tesis oxford anm

Upload: rafa-war

Post on 14-Apr-2018

233 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    1/53

    1

    Candidate Number: 54215

    Aurelio Nuo

    Trinity, 2008-05-19

    St Antonys College

    Building a National State without Taxation: thePolitical Consequences of the Fiscal Evolution in

    Mexico after the Armed Revolution, 1920-1930.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    2/53

    2

    Table of Contents

    Introduction 3

    I. Lack of International Wars and Forging a New Internal Coalition.. 6

    II. The Porfirian Fiscal Structure.. 13

    III. The Obregn Presidency: Limits and Possibilities of Fiscal Extraction 17

    IV. The Calles Presidency: Political Coalitions and Low Taxation.36

    Conclusion.47

    Bibliography. 50

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    3/53

    3

    Introduction

    After the armed period of the Mexican Revolution (1910-20), there emerged in

    the 1920s and 30s, a regime that proved more durable than Don Porfirios and

    an economy that, over time, eclipsed both its Porfirian predecessor and its Latin

    American rivals.1 In that sense, as Alan Knight argues, the Mexican Revolution

    displayed a distinctly Tocquevillean character: from the rubble of revolution

    was built a state both stronger and more stable than its old regime

    counterpart.2 Nevertheless, this stronger and more stable state did not create a

    solid fiscal system. The revolutionary governments of the 1920s collected, as

    percentage of GDP, almost the same revenue as the late Porfirian regime did.

    Moreover, in comparative perspective, Mexicos low levels of taxation were

    maintained during the entire twentieth century.

    Why did a stronger and more stable state not create an extensive fiscal

    system? Furthermore, how was it possible to create a stronger state without a

    solid fiscal system? What was the nature of the fiscal system forged after the

    armed Revolution? What were the political consequences of this new fiscal

    arrangement?

    My first hypothesis is that the combination of the nature of the internal

    challenges of state reconstruction with the lack of a serious threat of any

    international war against powerful states3 demanded a not-very extensive fiscal

    1 Knight, Alan, The Peculiarities of Mexican History: Mexico Compared to Latin America, 1821 -1992,inJournal of Latin American Studies, Vol. 24, 1992, p. 104.2 Ibid, p. 104.

    3 Until the end of the 1920s the threat of an US invasion was present. Yet, my contention is that themilitary superiority of the US was so evident that ironically it was no longer a real military threat.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    4/53

    4

    structure. Furthermore, my second hypothesis, and the central argument of this

    paper, is that the internal conditions that shaped the process of state

    reconstruction in Mexico after the Revolution not only failed to create pressure

    for increased taxation but also created strong incentives to avoid taxation.

    The strength of the new regime came from the formation of a broad coalition

    between the government and different sectors of the Mexican society. My

    contention is that one of the elements that helped the government to forge this

    coalition was offering low tax rates and fiscal waivers in exchange for political

    support. This process of coalition formation shaped a fiscal system full of

    waivers, privileges, and tolerated evasion that also reinforced a pattern of

    clientelistic politics.

    The present work confines itself to the 1920s, a period where the Mexican state

    experienced a rapid and radical process of reconstruction that shaped the

    nature of the new regime. This essay is divided into four parts. In the first part I

    develop my hypotheses and central arguments. In the second part I describe

    the main features of the Porfirian fiscal system that was inherited by the

    revolutionary governments of the 1920s. In the third part, I analyse the

    possibilities of and the limitations on taxation faced by the government of lvaro

    Obregn (1920-24), including the oil boom, the lack of both international and

    Furthermore, in terms of territory, the US, during the Mexican-American war (1846-48), had alreadytaken what it wanted from Mexico, thus by the 1920s a potential US invasion, such as the occupation ofVeracruz in 1914, did not put at risk the future of the country. A hypothetical invasion would only be atemporary occupation of some ports and oil fields. Furthermore, after Mexico defeated France in 1867,the risk of a European invasion disappeared and the other Mexican neighbors, Belize, Guatemala andCuba, were not a military threat. In a nutshell, since 1867 Mexico no longer had a security dilemma. For

    the concept of security dilemma see, Herz, John, Political Realism and Political Idealism: A Study inTheories and Realities, (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1951).

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    5/53

    5

    national loans, the Obregns failed attempts to create direct taxes and finally

    the imposition of the income tax after the delahuertista uprising (1923-24).

    Finally, in the fourth part, I analyse how the offer of low taxation and fiscal

    waivers helped to consummate, during the Plutarco Elas Calles presidency

    (1924-28), the political coalitions that gave the new regime its strength and

    stability.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    6/53

    6

    I. Lack of International Wars and Forging a New Internal Coalition

    The revolutionary governments between 1920 and 1930 collected, on average,

    5.85% of Mexicos GDP. This was just a small increase compared to the late

    Porfiriato, which between 1900 and 1910 had on average collected 5.35%. By

    any international comparison this figure was very low. For instance, during the

    1920s the UK government collected 19% of GDP, the US 13%, Brazil 9%, and

    Argentina 6.5%. Furthermore, in comparative perspective, Mexicos low levels

    of taxation were corrected neither during the 1930s nor indeed during the entire

    twentieth century.4

    Figure 1: Central Governments Revenues as percentage of GDP

    Central Governments Revenues as a percentage of GDP

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35

    40

    45

    1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

    Year

    %o

    fGDP

    Mexico

    UK

    US

    Brazil

    Argentina

    Sources: For Mexico, Brazil and Argentina, Oxford Latin America Economic History Database:http://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk. For UK from 1910 to 1970, Aboites, Excepciones y privilegios,p. 397 (Cuadro A2), from1970 to 2000, OECD, Revenue Statistics. For US from 1910 to 1950, US Department of the Treasury, Fact sheets:

    Taxes. History of the US Tax System: www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtml, from 1950 to1970, Aboites,Excepciones y privilegios,p. 397 (Cuadro A2), and from 1970 to 2000, OECD, Revenue Statistics.

    4 Percentages for Mexico, Brazil and Argentina were calculated using the Oxford Latin AmericaEconomic History Database:http://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk. For UK percentages see Aboites,Excepciones y

    privilegios. Modernizacin Tributaria y Centralizacin en Mxico, 1922-1972, (Mxico: El Colegio deMxico, 2003),p. 397 (Cuadro A2). For US percentages see US Department of the Treasury, Factsheets: Taxes. History of the US Tax System:www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtml.

    http://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/http://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/http://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/http://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/http://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/http://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/http://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/
  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    7/53

    7

    Charles Tilly argues that state construction in Western Europe was the result of

    interaction between the clash of expansionist political groups, which led to wars,

    extraction of resources in preparation for such wars, and the internal constraintsof tax extraction that were determined by the configuration of class structure.5 In

    a nutshell, wars made states and states made wars.6 From this perspective, the

    origins and the evolution of the fiscal structures of the Western European states

    were a consequence of war. The relationship between war and taxes was very

    clear during the World Wars. For instance, in 1910 the UK only collected around

    7% of its GDP, yet after the First World War UK revenues reached 20% of the

    GDP. Before the Second World War UK revenues were somewhat less than

    20% of its GDP, but after the war revenues were higher than 35%.7 A similar

    process was experienced by the US. During the First World War, federal

    revenues increased 300% in terms of GDP, and during World War II revenues

    increased 150%.8

    Clearly the Mexican Revolution did not have the same effect on the fiscal

    structure. As Centeno argues, not all wars have a positive influence on

    taxation.9 The principal difference between the Mexican Revolution and the

    European wars, especially the World Wars, was that the former was fought

    among internal factions, none of which was constituted by political structures

    with the organizational abilities that characterize European nation-states, and

    5 See, Tilly, Charles, Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992, (Oxford: BlackwellPublishers, 8th edition, 1998), pp. 1-37.6 Ibid, pp. 67-95.7 See, Aboites,Excepciones y privilegios,p. 397 (Cuadro A2).8See, US Department of the Treasury, Fact sheets: Taxes. History of the US Tax System:www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtml.9

    See, Centeno, Miguel ngel,Blood and Debt. War and the Nation-State In Latin America,(Philadelphia: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 2002), p. 104.

    http://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtmlhttp://www.treasury.gov/education/fact-sheets/taxes/ustax.shtml
  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    8/53

    8

    they required less material resources than the wars fought by the latter. Winning

    the Mexican Revolution required fewer resources than winning World War I.

    During the period of state reconstruction in the 1920s the new regime was not a

    centralized state searching for revenue to fight another powerful state. On the

    contrary, it was a weak state that had inherited a poor fiscal system trying to

    establish its internal authority over uncontrolled generals and local political

    bosses. Therefore, on the one hand, the revenue needed by the state to defeat

    internal dissidents, who also had only limited access to revenues, was less than

    that needed to defeat a powerful foreign enemy. On the other hand, precisely

    the fact that the central government was not yet able to monopolize the means

    of violence limited its possibilities of extracting revenue. Geographical and

    economic conditions, such as the lack of infrastructure and capital, as well as

    the extension of the territory, mountainous areas, and few navigable rivers,

    complicated the possibilities of raising taxes even more. Therefore, the

    combination of the internal challenges of state reconstruction with the lack of a

    serious threat of any international war demanded a not-very extensive fiscal

    structure.

    The new regime was immersed in an environment crowded by uncontrolled

    generals and well-mobilized popular organizations, who, if not allies of the

    government could be co-opted by military rebels. Therefore, the government

    was very soon forced to forge political coalitions with some of the most powerful

    factions of different, even contradictory, social and economic groups, for the

    fear that it might be overthrown by military dissidents.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    9/53

    9

    Yet the central problem was that the new regime had inherited a very weak

    fiscal structure, and the material benefits that it could offer to its allies were also

    very restricted. Under these circumstances, one of the most valuable resources

    that the government was able to offer or, from another perspective, was forced

    to offer in exchange for political support was not to tax, or to tax its allies very

    little. Indeed, as I attempt to demonstrate in the following pages, one of the key

    components that allowed the new regime to build a broad coalition among

    peasants, workers, capitalists, and local political bosses, and therefore to

    construct a stronger and more stable state than its old regime counterpart, was

    the establishment of very low taxes or even the full exemption of tax payments

    to the regimes allies.

    Another element that helped the new regime to forge a coalition without

    spending heavily was the fact that both land reform and organized workers

    demands could be achieved without exorbitant expenditure. The new

    Constitution of 1917 (especially article 27), combined with the Sonorans10

    military victory, opened the door to the distribution of some of the land owned by

    Porfirian hacendados. The revolutionary government had seized or could

    potentially seize some of the land. Land reform cost money, especially because

    it demanded new bureaucratic organizations, but it was cheaper than other

    social benefits and rights such as health and education might be, especially

    after a revolution where land had been seized by force. Also, in the case of

    10 The clique of revolutionary Generals who overthrew President Carranza in 1920 under the Plan de

    Agua Prieta were commanded by three Generals from the state of Sonora in North West Mexico: lvaroObregn, Adolfo de la Huerta and Plutarco Elas Calles. The presidential periods of Obregn and Calles(1920-28) is therefore also known as the Sonoran regime.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    10/53

    10

    organized workers the Constitution (especially article 123) and military triumph

    gave the government the ability to force entrepreneurs to meet workers

    demands, thus transferring a significant proportion of the cost of social reform to

    capitalists. Military victory in itself brought a significant change in power

    relations.

    Low tax rates and tax waivers did not fully exempt the government from

    rewarding some of its allies with material benefits. For instance, bringing the

    army under governments control and buying generals loyalty with cash was

    expensive. The Confederacin Regional Obrera Mexicana (CROM), the

    principal workers organization allied with the government, also demanded

    patronage, and a number of big landlords, some of them revolutionary generals,

    benefited from irrigation systems paid for by the government. Therefore,

    because revenues were limited, the coalition was also limited. Furthermore,

    precisely because one of the glues of the governments coalition was low

    taxation, the government had very limited options when it came to raising more

    money in order to expand the governments benefits to more people and

    enlarge its coalition.

    It was for these reasons that there emerged a pattern of selective rather than

    universal enforcement of property, social, legal and political rights and other

    economic benefits delivered by the government, thus reinforcing a process of

    political and economic articulation through clientelism. Moreover, precisely

    because the government did not have enough revenues to sustain itself without

    its clientelistic alliances, dissenters among the excluded groups threatened the

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    11/53

    11

    governments survival, and a pattern of repression of d issenters took shape in

    the 1920s.

    From the perspective of the New Institutional Economics (NIE)11, Haber, Razo

    and Maurer12 explain that economic growth during both the armed Mexican

    Revolution and the unstable period of state reconstruction of the 1920s was

    possible because of the formation of coalitions such as those described in this

    essay. They argue that the government selectively enforced the property rights

    of asset holders who joined the governments coalition. Therefore, those asset

    holders were secure in the knowledge that their properties and investment

    would not be affected by the government. They were therefore able to invest,

    and some degree of economic growth was achieved.

    Haber, Razo and Maurer call these forms of coalitions Vertical Political

    Integration (VPI). Governments are interested in creating VPI coalitions

    because they get revenues in exchange for enforcing the property rights of the

    asset holders who are members of the government coalition. While I agree with

    the analysis of how VPI coalitions worked in Mexico during the 1920s, the

    analysis of Haber, Razo and Maurer actually supports my hypothesis that low

    taxation was conceded in exchange for support, since they argue that one of

    the mechanisms of selective protection of property rights was preferential tax

    treatment. But from my perspective, these authors, for the case of Mexico in the

    11 The NIE is a development of neo-classical economics to include the role of transaction costs inexchange and so to take account of institutions as critical constrains on economic performance, see,

    Harris, John, Janet Hunter and Colin M. Lewis, The New Institutional Economics and Third WorldDevelopment, (London: Routledge, 1995), p. 3.12

    See, Haber, Stephen, Armando Razo and Noel Maurer, The Politics of Property Rights. PoliticalInstability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876-1929, (Cambridge:Cambridge University Press, 2003).

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    12/53

    12

    1920s, overestimate the governments interest in taxation. Obviously, the

    Mexican government was interested on getting some revenues from its allies,

    but it was even more interested in political support. Therefore, it displayed a

    strategy of achieving political support in exchange of low taxation, a formula that

    helped the revolutionary regime to build its success.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    13/53

    13

    II. The Porfirian Fiscal Structure

    The Porfirian fiscal structure was based on indirect taxes. The three most

    important sources of revenue were custom taxes, stamp tax, an indirect tax on

    internal trade and transactions, and taxes on public services and exploitation.

    The only direct tax during the Porfiriato was the property tax collected by

    municipalities. However, the big landowners did not pay this tax fully, especially

    during the late Porfiriato, and they normally reported lower values for their

    properties and lobbied to get fiscal reductions and waivers.13

    Custom revenues were the principal source of central government revenue

    during the Porfiriato, but when measured as percentages of total revenue

    tended to show a decrease, while stamp tax, the second most important

    revenue, tended to show an increase. This was an important shift in the

    structure of the Porfirian finances. In 1876, at the beginning of the Porfirian

    regime, custom revenues were 66% of federal revenues, the stamp tax only

    represented 11% of central government revenues and taxes on public services

    and exploitation were 23%. Fiscal dependency on foreign trade was

    remarkable. Yet in 1910, at the end of the Porfiriato, custom revenues were

    44% of federal revenues, while the stamp tax represented 30%, and taxes on

    public services and exploitation were 26%. Internal taxes had become more

    important than external taxes.

    13

    For the case of hacendados in Morelos see Womack, John,Zapata and the Mexican Revolution, (NewYork: Vintage Books, 1970), p. 42. For the case of Chihuahua see, Katz, Friederich, The Life and Timesof Pancho Villa, (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1998), pp. 50 and 129-130.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    14/53

    14

    Figure 2: Evolution of the Porfirian Fiscal Structure, 1876-1910

    Evolution of the Federal Revenues' Composition, 1876-1910

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    1876 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910

    Year

    %o

    fTotal

    FederalRevenues

    Customs

    Stamp Tax

    Public Services and Eploitation

    Sources: Crdenas, Enrique, Cuando se origin el atraso econmico de Mxico. La economamexicana en el largo siglo XIX, 1780-1920, (Madrid: Editorial Biblioteca Nueva, 2003), pp. 154-55 (Cuadro V.3). And Coso Villegas, Daniel, La cuestin arancelara en Mxico, vol. III,(Mxico: Centro Mexicano de Estudios Econmicos, 1932?), pp. 70-71 (Cuadro 6).

    Two factors explain the growth of internal taxes. First, the growth of the

    economy, and in particular the expansion of domestic trade related to the rapid

    growth of railway construction,14 stimulated an increase in internal taxes.

    Second, in 1893 the Minister of Finance, Jos Ives Limantour, implemented a

    14

    See, Crdenas, Enrique, Cuando se origin el atraso econmico de Mxico. La economa mexicana enel largo siglo XIX, 1780-1920, (Madrid: Editorial Biblioteca Nueva, 2003), pp, 142-51, and 157. See also,Knight, The Mexican Revolution, vol I, (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1990), pp. 80-1.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    15/53

    15

    fiscal reform raising the tariffs of the stamp tax on textiles, alcoholic beverages,

    and property transactions.15

    During the late Porfiriato, between 1900 and 1910, on average the federal

    government raised 5.35% of the Mexican GDP, a relatively low figure compared

    with Brazil and Argentina, two countries with a similar degree of development.

    Brazil, on average, collected 12.7% of its GDP and likewise Argentina raised

    7.3% of its GDP.

    Figure 3: Central Governments Revenues as a percentage of GDP, 1901-1919

    Central Governments Revenues as a percentage of GDP, 1901-1919

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    16

    1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919

    Year

    GDP% Mexico

    Brazil

    Argentina

    Source: Oxford Latin American Economic History Database.

    15 See, Crdenas, Cuando se origin el atraso,pp. 156-7.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    16/53

    16

    From the second half of the 1900s Mexican revenues declined as a percentage

    of GDP. By 1910, when the Mexican Revolution started, federal revenues were

    only 3.7%. This level was maintained until 1919. The Revolution might have had

    some influence on this decrease. Nevertheless, is important to notice that both

    Brazilian and Argentine revenues also declined during this period. Between

    1910 and 1920 the former collected, on average, 10% of its GDP, and the latter

    5.5% of its GDP. Therefore, it is not unrealistic to think that some other factors

    might also have influenced the decline in revenues.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    17/53

    17

    III. The Obregn Presidency: Limits and Possibilities of Fiscal Extraction

    On 1 December 1920, after the brief interim presidency of Adolfo de la Huerta,

    lvaro Obregn was sworn in as president. His government inherited the fiscal

    structure developed during the Porfirian regime. This meant that the Mexican

    federal government continued to depend on indirect taxes, and there was no

    federal direct tax. There were, however, two key structural differences between

    the Porfirian and Sonoran financial systems. Obregn not only inherited the

    Porfirian fiscal structure but also the monetary chaos created by the

    Revolution16 and the lack of both international and national credit. These two

    phenomena were new. The Porfirian regime had access to international credit

    and there was not a fragmented monetary sovereignty as there was during the

    armed Revolution.

    Payment of the external debt had been suspended since 1914 and international

    loans had therefore been also cancelled. President Venustiano Carranza (1917-

    20) ordered the confiscation of the assets of the Mexican banks, forcing them to

    finance his government, yet when Obregn took power the capital seized by

    Carranza had gone.17 Consequently, the national banks had no capital to

    borrow, and after the inflationary experiences and destruction of the banking

    system during the Revolution, the government knew that a strategy of printing

    money without the proper support of gold reserves would only worsen the

    economy. Furthermore, the government did not even have enough instruments

    16 See, Medina Pea, Luis,Hacia el Nuevo Estado. Mxico, 1920-1994, (Mxico: Fondo de Cultura

    Econmica, 2000), pp. 85-87.17 See, Zebada, Emilio,Banqueros y revolucionarios: la soberana financiera de Mxico, 1914-1929(Mxico: Fondo de Cultura Econmica and ColMex, 1994), p. 166.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    18/53

    18

    of monetary policy to implement fully the inflationary policy of printing money.18

    There was no central bank, and the monetary chaos of the Revolution reduced

    peoples confidence in government money. Gold and later silver coins were

    Mexicos primary circulating medium.19 In a nutshell, neither printing money nor

    loans nor budget deficits were an option.

    Under these circumstances, the only possible source of revenue was the

    Mexican economy itself. Yet Obregn was very lucky because the production

    and exporting of oil boomed in 1919. Between 1919 and 1920 oil production

    achieved an unprecedented increase: the value of crude oil grew 97%. The

    growth of oil production and exports had a very positive impact on federal

    revenues, and from 1919 to 1920, federal revenues increased by 31.5% as a

    percentage of GDP. However, government revenues were still very limited, and

    tax revenues raised by the Mexican government in 1920 were 5% of its GDP.

    By contrast, in the same year the UK government, for instance, collected more

    than 20% of GDP and the Brazilian central government extracted more than

    9%. Mexican fiscal capacity was more similar to Argentinas, which was 5.4% of

    GDP. Nevertheless, the Argentine government had not been obliged to face a

    mobilised country after ten years of Revolution.

    18 According to Enrique Crdenas the Mexican government did not develop effective instrument ofmonetary policy until the great depression of 1929. See, Crdenas, Enrique,La hacienda pblica y la

    poltica econmica, 1929-1958, (Mxico: Fondo de Cultura Econmica y ColMex, 2005), pp. 62-9.19 See, Noel, Maurer, The Power and the Money. The Mexican Financial System, 1876-1932, (Stanford:Stanford University Press, 2002), pp. 161-70.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    19/53

    19

    Figure 4: Central Governments Revenues as a percentage of GDP, 1917-1930

    Central Governments Revenues as a percentage of GDP

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930

    Year

    GDP% Mexico

    Brazil

    Argentina

    Source: Oxford Latin American Economic History Database.

    When Obregn took power his government did not have US, British, or French

    recognition. The foreign debt was around 1,000 million pesos, more than 300

    million pesos in overdue interest, and the federal government had a surplus in

    revenue from oil revenues - amounting to 3 million pesos for the year.20 The

    Mexican army of some 100,000 men absorbed almost 50 per cent of the budget

    and, although temporarily supporting Obregn, was not wholly loyal to the

    president, as was demonstrated three years later when, following Adolfo de la

    Huertas uprising, more than half the army rebelled.

    20See, Womack, John, The Mexican Revolution, in Bethell, Leslie (ed),Mexico since Independence,(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), p. 200.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    20/53

    20

    The government also had to deal with a national confederation of labour at odds

    with the railway union; a still largely landless peasantry demanding land;

    national confederations of merchants and manufacturers; powerful local political

    bosses scattered all over the country; and large foreign companies wanting to

    remain above Mexican law by running their enterprises as enclaves of their own

    nations within Mexican territory.21

    Although oil revenues were helpful the challenges were huge. On the one hand,

    the government had to bring the military under its control, distribute land among

    mobilised peasants, and attend to the demands of organized workers,

    especially to those of its new ally, the Confederacin Regional Obrera Mexicana

    (CROM). On the other hand, the government needed more fresh cash to meet

    these obligations. The Sonorans needed urgently therefore to re-establish both

    international and national credit, but a sine qua non for recovering credit was

    both the governments ability to pay external debts and the restitution of the

    national banks assets.

    Obregn could not wait for further resources to start the process of controlling

    the army, distributing land and attending to workers demands. He had to do all

    of these at the same time, otherwise his government risked being overthrown by

    an alliance of dissidents, generals, peasants, workers, entrepreneurs or

    landowners. It was for this reason that he started to attend to everything at

    once.

    21 See, Womack, The Mexican Revolution, p. 200.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    21/53

    21

    Fortunately for Obregn, as was argued previously, both land reform and the

    most basic workers demands could be met without spending too much money.

    Consequently, Obregn commenced his agrarian reform immediately. In

    December 1920, less than a month after he took office, he signed the Ley de

    Ejidos. This law was the first attempt to regulate some of the principles laid

    down in Article 27 of the Constitution. As Simpson argues, this law was

    confused, vague and incomplete, but it demonstrated Obregns desire to

    accelerate agrarian reform and forge a political coalition with the agraristas. 22

    A year before, Obregn had forged a durable alliance with the CROM. In a

    secret pact, the CROM promised to mobilise support for Obregn in the 1920

    presidential election, in exchange for privileged political resources and support

    for the CROM against the capitalists. In the same year, the CROM founded the

    Mexican Labour Party (PLM), which was a key ally of both Obregn and Calles

    in their fights against governors within Congress.23

    In contrast to the relatively cheap implementation of land and labour reforms,

    bringing generals under governments control was more expensive. The

    strategy followed by the Sonorans of demobilising the military took four forms:

    helping high-ranking officers to become entrepreneurs, reforming the internal

    structure of the army, creating agrarian and workers militias in order to

    counterbalance the generals military power, and buying the generals loyalty

    with cash. All these actions demanded resources. A huge share of the budget

    22 See, Simpson, Eyler, The Ejido. Mexicos Way Out, (Chapel Hill: The University of North CarolinaPress, 1937), p. 81.23

    See, Middlebrook, Kevin, The Paradox of Revolution. Labor, the State and Authoritarianism inMexico, (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkings University Press, 1995), p. 75.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    22/53

    22

    was expended on the military. During the Obregns presidency, on average,

    the military expenditure was 45% of the federal budget. For the presidential

    period of Calles it declined to 31%.24

    To sum up, at the beginning of Obregns government budgetary pressures

    were relatively high, and he needed to search for more revenue. Obregn had

    three options: to increase indirect taxes, to create direct taxes, or to achieve

    agreements with international and national financiers in order to re-establish

    credit. He did indeed try all of them.

    In order to increase indirect taxes the government had three options: to

    augment the stamp tax, to impose revenue-maximizing import and export tariffs,

    and/or to extract a higher share of oil revenues. The stamp tax was problematic.

    It had many different tariffs and its collection and administration were

    expensive. The stamp tax also represented to some extent the unpopular side

    of the Porfiriato. Both the government and the entrepreneurs were against this

    tax,25 and it was therefore not an option.

    Imports tariffs were lowered during the Carranza government, in an attempt

    both to diminish the hyperinflationary prices caused by the monetary chaos of

    the Revolution, and to bring in food and other products that were in short supply

    in some regions of the country owing to the armed Revolution.26 From the

    24 See, Wilkie, James, The Mexican Revolution: Federal Expenditure and Social Change since 1910,(Berkley: University of California Press, 1967), p, 102 (Table 5-2).25 See, Aboites,Excepcione y privilegios, pp. 66-67; and Collado, Mara del Carmen,Empresarios y

    polticos, (Mxico: INEHRM, 1996), p. 182.26 See, Haber and et al, The Politics of Property Rights,pp. 140-41; and Collado,Empresarios y politicos,pp. 202 and 204.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    23/53

    23

    beginnings of his government Obregn was pressed by industrialists to increase

    imports tariffs in order to recover the protectionist policy that they had enjoyed

    during the Porfiriato.

    Protective import tariffs are not designed to generate tax revenue, because the

    effect of those tariffs is to drive imports down to zero or at least to very low

    levels.27 At the beginning of the Obregn presidency the coalition between the

    government and the industrialists was at an incipient stage, so Obregn did not

    yet feel under any obligation to satisfy the industrialists demands. As a result,

    import tariffs increased by only 10%.28 Indeed, the government was able to

    increase its revenues from imports by a small margin. But while as the alliance

    between the government and the industrialists was taking shape, import tariffs

    increased, and government revenues from imports decreased.29

    Extracting more revenue from oil was very tempting. Fiscal extraction from the

    oil industry is relatively easy. Production and exports can easily be monitored by

    governments, and it is difficult to hide profits. Furthermore, the physical

    collection of taxes is also straightforward, as oil production and its producers

    are geographically concentrated rather than dispersed. Moreover, the oil

    industry has fixed assets, and high levels of investment are required before

    profits start to be received. In short, the oil industry cannot emigrate in order to

    avoid highly taxation. Negotiations over the extraction of resources are confined

    to a small group of protagonists, meaning that when oil production is high,

    27

    See, Haber and et al, The Politics of Property Rights,p. 140.28 Ibid, p. 142.29 See, Ibid, pp, 151-54.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    24/53

    24

    taxing it is very good business. Obregn did not hesitate to augment oil

    revenue.

    Nonetheless, at that moment, the situation was more complicated than that

    because the government had little power over the oil companies. Oil production

    was dominated by a few foreign companies, the majority of which were from the

    US and were backed by the US government. They therefore had the ability to

    act collectively and with the support of a very powerful government.

    Furthermore, US diplomatic recognition of Obregns government was

    conditional on respect for the oil producers assets, and the government did not

    yet have the ability to run the oil industry by itself. Any attempt to take over the

    industry would have caused a temporary but significant disruption in output of

    oil and therefore in tax collection.30 In a context where some powerful generals

    were waiting for an opportunity to seize power, the government could not afford

    the luxury of disrupting oil production.

    To complicate the picture even more, the re-establishment of the governments

    credit was connected with oil revenues, as extracting more of the latter was one

    of the fastest ways of obtaining huge quantities of fresh cash. Because of this,

    both the re-establishment of the national banks assets and the repayment of

    the external debt depended on the governments ability to extract oil revenues.

    What was more, US diplomatic recognition was also conditional on a

    resumption of debt payments. Therefore, extracting oil taxes, reaching an

    agreement with Mexicos creditors, and achieving diplomatic relations with the

    30 See, Ibid, pp. 191-92.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    25/53

    25

    US were all part of the same complex problem: how to extract more revenue

    without affecting the oil companies privileges.

    Within this context oil producers fiercely resisted any attempt at taxation. Yet

    Obregn had an important tool with which to put pressure on oil companies.

    Article 27 of the 1917 Constitution granted the nation (in practice the federal

    government) ownership of all the subsoil of the Mexican territory, including all

    the minerals that formed part of that subsoil. Foreign oil companies opposed

    this legislation, sought the protection of the US government in order to retain

    their property, and blocked the enforcement of article 27 quite effectively. Yet

    the threat of its enforcement gave leverage to government power over the oil

    companies, enabling the former to extract a greater share of revenue from the

    latter.

    However, the increment in revenue was not achieved without confrontation. On

    7June 1921, Obregn imposed a new oil export tax: a specific duty of from 1.55

    to 2.50 pesos per cubic meter of petroleum, assessed in addition to Carranzas

    export tax.31 The oil companies responded by curtailing output and stopping all

    investment. Exports went from 15 million barrels per month to less than 6

    million, and employment in the oil fields fell from 50,000 men to 20,000. After

    their confrontation with Obregn the companies reached an agreement: the

    Mexican government secured an increase in oil revenues, but the companies

    obtained a 60% reduction in Obregns new export tax.32

    31 See, Ibid, p. 208.32 Ibid, pp. 208-9.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    26/53

    26

    Despite all the difficulties and the clear limitations on the governments power

    over the oil companies, extraction of oil revenues was the favourite and most

    efficient revenue-producing strategy between 1920 and 1924. The significant

    increase of oil production after 1919 was used to increase on both federal tax

    revenues and the percentage of oil revenues in the federal income. In fact, the

    fiscal strategy of the government was shaped by the availability of oil revenues.

    Figure 5: Oil Revenues and Oil Production

    Oil Revenues as a Percentage of Total Revenues and Oil Production in Millions of Barrels

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35

    1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930

    Year

    %TotalRevenue

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    MillionsofBarrels

    Oil Revenues (% of Total Revenues)

    Oil Production (Millions of Barrels)

    Sources: Oxford Latin American Economic History Database; Meyer, Jean, Revolution andReconstruction in the 1920s, in Bethell, Leslie, Mexico since Independence, (Cambridge:Cambridge University Press, 1998), p. 224 (Table 3); and Haber, Stephen, Armando Razo andNoel Maurer, The Politics of Property Rights. Political Instability, Credible Commitments, andEconomic Growth in Mexico, 1876-1929, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), p,199 (Table 6.1).

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    27/53

    27

    Oil revenues allowed the Mexican government to restore assets to the national

    banks in 1921 and to reach an agreement with Mexicos international creditors

    in 1922. The payment of the Mexican debt was directly tied to oil revenues: in

    fact part of the debt was directly paid by oil companies, and such payments

    were discounted from their taxes.33

    Nevertheless, revenues were not bountiful enough to create the much-needed

    central bank. Therefore, although internal credit was restored after the payment

    of the internal debt, Mexican banks had very limited credit capacity. Without a

    central bank, and with a weak national financial system, the possibilities of

    obtaining significant internal loans continued to be extremely limited.

    Furthermore, what was known as the de la Huerta-Lamont agreement with

    international bankers did not include any loan. Negotiations were exclusively

    concerned with arranging a formula for the payment of the external debt.

    Although the Mexican government asked for a new loan, international creditors

    refused it, arguing that Mexico had first to show its payment capacity. So

    despite fiscal efforts to restore access to credit, Obregn did not enjoy any

    significant loan, and his government was highly dependent on oil revenues.

    When oil production declined, the government was forced to search out other

    sources of revenue.

    To impose direct taxation is a huge challenge. The straight extraction of

    peoples wealth is not the same as indirect extraction of trade. As Tilly argues,

    taxing peoples own profits, properties or income requires a much more

    33 See, Zebada,Banqueros y revolucionarios,pp. 182-222.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    28/53

    28

    extensive surveillance apparatus for collection than does the collection of

    revenue from goods passing across borders, which itself gives rise to a larger

    collection surveillance apparatus than the sale of precious minerals.34 For

    instance, even property tax, probably one of the easiest direct taxes to collect

    (because by definition assets are fixed and it is relatively easy to assign them a

    value) requires long and arduous administrative efforts in order to make a

    cadastral survey. In France, for instance, it took thirty eight years to complete

    such a survey.35

    Direct tax extraction, at least in the long run, can force governments to

    negotiate with large numbers of people, rather than relatively few groups of

    exporters or entrepreneurs as is the case with international trade tariffs or

    specific taxes of mineral or other industrial production. These negotiations can

    sometimes drive governments to concede rights and official representation to

    the people they are extracting resources from.36 It is not accidental that, if they

    have alternatives, governments normally prefer to avoid direct taxes. Moreover,

    when capital is abundant, as Tilly argues, taxation is relatively easier and less

    violent than when capital is scarce. 37 In the Mexico of the 1920s, capital was

    not abundant. Therefore, any attempt to extract peoples direct resources

    beyond the urban centres where capital was normally concentrated, would have

    34 Tilly, Charles,Democracy, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007), p, 202.35See, Deas, Malcolm, The Fiscal Problems of Nineteenth-Century Colombia,Journal of Latin

    American Studies, Vol.14, part 2, November, 1928, p. 287.36 See, Tilly, Charles, Coercion, Capital, and European States,pp. 96-126; and Tilly, Charles, Where

    Do Rights Come From?, in Skocpol, Theda,Democracy, Revolutions and History, (New York: CornellUniversity Press, 1998), pp. 61-63.37 See, Tilly, Coercion, Capital, and European States, pp. 16-20; 87-89, and 132-43.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    29/53

    29

    implied that even stronger state mobilization and coercion were needed, and

    could have caused unnecessary local rebellions.38

    It was these complications, combined with the availability of oil revenues and

    the political context, which shaped the pattern of direct taxation during the

    1920s. As noted before, Obregn tried to open up all possible alternatives in

    order to expand Mexican revenues. Yet, very soon, political reality and his

    pragmatism delimited the options.

    Obregns first attempt to establish a direct tax was the imposition of the

    Centenario tax, in 1921. This tax was a kind of income tax, because it levied

    profits and personal income. Yet, from the start, the government explained that

    the Centenario tax was only a provisional measure, and would be levied just

    once. Although the aim was to invest in port infrastructure and buy merchant

    ships, this tax was strongly opposed. Industrialists and merchant organizations

    criticized it fiercely, and their first reaction was to announce that they would not

    pay the tax.39 According to Zebada, because of the protest against the

    Centenario tax, this tax was derogated almost immediately after the budget for

    1921 was presented to Congress.40 In any case, at that moment oil revenues

    were 23% of the federal budget. From 1920 to 1921 oil revenues grew by 17%,

    and expectations of growth in oil revenues were very high. Under these

    circumstances it made sense not to defend the Centenario tax.

    38 One of the multiple reasons for rebellion during the Revolution in central north Mexico was the statepenetration and taxation of relatively autonomous towns in the region of Sierra Madre. See, Knight, The

    Mexican Revolution vol I,pp. 121 and 155.39 See, Collado,Empresarios y polticos,pp. 164-66.40 See, Zebada,Banqueros y revolucionarios,p. 160.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    30/53

    30

    The second attempt to impose a direct tax also failed. On 11 October 1922 a

    presidential decree, based on the extraordinary faculties that Congress gave to

    the president on fiscal affairs in 191741, established a federal tax on property.

    The most active opposition came from the National Agrarian Chambers and

    governors, though industrialists and merchants also expressed their

    disagreement. 42 The opposition, particularly the governors, argued that that the

    tax was illegal because, according to their interpretation of the Constitution,

    property taxes were only under state jurisdiction.43 The federal government

    argued that the tariff was very low (1% of properties value), and that the real

    purpose of the tax was to create a reliable cadastral census.

    On 30 May 1923 the decree regulations were published and protests intensified.

    The government agreed to convoke a national cadastral convention to discuss

    and negotiate the issue, and at that moment the federal government did not feel

    under huge pressure to collect more revenue. After all, in 1922 oil revenues

    were 31% of federal income, having growing by 35%. That year federal

    revenues reached 6% of Mexicos GDP. It represented a growth of 20% in only

    two years. And although oil production started to decline in 1923, this trend was

    not at all clear during the first semester of 1923. The convention was scheduled

    by the beginning of December.

    41 Between 1917 and 1946 Mexican presidents used those faculties to enact 92% of the fiscal disposition.See, Weldon, Jeffrey, El crecimiento de los poderes metaconstitucionales de Crdenas y vila Camacho.Su desempeo legislativo 1934-1946,Dilogo y Debate de Cultura Poltica, 1 (abril-junio), 1997, pp.24-25.42 See Collado,Empresarios y polticos, p. 116.43

    The governors argued that following the logic of articles 117 and 118 of the Constitution that forbadestates to impose indirect taxes, the federation should be forbidden to impose direct taxes. The sameargument was used against income tax. See, Aboites,Excepciones y privilegios,p. 115.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    31/53

    31

    It was very bad timing. On 7 December 1923 Adolfo de la Huerta rebelled, with

    the support of more than half of the army. The government needed the support

    of governors, landlords, agraristas, industrialists and merchants. Therefore,

    Obregn derogated the federal property tax.

    By February 1924 the delahuertista rebellion had been crushed. On 21

    February 1924 a decree was immediately published imposing the new income

    tax. This third attempt to impose a direct tax was finally successful. The context

    was very different. First, it was now clear that oil production was rapidly

    declining. In 1923 oil revenues were only 22% of federal revenue, 29% less

    than in 1922. Oil revenues dropped to the level of 1921 and the future did not

    seem very rosy. Second, the delahuertista uprising involved the government in

    extraordinary expense, creating a deficit that put at risk the governments ability

    to pay the foreign debt.

    More importantly, the Mexican government would probably have been

    overthrown by the rebels if it had not had the support of the agrarian and

    workers militias, and agreements with the US the Bucareli agreements - that

    allowed it to purchase weapons there. It also had the support of the US

    government and the oil companies during the rebellion. Therefore, the federal

    government had to repay its allies. Loyal generals had to be rewarded, agrarian

    reform had to be accelerated, the CROMs patronage had to be augmented,

    and oil companies were given privileges.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    32/53

    32

    These measures required more revenue, so although income tax was the most

    opposed and fiercely combated tax during the 1920s, this time the government

    did not capitulate. There was now no alternative: the income tax could no longer

    be postponed. Yet the delahuertista rebellion also brought a positive outcome

    for the government, as the latter was strengthened by its military victory. The

    combination of the urgent need for revenue with military triumph gave the

    government the necessary confidence to impose an extremely unpopular tax on

    both companies profits and personal income.

    The most fierce and well-organized resistance came from merchants and to a

    lesser extent from industrialists. National and local chambers of merchants and

    industrialists joined forces to present a united front against the income tax.

    Nevertheless, merchants asked for its abolition, whereas industrialists, probably

    following their experience of forging a coalition with the CROM and government

    to raise import tariffs, only asked for reductions and waivers.

    The opposition petitioned Obregn for the abrogation of the tax or at least

    reductions and waivers. Later, newspapers were flooded with articles and

    declarations by merchants and industrial leaders against the tax. The editorial

    stances of the newspapers were also against the income tax. National and local

    congresses of merchants and industrialists chambers were held, and their

    documents and statements opposing the tax were published. Studies

    undertaken by specialists were paid for and published by merchants and

    industrialists chambers. Finally, after it was clear that the government was firm

    in its position, opposition intensified. The national and regional chambers of

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    33/53

    33

    merchants openly called on the population to deny the payment, legal petitions

    were made against the tax in court, some merchants threatened to close their

    businesses, (some in fact did so), and even calls for rebellion were heard,

    echoing the American Revolution cry of no taxation without representation.44

    Nothing worked. The government did not capitulate.

    Calculating the real impact of the income tax on Mexican revenues is

    complicated. For instance, according to the Oxford Latin American Economic

    History Data, based on the data gathered by Mitchell45, from 1925 to 1930, on

    average, income tax was 12% of federal revenues. Yet, according to Iturriaga

    de la Fuente, Aboites and Collado, all of them using the data gathered by

    Aguilar46, the tax was only 6% of federal revenues. In any case, the impact was

    not that important, especially if compared with the impact of oil revenues.

    Nevertheless, the amount is significant, especially if the Oxford Latin American

    Economic History Data are considered.

    Calculating the impact of other taxes is also problematic. There is no unified

    criterion for the origin of taxes. Thus, for example, Aboites includes the category

    of taxes on natural resources but excludes the category of taxes on rights and

    exploitation.47 On the contrary, Iturriaga de la Fuente, excludes the category of

    taxes on natural resources but includes the category of taxes on rights and

    44 For a more complete narrative of the imposition of the income tax, see Collado,Empresarios ypolticos,pp. 174-199; and Aboites,Excepciones y privilegios,pp. 131-153.45 Mitchell, BR,International Historical Statistics. The Americas, 1750-1988, (Basingstoke: MacmillanPublishers, 1993).46

    Aguilar, Gustavo,Los presupuestos mexicanos, desde los tiempos de la Colonia hasta nuestros das,(Mxico: SHCP, 1940).47 See, Aboites,Excepciones y privilegios,p. 37 (Cuador 2).

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    34/53

    34

    exploitation.48 It is not surprising, then, to find that although all the authors and

    data consulted for this essay present almost the same figures for total federal

    revenues, they show different results when total taxes are divided by

    categories. Even more, in the few cases that they share categories, such as

    foreign trade revenues, their figures are dissimilar. That is why, in order to show

    a general tendency on the evolution of taxation in the 1920s, I present two types

    of figures. First, drawing from Coso Villegas data49, I display a graph on the

    evolution of external and internal taxes.50Second, using Iturriaga de la Fuentes

    figures, I work a table comparing the composition of federal revenues in 1924,

    the last year of Obregns presidency, and 1929, the end of the period studied

    in this essay.

    48 See, Iturriaga de la Fuente, Jos,La revolucin hacendaria. La hacienda pblica con el presidenteCalles, (Mxico: SEP, 1976), p. 77.49 Coso Villegas, Daniel, La cuestin arancelara en Mxico, vol. III, (Mxico: Centro Mexicano deEstudios Econmicos, 1932?), pp. 65 (Cuadro 5) and 70-71 (Cuadro 6).50

    Coso Villegas includes in the category of external taxes, imports, exports and consular rights taxes. Inthe case of internal taxes, he only clarifies that he added to the whole category of internal taxes public

    services and exploitation taxes.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    35/53

    35

    Figure 6: External and Internal Taxes as a percentage of Total Revenues, 1920-

    1929

    External and Internal Taxes as a percentage of Total Revenues

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929

    Year

    %TotalR

    evenues

    External Taxes

    Internal Taxes

    Source: Coso Villegas, Daniel, La cuestin arancelara en Mxico, vol. III, (Mxico: CentroMexicano de Estudios Econmicos, 1932?), pp. 65 (Cuadro 5) and 70-71 (Cuadro 6).

    Table 1: Structure of Federal Revenues, 1924 and 1929

    Type of Tax Percentage of TotalRevenues, 1924

    Percentage of TotalRevenues, 1929

    Foreign Trade 31.28 26.98Industry 28.74 14.96

    Income - 6.7Capitals 1.21 .85Stamp 13 6

    Public Services 5.84 19.93Consular Rights 5.48 .06

    The additional 10% 5.44 5.15Others rights, products and

    exploitation 919.36

    Total 100 100Source: Iturriaga de la Fuente, Jos,La revolucin hacendaria. La hacienda pblica con el presidenteCalles, (Mxico: SEP, 1976), p. 77.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    36/53

    36

    IV. The Calles Presidency: Political Coalitions and Low Taxation

    President Plutarco Elas Calles had to face a rapid decline in oil revenues. In

    1924 these were 20% of the federal revenue, but by 1928 they were only 6%.

    They had returned to the level they had been before 1918. In 1921 Mexico was

    the second world producer of oil, but by 1927 production had fallen 76%. The

    main problem was that almost all the wells had been exploited to their maximum

    capacity. 51 As Haber, Razo and Maurer argue, neither political instability, nor

    government taxes, nor article 27, caused the decline in oil production. It was

    due to purely ecological reasons.52

    The decline in oil revenues, combined with the extraordinary expense caused

    by the delahuertista rebellion, forced the government to suspend the payment of

    the external debt. Following this, Alberto Pani, the new minister of finance, had

    to renegotiate the Delahuerta-Lamont agreement, which was signed on the

    assumption that the high level of oil revenues would be constant. In the

    meantime, there was no possibility of a significant international loan. The

    extraordinary costs of the delahuertista rebellion were financed by national bank

    internal loans and taxes paid in advance by oil companies. Again, the only

    possible source of revenue was the Mexican economy itself, but oil revenues

    were now severely reduced.

    51

    See, Meyer,Revolution and Reconstruction, in Bethell, Leslie (ed),Mexico since Independence,(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991) p. 225.52 See, Haber and et al, The Politics of Property Rights,pp. 223-35.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    37/53

    37

    In 1925 Calles reformed income tax. His new decree established seven different

    tariffs that depended on economic activity and level of income.53 Also, in this

    year a slow movement towards fiscal centralization commenced. The most

    significant action here was the first National Fiscal Convention organized by

    Alberto Pani.54 Although the convention was not very successful at achieving a

    greater level of centralization55 it was useful in bringing about new direct taxes,

    and in December 1925 new inheritance taxes were created.56 Despite the

    decline in oil revenues, these measures, combined with an increase in public

    services and exploitation rights taxes, allowed the government to keep the level

    of taxation at 6% of Mexicos GDP. Furthermore, in 1925 the economy grew by

    6%57, so that the amount of revenue in pesos was augmented. These relatively

    good fiscal conditions allowed the government to reach a new agreement with

    Mexicos creditors, and to resume the payment of the external debt. Also,

    enough resources could finally be taken out to create a central bank.

    The establishment of the central bank was a key step in strengthening Mexican

    finances. The bank was able to finance small government deficits, and it played

    a key role in bringing the army under governments control, because it gave

    credit to revolutionary generals to finance their new industrial and agricultural

    enterprises. Therefore, many generals switched arms for business.

    53 See, Aboites,Excepciones y privilegios,p. 146.54 See, Ibid, pp. 291301.55 See, Daz-Cayeros, Alberto,Federalism, Fiscal Authority, and Centralization in Latin America,

    (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006), pp. 39-73.56 See, Iturriaga de la Fuente, p. 93.57 See, Ibid, p. 85.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    38/53

    38

    In April 1927 a new law on mining taxes was imposed.58 After this law no new

    significant taxes were imposed in the 1920s. On the contrary, Calles

    presidency saw an intensification of the process initiated by Obregn whereby

    coalitions were formed with organized workers, peasants, industrialist, big

    entrepreneurs, and even some landlords. Therefore, in order to bind those

    coalitions, fiscal privileges and waivers were also deepened.

    After the delahuertista rebellion the governments alliance with the CROM was

    intensified. The CROMs political and military support of the federal government

    through its workers militias was key to government victory over the rebels. In

    return for the CROMs loyalty, Calles appointed the CROM leader Morones as

    minister of industry, commerce, and labour. Morones position permitted the

    CROM to control the designation of both government and labour

    representatives in the labour conciliation and arbitration boards.59 Furthermore,

    the CROM also controlled the Department of Industrial Enterprise and Military

    Supply, the Federal Labour Office, and the National Printing Office, and with

    Calles support the CROM enforced fee deductions from public employees

    salaries, thereby increasing significantly its economic resources.60

    The CROMs power was also extended to local politics and, through the PLM, to

    Congress. Five governorships, including the Federal District, were controlled by

    58 See, Iturriaga de la Fuente,La revolucin hacendaria,p. 93.59 Conciliation and arbitration boards, consisting of government, employer and worker representatives,are responsible for legally registering labour unions. Collective labour agreements have legal standingonly after they are deposited with the boards, which also enforce a variety of specific legal requirementsregarding collective labour contracts, workplace conditions and minimum wages. The unions political

    viability is tied to the boards. Actually, conciliation and arbitration boards were and still are - the mostsignificant political tool to regulate labour affairs.60 See, Middlebrook, The Paradox of Revolution, p. 79-80.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    39/53

    39

    the CROM. By 1926, 11 out of 58 positions in the Senate and 40 out of 272

    seats in the Chamber of Deputies were also held by CROM members.61

    Control over these significant resources allowed Morones to centralize power

    within the CROM. In Febraury 1925, for instance, the CROMs national

    leadership informed its affiliates that they could strike only with the permission

    of the central committee. As Middlebrook argues, the centralized power of

    Morones and his strong endorsement of economic reconstruction, including

    support for direct foreign investment, were fundamental for Calles development

    programme.62 Furthermore, labour politics was an arena of constant

    confrontation between the federal government and governors. Specific labour

    legislation came under state jurisdiction. Nevertheless, both Article 123 of the

    Constitution and the precise national character of the CROM allowed the federal

    government to interfere constantly in local labour affairs.

    Although the CROM and industrialists were, for obvious reasons, at odds in

    many issues, they shared an interest in protecting industries from foreign

    competition. Therefore, despite all their differences, organized workers and

    capitalists pushed the government to raise import tariffs. From the beginning of

    Obregns presidency, as we noted before, industrialists lobbied to bring back

    the protectionist policies they had enjoyed during the Porfiriato. Yet as we also

    noted before, protectionist tariffs reduced the governments revenue. Before the

    CROM had been able to gain influence the President was better able to resist

    industrialists pressure, and import tariffs were not significantly increased.

    61 See, Ibid, p. 8062 See, Ibid, p. 78.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    40/53

    40

    Nevertheless, the delahuertista uprising changed power relations. The CROM,

    allied with industrialists, had enough power to persuade the government to

    create new protectionists policies, leading to import tariffs being significantly

    increased from 1923-4 onwards. For instance, according to Haber, in the cotton

    industry, the revenues from the excise were considerably less than the taxes

    that the government could have received had it imposed the revenue-

    maximizing import tariff.63

    A similar pattern was seen in other manufacturing industries. In 1925 Calles

    established a Tariff Reform Commission. This commission made

    recommendations to the president, who then, acting by decree, determined the

    tariff. The commission was made up of two representatives of the Ministry of

    Industry, Commerce, and Labour controlled by the CROM, two representatives

    from the Ministry of Finance, one representative from the Ministry of Agriculture,

    one representative from the Federation of Chambers of Commerce, and one

    representative from the Federation of Industrial Chambers. The industrialist

    had a mechanism to coordinate and signal their demands, and consumers had

    no representatives.64

    Table 2: Coefficient of Protection (tar i f f revenues divided b y the value ofdut iable good s)

    Year Coefficient of Protection1920 14%1923 24%1928 31%

    Source: Haber, Stephen, Armando Razo and Noel Maurer, The Politics of Property Rights.Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876-1929,

    (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), p, 152.

    63 Haber and et al, The Politics of Property Rights,p. 149.64 Ibid, p. 152.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    41/53

    41

    Table 3: Average Import Tariff for some Products

    Year Average ImportTariff forConsumers Goods*

    Average ImportTariff for Textiles Average ImportTariff forManufactured

    Clothing1924 38% 45% 43%1930 47% 59% 69%

    *Without including foodstuffs.Source: Haber, Stephen, Armando Razo and Noel Maurer, The Politics of Property Rights.Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876-1929,(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), pp, 152-53.

    According to Haber, Razo and Maurer, in the case of the mining sector, as in

    the case of oil, the Mexican governments of the 1920s did not have the ability to

    run the mines and smelters by themselves. Furthermore, as a consequence of

    political instability, the government needed tax revenues more desperately than

    the companies needed the income. Therefore, in the short run, companies had

    the ability effectively to threaten the government to cut back production if they

    were heavily taxed.65

    The situation was even more difficult than in the case of oil revenues because

    metal prices collapsed after the early 1920s, and the government had even less

    room to negotiate an increase in taxes. As a result, in order at least to extract

    some revenue, the Mexican government let the asset holders play a large role

    in writing the mining laws.66 Obviously, the outcome was low tax rates, and

    those rates, according to Haber, were also tied to metal prices in New York.

    65 See, Ibid, pp. 236-84.66 Ibid, p. 282.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    42/53

    42

    Table 4: Estimated Taxation Rates for Mexican Mining (taxes as apercentage of the gross v alue of product ion)

    Year Federal and State Tax Rate Combined1920 10.7

    1921 7.21922 7.91923 6.91924 6.81925 7.21926 6.31927 5.31928 5.61929 4.7

    Source: Haber, Stephen, Armando Razo and Noel Maurer, The Politics of Property Rights.Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876-1929,(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), p, 283 (Table 7.13).

    The governments coalition with peasants and some landlords, many of them

    revolutionary generals who had replaced Porfirian landlords followed roughly

    two paths. On the one hand, in areas with potential for agricultural exports,

    some landlords (either military men, or civilian farmers allied with generals)

    were allowed to keep relatively large extensions of land, and the federal

    government provided them with credit and irrigation programmes. For instance,

    the government constructed four large dams in Durango, Aguascalientes,

    Tamaulipas, and Coahuila.67 Irrigation work sponsored by the federal

    government was begun in 1926, and expenditure on irrigation grew in the

    following years. In 1926 1.6% of all federal funds were expended on irrigation,

    but by 1928 the amount achieved was 6.9%.68

    On the other hand, in areas with staple crops, much land was distributed among

    peasants in the forms of ejido lands.69 Land distribution followed political

    67 Ibid, p. 315.68

    See, Wilkie, The Mexican Revolution,pp. 132-34.69 Ejido land is not private property and cannot be bought and sold as if it were. However, since theconstitutional reforms of 1992, ejido land can be converted into private property and sold to third parties.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    43/53

    43

    criteria. For instance, former Zapatistas in Morelos who were allies of Obregn

    and afterwards of Calles were among the first groups to receive land. By 1927

    statistics indicated that Morelos had changed more from agrarian programs

    than any other state Provisionally at least 80 per cent of the states farming

    families now held field of their own, which altogether amounted to around 75 per

    cent of the arable land.70 In other areas agrarian reform was accelerated during

    and after the delahuertista uprising in compensation for peasants military

    participation against the rebels.

    The acceleration of agrarian reform after the delahuertista rebellion was clear.

    Under Obregns government 624 villages and 139,320 heads of families

    received around 1.2 million hectares of land. This was more than triple the

    number of villages and ejidatarios receiving land during Carranzas regime.71

    Yet, during the Calles government, after the de la Huerta uprising, 3.2 million

    hectares of land were distributed to 1,576 villages and 307,607 ejidatarios. This

    was more than three times as much land and villages as during the previous

    land distribution.72

    It is important to notice that agrarian reform and therefore the alliance between

    the government and peasants followed a complicated and messy pattern.

    Although the struggle for land was used by both the federal government and

    caciques to construct clientelar relationships, agrarian reform in the 1920s was

    not only controlled from above but also gained from below. The story of the

    agrarian revolt in Naranja and the Zacapu region of Michoacn analyzed by

    70

    See, Womack,Zapata,p. 374.71 See, Ibid, p. 87.72See, Ibid, pp. 96-7.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    44/53

    44

    Paul Friederich is an excellent example of this complex dynamic, involving: local

    agrarian mobilisation for land reform; government support for agrarian

    communities (and in some cases effective land distribution) in exchange for

    military support during rebellions; active mediation and manipulation by political

    brokers; and dissent and ensuing repression.73

    The alliance between the federal government and ejidatarios was bolstered by

    another not very well known but important innovation: the ejidalfiscal waiver. It

    might be true that many ejidatarios in the 1920s did not enjoy the same

    irrigation benefits that some of the new big land owners enjoyed, yet during the

    decade they were able to obtain a fiscal waiver.

    At the beginning of land reform this fiscal waiver for the ejidos was not clear; but

    from the early 1920s it was fairly evident that the federal government was trying

    to create a special fiscal regime for the agrarian sector. In 1921 the Agrarian

    National Commission established numerous fiscal waivers for the ejidos74.

    Nonetheless, other federal departments ignored the Agrarian National

    Commission regulations. For instance, the ejidos were charged for the use of

    water until President Calles exempted them for the payment of this utility in

    192675. A year later the law of patrimonio parcelario ejidalestablished that the

    only tax that the ejidos must pay was the local property tax. This special fiscal

    regime was confirmed by the agrarian codes of 1934 and 1943, and also by the

    agrarian law of 1971.

    73 See, Friederich, Paul,Agrarian Revolt in a Mexican Village, (New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1970).74

    See, Fabila, Manuel, Cinco siglos de legislacin agraria 1493-1940, (Mxico: Centro de EstudiosHistricos del Agrarismo Mexico-Secretara de la Reforma Agraria, 1981), p. 377.75 Aboites Aguilar, Luis,Excepciones y privilegios, p. 232.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    45/53

    45

    According to Aboites, although the local property tax could not exceed 5% of

    the annual value of the ejidalproduction, many ejidos refused to pay it76. Many

    local governments protested, but the federal government was as a rule not very

    receptive to their complaints. Therefore, many ejidos did not even pay the

    property tax77.

    Finally, in the case of the income tax, despite all the efforts to impose it,

    according to Aboites there are some indications that this tax was also used as a

    negotiating tool between the federal government and taxpayers, especially the

    wealthiest.78

    For instance, just after the 1920s, in 1933, the Under-secretary of Finance,

    Marte R. Gmez, argued that income tax has been perverted and its

    performance is very similar to the inconvenient system of the stamp tax79.

    Furthermore, in the plan sexenal80 of 1934, the National Revolutionary Party

    protested that income tax had been transformed into a working class tax

    because this segment of the population was the only one that was unable to

    avoid it.81 However, Aboites himself recognizes that the evidence is still weak,

    and that more archival research is needed to present a better picture of this

    phenomenon. Yet, following the logic of forging political alliances at the cost of

    taxation that we found with other taxes, it would not be odd to find that some

    76 Property tax was calculated in terms of production rather than property value.77 See, Aboites, Excepciones y privilegios, p. 233 and 234.78 Ibid, p. 152.79 Ibid, p. 149.80

    Plan Sexenal was the name of the Government Plan. It was presented at the beginning of thepresidential terms. Nowadays it is called Plan Nacional de Desarrollo (National Plan for Development).81 Ibid, p. 149.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    46/53

    46

    kind of evasion was indeed tolerated in the case of income tax in exchange of

    political support.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    47/53

    47

    Conclusion

    One of the paradoxes of the Mexican Revolution is that although it achieved a

    stronger and more stable state than both the Porfirian and the rest of the Latin

    American states, the features that gave it its strength and stability were the

    result of the actions of a weak state trying to survive in a challenging

    environment. The convergence of those social and political movements

    developed during the armed revolution, with a fragile state threatened by

    uncontrolled generals, gave birth to a new regime that in order to subsist forged

    a broad coalition with organized workers and peasants, capitalists, local political

    bosses and some military men. This broad alliance and the particularities that

    shaped it created the bases for a durable and stable regime unprecedented in

    the history of Latin America.

    A key element when seeking to understand the process that gave birth to this

    coalition is the combination of the fiscal structure inherited by the new regime

    with the type of financial demands that it was enduring. The new regime

    inherited from the old regime a poor fiscal system dependent on indirect taxes,

    and from the Revolution monetary chaos and the impossibility of accessing

    international or national credit. The financial demands that the revolutionary

    governments had to meet came from inside rather than from outside. The new

    regime did not have to prepare a national army in order to fight an international

    war. On the contrary, it had to demobilise and bring under its control a

    heterogeneous revolutionary army commanded by ambitious generals scattered

    all around the country. Therefore, the fiscal demands were modest in

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    48/53

    48

    comparison with the fiscal demands generated by total wars.82 Defeating local

    rebellions is cheaper than defeating foreign armies, especially when rebels can

    be counterbalanced through political alliances rather than through revenues.

    The inheritance of a weak fiscal system and the inability to get quick money

    through credit created the incentives to forge a broad coalition in order to

    counterbalance the military. It was precisely the fiscal limitation inherited by the

    new regime that restricted its ability to offer material benefits in exchange for

    political support. One of the elements that helped the government to forge a

    broad coalition (without spending huge quantities of money that it did not have)

    was offering low tax rates and fiscal waivers in exchange for political support.

    This process of coalition formation shaped a fiscal system full of waivers,

    privileges, and tolerated evasion that also reinforced a pattern of clientelistic

    politics. These characteristics of the fiscal system forged during the 1920s

    prevailed for many decades and even today many of these elements are still

    present.

    Ironically, the weakness of the fiscal structure helped to forge a stronger and

    more stable state than its previous counterpart, though the formula of low taxes

    in exchange for political support that created a national state without taxation

    was also one of the main weaknesses of the new regime. After some decades,

    the Mexican state, was put in an extremely difficult position by the lack of

    revenues, the growth of the population and the demand for more expensive

    82 Centeno,Blood and Debt,p, 21.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    49/53

    49

    social and economic benefits, such as health, housing, and education, instead

    of the relatively cheap demands of agrarian reform and eight hours journey.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    50/53

    50

    Bibliography, Books and Articles

    Aboites, Luis, Excepciones y privilegios. Modernizacin Tributaria

    Centralizacin en Mxico, 1922-1972, (Mxico: El Colegio de Mxico, 2003).

    Aguilar, Gustavo, Lospresupuestos mexicanos, desde los tiempos de la Colonia hasta

    nuestros das, (Mxico: SHCP, 1940).

    Crdenas, Enrique, Cuando se origin el atraso econmico de Mxico. La economa

    mexicana en el largo siglo XIX, 1780-1920, (Madrid: Editorial Biblioteca Nueva,

    2003).

    ------------- La hacienda pblica y la poltica econmica, 1929-1958, (Mxico: Fondode Cultura Econmica y ColMex, 2005).

    Centeno, Miguel ngel, Blood and Debt. War and the Nation-State In Latin America,

    (Philadelphia: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 2002).

    Collado, Mara del Carmen, Empresarios y polticos, (Mxico: INEHRM, 1996).

    Coso Villegas, Daniel, La cuestin arancelara en Mxico, vol. III, (Mxico: CentroMexicano de Estudios Econmicos, 1932?).

    Deas, Malcolm, The Fiscal Problems of Nineteenth-Century Colombia, Journal ofLatin American Studies, Vol.14, part 2, November, 1982.

    Daz-Cayeros, Alberto, Federalism, Fiscal Authority, and Centralization in Latin

    America, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006).

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    51/53

    51

    Fabila, Manuel, Cinco siglos de legislacin agraria 1493-1940, (Mxico: Centro deEstudios Histricos del Agrarismo Mexico-Secretara de la Reforma Agraria,1981).

    Friederich, Paul,Agrarian Revolt in a Mexican Village, (New Jersey: Prentice-Hall,1970).

    Haber, Stephen, Armando Razo and Noel Maurer, The Politics of Property Rights.Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico,1876-1929, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003).

    Harris, John, Janet Hunter and Colin M. Lewis, The New Institutional Economics and

    Third World Development, (London: Routledge, 1995).

    Herz, John, Political Realism and Political Idealism: A Study in Theories and Realities,

    (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1951).

    Iturriaga de la Fuente, Jos, La revolucin hacendaria. La hacienda pblica con elpresidente Calles, (Mxico: SEP, 1976).

    Katz, Friederich, The Life and Times of Pancho Villa, (Stanford: Stanford University

    Press, 1998), pp. 50 and 129-130.

    Knight, Alan, The Mexican Revolution, 2vols, (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press,1990).

    --------------The Peculiarities of Mexican History: Mexico Compared to Latin America,1821-1992, in Journal of Latin American Studies, Vol. 24, 1990).

    Medina, Luis, Hacia el Nuevo Estado. Mxico, 1920-1994, (Mxico: Fondo de

    Cultura Econmica, 2000), pp. 85-87.

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    52/53

    52

    Meyer, Jean, Revolution and Reconstruction, in Bethell, Leslie (ed), Mexico sinceIndependence, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).

    Middlebrook, Kevin, The Paradox of Revolution. Labor, the State and Authoritarianismin Mexico, (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkings University Press, 1995).

    Mitchell, BR, International Historical Statistics. The Americas, 1750-1988,(Basingstoke: Macmillan Publishers, 1993).

    Noel, Maurer, The Power and the Money. The Mexican Financial System, 1876-1932,(Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2002).

    Simpson, Eyler, The Ejido. Mexicos Way Out, (Chapel Hill: The University of NorthCarolina Press, 1937).

    Tilly, Charles, Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992, (Oxford:Blackwell Publishers, 8th edition, 1998).

    -------------, Democracy, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007).

    -------------, Where Do Rights Come From?, in Skocpol, Theda, Democracy,Revolutions and History, (New York: Cornell University Press, 1998).

    Weldon, Jeffrey, El crecimiento de los poderes metaconstitucionales de Crdenas y

    vila Camacho. Su desempeo legislativo 1934-1946, Dilogo y Debate deCultura Poltica, 1 (abril-junio), 1997.

    Wilkie, James, The Mexican Revolution: Federal Expenditure and Social Change since1910, (Berkley: University of California Press, 1967).

    Womack, John, Zapata and the Mexican Revolution, (New York: Vintage Books, 1970).

  • 7/30/2019 Tesis Oxford ANM

    53/53

    Womack, John, The Mexican Revolution, in Bethell, Leslie (ed), Mexico sinceIndependence, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).

    Zebada, Emilio, Banqueros y revolucionarios: la soberana financiera de Mxico,

    1914-1929 (Mxico: Fondo de Cultura Econmica and ColMex, 1994).