southern methodist university - international cross-listing ......∗lel is from the federal reserve...

41
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXIII, NO. 4 AUGUST 2008 International Cross-Listing, Firm Performance, and Top Management Turnover: A Test of the Bonding Hypothesis UGUR LEL and DARIUS P. MILLER ABSTRACT We examine a primary outcome of corporate governance, namely, the ability to iden- tify and terminate poorly performing CEOs, to test the effectiveness of U.S. investor protections in improving the corporate governance of cross-listed firms. We find that firms from weak investor protection regimes that are cross-listed on a major U.S. Ex- change are more likely to terminate poorly performing CEOs than non-cross-listed firms. Cross-listings on exchanges that do not require the adoption of stringent in- vestor protections (OTC, private placements, and London listings) are not associated with a higher propensity to remove poorly performing CEOs. DOES CROSS-LISTING IN THE UNITED STATES IMPROVE the corporate governance of foreign firms? The “bonding hypothesis” proposed by Coffee (1999, 2002) and Stulz (1999) predicts that after listing on a major U.S. stock exchange, foreign firms become subject to stringent U.S. investor protections that constrain in- siders from expropriating minority shareholders. Because this hypothesis has important implications for the effectiveness of U.S. laws and enforcement as well as the efficacy of market-based approaches in improving global corporate governance, it has attracted the recent attention of academics and practitioners alike. To date, empirical support for the bonding hypothesis is principally drawn from the large literature that examines the economic consequences of cross- listing in the United States. 1 However, as Leuz (2006) notes, the evidence in many of these studies is fairly indirect, as it is difficult to attribute the economic consequences of cross-listing directly to the bonding hypothesis because many Lel is from the Federal Reserve Board and Miller is from Edwin L. Cox School of Business at Southern Methodist University. We thank an anonymous referee and associate editor; Campbell Harvey (the editor); Mark Carey, Craig Doidge, Art Durnev, Nandini Gupta, David Mauer, Chip Ryan, Chester Spatt, and Wendy Wilson; and seminar participants at the 2006 University of North Carolina GIA Conference, the 2006 University of Oregon Corporate Finance Conference, the 2006 Financial Research Association Conference, the 2006 Utah Winter Finance Conference, Louisiana State University, and the University of Texas at Dallas. We thank Bill Megginson and Meghanna Ayyagari for data access and Charles Murry and Laurel Nguyen for excellent research assistance. This paper represents the authors’ opinions and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Board. All errors are the sole responsibility of the authors. 1 Karolyi (1998, 2006) and Benos and Weisbach (2004) provide comprehensive surveys. We also discuss the literature in Section II of this paper. 1897

Upload: others

Post on 09-Feb-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE • VOL. LXIII, NO. 4 • AUGUST 2008

    International Cross-Listing, Firm Performance,and Top Management Turnover: A Test of the

    Bonding Hypothesis

    UGUR LEL and DARIUS P. MILLER∗

    ABSTRACT

    We examine a primary outcome of corporate governance, namely, the ability to iden-tify and terminate poorly performing CEOs, to test the effectiveness of U.S. investorprotections in improving the corporate governance of cross-listed firms. We find thatfirms from weak investor protection regimes that are cross-listed on a major U.S. Ex-change are more likely to terminate poorly performing CEOs than non-cross-listedfirms. Cross-listings on exchanges that do not require the adoption of stringent in-vestor protections (OTC, private placements, and London listings) are not associatedwith a higher propensity to remove poorly performing CEOs.

    DOES CROSS-LISTING IN THE UNITED STATES IMPROVE the corporate governance offoreign firms? The “bonding hypothesis” proposed by Coffee (1999, 2002) andStulz (1999) predicts that after listing on a major U.S. stock exchange, foreignfirms become subject to stringent U.S. investor protections that constrain in-siders from expropriating minority shareholders. Because this hypothesis hasimportant implications for the effectiveness of U.S. laws and enforcement aswell as the efficacy of market-based approaches in improving global corporategovernance, it has attracted the recent attention of academics and practitionersalike.

    To date, empirical support for the bonding hypothesis is principally drawnfrom the large literature that examines the economic consequences of cross-listing in the United States.1 However, as Leuz (2006) notes, the evidence inmany of these studies is fairly indirect, as it is difficult to attribute the economicconsequences of cross-listing directly to the bonding hypothesis because many

    ∗Lel is from the Federal Reserve Board and Miller is from Edwin L. Cox School of Business atSouthern Methodist University. We thank an anonymous referee and associate editor; CampbellHarvey (the editor); Mark Carey, Craig Doidge, Art Durnev, Nandini Gupta, David Mauer, ChipRyan, Chester Spatt, and Wendy Wilson; and seminar participants at the 2006 University of NorthCarolina GIA Conference, the 2006 University of Oregon Corporate Finance Conference, the 2006Financial Research Association Conference, the 2006 Utah Winter Finance Conference, LouisianaState University, and the University of Texas at Dallas. We thank Bill Megginson and MeghannaAyyagari for data access and Charles Murry and Laurel Nguyen for excellent research assistance.This paper represents the authors’ opinions and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Board.All errors are the sole responsibility of the authors.

    1 Karolyi (1998, 2006) and Benos and Weisbach (2004) provide comprehensive surveys. We alsodiscuss the literature in Section II of this paper.

    1897

  • 1898 The Journal of Finance

    theories of cross-listing have similar economic predictions.2 Moreover, the va-lidity of the bonding hypothesis has been called into question by a number ofrecent studies that document cross-listed firms’ lack of compliance with certainU.S. laws and the low number of enforcement actions by U.S. legal institutions(see, for example, Siegel (2005) and Lang, Raedy, and Wilson (2006)). Therefore,whether U.S. securities laws and regulations improve the corporate governanceof cross-listed firms is under debate as the nascent empirical evidence is pre-dominantly indirect and yields mixed results.

    In this paper we pursue a different approach in testing the bonding hypothe-sis and examine a direct outcome of corporate governance: the propensity toreplace poorly performing CEOs. We argue that if cross-listing actually re-sults in increased shareholder protections, we should be able to observe spe-cific outcomes that are consistent with improved corporate governance. Wefocus on the sensitivity of top executive turnover to performance since an ex-tensive body of international research shows that a necessary component ofeffective corporate governance is the ability to identify and replace poorly per-forming CEOs (see, for example, Kaplan (1994), Coffee (1999), Murphy (1999),Volpin (2002), Dahya, McConnell, and Travlos (2002), Gibson (2003), DeFondand Hung (2004)). We compile a database of 70,976 firm-year observations from47 countries from 1992 to 2003 to test the hypothesis that CEOs of cross-listedfirms are more likely to face termination when firm performance is poor. We findthat the relation between CEO turnover and poor performance is stronger forcross-listed firms than non-cross-listed firms, and that the stronger turnover topoor performance relation for cross-listed firms is concentrated in firms listedon major U.S. exchanges (for example, Level 2 and 3 American depositary re-ceipts (ADRs)). Firms that list in the over-the-counter (OTC) market (Level 1),conduct private placements (Rule 144a), or even list in London do not have asignificantly different relation between CEO turnover and performance fromnon-cross-listed firms. Further, we find that the increased relation betweenCEO turnover and poor performance for cross-listed firms is strongest in coun-tries with weak investor protections. Overall, our results are consistent withthe hypothesis that U.S. securities laws and regulations improve the corporategovernance of cross-listed firms.

    We also investigate several alternative explanations for our results, includ-ing the potential endogeneities that arise in a study of cross-listing and gover-nance due to the nonrandom nature of the decision to list in the United States.For example, we investigate if our results are due to the notion that better-governed firms are the ones that self-select to cross-list. To do so, we examineseveral specifications that measure the sensitivity of CEO turnover to perfor-mance for cross-listed firms prior to cross-listing. These tests show that therelation of turnover to performance is insignificant (significant) in the pre-cross-listed (post-cross-listed) period, which suggests that our results are notan artifact of the pre-cross-listed governance status of our sample firms. We

    2 For further details on other theories that have been argued to generate similar predictions(e.g., market segmentation, investor recognition, increased liquidity, and better information) seethe discussion in Doidge, Karolyi, and Stulz (2004a) and Hail and Leuz (2004).

  • International Cross-Listing 1899

    also examine if other potential control changes around cross-listing such asprivatizations, changes in ownership, M&A events, and changes in the com-position of board of directions can explain our results. We find that our re-sults remain robust to these events. Further, we examine if cross-listing in-duces top management to leave their jobs to pursue employment in the UnitedStates where they are likely to be more highly compensated or if cross-listedfirms terminate poorly performing management because they are able to ac-cess a more international pool of top-management candidates. We find thatfirms that change CEOs tend to replace them with managers from their do-mestic labor pool and that departing CEOs most often get jobs in the localmarket. Therefore, shifts in the labor market also do not appear to explain ourresults.

    We subject our tests to a battery of firm- and county-level robustness testsas well. We find our results are robust to country, industry, and year fixedeffects in addition to the possible entrenchment effects of concentrated owner-ship structures. Our findings are also robust when we exclude countries thatcontain the largest portion of our sample, remove observations surroundingthe Asian financial crises, and omit financial and regulated industries. An im-portant methodological note is that all of our analyses control for the recentlyrecognized difficulty in implementing and interpreting interaction effects innonlinear models (see, for example, Ai and Norton, (2003)).

    Our results advance the literature in several ways. First, our findings addto the debate on whether U.S. securities laws and enforcement are effective inreaching non-U.S. firms. Second, by showing that CEOs of cross-listed firmsare more likely to face termination when firm performance is poor, our resultsalso contribute to the literature by documenting a specific channel throughwhich cross-listing improves corporate behavior, something that is not well-documented in the literature.3 Finally, our findings also have implications forthe growing literature that examines how global corporate governance can beimproved (see, for example, LaPorta et al. (2000) and Coffee (2002)). This re-search stems from a large number of studies that show that the economic conse-quences for firms located in countries with poor investor protections are severe.4

    Given the economic impact of poor investor protections and the correspondingdifficulty in changing a country’s legal structure (i.e., legal convergence), an im-portant question is whether market-based approaches (i.e., functional conver-gence), such as opting-in to a better legal system via cross-listing, can improvecorporate governance. Our finding that cross-listing in the United States is as-sociated with improved corporate governance is consistent with the hypothesisthat the functional convergence of legal systems to a higher global standard ispossible.

    The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section I discusses relatedliterature. Section II describes the data. Section III presents the research de-sign. Section IV shows the results and Section V presents robustness tests.Section VI concludes.

    3 See, for example, the discussion in Leuz (2006).4 See, for example, LLSV (1997, 1998) as well as the survey by Beck and Levine (2004).

  • 1900 The Journal of Finance

    I. Related Literature

    The bonding hypothesis of Coffee (1999) and Stulz (1999) posits that firmscross-listed on a major U.S. stock exchange have better corporate governancethan non-cross-listed firms from the same country, ceteris paribus, since cross-listed firms are subject to strong U.S. investor protections.5 For example, cross-listed firms on U.S. exchanges must adhere to U.S. disclosure practices, whichrequire them to reconcile their net income and shareholder’s equity to U.S.generally accepted accounting principle (GAAP), disclose the identity of ma-jority shareholders (10% or greater), and follow detailed procedures duringtender offers and going private transactions. These firms are also subject tofar-reaching U.S. investor protection laws such as the Foreign Corrupt Prac-tices Act and, more recently, the Sarbanes Oxley Act. Cross-listed firms arealso subject to punishment by U.S. law enforcement, both by the Securitiesand Exchange Commission (SEC) as well as private investor law suits, andto increased scrutiny from intermediaries such as financial analysts and debt-rating agencies.6 In contrast, listing on the OTC market or conducting a privateplacement allows substantial exemptions from these laws and regulations.7

    Specifically, the bonding hypothesis predicts that, ceteris paribus: (1) cross-listed firms will have better corporate governance than non-cross-listed firms,(2) the difference in governance between cross-listed firms and non-cross-listedfirms will be greatest in the countries with the weakest investor protections,and (3) cross-listings that require the most stringent U.S. investor protections(i.e., on the NYSE, AMEX, or NASDAQ) will have the largest differences incorporate governance. In this way, cross-listing in the United States representsa market-based approach to increased investor protection.

    While in theory a cross-listing in the United States should lead to more ef-fective corporate governance, the ability of a cross-listing to serve as a bondingmechanism is under debate. On the one hand, several empirical studies exam-ine the economic impact of cross-listing in the United States and find evidencethat is consistent with the bonding hypothesis. This line of research finds thatcross-listed firms from weak investor protection countries have larger stock-price reactions (Foerster and Karolyi (1999), Miller (1999)), higher valuation(Mitton (2002), Doidge, Karolyi, and Stulz (2004a)), more scrutiny by financialanalysts (Baker, Nofsinger, and Weaver (2002), Lang, Lins, and Miller (2003)),lower cost of capital (Errunza and Miller (2000), Hail and Leuz (2004)), bet-ter information environments (Bailey, Karolyi, and Salva (2005)), lower votingpremiums (Doidge (2004)), and more access to external finance (Reese andWeisbach (2002), Lins, Strickland, and Zenner (2005)). However, ascribing theevidence contained in many of these studies directly to the bonding hypothesis

    5 It is important to note that while firms may choose to cross-list for a variety of reasons, oncethey are listed they become subject to U.S. laws and regulations.

    6 Coffee (2002) calls these intermediaries “financial watchdogs.”7 For example, these firms are not required to register under the Exchange or Securities acts and

    are therefore exempt from most civil liability provisions and do not have to follow U.S. disclosurepractices (Doidge (2004)).

  • International Cross-Listing 1901

    is difficult given the well-known challenge in distinguishing among the varioustheories of cross-listing and the endogeneity issues inherent to this literature.8

    On the other hand, the evidence in several recent studies suggests bondingvia cross-listing in the United States is ineffective. For example, Siegel (2005)finds that the SEC and minority shareholders have rarely enforced U.S. lawsagainst cross-listed firms and Lang, Raedy, and Wilson (2006) find that the ac-counting data of cross-listed firms from weak investor protection environmentsare of lower quality even though cross-listed firms are required to follow nom-inally similar accounting standards as U.S. firms. However, the approaches inthese papers are not without their drawbacks, as Coffee (2002) and Benos andWeisbach (2004) suggest that measuring the incidence of legal actions may un-derstate the deterrent benefit of laws, and Leuz (2006) argues that disclosurequality differences between cross-listed and U.S. firms may not be clear evi-dence against bonding as cross-listed firms are allowed considerable discretionin preparing their financial statements to U.S. GAAP.

    Another challenge researchers face when testing the bonding hypothesis isthat it is often difficult to assess the quality of governance from observed mech-anisms of governance because governance mechanisms often substitute or com-plement one another, a finding that Doidge, Karolyi, and Stulz (2004b) empha-size is dependant on the extent of a country’s investor protections. Further, thisissue is likely to be exacerbated for cross-listed firms, given the many financialand regulatory changes that take place around a listing (see, for example, Lang,Lins, and Miller (2003, 2004)).

    In this paper, rather than calculating the stock-price consequences, legal en-forcement incidents, or changes in governance mechanisms around a cross-listing to infer improvements in investor protections, we measure a directoutcome of corporate governance: the propensity to replace poorly perform-ing CEOs. Why CEO turnover? Replacing poorly performing CEOs is arguedto be a necessary condition for good corporate governance (Shleifer and Vishny(1989, 1997)) and the sensitivity of top executive turnover to performance as ameasure of the quality of corporate governance has been supported by a largenumber of studies in the United States and abroad, including recent researchby Dahya et. al (2002), DeFond and Hung (2004), Gibson (2003), and Volpin(2002).9

    II. Sample Selection and Descriptive Statistics

    A. Sample Selection

    Our empirical analysis consists of three main parts. First, we investigatewhether the sensitivity of top executive turnover to poor firm performance ishigher for cross-listed firms. In these tests we differentiate cross-listings bytype in order to test whether cross-listings on major U.S. exchanges, which re-quire the strongest governance provisions, have the largest effect. Second, we

    8 For example, Sarkissian and Schill (2006) argue that valuation gains to cross-listing aretransitory.

    9 For U.S.-based studies see Hermalin and Weisbach (2003) and citations contained therein.

  • 1902 The Journal of Finance

    test if the effect of bonding is greatest for firms that are located in the countrieswith the weakest investor protection laws. We do so by examining the sensi-tivity of top executive turnover to poor firm performance across legal originsand investor protection laws. Finally, we conduct a battery of tests designedto gauge the robustness of our results by examining the sensitivity of top ex-ecutive turnover to poor firm performance in the pre-cross-listing period, theeffect of other potential governance changes concurrent with cross-listing, theexclusion of turnover that occurs in the list year, and the departing and en-tering CEOs’ work history. We also rerun our tests excluding countries thatcontain the largest portion of our sample firms, omitting firms with large blockownership, removing observations surrounding the Asian financial crisis, andexcluding financial and regulated firms.

    To execute this analysis, we gather data on executive turnover and firm per-formance between 1992 and 2003 from the Worldscope database.10 The initialsample consists of approximately 38,000 firms from 59 countries. We excludefirms with missing firm-specific financial and executive data, firms with noidentifiable top manager, and firms located in countries with missing legal en-vironment data. We also exclude U.S. firms as the bonding hypothesis predictsdifferences between cross-listed and non-cross-listed firms, rather than differ-ences between cross-listed and U.S. firms (see, for example, Leuz (2006)). Fi-nally, we exclude firms that are reported in the Worldscope database only oncebecause we need at least two consecutive years of nonmissing data on com-pany officers and their titles to compute CEO turnover. The resulting sampleincludes 70,976 firm-year observations of 19,091 firms from 47 countries over1992–2003. Every country in our final sample except Zimbabwe has at least onecross-listed firm in the United States . A breakdown of the sample distributionacross countries, cross-listing status, and years is reported in Table I.

    We obtain the list of cross-listed firms using several sources including theBank of New York, Citibank, NYSE, and Nasdaq and verify the listing datesusing Lexis–Nexis searches, Form 20-F, etc. Exchange-traded cross-listings aredenoted as Level 2/3, over-the-counter cross-listings as Level 1, and privateplacements as Rule 144a. The data set also takes into account ADR programupgrades, such as from a Level 1 to a Level 2 program, and delistings fromthe U.S. market. We also include direct listings. Most notably, Canadian firmslist their shares on U.S. exchanges directly without issuing ADRs . Given thatthe increased disclosure and securities law provisions required in listing on amajor U.S. exchange are functionally equivalent for ADRs and direct listings,we classify Canadian firms that are traded on both a Canadian and a majorU.S. exchange as Level 2/3 ADRs. However, the exclusion of Canadian firmsfrom the sample does not change our conclusions.

    We follow DeFond and Hung (2004) and use the titles CEO, Chief ExecutiveOfficer, and Chief Executive to identify the top manager in each firm. However,

    10 We use a total of 37 Worldscope CDROMs during our sample period. Because of delays byfirms in releasing information and Worldscope’s backfilling procedure, Worldscope indicated to usthat multiple CDROMs from each year should be used as they often contain different numbers offirms.

  • International Cross-Listing 1903

    Table IDescriptive Statistics

    This table presents the distribution of the sample used in the regression analysis by country,cross-listing status, and year, and descriptive statistics for the main firm-level variables. Panel Adescribes the number of observations, number of firms, and CEO turnover percentage across coun-tries. Panel B presents the distribution of the sample over time. Panel C displays the distributionof the sample by cross-listing status. Panel D presents the summary statistics for the sample usedin the regression analysis. The last column in Panel D reports the median differences of the firmperformance variables between the CEO turnover and nonturnover observations and the relatedresults from a nonparametric test on the equality of medians. CL dummy is 1 if the firm cross-listsin the United States, 0 otherwise. Level 2/3 dummy is 1 if the firm has a Level 2 or Level 3 ADRprogram, 0 otherwise. Level 1 dummy is 1 if the firm has a Level 1 ADR program, 0 otherwise. Rule144A dummy is 1 if the firm has a Rule 144A issuance, 0 otherwise. Lagged Earnings Ratio is the1-year lagged ratio of earnings before interest and taxes to total assets. Lagged Excess Returns isthe 1-year lagged total stock returns in excess of the country average. Total Assets is measured inmillion $U.S. ∗∗∗ indicates significance at the 1% level.

    Panel A: By Country

    Country No of Obs. No of Firms CEO Turnover %

    Argentina 36 18 25.00Australia 2,463 1,001 15.79Austria 530 160 15.09Belgium 711 187 14.21Brazil 348 155 11.78Canada 3,455 1,011 19.28Chile 473 152 18.39China 276 170 19.57Colombia 3 3 33.33Czech Republic 83 42 15.66Denmark 1,146 283 14.22Finland 766 212 13.71France 3,200 1,019 12.25Germany 3,692 1,047 17.39Greece 517 216 15.28Hong Kong 2,028 797 16.18Hungary 114 36 19.30India 1,268 358 13.17Indonesia 1,090 324 24.13Ireland 418 93 14.83Israel 217 90 21.66Italy 1,192 318 18.04Japan 21,009 3,776 14.15Korea 1,704 675 38.40Luxembourg 59 18 15.25Malaysia 2,185 687 13.27Mexico 304 117 17.76Netherlands 1,034 305 19.05New Zealand 294 90 18.71Norway 356 110 18.82Pakistan 459 111 12.64Peru 87 43 24.14Philippines 674 205 20.47Poland 239 83 19.67

    (continued)

  • 1904 The Journal of Finance

    Table I—Continued

    Panel A: By Country

    Country No of Obs. No of Firms CEO Turnover %

    Portugal 152 62 9.21Singapore 1,304 429 17.02South Africa 1,210 450 16.28Spain 590 163 16.95Sri Lanka 37 14 8.11Sweden 1,359 420 18.91Switzerland 1,413 360 20.74Taiwan 1,241 423 25.56Thailand 898 269 18.04Turkey 316 124 15.19United Kingdom 9,981 2,448 14.59Venezuela 25 11 4.00Zimbabwe 20 6 25.00

    Panel B: By Year

    Year No of Obs. No of Firms CEO Turnover %

    1992 1,602 – 17.851993 4,081 – 17.741994 4,721 – 13.851995 5,369 – 11.511996 6,083 – 12.941997 6,790 – 13.781998 6,359 – 15.851999 6,893 – 14.842000 6,813 – 23.162001 7,712 – 19.852002 9,962 – 17.512003 4,591 – 14.75

    Panel C: By Cross-listing Status

    Cross-listing Status No of Obs. No of Firms CEO Turnover %

    Non-CL firms 65,563 17,729 16.06CL firms 5,413 1,362 19.18Level 2/3 2,088 609 21.50Level 1 2,494 565 16.92Rule 144A 801 188 20.22

    Total 70,976 19,091 16.30

    Panel D: Summary Statistics

    Turnover vs.5th 95th Nonturnover

    N Mean Median Percentile Percentile (Medians)

    Lagged Earnings Ratio 70,976 0.218 0.052 −0.133 0.202 −0.006∗∗∗Lagged Excess Returns 62,333 −0.011 −0.079 −0.724 0.909 −0.030∗∗∗Total Assets 70,976 259,278 372.651 15.534 494,872 –

  • International Cross-Listing 1905

    many countries use other titles for top managers, which vary across and withincountries. We use two sources to determine the top manager in the rest of thesample. When available, we use the top manager titles used by DeFond andHung (2004) and Gibson (2003). For example, the titles CEO, Chief ExecutiveOfficer, Chief Executive, and President are used to identify the top managerin Argentina. We exclude firms in which the top manager title is shared bytwo officers to prevent a split turnover (Gibson (2003)). For the remaining 15countries not covered in DeFond and Hung (2004) or Gibson (2003) (4.68% ofour sample), we use press accounts, country experts’ opinions, and manual datainspections of manager titles in each country to determine the top manager title.A list of top manager titles used in each country is displayed in the Appendix.11

    After the top manager in the firm is identified, we first compare the last namesand the first letter of first names of top managers of the firm over time todetermine whether there was a top manager replacement in any given year.We next hand-check CEO turnover events for the entire sample given thatDefond and Hung (2004) find that first names of managers do not consistentlyprecede their last names in several Asian countries such as Korea and Japan,and Worldscope infrequently contains typos on executive names for foreignfirms.

    As in DeFond and Hung (2004) and Gibson (2003), we do not know whether aCEO turnover event is voluntary (for example, due to retirement) because theWorldscope does not provide information on CEO age and tenure, and mediacoverage in English for the sample firms varies substantially across countries.Hermalin and Weisbach (2003) argue that voluntary turnover is unlikely to berelated to performance, and hence not distinguishing between voluntary andforced turnovers events leads to additional noise in the dependent variable,which only affects standard errors. Consistent with their assertion, the empir-ical evidence suggests a similar or more sensitive relationship between CEOturnover and performance for involuntary (forced) replacements (see, for exam-ple, Huson, Parrino, and Starks (2001), Dahya et al. (2002), and Kaplan andMinton (1994)). Therefore, we do not expect this data limitation to alter ourconclusions.

    B. Descriptive Statistics

    Panel A of Table I provides summary statistics for the sample based on afirm’s country of domicile. Turnover ranges from a low of 4% in Venezuela toa high of 38.4% in Korea, with an average of 16.30%. For comparison, overour sample period the U.S. turnover rate was 12.86%. Similar to other studiesthat employ the Worldscope database, there is a clustering of observations inJapan and United Kingdom. Although our analysis is based on fixed countryeffects to ensure we are comparing CEO turnover differences within countries,in robustness tests reported later in the paper we remove observations fromJapan and the United Kingdom and find that our conclusions are unaffected.

    11 We use the terms CEO turnover and top manager turnover interchangeably.

  • 1906 The Journal of Finance

    Panel B of Table I shows turnover by year, which ranges from a low of 11.51% in1995 to a high of 23.16% in 2000. Panel C of Table I presents turnover by cross-listing status. The panel indicates that cross-listed firms have higher CEOturnover than non-cross-listed firms (19.18% vs. 16.06%). Of the cross-listedfirms, CEO turnover is greatest for Level 2/3 firms, followed by Rule 144a andthen Level 1 companies (21.50%, 16.92%, and 20.22%, respectively). Panel Cof Table I also shows that 1,362 foreign firms are identified as cross-listed inour sample, of which 609 are exchange-traded cross-listings (Level 2/3), 565are OTC cross-listings (Level 1), and 188 are private placements via Rule 144Aissuance (Rule 144a).

    We consider various measures of firm performance, including both operat-ing performance measures and stock-price-based measures. We augment stockprice data from Worldscope with data from Datastream International wherepossible. However, we expect the operating performance measures to be a bet-ter proxy in our international setting, as both Volpin (2002) and DeFond andHung (2004) find that stock returns are not related to CEO turnover in coun-tries whose markets are characterized by high stock-price synchronicity andilliquidity, attributes that make stock-price-based measures less informative.12

    For our main tests, we focus on the ratio of accounting earnings before inter-est and taxes (EBIT) to book value of assets (earnings ratio), and the total stockreturns in excess of the country average (excess returns). We follow DeFond andHung (2004) and Volpin (2002) and use EBIT among accounting-based firmperformance measures because it is not influenced by firms’ capital structurepolicies or by differential country-level tax regimes. Similar forms of both vari-ables are used extensively to proxy for firm performance in studies examiningthe sensitivity of CEO turnover to firm performance.13 We lag both performancevariables by 1 year to prevent a possible overlap of the replaced CEO’s perfor-mance with that of the new CEO. Panel D of Table 1 reports sample statisticsof the main performance measures and shows that the lagged performancemeasures are significantly lower in firm-years with CEO turnover than in non-turnover years. In terms of the depth of the sample, the mean (median) numberof years a firm is in our regression analysis is 3.84 (3) years.

    We also use sales growth and the change in EBIT to total assets as alterna-tive accounting-based measures of firm performance and obtain qualitativelysimilar results. In addition, we recompute our firm performance measures inwhich industry-adjusted performance is calculated as firm performance minusthe median value of the corresponding two-digit SIC global industry and obtainsimilar results.

    12 Harvey (1995) shows that first-order autocorrelations in emerging markets are positive andsignificant and Lesmond (2005) finds that liquidity-related transactions costs in countries withweak legal institutions are higher than in markets with strong legal systems.

    13 See Huson et al. (2001), Mikkelson and Partch (1997), Gibson (2003), and Kang and Shivdasani(1995) for the accounting-based measure and Weisbach (1988), Kang and Shivdasani (1995), Defondand Hung (2004), Huson, Parrino, and Starks (2001), and Hadlock and Lumer (1997) for the stock-market-based measure.

  • International Cross-Listing 1907

    III. Research Design

    A. Empirical Model

    To test our hypothesis that CEO turnover is more sensitive to poor perfor-mance for exchange-traded cross-listed firms than non-cross-listed firms, weestimate a series of probit models that take the form:

    Pr (Turnover) = φ[α + β1(FirmPerformance)] + β2(L23)+ β12(L23∗FirmPerformance) + β3(L1)+ β13(L1∗FirmPerformance) + β4(R144A)+ β14(R144A∗FirmPerformance) + δX ] (1)

    where φ is the standard normal cumulative distribution, L23 refers to exchange-traded cross-listings, L1 refers to OTC cross-listings, R144A refers to privateplacements, and X is a set of firm control variables, country controls, industrycontrols, and year controls. Note that the cross-listed dummies are time-varyingin that they take the value of 1 in the cross-listing year and can switch back to0 if the firm delists or changes level of cross-listing.

    We follow previous research and measure turnover as a binary variable thattakes the value 1 if the top manager is changed in that year. We include firmsize measured as the natural logarithm of the book value of total assets inmillions of U.S. dollars. In the regression analysis, we winsorize the continuousvariables at the 1% level for each country.

    It is also important to note that throughout our analysis, we include coun-try fixed effects that ensure we are measuring within-country differencesbetween cross-listed and non-cross-listed firms as well as controlling for un-observed country effects. In addition, we include industry dummies using thetwo-digit SIC code to control for global industry-wide factors that may affectCEO turnover and firm performance. Finally, our regressions include indica-tor variables for each year. Our regressions also correct the standard errorsfor possible serial correlation and heteroskedasticity by clustering at the firmlevel.

    We test our second hypothesis, which posits that the difference in the sensitiv-ity of top management turnover to performance between cross-listed firms andnon-cross-listed firms is greatest in the countries with the weakest corporategovernance, by classifying countries into strong and weak investor protectionregimes and comparing coefficients across samples. Alternatively, a randomcountry effects specification could be employed with interaction effects, but inour sample this is inappropriate as it fails the Hausman specification test. Wefocus on three country-level measures of investor protection. The first measure,from La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (LLSV) (1997, 1998), iswhether the home country has an English legal origin, which is an overallmeasure of strong investor protections. Following Djankov et al. (2005) we usethe anti-director rights index (ADRI), which is a revised version of the originalADRI index from LLSV (1997) that addresses the coding concerns expressed

  • 1908 The Journal of Finance

    in Pagano and Volpin (2005) and Spamann (2006). The ADRI represents thedegree of minority shareholder protection. We also use the anti-self-dealingindex from Djankov et al. (2005), which measures how difficult it is for minor-ity shareholders to thwart the consumption of private benefits by controllingshareholders. Djankov et al. (2005) argue that self-dealing is the central prob-lem of corporate governance in most countries. In unreported tests, we alsoexamine other country-level measures of investor protection from LLSV (1998)and La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes, and Shleifer (LLS) (2006), such as the ruleof law, burden of proof, disclosure, and private law enforcement indexes. In allinstances, our results are consistent across every measure of high versus lowinvestor protection. Further, the results are robust to using Spamann’s (2006)ADRI.

    B. Interpretation of Interactions in Probit Models

    Recent research by Ai and Norton (2003) and Powers (2005) emphasizes thedifficulty present in interpreting interactions in nonlinear models. Strikingly,the interaction effect cannot be evaluated by looking at the sign, magnitude, orstatistical significance of the coefficient on the conventional interaction term.Ai and Norton (2003) show that the interaction effect is conditional on the inde-pendent variable, and therefore both the magnitude and statistical significanceof the interaction term can vary across observations. For example, in our probitspecification the correct marginal effect of a change in the interaction variablebetween the L23 dummy and firm performance is

    �∂F (u)

    ∂FirmPerformance�L23

    = (β1 + β12) ∗ φ[(β1 + β12) ∗ FirmPerformance + β2 + X δ]− β1 ∗ φ [β1 ∗ FirmPerformance + δX ] (2)

    where F (u) = Pr(Turnover), which is given by equation (1) and u denotes theregression specification. Equation (2) shows that the marginal effect of theinteraction variable may not be zero even when β12 is zero. Thus, the standardcoefficient on the interaction term may have an incorrect magnitude, standarderror, and even sign relative to the true interaction effect.

    To ensure our inferences are correct, we use the methodology developedby Norton, Wang, and Ai (2004) to compute the correct marginal effect of achange in the interaction variable between the respective cross-listed dummyand firm performance. We report both the marginal effects and their standarderrors and display the graphs of the distribution of marginal effects and theassociated z-statistics over the entire range of predicted probabilities for ourmain models. In tests where our inferences are unambiguous, we also sum-marize the range of corrected interactions by the mean interaction effect andits significance.

  • International Cross-Listing 1909

    IV. The Effect of Cross-Listing on CEO Turnover

    A. By Cross-Listing Type

    Table II presents a series of probit regressions that include interactionsbetween firm performance and cross-listing type to test the hypothesis thatcross-listed firms have a higher performance to turnover sensitivity than non-cross-listed firms. Model 1 reports the results for the accounting-based per-formance measure and Model 2 presents the results for the stock-price-basedperformance measure. All regression models include country, industry, and yearfixed effects as well as control for firm size.

    Model 1 shows that the interaction between Level 2/3 and lagged earningsratio is negative and significant (−0.332, t-statistic = −2.087). In contrast,OTC or Rule 144a cross-listings do not have a significantly higher propensityto terminate poorly performing CEOs than non-cross-listed firms’ interaction(coefficient = −0.120, t-statistic = −0.452 and −0.350, t-statistic = −0.675, re-spectively). This finding is consistent with the hypothesis that non-U.S. firmsadopting the strongest governance and reporting requirements by cross-listingin the United States observe outcomes consistent with improved governanceover similar firms that are not cross-listed in the United States. However,given the aforementioned problems with interpreting simple interaction termsin discrete choice models, we follow Ai and Norton (2003) and evaluate the cor-rected marginal effects and their significance at every predicted probability.Figure 1a shows that for major exchange-traded cross-listings, the correctedinteraction effects are overwhelmingly negative across the predicted probabil-ities, while Figure 1b shows that these interaction effects are also significant(less than −1.96) for most probabilities. We summarize the corrected inter-active effect and its significance in the last row of Table II by reporting themean interaction effect and its significance (−0.084, t-statistic = −2.082). Interms of economic significance, the absolute probability of replacing the CEOincreases by 1.34% for Level 2/3 ADRs when we move from the top quartileto the bottom quartile of firm performance. For OTC (Rule144a) cross-listings,the corrected interactive effects, presented in Figures 1c–f and summarizedin the bottom rows of Table II, further confirm that the interaction effectis rarely significant across the range of predicted probabilities (the mean-corrected effect is −0.030, t-statistic = −0.452, and −0.086, t-statistic = −0.667,respectively).

    For the control variables, we find that firm size is positively related to CEOturnover.14 Firm performance (lagged earnings ratio) is negative yet statisti-cally insignificant, a finding that is the result of pooling countries where firmperformance is unlikely to be used to evaluate management.15 The coefficienton L2/3 is positive, indicating that exchange cross-listed firms also have higher

    14 In the United States, size is generally thought to capture the effects of CEO and institutionalstock ownership, board composition, managerial depth, and formal succession processes (see, e.g.,Huson et al. (2001)). Gibson (2003) and DeFond and Hung (2004) also find that firm size is positivelyrelated to CEO turnover internationally.

    15 When we split by investor protection regimes, the coefficient on lagged earning ratio is negativeand significant in high protection countries.

  • 1910 The Journal of Finance

    Table IICEO Turnover and Cross-Listing

    This table presents the probit estimates of the relationship between the probability of CEO turnoverand firm performance measured by Lagged Earnings Ratio (1-year lagged ratio of earnings beforeinterest and taxes to total assets) or Lagged Excess Returns (1-year lagged total stock returns inexcess of the country average returns). Level 2/3 dummy is 1 if the firm has a Level 2 or Level 3ADR program, 0 otherwise. Level 1 dummy is 1 if the firm has a Level 1 ADR program, 0 otherwise.Rule 144A dummy is 1 if the firm has a Rule 144A issuance, 0 otherwise. Log Assets is the naturallog of total assets measured in million $U.S. The continuous variables are winsorized at the 1%level for each country. The interaction effect is defined as the change in the predicted probabilityof CEO turnover for a change in both the firm performance and the respective cross-listed dummyusing the methodology of Norton, Wang, and Ai (2004). The z-statistics appear in parentheses belowparameter estimates. Robust standard errors are estimated using the Rogers method of clusteringby firm. ∗∗∗ and ∗∗ indicate significance at the 1% and 5% level, respectively.

    Variable (1) (2)

    Log assets 0.023∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗[9.939] [9.433]

    Firm performance: Lagged earnings ratio −0.002 –[−1.528]

    Firm Performance: Lagged excess returns – −0.012[−1.317]

    L2/3 0.077∗∗ 0.029[2.226] [0.860]

    L2/3 ∗ firm performance −0.332∗∗ −0.092∗∗[−2.087] [−2.115]

    L1 0.043 0.076∗∗[1.274] [2.491]

    L1 ∗ Firm performance −0.120 0.001[−0.452] [0.107]

    R144A 0.049 −0.012[0.704] [−0.202]

    R144A ∗ Firm performance −0.350 0.015[−0.675] [0.330]

    Constant −0.905∗∗∗ −0.966∗∗∗[−3.245] [−3.302]

    Country effects Yes YesIndustry effects (two-digit SIC) Yes YesYear effects Yes YesObservations 70,976 62,333Pseudo-R2 0.026 0.028

    Mean interaction effect for −0.084∗∗ −0.022∗∗L23 ∗ Firm performance [−2.082] [−2.009]Mean interaction effect for −0.030 0.0002L1 ∗ Firm performance [−0.452] [0.067]Mean interaction effect for −0.086 0.003R144 ∗ firm performance [−0.667] [0.273]

  • International Cross-Listing 1911

    Figure 1. The economic significance of the impact of cross-listing on the relationshipbetween CEO turnover and firm performance. The following graphs display the interactioneffects and corresponding z-statistics on the interaction variable between the respective cross-listeddummy and firm performance measure reported in Table II, estimated using Norton, Wang, and Ai(2004). The interaction effect is defined as the change in the predicted probability of CEO turnoverfor a change in both firm performance and the respective cross-listed dummy. Panel A plots thegraphs associated with the lagged earnings ratio measure and Panel B depicts the graphs for thelagged excess returns measure. The lines above and below 0 on the figures located on the right siderepresent the 5% significance levels (±1.96).

  • 1912 The Journal of Finance

    Figure 1—Continued.

    absolute turnover, a result that is primarily driven by firms from the UnitedKingdom.16

    Model 2 of Table II examines the sensitivity of CEO turnover to performanceemploying our alternative firm performance measure, 1-year lagged excess

    16 Dahya et al. (2002) show that after the Cadbury Act was passed in 1992, CEO turnoverincreased for U.K. firms.

  • International Cross-Listing 1913

    stock market returns. We find that the interaction between L2/3 and stock-price-based performance is negative and significant, while the interactions be-tween L1 or R144a and stock-price-based performance are insignificant. There-fore, with this alternative performance measure we continue to find that cross-listed firms that are associated with the most stringent U.S. investor protectionsare more likely to terminate poorly performing CEOs.

    Overall, the results contained in Table II provide support for the hypothesisthat cross-listing on a major U.S. exchange, which requires the adoption of strin-gent U.S. investor protection laws, results in a significantly higher propensityto terminate poorly performing CEOs than their non-cross-listed counterparts.In addition, firms that cross-list via Level 1 or Rule 144a ADRs do not have anincreased association between CEO turnover and poor firm performance.

    In untabulated results, we also split our sample into countries with highand low stock-price informativeness to examine if the CEO turnover to per-formance sensitivity is higher in countries where stock prices are more infor-mative about firm-specific performance. Prior research by DeFond and Hung(2004) and Volpin (2002) argues that only in countries where stock prices areinformative is CEO turnover related to stock market performance.17 However,it is important to note that a significant relation between CEO turnover andperformance in low informativeness countries is possible if stock prices be-come more informative about performance due to cross-listing, something thatFernandes and Ferreira (2006) and Dasgupta, Gan, Ning, (2005) suggest oc-curs. Consistent with DeFond and Hung (2004) and Volpin (2002), we find thatthe interaction between cross-listing types and firm performance is insignif-icant in countries that have below-median stock-price informativeness, whilein countries where stock prices are informative, cross-listing on a major U.S.exchange results in a higher propensity to shed poorly performing CEOs. Theseresults also suggest that the increased CEO turnover to performance sensitiv-ity for cross-listed firms is not driven purely by stock prices becoming moreinformative for cross-listed firms in certain countries.

    Overall, the results in Table II provide support for the bonding hypothesis.We find that cross-listed firms have outcomes that are consistent with bettercorporate governance systems than similar non-cross-listed firms. Further, thefindings suggest that governance outcome differences are only significant forthose firms that adopt the strongest U.S. investor protections by listing on amajor U.S. exchange, rather than an OTC listing or private placement. Theseresults provide support for the hypothesis that by cross-listing in the UnitedStates, firms are able to opt-in to superior corporate governance.

    B. The Strength of Bonding for Firms in Low Investor Protection Countries

    Table III tests the third prediction of the bonding hypothesis that the ef-fect of bonding will be greatest for firms domiciled in the countries with theweakest investor protections. We test this hypothesis by splitting the sample

    17 Bushman, Piotroski, and Smith (2004) show that corporate transparency is low in poor investorprotection countries.

  • 1914 The Journal of Finance

    Tab

    leII

    IC

    EO

    Tu

    rnov

    er,C

    ross

    -Lis

    tin

    g,an

    dL

    egal

    En

    viro

    nm

    ent

    Th

    ista

    ble

    pres

    ents

    the

    prob

    ites

    tim

    ates

    ofth

    ere

    lati

    onsh

    ipbe

    twee

    nth

    epr

    obab

    ilit

    yof

    CE

    Otu

    rnov

    eran

    dfi

    rmpe

    rfor

    man

    ceu

    nde

    rva

    riou

    sm

    easu

    res

    ofa

    cou

    ntr

    y’s

    lega

    len

    viro

    nm

    ent.

    Fir

    mpe

    rfor

    man

    ceis

    mea

    sure

    dby

    Lag

    ged

    Ear

    nin

    gsR

    atio

    ,wh

    ich

    isth

    e1-

    year

    lagg

    edra

    tio

    ofea

    rnin

    gsbe

    fore

    inte

    rest

    and

    taxe

    sto

    tota

    lass

    ets,

    orL

    agge

    dE

    xces

    sR

    etu

    rns,

    wh

    ich

    isth

    e1-

    year

    lagg

    edto

    tals

    tock

    retu

    rns

    inex

    cess

    ofth

    eco

    un

    try

    aver

    age

    retu

    rns.

    Th

    eC

    ivil

    Law

    sam

    ple

    incl

    ude

    sfi

    rms

    loca

    ted

    inco

    un

    trie

    sw

    ith

    aF

    ren

    ch,

    Ger

    man

    ,or

    Sca

    ndi

    nav

    ian

    lega

    lsy

    stem

    .T

    he

    Com

    mon

    Law

    sam

    ple

    refe

    rsto

    firm

    slo

    cate

    din

    cou

    ntr

    ies

    wit

    hth

    eE

    ngl

    ish

    lega

    lori

    gin

    .An

    ti-d

    irec

    tor

    righ

    tsin

    dex

    mea

    sure

    sth

    ede

    gree

    ofm

    inor

    ity

    shar

    ehol

    der

    prot

    ecti

    on.A

    nti

    -sel

    f-de

    alin

    gis

    anin

    dex

    ofth

    est

    ren

    gth

    ofm

    inor

    ity

    shar

    ehol

    der

    prot

    ecti

    onag

    ain

    stse

    lf-d

    eali

    ng

    byth

    eco

    ntr

    olli

    ng

    shar

    ehol

    der.

    All

    thes

    eco

    un

    try-

    leve

    lin

    dice

    sar

    eob

    tain

    edfr

    omD

    jan

    kov

    etal

    .(20

    05).

    Th

    em

    edia

    ns

    of3.

    5fo

    ran

    ti-d

    irec

    tor

    righ

    tsan

    d0.

    42fo

    ran

    tise

    lf-d

    eali

    ng

    inde

    xu

    sed

    inD

    jan

    kov

    etal

    .(20

    05)

    are

    use

    dto

    grou

    pfi

    rms

    into

    hig

    hve

    rsu

    slo

    win

    vest

    orpr

    otec

    tion

    regi

    mes

    (low

    erth

    anor

    equ

    alto

    the

    med

    ian

    refe

    rsto

    low

    gove

    rnan

    cesu

    bsam

    ples

    ).L

    evel

    2/3

    dum

    my

    is1

    ifth

    efi

    rmh

    asa

    Lev

    el2

    orL

    evel

    3A

    DR

    prog

    ram

    ,0ot

    her

    wis

    e.L

    evel

    1du

    mm

    yis

    1if

    the

    firm

    has

    aL

    evel

    1A

    DR

    prog

    ram

    ,0ot

    her

    wis

    e.R

    ule

    144A

    dum

    my

    is1

    ifth

    efi

    rmh

    asa

    Ru

    le14

    4Ais

    suan

    ce,0

    oth

    erw

    ise.

    Log

    Ass

    ets

    isth

    en

    atu

    rall

    ogof

    tota

    lass

    ets

    mea

    sure

    din

    mil

    lion

    $U.S

    .Th

    eco

    nti

    nu

    ous

    vari

    able

    sar

    ew

    inso

    rize

    dat

    the

    1%le

    velf

    orea

    chco

    un

    try.

    Th

    ein

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    isde

    fin

    edas

    the

    chan

    gein

    the

    pred

    icte

    dpr

    obab

    ilit

    yof

    CE

    Otu

    rnov

    erfo

    ra

    chan

    gein

    both

    the

    firm

    perf

    orm

    ance

    and

    the

    resp

    ecti

    vecr

    oss-

    list

    eddu

    mm

    yu

    sin

    gth

    em

    eth

    odol

    ogy

    ofN

    orto

    n,W

    ang,

    and

    Ai(

    2004

    ).T

    he

    z-st

    atis

    tics

    appe

    arin

    pare

    nth

    eses

    belo

    wpa

    ram

    eter

    esti

    mat

    es.R

    obu

    stst

    anda

    rder

    rors

    are

    esti

    mat

    edu

    sin

    gth

    eR

    oger

    sm

    eth

    odof

    clu

    ster

    ing

    byfi

    rm.

    ∗∗∗

    and

    ∗∗in

    dica

    tesi

    gnif

    ican

    ceat

    the

    1%an

    d5%

    leve

    l,re

    spec

    tive

    ly.

    Pan

    elA

    :On

    e-Ye

    arL

    agge

    dE

    arn

    ings

    Rat

    io

    Low

    An

    ti-

    Hig

    hA

    nti

    -L

    owA

    nti

    -H

    igh

    An

    ti-

    Civ

    ilC

    omm

    onD

    irec

    tor

    Dir

    ecto

    rS

    elf-

    Sel

    f-L

    awL

    awR

    igh

    tsR

    igh

    tsD

    eali

    ng

    Hig

    hD

    eali

    ng

    Var

    iabl

    e(1

    )(2

    )(3

    )(4

    )(5

    )(6

    )

    Fir

    m,c

    oun

    try,

    indu

    stry

    ,yea

    rco

    ntr

    ols

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Obs

    erva

    tion

    s44

    ,735

    26,2

    3741

    ,007

    29,9

    6715

    ,936

    55,0

    20P

    seu

    do-R

    20.

    033

    0.02

    20.

    034

    0.02

    30.

    031

    0.02

    9M

    ean

    inte

    ract

    ion

    effe

    ctfo

    r−0

    .341

    ∗∗∗

    0.01

    9−0

    .333

    ∗∗∗

    0.01

    8−0

    .328

    ∗∗∗

    −0.0

    45L

    23∗l

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    [−3.

    435]

    [0.4

    18]

    [−3.

    339]

    [0.3

    86]

    [−3.

    121]

    [−1.

    023]

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    for

    −0.1

    120.

    040

    −0.1

    0400

    38−0

    .023

    −0.0

    31L

    1∗l

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    [−0.

    850]

    [0.5

    40]

    [−0.

    763]

    [0.5

    19]

    [−0.

    154]

    [−0.

    440]

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    for

    −0.1

    640.

    129

    −0.1

    830.

    058

    −0.1

    21−0

    .076

    R14

    4∗l

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    [−1.

    071]

    [0.5

    02]

    [−0.

    975]

    [0.3

    31]

    [−0.

    535]

    [−0.

    497]

  • International Cross-Listing 1915

    Pan

    elB

    :On

    e-Ye

    arL

    agge

    dE

    xces

    sR

    etu

    rns

    Low

    An

    ti-

    Hig

    hA

    nti

    -L

    owA

    nti

    -H

    igh

    An

    ti-

    Civ

    ilC

    omm

    onD

    irec

    tor

    Dir

    ecto

    rS

    elf-

    Sel

    f-L

    awL

    awR

    igh

    tsR

    igh

    tsD

    eali

    ng

    Hig

    hD

    eali

    ng

    Var

    iabl

    e(1

    )(2

    )(3

    )(4

    )(5

    )(6

    )

    Fir

    m,c

    oun

    try,

    indu

    stry

    ,yea

    rco

    ntr

    ols

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Obs

    erva

    tion

    s39

    ,809

    22,5

    1936

    ,552

    25,7

    7113

    ,455

    48,8

    54P

    seu

    do-R

    20.

    033

    0.02

    30.

    034

    0.02

    40.

    032

    0.03

    0M

    ean

    inte

    ract

    ion

    effe

    ctfo

    r−0

    .044

    ∗∗∗

    0.01

    3−0

    .054

    ∗∗0.

    007

    −0.0

    35∗∗

    −0.0

    09L

    23∗l

    agge

    dex

    cess

    retu

    rns

    [−3.

    256]

    [0.8

    01]

    [−2.

    077]

    [0.5

    00]

    [−2.

    492]

    [−0.

    655]

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    for

    0.00

    040.

    002

    −0.0

    090.

    003

    −0.0

    002

    −0.0

    03L

    1∗l

    agge

    dex

    cess

    retu

    rns

    [0.1

    48]

    [0.1

    10]

    [−0.

    250]

    [0.7

    51]

    [−0.

    077]

    [−0.

    200]

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    for

    −0.0

    002

    0.02

    60.

    004

    0.00

    4−0

    .004

    0.01

    4R

    144

    ∗lag

    ged

    exce

    ssre

    turn

    s[−

    0.01

    5][0

    .931

    ][0

    .267

    ][0

    .250

    ][−

    0.25

    3][1

    .148

    ]

  • 1916 The Journal of Finance

    by investor protection regimes and examining the interactions between cross-listing types and firm performance, for both accounting- and stock-market-based performance measures (Panels A and B, respectively). Firm, country,industry, and year controls are included in all regressions.

    The first two columns in Panel A of Table III split the sample by legal origin, aclassification that proxies for the overall protection of minority shareholders ina country (see, for example, LLSV (1998)). Model 1 shows that in countries withCivil Law tradition, where investor protection is weakest, the corrected interac-tion between Level 2/3 and Lagged Earnings Ratio is negative and significant(−0.341, t-statistic = −3.435). Model 1 also shows that the corrected interac-tions between firm performance and L1 or R144a are insignificant (−0.112,t-statistic = −0.850, and −0.164, t-statistic = −1.071, respectively). Therefore,in countries with poor investor protections, cross-listing on a major U.S. ex-change is associated with an increased CEO turnover to poor firm performancesensitivity. In terms of economic significance, the probability of replacing theCEO increases by 4.36% in absolute terms for Level 2/3 ADRs when we movefrom the top quartile to the bottom quartile of firm performance measured inCivil Law countries.18

    Model 2 of Panel A presents the results for Common Law countries, whereinvestor protection is strongest. In these countries, we find that all the interac-tions between cross-listing type and the Lagged Earnings Ratio are statisticallyinsignificant. Further, the difference in the interaction terms between Civil andCommon Law countries is significant (p-value of lower than 0.01). Therefore,the results indicate that the effect of U.S. investor protections is most signifi-cant when the firm’s home country investor protections are weakest. Althoughnot reported, we find that the Lagged Earnings Ratio coefficient is negative andsignificant, which is consistent with previous research that finds accounting-based performance is used for managerial performance evaluation.

    To further test if the extent of bonding is dependent on the category of pro-tections investors are afforded in a particular country, we also investigate al-ternative investor protection indices from Djankov et al. (2005). Models 3 and5 report results for countries classified as having weak protection of minorityshareholders and poor safeguards against corporate tunneling. In both models,we find the interactions (both standard and corrected) between Level 2/3 andLagged Earnings Ratio are negative and significant, indicating that in theselow investor protection countries, cross-listing on a major U.S. exchange is as-sociated with increased CEO turnover to poor firm performance sensitivity.Models 4 and 6 report results for the strong investor protection countries. Inboth these models, the interactions between cross-listing type (Level 2/3, L1, orR144a) are insignificant, indicating no difference in the CEO turnover to firmperformance relation in countries that have strong investor protection.19

    18 For comparison, Huson et al. (2001) show that going from the top quartile to the lowest quartilein EBIT/TA ratio increases the probability of CEO turnover by 2%.

    19 Using alternative measures of investor protection laws from LLS (2006) and LLSV (1998),such as the burden of proof, investor protection, private law enforcement, disclosure, and ruleof law indexes, produces similar conclusions. Further, the results are robust to using Spamann’s(2006) ADRI.

  • International Cross-Listing 1917

    Panel B provides the results for the stock-price-based firm performance mea-sure. As in Panel A, we find across all weak investor protection subsamples,the interaction between firm performance and Level 2/3 is negative and signifi-cant. For example, the mean-corrected interactive effect in Civil Law countriesis −0.044 (t-statistic = −3.256). For other cross-listing types, the interactioncoefficients are insignificant. Further, Models 2, 4, and 6 show that in stronginvestor protection countries, cross-listing does not increase the sensitivity ofCEO turnover to poor firm performance.

    Taken together, the results in Table III show that in countries where investorprotections are weakest, adopting the strongest U.S. investor protection provi-sions results in significantly greater propensity to terminate poorly performingCEOs, while in countries that already have strong investor protections, cross-listing does not change the CEO turnover to performance sensitivity. Further,the results show that in weak investor protection countries, only cross-listingsthat require the most stringent of U.S. investor protections (exchange-listedcross-listings) are associated with better governance outcomes. Therefore, theresults provide support for the second and third main predictions of the bondinghypothesis.

    C. Sensitivity of CEO Turnover to Performance in the Pre-Cross-Listing Period

    The previous analysis establishes that cross-listed firms on major U.S. ex-changes have outcomes that are consistent with improved corporate gover-nance over non-cross-listed firms. In this analysis, the comparison group isall non-cross-listed firms, which includes firms that may never cross-list aswell as cross-listed firms in their pre-cross-listing period. However, an alterna-tive explanation for our findings is that only the better-governed firms chooseto cross-list on a major U.S. exchange, which would drive our results. Whileour previous tests employed time-varying cross-listing indicator variables thatequal one only after the firm cross-listed, we further examine this issue byperforming two additional tests in which we examine the sensitivity of CEOturnover to performance in the pre-cross-listing period.

    In the first test, we examine how the sensitivity of CEO turnover to firmperformance differs before and after cross-listing, where we restrict the sam-ple to firms that will have a cross-listing of the same type during our sampleperiod.20 The advantage of this experiment is that the non-cross-listed compari-son group consists of firms that will have a cross-listing of a similar type duringthe sample period (that is, the pre-cross-listing period of the cross-listed firms).If firms that pursue exchange-traded cross-listings have better governanceprior to cross-listing, then we would expect to find little difference betweencross-listed firms and “to-be” cross-listed firms. Due to space considerations,in this test we focus on the broad Civil versus Common Law classificationsusing the lagged earnings ratio performance measure, but other governance

    20 We also examine the comparison groups together with indicator variables for cross-listingtypes (i.e., Level 2/3, Level 1, and Rule144a dummies together) and obtain similar results.

  • 1918 The Journal of Finance

    classifications and performance measures produce consistent results.21 Model1 in Table IV shows that the sensitivity of turnover to performance for exchange-traded cross-listings is significantly larger than that for non-cross-listed firmsthat will eventually cross-list on a major exchange in low shareholder protec-tion countries. Therefore, the results suggest that the difference in governanceoutcomes is driven by the post-cross-listing period of cross-listed firms. Thecoefficient on L2/3 also shows that these firms have higher absolute turnoverafter cross-listing. For Level 1 and Rule 144a cross-listings, the interactionsbetween cross-listing type and firm performance are not significantly differentbetween cross-listed and non-cross-listed firms.

    The second way we test if the pre-cross-listing governance of our samplefirms is driving our results is to exclude all observations for cross-listed firmsfollowing the cross-listing year and compare the interactions of “to-be” cross-listed firms’ performance to the full sample of non-cross-listed firms. If the pre-cross-listing status of cross-listed firms is driving our results, we might expectto see results in this analysis similar to our full sample tests presented earlier.An advantage of this test is that we are able to use the full sample of non-cross-listed firms. The disadvantage is that there are relatively few observations inthe prelisting period, which is likely to lower the power of the test. Table V showsthat when the post-cross-listing observations are excluded, we no longer findthat cross-listed firms are more likely to terminate poorly performing CEOs.22

    We also find in Table V that Before L1 ∗ Lagged Earnings Ratio is positiveand significant, which suggests these firms see an improvement from a verylow level of corporate governance, where well-performing managers are morelikely to leave, to a low level where there is no relation between turnover andperformance.

    Overall, the results in Tables IV and V show that when compared to theirpre-cross-listing status, cross-listing on a major U.S. exchange results in sig-nificantly higher CEO turnover to firm performance sensitivity. Therefore, theresults indicate that it is not the pre-cross-listing governance of firms that isdriving the results. Taken together, the evidence in the preceding sections sug-gests that in countries with poor investor protections, cross-listing on a majorU.S. exchange increases the likelihood that firms will have outcomes consistentwith improved corporate governance systems.

    D. London Listings

    Listing in London is an often-cited alternative for firms that do not wish tosubject themselves to the stringent listing requirements in the United States.23

    21 For example, using the excess returns measure, the interaction between performance andLevel 2/3 is also statistically significant (insignificant) in Civil (Common) Law, weak (strong) anti-director rights, and low (high) anti-self-dealing subsamples.

    22 We also estimate a two-stage model for self-selection that controls for the decision to list inthe first stage and find that our results are robust to this specification.

    23 See, for example, “London Calling” in Forbes Magazine May 8, 2006.

  • International Cross-Listing 1919

    Tab

    leIV

    CE

    OT

    urn

    over

    and

    Cro

    ss-L

    isti

    ng:

    Fir

    ms

    wit

    ha

    Cro

    ss-L

    isti

    ng

    ofth

    eS

    ame

    Typ

    eT

    his

    tabl

    epr

    esen

    tsth

    epr

    obit

    esti

    mat

    esof

    the

    rela

    tion

    ship

    betw

    een

    the

    prob

    abil

    ity

    ofC

    EO

    turn

    over

    and

    firm

    perf

    orm

    ance

    for

    firm

    sth

    ath

    ave

    orw

    ill

    hav

    ea

    sim

    ilar

    type

    ofA

    DR

    prog

    ram

    duri

    ng

    the

    sam

    ple

    peri

    od.T

    he

    sam

    ple

    inco

    lum

    ns

    1–2

    isli

    mit

    edto

    firm

    sth

    ath

    ave

    orw

    illh

    ave

    list

    edon

    am

    ajor

    U.S

    .exc

    han

    gedu

    rin

    gou

    rsa

    mpl

    epe

    riod

    .Sim

    ilar

    ly,t

    he

    sam

    ples

    inco

    lum

    ns

    3–4

    and

    5–6

    rest

    rict

    the

    sam

    ple

    tofi

    rms

    that

    list

    onth

    eO

    TC

    mar

    ket

    and

    issu

    epr

    ivat

    epl

    acem

    ents

    via

    Ru

    le14

    4aan

    ytim

    edu

    rin

    gou

    rsa

    mpl

    epe

    riod

    ,res

    pect

    ivel

    y.L

    agge

    dE

    arn

    ings

    Rat

    iois

    the

    1-ye

    arla

    gged

    rati

    oof

    earn

    ings

    befo

    rein

    tere

    stan

    dta

    xes

    toto

    tal

    asse

    ts.

    Th

    eC

    ivil

    Law

    sam

    ple

    incl

    ude

    sfi

    rms

    loca

    ted

    inco

    un

    trie

    sw

    ith

    aF

    ren

    ch,

    Ger

    man

    ,or

    Sca

    ndi

    nav

    ian

    lega

    lsy

    stem

    .Th

    eC

    omm

    onL

    awsa

    mpl

    ere

    fers

    tofi

    rms

    loca

    ted

    inco

    un

    trie

    sw

    ith

    the

    En

    glis

    hle

    galo

    rigi

    n.T

    his

    clas

    sifi

    cati

    onof

    lega

    lreg

    imes

    isob

    tain

    edfr

    omD

    jan

    kov

    etal

    .(20

    05).

    Lev

    el2/

    3du

    mm

    yis

    1if

    the

    firm

    has

    aL

    evel

    2or

    Lev

    el3

    AD

    Rpr

    ogra

    m,0

    oth

    erw

    ise.

    Lev

    el1

    dum

    my

    is1

    ifth

    efi

    rmh

    asa

    Lev

    el1

    AD

    Rpr

    ogra

    m,0

    oth

    erw

    ise.

    Ru

    le14

    4Adu

    mm

    yis

    1if

    the

    firm

    has

    aR

    ule

    144A

    issu

    ance

    ,0ot

    her

    wis

    e.L

    ogA

    sset

    sis

    the

    nat

    ura

    llo

    gof

    tota

    las

    sets

    mea

    sure

    din

    mil

    lion

    $U.S

    .Th

    eco

    nti

    nu

    ous

    vari

    able

    sar

    ew

    inso

    rize

    dat

    the

    1%le

    velf

    orea

    chco

    un

    try.

    Th

    ein

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    isde

    fin

    edas

    the

    chan

    gein

    the

    pred

    icte

    dpr

    obab

    ilit

    yof

    CE

    Otu

    rnov

    erfo

    ra

    chan

    gein

    both

    the

    firm

    perf

    orm

    ance

    and

    the

    resp

    ecti

    vecr

    oss-

    list

    eddu

    mm

    yu

    sin

    gth

    em

    eth

    odol

    ogy

    ofN

    orto

    n,W

    ang,

    and

    Ai

    (200

    4).T

    he

    z-st

    atis

    tics

    appe

    arin

    pare

    nth

    eses

    belo

    wpa

    ram

    eter

    esti

    mat

    es.R

    obu

    stst

    anda

    rder

    rors

    are

    esti

    mat

    edu

    sin

    gth

    eR

    oger

    sm

    eth

    odof

    clu

    ster

    ing

    byfi

    rm.∗

    ∗∗,∗

    ∗ ,an

    d∗

    indi

    cate

    sign

    ific

    ance

    atth

    e1%

    ,5%

    ,an

    d10

    %le

    vel,

    resp

    ecti

    vely

    .

    Exc

    han

    ge-T

    rade

    dA

    DR

    sO

    TC

    -Tra

    ded

    AD

    Rs

    Pri

    vate

    Pla

    cem

    ents

    Civ

    ilL

    awC

    omm

    onL

    awC

    ivil

    Law

    Com

    mon

    Law

    Civ

    ilL

    awC

    omm

    onL

    awV

    aria

    ble

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    Log

    asse

    ts−0

    .011

    0.02

    8∗−0

    .006

    0.01

    30.

    148∗

    ∗∗0.

    122∗

    ∗[−

    0.48

    1][1

    .770

    ][0

    .299

    ][0

    .769

    ][3

    .028

    ][2

    .299

    ]L

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    1.40

    5−0

    .134

    −0.0

    27−0

    .122

    −0.8

    88−2

    .495

    [0.9

    64]

    [−0.

    509]

    [−0.

    837]

    [−0.

    829]

    [−0.

    705]

    [−0.

    668]

    L2/

    30.

    631∗

    ∗∗0.

    021

    ––

    ––

    [3.2

    19]

    [0.2

    03]

    L2/

    3∗l

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    −2.8

    52∗

    0.02

    1–

    ––

    –[−

    1.90

    3][0

    .067

    ]L

    1–

    –0.

    194

    −0.0

    63–

    –[1

    .547

    ][−

    0.56

    7]L

    1∗l

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    ––

    −0.2

    660.

    094

    ––

    [−0.

    449]

    [0.2

    50]

    (con

    tin

    ued

    )

  • 1920 The Journal of Finance

    Tab

    leIV

    —C

    onti

    nu

    ed

    Exc

    han

    ge-T

    rade

    dA

    DR

    sO

    TC

    -Tra

    ded

    AD

    Rs

    Pri

    vate

    Pla

    cem

    ents

    Civ

    ilL

    awC

    omm

    onL

    awC

    ivil

    Law

    Com

    mon

    Law

    Civ

    ilL

    awC

    omm

    onL

    awV

    aria

    ble

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    R14

    4A–

    ––

    –0.

    196

    −0.7

    14[0

    .899

    ][−

    1.57

    5]R

    144A

    ∗lag

    ged

    earn

    ings

    rati

    o–

    ––

    –0.

    472

    3.14

    4[0

    .303

    ][0

    .796

    ]C

    onst

    ant

    0.47

    3−6

    .433

    ∗∗∗

    −11.

    514∗

    ∗∗−6

    .577

    ∗∗∗

    −0.7

    69−0

    .320

    [0.6

    35]

    [−10

    .192

    ][−

    40.6

    28]

    [−18

    .563

    ][−

    0.82

    8][−

    0.42

    7]C

    oun

    try

    effe

    cts

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    indu

    stry

    effe

    cts

    (tw

    o-di

    git

    SIC

    )Ye

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    aref

    fect

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    s

    Obs

    erva

    tion

    s73

    71,

    567

    1,49

    61,

    656

    544

    367

    Pse

    udo

    -R2

    0.14

    70.

    061

    0.05

    90.

    067

    0.24

    20.

    171

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    −0.5

    65∗

    0.00

    5−0

    .092

    0.02

    30.

    046

    0.81

    9[−

    1.70

    2][0

    .061

    ][−

    0.63

    3][0

    .266

    ][0

    .084

    ][0

    .748

    ]

  • International Cross-Listing 1921T

    able

    VC

    EO

    Tu

    rnov

    erP

    rior

    toC

    ross

    -Lis

    tin

    gT

    his

    tabl

    epr

    esen

    tsth

    epr

    obit

    esti

    mat

    esof

    the

    rela

    tion

    ship

    betw

    een

    the

    prob

    abil

    ity

    ofC

    EO

    turn

    over

    and

    firm

    perf

    orm

    ance

    un

    der

    vari

    ous

    lega

    len

    viro

    nm

    ents

    prio

    rto

    cros

    s-li

    stin

    g.O

    bser

    vati

    ons

    for

    cros

    s-li

    sted

    firm

    sfr

    omth

    ecr

    oss-

    list

    ing

    year

    onar

    eex

    clu

    ded.

    Lag

    ged

    Ear

    nin

    gsR

    atio

    isth

    e1-

    year

    lagg

    edra

    tio

    ofea

    rnin

    gsbe

    fore

    inte

    rest

    and

    taxe

    sto

    tota

    lass

    ets.

    Civ

    ilL

    awsa

    mpl

    ein

    clu

    des

    firm

    slo

    cate

    din

    cou

    ntr

    ies

    wit

    ha

    Fre

    nch

    ,Ger

    man

    ,or

    Sca

    ndi

    nav

    ian

    lega

    lsys

    tem

    .Th

    eC

    omm

    onL

    awsa

    mpl

    ere

    fers

    tofi

    rms

    loca

    ted

    inco

    un

    trie

    sw

    ith

    the

    En

    glis

    hle

    galo

    rigi

    n.A

    nti

    -dir

    ecto

    rri

    ghts

    inde

    xm

    easu

    res

    the

    degr

    eeof

    min

    orit

    ysh

    areh

    olde

    rpr

    otec

    tion

    .A

    nti

    -sel

    f-de

    alin

    gis

    anin

    dex

    ofth

    est

    ren

    gth

    ofm

    inor

    ity

    shar

    ehol

    der

    prot

    ecti

    onag

    ain

    stse

    lf-d

    eali

    ng

    byth

    eco

    ntr

    olli

    ng

    shar

    ehol

    der.

    All

    thes

    eco

    un

    try-

    leve

    lin

    dice

    sar

    eob

    tain

    edfr

    omD

    jan

    kov

    etal

    .(20

    05).

    Th

    em

    edia

    ns

    of3.

    5fo

    ran

    ti-d

    irec

    tor

    righ

    tsan

    d0.

    42fo

    ran

    ti-s

    elf-

    deal

    ing

    inde

    xu

    sed

    inD

    jan

    kov

    etal

    .(2

    005)

    are

    use

    dto

    grou

    pfi

    rms

    into

    hig

    hve

    rsu

    slo

    win

    vest

    orpr

    otec

    tion

    regi

    mes

    (low

    erth

    anor

    equ

    alto

    the

    med

    ian

    refe

    rsto

    low

    gove

    rnan

    cesu

    bsam

    ples

    ).B

    efor

    eL

    evel

    2/3

    dum

    my

    is1

    for

    the

    peri

    odbe

    fore

    the

    firm

    cros

    s-li

    sts

    ona

    maj

    orst

    ock

    exch

    ange

    inth

    eU

    .S.,

    0ot

    her

    wis

    e.B

    efor

    eL

    evel

    1du

    mm

    yis

    1fo

    rth

    epe

    riod

    befo

    reth

    efi

    rmcr

    oss-

    list

    sin

    the

    OT

    Cm

    arke

    tsin

    the

    U.S

    .,0

    oth

    erw

    ise.

    Bef

    ore

    Ru

    le14

    4Adu

    mm

    yis

    1fo

    rth

    epe

    riod

    befo

    reth

    efi

    rmh

    asa

    priv

    ate

    plac

    emen

    tin

    the

    U.S

    .,0

    oth

    erw

    ise.

    Log

    Ass

    ets

    isth

    en

    atu

    rall

    ogof

    tota

    lass

    ets

    mea

    sure

    din

    mil

    lion

    $U.S

    .Th

    eco

    nti

    nu

    ous

    vari

    able

    sar

    ew

    inso

    rize

    dat

    the

    1%le

    velf

    orea

    chco

    un

    try.

    Th

    ein

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    isde

    fin

    edas

    the

    chan

    gein

    the

    pred

    icte

    dpr

    obab

    ilit

    yof

    CE

    Otu

    rnov

    erfo

    ra

    chan

    gein

    both

    the

    firm

    perf

    orm

    ance

    and

    the

    resp

    ecti

    vecr

    oss-

    list

    eddu

    mm

    yu

    sin

    gth

    em

    eth

    odol

    ogy

    ofN

    orto

    n,W

    ang,

    and

    Ai(

    2004

    ).T

    he

    z-st

    atis

    tics

    appe

    arin

    pare

    nth

    eses

    belo

    wpa

    ram

    eter

    esti

    mat

    es.R

    obu

    stst

    anda

    rder

    rors

    are

    esti

    mat

    edu

    sin

    gth

    eR

    oger

    sm

    eth

    odof

    clu

    ster

    ing

    byfi

    rm.∗

    ∗∗,∗

    ∗ ,an

    d∗

    indi

    cate

    sign

    ific

    ance

    atth

    e1%

    ,5%

    ,an

    d10

    %le

    vel,

    resp

    ecti

    vely

    .

    Civ

    ilC

    omm

    onL

    owA

    nti

    -H

    igh

    An

    ti-

    Low

    An

    ti-

    Hig

    hA

    nti

    -L

    awL

    awD

    irec

    tor

    Rig

    hts

    Dir

    ecto

    rR

    igh

    tsS

    elf-

    Dea

    lin

    gS

    elf-

    Dea

    lin

    gV

    aria

    ble

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    Log

    asse

    ts0.

    022∗

    ∗∗0.

    029∗

    ∗∗0.

    020∗

    ∗∗0.

    029∗

    ∗∗0.

    020∗

    ∗∗0.

    025∗

    ∗∗[7

    .076

    ][7

    .211

    ][6

    .068

    ][7

    .890

    ][4

    .084

    ][8

    .877

    ]L

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    −0.0

    01∗∗

    −0.2

    63∗∗

    ∗−0

    .001

    ∗∗∗

    −0.2

    73∗∗

    ∗−0

    .005

    −0.0

    01∗∗

    [−2.

    260]

    [−6.

    550]

    [−2.

    912]

    [−6.

    978]

    [−1.

    065]

    [−2.

    334]

    Bef

    ore

    L2/

    3−0

    .310

    0.04

    2−0

    .342

    0.03

    8−0

    .262

    0.02

    7[−

    1.58

    0][0

    .478

    ][−

    1.47

    1][0

    .453

    ][−

    1.32

    0][0

    .319

    ]B

    efor

    eL

    2/3

    ∗lag

    ged

    earn

    ings

    rati

    o2.

    499

    0.01

    42.

    472

    0.02

    02.

    978

    −0.1

    43[1

    .444

    ][0

    .054

    ][1

    .254

    ][0

    .077

    ][1

    .538

    ][−

    0.56

    5]B

    efor

    eL

    1−0

    .181

    −0.0

    42−0

    .270

    ∗∗−0

    .030

    −0.1

    31−0

    .055

    [−1.

    509]

    [−0.

    626]

    [−1.

    994]

    [−0.

    471]

    [−0.

    862]

    [−0.

    883]

    Bef

    ore

    L1

    ∗lag

    ged

    earn

    ings

    rati

    o0.

    048∗

    ∗0.

    114

    0.05

    5∗∗∗

    0.10

    80.

    058∗

    ∗∗−0

    .117

    [2.5

    36]

    [0.8

    17]

    [2.8

    42]

    [0.7

    81]

    [2.7

    55]

    [−0.

    864]

    Bef

    ore

    R14

    4A−0

    .281

    ∗0.

    352

    −0.3

    540.

    096

    −0.4

    93−0

    .224

    [−1.

    835]

    [1.1

    25]

    [−1.

    558]

    [0.5

    77]

    [−1.

    517]

    [−0.

    940]

    (con

    tin

    ued

    )

  • 1922 The Journal of Finance

    Tab

    leV

    —C

    onti

    nu

    ed

    Civ

    ilC

    omm

    onL

    owA

    nti

    -H

    igh

    An

    ti-

    Low

    An

    ti-

    Hig

    hA

    nti

    -L

    awL

    awD

    irec

    tor

    Rig

    hts

    Dir

    ecto

    rR

    igh

    tsS

    elf-

    Dea

    lin

    gS

    elf-

    Dea

    lin

    gV

    aria

    ble

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    Bef

    ore

    R14

    4A∗l

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    −0.0

    01−1

    .171

    1.50

    50.

    270∗

    ∗∗−0

    .516

    2.28

    2[−

    1.04

    6][−

    0.48

    2][0

    .694

    ][6

    .895

    ][−

    0.19

    2][1

    .077

    ]C

    onst

    ant

    −0.9

    36∗∗

    −0.6

    40∗

    −0.8

    89∗

    −1.4

    86∗∗

    ∗−1

    .528

    ∗∗∗

    −0.8

    69∗

    [−2.

    048]

    [−1.

    676]

    [−1.

    935]

    [−2.

    822]

    [−3.

    415]

    [−1.

    909]

    Cou

    ntr

    yef

    fect

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sYe

    sIn

    dust

    ryef

    fect

    s(t

    wo-

    digi

    tS

    IC)

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Year

    effe

    cts

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Obs

    erva

    tion

    s42

    ,137

    23,4

    0938

    ,556

    26,9

    9214

    ,869

    50,6

    62P

    seu

    do-R

    20.

    033

    0.02

    10.

    034

    0.02

    20.

    030

    0.02

    8

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    for

    befo

    re0.

    494

    0.00

    10.

    466

    0.00

    20.

    660

    −0.0

    34L

    23∗l

    agge

    dea

    rnin

    gsra

    tio

    [1.4

    21]

    [0.0

    13]

    [1.2

    68]

    [0.0

    38]

    [1.4

    06]

    [−0.

    567]

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    for

    befo

    re0.

    010∗

    ∗∗0.

    028

    0.01

    0∗∗∗

    0.02

    60.

    012∗

    ∗∗−0

    .026

    L1

    ∗lag

    ged

    earn

    ings

    rati

    o[2

    .916

    ][0

    .896

    ][3

    .509

    ][0

    .842

    ][3

    .100

    ][−

    0.87

    1]

    Mea

    nin

    tera

    ctio

    nef

    fect

    for

    befo

    re−0

    .000

    1−0

    .353

    0.26

    50.

    063∗

    ∗∗−0

    .068

    0.47

    9R

    144

    ∗lag

    ged

    earn

    ings

    rati

    o[−

    0.29

    6][−

    0.49

    0][0

    .718

    ][5

    .712

    ][−

    0.18

    7][1

    .134

    ]

  • International Cross-Listing 1923

    Consistent with the hypothesis that a London listing does not convey the samegovernance commitment as a U.S. listing, Doidge et al. (2006) find that firmswith high private benefits of control are more likely to list in London ratherthan on a major U.S. exchange. Baker et al. (2002) also find that monitoringby financial analysts is lower in London Stock Exchange (LSE) cross-listingsversus U.S. cross-listings and Seetharaman, Ferdinand, and Lynn (2002) findthat U.K. auditors charge higher fees for client firms that are listed in theUnited States to compensate for the higher risk of litigation.

    To test if cross-listing on the LSE also results in improved governance out-comes, we gather a sample of 688 firm-year observations (145 firms from 27countries) that trade in London and rerun our models to examine the sensitiv-ity of CEO turnover to performance between firms that cross-listed in Londonand those firms that did not.24 Since we are examining London listings, weexclude observations from the United Kingdom. Table VI reports that the in-teraction between LSE Listing and firm performance is not significant in anyspecification. In addition, the results are robust when U.S. firms are included.In unreported tests, we also find that the difference between listing on a majorU.S. exchange and on the LSE is statistically significant at the 5% level. There-fore, unlike a major U.S. exchange cross-listing, we do not find that listing onthe LSE is associated with better corporate governance outcomes.

    E. Labor Market Effects: The Departing and Replacement CEOs’ Work History

    A potential explanation for our results is that cross-listing also changes thelabor market for top management. For example, one possibility is that cross-listing may induce top management to leave their jobs to pursue employment inthe United States where they are likely to receive higher compensation. Anotherpossibility is that by cross-listing, firms are able to tap a more internationalpool of top management candidates and therefore are more likely to fire poorlyperforming managers. To investigate these effects, we examine a subsample of150 cross-listed firms that experienced a CEO turnover after cross-listing. Dueto the labor intensiveness of this investigation, these CEO turnover events arerandomly drawn from sample firms, with an equal number for Level 2/3 ADRs,Level 1 ADRs, and private placements.

    We first search news articles as well as reexamine the CEO data on theWorldScope database to find out where the departing CEO found employment.We are able to find the post-turnover employment information for 110 CEOs.Of these, only eight went to a U.S. firm, and only five of these were from amajor exchange cross-listed firm (Level 2/3). Further, only one of the five leftvoluntarily. Therefore, this evidence does not appear to be consistent with alarge number of CEOs leaving to take higher paid jobs in the United States.

    We next investigate the newly appointed CEOs’ previous work experienceto see if cross-listed firms may be more likely to terminate poorly performingmanagement when the potential quality of the labor market is higher. For t