simple pigovian taxes vs. emission eees to control negative

Upload: tanjim-ahmed

Post on 02-Jun-2018

222 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    1/8

    SIMPLE PIGOVIAN TAXES VS. EMISSION EEES TO CONTROL NEGATIV

    EXTERNA LITIES: A PEDAGOGICAL NOTE

    by Robert S. Main*

    Abstract

    Many economics texts introduce their analysis of negative externalities by examining a tax on the

    output of polluting firms, sometimes called a simp le Pigovian tax, often pointing out that taxing

    pollution directly is superior to taxing output and proceeding to discuss an emission fee as an alterna-

    tive. They do not show how and why an emission fee is more efficient than an output tax. This note

    presents a numerical example allowing comparison of the welfare effects of the two approaches, as

    well as showing why simply reducing the pollution intensity of polluters' output would be inferior to

    an emission fee.

    eywords Simple Pigovian tax. Emission fee. Pollution, Efficiency, Command and control

    I. Introduction

    Almost all principles of economics texts, public

    finance texts, environmental economics texts and

    intermediate microeconomics texts deal with the

    economics of extemalities. (Representative Princi-

    ples texts: Mankiw (2007) and Frank/Bemanke

    (2007).

    Public Finance texts: Anderson (2003),

    Gmber (2007), Holcombe (2006), Hyman (2008),

    Steineman, et al (2005), Stiglitz (2000), and

    Ulbrich (2003). Environmental texts: Callan and

    Thomas (2000), Kahn (2005), Keohane/Olmstead

    (2007) and Tietenberg (2003). Intermediate Micro-

    economics texts: Besanko/Braeutigan (2005) and

    Waldman (2004).) The discussion of negative pro-

    duction extemalities usually begins by pointing out

    that the social cost of producing goods that entail

    negative extemalities is higher than the private

    cost. The authors then point out that the resulting

    exce ss output can be corrected by imposing a

    taxoften called a Pigovian taxon the output of

    the offending product. Many texts continue by

    pointing out that taxing pollution directly, instead

    of output, can be more efficient. However, the

    texts do not show or fully explain why one ap-

    proach is more efficient than the other. This note

    offers a straightforward numerical example to il-

    lustrate the efficiency gains from taxing pollution

    directly rather than taxing the output of pollu

    generating goods. The example also illustrates

    simply ordering firms to reduce the pollution

    tensity of their products is less efficient than ta

    pollution direcdy. The issue of how to deal

    negative extemalities is important, because the

    ferent approaches discussed in the paper can

    significantly different welfare implications.

    II. Current Textbook Treatment

    Economics textbooks often introduce the

    cept of negative extemalities using an exampl

    which the production of each unit of a good re

    in a certain amount of extemal damage. (See

    example, Mankiw (2007, 206-7), Frank and

    nanke (2007, 349-51), Tietenberg

    (2003,

    6

    Kahn (2005, 47-8), Keohane and Olmstead (2

    67- 70 ) , Callan and Thomas (2000, 86-95),

    Besanko/Braeutigan (2005, 638-6 47).) The ex

    ple usually shows the competitive market su

    curve (Marginal Private Cost) the demand c

    (Marginal Private Benefitequal to Marginal

    cial Benefit, if there is no extemality in consu

    tion) and Marginal Social Cost, equal to

    vertical sum of the MPC and the Marginal Ext

    Damage (MED). The socially optimal quantit

    where MSC intersects MSB, but a compet

    Department of Economics, Law and Finance, College of Business, BuUer University, Indianap

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    2/8

    the competitive market produces too much

    Pigovian tax equal to the level of MED. (If

    careful graphical

    and Kahn (2005, 47-8).)

    Some texts point out that taxing the output of

    is fully efficient only if the amount

    ient to tax the output of firms. Rather, the pol-

    t uses the word Pigovian to describe the direct

    to connect the two stories.

    n

    The xample

    Imagine a competitive industry producing good

    10 units of a pollutant. (Call this amount E.) Each

    unit of the pollutant that is emitted causes a dam-

    age of $7.50. (Call this amount f ) There is no

    extemality associated with the consumption of the

    good. Then the total extemal damage (TED)

    caused by the production of the good is: f E-x

    where x is the total amount of the good produced

    by the industry, and the damage per unit is f E, or

    75,

    in this example.

    The demand for the good (the Marginal Private

    Benefit, which in this case is also the Marginal

    Social Benefit) is given by:

    = 10 0 - 2 X

    1

    The function showing the cost of production (total

    private cost) incorporates the notion that the amount

    of pollutant emitted per unit of output can be re-

    duced, at some cost. In accordance with the assump-

    tions of our example, assume that the least costly

    way to produce good X is to emit 10 units of pollut-

    ant per unit of X produced. The cost function then

    reflects both the cost of producing more output, hold-

    ing emissions per unit constant, and the cost of de-

    creasing emissions per unit, holding output constant.

    2

    where j is a positive parameter, EQ is 10 in this

    example, and E is the amount of emissions per uni

    of output that firms actually produce. Since j is

    assumed to be positive, firms minimize their cos

    of producing any given quantity of output by emit

    ting E =

    EQ

    units of pollutant per unit of X pro

    duced, if there is no tax on pollution, and no

    regulation of pollution. Thus, if the firms in this

    example were unregulated, they would emit 10 units

    of pollutant per unit of X produced.

    Since the supply curve in an unregulated com-

    petitive market is the Marginal Private Cost

    and since firms minimize their cost by emitting

    E = Eo of pollutant per unit of output, the relevan

    TPC = X- and the MPC = 2 x.

    nregulated quilibrium

    Given the information provided, it is a simple

    matter to calculate the market equilibrium quantity

    and price, along with the total extemal damage

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    3/8

    The results are as follows:

    p = 50, X = 25, CS = 625, PS = 625, TED =

    75 25 = 1875, NSB = -6 2 5 , and DW L = 703.125.

    DWL is anived at by calculating the area between

    the MSC curve and the MSB (demand) curve over

    the difference in quantity between the unregulated

    equilibrium quantity and the socially efficient quan-

    tity. The socially efficient quantity, given that each

    unit of output results in 10 units of pollution, each

    resulting in a damag e of 7.50, is the quantity at

    which the Marginal Social Cost (equal to MPC

    75) intersects the demand curve. In this exa

    that quantity is 6.25 units, so the

    DW L = 0.5 (25 - 6.25) (125 - 50) = 703

    (See Fig. 1)

    2. Simple Pigovian Tax

    Since each unit of the good prod uced results

    extem al dam age of 75 , a simple Pigovian ta

    125

    87.5

    75

    50

    12.5

    MSC = MPC + MED

    Simple Pigovian

    Tax = 75 per unit

    MPC

    D = MPB

    MSB

    6.25 25

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    4/8

    of $75 perunit corrects theextemality

    Itresultsin amarket equilibrium priceof

    aquantityof6.25 units. At that quantity,

    = 75 -hMPC= $87.50= P = MSB.At

    CS = PS =$39.0625, while Tax

    =Total Extemal Damage=$468.75. Net

    =CS -I- PS -I- Tax Revenue- Total

    =

    $78.125. There

    is no

    Dead-

    theequilibrium is at theinter-

    of MSC and MSB, and the increase in

    theimposition of the tax is

    was thesizeof theDWL in the

    It would bepossible to

    intotal extemal damage exceeds the reduction

    andproducer surpluses by$703.125.

    1)

    This is the standard story one might expect to see

    a textbook treatment of aPigovian taxthatis

    to correct anextemality.' Thestory allows

    to see anumber of important points:

    inthe presenceofa negative production extemal-

    anunregulated competitive market will produce

    ofthe good, because theproducersof

    notreflect) all of thecostsofproducingthe

    2) ifthe extemal costs are broughttobear on

    (by

    imposing

    a

    tax equal

    to

    oneither buyersor

    themarketcan beinduced toproducethe

    3)usually,theefficient quantity

    isnot zerorather,it is the

    atwhich the last unit produced hasavalue

    to thefull (private

    of

    it.Authors often note that thisis asim-

    of the tme story, since it implicitly

    the

    amount

    of

    pollutant emitted

    per

    ofthe good produced cannot be changed. (See,

    etal (2005, 214-16), and

    saythat, because

    ofpollution emissionscan bechanged,

    inprinciple,todeal with the problem

    is to tax thepollutantdi-

    notext-

    Ihave found attemptstomodel how costsof

    theamount of pollutant

    per

    unit

    is

    reduced. Nor does any textbook

    amodel orexample that allows thecom-

    all authors (forexample, seeAnderson, Gmber

    Hyman, Ulbrich, andWaldman) simply moveon

    to thedi.scussion of how a firm would react to

    an emissions fee and other approaches to controlling

    emissions (suchasemission standardsandtradabl

    emission permits).

    3

    A Tax on Pollution Emissions

    Wecan use themodel introduced aboveto ex

    amine how a tax on pollution emissions would

    work. Wealready know that thedamage caused

    per unitofemissionsisrepresentedbythe parame

    ter/($7.50, in this example).Ifa firmisassessed

    taxof$7.50perunitofpollutant emitted, itwil

    reduceE(the amountofpollutant emittedperuni

    of output)aslongas thesaving inemission taxe

    paid exceeds the increase in production cos

    entailed thereby.Itwill stop reducingEwhenth

    reduction in taxes due to reducing E by 1uni

    equals the increase in production cost due to reduc

    ingE by1 unit. The savingintaxes equalsT x (o

    $7.50

    X

    inthis case), while the increaseinprodu

    tion cost (the negative

    of

    the partial derivative

    o

    TPC with respecttoE)is:

    2-j-(Eo-E)-x.

    3

    The optimal amountof E isthus whereT = 2

    j

    Q

    -E). (Thex'scancel.) The optimalE forfirm

    to emit isthus E* = 10 - (T/(2j)). Tokeepthe

    computations simple,

    I

    selected

    a

    value

    of j =

    0.536, resultingin avalueofE*of3.0. Therefore

    in my example, firms faced with an emissionfeeo

    $7.50 per unitofpollutant they emit would choos

    to reduce the emissionsperunitofoutput from1

    to3. Of course, this results in higher totaland

    marginal production costs

    for

    firms. Given

    a re

    duction of emissions from 10 perunit to 3 pe

    unit, themarginal costofproducing more outpu

    (the partial derivative ofTPC with respect to x

    becomes

    MPCx =

    (0.536)-(7^)-2-x-t-26.264 (4

    Recall, however, that the firms are paying the gov

    emment $7.50perunitofpollutant emitted. Sinc

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    5/8

    the firms are paying $22.50 to the govemment, per

    unit of output produced, in addition to the produc-

    tion cost. W hen that co st is included , the height of

    the supply curve becomes 2 x + 26.264 + 22.5 =

    2 X + 48.764. This is the full MC (including tax)

    that firms incur to prod uce X . It is the ind ustry

    supply curve, in the presence of the emissions fee,

    and the intersection of this curve with the demand

    curve gives the market equilibrium.

    Given the parameters of our example, this equi-

    librium is as follows: P = $74.382, output =

    12.809, TSB = TPB = $1116.829, TD = Tax

    Reven ue = $28 8.56 1, Total Private (production)

    Cost = $500.12 7, NSB = CS + PS + Tax Reve-

    nue - TD = $32 8.141 1. (See Fig. 2)

    4 Com parison of an Em ission Fee with

    Simple Pigovian Tax

    Note that the output of the good, consu

    surplus, producer surplus and net social be

    are all greater than they were whe n the unr

    lated amoun t of pollution per unit of good X

    used to determine the simple Pigovian tax. W

    no govemment intervention, the least costly

    to produce X was to emit 10 units of pollutan

    unit of X p roduc ed. That resulted in an exte

    dam age of $75 per unit of X produced. If

    govemment responds by imposing a $75 tax

    each unit produced, firms have no incentiv

    reduce the amount of pollutant they emit, per

    1

    74 382

    63 132

    5

    48 764

    26 264

    Equilibrium

    with emission

    fee

    MSC = MPC + MED = MPC + T =

    26.264 + 2-x + 22.5 = 48.764 + 2-x

    MPC - 26.264 + 2-x

    (when E is reduced from 10 to 3)

    Equilibrium with command

    and control regulation

    S = M PC with no

    regulation

    Equilibrium with

    no regulation

    D = MPB =

    MSB

    12.809 18.434 25 50

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    6/8

    X produced. The equilibrium in the market is

    the price per unitof X is $75 higher

    the marginal cost of production. This occurs

    is 6.25,price is$87.50,and the mar-

    of

    production

    is

    $12.50.

    By way of

    is

    taxed directly,

    via an

    fee of

    $7.50

    per

    unit

    of

    pollution, firms

    to

    reduce

    E

    from

    10 per

    unit

    X to

    per

    unit

    of X,

    since

    the

    marginal cost

    to

    firms

    is less than $7.50 per unit

    for emission levels higher than 3 per

    of X. When the simple Pigovian tax was

    all of the correction for the pollution

    had to come in the form of reduced

    of X. When the emission fee was

    of the correction camein the form

    the emissions per unitof X. The rest

    in the

    form

    of

    reduced output.

    The net ef-

    was simultaneously to reduce the amount of

    62.5 units to 38.43 units)

    the amount of X produced (from

    to 12.809).

    NSBislarger withtheemissionfeethan withthe

    taxbecause,up to apoint, reducing

    eE (theamountofpollution emittedperunitof X

    isless costlyto society than reducingthe

    of X produced, while holding E constant.

    fee

    allows market participants

    to

    One might argue that

    a

    well-designed output

    tax

    the

    same result

    as an

    emission

    fee.

    is, ifeach producerof X were confronted with

    the tax on itsoutput would

    the amount of pollutant that firm

    perunit of X produced, then firms would

    toreducetheamountof pollutant emit-

    d perunitof X,justas in theemission fee case.

    the

    output

    tax

    would

    in

    that case actually

    an emission fee. (This appears to be whatSti-

    has in mind.) Real woridout-

    do notappearto be calculated thatway.

    at theamount of pollution actu-

    per unit of output to determine the

    tax.

    5 .

    omparing

    an

    Emission

    ee to

    ommand

    and

    ontrol

    reduce emissions from 10 per unit of X to 3 pe

    unitof X (theefficient amo unt of emission reduc

    tion, given the cost function and the margina

    damage per unit of pollution). In that case, the

    industry supply curve would

    be

    given

    by the mar

    ginal production cost curve

    (MC =

    26.264

    -f 2x)

    The equilibrium quantity would

    be

    18.434,

    and

    the price would

    be

    $63.132. Since

    the

    efficien

    quantity

    is

    12.809, there

    is a

    deadweight loss

    equal to$63.281. The apparatus used in this note

    allows us to see how much more efficient an

    emission fee is than direct control, even if firms

    do not differ in their marginal cost functions and

    even if the govem ment could, somehow, deter

    mine the proper amount of reduction in E fo

    firms to undertake. If firms were subsidized to

    reduce emissions, the deadweight loss would be

    even greater. ' '

    IV. Conclusion

    Many authors introducetheanalysisof negative

    production extemalities

    by

    examining

    a tax on the

    output

    of

    polluting firms, what

    I

    have called

    a

    simple Pigovian

    tax.

    Most then point

    out

    tha

    taxing pollution directly

    is

    more efficient than

    tax

    ing output andproceed todiscuss anem ission fee

    along with command and control regulation and

    tradable permits. No attempt is made in the text

    books to show how and why an emission fee i

    more efficient than an output tax. This note ha

    presented a simple numerical example that allow

    the welfare effects of the two approaches to be

    easily compared. It also allows studentsto see eas

    ilywhy a govemment policy of ordering firms to

    reducethepollution intensityof their output would

    be less efficient than theemissionfee.

    Notes

    1. M ore thorough treatmentsof this storyare giv

    enbyCallan/Thom as (2000, 79-8 6and 92) an

    by Besanko/Braeutigan (2005, 638-47).

    2.

    Ho lcombe explicitly asks, W hat should b

    taxed?

    He then argues verbally and graphi

    cally that taxing pollution directly results in a

    more efficient outcome.

    His

    Figure

    4.2 (p. 74

    is similar

    to my

    Figure

    2.

    However ,

    he

    doe

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    7/8

    3 .

    Nichols (1984, 27 -29 ) reaches similar con-

    clusions using a simplified diagrammatic

    approach with constant marginal costs. His

    treatment does not contain an explicit algebra-

    ic model showing how firms adjust the amount

    of pollution emitted per unit of output in re-

    sponse to a tax on emissions.

    References

    Anderson, John E. 2 003 .

    Public Finance.

    Boston:

    Houghton Mifflin.

    Besanko, David, and Ronald R. Braeutigam. 2005.

    Microeconomics, 2 * ed. New York: Wiley.

    Callan, Scott J. and Janet M. Thomas. 2000.

    Envi-

    ronmental Economics and Managem ent, 2 ^

    ed.

    Eon Wonh: Dryden.

    Erank, Roben H. and Ben S. Bemanke. 2007.

    Principles of Econo mics, 3* ed. New Y ork :

    McGraw-Hill Irwin.

    Gruber, Jonathan. 2007.

    Public Finance and P ub-

    lic Policy,

    2 ' ' ed. New Y ork: Worth.

    Holcombe, Randall. 2006.Public Sector Economics.

    Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall.

    Hyman, David N. 2008. Public F inance, 9

    Mason, OH: Thomson South-Westem.

    it h

    ed.

    Kahn, James R. 2005. The Economic Approac

    Environmental and Natural Resources, 3*

    Mason, OH: Thomson South-Westem.

    Keohane, Nathaniel O. and Sheila M. Olms

    2007 . Markets and the Environment.

    Was

    ton, D.C: Island Press.

    Mankiw, N. Gregory . 2007.

    Principles of

    nomics, 4* ed. Mason, OH: Thomson S

    Wes tem.

    Nichols, Albert L. 1984.

    Targeting Economic I

    tives for Environm ental Protection.

    Cambr

    MA: MIT Press.

    Steineman, Anne C , W illiam C. Apgar

    H. James Brown. 2005. Microeconomics

    Public Decisions. Mason, OH: Thom son S

    Wes tem.

    Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2000.

    Economics of the P

    Sector,

    3'^''

    ed. New Y ork: Norton.

    Tietenberg, Tom. 2003 .Environmental and N a

    Resource Economics, 6 ^ ed. B oston: Add

    Wesley.

    Ulbrich, Holly. 2 003 .

    Public Finance in Th

    and Practice.

    Mason, OH : Thom son S

    Wes tem.

    Waldman, Don E. 2004.

    M icroeconomics.

    Bo

    Pearson Addison Wesley.

  • 8/10/2019 Simple Pigovian Taxes vs. Emission Eees to Control Negative

    8/8

    Copyright of American Economist is the property of American Economist and its content may not be copied or

    emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission.

    However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.