stock market transaction costs and economic growth …

96
STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH by GREGORY RICHARD EVANS (Under the Direction of George Selgin) ABSTRACT Previous attempts to determine stock markets' contribution to economic growth have measured stock market development by stock market size and activity. But stock market size and activity are poor proxies of stock market development that lead to simultaneity and omitted variable problems and unclear policy prescriptions. By looking at the efficiency of stock markets, specifically how inexpensive it is to transact on, obtain information from, and enforce contracts through them, the simultaneity and omitted variable problems can be overcome and better policy prescriptions can be determined. To look at these costs, a measure of transaction costs across different countries is needed. I estimate the cost of transacting on 95 exchanges in 74 countries using an approach suggested by Lesmond, Ogden, and Trzcinka (1999). I use these estimates, and determinants of information and contract enforcement costs, to supplant the proxy measures of stock market development used in previous models of stock

Upload: others

Post on 19-Jan-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

by

GREGORY RICHARD EVANS

(Under the Direction of George Selgin)

ABSTRACT

Previous attempts to determine stock markets' contribution to economic growth have

measured stock market development by stock market size and activity. But stock market size

and activity are poor proxies of stock market development that lead to simultaneity and omitted

variable problems and unclear policy prescriptions. By looking at the efficiency of stock

markets, specifically how inexpensive it is to transact on, obtain information from, and enforce

contracts through them, the simultaneity and omitted variable problems can be overcome and

better policy prescriptions can be determined. To look at these costs, a measure of transaction

costs across different countries is needed. I estimate the cost of transacting on 95 exchanges in

74 countries using an approach suggested by Lesmond, Ogden, and Trzcinka (1999).

I use these estimates, and determinants of information and contract enforcement costs, to

supplant the proxy measures of stock market development used in previous models of stock

Page 2: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

market development and economic growth. Though tepid, the results provide some support for

previous findings of a positive link between stock markets and economic growth and suggest that

reducing transaction costs is the most important cost reduced by stock markets.

Including the efficiency of stock markets in our understanding of stock market

development sheds more light on stock market policies and paves the way for additional

research. The results suggest that additional taxation of stock markets, through a securities

transaction tax and possibly capital gains taxes, would decrease economic growth. Based on the

estimated effects produced here, a 0.5% roundtrip tax on stock trades would be expected to

decrease current economic growth by $5 to $17 billion a year.

INDEX WORDS: economic growth; financial development; stock market; tobin tax

Page 3: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

by

GREGORY RICHARD EVANS

B.S., Business Economics, Marquette University, 1998

M.S., Applied Economics, Marquette University, 1999

A Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate Faculty

Of The University of Georgia in Partial Fulfillment

of the

Requirements for the Degree

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

ATHENS, GEORGIA

2012

Page 4: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

© 2012

Gregory Richard Evans

All Rights Reserved

Page 5: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

by

GREGORY RICHARD EVANS

Approved:

Major Professor: George Selgin

Committee: Santanu Chatterjee

William Lastrapes

Scott Atkinson

Electronic Version Approved:

Maureen Grasso

Dean of the Graduate School

The University of Georgia

August 2012

Page 6: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

iv

DEDICATION

To my wife, Crystal, I will always be in your pocket.

To my children, Savannah and Austin, never put your success in another person’s hands. Be

your own persons and control your own destinies.

To my parents, Cathy and Moe, you have always been there to support and help me in any way

that you could.

Page 7: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

v

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

I would like thank Dr. Selgin for seeing me through on this dissertation. I am sure it was a much

longer journey than he thought it would be when he agreed to be my advisor.

I would like to thank Dr. Lastrapes, Dr. Chatterjee, and Dr. Atkinson for their input, particularly

at the Defense. They made this dissertation considerably better.

I would like to thank my wife, Crystal, for her help running the numerous models that had to be

run for the transaction cost estimates and for helpful comments reading my many drafts. I have

tried to limit the analogies to running water as best I could.

I would like to thank my mother, Cathy, for always offering ways to help me complete my

dissertation.

I would like to thank my father, Moe, for his help running the numerous models that had to be

run for the transaction cost estimates.

I would like to thank my brother, Bill, and Megan Friesen for their proofreading comments.

I would like to thank Sixto Alvarez and Thurman “Tap” Pearson for their help running the

numerous models that had to be run for the transaction cost estimates.

Page 8: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

vi

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ............................................................................................................ v

LIST OF TABLES ....................................................................................................................... viii

LIST OF FIGURES ........................................................................................................................ x

CHAPTER 1 – STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT THEORY AND MEASUREMENT ....... 1

1.1 STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT IN THE LITERATURE ......................................... 3

1.2 BENEFITS OF MEASURING STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT BY COSTS .......... 6

1.3 DEFINING STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS ................................................. 8

1.4 THE TRANSACTION COST MODEL ............................................................................. 10

1.5 MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE INFLUENCES ............................................................. 13

CHAPTER 2 – ESTIMATING TRANSACTION COSTS .......................................................... 16

2.1 DATA CONSIDERATIONS .............................................................................................. 16

2.2 TRANSACTION COST ESTIMATES .............................................................................. 18

2.3 STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT AND TRANSACTION COSTS ........................... 23

CHAPTER 3 – ECONOMIC GROWTH REGRESSIONS ......................................................... 27

3.1 GENERAL SPECIFICATION ........................................................................................... 27

3.2 INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES ...................................................................................... 28

3.3 REDUCED FORM CROSS-COUNTRY ESTIMATES .................................................... 30

3.4 REDUCED FORM FIXED-EFFECTS ESTIMATES........................................................ 33

3.5 COMPARISON TO REGRESSIONS WITH TURNOVER RATIO ................................. 34

3.6 REMAINING ISSUES ....................................................................................................... 35

CHAPTER 4 – POLICY IMPLICATIONS .................................................................................. 38

4.1 SECURITIES TRANSACTION TAXES ........................................................................... 38

4.2 CAPITAL GAINS TAXES................................................................................................. 44

4.3 SOURCES OF GROWTH .................................................................................................. 45

4.4 GROWTH VOLATILITY .................................................................................................. 47

4.5 DETERMINANTS OF TRANSACTION COSTS ............................................................. 49

Page 9: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

vii

4.6 CONCLUSION ................................................................................................................... 50

BIBLIOGRAPHY ......................................................................................................................... 52

APPENDIX A - TABLES ............................................................................................................ 57

APPENDIX B - FIGURES ........................................................................................................... 75

Page 10: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

viii

LIST OF TABLES

Page

TABLE 1 – COUNTRY AND EXCHANGE TRANSACTION COST ESTIMATES ................57

TABLE 2 – CORRELATIONS WITH TRANSACTION COST ESTIMATES ..........................60

TABLE 3 – CROSS COUNTRY REGRESSIONS OF STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT ..62

TABLE 4 – FIXED EFFECTS REGRESSIONS OF STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT ......63

TABLE 5 – COUNTRIES IN THE CROSS-SECTION REGRESSIONS ...................................64

TABLE 6 – SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR CROSS-SECTION COUNTRIES ........................64

TABLE 7 – INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES CROSS-SECTION REGRESSIONS .................65

TABLE 8 – COUNTRIES IN 4 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL DATA ...................66

TABLE 9 – SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR 4 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL

DATA ............................................................................................................................................66

TABLE 10 – INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES FIXED-EFFECTS REGRESSIONS ................67

TABLE 11 – CROSS-COUNTRY REGRESSIONS ....................................................................68

TABLE 12 – FIXED EFFECTS REGRESSIONS, 4 5-YEAR PERIODS, 1990-2009 ................68

TABLE 13 – COUNTRIES IN 3 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL DATA .................69

TABLE 14 – SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR 3 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL

DATA ............................................................................................................................................70

TABLE 15 – FIXED-EFFECTS REGRESSIONS, 3 5-YEAR PERIODS, 1993-2007 ................71

TABLE 16 – CROSS-COUNTRY REGRESSIONS WITH TURNOVER RATIO .....................72

TABLE 17 – FIXED-EFFECTS REGRESSIONS WITH TURNOVER RATIO ........................73

Page 11: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

ix

TABLE 18 – SYSTEM DIFFERENCE ESTIMATOR REGRESSIONS .....................................74

Page 12: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

x

LIST OF FIGURES

PAGE

FIGURE 1 ......................................................................................................................................75

FIGURE 2 ......................................................................................................................................75

FIGURE 3 ......................................................................................................................................75

FIGURE 4 ......................................................................................................................................75

FIGURE 5 ......................................................................................................................................76

FIGURE 6 ......................................................................................................................................76

FIGURE 7 ......................................................................................................................................76

FIGURE 8 ......................................................................................................................................76

FIGURE 9 ......................................................................................................................................77

FIGURE 10 ....................................................................................................................................77

FIGURE 11 ....................................................................................................................................77

FIGURE 12 ....................................................................................................................................77

FIGURE 13 ....................................................................................................................................78

FIGURE 14 ....................................................................................................................................78

FIGURE 15 ....................................................................................................................................78

FIGURE 16 ....................................................................................................................................78

FIGURE 17 ....................................................................................................................................79

FIGURE 18 ....................................................................................................................................79

FIGURE 19 ....................................................................................................................................79

Page 13: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

xi

FIGURE 20 ....................................................................................................................................79

FIGURE 21 ....................................................................................................................................80

FIGURE 22 ....................................................................................................................................80

FIGURE 23 ....................................................................................................................................80

FIGURE 24 ....................................................................................................................................80

FIGURE 25 ....................................................................................................................................81

FIGURE 26 ....................................................................................................................................81

FIGURE 27 ....................................................................................................................................81

FIGURE 28 ....................................................................................................................................81

FIGURE 29 ....................................................................................................................................82

FIGURE 30 ....................................................................................................................................82

FIGURE 31 ....................................................................................................................................82

FIGURE 32 ....................................................................................................................................82

FIGURE 33 ....................................................................................................................................83

Page 14: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

1

CHAPTER 1 – STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT THEORY AND MEASUREMENT

Researchers have attempted to measure stock markets’ contribution to economic growth

by including proxy measures of stock market development, such as stock market capitalization,

value traded, and turnover ratio, in economic growth regressions. Stock market development

“occurs when financial instruments, markets, and intermediaries ameliorate – though do not

necessarily eliminate – the effects of information, (contract) enforcement, and transaction costs”

(Levine 2005, 869). The traditional proxy measures of stock market development sometimes

give indications of how well stock markets ameliorate the effects of these costs but “too

frequently empirical measures of financial development do not directly measure” these costs

(Levine 2005, 922). These traditional proxy measures also suffer simultaneity and omitted

variable biases. Simultaneity bias can occur when economic growth leads to more investment

on, or in the operation of, a stock market, making the stock market larger, more active, or more

efficient. Omitted variable bias can occur when an unobserved variable, such as technological

advancement increases economic growth and improves stock market development. I develop

more exogenous and direct estimates of transaction costs to use, along with exogenous measures

of information and contract enforcement costs, in economic growth regressions. Replacing the

traditional proxy measures of stock market development with measures of the efficiency of stock

markets brings the research in line with the theorized benefits of stock markets and reduces the

biases inherent in using measures of stock market size and activity.

Previous researchers on financial development have identified factors related to

information and contract enforcement costs that should be exogenous to current economic

Page 15: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

2

growth. An index measuring the quality of company annual reports in 1990 indicates

information costs. The quality of information companies provided in annual reports in 1990

likely was not influenced by economic growth from 1990 to 2009, unless companies were

anticipating economic growth and constructing their reports accordingly. The origin of the

commercial law system indicates contract enforcement costs. The people establishing the legal

system in different countries were likely not influenced by current economic growth. There has

not, however, been a satisfactory development of a broad set of transaction cost estimates. This

research will change that. Transaction costs are determined by the structure of the exchange,

taxes, fees, and commissions and should be shielded from current economic growth and

unobserved effects like technology.1

This paper will seek to advance our understanding of stock markets’ contribution to

economic growth by developing a set of transaction cost estimates that span 74 countries for up

to 20 years to use in cross-section and fixed-effects economic growth regressions to replace the

previously used proxy measures for stock market development. This approach will help to

alleviate the simultaneity and omitted variable problems inherent in the stock market

development proxies and produce more detailed information on the importance of stock market

efficiency. The results suggest a modest contribution from stock markets to economic growth.

Transaction costs appear to be the more important cost that stock markets reduce. Having more

specific detail on the effects of these costs on economic growth allows for examination specific

policy proposals, such a securities transaction tax.

1 The assumption that economic growth and omitted variable bias do not affect transaction costs is probably the

most questionable assumption made here. This effect, however, is likely small. Economic growth does not

influence taxes, fees, and trading methods (quote driven or order driven market). Technological advancements are

also unlikely to influence taxes, fees or trading methods. They may, however, influence commissions, opportunity

costs, and the trading software exchanges use. Still, the feedback from economic growth to transaction costs is

likely to be considerably smaller than the feedback to size and activity since economic growth attracts additional

investment. I will also make use of econometric techniques to attempt to further control for the potential

simultaneity and omitted variable problems.

Page 16: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

3

1.1 STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT IN THE LITERATURE

Stock markets arise to improve liquidity and facilitate investment in multiple risky

projects, thereby spreading out the risk from any one project (Levine 1991, 1446). Stock

markets improve liquidity by reducing the cost of transacting on equity shares, reducing the cost

of acquiring financial information and enforcing financial contracts. With lower transaction

costs, investors can trade in and out of stocks without having their savings consumed by fees.

Low transaction costs also help investors reduce risk by enabling them to afford to invest in

multiple projects. Lower information costs help investors to know more about more projects and

to know which investments to trade in and out of and when.

These private benefits give rise to a stock market but the existence of a stock market also

brings public benefits. Stock markets enhance economic activity by producing information,

monitoring investments, facilitating risk management, mobilizing savings, and easing exchange

of goods and services (Levine 2006, 869). The lower the cost of transacting on a stock market

and obtaining information, the more people will trade on the stock market and the better the

stock market should perform these economic activity enhancing functions. Measuring stock

market development by size and activity hints at these costs but does not measure them. Further,

a growing economy is likely to result in a larger and more active stock market leading to

simultaneity and omitted variable problems when used in economic growth regressions.

Researchers have focused on correcting the simultaneity and omitted variable problems

but have done so in unsatisfactory ways. Raymond Atje and Boyan Jovanovic (1993, 632) make

one of the first attempts to empirically measure the effect of stock market development on

economic growth. They use cross-section data for 39 countries from 1980 to 1988. While the

Page 17: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

4

authors find support that the value traded on the stock market positively affects economic

growth, Richard Harris (1997, 140) identifies several problems with the study. Atje and

Jovanovic primarily attempt to control for the simultaneity and omitted variable problems with

the stock market development proxy measures by using lagged and initial values of investment

and value traded. Using initial values implies an information loss since theory suggests a

relationship between economic growth and contemporaneous stock market development. The

estimated effects are potentially inconsistent since the initial values are imperfect proxies for

contemporaneous values. Harris uses these lagged and initial values as instruments in a two-

stage least squares regression and finds it reduces the significance of value traded’s effect on

economic growth. Harris’s findings suggest that if value traded is an accurate measure of stock

market development, then stock market development does not affect economic growth.

Ross Levine and Sara Zervos (1998, 538) find evidence to support the theory that stock

market development increases economic growth, though they also use initial levels of the stock

market development proxies to control for the simultaneity and omitted variable problems like

Atje and Jovanovich did. Specifically, more value traded and turnover are associated with higher

rates of economic growth. They expand the number of countries from Atje and Jovanovic’s

study to 47 and the time period to 17 years, with data from 1976 to 1993.

Ross Levine (1998, 597), Ross Levine (1999, 30) and Ross Levine, Norman Loayza and

Thorsten Beck (2000, 34) use Rafael LaPorta, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and

Robert Vishny’s (1997, 1138) origin of the commercial law system in a country as an

instrumental variable to correct for the simultaneity and omitted variable problems with

economic growth and bank development. The origin of the legal system helps determine how

creditors are treated and property rights are enforced. Thorten Beck, Asli Demirguc-Kunt and

Page 18: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

5

Ross Levine (2001, 497) demonstrate that market capitalization differs significantly across

countries with different legal origins, making it a candidate to be an exogenous determinant of

contract enforcement costs.

Philip Arestis, Panicos Demetriades and Kul Luintel (2001, 17) use quarterly time series

data for 5 developed economies to investigate the effect of stock markets on economic growth.

The authors find stock markets contribute only modestly to economic growth, though this finding

may largely be a result of the two stock market variables they use: capitalization and volatility.

Levine and Zervos find both of these variables to be unreliable determinants of economic

growth. Specifically, the effect of stock market capitalization and volatility on economic growth

is influenced greatly by which countries are included in the regression. The use of quarterly data

is also questionable when looking at economic growth because economic growth is a long-run

concept that looks beyond a given business cycle. A recession is, at a minimum, two quarters

long, so one time period would only be half a recession at best.

Peter Rousseau and Paul Wachtel (2000, 1934) use the difference estimator, an

estimation technique that uses lagged values of the variables as instruments for the first-

differenced variables, to look at the effect of stock market development on economic growth.

The authors use annual data, which is an improvement upon the quarterly data Arestis et al.

(2001) use. Rousseau and Wachtel (1935) find evidence supporting a positive link between

stock market development, as measured by value traded, and economic growth.

Building on the use of the difference estimator, Thorsten Beck and Ross Levine (2004,

436) use the system difference estimator to control for the feedback between turnover ratio and

economic growth. The system difference estimator estimates a system of equations, the first

equation is the difference estimator with the lagged levels of the variables used as instruments

Page 19: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

6

for the first-difference of the variables, and the second equation uses first differences as

instruments for the levels. Beck and Levine use five-year averages and expand the time period

to 1998, though there are only 40 countries in their study. Beck and Levine (428) narrow the

focus of stock market development to turnover ratio, deeming market capitalization to lack

theoretical and empirical significance and value traded to be an inadequate and biased measure

of liquidity. Five-year increments, while better than quarterly or annual data, are still not

necessarily long enough to accurately measure long-run growth.

1.2 BENEFITS OF MEASURING STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT BY COSTS

The simultaneity and omitted variable problems can be addressed further by better

identifying the benefits of stock market development, specifically with exogenous measures of

information, transaction, and contract enforcement costs. LaPorta et al. (1997) and Beck et al.

(2001) make considerable progress on identifying determinants of financial information and

contract enforcement costs. These studies do not address transaction costs, however. Adding

stock market transaction costs will provide a fuller explanation of stock market development and

allow for better control of the simultaneity and omitted variable problems with economic growth.

Even if the simultaneity and omitted variable problems are corrected, there are other

benefits to measuring stock market development by information, transaction, and contract

enforcement costs instead of by the traditional proxy measures. Size and activity of a stock

market do not measure how well the stock market functions (Levine 2006, 922). Looking at the

inner workings of the stock market will help us understand what particular aspects and features

of a market promote good, or bad, outcomes. While research suggests a positive effect of stock

markets on economic growth in general, some research indicates that stock markets hurt resource

Page 20: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

7

allocation. Stock markets may have poor incentives to gather information, lead to weak

corporate governance, and have incentives to engage in short-sighted trading (Levine 2006, 882).

The thought that markets are weak at corporate governance stems from the thought that

corporate takeovers are the only tool of corporate governance. Corporate takeovers may be

unlikely to occur in a market system because insiders have better information than outsiders

(Stiglitz 1985, 137), other investors can free-ride simply by watching the market activities of

bigger investors (Grossman and Hart 1980, 43), and poison pills put in place by existing

managers reduce incentives to take over a firm (DeAngelo and Rice 1983, 332). These

weaknesses all rely on takeovers being unlikely and being the sole means of exerting corporate

governance.

Takeovers are not, however, the sole means of exerting corporate governance. While

takeovers certainly lead to corporate control, corporate governance can also come from corporate

influence. Influence can come, for example, from research departments at large investment

houses issuing buy, hold, or sell ratings. Determining and issuing these ratings is an information

cost and the ability to act on the information is determined by transaction costs. Similarly, the

lower the cost to trade a company’s stock, the easier it is to sell (buy) the stock to punish

(reward) bad (good) behavior. As long as the managers of the company care about the stock

price, such trading will influence their behavior. Measuring transaction costs does not directly

address corporate governance but it does measure an important tool for exerting corporate

governance. Looking at size and activity of stock markets does not necessarily look at the tools

of corporate governance.

The other main critique of market systems is that stock markets encourage short-sighted

trading. The easier and cheaper it is for investors to seek immediate gains, the less likely

Page 21: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

8

investors will be to stick with an investment through the ups and downs of a long project. Short-

sighted investors will lead to short-sighted managers. Robert Pollin, Dean Baker, and Marc

Schaberg (2003, 530) argue that encouraging short-sighted behavior leads to an inefficient

allocation of resources. If this critique is valid, then one of the primary motivations for stock

markets, to facilitate investment in long term projects, would be in doubt. Incorporating a

measure of transaction costs into economic growth research will allow for a test of these

competing theories.

Information, transaction, and contract enforcement costs also give a better indication of

proverbial rocks or dams that might prevent capital from flowing to its most productive uses.

Stock market size and activity do not give an indication of whether the capital is moving to

where it is most productive, simply that it exists and is moving. Therefore, it is important to

measure the effect of information, transaction, and contract enforcement costs on economic

growth and not just the effect of stock market size and activity on economic growth. Looking

specifically at the effects of these proverbial rocks and dams we will also be able to make more

informed policy decisions.

1.3 DEFINING STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS

Larry Harris (2003, 421) identifies three types of transaction costs: explicit costs, implicit

costs, and missed trade opportunity costs. Explicit costs are those visible to an accountant such

as commissions, exchange fees, and taxes. Implicit costs do not involve a direct expenditure of

funds but involve some type of opportunity cost. The missed trade opportunity costs are implicit

costs that arise specifically from missing out on a trade. Adding up the various explicit costs is

Page 22: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

9

straightforward as long as all of the commissions, fees, and taxes associated with a trade can be

defined and identified.

The explicit costs are not always straightforward however. Commissions, for example,

vary by quality of service and by quantity of trades. The commissions for full-service brokerage

firms are higher than for discount and online brokerages. In Korea, for example, commissions

through a traditional broker are up to four times more than commissions from online trading

(Batista & Palmiero 2002, 253).

While exchange fees, stamp duties and transfer fees are relatively straightforward,

government tax laws can make them more complicated. Morocco subjects commissions and fees

to the value-added tax, while Switzerland exempts banking and securities transactions from the

tax. Even within countries, the tax treatment is not always consistent. In Switzerland, asset

management services are not exempt from the value-added tax, so the cost to transact would be

different based on how a trader interacts with the market.

Harris’s implicit costs arise from price effects of a trade, as indicated by bid-ask spreads.

The bid-ask spread represents the difference between the price buyers pay for a stock and the

price sellers receive for it. If a trader were to buy a stock and sell it immediately, the trader

would lose the difference between the bid and the ask.

Missed trade opportunity costs come from investors offering a bid that is just below the

ask or asking a price that is just above the bid, which results in missing out on the trade. Had the

investor offered a slightly better price, she would have consummated the trade and earned the

return. Harris's definition of implicit costs needs to be expanded to include opportunity costs to

the investor for having to spend time deciding on a trade and contacting a broker. The time it

takes to contact a broker can also result in missed trades. If an investor can enter an order online,

Page 23: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

10

as opposed to trying to get in touch by phone with a broker, the investor is less likely to miss the

trade.

The most common empirical measure of transaction costs has been the bid-ask spread

plus a representative commission. This approach suffers from the fact it overlooks explicit and

opportunity costs, and also from the fact commission data are not always available for a cross-

section of countries for long periods of time. An available and comparable measure of

transaction costs across countries is needed for better research on the relationship between stock

market development and economic growth.

David Lesmond, Joseph Ogden, and Charles Trzcinka (1999) develop a model to estimate

transaction costs that accounts for these problems. They use a Tobit model with frictions based

on expected and actual stock returns. Since the estimates are based on returns, the transaction

costs are derived from investors’ decisions regarding their own costs rather than a researcher

estimating the specific costs the investors would consider. Also, since return data are more

readily available than spread and commission data, the model can be used to estimate transaction

costs for numerous stock exchanges. I use this model to estimate transaction costs for 95

exchanges in 74 countries.

1.4 THE TRANSACTION COST MODEL

The Tobit model by Lesmond et al. (1999) accounts for the explicit and implicit costs

considered by traders by using data on individual stock and index returns to measure transaction

costs. An investor will trade on new information if the expected gain from that information

exceeds the cost of making the trade. When transaction costs are higher than the expected return,

trades will not occur. The threshold return for trades to take place can thus be regarded as a

Page 24: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

11

measure of the overall cost of transacting in the market in question. Hard to measure costs, such

as the opportunity cost to contact a broker, are included implicitly in the estimates from Lesmond

et al.'s model, making the estimates a more complete measure of transaction costs than the

common bid-ask spread plus commission.

In applying the Lesmond et al. approach, the expected returns are represented by a local

market index. While individual stocks do not necessarily move with an index, variations are

assumed to be independently and identically distributed.

The relationship between a stock's actual return, Rjt, and its gross return, , is thus

represented as

, (1)

where

if

, (2)

if , (3)

if

. (4)

Rmt, α1j and α2j are the market return, the selling threshold and the buying threshold, respectively.

If the gross return is between these thresholds, then the stock is expected to have an actual return

of zero. If the gross return is less than α1j, then the actual return is expected to equal the gross

return less this threshold. On the other end, if the gross return exceeds α2j, then the actual return

is expected to equal the gross return less this threshold.

The total cost to buy and sell the stock is the difference between α1j and α2j. Since α1j is a

negative number, this difference becomes the sum of the two costs. The transaction costs are

thus estimated as percentages of price, or return. Since the transaction costs are estimated as

returns, they are estimated as completely variable costs without an explicit fixed cost component.

Page 25: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

12

Lesmond et al. develop this model on two quote-driven markets (the New York Stock

Exchange, NYSE and the American Stock Exchange, AMEX), and it has been used to estimate

transaction costs on two order-driven markets (the Tunisia Stock Exchange (Bellalah et al. 2006)

and the Oslo Stock Exchange (Odegaard 2008)). Lesmond et al. compare their estimates with

spread plus commission data and found both measures of transaction costs follow similar time

patterns, with peaks and valleys occurring at similar intervals. Mondher Bellalah, Adel

Boubaker, and Saber Sebai (2006) and Bernt Odegaard (2008) compare estimates using this

model with the spread estimates using the approaches by Richard Roll (1984) and Thomas

George, Gautam Kaul, and Michigan Nimalendran (1991). Again, the alternative estimates

follow similar time patterns, though the estimates using Lesmond et al.'s model are greater than

both spread estimates, as expected.

Randi Naes, Johannes Skjeltorp, and Bernt Odegaard (2008, 22) also estimate transaction

costs with the model by Lesmond et al. and report correlations between transaction cost

estimates and various other measures of transaction costs and liquidity for the Oslo Stock

Exchange. They find that Lesmond et al.'s Tobit estimates are least correlated with quoted bid-

ask spreads and turnover. This result also indicates that the Lesmond et al. approach provides

other information than the popular measure of transaction costs and one of the popular measures

of stock market development.

Lesmond et al.'s model has attracted some attention from financial development and

macroeconomics economists. Ross Levine and Sergio Schmukler (2006) use a simplified

version of the model to estimate stock market liquidity in developing countries. Rather than

using it as a measure of transaction costs, however, Levine and Schmukler take the frequency of

zero return trading days as an indicator of market liquidity. Randi Naes, Johannes Skjeltorp, and

Page 26: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

13

Bernt Odegaard (2011) use estimates from the model to examine the link between liquidity and

the business cycle in the United States and Norway. Despite these researchers using transaction

costs as measures of stock market development, there is still a need for a broad cross-country set

of transaction cost estimates.

1.5 MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE INFLUENCES

Before estimating the transaction costs for a broad cross-section of countries, I examine

how market microstructures influence transaction costs. Understanding stock market

microstructure, or the process and outcomes of trading stocks under explicit trading rules

(O’Hara 1995, 1), serves as a way to see if the estimates line up with expectations. The explicit

costs and implicit costs can be influenced by the microstructure of the stock market. Market

microstructure can be broken down into three categories: the degree of continuity, the extent of

reliance on dealers, and the degree of market transparency (Naes 2008, 4).

Continuity is how frequently trading occurs. Electronic trading generally allows for

exchanges to have continuous trading. In contrast, periodic trading systems hold call auctions at

certain points in time. The primary benefit of a continuous trading system is liquidity, though a

periodic call auction may be more efficient as it is easier to match up buyers and sellers at once

than to match them as the orders are placed (Naes 2008, 6). A preference for continuous trading

versus periodic call auctions could be an example of traders valuing liquidity over efficiency. In

practice, many exchanges combine the two trading schedules. Poland, for example, has

continuous trading from 10:00-4:00, but also holds two single-price auctions from 11:15-11:45

and 3:00-3:30.

Page 27: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

14

The second consideration is whether orders are matched in an order-driven or quote-

driven system. Order-driven markets match orders based on predetermined criteria, usually price

and time. With the advent of electronic market systems, the matching of orders based on

decision criteria is fast and efficient. In quote-driven markets, market makers quote bid and ask

prices for a stock and are responsible for matching orders. Market makers earn their revenue

from the spread between the bid and ask prices. Quote-driven markets are more liquid because

the market maker will often fulfill one end of a transaction if an order cannot be matched. In

order to do ensure orders can be matched, market makers have inventories of their assigned

stocks. Mark Garman (1976) and Yakov Amihud and Haim Mendelson (1980), find inventory

costs are an important cost for a market maker to consider when setting the spread. Market

makers also have pricing power over the spread. Amber Anand, Carsten Tanggaard, and Daniel

Weaver (2009) find that spreads drop when the Stockholm Stock Exchange allowed companies

to negotiate with market makers.

As with the decision on trading frequency, several markets have become hybrids between

quote-driven and order-driven market systems. In a hybrid system, the primary matching system

is order-driven, but market makers are available to insure liquidity. The NYSE is an example of

a hybrid market. The NYSE began as a quote-driven market but now runs most trades through a

limit order book with market makers still available for liquidity.

The last consideration is transparency. Order-driven markets often have the best

transparency since the orders go into a public order book. Quote-driven markets are less

transparent since the availability of information depends on the market maker. Several studies

(Admati & Pfleiderer 1991, Forster & George 1992, Benveniste et al. 1992), though not all (e.g.

Madhavan 1995), find that transparency is good for both liquidity and transaction costs. Based

Page 28: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

15

on the research behind these three considerations, we should expect order-driven markets with

public limit order books and at least some periodic trading to have the lowest transaction costs.

Page 29: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

16

CHAPTER 2 – ESTIMATING TRANSACTION COSTS

Developed stock markets are supposed to reduce financial transaction, information, and

contract enforcement costs. Researchers studying stock market development have used

imperfect measures of development that do not necessarily reflect these costs. At best,

researchers have focused on only two of these three costs, though often times on none of them.

Previous researchers have either estimated transaction costs using the Lesmond et al.

model for only a few countries or have used a simplified version of the model for several

countries. In this chapter, I use the approach developed by Lesmond et al. to estimate and

evaluate the transaction costs for 95 exchanges in 74 countries. I then test these estimates as an

explanatory variable in models of stock market development.

2.1 DATA CONSIDERATIONS

I construct annual estimates of transaction costs using daily data on individual stock

returns for 95 exchanges in 74 countries from 1990 to 2009. Transaction costs are estimated by

firm and averaged over the exchange. I assign a firm to the exchange and country where its

primary quote appears. The initial data included 97,128 firms with 248,908,929 observations,

though for reasons given below, the final data set was smaller. The expected market return is

represented by a local index given by DataStream.

Data are not available on all exchanges for the entire time period, and the data for some

years are sparse. An exchange is deemed to be active when the local index has a non-zero return

and the number of stocks on the exchange in a given year is not too different from most other

Page 30: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

17

years. For example, for the exchange in Sao Paulo, Brazil there are 1, 3, 4, and 7 stocks with

useable data from 1990 to 1993, and then in 1994 there are 163. I, therefore, exclude the data

from 1990 to 1993.

I also only keep stocks that had evidence of trading activity on at least 20% of the trading

days. Since the model relies on the occurrence of zero-return days, there is a tradeoff between

trying to use only good data and keeping with the rationale underlying Lesmond et al.'s model.

In a paper on international stock market efficiency, John Griffin, Patrick Kelly, and Frederico

Nardari (2006) use a 30% cutoff. I chose a 20% cutoff because, based on the data, it is less

restrictive of stocks with minimal trading activity. Future researchers looking to make use of this

data would be able to set their own cutoff.

Another consideration with the data is that it is organized at the exchange level and not

simply by country. Most countries only have one exchange, so this problem is only a concern

for the 12 countries with multiple exchanges. Countries with multiple exchanges segment firms

of different sizes and types among their exchanges. Countries with only one exchange serve all

of their firms on that exchange. The cost of transacting on the stocks of smaller firms tends to be

greater than the costs of transacting on the stocks of larger firms. Lesmond et al. build the model

on return data from the NYSE, the main market in the United States, and the AMEX, a smaller

market in the United States. The estimated transaction costs differed by as much as 36%.

Furthermore, the NYSE had lower transaction costs for larger sized firms than the AMEX, and

the AMEX had lower transaction costs for smaller firms than the NYSE. Countries whose stock

markets serve a broader segment of stocks should be considered to have more developed stock

markets than countries whose stock markets serve only a narrow group of stocks. The

transaction costs, however, may indicate the opposite.

Page 31: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

18

2.2 TRANSACTION COST ESTIMATES

The average estimated transaction costs, along with minimum, maximum and trend, for

each exchange are given in Table 1. For brevity, only the estimates of the total cost to trade are

given, though separate costs to buy and sell are available. I have confidence in the results for

four reasons. First, the results are similar in level and variation to those produced by other

researchers using the same model. Lesmond et al. (1999) and Naes et al. (2011, 146) produce

transaction cost estimates for the NYSE from 1963 to 1990 and from 1947 to 2008, respectively.

The Lesmond et al. estimates average 3.3% and the Naes et al. estimates average 3.5% overall,

4.0% from 1990 to 1999, and 2.7% from 2000 to 2008. My estimates average 2.3%. My

estimates are also lower in the 2000 to 2008 time period than in the 1990 to 1999 time period,

similar to the estimates from Naes et al.

Odegaard (2008, 4) and Naes et al. (2011, 146) use the same approach to estimate

transaction costs for Norway from 1980 to 2007. Both studies find costs ranging from a little

more than 3% to almost 10% with the costs in most years between 4% and 7%. My estimates

range from 2.4% to 11.7% with most years also between 4% and 7%.

Second, exchanges within country follow an expected ordering, with primary exchanges

having lower costs than secondary exchanges. The exchanges within country also have similar

trends. The estimated transaction costs on the NYSE are lower than the estimated costs for the

AMEX. This ordering holds in my estimates for the Toronto and TSX exchanges in Canada, the

Tokyo and JASDAQ exchanges in Japan, the Korean and KOSDAQ exchanges in Korea, the

Main Board, the 2nd

Board, and the MESDAQ in Malaysia, the Singapore and Catalist exchanges

in Singapore, and the Taiwan and Gre Tai exchanges in Taiwan.

Page 32: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

19

Similarity in trends within a country can be seen in the Canadian (Figures 2 and 3),

Chinese (Figures 4 and 5), and Malaysian (Figures 15, 16, and 17) exchanges. The estimated

transaction costs for the Chinese exchanges are stable except for a spike in both exchanges in

2006. The Canadian exchanges are more volatile with high costs in the early 1990s, followed by

a drastic decrease in costs, only to have another increase in costs in 2001. Transaction costs on

the Canadian exchanges then decrease substantially, only begin increasing again in 2008. The

costs on each of the Malaysian exchanges are generally in the low to mid-single digits until a

sudden increase in 2007. While the size of the increase is different on the different exchanges,

each exchange experienced a spike beginning in 2007.

Third, there is considerable time series variation in the estimates. It is common for the

estimated transaction costs on an exchange to triple, if not more, throughout the time period. For

example, in Venezuela, estimated costs range from less than 5% to more than 25%. For the

NYSE, the estimates range from less than 1% to greater than 6%. These estimates might seem at

first brush like a weakness of the estimates. Other researchers, however, have found similar

results using the same and different methods.

Odegaard (2008, 7-8) calculates the bid-ask spread, the relative spread and the Roll

(1984) measure of trading costs for the Oslo exchange. The high for the bid-ask spread is 7

times the low, and the high for the relative spread is almost 4 times the low. The Roll measure

gave a tighter range of trading costs, ranging from under 2% to almost 4%. Lesmond et al.

calculate the spread plus commission for the NYSE and find the highest estimates to be up to 5

times the lowest estimates.

The transaction costs estimates have such a large time series variation owing largely to

liquidity concerns. Some of the costs associated with buying stock, like taxes, are pre-

Page 33: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

20

determined, or at least stable, such that they would not fluctuate wildly from year to year. The

spread however, is set by the market maker and subject to more frequent changes. With the

spread, the market maker covers: order processing costs such as costs incurred in setting up,

fixed exchange fees, etc.; risk of holding inventory, which is related to the volatility; and

adverse information costs such as the risk of trading with a counterparty with superior

information (Plerou, et al. 2005, p. 046131-1). The first source of costs is predetermined and

should not change wildly from year to year. The other two sources of cost arise from the risks

the market-maker faces and are much more variable. The more risk the market-maker perceives,

the greater the spread between the bid and the ask.

A market maker is likely to perceive more risk of holding inventory in a down market.

That is, if prices are falling, then more people are selling than buying so the market-maker will

likely accumulate inventory and will want to set the spread higher to account the increased

inventory costs. Inversely, if prices are rising, then more people are buying than selling so the

market maker will likely reduce inventory and will have lower inventory costs. As mentioned in

Section 1.4, research suggests market makers consider inventory costs when setting the spread.

The time series variation leads to the last reason to have confidence in the results.

Historical events are visible in the time series variation of the estimates. Specifically, transaction

costs are high during periods when market-makers would likely perceive more inventory risk

because of down markets and transaction costs lower with expectations of up markets. For

example, the Asian Financial Crisis can be seen by spikes in the estimated costs for the

exchanges in Hong Kong (Figure 10), Indonesia (Figure 13), Japan (Figures 14 and 15),

Malaysia (Figures 15, 16, and 17), the Philippines (Figure 20), South Korea (Figures 27 and 28),

and Thailand (Figure 31).

Page 34: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

21

The estimated costs for the Russian exchanges (Figures 23, 24, and 25) are similarly

volatile during the Russian debt crisis. Former Soviet Bloc countries, such as Croatia (Figure 6),

the Czech Republic (Figure 7), Estonia (Figure 9), Hungary (Figure 11), Poland (Figures 21 and

22), and Slovenia (Figure 26), had similar spikes between 1997 and 2000. While Mexico (Figure

18) actually experienced decreasing costs during the Mexican Peso Crisis, Argentina (Figure 1)

experienced increased costs during an economic crisis in 2001 and 2002. Costs in Sri Lanka

(Figure 29) spiked during a recession in 2001. Venezuela (Figure 33) also had a considerable

increase in costs beginning in 1999, which is when Hugo Chavez was elected. Though there

have been some fluctuations, costs are about double the pre-election period.

In 1998, the NOREX trading system was formed with the exchanges in Denmark (Figure

8), Iceland (Figure 12), Norway (Figure 19), and Sweden (Figure 30). Since the new system was

formed, the transaction costs in those countries have followed similar trends. Since 2002, the

transaction costs in all four countries have decreased. Transaction costs have increased in all of

these exchanges in costs in the last two years of data.

There are some questionable results that deserve attention. The estimates for the Chinese

exchanges (Figures 4 and 5) were remarkably low and stable, except for the spike in 2006. The

low results seem incorrect based on a summation of known explicit costs. Commissions on the

Shanghai exchange are 0.7%, and trades are subject to a 0.1% transfer fee and a stamp duty of

0.3%. At a minimum, the estimated round-trip transaction costs for Shanghai should be at least

1.8%. Similarly, the Shenzhen exchange has brokerage commissions of 0.43%, a stamp duty of

0.3%, a stock exchange charge of 0.03%, a clearing charge of 0.05%, and a China Securities

Regulatory Commission fee of 0.0046%. Transaction costs on the Shenzhen exchange should

not be less than 1.6%. The estimated costs average only 0.5% and 0.6%. One possible reason

Page 35: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

22

for the low estimated costs is investors being more concerned with missed trade opportunities

than explicit trading costs.

There is a spike in the estimated transaction costs for the Chinese exchanges in 2006.

This spike may be attributed to efforts by the Chinese government to slow investment growth by

raising reserve requirements 3 times in the second half of the year. The government continued

raising reserve requirements after 2006, however, the estimated transaction costs returned to the

pre-spike range.

The cost estimates for the NYSE (Figure 33) reached a low of 0.3% in 2005, 2006, and

2007. The low transaction costs can be expected in part because of the move to decimal pricing

(Batista & Palmiero 2002, 480) and advances in technology. These years preceded the Financial

Crisis of 2008 but even after the liquidity crunch, the estimated stock market transaction cost

only increased slightly. The lack of a spike is contrary to the experience in most other countries.

The reason may be the response to the crisis. The Federal Reserve pursued a loose monetary

policy when the crisis set in. Also, the other financial crises were regional, which meant

investors seeking quality could substitute away from the affected region. The Financial Crisis of

2008 was more global than the others, so a flight to quality would still send investors to the

United States.

There is also evidence that this approach does not work for all exchanges. The cost

estimates for the over-the-counter (OTC) markets in the United States are particularly high. The

estimates can be partially explained by the nature of the OTC markets in the United States. The

OTC markets typically serve penny stocks, so higher transaction costs are expected. There is

another, more problematic, cause of the high estimates. The estimates are based on comparing a

stock’s actual return to its expected return. A local index is used as a proxy for the expected

Page 36: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

23

return. If that index does not accurately represent the expected return for the stock, then the

model will produce inaccurate estimates. For all of the U.S. markets, the S&P 500 Composite is

used as the expected market return. The expected return for penny stocks is probably not well

represented by the return for the S&P 500 Composite.

In general, the estimated transaction costs hold up to inspection of individual exchanges.

The results for the exchanges in China and for some of the secondary exchanges and OTC

markets are suspect. Most of the estimates, however, appear to be reasonable estimates of the

cost of transacting on various stock exchanges.

2.3 STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT AND TRANSACTION COSTS

The purpose of estimating transaction costs is to gain a better understanding of stock

market development and improve our understanding of its economic effects. Theory suggests

transaction costs would be negatively correlated with the measures of stock market development.

That is, lower transaction costs should mean greater stock market development. There are 67

exchanges with both transaction cost estimates and data for market capitalization, value traded,

and turnover. Correlations are given in Table 2. Of those cases, theory holds 50, 48, and 42

times for market capitalization, value traded, and turnover. Data on these measures come from

Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine (2000). In countries with multiple

exchanges, the data on capitalization, value traded and turnover are aggregated by combining the

primary and secondary stock exchanges in those countries. The transaction cost estimates are

separated by exchange. For Canada, for example, this separation means there are separate

correlation results between capitalization and transaction costs for the Toronto exchange and for

the TSX, though the capitalization numbers are the same in both cases.

Page 37: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

24

These results are simple correlations without any controls. To gain a better

understanding of the relationship between transaction costs and stock market development, I

estimate cross-section and fixed-effects regressions. Previous researchers have identified several

other explanatory variables for stock market development. These control variables include legal

tradition, shareholder rights, property rights, accounting standards, political openness, trade, and

geography (e.g. Beck et al. 2001, Chinn & Ito 2006, Law & Habibullah 2009). The first three

variables indicate how costly it is to enforce contracts in a country. Legal tradition indicates how

well a country protects shareholders and creditors and comes from LaPorta et al. (1997).

Shareholder rights indicate how well minority shareholders are protected from exploitation by

majority shareholders and come from Beck et al. (2001). Property rights indicate how well

property is protected in a country and come from the Index of Economic Freedom.

Information costs are indicated by accounting standards in each country. The accounting

standards measure is based on the quality of reporting in annual reports and comes from the

Center for International Financial Analysis through Beck et al. (2001).

There are 3 additional control variables included that are thought to be determinants of

financial development. The first two pertain to how likely a country is to foster competition.

Political openness comes from Beck et al. (2001) and is a composite index variable measuring

how closed a political system is, access to institutional structures for political expression, access

of non-elites to executive offices, and how competitive the selection process for executives is.

Openness to trade comes from the World Bank Development Indicators and is measured by the

sum of imports and exports divided by GDP. Both variables indicate how open the entrenched

interests in a country are to competition. Since a stock market broadens access to financial

Page 38: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

25

capital, a stock market should foster a more competitive environment and be more accepted in a

country where the entrenched interests are more open to competition.

The final variable controls for the incentive a country may have to invest in long term

projects and the country's need for a stock market. Geography is linked with health and disease.

In countries with lower life expectancies, investors may not be interested in investing in long

term projects. Geography is measured by World Bank classification of a country as having a

tropical climate and comes from Beck et al. (2001).

The data range from 1995 to 2005 with 31 countries in the cross-section regressions. I

include countries with at least 10 years of data during this time. There are separate regressions

for each measure of stock market development. Transaction costs and the measures of stock

market development all enter the regression in log form. The cross-section specification is

, (5)

where is a stock market development measure that is capitalization, turnover ratio, or value

traded and is a series of control variables described above. Results are given in Table 3.

The results support the theory that transaction costs are an important determinant of stock market

development. In all of the measures of stock market development, the direction of effect

between transaction costs and stock market development is negative as expected, with almost all

results being statistically significant. Reducing the cost of transacting on the stock market in a

country by one percent would suggest an increase in stock market development of about a half a

percent.

There are 38 countries in the fixed effects regressions. The fixed effects specification is

, (6)

Page 39: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

26

where the subscript t is the time period and is the country-specific effects. The time variation

in the fixed effects regression also reduces the available control variables. Only property rights

and international trade are included in . Results are given in Table 4. The fixed-effects

regression results are all statistically significant and indicate an economically significant, though

smaller, relationship between transaction costs and stock market development. From the fixed-

effects results, reducing transaction costs in a country by one percent would suggest an increase

in stock market development of about a quarter of a percent.

One final interesting note on the results is that the other consistently significant variable

is accounting standards. Recall that accounting standards are a measure of information cost.

The significance of stock market transaction cost and accounting standards indicate transaction

costs and information costs are very important for the development of stock markets. Based on

these findings, future research to measure information costs across stock markets may be

beneficial to help better understand the contribution of stock markets to economic growth.

Page 40: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

27

CHAPTER 3 – ECONOMIC GROWTH REGRESSIONS

In this chapter, I improve our understanding of stock markets’ role in economic growth

by using exogenous measures of transaction, information, and contract enforcement costs in

economic growth regressions. As Beck and Levine. (2004, 427-428) note when using the

traditional proxy measures of stock market development,

“there are important weaknesses with the measures. Theory focuses on the role that stock

markets and banks may play in reducing informational asymmetries and lowering

transaction costs. We do not, however, have direct measures of the degree to which

markets and banks in a broad cross-section of countries ameliorate information and

transaction costs.”

With exogenous measures of transaction, information, and contract enforcement costs I can

avoid using proxy measures for stock market development and the burden of simultaneity and

omitted variables that plague them. The measures also bring the empirical work in line with the

theory. The findings are far from definitive, but they do add to the growing body of evidence

that suggests a link between stock markets and economic growth in a much cleaner method than

previously used. Also, the estimated effects for transaction costs can be used to evaluate policy

proposals such as a securities transaction tax that I discuss in Chapter 4.

3.1 GENERAL SPECIFICATION

Previous researchers have used a general form to represent stock markets’ relationship

with economic growth of

Page 41: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

28

, (7)

where GROWTH is the annual growth rate of real GDP per capita, SD is stock market

development, and X is a set of exogenous control variables. Unfortunately, stock market

development, particularly the proxy variables traditionally used to measure it, is aided by

economic growth,

, (8)

where Z is a set of exogenous determinants of stock market development. Since economic

growth influences stock market development, using the traditional proxy measures in an

economic growth regression causes a simultaneity problem that leads to inconsistent estimates.

Also, any unobserved components of Z, such as advances in technology, that are not actually

exogenous can lead to omitted variable bias.

3.2 INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES

Rather than using the proxy measures of stock market development, I use transaction

costs, an exogenous component of Z, to serve as an instrument for turnover ratio in economic

growth regressions. Beck and Levine (2004) suggest turnover ratio is the preferred proxy

measures of stock market development. Capitalization is not a good variable because theory

does not suggest that simply listing shares on the stock market will influence resource allocation

and growth (Beck and Levine 2004, 428). Value traded is not a good proxy because it measures

the size of the stock market relative to the size of the economy and not stock market liquidity.

Value traded is also potentially more biased than turnover ratio because value traded includes

share prices that would likely be bid up with expectations of higher economic growth (Beck, et al

2004, 428).

Page 42: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

29

The system of equations I estimate is

, (9)

, (10)

where TR is turnover ratio, and the hat over TR indicates it is the predicted values of TR from

the first equation. Some of the variables in X appear in all of the regressions. The constant

controls are: the log of the initial level of GDP per capita, the log of one plus the average years

of schooling, and the log of credit issued by the banking sector as a percentage of GDP. The

remaining controls in X are interchanged in separate regressions. The remaining controls are the

log of government consumption as a percentage of GDP, the log of imports and exports divided

by GDP, and the log of one plus CPI inflation.

I estimate both cross-section and fixed-effects models. Countries in the cross-section

regressions are given in Table 5 and summary statistics are given in Table 6. To compare with

previous results, the transaction cost estimates are matched up to the data from Beck and Levine

(2004). Although the transaction costs are estimated for 74 countries, Beck and Levine only

have 40 countries and of those, only 29 of those countries have both transaction cost and

turnover ratio data. Results are given in Table 7. The estimated effects are at best only a tenth

the size of the estimated effects Beck and Levine find. I bootstrap with a thousand repetitions to

account for the small sample size and none of the results are statistically significant.

Countries in the fixed-effects regressions are given in Table 8 and summary statistics are

given in Table 9. There are more countries in the fixed-effects regression as I am not matching

up to the regressions by Beck and Levine. There are almost 50 countries in the instrumental

variables fixed effects regressions. Some of the 74 countries I estimate transaction costs for only

have a few years of data and some do not have data for turnover ratio. The instrumental

Page 43: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

30

variables fixed-effects results are given in Table 10. Unlike in the cross-section regressions, the

estimated effects from the fixed-effects regressions are considerably larger than the results Beck

and Levine find. The estimated effects are more than 8 times greater than Beck and Levine find.

Despite the larger estimated effects, none of the estimated effects are statistically significant.

The strange results likely result from transaction costs being a weak instrument for

turnover ratio. To be a valid instrument for turnover ratio in an economic growth regression,

transaction costs must be uncorrelated with the error term in Equation 10 such that

. (11)

This condition is assumed to hold, although in the introductory section I gave some reasons why

it might not hold that I will revisit in Section 3.6. The second criterion for transaction cost to be

a valid instrument for turnover ratio is for transaction costs to be partially correlated with

turnover ratio. Despite the findings in Chapter 2, this assumption does not appear to hold. The

F-statistic from the first equation is never greater than 2, suggesting the transaction cost

estimates do not serve as a good instrument turnover ratio. The weakness of transaction costs

may at least partially explain the statistically and economically insignificant results found in the

instrumental variables regressions.

3.3 REDUCED FORM CROSS-COUNTRY ESTIMATES

For a different approach, I replace the traditional proxy measures of stock market

development with measures of stock market efficiency from Z and estimate a reduced form

equation. Specifically, I use exogenous measures of transaction, information, and contract

enforcement costs so the economic growth equation becomes

, (12)

Page 44: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

31

where TC is transaction costs, IC is information costs, and CE is contract enforcement costs.

Including measures of these costs also allows for better policy prescriptions than when including

the proxy measures of stock market development.

In Chapter 2, I develop estimates of transaction costs. I also discuss variables that

represent information costs and contract enforcement costs. A measure of accounting standards

from the Center for International Financial Analysis represents information costs. A set of

dummy variables identifying the origin of the commercial law system represents contract

enforcement costs. The regression specification I estimate is

, (13)

where AC is accounting standards, LOB is British legal origin, LOF is French legal origin, and

LOS is Scandinavian legal origin. Socialist legal origin is the excluded dummy variable.

The results are given in Table 11 and standard errors are derived by bootstrapping with

1,000 repetitions to account for the small sample size. The variables related to stock market

costs all enter in level form, as does the growth rate of real GDP per capita, so the coefficient

interpretation is straightforward. The coefficients no longer represent stock market development

generally, rather they are estimated effects of the individual costs stock markets theoretically

reduce. The estimated effect of transaction cost is consistently negative. Lower transaction costs

indicate a more developed stock market, which theory suggests leads to more economic growth.

The estimated effect size ranges from -0.07 and -0.16 so a one-percentage point decrease in

transaction costs would suggest an increase in economic growth between 0.07 and 0.16

percentage points. A one standard deviation decrease in a country’s transaction costs would

suggest an increase in economic growth between 0.33 percentage points and 0.77 percentage

points. These results, however, are not statistically significant.

Page 45: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

32

The estimated effects for information costs are unexpected. Accounting standards has a

negative estimated effect, which is counterintuitive since a higher score on accounting standards

indicates better information is available in those countries. Better information availability should

be good for economic growth. The results are statistically significant but economically small.

The estimated effect size is only -0.002. A one standard deviation improvement in accounting

standards would suggest a decrease in economic growth of only 0.026 percentage points. In fact,

a country moving from the minimum accounting standard to the highest account standard would

expect to see a change in economic growth of only 0.11 percentage points. It may be that the

effort expended on keeping high accounting standards exceeds the benefit of low information

costs.

The estimated effects for contract enforcement costs are all small and statistically

insignificant. The greatest magnitude of effect is 0.031 and the smallest is -0.001. Countries

with British and Scandinavian origins for their commercial law systems do slightly better than

countries with socialist origins. Countries with French origins for their commercial law systems

perform slightly worse than countries with socialist origins.

Taken together the results indicate stock markets have a modest effect on economic

growth at best. I test the joint significance of the measures for transaction, information, and

contract enforcement costs and find they are not jointly significant. Also, the reduction of

different costs has different direction of effects on economic growth. One possible cause of the

small estimated effects for information costs and contract enforcement costs is that the variables

used to represent those costs are not direct measurements of the costs like the transaction cost

measure is. More work to develop actual measures of those costs could help to improve the

estimated effects. More work to develop better measures of information and contract

Page 46: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

33

enforcement costs might also focus on developing measures of those costs with a time series

component that would allow for a panel examination of how those costs affect economic growth.

3.4 REDUCED FORM FIXED-EFFECTS ESTIMATES

Since the transaction cost estimates are available over time as well as across countries,

they can be used in panel regressions. The information and contract enforcement costs do not

vary over time, however, so the new regression equation is simply

, (14)

where is the country-specific effects and t is the time period. The data are averaged into four

five-year periods from 1990 to 2009. 2 There are more than 60 countries available since turnover

ratio is no longer needed for these regressions.

Results for this data are given in Table 12. The estimated effects for transaction costs

have the expected negative sign, are statistically significant, and are larger than the cross-country

estimated effects. The estimated effects are between -0.172 and -0.225. A one standard

deviation decrease in transaction costs would suggest an increase in economic growth between

0.81 and 1.1 percentage points.

The panel results not only support the findings from the cross-section regression of a

negative relationship between transaction costs and economic growth, they also suggest the

effect might be larger. The ability to trade in and out of stock holdings does seem to matter for

economic growth. One note of caution on the panel results is warranted. Since information and

contract enforcement costs are not in the regression there is a potential for omitted variable bias

leading to inflated, or deflated, estimated effects of transaction costs. This would only be a

2 The data was also divided into three five-year periods from 1993 to 2007 to see if the cutoff years for the time

periods made a difference. Countries and summary statistics are given in Tables 13 and 14. The results are given in

Table 15. The cutoff points do not seem to make a difference.

Page 47: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

34

problem, however, if information or contract enforcement costs mattered for economic growth

and mattered for transaction costs.

The cross-section results raise doubts about the importance of information and contract

enforcement costs for economic growth. It is also not likely that those costs are very important

for transaction costs since transaction costs are driven by fees, commissions, bid-ask spreads and

liquidity concerns. Information costs could play a role in the bid-ask spread as higher

information costs give more pricing power to the market maker. That pricing power relates to

only one component of transaction costs, however, and any bias it introduced would depend on

the effect size of information costs on economic growth.

3.5 COMPARISON TO REGRESSIONS WITH TURNOVER RATIO

To see if the smaller estimated effects I find are a function of the new approach I use or

something else, I estimate the same cross-section regression without controlling for simultaneity

or omitted variables that Beck and Levine (2004) estimate but on the smaller time period and

number of countries. I also estimate fixed-effects regressions without controlling for

simultaneity or omitted variables. The cross-section regression results are given in Table 16 and

the fixed-effects results are given in Table 17. Turnover ratio is not statistically significant in

any of the cross-section or fixed-effects regressions. The estimated effect sizes are a tenth to a

third of the estimated effects found by Beck and Levine. These results suggest that the time

period and countries in the sample are important factors in measuring the relationship between

stock markets and economic growth. The small and statistically insignificant estimated effects

for transaction, information, and contract enforcement costs may be the result of stock markets

not exerting as much influence on economic growth as they did in previous time periods.

Page 48: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

35

3.6 REMAINING ISSUES

These results modestly support the previous research that stock market development

contributes positively to economic growth. The contribution does not appear to be large and

comes mainly from transaction costs. This small effect may result from poor variables used to

stand in for information and contract enforcement costs. Transaction costs were the only costs

that were directly estimated and their estimated effects were considerably larger than the

estimated effects for the other costs. It is possible that better measures of the other costs would

have a similar result. The smaller and insignificant findings using turnover ratio as a proxy

measure of stock market development than other studies find suggest the link between stock

markets and economic growth may not be as strong as it once was.

Another potential problem with these results is the assumption that the costs are

exogenous to economic growth. This assumption is likely valid for the variables representing

contract enforcement and information costs. The origin of the commercial law system was likely

not influenced by current economic growth. Accounting standards are also determined prior to

current economic growth. As mentioned in Chapter 2, however, the transaction cost estimates

are influenced by liquidity concerns. These concerns are particularly noticeable with business

cycle fluctuations. Economic growth, however, is a long-run concept that is not influenced by

short-run fluctuations. Looking at transaction costs over a similarly long period of time should

remove the influence of the short-run liquidity concerns.

The simultaneity and omitted variable problems may not be completely eliminated by

using the transaction cost estimates either. Economic growth may lead to additional resources

being devoted to developing the stock market, which could reduce transaction costs. Also,

Page 49: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

36

unobserved effects, such as the internet, could improve both economic growth and transaction

costs. This effect, however, is likely small. Economic growth does not influence taxes, fees, and

trading methods (quote driven or order driven market). Technological advancements are also

unlikely to influence taxes, fees or trading methods. They may, however, influence

commissions, opportunity costs, and the trading software exchanges use. If transaction costs are

not sufficiently exogenous to economic growth, then the results from instrumental variables

regressions in Section 3.2 would be invalid. Still, the simultaneity and omitted variable

problems with economic growth and transaction costs are likely to be considerably smaller than

the simultaneity and omitted variable problems with size and activity since economic growth

attracts additional investment.

To allow for the possibility the exogeneity assumption does not hold for transaction costs,

I also use the system difference estimator by Arellano-Bover (1995). The system difference

estimator builds on the Arellano and Bond (1991) approach by combining the regression in

differences, the Arellano-Bond procedure, with a regression in levels. The regression in

differences handles endogeneity by assuming that lagged values of the explanatory variables in

levels are not correlated with the differenced error terms. The regression in levels, on the other

hand, assumes differenced explanatory variables are not correlated with the error term in levels

or the country specific effects. Using Equation 13, the following moment conditions are:

( ) for s ≥ 0; t = 3, . . ., T, (15)

for s ≥ 0; t = 3, . . ., T, (16)

for the regression in differences and

( ) for s = 1, (17)

for s = 1, (18)

Page 50: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

37

for the regression in levels, where X includes all of the previously mentioned explanatory

variables except the level of real GDP per capita and Y is the level of real GDP per capita rather

than the growth rate.

This estimator will be consistent as long as the instruments are valid and the error terms

do not exhibit serial correlation. The instruments are considered valid if the moment conditions

just described hold in the sample. Serial correlation is considered not to exist if there is no

second-order serial correlation in the differenced error term. Both tests are constructed such that

not rejecting the null hypothesis is evidence in favor of the model. One other note on the test is

that the standard errors in the system difference estimator could be biased downwards,

particularly if the number of instruments exceeds the number of countries. In this model, the

number of countries, around 60, exceeds the number of instruments, around 20. I also use small

sample properties and the robust two-step estimator to correct for the downward bias.

Results of the system difference estimator are given in Table 18. The test results on the

suitability of the model are mixed. Serial correlation is not a problem as the null hypothesis of

no serial correlation is not rejected in any of the regressions. The quality of the instruments is

troublesome with the null hypothesis that the moment conditions holding being rejected in two of

the four regressions. The lack of quality results for the model overall may result from only

having only four time periods. While there are enough periods to estimate the model, the method

is based on using multiple lags as instruments. With only four time periods, there simply are not

many lags to be used. The results generally support the effect size found in the other regressions

as well as their statistical insignificance.

Page 51: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

38

CHAPTER 4 – POLICY IMPLICATIONS

Using measures of transaction, information, and contract enforcement costs as measures

of stock market development opens up new opportunities for research in ways that give clearer

policy guidance than when stock market development is measured by the traditional proxy

measures. The link between stock market activity and economic growth has been one of indirect

association. Active stock markets probably have lower information, transaction, and contract

enforcement costs than less active stock markets so they probably do a better job of producing

information, monitoring investments, facilitating risk management, mobilizing savings, and

easing exchange of goods and services too (Levine 2006, 869).

These positive outcomes from stock markets are probably not the direct result of size or

activity, however. If they were, then governments could increase economic growth simply by

buying and selling shares of stock. It is more likely that greater stock market activity results

from reduced information, transaction, and contract enforcement costs and those reduced costs

also lead to greater economic growth. Gaining a better understanding of how important these

costs are for economic growth will lead to better policy prescriptions than simply increasing

trading activity. By looking specifically at transaction costs, for example, we can evaluate

policies that would affect the cost of trading.

4.1 SECURITIES TRANSACTION TAXES

One such policy is the proposal to tax securities transactions. The logic behind this

policy is that the tax would reduce the volatility of stock markets by driving out speculators.

Page 52: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

39

Since stock market volatility can be destabilizing to an economy, decreasing it is good. The

estimates of transaction costs will help us evaluate whether such taxes would reduce stock

market volatility or not. Regardless of whether the taxes reduce stock market volatility or not,

the research in the previous chapter refutes the overall benefits of securities transaction taxes in a

way the other research on stock market development does not. By estimating the direction and

size of the effect transaction costs have on economic growth, I show by how much a securities

transaction tax would negatively affect economic growth.

Proposals to tax securities have popped up every decade for the last 30 years. Although

the proposals can be traced back to Keynes' General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money

where he likened Wall Street to a casino (159), the modern push for the tax originated with

James Tobin's (1978, 6) advocacy for a tax on foreign exchange transactions. Lawrence

Summers (1989) calls for a 0.5% tax on debt and equity securities trades. Pollin et al. (2003)

continue the push for a 0.5% tax on securities transactions. In 2009, House Resolution 1068,

called the “Let Wall Street Pay for Wall Street's Bailout Act,” was introduced calling for

unspecified securities transaction taxes.

Proponents of a securities transaction tax cite two primary reasons to support it: it would

discourage short-term speculation, and it would raise tax revenue. Short-term speculation, the

thinking goes, leads to excessive volatility, a diversion of human and physical capital into the

financial sector away from more socially profitable activities, and short-sighted corporate

investment decisions (Summers 1989, 165). Pollin et al. (2003, 532) propose two other negative

effects of speculation in financial markets: herd behavior that leads to deflationary spirals and

weakened macroeconomic stabilization tools. The suggested cure, however, has little to do with

the disease.

Page 53: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

40

Levine and Zervos (1998, 550) find a negative relationship between volatility and

economic growth. To the extent that speculators are the cause of excessive volatility, reducing

speculation may be beneficial to economic growth. But not all speculators are destabilizing.

Speculation can be loosely broken out into two groups: trading against price movements and

trading with price movements. Traders who trade going against price movements would buy a

stock that seems undervalued and sell a stock that seems overvalued. These traders would push a

stock's price back towards its fundamentals determined value and reduce volatility. Traders who

trade going with price movements would sell when prices are falling and buy when prices are

rising. These traders would be expecting the trend to continue and would reinforce it by their

actions. They would potentially drive the price further away from its fundamentals determined

value. These “noise traders” would lead to the herd mentality that leads to deflationary spirals

and increases volatility.

The advocates of a securities transaction tax seek to discourage noise traders. A

securities transaction tax, however, does not discriminate between noise traders and investors

trading on fundamentals. The hope is that noise traders would be more affected by the tax

because they trade more than investors who trade on fundamentals and who employ a buy and

hold strategy. But since investors who buy and hold do not, by definition, trade frequently, they

do not help a stock move back toward a fundamentals determined price. It takes traders who are

willing to make trades whenever a stock price has deviated from its fundamentals determined

value to keep the price near that value. To reduce the influence of noise investors, a market

needs to increase short-term trading based on fundamentals relative to short-term trading based

on trends. A securities transaction tax would not do so.

Page 54: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

41

Evidence indicates that a securities transaction tax would actually increase volatility.

Charles Jones and Paul Seguin (1997, 729) look at the deregulation of commissions in the United

States. Steven Umlauf (1993, 233) looks at changes in securities taxes in Sweden. Harald Hau

(2006, 864) looks at changes in the tick size on the Paris Bourse. All of these researchers find a

positive relationship between transaction costs and volatility, indicating a securities transaction

tax would increase volatility. This finding is the opposite effect proponents of such a tax intend.

There is some research indicating securities transaction taxes do work to dampen

volatility, but this evidence is weak at best. Wade Brorsen (1991, 161) and Shing-Yang Hu

(1998) find some support for taxes reducing volatility, but the effects were either short-run or not

robust. Richard Roll (1989, 140) looks at the performance of financial markets in 23 countries

around the 1987 crash and found weak support for transaction taxes reducing volatility. Roll

relies on a dummy variable for whether a country had a securities transaction tax or not, but only

four countries in his sample did not have the tax. Also, while the results consistently show the

expected negative result between the presence of a tax and volatility, these results are seldom

significant and are sensitive to the inclusion of Mexico. When Mexico is excluded, the results

are no longer even weakly significant nor do they have the expected negative relationship. Roll

is also looking specifically around the 1987 crash. Tax proponents are concerned generally

about market volatility, but it is particularly destabilizing market crashes that concern them the

most. In one of the most extreme crashes, the ability to dampen volatility appears to be lacking.

The transaction cost estimates produced here can provide more direct evidence on whether

taxing stock market transactions would reduce stock market volatility.

Even in advocating for a securities transaction tax, Pollin et al. (538) admit that the

evidence is mixed on whether or not increased transaction costs reduce stock market volatility.

Page 55: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

42

There is another avenue, according to Pollin et al., for securities transaction taxes to reduce the

negative effects of volatility. By reducing the size of the market, a lender of last resort, such as

the government, will be able to have greater influence during a crisis. Since securities

transaction taxes may well increase volatility, it seems counterproductive to want to strengthen

the ability of the government to fix a problem that is exacerbated by the very attempt to

strengthen the government. Also, strengthening the government's ability to manage a crisis in

the stock market would come at the expense of economic growth.

Atje and Jovanovic (1993, 632), Levine and Zervos (1998), Arestis et al. (2001, 17),

Rousseau and Wachtel (2000, 1934), and Beck and Levine (2004, 436) find a positive

relationship between stock market size and/or activity and economic growth. Furthermore, the

research in the previous chapter refutes the benefits of a securities transaction tax even further.

The cost of transacting on stock markets is negatively related with economic growth. That is, it

is not just stock market activity that matters for growth, the cost of trading matters too. A tax

that increases the cost of trading securities would thus decrease economic growth.

The other concerns raised regarding excessive volatility also seem to have little to do

with the cost of transacting on stock markets and would not necessarily be addressed by a

securities transaction tax. The finance industry is not a socially undesirable industry, so capital

invested in finance does not necessarily have a more socially profitable pursuit. Like all

industries, the socially desirable allocation of capital depends on the cost of capital and the return

generated by that capital. A decrease in transaction costs would change this allocation in favor

of more capital in the financial sector, but if well-functioning stock markets increase economic

growth, then more capital would be a good thing. If there is reason to believe there is excess

Page 56: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

43

investment in the financial sector, it is better to look at non-market reasons for either the excess

return in finance or depressed returns in other sectors.

Another concern is that stock markets encourage managers to focus on short-run gains at

the expense of long-run planning. This focus, however, happens because of investors, not low

transaction costs. To the extent that low transaction costs increase the number of investors in a

stock market, they will increase the number of investors interested in long-term planning. Paul

Davidson (1998) discusses how a securities transaction tax will reduce trading volume and

increase volatility. A thicker market will be more likely to have traders with more diverse views.

The final point in favor of a securities transaction tax is that it generates tax revenue.

While the tax may not discourage negative activity, if it provides tax revenue that could offset

other more distortionary taxes or fund more productive government activities, then the tax could

still be a good idea. Given that the tax is likely to reduce economic growth, the usefulness of the

tax would depend on the gains from government using the tax revenue exceeding the lost

economic growth.

Pollin et al. (2003) estimate tax revenue for a 0.5% roundtrip securities transaction tax on

equity securities to range from $27.5 billion to $54.9 billion based on 1997 trading data. Based

on the results from the previous chapter, a 0.5% tax per transaction would have been associated

with 0.035 to 0.11 percentage points slower economic growth in the United States. GDP in 1997

was $8.3 trillion, so the tax would have been associated with GDP growth between $2.9 billion

and $9.3 billion less that year than without the tax.3 These numbers do not include the loss in tax

revenue from other taxes. Ulauf (1993) finds that Swedish transaction taxes reduced capital

gains tax collections by about the same amount as the taxes collected by the transaction tax. If

economic growth decreases, then income taxes, payroll, and corporate taxes would decrease too.

3 Based on 2011 GDP, the lost growth would range between $5 billion and $17 billion a year.

Page 57: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

44

A securities transaction tax not only reduces economic growth but it may decrease overall tax

revenue.

Whatever appeal a securities transaction tax may have, the empirical evidence does not

support the theoretical predictions of its advocates. Even if the large and active markets were

susceptible to destabilizing volatility, the evidence presented in this dissertation indicates

increasing transaction costs on those markets is not a wise cure. The cost of transacting on a

stock market is shown to be important for economic growth. The efficiency of stock markets

matters. Getting capital flowing on a market is important, but it is also important not to impede

that capital. That is exactly what a securities transaction tax would do.

4.2 CAPITAL GAINS TAXES

Like transaction costs, capital gains taxes affect investor decisions to trade. The tax

treatment of short-term and long-term gains can reduce market volatility by punishing different

types of trading behavior more than others. As with securities transaction taxes, capital gains

taxes alter trading behavior and can be expected to affect economic growth. Evidence of

behavior resulting from tax considerations can be found in increased trading around the dates of

capital gains tax changes and December trading to take the tax deduction from losses. Since

capital gains taxes affect trading decisions, the transaction costs estimated here may fully capture

the economic effect of these taxes. However, they may not, so the effect of capital gains taxes is

worth further examination.

If short-term capital gains are taxed at a higher rate than long-term gains, investors are

encouraged to hold stocks for longer periods of time and discouraged from short-term

speculation. As stated previously, discouraging short-term trading does not mean discouraging

Page 58: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

45

only destabilizing trading. Also, by giving a tax advantage to short-term losses, policy makers

are encouraging investors to take losses on short-term holdings over long-term holdings, which

can reinforce a deflationary spiral.

The effect on trading behavior of capital gains taxes is well documented. George

Constantinides (1984) uses simulations to demonstrate how traders can increase profits by using

timely trading strategies based on when gains and losses are realized. Edward Dyl (1977) and

Joel Slemrod (1982) find empirical support for the hypothesis that capital gains taxes lead to

abnormally high selling of down stocks and abnormally low selling of up stocks in December.

Ross Levine (1991) constructs a theoretical model of stock markets, economic growth,

and several different taxes. While a capital gains tax, which is actually a transaction tax in the

model, is not found to be the most disruptive of the taxes, it does impede capital accumulation,

and thus economic growth. More examination of the relationship between transaction costs and

capital gains taxes will help determine if Levine's treatment of a capital gains tax as a securities

transaction tax is appropriate or if the behavior changes brought on by capital gains taxes

produce separate growth effects.

4.3 SOURCES OF GROWTH

There are also opportunities to improve our understanding of stock markets’ role in

economic growth. The channels for stock market development to affect economic growth still

need more study. Do more efficient stock markets help capital find more productive uses? Do

more efficient stock markets encourage more savings and capital accumulation? Do more

efficient stock markets do both? More efficient stock markets may be particularly important for

Page 59: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

46

one or more of the following: producing information, monitoring investments, facilitating risk

management, mobilizing savings, and easing exchange of goods and services.

The research presented here adds to previous findings that stock market development is

important for economic growth by specifically looking at the efficiency of stock markets. It does

not, however, address how that efficiency translates into more economic growth. Levine and

Zervos (1998) consider three different channels through which stock markets might affect

economic growth. They find that stock market development increases productivity and capital

accumulation but has no effect on savings rates. Valerie Bencivenga, Bruce Smith, and Ross

Starr (1995) present a theoretical framework for the relationship between transaction costs and

capital accumulation. In their model, lower transaction costs lead to higher rates of savings, but

the composition of the savings, and subsequently the capital stock, change in ambiguous ways.

This theoretical finding is the opposite of the empirical findings of Levine and Zervos.

The stock market transaction cost estimates produced in this dissertation can provide a

more direct test of the findings of Bencivenga et al. It is possible that the theoretical results hold

when applied to transaction costs but get reversed when looking at other measures of stock

market development. For example, lower transaction costs may promote more savings, but a

wealth effect from increased economic growth may bring that rate back down.

Similarly, the transaction costs produced here can be used to help examine how

successful stock markets are at producing information, monitoring investments, facilitating risk

management, mobilizing savings, and easing exchange of goods and services. A critique of

stock markets' role in economic growth is that stock markets do not provide sufficient

information, diversification of risk, or corporate governance. Since stock markets are supposed

to do these things by reducing financial information, transaction, and contract enforcement costs;

Page 60: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

47

then using measures of transaction costs will help to identify how well stock market perform

those functions.

4.4 GROWTH VOLATILITY

A transaction cost approach to stock market development can also improve our

understanding of how stock markets contribute to economic growth volatility. As John Maynard

Keynes once said, we are all dead in the long run. Stock markets may have positive long-run

effects on an economy but still be destabilizing in the short-run. Stock markets may help capital

find its most productive use, but that does not necessarily mean that it does so quickly or

painlessly. The ability to transfer ownership of assets does nothing to change either the nature of

the physical capital or the incentive for firms to acquire more physical capital (Pollin 2003, 529).

If highly active and efficient stock markets contribute to economic volatility, these negative

effects may outweigh the positive gains to economic growth. If, however, well-functioning stock

markets contribute to a stable short-run economic environment, then there is added reason to

promote stock markets with low trading costs.

The short-run effects of transaction costs are not addressed here. Much like with

economic growth, however, other researchers have examined the role of stock market size and

activity in economic volatility. The results have been a mix of stock markets dampening

volatility, to magnifying it, to doing nothing.

William Easterly, Roumeen Islam, and Joseph Stiglitz (2000) examine various causes of

growth volatility and find financial development to be a more important determinant than more

expected causes, like wage and price rigidity. The authors focus primarily on measures of bank

development but do find that stock market development, as measured by value traded, reduces

Page 61: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

48

the probability of an economic downturn (204). The authors also find that banking development

is a stabilizing force on economic volatility for low levels of banking development (202). As a

banking sector develops more, however, banks tend to exacerbate economic volatility. The

authors do not report whether they find the same result with stock market development.

Another interesting finding from Easterly et al. (204) is that banking development

increases the probability of an economic downturn even though it reduces economic volatility.

Combined with the result on stock market development, this finding means that economies

respond differently depending on whether debt or equity is the more prominent finance vehicle.

Add this result to the finding of Arestis et al. (2001) that banking development exerts a much

larger influence on economic growth than stock market development, and there is an obvious

risk-reward tradeoff. A country could have more growth with bank development but a greater

chance of recessions than with stock market development.

Thorsten Beck, Mattias Lundberg and Giovanni Majnoni (2006, 1159) find the effect of

banking development on economic volatility depends on what caused the volatility in the first

place. Real sector shocks are dampened by a more developed banking system while monetary

shocks are magnified. This finding suggests a volatile monetary policy could have a magnified

effect in a country with a well-developed banking system. The authors control for stock market

capitalization but do not report how stock market development matters for growth volatility.

Piyapas Tharavanij (2007, 22) uses turnover ratio to look specifically at the role of stock

markets in business cycle volatility. Using panel data for 44 countries from 1975 to 2004, the

author finds more developed stock markets reduce economic fluctuations. Interestingly,

Tharavanij finds less support for banking development playing an important role in economic

growth volatility. Combining this result with the results from Arestis et al. (2001) that bank

Page 62: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

49

development is much more important for economic growth than stock market development, there

is again a contrast between when and how the different types of financial development matter for

economic activity. This conflict can be better resolved using transaction costs to measure stock

market development.

4.5 DETERMINANTS OF TRANSACTION COSTS

The transaction cost estimates can be used to study a variety of effects stock markets

have on other economic activity. Perhaps equally interesting, however, is using them to study

what causes the efficiency of stock markets to differ across countries. In this case transaction

costs would go from being an independent variable to the dependent variable. Such a study

would further help guide policy makers in decisions about taxing, regulating, and configuring

stock markets.

Transaction taxes have already been shown to negatively affect economic growth. The

transaction costs produced here could also be used to see who bears the tax burden of transaction

taxes. If the demand for trading stock is inelastic, then transaction taxes would be expected to

increase the transaction cost by the amount of the tax. If, however, investors have other options

(such as other investments or buying the same stocks on overseas exchanges) then the demand

for investing can be expected to be elastic. If so, transaction taxes may have minimal effect on

transaction costs as the market maker or the exchange bear the burden of the tax.

These transaction cost estimates can also be used to determine which system, quote-

driven or order-driven, results in lower transaction costs. One practical difficulty in evaluating

the different systems is that most markets are now hybrid systems, with most orders being

matched in an order driven system but with market makers available to match trades when

Page 63: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

50

needed. Adequately classifying the differences in markets may be difficult. Still, there are

variations in how markets operate so these estimates can be used to help determine which

variations are the most efficient. Armed with this information, exchanges could set up their

trading systems in the most efficient way.

Internet trading grew increasingly popular during the time period of these transaction cost

estimates. In the earliest years of the estimates, there was no internet trading. Internet trading

also grew in popularity at different rates in different countries. These transaction cost estimates

can be used to determine how big of an effect the internet had on the cost of trading stock.

4.6 CONCLUSION

The research produced here contributes to our base of economic knowledge in three

distinct steps. Step 1 is to produce the means. In Chapter 2, I produce a set of annual stock

market transaction cost estimates that spans 95 exchanges in 74 countries for up to 20 years. The

estimates can be aggregated by country or disaggregated by firm. While the estimates by

themselves are of limited value, they can facilitate future research into stock markets and their

economic effects.

In Chapter 3, I advance our understanding of how stock markets affect economic growth.

Stock markets develop by reducing financial information, transaction, and contract enforcement

costs. Previous empirical research has glossed over these theorized functions of stock markets

by focusing on proxy measures of stock market development that measure stock market size and

activity. Large stock markets with lots of activity probably reduce these costs better than stock

markets with less activity and lead to better economic growth but better economic growth also

leads to larger and more active stock markets. By replacing these proxy measures of stock

Page 64: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

51

market development with measures of information, transaction, and contract enforcement costs, I

can better control for the simultaneity and omitted variable problems with stock markets and

economic growth and infer better policy prescriptions. The estimated effect sizes are small and

indicate the importance of stock markets may have faded since the earlier studies. The change in

findings over time suggests more study is need to test the durability of the relationship between

stock markets and economic growth.

In Chapter 4, I am able to make direct policy prescriptions based on these findings.

Previous research could only say that trading activity was good for economic growth but it could

not get more concrete than that. Based on the estimated effects produced here, a 0.5% roundtrip

tax on stock trades would be expected to decrease current economic growth by $5 to $17 billion

a year.

Page 65: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

52

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Admati, A., & Pfleiderer, P. (1991). Sunshine trading and financial market equilibrium. Review

of Financial Studies, 4(3), 443-481.

Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1980). Dealership Market: Market Making with Inventory.

Journal of Financial Economics, 8(1), 31-53.

Anand, A., Tanggaard, C., & Weaver, D. (2009). Paying for market quality. Jounral of Financial

and Quantitative Analysis, 44(6), 1427-1457.

Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo and an

application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-297.

Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation of error-

components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-52.

Arestis, P., Demetriades, P., & Luintel, K. (2001). Financial Development and Economic

Growth: The Role of Stock Markets. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 33(1), 16-

41.

Atje, R., & Jovanovic, B. (1993). Stock Markets and Development. European Economic Review,

37(2-3), 632-640.

Bagehot, W. (1873). Lombard Street. A Description of the Money Market (2005 ed.). Fairford,

Glas: The Echo Library.

Batista, V., & Palmiero, T. (2002). The Euromoney Guide to World Equity Markets 2002.

London: Euromoney Books.

Beck, T., & Levine, R. (2004). Stock markets, banks, and growth: Panel evidence. Journal of

Banking and Finance, 28(3), 423-442.

Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2000). A New Database on on the Structure and

Development of the Financial Sector. World Bank Economic Review, 14(3), 597-605.

Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2001). Legal Theories of Financial Development.

Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 17(4), 483-501.

Beck, T., Lundberg, M., & Majnoni, G. (2006). Financial intermediary development and growth

volatility: Do intermediaries dampen or magnify shocks? Journal of Internatinoal Money

and Finance, 25(7), 1146-1167.

Page 66: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

53

Bellelah, M., Boubaker, A., & Sebai, S. (2006). Estimation of Transaction Costs on the Tunisia

Stock Exchange: An Empirical Research Via a Tobit Model with Frictions. International

Journal of Business, 11(2), 89-106.

Bencivenga, V., & Smith, B. &. (1995). Transaction Costs, Technological Choice and

Endogenous Growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 67(1), 153-177.

Bentson, G., & Smith, C. (1976). A Transaction Cost Approach to the Theory of Financial

Intermediation. Journal of Finance, 32(2), 215-231.

Benveniste, L., Marcus, A., & Wilhelm, W. (1992). What's special about the specialist. Journal

of Financial Economics, 32(1), 61-86.

Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel

data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143.

Brorsen, W. (1991). Futures Trading, Transaction Costs, and Stock Market Volatility. The

Journal of Futures Markets, 11(2), 153-163.

Chinn, M., & Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? Capital controls,

institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics, 81(1), 163-192.

Constantinides, G. (1984). Optimal Trading with Personal Taxes: Implications for Prices and

Abnormal January Returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 13(1), 65-89.

Davidson, P. (1998). Volatile Financial Markets and the Speculator. Economic Issues, 3(2), 1-18.

De Soto, H. (2000). The Mystery of Capital. New York, NY: Basic Books.

DeAngelo, H., & E, R. (1983). Anti-Takeover Charter Amendments and Stockholder Wealth.

Journal of Financial Economics, 11(1-4), 329-360.

Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2001). Financial Structure and Economic Growth: A Cross-

Country Comparison of Banks, Markets, and Development. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Dyl, E. (1977). Capital Gains Taxation and Year-End Stock Market Behavior. The Journal of

Finance, 32(1), 165-175.

Easterly, W., Islam, R., & Stiglitz, J. (2000). Shaken and Stirred: Explaining Growth Volatility.

(B. Pleskovic, & N. Stern, Eds.) Annual Bank Conference on Development 2000, pp. 191-

211.

Foster, M., & George, T. (1992). Anonymity in securities markets. Journal of Financial

Intermediation, 2(2), 168-206.

Garman, M. (1976). Market Microstructure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(3), 257-275.

Page 67: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

54

George, T., Kaul, G., & Nimalendran, M. (1991). Estimation of the Bid-Ask Spread and its

Components. Review of Financial Studies, 4(4), 623-656.

Griffin, J., Kelly, P., & Nardari, F. (2006, January 16). Measurement Short-Term International

Stock Market Efficiency. Retrieved July 25, 2011, from

http://69.175.2.130/~finman/Orlando/Papers/IntlInfoEff.pdf

Grossman, S., & Hart, O. (1980). Takeover Bids, the Free-Rider Problem, and the Theory of the

Corporation. Bell Journal of Economics, 11(1), 42-64.

Harris, L. (2003). Trading and Exchanges: Market Microstructure for Practitioners. New York,

NY: Oxford University Press.

Harris, R. (1997). Stock markets and development: A re-assessment. European Economic

Review, 41(1), 139-146.

Hau, H. (2006). The Role of Transaction Costs in Financial Volatility: Evidence from the Paris

Bourse. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(4), 862-890.

Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2011). Penn World Table Version 7.0. Center for

International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of

Pennsylvania.

Hu, S. (1998). The Effects of the Stock Transaction Tax on the Stock Market - Experience from

Asian Markets. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 6(3-4), 985-1000.

Jensen, M. (1993). The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal Control

Systems. Journal of Finance, 48(3), 831-880.

Jones, C., & Seguin, P. (1997). Transaction Costs and Price Volatility. American Economic

Review, 87(4), 728-737.

Keynes, J. (1936). General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York: Harcourt,

Brace and Company.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Government Ownership of Banks.

Journal of Finance, 57(1), 265-301.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Legal Determinants of

External Finance. Journal of Finance, 52(3), 1131-1150.

Law, S., & Habibulla, M. (2009). The determinants of financial development: Institutions,

openness, and financial liberalization. South African Journal of Economics, 77(1), 45-58.

Lesmond, D., Ogden, J., & Trzcinka, C. (1999). A New Estimate of Transaction Costs. The

Review of Financial Studies, 12(5), 1113-1141.

Page 68: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

55

Levine, R. (1991). Stock Markets, Growth, and Tax Policy. The Journal of Finance, 46(4), 1445-

1465.

Levine, R. (1997). Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda. Journal

of Economic Literature, 35(2), 688-726.

Levine, R. (1998). The Legal Environment, Banks, and Long-Run Economic Growth. Journal of

Money, Credit, and Banking, 30(3), 596-613.

Levine, R. (1999). Law, Finance, and Economic Growth. Journal of Financial Intermediation,

8(1-2), 8-35.

Levine, R. (2006). Finance and Growth: Theory, Evidence, and Mechanism. In P. Aghion, & S.

Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 1A (pp. 865-934). Amsterdam:

North Holland.

Levine, R., & Renelt, D. (1992). A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions.

American Economic Review, 82(4), 942-63.

Levine, R., & Schmukler, S. (2006). Internationalization and Stock Market Liquidity. Review of

Finance, 10(1), 1-35.

Levine, R., & Zervos, S. (1998). Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth. American

Economic Review, 88(3), 537-558.

Levine, R., Loayza, N., & Beck, T. (2000). Financial Intermediation and Growth: Causality and

Causes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(1), 31-77.

Madhavan, A. (1995). Consolidation, fragmentation, and the disclosure of trading information.

Review of Financial Studies, 8(3), 579-603.

Naes, R., Skjeltorp, J., & Odegaard, B. (2008, April). Liquidity at the Oslo Stock Exchange.

Retrieved July 25, 2011, from Social Science Research Network:

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1158410

Naes, R., Skjeltorp, J., & Odegaard, B. (2011). Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle.

Journal of Finance, 66(1), 139-176.

Odegaard, B. (2008, September). The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock

Exchange. What does the data tell us? Retrieved July 25, 2011, from UiS Working

Papers in Economics and Finance:

http://www1.uis.no/ansatt/odegaard/uis_wps_econ_fin/uis_wps_2009_17_odegaard.pdf

O'Hara, M. (1995). Market Microstructure Theory. Oxford: Basil Blackwell Inc.

Page 69: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

56

Plerou, V. G. (2005). Quantifying Fluctuations in Market Liquidity: Analysis of the Bid-Ask

Spread. Physical Review E, 71, 046131.

Pollin, R., Baker, D., & Schaberg, M. (2003). Securities Transaction Taxes for U.S. Financial

Markets. Eastern Economic Journal, 29(4), 527-558.

Roll, R. (1984). A Simple Measure of the Bid-Ask Spread in an Efficient Market. Journal of

Finance, 39(4), 1127-1140.

Roll, R. (1989). Price Volatility, International Market Links, and Their Implications for

Regulatory Policy. Journal of Financial Services Research, 3(2-3), 211-246.

Rousseau, P., & Wachtel, P. (2000). Equity Markets and Growth: Cross-Country Evidence on

Timing and Outcomes. Journal of Business and Finance, 24(12), 1933-1957.

Sala-I-Martin, X. (1997). I Just Ran Two Million Regressions. American Economic Review,

87(2), 178-183.

Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1985). The Disposition to Sell Winners Too Early and Ride Losers

Too Long: Theory and Evidence. The Journal of Finance, 40(3), 777-790.

Slemrod, J. (1982). The Effect of Capital Gains Taxation on Year-End Stock Market Behavior.

National Tax Journal, 35(1), 69-77.

Stiglitz, J. (1985). Credit Markets and Control of Capital. Jounral of Money, Credit, and

Banking, 17(2), 133-152.

Summers, L., & Summers, V. (1989). When Financial Markets Work Too Well: A Cautious

Case for a Securities Transaction Tax. Journal of Financial Services Research, 3(2-3),

261-286.

Tharavanij, P. (2007, September 9). Capital Market and Business Cycle Volatility. Retrieved

July 24, 2011, from Munich Personal RePEc Archive: http://mpra.ub.uni-

muenchen.de/5188/1/MPRA_paper_5188.pdf

Tobin, J. (1978). A Proposal for International Monetary Reform. Eastern Economic Journal,

4(3-4), 153-159.

Umlauf, S. (1993). Transaction Taxes and the Behavior of the Swedish Stock Market. Journal of

Financial Economics, 33(2), 227-240.

Zhu, A., Ash, M., & Pollin, R. (2004). Stock Market Liquidity and Economic Growth: A Critical

Appraisal of the Levine/Zervos Model. International Review of Applied Economics,

18(1), 63-71.

Page 70: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

57

APPENDIX A - TABLES

TABLE 1 – COUNTRY AND EXCHANGE TRANSACTION COST ESTIMATES

Country Exchange Avg

Cost

Min

Cost

Max

Cost Trend

OECD

Australia Australia 12.9% 6.5% 32.1% -0.41%

Austria Vienna 4.9% 1.7% 9.2% 0.28%

Belgium Euronext Brussels 4.7% 3.0% 8.0% 0.05%

Canada Toronto 9.2% 2.8% 22.0% -0.60%

Canada TSX 30.5% 13.0% 54.8% -0.40%

Chile Santiago 5.3% 3.0% 8.1% -0.19%

Czech Republic Prague 5.2% 1.6% 10.8% -0.13%

Denmark Copenhagen 4.7% 2.2% 6.4% -0.06%

Estonia Tallinn 6.0% 1.2% 16.6% -0.22%

Finland Helsinki 5.5% 2.3% 10.8% -0.32%

France Euronext Paris 5.8% 3.7% 8.1% 0.12%

Germany Frankfurt 5.2% 2.0% 15.0% 0.44%

Greece Athens 2.8% 0.5% 10.8% -0.21%

Hungary Budapest 7.3% 4.1% 12.7% -0.35%

Iceland Iceland 6.4% 1.2% 23.4% 1.02%

Ireland Dublin 11.9% 5.4% 20.6% 0.02%

Israel Tel Aviv 7.0% 3.3% 11.1% 0.11%

Italy Milan 0.8% 0.4% 1.0% -0.02%

Japan OTC 7.5% 2.4% 14.7% -0.32%

Japan Tokyo 2.0% 0.7% 3.8% -0.08%

Korea Korea 1.8% 1.0% 3.9% 0.01%

Korea KOSDAQ 2.8% 1.0% 9.6% -0.27%

Luxembourg Luxembourg 4.2% 2.6% 5.0% 0.09%

Mexico Mexico 5.8% 2.6% 8.4% -0.13%

Netherlands Euronext Amsterdam 3.8% 1.8% 9.5% 0.07%

New Zealand New Zealand 8.0% 5.8% 11.2% 0.47%

Norway Oslo 6.6% 2.4% 11.7% -0.22%

Poland Warsaw 4.7% 1.1% 20.1% 0.16%

Poland Warsaw Cont' 2.7% 1.0% 5.6% 0.06%

Page 71: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

58

TABLE 1 – COUNTRY AND EXCHANGE TRANSACTION COST

ESTIMATES

Country Exchange

Avg

Cost

Min

Cost

Max

Cost Trend

OECD Continued

Portugal Euronext Lisbon 5.6% 3.5% 8.6% -0.12%

Slovakia Bratislavia 9.3% 2.9% 17.7% 0.10%

Slovenia Ljubljana 2.6% 1.4% 3.6% 0.06%

Spain Barcelona 15.6% 0.5% 46.7% 0.80%

Spain Madrid 7.3% 0.3% 16.6% -0.59%

Spain Madrid SIBE 1.7% 0.7% 2.6% -0.05%

Sweden Stockholm 6.9% 2.4% 16.0% -0.10%

Switzerland SIX Swiss 3.8% 1.6% 7.9% -0.25%

Turkey Istanbul 2.9% 1.5% 7.2% -0.17%

United Kingdom London 8.1% 6.1% 10.7% 0.10%

United States Amex 6.2% 2.3% 9.9% -0.07%

United States NASDAQ 3.2% 1.3% 6.5% -0.21%

United States NASDAQ_NMS 7.7% 0.3% 15.3% -0.61%

United States New York 1.9% 0.3% 6.6% -0.30%

United States Non-NASDAQ OTC 36.5% 8.9% 92.2% 3.34%

United States OTC Bulletin 23.2% 9.7% 46.3% 1.24%

Europe

Bulgaria Sofia 17.5% 15.6% 21.1% 0.84%

Croatia Zagreb 15.6% 4.0% 47.2% -2.06%

Cyprus Cyprus 13.2% 9.5% 22.3% 1.11%

Latvia Riga 9.3% 2.0% 22.6% -1.80%

Lithuania Lithuania 11.3% 4.3% 15.4% -1.25%

Malta Malta 4.1% 1.7% 5.8% 0.09%

Serbia Belgrade 10.0% 10.0% 10.0% NA

Asia

Bangladesh Dhaka 4.1% 3.7% 4.6% -0.05%

China Shanghai 0.5% 0.3% 1.4% 0.04%

China Shenzhen 0.6% 0.2% 1.5% 0.09%

Hong Kong Hong Kong 5.9% 2.2% 10.0% 0.26%

India Bombay 7.9% 0.4% 18.3% -0.74%

Indonesia Indonesia 15.3% 8.4% 36.5% -0.13%

Kazakhstan Kazakhstan 4.3% 4.3% 4.3% NA

Malaysia 2nd Board 10.8% 1.5% 57.2% 2.02%

Malaysia Kuala Lumpur 3.9% 1.8% 11.1% 0.29%

Malaysia Mesdaq 16.5% 4.3% 37.5% 6.91%

Philippines Philippines 14.2% 9.4% 19.2% -0.09%

Page 72: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

59

TABLE 1 – COUNTRY AND EXCHANGE TRANSACTION COST

ESTIMATES

Country Exchange

Avg

Cost

Min

Cost

Max

Cost Trend

Asia Continued

Russia ICE 8.1% 1.0% 22.0% -0.38%

Russia Moscow 40.0% 8.0% 148.0% -3.54%

Russia RTS 28.8% 0.2% 63.2% -0.69%

Singapore Catalist 21.6% 3.0% 42.2% 3.33%

Singapore Singapore 9.3% 1.9% 16.8% 1.07%

Sri Lanka Colombo 13.1% 8.4% 21.1% -0.18%

Taiwan OTC 1.3% 0.9% 1.9% 0.03%

Taiwan Taiwan 1.0% 0.7% 1.3% -0.01%

Thailand Bangkok 5.9% 2.1% 20.2% 0.09%

Vietnam Hanoi OTC 1.4% 1.1% 2.0% -0.32%

Vietnam Hanoi STC 1.5% 1.2% 2.0% -0.33%

Vietnam Ho Chi Minh 0.9% 0.6% 1.2% -0.08%

South America

Argentina Buenos Aries 5.6% 3.6% 10.1% -0.23%

Brazil Sao Paulo 10.9% 5.4% 20.7% -0.96%

Colombia Bogota 5.7% 3.5% 9.5% -0.17%

Peru Lima 10.9% 6.9% 19.9% -0.47%

Venezuela Caracas 11.0% 4.3% 25.5% 0.55%

Middle East & Africa

Bahrain Bahrain 6.9% 4.3% 11.5% 0.76%

Egypt Cairo 3.5% 2.3% 6.2% -0.17%

Jordan Amman 2.9% 2.7% 3.4% 0.18%

Kenya Nairobi 9.0% 2.8% 19.1% -0.72%

Kuwait Kuwait City 4.4% 3.2% 6.7% 0.58%

Lebanon Beirut 9.1% 2.0% 26.0% -0.60%

Morocco Casablanca 4.7% 2.4% 6.8% -0.14%

Oman Muscat 6.1% 5.2% 7.1% 0.06%

Pakistan Karachi 9.3% 3.7% 17.3% -0.32%

Qatar Doha 2.1% 1.3% 2.9% 0.03%

Saudi Arabia Riyadh 1.6% 0.8% 3.7% -0.16%

South Africa Johannesburg 11.7% 6.7% 18.6% -0.10%

United Arab Emirates Abu Dhabi 5.0% 3.8% 7.8% 0.57%

United Arab Emirates Dubai 3.5% 2.0% 6.8% -0.39%

Zimbabwe Zimbabwe 16.1% 5.5% 29.3% 1.05%

Page 73: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

60

TABLE 2 – CORRELATIONS WITH TRANSACTION COST ESTIMATES

Country Exchange Capitalization Turnover Value

Traded

Argentina Buenos Aires 0.44 0.12 -0.01

Australia Australia -0.62 -0.52 -0.53

Austria Vienna 0.65 -0.56 -0.17

Bangladesh Dhaka -0.07 0.59 0.48

Belgium Euronext Brussels -0.30 0.16 -0.21

Brazil Sao Paulo -0.86 0.66 0.18

Canada Toronto -0.54 -0.80 -0.61

Canada TSX -0.15 -0.48 -0.24

Chile Santiago -0.47 -0.26 -0.40

China Shanghai -0.12 0.28 0.12

China Shenzhen 0.39 -0.33 0.08

Colombia Bogota 0.50 0.48 0.52

Croatia Zagreb -0.26 -0.62 -0.57

Czech Republic Prague 0.16 0.11 -0.05

Denmark Copenhagen -0.10 -0.26 -0.20

Estonia Tallinn 0.30 0.33 -0.14

Finland Helsinki -0.44 -0.88 -0.69

France Euronext Paris 0.40 0.38 0.49

Germany Frankfurt 0.44 0.27 0.59

Greece Athens -0.54 -0.42 -0.44

Hungary Budapest -0.37 -0.38 -0.33

Iceland Iceland -0.91 -0.20 -0.59

India Bombay -0.38 0.01 -0.14

Indonesia Indonesia 0.07 -0.01 0.00

Ireland Dublin 0.17 0.28 0.15

Israel Tel Aviv 0.39 -0.02 0.34

Italy Milan -0.83 0.32 -0.99

Japan OTC -0.07 -0.52 -0.55

Japan Tokyo -0.17 -0.54 -0.59

Kenya Nairobi -0.31 -0.92 -0.84

Latvia Riga -0.84 0.61 0.65

Lebanon Beirut -0.47 -0.25 -0.35

Lithuania Lithuania -0.87 0.70 0.19

Luxembourg Luxembourg -0.28 -0.41 -0.36

Malaysia 2nd Board -0.61 -0.60 -0.63

Malaysia Kuala Lumpur -0.40 -0.44 -0.48

Page 74: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

61

TABLE 2 CONTINUED – CORRELATIONS WITH TRANSACTION COST

ESTIMATES

Country Exchange Capitalization Turnover Value

Traded

Malta Malta -0.25 -0.71 -0.73

Mexico Mexico -0.14 -0.25 -0.25

Morocco Casablanca -0.64 -0.35 -0.42

Netherlands Euronext Amsterdam -0.17 0.21 0.04

New Zealand New Zealand -0.58 0.27 -0.31

Norway Oslo -0.58 -0.44 -0.54

Pakistan Karachi -0.67 -0.09 -0.44

Peru Lima -0.69 0.68 0.39

Philippines Philippines -0.27 -0.39 -0.45

Poland Warsaw 0.33 -0.53 -0.38

Poland Warsaw Continuous -0.39 -0.06 -0.72

Portugal Euronext Lisbon -0.25 0.03 -0.02

Singapore Catalist -0.64 -0.35 -0.71

Singapore Singapore -0.74 -0.35 -0.79

Slovenia Ljubljana 0.46 -0.65 -0.19

South Africa Johannesburg -0.56 0.37 0.16

Spain Barcelona -0.81 -0.29 -0.86

Spain Madrid -0.40 -0.37 -0.31

Spain Madrid SIBE -0.50 -0.31 -0.39

Sri Lanka Colombo -0.55 0.29 -0.08

Sweden Stockholm -0.35 -0.37 -0.30

Switzerland SIX Swiss -0.77 -0.58 -0.78

Thailand Bangkok -0.48 -0.28 -0.55

Turkey Istanbul -0.51 -0.63 -0.56

United Kingdom London 0.03 0.45 0.45

United States Amex 0.34 0.53 0.50

United States NASDAQ -0.68 -0.50 -0.51

United States NASDAQ NMS -0.34 -0.34 -0.30

United States New York -0.85 -0.73 -0.73

United States Non-NASDAQ OTC 0.63 0.78 0.71

United States OTC Bulletin 0.70 0.78 0.74

Page 75: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

62

TABLE 3 – CROSS COUNTRY REGRESSIONS OF STOCK MARKET

DEVELOPMENT

Capitalization Value Traded Turnover Ratio

Transaction Cost -0.108 -0.598** -0.458*

(0.354) (0.000) (0.022)

Shareholder Rights 0.192* -0.025 -0.195

(0.038) (0.864) (0.174)

Accounting Standards 0.024** 0.055** 0.029*

(0.004) (0.001) (0.044)

Legal Origin UK 0.285 0.571 0.270

(0.412) (0.110) (0.347)

Legal Origin French 0.392 0.108 -0.259

(0.235) (0.803) (0.477)

Legal Origin German 0.670 0.446 -0.162

(0.180) (0.418) (0.609)

Property Rights 0.002 -0.001 -0.004

(0.827) (0.872) (0.749)

Politics -0.141 -0.276 -0.149

(0.812) (0.817) (0.858)

Trade 0.007** 0.001 -0.006

(0.008) (0.771) (0.102)

Climate -0.606+ -0.768 -0.261

(0.099) (0.163) (0.585)

Constant -3.542** -6.206** -2.482+

(0.000) (0.000) (0.050)

Observations 31 31 31

Adjusted R-squared 0.620 0.681 0.372

F-stat 8.492 9.429 5.075

Robust p-values in parentheses

**p<0.01, *p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 76: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

63

TABLE 4 – FIXED EFFECTS REGRESSIONS OF STOCK MARKET DEVELOPMENT

Capitalization Value Traded Turnover Ratio

Transaction Cost -0.200** -0.355** -0.158+

(0.003) (0.004) (0.079)

Property Rights 0.006 0.007 0.001

(0.109) (0.501) (0.911)

Trade 0.010** 0.011** 0.000

(0.001) (0.006) (0.925)

Constant -2.383** -3.835** -1.367

(0.000) (0.000) (0.119)

Observations 408 408 410

R-squared 0.158 0.093 0.014

Number of countries 38 38 39

F-stat 7.831 6.491 1.190

Robust p-values in parentheses

**p<0.01, *p<0.05, +p<0.1

Page 77: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

64

TABLE 5 – COUNTRIES IN THE CROSS-SECTION REGRESSIONS

Australia Germany Israel Pakistan Thailand

Austria Finland Japan Peru Taiwan

Belgium France Mexico Philippines United Kingdom

Brazil Greece Malaysia South Africa United States

Canada India Netherlands South Korea Zimbabwe

Chile Indonesia Norway Sweden

TABLE 6 – SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR CROSS-SECTION COUNTRIES

Summary Statistics: Cross-Section Data 1990-1998

Economic Growth Transaction Costs Turnover Ratio

Accounting

Standards

Descriptive Statistics

Mean 0.021 0.079 0.572 68.781

Maximum 0.058 0.260 2.951 83

Minimum -0.010 0.010 0.075 24

Standard Deviation 0.017 0.057 0.531 12.886

Observations 29 29 29 25

Page 78: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

65

TABLE 7 – INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES CROSS-SECTION REGRESSIONS

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

Instrumental Variable: Transaction Costs

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Turnover Ratio 0.121 0.112 0.064 0.049

(0.929) (0.957) (0.970) (0.891)

Private Credit -0.038 -0.034 -0.018 -0.012

(0.915) (0.960) (0.963) (0.951)

Average Years of Schooling 0.052 0.049 0.027 0.022

(0.966) (0.970) (0.961) (0.908)

Initial Level of Real GDP per Capita -0.023 -0.021 -0.014 -0.013

(0.949) (0.969) (0.920) (0.822)

Government Consumption

-0.005

(0.989)

International Trade

0.014

(0.937)

Inflation

-0.030

(0.951)

Black Market Premium

Constant 0.186 0.185 0.073 0.124

(0.923) (0.960) (0.970) (0.874)

Observations 29 29 29 29

R-squared -19.594 -16.548 -4.158 -2.107

C-stat 5.140 3.711 3.108 5.135

(0.023) (0.054) (0.078) (0.023)

LM 0.173 0.102 0.567 1.805

0.677 (0.750) (0.452) (0.179)

F-stat . . . .

(0.975) (0.972) (0.843) (0.582)

F-stat First Stage 1.65 1.44 1.33 1.69

(0.194) (0.248) (0.286) (0.178)

Bootstrapped p values in parentheses

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 79: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

66

TABLE 8 – COUNTRIES IN 4 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL DATA

Argentina Denmark Ireland Latvia Portugal

Australia Egypt Iceland Morocco Russian Federation

Austria Spain Israel Mexico Saudi Arabia

Belgium Estonia Italy Malta Singapore

Bulgaria Finland Jordan Malaysia Slovak Republic

Bahrain France Japan Netherlands Slovenia

Brazil United Kingdom Kenya Norway Sweden

Canada Greece Korea New Zealand Thailand

Switzerland Hong Kong Kuwait Oman Turkey

China Croatia Lebanon Pakistan United States

Colombia Hungary Sri Lanka Peru Venezuela

Cyprus Indonesia Lithuania Philippines South Africa

Czech Republic India Luxembourg Poland Zimbabwe

Germany

TABLE 9 – SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR 4 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL

DATA

Summary Statistics: Panel Data, 1990-2009

Economic

Growth

Transaction

Costs

Turnover

Ratio

Descriptive

Statistics

Mean 2.5 6.9 68.3

Maximum 10.8 34.4 354.8

Minimum -6.0 0.3 0.3

Std. Dev. 2.2 4.7 57.0

Observations 187 187 182

Page 80: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

67

TABLE 10 – INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES FIXED-EFFECTS REGRESSIONS

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

Instrumental Variable: Transaction Costs

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Turnover Ratio 8.377 17.754 8.212 6.083

(0.278) (0.521) (0.249) (0.167)

Private Credit -4.742 -5.839 -4.764 -3.989+

(0.119) (0.340) (0.115) (0.058)

Initial Level of Real GDP per Capita 3.357 11.876 3.748 3.444

(0.626) (0.527) (0.613) (0.517)

Average Years of Schooling -20.130 -40.718 -19.893 -17.657

(0.372) (0.515) (0.358) (0.252)

Government Consumption

34.818

(0.476)

International Trade

-0.006

(0.843)

Inflation

-21.562

(0.419)

Observations 142 139 142 142

R-squared -8.327 -36.176 -7.989 -4.228

Number of countries 48 47 48 48

C-stat 5.981 7.093 6.638 6.663

(0.014) (0.008) (0.010) (0.010)

LM 1.241 0.400 1.406 1.987

(0.265) (0.529) (0.236) (0.159)

F-stat 0.853 0.281 0.713 1.132

(0.500) (0.923) (0.71) (0.349)

F-stat First Stage 1.70 1.99 1.40 1.53

(0.156) (0.088) (0.231) (0.190)

Robust p values in parentheses

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 81: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

68

TABLE 11 – CROSS-COUNTRY REGRESSIONS

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Transaction Costs -0.108 -0.083 -0.071 -0.160

(0.405) (0.559) (0.639) (0.451)

Accounting Standards -0.002* -0.002 -0.002* -0.002+

(0.022) (0.115) (0.032) (0.063)

Legal Origin – UK 0.008 0.013 0.005 0.010

(0.613) (0.540) (0.778) (0.574)

Legal Origin – France -0.003 -0.003 -0.010 -0.001

(0.808) (0.875) (0.521) (0.956)

Legal Origin – Scandinavian 0.025 0.030 0.019 0.028

(0.200) (0.182) (0.395) (0.235)

Private Credit 0.019+ 0.018 0.014 0.021

(0.099) (0.141) (0.258) (0.147)

Average Years of Schooling 0.010 0.003 0.003 0.025

(0.802) (0.952) (0.950) (0.637)

Initial Level of Real GDP per

Capita -0.009 -0.004 -0.006 -0.012

(0.403) (0.765) (0.607) (0.327)

Government Consumption

-0.020

(0.428)

International Trade

0.009

(0.337)

Inflation

0.026

(0.870)

Black Market Premium

Constant 0.211** 0.217** 0.168* 0.204*

(0.001) (0.001) (0.040) (0.024)

Number of Countries 25 25 25 25

Adjusted R-squared 0.321 0.370 0.349 0.298

Wald Chi-Sq 11.84 13.28 11.32 8.64

(0.158) (0.150) (0.254) (0.472)

Joint Significance P-value (0.196) (0.520) (0.229) (0.405)

Bootstrapped p values in parentheses

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 82: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

69

TABLE 12 – FIXED-EFFECTS REGRESSIONS, 4 5-YEAR PERIODS, 1990-2009

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Transaction Costs -0.172* -0.186** -0.183* -0.225**

(0.016) (0.004) (0.010) (0.004)

Private Credit -2.909** -2.837** -2.708** -3.170**

(0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.001)

Initial Level of Real GDP per Capita 3.300+ 4.114** 1.858 3.090

(0.085) (0.008) (0.368) (0.117)

Average Years of Schooling -7.700+ -8.556* -7.655 -6.877

(0.095) (0.031) (0.103) (0.144)

Government Consumption

2.722

(0.335)

International Trade

0.020*

(0.020)

Inflation

24.067+

(0.061)

Constant -0.712 -2.669 11.786 -109.724+

(0.956) (0.837) (0.413) (0.059)

Observations 160 155 160 160

R-squared 0.211 0.227 0.230 0.228

Number of Countries 61 58 61 61

F-stat 4.520 9.540 5.338 9.502

(0.003) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Robust p values in parentheses

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 83: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

70

TABLE 13 – COUNTRIES IN 3 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL DATA

Argentina Egypt Iceland Morocco Russian Federation

Australia Spain Israel Mexico Saudi Arabia

Austria Estonia Italy Malta Singapore

Belgium Finland Japan Malaysia Slovak Republic

Bulgaria France Kenya Netherlands Slovenia

Brazil United Kingdom Korea Norway Sweden

Canada Greece Kuwait New Zealand Thailand

Switzerland Hong Kong Lebanon Pakistan Turkey

China Croatia Sri Lanka Peru United States

Colombia Hungary Lithuania Philippines Venezuela

Czech Republic Indonesia Luxembourg Poland South Africa

Germany India Latvia Portugal Zimbabwe

Denmark Ireland

TABLE 14 – SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR 3 PERIODS, 5-YEAR AVERAGES PANEL

DATA

Summary Statistics: Panel Data, 1993-2007

Economic Growth Transaction Costs Turnover

Ratio

Descriptive Statistics

Mean 3.0 7.0 68.9

Maximum 11.0 27.3 329.3

Minimum -4.2 0.3 0.3

Std. Dev. 2.4 4.8 59.1

Observations 146 146 146

Page 84: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

71

TABLE 15 – FIXED-EFFECTS REGRESSIONS, 3 5-YEAR PERIODS, 1993-2007

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Transaction Costs -0.212+ -0.226* -0.228* -0.326**

(0.054) (0.037) (0.041) (0.001)

Private Credit -1.483 -1.526 -1.150 -2.517

(0.417) (0.398) (0.527) (0.138)

Initial Level of Real GDP per Capita 4.838+ 5.694* 3.174 4.234+

(0.080) (0.037) (0.281) (0.095)

Average Years of Schooling -3.891 -5.043 -4.065 -0.661

(0.610) (0.463) (0.600) (0.928)

Government Consumption

2.306

(0.631)

International Trade

0.025+

(0.097)

Inflation

101.195**

(0.001)

Constant -31.055* -32.930* -16.501 -492.895**

(0.034) (0.045) (0.252) (0.000)

Observations 127 125 127 127

R-squared 0.195 0.197 0.215 0.267

Number of Countries 58 57 58 58

F-stat 5.592 3.878 6.009 9.519

(0.001) (0.004) (0.000) (0.000)

Robust p values in parentheses

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 85: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

72

TABLE 16 – CROSS-COUNTRY REGRESSIONS WITH TURNOVER RATIO

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Turnover Ratio 0.009 0.008 0.010 0.009

(0.149) (0.117) (0.143) (0.166)

Private Credit 0.011+ 0.011* 0.009 0.012

(0.059) (0.032) (0.151) (0.154)

Average Years of Schooling 0.024 0.019 0.020 0.025

(0.255) (0.309) (0.359) (0.280)

Initial Level of GDP per Capita -0.012* -0.008 -0.011+ -0.012*

(0.032) (0.153) (0.064) (0.049)

Government Consumption

-0.021*

(0.026)

International Trade

0.005

(0.286)

Inflation

0.005

(0.919)

Black Market Premium

Constant 0.091** 0.120** 0.070* 0.091**

(0.000) (0.000) (0.016) (0.000)

Observations 29 29 29 29

Adjusted R-squared 0.315 0.460 0.308 0.287

Wald Chi Squared 16.19 28.29 19.50 13.78

(0.003) (0.000) (0.002) (0.017)

p-values in parentheses, standard errors derived from bootstrapping

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 86: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

73

TABLE 17 – FIXED-EFFECTS REGRESSIONS WITH TURNOVER RATIO

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Turnover Ratio 0.182 0.250 0.175 0.189

(0.496) (0.337) (0.514) (0.481)

Private Credit -3.001** -2.946** -2.909** -2.879**

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

Initial Level of Real GDP per Capita 2.728 3.466+ 2.093 2.851

(0.211) (0.080) (0.370) (0.196)

Average Years of Schooling -4.437 -5.072 -4.301 -5.343

(0.352) (0.254) (0.378) (0.318)

Government Consumption

2.507

(0.395)

International Trade

0.009

(0.363)

Inflation

-10.009

(0.394)

Constant -3.774 -6.102 1.450 42.540

(0.798) (0.679) (0.928) (0.429)

Observations 155 150 155 155

R-squared 0.138 0.151 0.143 0.143

Number of countries 61 58 61 61

F-stat 3.870 5.316 3.256 4.778

Robust p values in parentheses

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 87: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

74

TABLE 18 – SYSTEM DIFFERENCE ESTIMATOR REGRESSIONS

Dependent Variable: Growth of Real GDP per Capita

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Transaction Costs -0.205 -0.243 -0.066 -0.105

(0.191) (0.101) (0.696) (0.218)

Private Credit -1.011 -0.962+ -0.565 -0.380

(0.296) (0.077) (0.314) (0.615)

Initial Level of Real GDP per Capita 0.192 0.372 0.357 0.120

(0.702) (0.218) (0.425) (0.769)

Average Years of Schooling 1.588 -0.296 0.183 1.380

(0.328) (0.931) (0.901) (0.288)

Government Consumption

0.456

(0.845)

International Trade

0.002

(0.750)

Inflation

-305.685

(0.151)

Constant 3.075 6.141 1.281 1,408.857

(0.397) (0.532) (0.730) (0.152)

Observations 160 155 160 160

Number of countries 61 58 61 61

F-stat 0.797 1.810 0.447 0.975

(0.532) (0.125) (0.813) (0.441)

Overidentification Test (p-value) (0.051) (0.101) (0.001) (0.991)

Serial Correlation Test (p-value) (0.204) (0.177) (0.225) (0.275)

p values in parentheses

** p<0.01, * p<0.05, + p<0.1

Page 88: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

75

APPENDIX B - FIGURES

GRAPHS OF TRANSACTION COST ESTIMATES AND PERIOD AVERAGES FOR

SELECT COUNTRIES AND EXCHANGES

FIGURE 1 FIGURE 2

FIGURE 3 FIGURE 4

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Argentina

Buenos Aires

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Canada

Toronto

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Canada

TSX

0.0%

0.2%

0.4%

0.6%

0.8%

1.0%

1.2%

1.4%

1.6%

19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

China

Shanghai

Page 89: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

76

FIGURE 5 FIGURE 6

FIGURE 7 FIGURE 8

0.0%

0.2%

0.4%

0.6%

0.8%

1.0%

1.2%

1.4%

1.6%19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

Pe

rce

nt

Year

China

Shenzhen

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

50%

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Croatia

Zagreb

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

19

94

19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Czech Republic

Prague

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Denmark

Copenhagen

Page 90: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

77

FIGURE 9 FIGURE 10

FIGURE 11 FIGURE 12

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

16%

18%19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Estonia

Tallinn

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Hong Kong

Hong Kong

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

19

94

19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Hungary

Budapest

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Iceland

Iceland

Page 91: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

78

FIGURE 13 FIGURE 14

FIGURE 15 FIGURE 16

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Indonesia

Indonesia

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

3.5%

4.0%

4.5%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Japan

Tokyo

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Malaysia

Kuala Lumpur

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

Per

cen

t

Year

Malaysia

2nd Board

Page 92: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

79

FIGURE 17 FIGURE 18

FIGURE 19 FIGURE 20

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Malaysia

MESDAQ

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

9%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Mexico

Mexico

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Norway

Oslo

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

19

91

19

94

19

97

20

00

20

03

20

06

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Philippines

Philippines

Page 93: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

80

FIGURE 21 FIGURE 22

FIGURE 23 FIGURE 24

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%19

94

19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Poland

Warsaw

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Poland

Continuous

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

120%

140%

160%

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

Per

cen

t

Year

Russia

Moscow

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Russia

Interbank Currency Exchange

Page 94: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

81

FIGURE 25 FIGURE 26

FIGURE 27 FIGURE 28

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Russia

Russian Trading System

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

3.5%

4.0%

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Slovenia

Ljubljana

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

3.5%

4.0%

4.5%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

South Korea

Korean

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

South Korea

KOSDAQ

Page 95: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

82

FIGURE 29 FIGURE 30

FIGURE 31 FIGURE 32

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

Per

cen

t

Year

Sri Lanka

Colombo

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

16%

18%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Sweden

Stockholm

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

Thailand

Bangkok

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

19

90

19

93

19

96

19

99

20

02

20

05

20

08

Per

cen

t

Year

United States

NYSE

Page 96: STOCK MARKET TRANSACTION COSTS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH …

83

FIGURE 33

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

Per

cen

t

Year

Venezuela

Caracas