencefromFinlandinthe1990’s.”FinnishEconomicPapers17(1):18–34.Sinn,H.‐W.(1997).“TheSelectionPrincipleandMarketFailureinSystemsCompetition.”JournalofPublicEconomics66:247‐274.Thistle,P.D.(1993).“NegativeMoments,RiskAversionandStochasticDominance.“JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis28(2):301–311.UnitedNations,DepartmentofEconomicandSocialAffairs(2013).TrendsinInternationalMigrantStock:MigrantsbyDestinationandOrigin(UnitedNationsdatabase,POP/DB/MIG/Stock/Rev.2013).Wegge,S.A.(1999).“ToPartorNottoPart:EmigrationandInheritanceInstitutionsinNineteenth‐CenturyHesse‐Cassel.”ExplorationsinEconomicHistory36(1):30–55.Wegge,S.A.(2002).“OccupationalSelf‐SelectionofEuropeanEmigrants:EvidencefromNineteenth‐CenturyHesse‐Cassel.”EuropeanReviewofEconomicHistory6(3):365–94.Wildasin,D.E.(1991).“IncomeRedistributioninaCommonLaborMarket.”AmericanEconomicReview81(4):757–774.

  • a.Men

    b.Wom

    men

    Figurre1.Evolu

    38

    utionoftheeemigratioonrate

  • Figur

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    e2.Evolut

    men

    tionofthe

    differencemigrant

    39

    ebetweentsandnon

    averagelo‐migrants

    ogstandar

    rdizedearnningsof

  • Figur

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    re3.Distri

    men

    butionfun

    nctionsofsn

    40

    standardiznon‐migran

    zedannualnts

    learnings

    formigranntsand

  • Figurea.Men

    b.Wom

    4.Density

    men

    yfunctions

    sforstand

    41

    ardizedeaarningsforrmigrants

    sandnon‐mmigrants

  • Figuearn

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    ure5.Diffeningsbetw

    men

    erenceoftweenmigra

    thecumulaantsmovin

    42

    ativedistringoutside

    ibutionfunNordicco

    nctionsforuntriesan

    rpre‐migrndnon‐mig

    rationgrants

  • Figu

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    ure6.Diffeearningso

    men

    erenceoftofmigrant

    thecumulatsgoingto

    43

    ativedistriotherNor

    ibutionfunrdiccountr

    nctionsforriesandno

    rpre‐migron‐migrant

    rationts

  • Figure

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    e7.Distrib

    men

    butionfunnctionsofrand

    44

    residualsfrdnon‐migr

    romearninrants

    ngsregres

    ssionformmigrants

  • Fig

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    gure8.Difmigran

    men

    fferenceofntsgoingo

    fthecumuoutsideoth

    45

    ulativedistherNordic

    tributionfucountries

    unctionsoandnon‐m

    ofresidualsmigrants

    sfor

  • Fig

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    gure9.Difmig

    men

    fferenceofgrantsgoin

    fthecumungtoother

    46

    ulativedistNordicco

    tributionfuuntriesan

    unctionsondnon‐mig

    ofresidualsgrants

    sfor

  • Fig

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    gure10.Co

    men

    ounterfactuualandact

    47

    tualdensittiesofstanndardized

    grossearnnings

  • Figure

    a.Men

    b.Wom

    e11.Distr

    men

    ributionfunandSwitze

    nctionsoferlandand

    48

    annualgrdmigrants

    ossearninstootherd

    ngsformigdestination

    grantstothns

    heEU15

  • 49

    Table1.Summarystatistics

    Non-migrant men Migrant

    men Non-migrant

    women Migrant women

    Observations 6450665 7323 5163129 3436 Age

    Average 39.8 33.0 40.2 35 Median 40.0 35.4 40.0 33.0

    Annual earnings in 2010 euros

    Average 52725 68151 40299 46412 Median 46675 57350 37976 42393

    Standardized annual earnings

    Average 1.0 1.3 1.0 1.2 Median 0.9 1.2 0.95 1.1

  • 50

    Table2.Numbersofmigrants,bydestination

    Men Women Sweden 1466 699The United States 763 363 The United Kingdom 725 432 Norway 576 273 Germany 560 249 Spain 255 147 Switzerland 233 118 France 222 156 Other 2523 999

  • 51

    Table3.Educationlevelsofnon‐migrantsandmigrantsgoingtoNordiccountriesor

    tootherdestinations

    Men Women

    Education Non-migrants Nordic

    countries Other

    destinations Non-

    migrants Nordic

    countries Other

    destinations

    Comprehensive school 21.4 19.8 8.3 21.5 15.7 8.9

    High school 3.2 7.8 8.6 3.1 6.9 8.9

    Vocational school 49.8 43.5 30.3 41.8 36.5 30.8

    Advanced vocational 5.6 5.7 6.6 4.9 5.1 7.8

    Bachelor or equivalent 12.2 11.6 20.6 23.3 22.9 25.4

    Master’s or equivalent 7.3 10.6 23.9 5.1 12.3 17.6

    Doctoral or equivalent 0.5 1.0 1.7 0.2 0.7 0.7

    Notes: The unit is percentage. The category “advanced vocational” includes all the tertiary education programs below the level of a Bachelor’s program or equivalent. Programs on this level may be referred to for instance with such terms as community college education, advanced vocational training or associate degree.

  • 52

    Table4.Summaryoftestsofstochasticdominanceindistributionsofstandardizedpre‐migrationearnings

    Distributions being compared:

    Percent of sample below lower bound

    Percent of sample above upper bound

    Migrants Non-migrants Migrants Non-migrantsMigrants outside Nordic countries and non-migrants

    Male 2.0 3.4 0.1 0.0 Female 2.8 4.1 0.2 0.0

    Migrants to Nordic countries and non-migrants

    Male 11.6 15.5 1.5 0.7 Female 2.6 4.1 2.6 1.3

    Notes:Lowerboundandupperboundrefertotherangeoverwhichthedifferenceofthecumulativedistributionfunctionsissignificantata95percentconfidencelevel.

  • 53

    Table5.Mincerianearningsregressions,bygender

    (1) men (2) women B Se B se

    Married 0.068*** (0.00) -0.016*** (0.00) Children 0.025*** (0.00) -0.048*** (0.00)

    High school 0.224*** (0.00) 0.190*** (0.00) Vocational school 0.092*** (0.00) 0.089*** (0.00)

    Advanced vocational 0.186*** (0.00) 0.198*** (0.00) Bachelor 0.298*** (0.00) 0.225*** (0.00) Master’s 0.498*** (0.00) 0.536*** (0.00)

    PhD 0.490*** (0.00) 0.622*** (0.00) 1996 0.020*** (0.00) 0.017*** (0.00) 1997 0.043*** (0.00) 0.041*** (0.00) 1998 0.078*** (0.00) 0.083*** (0.00) 1999 0.103*** (0.00) 0.112*** (0.00) 2000 0.141*** (0.00) 0.143*** (0.00) 2001 0.175*** (0.00) 0.175*** (0.00) 2002 0.207*** (0.00) 0.210*** (0.00) 2003 0.236*** (0.00) 0.235*** (0.00) 2004 0.252*** (0.00) 0.258*** (0.00)

    Constant Age fixed effects

    12.131*** Yes

    (0.00)

    11.931*** Yes

    (0.00)

    N R-squared

    6470720 0.2597

    5173706 0.3062

    *p

  • 54

    Table6.SummaryoftestsofstochasticdominanceindistributionsofresidualsDistributions being compared:

    Percent of sample below lower bound

    Percent of sample above upper bound

    Migrants Non-migrants

    Migrants Non-migrants

    Migrants outside Nordic countries and non-migrants

    Male 9.9 15.2 0.1 0.0 Female 19.6 24.7 0.4 0.0

    Migrants to Nordic countries and non-migrants

    Male 13.4 15.2 2.0 0.9 Female 19.5 24.7 3.4 1.8

    Notes:Lowerboundandupperboundrefertotherangeoverwhichthedifferenceofthecumulativedistributionfunctionsissignificantata95percentconfidencelevel.

  • 55

    Table7.Logitestimatesoftheprobabilityofemigration,bygender

    (1) men (2) women B Se B se

    Married -0.110** (0.04) -0.191*** (0.05) Children -1.137*** (0.05) -1.232*** (0.07)

    Married*Children 0.460*** (0.07) 0.374*** (0.09) High school 1.377*** (0.05) 1.158*** (0.08)

    Vocational school 0.186*** (0.04) 0.159** (0.06) Advanced vocational 0.648*** (0.06) 0.714*** (0.08)

    Bachelor 1.097*** (0.04) 0.581*** (0.06) Master’s 1.652*** (0.04) 1.444*** (0.07)

    PhD 1.723*** (0.10) 1.655*** (0.21) y1996 -0.032 (0.06) -0.001 (0.08) y1997 0.002 (0.06) -0.016 (0.08) y1998 -0.024 (0.06) -0.001 (0.08) y1999 0.230*** (0.05) 0.131 (0.08) y2000 0.260*** (0.06) 0.238** (0.09) y2001 0.161** (0.05) 0.146 (0.08) y2002 0.208*** (0.05) 0.046 (0.08) y2003 0.198*** (0.05) 0.112 (0.08) y2004 0.246*** (0.05) 0.178* (0.08)

    Constant -6.700*** (0.08) -6.951*** (0.12) N 6470720 5173706

    Pseudo 0.0540 0.0557 *p

  • 56

    Table8.Actualandcounterfactualdifferencesbetweentheaveragelogstandardizedearningsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants

    Men Women Non-migrant average -0.065 -0.040Estimated average for migrants 0.008 0.034 True average for migrants 0.180 0.117 True difference 0.245 0.157 Counterfactual difference 0.073 0.074 Share of the actual difference explained by observable characteristics, %

    29.6

    47.0