speed of learning and price multiples

Upload: eleanor-rigby

Post on 04-Apr-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    1/35

    1

    The Speed of Learning about Firms Profitability and their Price Multiples: A

    Global Perspective

    PANKAJ K. JAIN AND UDOMSAK WONGCHOTI*

    Abstract

    This paper is an application of learning models in valuation of stocks listed on 52

    international stock exchanges. We present direct evidence of declining analyst forecast errors

    and return volatility with advancement in a firms age in the context of a learning model.

    Consistent with a relatively new theory of learning and unlike the traditional focus of asset

    pricing models on the discount rate in denominator, we find support for the notion that this

    reduction in uncertainty about a firms prospects affects the expected value of cash flows in the

    numerator of the valuation equation. This results in an inverse and convex relation between a

    firms age and its market-to-book ratio. The valuation effects of learning are pervasive over time

    and across countries, and are stronger for firms that do not pay dividends. We also find that the

    speed of learning about firms profitability and its impact on valuation varies in economies with

    diverse market designs and legal frameworks. Forecast errors are lower with strict enforcement

    of laws prohibiting insider trading, higher feasibility of short selling, and dominance of local

    versus foreign investors. These features also increase the learning speed and fuel quicker

    achievement of long run equilibrium valuations.

    JEL Classification Codes: G12, G14, G15

    Key Words: Market to book ratio

    ______________________

    * Jain is from Fogelman College of Business and Economics, The University of Memphis, USA and Wongchoti isfrom Massey University, Palmerston North, New Zealand. Please send correspondence to Pankaj Jain, FCBE 425,University of Memphis, Memphis, TN 38111, Phone (901) 678 3810, Fax (901) 678 0839, Email:

    [email protected] or [email protected]. We are grateful to Michael Pagano, Ian Cooper, Henk

    Berkman, John G Powell, Geoff Jones, Ben Jacobsen, and seminar participants at the European Finance Association

    Annual Meeting 2008 (Athens, Greece), University of Mississippi, Southern Methodist University, and OldDominion Universityfor comments and suggestions. All errors are our responsibility.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    2/35

    2

    The Speed of Learning about Firms Profitability and their Price Multiples: A

    Global Perspective

    Abstract

    This paper is an application of learning models in valuation of stocks listed on 52

    international stock exchanges. We present direct evidence of declining analyst forecast errors

    and return volatility with advancement in a firms age in the context of a learning model.

    Consistent with a relatively new theory of learning and unlike the traditional focus of asset

    pricing models on the discount rate in denominator, we find support for the notion that this

    reduction in uncertainty about a firms prospects affects the expected value of cash flows in the

    numerator of the valuation equation. This results in an inverse and convex relation between a

    firms age and its market-to-book ratio. The valuation effects of learning are pervasive over time

    and across countries, and are stronger for firms that do not pay dividends. We also find that the

    speed of learning about firms profitability and its impact on valuation varies in economies with

    diverse market designs and legal frameworks. Forecast errors are lower with strict enforcement

    of laws prohibiting insider trading, higher feasibility of short selling, and dominance of local

    versus foreign investors. These features also increase the learning speed and fuel quicker

    achievement of long run equilibrium valuations.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    3/35

    3

    Capital markets play an important role in the economic development of any country. Well

    functioning markets ensure that both corporations and investors pay or receive fair prices for

    their securities. This equilibrium assures that valuable projects are financed and negative present

    value projects are rejected. In this framework, valuation of equity securities involves discounting

    the profits (dividends, earnings, or cash flows) the stock brings to the stockholder in the

    foreseeable future, and a final value upon disposition.

    Much of the financial research, including the seminal CAPM and Fama-French (1995) 3-

    factor model, is focused on the discount rate and its equity risk premium component. Formulas

    for arriving at the profitability of a firm are in place as well. The calculations, however, depend

    heavily on accurate forecasts of the firms revenues and expenses. Forecasting the future demand

    for a firms products and its future competitive position accurately is indeed a big challenge. Bulk

    of the finance literature implicitly assumes that since the negative errors in forecasting may be

    offset by an equal amount of positive errors, such errors may be inconsequential in valuing

    stocks at the portfolio level.

    Only recently, Pastor and Veronesi (2003) suggest that the uncertainty about future

    profitability and forecasting errors, even if symmetric around zero, affect asset prices and

    valuations because of convexity in asset pricing formula. The gains from a positive surprise in

    firms earnings growth asymmetrically outweigh the losses from a negative surprise of the same

    magnitude. They predict that the ratio of market value to book value (M/B) declines with firms

    age by assuming that investors learn about its expected future profitability with the

    advancements in a firms age.

    The goal of this study is to enhance our understanding of the learning process and its

    valuation implications along several dimensions. First, we establish the validity of the existence

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    4/35

    4

    of a learning process and declining uncertainties by directly testing for any changes in analyst

    forecast errors with advancements in a firms age. This is an important link in the learning theory

    not yet tested explicitly. Second, we present pervasive international evidence of the valuation

    implications of the learning theory from firms listed in 52 stock exchanges around the world. Our

    third contribution deals with a subtle extension of the concept of speed of learning beyond firm

    specific characteristics. We do confirm the differences in the learning process for dividend

    paying and non-dividend paying firms, in international samples. We then extend that logic to

    demonstrate differences in the learning process and its valuation implications in economies with

    diverse market designs and legal frameworks. In our panel data analysis, the effects of market

    restructuring are particularly interesting to analyze. There have been some significant changes in

    the financial environment in recent years. Examples include stricter enforcement of laws

    prohibiting insider trading laws, ever changing restrictions on short-selling constraints, and

    increased involvement of sophisticated foreign institutional traders in global markets. Important

    empirical questions arise as a result. Does a systematic pattern of learning exist in all markets?

    Does the speed of learning change with significant variations in financial market regulations and

    foreign investor participation? We develop these hypothesis and provide a related literature

    review in section I of the paper.

    We then address these issues empirically in a cross-country setting by analyzing a

    universe of 22,858 international firms and its various subsets based on data availability in

    Datastream international and I/BE/S international. Data sources are sample characteristics are

    shown in section II. In that section, we also present the results of our data analysis. Both analyst

    forecast errors and return volatility decline with advancement of firms age. This is a direct

    evidence of a learning curve for analysts and stock market investors in the global markets.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    5/35

    5

    Consistent with the asset pricing model based on learning, M/B ratio declines with the resolution

    of uncertainty with advancement in firms age. The valuation effects of learning are pervasive

    over time and across countries, and are stronger for firms that do not pay dividends. We also find

    that the speed of learning about firms profitability and its impact on valuation varies in

    economies with diverse market designs and legal frameworks. Forecast errors are lower with

    strict enforcement of laws prohibiting insider trading, higher feasibility of short selling, and

    dominance of local versus foreign investors. These features also increase the learning speed and

    fuel quicker achievement of long run equilibrium valuations. However, some features such as

    short selling introduce additional noise in emerging markets that outweigh the benefits of

    speedier learning about negative news.

    We summarize our findings and discuss some potentially fruitful directions for further

    research in section III.

    I. Testable Hypotheses

    H10: The Learning Process:There is a reduction in uncertainty about the profitability of a

    firm with advancement in its age:

    0 1

    where 2represents the uncertainty about profitability. New firms tend to possess high degree of

    uncertainty about their product demand, revenue stream, operational cost, cash flow and

    profitability. These uncertainties can manifest themselves in higher analyst forecast errors in the

    early year of the firms existence. With the passage of time, such uncertainties resolve as the firm

    goes through the concrete implementation of its business plans. The analysts can also forecast

    the firms profitability more accurately with the advancement in firms age with more data

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    6/35

    6

    availability on actual historic performance of the firms and its financial results. Markov and

    Tamayo (2006) and Linnainmaa and Torous (2009) develop models to explain predictability of

    analyst forecast errors based on a learning process, although their focus is on separating learning

    from irrationality at the analyst level. We conduct original and direct cross-country tests of

    aggregate learning by investigating the relation between median analyst forecast error from

    I/B/E/S international and firm age.

    Valuation Model that includes the Numerator Effect of Uncertainty: The learning curve

    in the financial markets around the world affects firms valuations if the effects of uncertainty

    are explicitly modeled. Pastor and Veronesi (2003) predict higher M/B ratios for younger firms

    due to greater uncertainty about their future profitability. The genesis of this relationship is the

    convexity in the following valuation equation:

    ])2/exp[(]}){exp[( 2 TrgTrgEB

    M+== (2)

    whereM/B stands for market to book ratio, E{.} is the expectations operator, g is the growth rate,

    ris the stochastic discount factor, Tcan be interpreted as the time after which firm is not

    expected to grow at an abnormal rate, exp stands for exponential, It is a mathematical property of

    this equation that M/B increases in 2

    because of the convex relationship between growth rate

    and valuation resulting from the convexity of compounding. Innovation is good and innovative

    firms are valued highly even when their profitability is highly uncertain. The absolute wealth

    increases associated with growth rates one unit about average dominate the absolute wealth

    decrease associated with growth rates one unit below average. With learning, such uncertainties

    reduce over time.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    7/35

    7

    H20: Valuation Implication of the Learning Curve: Thus, the theoretical prediction about the

    effect of learning on valuations is that, ceteris paribus, M/B declines with the advancement in a

    firms age:

    /

    0

    /

    0 3

    Previous literature has confirmed this relationship for U.S. stocks. We present

    comprehensive tests of this hypothesis in a global setting.

    Speed of Learning: We formulate the concept of speed of learning for a given change in

    the learning environment (E) as the change in the rate of reduction of uncertainty in analyst in

    each year of a firms life as follows:

    4

    We examine three specific learning environment variables. The first variable relates to

    the laws prohibiting insider trading. Stricter enforcement of such laws could either slow the

    learning process or speed it up depending on the trade-off between internal and external sources

    of information. On the one hand such laws eliminate arguably the most informed participants

    (insiders) from affecting the learning grounds. This effect can slow the learning process. On the

    other hand, the persistence of insider trading poses puts everyone else at a relative disadvantage;

    a disincentive for equity research analysts and expert investors that could drive them away from

    spending efforts towards learning about firms profitability. Empirical analysis is necessary to

    determine which of these two effects dominate. We divide the firms years into those before and

    those after the first enforcement of insider trading law in each country. The cut-off year for each

    country is taken from Bhattacharya and Daouk (2002) and is reproduced in Appendix 1.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    8/35

    8

    The second aspect of the learning environment is the feasibility of short-selling in a

    market. The ability to short-sell is an important tool for arbitrageurs or analysts to exploit both

    positive and negative news about a firm. Without this tool, there are limited incentives to search

    for negative information about stocks that one does not own. As a result, we conjecture that the

    feasibility of short-selling helps sharpen up the learning process. We divide the sample into

    markets where short selling is feasible versus those where it is infeasible. This information is

    obtained from Charoenrook and Daouk (2005). They study the impact of short selling constraints

    on the cost of equity (the discounting rate in asset pricing models, which is a denominator effect)

    whereas our focus on reduction in uncertainty of the cash flows through learning (a numerator

    effect). Short selling facility is likely to enhance the learning process by rewarding both positive

    and negative findings about the prospects of a stock.

    The third aspect of learning environment that we analyze is the intensity of involvement

    of foreign institutional traders in a countrys stock markets. Foreign investors can speed up

    learning process because they can bring more sophisticated research skills into the country.

    However, the involvement of foreign institutions is also associated with factors that can

    introduce a lot of noise in the valuation process and slow down learning. Such factors include

    capital flight, language barriers, and deviation of systemic or idiosyncratic foreign factors from

    domestic factors. Empirical investigation can help us understand whether foreign institutions add

    more speed or more noise to the learning process. Of the 52 countries in our sample, only 40

    countries have foreign institutional trading data available in the Plexus database.1

    Thus, a

    reduced sample is analyzed for this set of regressions. We divide the total dollar volume of all

    trades undertaken by foreign institutions in a country by the total market capitalization of that

    1 The details of Plexus dataset are described in Chiyachantana et al. (2004).

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    9/35

    9

    countrys stock market. Based on the median of this measure we divide the sample into countries

    with high versus low foreign institution involvement.

    These arguments lead us to the following hypothesis which we test by comparing the rate

    of decrease in analyst forecast errors over time, across markets which possess stricter versus

    weaker learning environment.

    H30:Learning Environment: Various aspects of the learning environment affect the speed

    learning by the investors.

    We test this hypothesis separately for each aspect of the learning environment. For

    example, the tests for the effect of short selling compares the rate of decrease in analyst errors

    over time in markets with feasible short selling with the decrease in markets with restricted short

    selling.

    Following Corollary 4 about dividend paying versus non-dividend paying firms in Pastor

    and Veronesi (2003), we generalize the valuation implications of speed of learning for other firm

    characteristics and market design. The valuation effects of a change in the speed of learning

    resulting from a given change in the learning environment (E) is measured as the change in the

    slope of M/B ratio in each year of a firms life as follows:

    /

    5

    We test the valuation implications of differential learning environments by separately estimating

    the coefficients of the learning model for the three aspects of stricter versus weaker enforcement

    of insider trading regulation, short selling feasibility, and involvement of foreign institutional

    investors.

    II. Data and Empirical results

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    10/35

    10

    Our main data sources are I/B/E/S International and Datastream International. We obtain

    data item forecast period (FPEDATS), stock ticker symbol (TICKER) mean analyst forecasted

    EPS (MEANEST), number of analysts or forecasters (NUMEST) for the stock for the given

    period, and actual EPS (data ACTUAL) for each firm from I/B/E/S summary file for 12,453 US

    firms and 21,271 international firms for each available year and then focus on the period from

    1981 to 2004. We obtain market to book ratio (data item mnemonic MTBV), dividend per share

    (DPS), total assets (DWTA), return on equity (DWRE), long term debt (account item 321), stock

    return index (RI), and stock price (P) for 22,858 international firms from Datastream

    International. We verify the accuracy of this historical data by comparing it with Compustat

    Global datasets and Yahoo Finance for one company in each country. The next important item

    we need is the age of each firm. Direct information on this variable is not available in any

    traditional dataset. Therefore, we follow Fama and French (2001) and Pastor and Veronesi

    (2003) and use the year of first appearance of any variable for a firm in the dataset as its year of

    birth.2

    A. Evidence of learning process in a univariate setting

    Table 1 provides preliminarily evidence consistent with Hypothesis 1 along two dimensions.

    First, we investigate whether there is a long-run declining trend of analyst forecast errors over

    time. Analyst forecast errors is computed as the absolute difference between mean year-end

    forecast and actual year-end EPS, divided by the absolute actual EPS. Panel A shows that

    median analyst forecast error is 20.69% for 1 year old US firms and 11.42% for 20 year old US

    2 In Datastream, annual price tends to be the variable that becomes available first. As a result, the definition of age in

    our study is based primarily on the first year the annual price is available. This information is used to allocate the

    firm to an age category in our panel dataset. We start this process from the year 1969 which is the first year ofavailability of price data in Datastream for UK firms. Our sample ends in the year 2004 implying that the maximum

    age that any firm can attain in our sample is 36 years. Book value data becomes available in Datastream only from

    the year 1981, which practically becomes the beginning date for all of our empirical analyses based on M/B ratio.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    11/35

    11

    firms.3

    The difference of 9.27% between the two median errors is statistically significant at 1%

    level and can be interpreted as the cumulative amount of learning. This finding verifies an

    important but untested assumption implicit in the Pastor and Veronesi (2003) learning model that

    investor learn about firms profitability with advancement in its age. In Panel B, we establish that

    the learning process is omnipresent in the worldwide sample of firms. The cumulative magnitude

    of learning is 9.08% in the international sample is very similar to the US sample although in

    international firms in any given age group have larger errors than the US firms.

    [Insert Table 1 about here]

    Another dimension of uncertainty about the firms profitability is its return volatility. We

    compute return volatility as the standard deviation of monthly returns of each stock in each year

    of observation. Panel C of Table 1 shows that return volatility declines with advancement is a

    firms age. Median return volatility is 11.89% for 1 year old firms and 7.75% for 20 year old

    firms. The difference between the two groups is 4.13%, which is statistically significant at the

    1% level.

    B.Country-wise analysis of the impact of the learning process on firms price multiples

    The value implication of the learning process is declining M/B ratio with advancement in

    a firms age, as stated in our second hypothesis, Table presents the median M/B ratio in 52

    countries for firms in ages ranging from one to 10 ten years. Ratios for US firms, shown in bold

    font, are reproduced from the Pastor and Veronesi (2003) article. Our international evidence is

    consistent with the patterns found in their study and serve to establish the pervasive global

    3 The forecast errors are low in the IPO year of the firms, jump up in year 2 and then decline monotonically giving

    the error curve a hump-shape. Reasons for low errors in the IPO year could include the fact the costs in the projectbuild-up stage (when there are usually no revenues) could be easier to forecast than the combination of revenues and

    costs in the subsequent years. The legal consequence of erroneous predictions in the IPO prospectus are also more

    severe than the analyst forecast errors in subsequent errors.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    12/35

    12

    application of valuation implications of the learning model. For the overall sample, median M/B

    of 1 year old firms is 1.99 compared to M/B of 1.27 for 10 year old firms. The difference of 0.72

    between the two groups reported in the second last column is statistically significant at the 1%

    level. We present country-wise data for each of the 52 countries. The countries are grouped into

    developed and emerging markets based on the classification obtained from Morgan Stanley

    Capital Internationals website at mscidata.com. The direction of the change in M/B is consistent

    with the learning model in 46 out of the 52 countries or 88% of our sample and the difference is

    statistically significant in 43 countries or 83% of the sample countries. The countries with some

    of the biggest learning effects include Netherlands, Japan, and France among the developed

    markets and Egypt, Thailand, and Morocco among the emerging markets. We corroborate these

    country-wise findings on the valuation implications of the learning process in multivariate

    settings in the following sections.

    [Insert Table 2 about here]

    C. Multivariate analysis of the valuation implications of the learning model

    Next we perform a international panel data regressions to confirm the significance of the

    inverse relationship between M/B and firms age controlling for other factors that are known to

    affect M/B4.:

    log(M/B)i,t = a + b.AGEi,t + c.DDi,t + d.LEVi,t + e.SIZEi,t + f.ROEi,t + g.ROE(1)i,t

    + h.ROE(2)i,t + i.ROE(3)i,t + j.RET(1)i,t + k.RET(2)i,t + l.RET(3)i,t+ m.RET(3)i,t + i,t (6)

    where i = 1- N, N is the # of firms in each year t. AGE is defined as - 1/ (1+ Firms Age) as this

    specification captures the convexity in the relationship between M/B and firm age in accordance

    with Pastor and Veronesis (2003) learning model. DD is the dividend dummy with value 1 for

    4 For all regression analyses, we winsorize observations with any variable at the 1st and 99th percentile, to arrive at

    the final sample. Firms which were born in the year 2002 onwards are also excluded as we need three years of data

    for future ROE and annual stock returns.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    13/35

    13

    dividend paying firm and 0 otherwise. LEV is the debt ratio. SIZE is the natural log of the firms

    total asset. Pastor and Veronesi (2003) utilize the Bayesian updating technique in their learning

    model to predict the relationship between expected profitability (positive) and expected future

    stock returns (negative) and Market-to-book ratio. In our regression, ROE is the return on equity

    and regressed up to three years following year t. RET is future annual stock return up to three

    years from current period. The standard errors are clustered by firm to take into account residual

    dependence created by firm effect, as suggested by Petersen (2009).5

    The results are provided in

    Table 3.

    [Insert Table 3 about here]

    The global prevalence of inverse relationship between M/B ratio and the firms age

    implied by the learning model is confirmed in the regression framework where the coefficient on

    age is -0.81 with a t-statistics of -17.22, which makes it highly significant at the 1% level. The

    magnitude of the coefficient compares well with the benchmark for NYSE stocks during 1962 to

    2000 analyzed by Pastor and Veronesi (2003). They report the AGE coefficient of -0.71 which

    translates into a economically significant 12.5 percent difference in valuation between the one

    and two years old firm. The coefficients on control variables are in the expected direction. There

    is a positive relation between future growth in profitability and the M/B ratio implying that

    investors pay a higher price for firms with higher growth prospects (g). Future stock returns are

    negatively correlated with current M/B ratio implying that investors are willing to accept a lower

    equity premium (r) by paying a higher stock price today for the high M/B stocks. It is important

    5 In line with Pastor and Veronesi (2003), we also perform Fama and Macbeth(1973) regression to deal withpotential time effect in our study and arrive at the same conclusion as clustered standard errors method reported in

    the Tables. The Fama and Macbeth(1973) results are not presented for brevity but are available upon request.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    14/35

    14

    to note that the effect of uncertainty of profitability (2), measured through firm age, survives in

    these regressions after controlling for these other important determinants of M/B ratio.

    We also divide our sample into developed and emerging markets. The coefficient on age

    is more negative in the emerging markets. One interpretation of this finding is that the lower

    quality of disclosures in emerging markets increases the uncertainties about the cash flows of the

    new companies. Therefore, investors have to learn more from the companys actual cash flows

    than from the financial projections. The other interesting insight includes a stronger preference

    for dividend payments in emerging markets. M/B ratio is 0.14 times higher for dividend paying

    firms in emerging market relative to non-dividend paying firms. On the contrary, M/B ratio is

    lower by 0.16 times for dividend paying firms in developed market relative to non-dividend

    paying firms in those markets. Results in all panels of table 3 are consistent with our second

    hypothesis.

    D. Dividend vs Non-dividend paying firms

    Dividend payments have two opposite effects on the M/B ratio in the context of learning.

    The positive effect of dividend payments is a quicker reduction in the uncertainty about the cash

    flows that investors receive from younger firms. A bird in hand is better than two in the bush.

    The company can lose undistributed profits in future but it cannot reclaim distributed dividends

    because of the limited liability feature. Moreover, managers tend to smooth dividend payments

    over time. Thus, dividend policy can release information to the outside investors about

    managements expectations of future profitability. These uncertainty dampening effects of

    dividend payment would increase the correlation due to a higher speed of learning. However, the

    opposite effect in the context of learning is that dividend payments reduce the firms growth rate

    (Pastor and Veronesi (2003)) and thus convexity. Reduced uncertainty also lowers convexity and

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    15/35

    15

    correlations of dividend paying firms. The net result of these two effects is an empirical issue

    which we examine in Table 4.

    [Insert Table 4 about here]

    An extended version of regression equation (6) is used to capture the incremental effect

    of dividend payments on the learning process. We now have an interaction term between AGE

    and dividend dummy, in addition to the other variables discussed previously. Overall, dividend

    payment has an important role in determining the strength of the relationship between M/B and

    the firms age. In developed markets, dividend payments weaken the convexity of the M/B to

    age relationship, consistent with Pastor and Versoni (2003) prediction of lower growth rate of

    dividend paying firms.The coefficient on the interaction term of age times dividend dummy is

    positive 0.56 and statistically significant in Panel A for the entire sample and 0.60 and

    statistically significant in Panel B for the developed markets. However, in emerging markets

    dividend payments do not significantly affect the learning phenomenon. The interaction term has

    an insignificant coefficient of 0.079 with a t-statistics of 0.43.It is possible that uncertainty

    reduction effects of dividends in the emerging markets offset the growth dampening effect.

    E. Analyst forecast errors and the learning environment

    We now merge the firm-specific and country-specific information from the various data

    sources i.e. I/B/E/S, Datastream International, and learning environment values for each country

    for each year. The purpose of this exercise is to understand the incremental effects of each

    variable and also how a change in a given feature of the learning environment affects the

    learning process and its valuation implications. Only those firm-year or country-year

    observations which are present in all three data sources are included.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    16/35

    16

    We test if the mean analyst error is related to a firms age. Table 5 presents several variations of

    regression results all of which point to an inverse relationship between analyst errors and firms

    age. Each observation represents a firm-year. Dependent variable is the analyst forecast error

    throughout this table. Results in Panel A are based on all countries. The first row uses only firm

    age as the explanatory variables; the second row adds control variables commonly used in

    analyst forecast literature such as Thomas (2002); and the third row adds control variables from

    the learning model. Results for sub-samples based on developed market are in Panel B, emerging

    markets in Panel C, and just the U.S. in Panel D. The coefficient on age is negative and

    statistically significant in each row. This finding is consistent with the learning curve stated in

    the first hypothesis. The coefficients on the control variables are generally consistent with prior

    literature and can be interpreted as follows. Firm size matters; the bigger the firm, the smaller are

    the errors. Consistent with previous studies, analyst forecast errors decline with the number of

    analysts, whereas they increase with leverage and return volatility. With all these control

    variables included in the regression, the negative relationship between analyst forecast errors and

    firm age is still significant at the 1% level. Our findings represent the first large scale worldwide

    evidence of the existence of a learning curve for the equity analysts.

    [Insert Table 5 about here]

    Next, we turn our attention to three different features of the learning environment in each

    country to analyze how they affect the learning process. These features are a history of actual

    enforcement and convictions under laws prohibiting insider trading laws, feasibility of executing

    short sales by investors who possess negative information but do not own the stock, and above

    median involvement of sophisticated foreign institutional traders in a country. For each feature,

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    17/35

    17

    we define a learning environment indictor dummy variable (E) and assign it the value of 1 for the

    country-years when that feature is present and 0 if it is absent.

    There is a rich cross-sectional variation as well as time-series variation in the learning

    environment features across countries. At the beginning of our sample in 1981, the proportion of

    firms from countries where prohibition against insider trading was enforced is 11% and this

    proportion increases to 84% by 2004. The proportion of firms from countries where short selling

    is feasible changes from 96% in 1981 to 72% in 2004. Although this statistic might seem odd,

    but it is a manifestation of the typical regulatory response to major market crashes. Thus, not

    many countries thought about restricting short sales until 1987, when a host of restrictions were

    considered by the regulators. Many restrictions are removed after a significant amount of time

    elapses after a major crash. Thus, short selling feasibility has a tremendous amount of cross

    sectional and time series variation in our sample. Finally, the proportion of firms-years where

    foreign institutional holding is above median is constant at 50% for each year by definition.

    We estimate the analyst forecast error regressions similar to Table 5 again but after

    adding the interactive learning environment * age variables among the explanatory variables and

    report the results in Table 6. Separate regressions are estimated to assess the effect of each

    learning environment variable. Negative coefficient should be interpreted as faster speed of

    learning.

    [Insert Table 6 about here]

    Enforcement of insider trading law speeds up the rate of decline of analyst forecast errors

    with advancement in a firms age. Thus, the incentives for outside analysts to generate profitable

    information outweigh any information losses from eliminating corporate insiders from the price

    discovery process. Regulators should, therefore, enact insider trading prohibitions and

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    18/35

    18

    enthusiastically prosecute insider trading cases. Feasibility of executing short sell transactions is

    another market environment feature that speeds up the rate of decline of analyst forecast errors

    with advancement in a firms age. This finding is consistent with our hypothesis that short selling

    creates bigger incentives for learning about both positive and negative information about a firms

    profitability. In contrast, the involvement of foreign institutional investors appears to generates

    higher errors for older firms, which is inconsistent with the notion of a learning curve. Thus, it

    appears that the noise introduced by factors such as capital flight, language barriers, or deviation

    of systemic or idiosyncratic foreign factors from domestic factors outweigh the sophistication

    and skill that foreign investors might bring to a stock research in a given country.

    F. Valuation implications of the learning environment and the speed of learning

    Finally, we estimate an incremental effect regression model similar to one proposed by He and

    Ng (1998) to investigate the incremental effect of learning environments on learning speed,

    which is captured by the negative and convex relationship between the rate of change in M/B

    ratio (i.e., log(M/B)t - log(M/B)t-1) and the firms age :

    Rate of Change of Valuation = cd0E + cd1E AGEi + cd2E DIVi + cd3E.LEVi +cd4E.SIZEi + cd5E ROEi + cd6E ROE(1)i + cd7E ROE(2)i + cd8E ROE(3)i + cd9E

    RET(1)i + cd10E RET(2)i + cd11E RET(3)i + c0 + c1AGEi + c2DDi + c3LEVi +

    c4SIZEi + c5ROEi + c6ROE(1)i + c7ROE(2)i + c8ROE(3)i + c9RET(1)i + c10RET(2)i +c11D RET(3)i + i

    where (i = 1- N, N is the # of firms). AGE is defined as - 1/ (1+ Firms Age), which captures the

    convex relationship between M/B and firm age in the Pastor and Veronesi (2003) learning

    model. DIV is the dividend dummy with value 1 for dividend paying firm and 0 otherwise. LEV

    is the debt ratio. SIZE is the natural log of the firms totol asset. ROE is the return on equity and

    regressed up to three years following year t. RET is future annual stock return up to three years

    from current period. E represents learning environment dummy variable. E equals 1 for better

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    19/35

    19

    learning environment and 0 otherwise as described in the previous section. All variables of firms

    in each country are measured in its own currency. There are 9,640 firms (68,034 firm-year

    observations) with valid data for the whole sample, and 6,631 and 3,009 representing developed

    and emerging markets respectively. All t-statistics reported in parentheses are based on clustered

    standard errors as suggested by Petersen (2009). For brevity, we report only three regression

    coefficients, AGE, E, and AGE*E. Panel A is based on full dataset whereas Panel B and Panel C

    are based on developed market and emerging market sub-samples, respectively. Three separate

    regressions are reported in each panel, one for each learning environment.

    [Insert Table 7 about here]

    The negative coefficient on AGE variable in every panel establishes the inverse and

    convex relation between M/B and firm age. The second column is simply the direct effect of a

    particular type of regulation on valuation. Note that the coefficients in the second column only

    capture the level of valuations and are not related to the learning model because the learning

    model requires an interaction with firm age. From the overall sample used in Panel A, we

    observe that all three features of the learning environment have positive coefficient. Thus, we

    conclude enforcement of insider trading laws, feasibility of short selling transaction, increased

    presence of foreign institutional investors, are all associated with higher stock valuations. Thus

    in the valuation sense, these features are good. However, to assess the impact of these features on

    the speed of learning and change in M/B, we interact firm age with learning environment

    dummy. The coefficients are in the third column. Negative coefficients represent faster speed

    according to the learning model. Negative coefficient suggests that enforcement of insider

    trading speeds up the learning process whereas positive coefficients for short selling and foreign

    investors suggest that those features actually slow the learning process. In Panel B for developed

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    20/35

    20

    markets and Panel C for emerging markets, we see that the results are consistent with overall

    results for speedier learning with enforcement of insider trading and slower learning with above

    median foreign institutional investors. However, the short selling activities have opposite effects

    in developed versus emerging markets. Short selling appears to speed up the learning process

    only in developed markets. In emerging markets short selling is slowing the learning process

    through additional noise. The overall conclusion from the table is consistent with our third

    hypothesis which states that various features of learning environment matter as determinants of

    the speed of learning.

    G. Robustness tests

    We conduct several robustness checks to verify that our findings can be generalized.

    Tables are not included in the manuscript for brevity but will be available from authors or data

    section of the journal website, if this facility is provided. Earlier in Tables 1 and 2, we showed

    that the decline in analyst forecast errors and M/B ratio with the advancement of firms age is

    pervasive across markets and countries. We also conduct year-by-year analysis and find that the

    in any given year, the analyst forecast errors and M/B ratio are lower for older firms than those

    for younger firms.

    III. Conclusion

    This paper provides pervasive global evidence consistent with an intriguing valuation

    theory that takes into account a learning curve for stock market analysts and investors. The

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    21/35

    21

    valuation model proposed by Pastor and Veronesi (2003) assumes that investors face significant

    uncertainty about profitability and cash flows of young firms. Unlike the traditional focus of

    asset pricing models on the denominator or discount rates, they focus on how the uncertainty

    affects the expected value of cash flows in the numerator. The convex nature of valuation

    equation implies that the uncertainty actually increases the M/B. However, as time passes,

    investors learn about the true potential of firms profitability and resolve the uncertainty. Thus,

    the model predicts that M/B is higher for younger firms than for older firms.

    In this paper, we provide a comprehensive empirical analysis of this issue in a global

    setting. By directly showing that analyst forecast errors decline with advancements in a firms

    age, we provide an important link in the learning theory not yet tested globally in the empirical

    literature. Return volatility of stocks in global, developed, and emerging markets also decreases

    with a firms age. Next, we present pervasive international evidence of the valuation implications

    of the learning theory from firms listed in 52 stock exchanges around the world. Over eighty

    percent of the countries have statistically significant valuation changes consistent with the

    learning theory. This inverse and convex relationship between M/B and firm age is statistically

    significant in the regression framework after controlling for other factors known to determine the

    market-to-book ratio such as future growth potential and expected equity premium. The inverse

    relationship between M/B and firms age is also more striking for non-dividend paying firms.

    We extend the concept of speed of learning beyond firm specific characteristics to

    understand the impact of diverse market designs and legal frameworks on the learning process.

    The three key learning environment features included in our analysis are stricter enforcement of

    laws prohibiting insider trading laws, ever changing restrictions on short-selling constraints, and

    increased involvement of sophisticated foreign institutional traders in global markets.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    22/35

    22

    Enforcement of insider trading law speeds up the rate of decline of analyst forecast errors with

    advancement in a firms age, and firms are valued at their long run equilibrium values more

    quickly. Thus, the incentives for outside analysts to generate profitable information outweigh any

    information losses from eliminating corporate insiders from the price discovery process.

    Regulators should, therefore, enact insider trading prohibitions and enthusiastically prosecute

    insider trading cases. Feasibility of executing short sell transactions is another market

    environment feature that speeds up the rate of decline of analyst forecast errors with

    advancement in a firms age. This finding is consistent with our hypothesis that short selling

    creates bigger incentives for learning about both positive and negative information about a firms

    profitability. However, the short selling activities have opposite valuation effects in developed

    versus emerging markets suggesting that this feature might be introduce more noise in emerging

    markets outweighing the uncertainty resolution effects. Finally, the involvement of foreign

    institutional investors appears to generate higher errors for older firms, which is inconsistent with

    the notion of a learning curve. Thus, it appears that the noise introduced by factors such as

    capital flight, language barriers, or deviation of systemic or idiosyncratic foreign factors from

    domestic factors outweigh the sophistication and skill that foreign investors might bring to a

    stock research in a given country. When domestic investors dominate, learning speed is faster

    and M/B valuation ratio approaches long term equilibrium faster.

    rmFuture research can explore additional determinants of the speed of learning and also

    develop more advanced theoretical constructs for this concept. The results in this paper implore

    that asset pricing models include the learning curve as an important factor. The learning process

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    23/35

    23

    about firms profitability has important implications for stock valuation in countries around the

    world.

    References

    Bekaert, Geert, and Campbell R. Harvey, 1995, Time-varying world market integration,Journal of

    Finance 50, 403-444.

    Bekaert, Geert, and Campbell Harvey, 2000, Foreign speculators and emerging equity markets,

    Journal of Finance 55, 565-613.

    Bhattacharya, Utpal, and Hazem Daouk, 2002, The world price of insider trading, Journal of Finance

    57, 75-108.

    Chan, Louis K., Yasushi Hamao, and Josef Lakonishok, 1991, Fundamentals and Stock Returns in

    Japan,Journal of Finance 46, 1739-1764.

    Charoenrook, A. and H. Daouk, 2005, A Study of Market-Wide Short-Selling Restrictions, Working

    paper,. http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract_id=687562.

    Chiyachantana, Chiraphol N., Pankaj K. Jain, Christine Jiang, and Robert A. Wood, 2004,

    International evidence on institutional trading behavior and determinants of price impact,

    Journal of Finance 59, 865-894.

    Compaq Handbook of World Stock, Derivative and Commodity Exchanges, 2001, Financial

    Publications, UK.

    Daniel, Kent and Sheridan Titman, 1997. Evidence on the characteristics of cross sectional

    variation in stock returns.Journal of Finance 52, 1-33.

    Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth French, 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns,

    Journal of Finance 47, 427-465.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    24/35

    24

    Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth French, 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on bonds and

    stocks,Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56.

    Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth French, 1995. Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and

    returns. The Journal of Finance 50, 131-155.

    Griffin, John M. and Andrew G. Karolyi, 1998, Another Look at the Role of the Industrial Structure

    of Markets for International Diversification Strategies,Journal of Financial Economics 50,

    351- 373.

    He, J and L. Ng, 1998, The Foreign Exchange Exposure of Japanese Multinational Corporations,

    Journal of Finance, 53, 733 753.

    Henry, Peter B., 2000, Stock market liberalization, economic reform, and emerging market equity

    prices,Journal of Finance 55, 529-564.

    Jain, Pankaj K., 2005, Financial market design and equity premium, Floor versus electronic trading,

    Forthcoming, Journal of Finance.

    Lakonishok, Josef, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1992, Contrarian investment,

    extrapolation, and risk,Journal of Finance 49, 1541-1578.

    Linnainmaa, Juhani T. and Walter N. Torous, 2009, Reading the tea leaves: Why serial correlation

    patterns in analyst forecast errors are not evidence of inefficient information processing.

    University og Chicago Working Paper.

    Markov, Stanimir and Ane Tamayo, 2006, Predictibility in financial analyst forecast errors,Journal

    of Accounting Research 44, 725-761.

    Pastor, Lubos, and Pietro Veronesi, 2003, Stock Valuation and Learning about Profitability,Journal

    of Finance 58, 1749-1789.

    Petersen, M., 2009, Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel Data Sets: Comparing

    Approaches,Review of Financial Studies 22, 435480.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    25/35

    25

    Shefrin, Hersh and Meir Statman, 1995, Making Sense of Beta, Size, and Book-to-market,

    Journal of Portfolio Management21, 26-34.

    Thomas, Shawn, 2002, Firm Diversification and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from

    Analysts Forecasts and Earnings Announcements, Journal of Financial Economics,

    2002, 64, 373-396.

    World Federation of Exchanges (formerly known as the International Federation of Stock

    Exchanges FIBV) archives at www.fibv.com.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    26/35

    TABLE 1. The Learning process: Declining uncertainty with advancement in firms age

    We obtain mean analyst forecasted EPS and actual EPS for each firm from I/B/E/S international dataseforecast errors is computed as the absolute difference between mean forecast and actual EPS, divided b

    Data are winsorized at 1st

    percentile and 99th

    percentile to eliminate potential outliers and input errors. T

    in the database is used as a proxy for the firms year of birth for the purposes of calculating its age. Each

    are grouped together. Panel A used only 12,453 US firms and shows the median analyst forecast errors group. Panel B repeats the analysis including 21,271 international firms. We obtain total monthly return

    Datastream International. Return volatility is computed as the standard deviation of monthly returns of observation. Panel C presents the median return volatility for firms within each age group. Total learnin

    year 1 and year 20. Asterisks indicate statistical significance at 1% level with ***.

    Panel A. Declining Analyst Forecast Errors for US Firms

    Firm Age in Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

    Forecast Error 20.69% 29.27% 31.56% 31.79% 30.77% 27.45% 23.99% 25.00%

    Firm Age in Years 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18

    Forecast Error 19.40% 19.12% 18.58% 17.32% 15.75% 16.34% 15.69% 13.63%Total Learning 9.27%***

    Panel B: Global Evidence on Declining Analyst Forecast Errors

    Firm Age in Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

    Forecast Error 23.08% 31.92% 33.33% 33.56% 34.49% 32.26% 30.83% 30.79%

    Firm Age in Years 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18

    Forecast Error 23.19% 23.57% 24.64% 24.14% 22.05% 24.73% 23.19% 18.88%

    Total Learning 9.08%***

    Panel C: Declining Return Volatility for Firms around the World

    Firm Age in Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

    Return Volatility 11.89% 11.32% 11.28% 11.19% 10.75% 10.64% 10.29% 9.95%

    Firm Age in Years 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18

    Return Volatility 10.02% 9.89% 9.17% 9.74% 9.38% 8.59% 8.38% 9.03%Total Reduction 4.13%***

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    27/35

    TABLE 2. Country-wise analysis of the impact of the learning process on firms price multip

    This table presents the medianmarket to book ratio (Datastream mnemonic MTBV) in 52 countries for

    one to 10 ten years. The last column shows the number of firms for which Datastream has MTBV. Data

    percentiles of MTBV to remove potential outliers and data entry errors. Sample period ranges from 198

    appearance of a firm is used as a proxy for the firms years of birth for the purposes of calculating its agshown in bold font, are reproduced from the Pastor and Veronesi (2003) article. Cumulative effect of le

    as the difference between year 1 M/B and year 10 M/B. We indicate statistical significance of the differ

    levels with ***, **, *, respectively.

    Age 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    Cum

    effec

    learn

    valua

    All firms 1.99 1.79 1.62 1.55 1.43 1.43 1.41 1.37 1.30 1.27 0

    Panel A: Developed markets

    Australia 1.68 1.55 1.38 1.40 1.20 1.48 1.43 1.56 1.36 1.33 0

    Austria 1.49 1.31 1.12 1.23 1.30 1.27 0.98 1.03 0.98 0.97 0

    Belgium 1.62 1.30 1.18 1.24 1.15 1.18 1.05 1.18 0.97 1.03 0

    Canada 1.54 1.56 1.49 1.55 1.50 1.50 1.61 1.71 1.60 1.56 -0

    Denmark 1.22 1.28 1.07 1.13 0.99 1.14 1.08 1.01 0.96 0.99 0

    Finland 1.50 1.23 1.22 1.31 1.35 1.33 1.3 1.22 1.22 1.39 0

    France 2.29 1.90 1.60 1.40 1.40 1.30 1.19 1.09 1.16 1.23

    Germany 2.37 1.95 1.55 1.32 1.33 1.69 1.90 2.10 2.11 1.86 0

    Hong Kong 1.71 1.40 1.20 1.08 0.90 0.87 0.87 0.75 0.81 0.81 0

    Ireland 1.81 1.71 1.55 1.61 1.59 1.64 1.58 1.87 1.79 1.88 -0

    Italy 1.60 1.51 1.40 1.39 1.15 1.05 0.94 0.99 1.00 0.91 0

    Japan 2.42 2.27 1.98 1.79 1.53 1.48 1.54 1.40 1.37 1.17

    Luxemboug 0.87 1.40 1.26 1.19 1.44 1.88 1.81 1.34 1.05 0.90 -0

    Netherlands 2.63 2.46 2.01 1.795 1.74 1.53 1.77 1.73 1.28 1.12

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    28/35

    TABLE 2. ..Continued.

    Age

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    New Zealand 1.36 1.22 1.07 1.02 1.02 1.03 1.04 1.31 1.35 1.30 0Norway 1.50 1.30 1.30 1.26 1.32 1.31 1.28 1.29 1.38 1.25 0Portugal 1.84 1.76 1.63 1.51 1.35 1.30 1.28 1.00 1.09 1.20 0Singapore 2.02 2.01 1.72 1.80 1.71 1.36 1.52 1.42 1.44 1.30 0Spain 1.83 1.66 1.55 1.30 1.37 1.30 1.43 1.41 1.48 1.66 0Sweden 2.07 1.99 1.90 1.70 1.45 1.55 1.59 1.55 1.49 1.61 0

    Switzerland 1.50 1.31 1.17 1.19 1.11 1.07 1.16 1.11 1.11 1.04 0

    UK 2.61 2.22 1.97 1.83 1.79 1.75 1.70 1.68 1.66 1.76 0

    USA 2.25 1.80 1.57 1.49 1.39 1.38 1.35 1.33 1.27 1.25 1

    Panel B: Emerging markets

    Argentina 1.22 1.00 1.04 1.34 1.19 0.84 0.78 0.58 0.4 0.65 0.

    Brazil 0.83 1.28 0.82 0.75 0.92 0.97 0.95 0.93 0.66 0.585 0.

    Chile 1.18 1.12 1.63 1.43 1.28 1.44 1.33 1.08 0.97 0.74 0.

    China 3.33 2.70 2.50 2.75 2.76 2.56 2.58 3.10 3.31 3.01 0.

    Colombia 1.09 0.72 0.74 0.65 0.43 0.53 0.56 0.51 0.48 0.545 0.

    Czech Rep. 0.77 1.20 1.01 0.66 0.74 0.5 0.45 0.54 0.82 0.42 0.

    Egypt 2.34 2.87 1.63 1.6 1.27 0.93 0.82 1.04 0.5 0.34 2.

    Ethiopia 2.5 1.47 2.1 2.78 2.85 2.5 1.47 2.1 2.14 2.99 -0.Greece 2.53 2.23 1.89 1.91 1.42 1.53 1.35 1.25 1.22 1.98 0.

    Hungary 1.49 1.06 1.20 1.10 0.96 0.9 0.94 0.94 0.78 0.74 0.

    India 1.84 1.85 2.01 2.16 2.12 2.23 1.54 1.34 1.04 0.89 0.

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    29/35

    TABLE 2. ..Continued.

    Age

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    C

    iv

    Indonesia 1.69 1.28 1.18 1.25 0.93 0.88 0.83 0.79 0.75 1.15 0.

    Israel 1.94 1.84 2.31 1.86 1.51 1.16 1.54 1.92 1.61 1.83 0

    Korea 1.45 1.26 1.06 0.87 0.83 0.91 0.78 0.69 0.61 0.66 0.

    Malaysia 1.47 1.44 1.42 1.50 1.28 1.17 1.12 1.29 1.41 1.40 0

    Mexico 1.23 1.49 1.25 1.19 1.13 1.19 1.11 0.97 1.06 1.00 0.

    Morocco 2.98 2.07 2.40 2.01 2.03 2.31 2.10 1.74 1.62 1.48 1.

    Pakistan 1.81 2.61 1.96 1.18 0.93 1.00 0.78 0.83 1.01 0.92 0.

    Peru 1.31 1.08 1.18 1.10 1.06 0.95 0.84 0.81 0.75 0.77 0.

    Philippines 1.86 1.75 1.39 1.21 1.29 1.24 1.14 1.02 0.81 0.8 1.

    Poland 1.13 1.10 1.12 1.20 1.12 1.33 1.28 1.31 1.04 1.00 0.

    Russia 0.39 0.30 0.62 0.31 0.43 0.37 0.36 0.30 0.65 0.19 0.

    South Africa 2.31 2.22 1.61 1.19 1.25 1.32 1.25 1.44 1.03 1.16 1.

    Sri Lanka 1.65 2.16 0.98 1.16 1.49 0.94 1.89 1.72 1.07 1.03 0.

    Taiwan 2.46 2.31 1.96 1.67 1.61 1.67 1.59 1.46 1.43 1.30 1.

    Thailand 2.64 2.33 2.08 1.61 1.57 1.52 1.28 1.13 1.01 1.06 1.

    Turkey 1.35 1.91 1.34 1.58 1.25 1.43 1.37 1.29 1.40 1.85 -0.

    Venezuela 0.21 0.49 0.41 0.37 0.85 0.42 0.53 0.58 0.22 0.27 -0.

    Zimbabwe 1.27 1.24 0.83 1.01 0.62 0.485 0.51 0.285 0.31 0.38 0.

    Number (and percentage) of countries with year 1 M/B higher than year 10 M/B Number (and percentage) of countries with statistically significant M/B changes

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    30/35

    Table 3. Clustered standard errors regression analysis on M/B ratio and the firms age for globa

    The following panel regression is estimated on pooled dataset while using clustered standard errors as

    log(M/B)i,t = a + b.AGEi,t + c.DDi,t + d.LEVi,t + e.SIZEi,t + f.ROEi,t + g.ROE(1)i,t + h.ROE(2)i,t + i.ROE(3)i,t

    + j.RET(1)i,t + k.RET(2)i,t + l.RET(3)i,t + i,t

    where (i = 1- N, N is the # of firms). M/Bi,t is the market to book ratio for firm i in period t. AGE is de

    Age), which captures the convex relationship between M/B and firm age in the Pastor and Veronesi (2

    is the dividend dummy with value 1 for dividend paying firm and 0 otherwise. LEV is the debt ratio. Sthe firms totol asset. ROE is the return on equity and regressed up to three years following year t. RE

    return up to three years from current period. i,t is the error term, which we cluster in SAS using proc sfirms in each country are measured in its own currency. These regressions are based on 10,656 interna

    historic data for all variables in the model are available in Datastream. All t-statistics are reported in p

    Intercept AGE DD LEV SIZE ROE ROE(1) ROE(2) ROE(3) RET(1) RET

    Panel A: All firms

    Coefficient 0.203 -0.813 -0.052 0.026 0.009 0.241 0.569 0.413 0.114 -0.373 -0.3

    T-statistics (5.02) (-17.22) (-3.07) (0.53) (3.70) (9.74) (19.73) (18.92) (6.86) (-45.04) (-38

    Panel B: Developed markets firms

    Coefficient 0.177 -0.686 -0.145 0.072 0.018 0.258 0.538 0.400 0.113 -0.364 -0.2

    T-statistics (4.02) (-13.00) (-7.09) (1.34) (7.21) (8.66) (15.05) (15.07) (5.42) (-36.23) (-28

    Panel C: Emerging markets firms

    Coefficient 0.569 -1.673 0.136 -0.129 -0.039 0.268 0.670 0.448 0.112 -0.413 -0.3

    T-statistics (5.58) (-16.61) (5.08) (-1.23) (-6.37) (7.07) (15.92) (12.34) (4.24) (-30.32) (-29

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    31/35

    Table 4. The effect of dividend payment on the learning process and price multiples

    The following panel data regression is estimated on pooled dataset while using clustered standard erroPetersen (2009):

    log(M/B)i,t = a + b.AGEi,t + c.DDi,t + e.DD.AGEi,t + f.LEVi,t + g.SIZEi,t + h.ROEi,t + i.RO+ k.ROE(3)i,t + l.RET(1)i,t + m.RET(2)i,t + n.RET(3)i,t + i,t

    The term DD.AGE captures the incremental effect of dividend payment on the learning process. Rest

    definitions from the previous table. The dataset is identical to one used in the previous table.Intercept AGE DD AGE.DD LEV SIZE ROE ROE(1) ROE(2) ROE(3) RET(1)

    Panel A: All Sample

    Coeff. 0.134 -1.218 0.04 0.564 0.027 0.009 0.239 0.569 0.413 0.113 -0.373

    T-stat (3.06) (-12.97) (1.50) (19.78) (0.55) (3.69) (9.73) (19.78) (18.97) (6.83) (-45.07)

    Panel B: Developed market firms

    Coeff. 0.103 -1.129 -0.05 0.60 0.072 0.018 0.257 0.539 0.401 0.113 -0.364

    T-stat (2.13) (-10.10) (-1.59) (5.07) (1.33) (7.23) (8.69) (15.12) (15.14) (5.42) (-36.30)

    Panel C: Emerging market firms

    Coeff. 0.561 -1.722 0.15 0.079 -0.129 -0.039 0.267 0.67 0.448 0.112 -0.413

    T-stat (5.23) (-11.13) (3.19) (0.43) (-1.23) (-6.37) (7.06) (15.93) (12.34) (4.24) (-30.24)

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    32/35

    Table 5. The learning process and declining analyst forecast errors with advancement in firms age

    The following OLS regression is estimated to capture the relationship between analyst forecast errors and

    FEi,t = a + b.AGEi,t + c.SIZEi,t + d.LEVi,t + e.RETVOLi,t + f.NUMESTi,t + g.DDi,t + h.ROj.ROE(2)i,t + k.ROE(3)i,t + l.RET(1)i,t + m.RET(2)i,t + n.RET(3)i,t + i,t

    where (i = 1- N, N is the # of firms). White-adjusted standard errors are used to calculate t-statistics reFE is analyst forecast error which is calculated as the (absolute) difference between median forecasted

    reported EPS scaled by the year-end stock price. AGE is defined as the natural log of age (first year o

    Datastream dataset). LEV is the debt ratio. SIZE is the natural log of the firms total asset. RETVOL iof each stock as defined by the standard deviation of monthly returns during the observation year. NU

    analysts involved in predicting EPS for the relevant period (i.e., analyst coverage). There are 14,594 f

    our Datastream-IBES merged sample.

    Intercept AGE SIZE LEV RET

    VOL

    NUMEST DD ROE ROE(1) ROE(2) ROE(3) RE

    Panel A: All Firms

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.093

    (19.70)-0.018

    (-8.57)

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.07

    (6.23)-0.014

    (-6.18)

    -0.001

    (-1.32)

    0.007

    (0.68)

    0.402

    (13.5)

    -0.002

    (-6.92)

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.092

    (7.99)-0.013

    (-5.86)

    -0.013

    (-5.86)

    0.002

    (0.17)

    0.32

    (10.1)

    -0.002

    (-6.35)

    -0.005

    (-1.14)

    -0.071

    (-9.30)

    -0.053

    (-6.17)

    -0.012

    (-1.47)

    -0.0004

    (-0.05)

    0.0

    (3.5

    Panel B: Developed markets

    CoeffT-Stat 0.087(18.69) -0.016(-7.67)

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.063

    (5.66)-0.012

    (-5.43)

    -0.001

    (-0.90)

    0.012

    (1.23)

    0.377

    (12.5)

    -0.002

    (-7.43)

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.09

    (7.73)-0.011

    (-5.04)

    -0.001

    (-0.93)

    0.005

    (0.54)

    0.284

    (8.78)

    -0.002

    (-6.80)

    -0.008

    (-1.92)

    -0.071

    (-9.44)

    -0.052

    (-6.02)

    -0.011

    (-1.40)

    -0.001

    (-0.14)

    0.0

    (2.7

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    33/35

    Table 5. Continued

    Intercept AGE SIZE LEV RET

    VOL

    NUMEST DD ROE ROE(1) ROE(2) ROE(3) RE

    Panel C: Emerging markets

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.395

    (5.96)-0.141

    (-4.12)

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.729

    (5.18)-0.136

    (-4.00)

    -0.0229

    (-3.18)

    -0.186

    (-1.25)

    0.587

    (2.58)

    0.002

    (0.85)

    CoeffT-Stat

    0.711(4.61)

    -0.132

    (-3.88)

    -0.027(-2.89)

    -0.142(-0.95)

    0.493(2.12)

    0.002(0.80)

    -0.001(-0.02)

    -0.13(-1.73)

    -0.05(-0.77)

    -0.048(-0.64)

    0.046(0.49)

    0.1(3.2

    Panel D: US market

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.066

    (19.70)-0.015

    (-9.69)

    CoeffT-Stat 0.035(4.03) -0.014(-8.91) 0.0003(-0.45) 0.043(5.93) 0.269(11.2) -0.001(-4.49)

    Coeff

    T-Stat

    0.048

    (5.31)-0.013

    (-8.31)

    0.0001

    (0.12)

    0.38

    (5.25)

    0.241

    (9.47)

    -0.001

    (-3.89)

    -0.005

    (-1.49)

    -0.056

    (-9.80)

    -0.019

    (-2.91)

    -0.009

    (-1.40)

    0.002

    (0.43)

    0.0

    (2.5

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    34/35

    Table 6. Learning environment and analyst forecast errors

    The following simple ordinary least squares regression model is estimated to capture therelationship between analyst forecast errors and firm age:

    FEi,t = a + b.Sizei,t + c.Leveragei,t + d.Return Volatilityi,t + e.Number of Analystsi,t

    + f.ENVIRONMENT.AGEi,t + g.ANTI.ENVIRONMENT.AGE i,t + i,t

    where FEi,t is analyst forecast error for firm i in yeart, which is calculated as the (absolute)

    difference between median forecasted EPS and the actually reported EPS scaled by theactual EPS. Size is the natural log of the firms total asset. Leverage is the debt ratio.

    Return Volatility is simple return volatility of each stock as defined by the standard

    deviation of monthly returns during the observation year. Number of analysts involved inpredicting EPS for the relevant period is the proxy for analyst coverage. Age is defined as

    the plain age (first year of appearance on the Datastream dataset). Separate regressions are

    estimated for each learning environment. For insider trading law, Environment equals 1 if

    insider trading law is enforced and 0 otherwise. Anti.Environement is the complement ofenvironment. Both environment and anti.environment are interacted with AGE. The

    interactive variables are computed analogously for the other two learning environment

    features. For shortsell feasibility, environment equals 1 if shortselling transactions areallowed and 0 otherwise. For foreign trading, environment equals 1 if foreign institutional

    traders are active in the countrys market and 0 otherwise. All variables of firms in each

    country are measured in its own currency. There are 20,416 firm-year observations in ourDatastream-IBES merged sample. We use White-adjusted standard errors to calculate t-

    statistics reported in the parentheses.

    Analyst Errors

    when Insider

    trading law is

    enforced

    Analyst Errors

    when Shortselling

    is feasible

    Analyst Errors

    when Foreign

    trading is above

    median

    Intercept 0.115(9.50)

    0.114(9.41)

    0.116(9.79)

    Size -0.016

    (-8.28)

    -0.015

    (-7.46)

    -0.016

    (-8.47)

    Leverage 0.031(3.67)

    0.027(3.19)

    0.046(5.51)

    Return Volatility 0.516

    (21.12)

    0.493

    (19.99)

    0.475

    (19.87)

    Number of Analysts -0.001

    (-3.94)

    -0.001

    (-4.55)

    -0.001

    (-2.54)

    ENVIRONMENT*AGE -0.005

    (-2.62)

    -0.006

    (-3.24)

    0.101

    (37.85)

    ANTI.ENVIRONMENT*AGE

    0.077(16.91)

    0.062(12.15)

    -0.010(-5.24)

    Adjusted R-squared

    0.05 0.04 0.10

  • 7/29/2019 Speed of Learning and Price Multiples

    35/35

    Table 7. Incremental effect regression: Impact of learning environments on valuation

    We defineEquilibrium Valuation Speedas the rate of change of M/B ratio (i.e.,log(M/B)t - log(M/B)t-1)and regress it on various explanatory variables focusing on

    firms age and the learning environment per the methodology of He and Ng (1998):

    Equilibrium Valuation Speed = c0 + c1Agei + cd0Environment + cd1Environment*Agei+ c2DDi + c3LEVi + c4SIZEi + c5ROEi + c6ROE(1)i + c7ROE(2)i + c8ROE(3)i

    + c9RET(1)i + c10RET(2)i + c11D RET(3)i + cd2E DIVi + cd3E.LEVi + cd4E.SIZEi

    + cd5E ROEi + cd6E ROE(1)i + cd7E ROE(2)i + cd8E ROE(3)i + cd9E RET(1)i+ cd10E RET(2)i + cd11E RET(3)i + i

    where Age and other base variables retain their definitions from Table 3 and interactive

    variables are obtained by multiplying the value of Environment variable with the basevariable. Environment (E) represents the learning environment indicator variable as

    defined in Table 6. For example, E equals 1 if insider trading law is enforced in a given

    country in a given year and 0 otherwise and then that value is assigned to all applicablefirm-year observations. All variables of firms in each country are measured in its own

    currency. There are 9,640 firms (68,034 firm-year observations) with valid data for thewhole sample, and 6,631 and 3,009 representing developed and emerging marketsrespectively. For brevity, we report only three regression coefficients, AGE, E, and

    AGE*E. All t-statistics reported in parentheses are based on clustered standard errors as

    suggested by Petersen (2009).

    Valuation Speed AGE E = Learning

    environment

    E*AGE Adj. R2

    Panel A: All countriesInsider trading law enforced -0.217

    (-7.02)

    0.039(1.71)

    -0.16(-3.97)

    0.27

    Shortselling feasible -0.631(-12.63)

    0.068(1.81)

    0.338(6.22)

    0.27

    Foreign trading -0.449(-16.65)

    0.108(3.68)

    0.169(4.20)

    0.27

    Panel B: Developed markets

    Insider trading law enforced -0.078

    (-2.88)

    0.095

    (3.40)-0.237(-6.32)

    0.29

    Shortselling feasible -0.04(-0.54)

    0.03(0.06)

    -0.253(-3.25)

    0.28

    Foreign trading -0.389

    (-14.25)

    0.018

    (0.59)0.188(4.68)

    0.29

    Panel C: Emerging marketsInsider trading law enforced -0.477

    (-6.03)

    -0.346(-4.03)

    -0.398(-3.18)

    0.24

    Shortselling feasible -0.88(-13.65)

    -0.112(-0.85)

    0.518(3.13)

    0.22

    Foreign trading -0.707(-9.14)

    0.67(5.28)

    0.002(0.01)

    0.25