subadditivity of cost functions lecture xx. concepts of subadditivity evans, d. s. and j. j....

30
Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX

Upload: horace-wiggins

Post on 29-Dec-2015

227 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Subadditivity of Cost Functions

Lecture XX

Page 2: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Concepts of Subadditivity

Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with an Application to the Bell System.” American Economic Review 74(1984): 615-23. The issue addressed in this article involves the emergence of natural monopolies. Specifically, is it possible that a single firm is the most cost-efficient way to generate the product.

Page 3: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

In the specific application, the researchers are interested in the Bell System (the phone company before it was split up).

Page 4: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

The cost function C(q) is subadditive at some output level if and only if:

which states that the cost function is subadditive if a single firm could produce the same output for less cost.

As a mathematical nicety, the point must have at least two nonzero firms. Otherwise the cost function is by definition the same.

1

1

ni

i

ni

i

C q C q

q q

Page 5: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Developing a formal test, Evans and Heckman assume a cost function based on two input:

Thus, each of i firms produce ai percent of output q1 and bi percent of the output q2.

1 2 1 2, , 1,

1 1 0 0

i ii

i i i ii i

C a q b q C q q i n

a b a b

Page 6: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

A primary focus of the article is the region over which subadditivity is tested. The cost function is subadditive, and

the technology implies a natural monopoly.

The cost function is superadditive, and the firm could save money by breaking itself up into two or more divisions.

1 2 1 2, ,i iiC a q b q C q q

1 2 1 2, ,i iiC a q b q C q q

Page 7: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

The cost function is additive

The notion of additivity combines two concepts from the cost function: Economies of Scope and Economies of Scale.

1 2 1 2, ,i iiC a q b q C q q

Page 8: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Under Economies of Scope, it is cheaper to produce two goods together. The example I typically give for this is the grazing cattle on winter wheat.

However, we also recognize following the concepts of Coase, Williamson, and Grossman and Hart that there may diseconomies of scope.

The second concept is the economies of scale argument that we have discussed before.

Page 9: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

As stated previously, a primary focus of this article is the region of subadditivity. In our discussion of cost functions, I

have mentioned the concepts of Global versus local. To make the discussion more concrete, let us return to our discussion of concavity.

Page 10: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

From the properties of the cost function, we know that the cost function is concave in input price space. Thus, using the Translog form:

The gradient vector for the Translog cost function is then:

0

, exp ln

1 1ln ln ln ln ln ln ln ln ln2 2

C w y C

C w w A w y y B y w y

Page 11: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

1 1 1 1

, exp ln exp lnw

n n n n

s A w y

C w y C C

s A w y

1 1 1 1 1 1 11 12

1

, exp ln exp ln

, ,

n

ww

i i i i i i n nn

A w y A w y A A

C w y C C

A w y A w y A A

C A w y w y

Page 12: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Given that the cost is always positive, the positive versus negative nature of the matrix is determined by:

Comparing this results with the result for the quadratic function, we see that

, ,A w y w y

2 ,wwC w y A

Page 13: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Thus, the Hessian of the Translog varies over input prices and output levels while the Hessian matrix for the Quadratic does not.

In this sense, the restrictions on concavity for the Quadratic cost function are global–they do not change with respect to output and input prices. However, the concavity restrictions on the Translog are local–fixed at a specific point, because they depend on prices and output levels.

Page 14: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Note that this is important for the Translog. Specifically, if we want the cost function to be concave in input prices:

, , 0

, , 0

, , 0

But , , 0

x A w y w y x x

x Ax x w y w y x

x Ax w y x w y x

w y x w y x

Page 15: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Thus, any discussion of subadditivity, especially if a Translog cost function is used (or any cost function other than a quadratic), needs to consider the region over which the cost function is to be tested.

Page 16: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Admissible Region

q2

q1

C

Page 17: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Thus, much of the discussion in Evans and Heckman involve the choice of the region for the test. Specifically, the test region is restricted to a region of observed point.

Page 18: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Defining q*1M as the minimum amount

of q1 produced by any firm and q*2M as

the minimum amount of q2 produced, we an define alternative production bundles as:

* *1 1 2 2

* *1 1 2 2

,

1 , 1

0 1,0 1

At t M t m

Bt t M t M

q q q q q

q q q q q

Page 19: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Thus, the production for any firm can be divided into two components within the observed range of output. Thus, subadditivity can be defined as:

ˆ,

ˆ,

, ,,

A A At t M t

B B Bt t M t

A Bt t t t

A Bt t t

t

t

C C q C q q

C C q C q q

C C q q C q

C C CSub

C

Page 20: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

If Subt() is less than zero, the cost function is subadditive, if it is equal to zero the cost function is additive, and if it is greater than zero, the cost function is superadditive.

Consistent with their concept of the region of the test, Evans and Heckman calculate the maximum and minimum Subt() for the region.

Page 21: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Composite Cost Functions and Subadditivity

Pulley, L. B. and Y. M. Braunstein. “A Composite Cost Function for Multiproduct Firms with an Application to Economies of Scope in Banking.” Review of Economics and Statistics 74(1992): 221-30.

Page 22: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Building on the concept of subadditivity and the global nature of the flexible function form, it is apparent that the estimation of subadditivity is dependent on functional form

Page 23: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Pulley and Braunstein allow for a more general form of the cost function by allowing the Box-Cox transformation to be different for the inputs and outputs.

1: 0

ln : 0

yy

y

Page 24: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

0

0

1exp 2

1exp 2

,ln

q q Aq q rC

r r Br q r

f q r

Page 25: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

If =0, =0 and =1 the form yields a standard Translog with normal share equations.

If =0 and =1 the form yields a generalized Translog:

01 1ln ln ln ln ln2 2

ln

C q q Aq q r r r B r

s q B r

Page 26: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

If =1,=0 and ,=0, the specification becomes a separable quadratic specification

0

0

12

1exp ln ln ln2

ln

q q AqC

r r B r

s B r

Page 27: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

The demand equations for the composite function is:

1

01 ln ln2s q q Aq q r q B r q

Page 28: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Given the estimates, we can then measure Economies of Scope in two ways. The first measures is a traditional measure:

1 2

1 2

1 2

,0, 0, 0, ,0, 0,

0, 0, , , , ,

, , ,n n

n

C q r C q r

C q r C q q q rSCOPE

C q q q r

Page 29: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

Another measure suggested by the article is “quasi” economies of scope

1 2 1 2 3

1 2

1 2

1 1 , , , , 1 1 , , ,

, , ,

, , ,

n n

n

n

C m q q q r C q m q q q r

C q q q rQSCOPE

C q q q r

Page 30: Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with

The Economies of Scale are then defined as:

,

,i

i i

C q rSCALE

C q rq

q