the consortium standard and patent...

13
Eza-ee Vol. 55, No. 4, Oct. 2004 : The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi' Reiko Aoki and Sadao Nagaoka 1 1. Introduction In this paper we examine the current practices of a patent pool that is part of a consortium standard. A consortium stan- dard is a collaborative venture of firms to promote a new technical standard. It can eventually be adopted by national or inter- national standard setting bodies (a de 1-ure standard) or become the de facto standard after winning the competition with other possible standards. A collaborative approach to standardization has become essential in the information and communi- cation technology areas where speed of innovation and the world wide reach of the technologies have made compatibility and early establishment of a standard critical. Consortium standard is distinguished from a standard sponsored by a single firm in the following two respects. First, it involves multiple firms with different interests. Second, it often adopts open licensing policy through its commitment to standard bodies such as ITU and ISO. Since a majority of the recent standards involve proprietary technologies, patent pools have become an essential feature of consortiums. We look at the two sides of a patent pool : interactions among members and with users of the technology. A list of recent prominent consortiums is provided in Appendix 2. Since such a consortium often involves collaboration among competitors, there is the question of how such collaboration can be designed to avoid becoming an anti- competitive device. The criti respect is whether it is fo plementary patents or not Tirole (2004) for the anal tion rules for a patent po freedom of bypassing the p not effect (Shapiro (2001 socially beneficial to bu tary patents. Recognizing U.S. antitrust authority ha patent pool of essential anticompetitive2}. A patent i standard if the standard is implement without infrin essential patents for a par are always complementary, socially desirable to have th form a pools and be license Bundling essential pat tional dynamic beneficial p dling improves not only c but also the competitive po sortium standard relative controlled by a single firm (2000) for a potentially h disadvantage of uncoordin complements.) Second, the firms is larger when the p dled, since the unbundled p profit maximizing price. T R & D investment will be patents are bundled. In spite of these benefi such collaboration does n occur. An outsider of the emerge, who does not join licenses an essential paten 1

Upload: others

Post on 24-Feb-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

Eza-eeVol. 55, No. 4, Oct. 2004

:

The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'

Reiko Aoki and Sadao Nagaoka

1

1. Introduction

In this paper we examine the currentpractices of a patent pool that is part of a

consortium standard. A consortium stan-dard is a collaborative venture of firms to

promote a new technical standard. It caneventually be adopted by national or inter-

national standard setting bodies (a de 1-ure

standard) or become the de facto standard

after winning the competition with other

possible standards. A collaborativeapproach to standardization has becomeessential in the information and communi-

cation technology areas where speed ofinnovation and the world wide reach of the

technologies have made compatibility andearly establishment of a standard critical.

Consortium standard is distinguished from

a standard sponsored by a single firm in

the following two respects. First, itinvolves multiple firms with differentinterests. Second, it often adopts openlicensing policy through its commitment to

standard bodies such as ITU and ISO.Since a majority of the recent standards

involve proprietary technologies, patentpools have become an essential feature of

consortiums. We look at the two sides of a

patent pool : interactions among membersand with users of the technology. A list of

recent prominent consortiums is providedin Appendix 2.

Since such a consortium often involves

collaboration among competitors, there is

the question of how such collaboration can

be designed to avoid becoming an anti-

competitive device. The critical rule in this

respect is whether it is for combining com-

plementary patents or not (see Lerner and

Tirole (2004) for the analysis of competi-

tion rules for a patent pool, such as thefreedom of bypassing the pool). The Cour-

not effect (Shapiro (2001)) means it is

socially beneficial to bundle complemen-tary patents. Recognizing this fact, theU.S. antitrust authority has stated that a

patent pool of essential patents are notanticompetitive2}. A patent is essential to a

standard if the standard is not possible to

implement without infringing it. Thusessential patents for a particular standard

are always complementary, implying it issocially desirable to have the set of patents

form a pools and be licensed as a bundle.

Bundling essential patents has addi-tional dynamic beneficial properties. Bun-

dling improves not only consumer welfarebut also the competitive position of a con-

sortium standard relative to the standardcontrolled by a single firm. (See Nalebuff

(2000) for a potentially huge competitive

disadvantage of uncoordinated pricing ofcomplements.) Second, the joint profit of

firms is larger when the patents are bun-

dled, since the unbundled prices exceed the

profit maximizing price. Thus return from

R & D investment will be greater whenpatents are bundled.

In spite of these beneficial properties,

such collaboration does not necessarilyoccur. An outsider of the patent pool can

emerge, who does not join in the pool and

licenses an essential patent independently

1

Page 2: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

346 ff esfrom the pool. Although such a licensormay be still subject to the RAND (reason-

able and non-discriminatory) conditions

when it has participated in the standard

development, his Iicensing term is notbound by the licensing policy of the patent

pool. In the worst case, a "submarine"patent may emerge after the adoption ofthe standard. The outsider who suddenlysurfaces can charge whatever the marketbears, causing the hold-up problem in addi-

tion to double marginalization. Anotherpossibility is that a patent pool for a single

standard may split, so that a licensee must

obtain licenses separately from two ormore group of the patentees. In the case of

the DVD patent pool, a firm must obtain at

least two independent licenses, one each

from the 3C group and the 6C group. Such

breakdown of an integrated patent poolnot only raises the total price to be paid by

licensees but also reduces the joint profit

of the patentees.

The question is why we see the emer-gence of an outsider and the split of the

patent pool. In the next two sections we

identify two major sources:free riderproblem and bargaining failure due toheterogenous membership. In Section 4 we focus on how a patentpool interacts with its users. In particular

we examine the effectiveness of RAND aspart of the consortium standard. Standard

setting organizations which are willing to

accommodate standards with non-free pat-

ents require the firms to commit them-selves to licensing under RAND conditions(i. e., licensing under reasonable and non-

discriminatory terms) for members of the

organizations and often for the generalpublic3). However, the economic rationale

of RAND conditions has not been explicit-

ly specified and there are many ambigu-ities on what they mean. We analyzewhether non-discriminatory licensingensures ex-post efficiency and whetherthere are any good grounds for the govern-ment (e.g., competition policy authority)

m eeto control the level of royalty.

2. The Free Rider Problem

First we introduce the basic frame-work. A firm that receives the licenses of

all the patents necessary to implement the

technology for royaltycifor i-th patentwill pay total of2ici,Firm Es optimaloutput qh(Zici) maximizes its profit`).That is, it solves,

max qh (A(qk, q-k) -2ci- 7) ,

qk iwhere 7 is the non-license marginal costand I2le (qk, q-h) is k's inverse demand func-

tion given other firms are producing q-h=(qi,''',qh-i,qh+i,"'qn)5) when there are n

licensees in total. The total demand forlicenses will be,

q(l2i.]ci) == :i]qh(¥. ci).

Because the patents are essential, this is

also the demand for any one of the essen-

tial patents as well as demand for thebundle if the patents are bundled. Weassume that q'<O and q'+cq":{;O. Whenthe patents are priced as a bundle by the

patent pool, demand for the bundle will be

function of the single bundle price coinstead of 2ici.

The incentive to remain an outsider or

split away from a pool can be illustrated

using Figure 1 where co represents thelicense royalty set by a pool and ci theroyalty set by an outsider. The reactioncurve Ro(ci) shows how the pool's profit

(co(q(ci+co)) maximizing royaltychanges as the outsider's royalty changes.

Since q'+ cq"gO, it satisfies the first-order

condition,

q(co+ci)+coq'(co+ci) = O. (1)The reaction curve is negatively slopedsince the patents are complementary. Simi-larly, the reaction curve Ri (co) shows how

the royalty of the outsider changes as the

pool royalty changes. This satisfies

q(ci+co)+ciq'(ci+co) == O. (2)Since all patents (pool's and outsider's)

are essential, two curves are entirely sym-

Page 3: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

/

C,

C'

c'

n

The Consortium Standard

Figure 1. Patent Pool and Outsider

Ro (Ci)

N nl

tl /N

c

jittt

t nl

and Patent

Ri (Co)

c'

metric, irrespective of the relative number

of the patents held by the pool and theoutsider. The intersection is a Nash equi-librium (ci", c6") (Point N in Figure 1.),

which gives the outsider and the pool equalrevenues since ci"= corv. The iso-profit curve

for the outsider at the Nash equilibrium is

denoted ni".

If the outsider joins the pool, the new

pool royalty c* that maximizes pool reve-

nue, cq(c), satisfies the following first-

order condition,

q(c")+c"q'(c*) == O.Equations (1) and (2) implies q(ci"+co")+ (c,"+ co") q'(ci"+ co") == co"q'(ci"+ cSg) < O

from which we have the Cournot effect,

c" < ci"+ co".

We can find the outsider's iso-profit

curve when it becomes a pool member byidentifying the appropriate point on theline co+ci==c". If there are n members(including the outsider) in the pool, the

c*relevant point is C where ci=

outsider's share o

corresponding iso-profitFigure 1 (assumes n2)3).

integration of the outsider,

fall and the joint profit

ever, if the pool's profit is

since the nf pool revenue is -III. The

't' curve ls zl ln As a result of the

royalty would would rise. How- distributed

Co

the standard6).

The incentive to1as identif

problem.

access to

ls, lt ls a

standard

public goodthey are patented

be controlled.

demand forwhich has an essential patent related to the

standardthe other suppliers of the standard technol-

ogies to impose royalty on th

standard techno

a user ofaccess toindirectly through licensing policy of the

pool members. That is, the pool memberscan demand reciprocity in licensing to the

outsider firm. It is important to note that

the DOJ explicitly allows such clause as a

device to support the viability of a patent

pool against outsiders in its businessreview letter. However, such a clause isnot effective at all on those outsiders who

are specialized in licensing with respect to

that standard.

Pools 347 equally among its members, the

profit of the outsider is most likely to fall significantly, espe-

cially when the number of the pool membership is large. (The

point C moves south east along ci + co == c* as n increases).

Thus, notjoining the pool is

profitable as a unilateral con-

duct. The disincentive for join-

ing the pool increases as the

number of complementary pat- ents increases, since the profit

share of a particular member of

the patent pool declines while

what it can collect as an out- sider increases with the value of

icense independentlyied above is due to the free rider

Free rider problem arises whenthe good is not excludable, that

public good. In the case of a specification patent pool, the

is not the technology, since

and access to them can

The public good is the the standard. The outsider

does not need permission from

e users of the logy. If the outsider is also

the standard technology, his the demand can be controlled

l

Page 4: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

348 ff za

3. Heterogenous Membership

In this section we analyze the bargain-

ing failure inherent in patent pools andexplore possible solutions. Coalition for-

mation literature has shown that even with

open membership, the grand coalition may

not form in equilibrium when there isasymmetry among firms (Belleflamme(2002)). We do note that the premises of

his analysis is quite specific (firms are

Cournot competitors and coalitions reducemarginal costs), not applicable to extent

of asymmetry in our analysis. A simulation

analysis by Axelrod et. al (1995) of the

UNIX operating standard also suggestsfragmentation from heterogeneity.Together with the Belleflamme result, we

suspect a similar heterogeneity frompreventing some firms to join the patentpool.

To demonstrate we extend the basicmodel to three types of firms that differ by

vertical structure: insider manufacturingV-firm (vertically integrated firm), out-

sider manufacturing M-firm, and insiderresearch R-firm. Insider means a firm inthe patent pool, which collects specificroyalty c from licensees. The patent pool

has only 2 members, V and R firms, each of

which has an essential patent. There are

two licensees, V and M firms which pro-duce very different products: each firmproduces as a monopolist in respectiveseparate but identical markets. Thisallows us to focus only on significance of

vertical structure of firms'). Using the ini-

tial basic formulation, firm k's inverse

demand is, Rle(qk, q-k) = P(qh),

for any k. When the (total) royalty is c,

M-firm always produces the monopolyoutput when marginal cost is c, denoted qM(c).

Patent Pool and Independent Licensing When there is a patent pool chargingthe bundle price c, V-firm chooses output q

bl ee

to maxlmlze, q+qM(c), (P(q)-c)q+ 2 C・Reorganizing, we get

(P(q)--SL)q+ q"iC) c.

The V-firm produces as if the marginal

cost were -S-. We denote the maximum

profit achieved with q==qv(c) by nv(c).

When V- and M-firms are producingoptimally given c, R-firm's profit is,

- qv(c)+qM(c) 7b? (C)- 2 C・The pool sets royalty to maximize poolrevenue c(qv(c) +qM(c)). This also maxi-

mizes patent R-firm's profit.

When firms license independently,V-firm chooses cv and q simultaneously to

maximize its profit. It is equivalent tomaximizing8) 7rv = (P(qM(CR))-CR)qM(CR)

+qM(cv+cR)cv,and R-firm chooses cR to maximize 7t:R = (qV(CR)+qM(eR+CV))CR.

This is a non-cooperative game where thefirms choose royalty (firm's strategy)

simultaneously.

The following proposition character-izes the relationship between royalty set

by a patent pool and royalties set indepen-

dently.

Proposition 1. IWien c*,nt,zv* are thePatent Pool revenue meximizing rayaltyand Profts, and cAR, c-v, fiR, fiv are equilib-

n'um rQyalties and Profts when R- andVVirms set them independently, then

C* (i) C*<CAR+C-V, CAR>C-V, C-R> 2' (ii) fiR + rr-V< nt + ni fiV< rrV".

The proposition is summarized inFigure 2. (The proof is in Appendix 1.) Bv

and IeR are best-response correspondences

and are downward sloping since the roy-alties are strategic substitutes. R-firm's

response correspondence is steeperbecause its royalty effects outputs of both

Page 5: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

1

I

:

The Consortium Standard and Patent Pools 349M- and V-firms. V-firm only gets revenue

from M-firm. Thus for the same increaseof rival royalty, R-firms reduces its royalty

less. Both firms charge the same royalty,

cm, if it were the sole licensor, equivalent

to O rival royalty9). This implies the Nash

equilibrium (point III) must be under the

45 degree line (cR==cv), i.e., c-R>c-v. In

addition, the sum of the royalties at point

IE exceeds the pool revenue maximizingroyalty, since each firm does not internal-

yze the negative spillover of its own roy-

alty increase on each other (Cournoteffect). This implies c*< c-R+ c-v.

Since R-firm's profit is proportional to

that of the patent pool revenue, the highest

level along 45 degree line is at c" (as

drawn in Figure 2). V-firm's profitdecreases monotonically in total royalty

along the 45 degree line and with rivalroyalty, cR, along its own best-responsecorrespondence. This implies fiv< nv". The

sum of R-firm and V-firms profits is(cR +cv) qM (cR + cv) +P(qv(cR)) qv (cR)

(3)The first term is decreasing in total roy-

alty in the relevant region and thus ishigher with patent pool royalty c*. The

second term is also decreasing in cR. Thus

aggregate profit will be larger with patent

pool royalty c*. R-firm's profit may be

c'

Cm

C'

2

higher or lower by licensing independently.

In Figure 2, R-firm is better-off (as in the

following case of linear demand). But the

equilibrium IE may be on a lower iso-profit line. R-firm always has incentive to

deviate from a patent pool but independent

licensing may make it worse off.

Bargaining Failure We investigate the relationship fur-ther by assuming the product market haslinear demand P(q)==1-q. Profits withpatent pool royalty c are,

rr. (c) = t- 3iC62 , nbe (c) = g(i-ic),

rr(c) - t+g-kc2,

where n(c)=nv(c) +7b? (c). Note that the

V-firm has the same incentive as theM-firm in that it wants c to be as low as

possible. Of course this will not be desir-

able for the R-firm. Although the R-firmwould not like the royalty to be too highsince it reduces demand, it finds its profit

increasing in c when c is small. That is, 7be

(c) is increasing in c for csgg and

decreasing for larger c's.

We can highlight the trade-off bydrawing a curve in (nbe, nv) space by plot-

ting (7be(c), rrv(c)) for OKcSl. We will

Figure 2. Patent Pool and Independent Licensing

Cv 19R . nv

""'''--- ----.."R.Y..

..x i '/ i

"i iP i/ te t1 t1 tP t/ / C'[ / -[ / 2:

it tt

E n'R Bv

Cm c'CR

refer to this as the frontier(Figure 3). The frontier is on

the vertical axis when c=Osince nk(O)=O. Raising royalty

benefits R-firm and hurts theV-firm. However the trade-offis not one to one because theV-firm will adjust output. It is

downward sloping until c={}.

Then it is upward sloping until

the curve ends at (-5H, -il6L) corre-

sponding to c=1. Making roy-alty too high is not good forboth firms.

If the pool sets royalty to

11

Page 6: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

i

350 wa zamaximize revenue, then the royalty should

be c'=-g-. In this case,

rrv* - rrv(g) = t' nt

- nk(g) - t・

.*-n(g)-t・ 'outputs will be -l;- for M-firm and -ii- for

V-firm. This would be most desirable roy-

alty for the R-firm. The frontier is vertical

at this point. (This is point RY in Figures

2 and 3).

If the pool sets royalty to maximizethe joint profit of the V-and R-firms, n(c),

then the royalty is cPF ==-g-. Profits are,

..pF = ..(g) = 12o3s, rfF = lk(g) = it,

npR = z(g) = e/・

This is the point farthest from the originon the frontier. (This is point PF in Figure

3).

If the firms license independently, the

Nash equilibrium royalties are,

- 2 .. 3 Cv= 7T, CR=7・Recall that royalty rates are strategic sub-

stitutes for essential patents. The equilib-

rium profits are,

Figure3. Patent Pool Frontier

c=onv

C=1

PF

RY

SQ

IE

M ee fiv = ?t, jiR = zR}-, fi = t/ < n'*.

The point is marked IE in Figures 2 and 3.

V-firm has lower profit than the R-firm.R-firm is better off than the patent pool.

If R-firm moves first, then it will set

1royalty level cfi=-2-. V-firm chooses cSv--

1T・ Profits are,

7riQ=-iiiltT, rfQ= ;t, rrSQ == JiiltT.

R-firm's profit increases but V-firm Ioses

out. This corresponds to point SQ in Fig-

ure 3.

Both points IE and SQ are outside the

frontier. Independent licensing is moreattractive to the R-firm than a patent pool

while the V-firm always prefers the pool.

We also note that revenue maximizing isnot the best option for the patent pool as a

whole. The aggregate profit is largest when c=cPF. Both simultaneous independent and

R first mover licensing result in smaller

total profit. The total profits are even

lower than with the revenue maximizingroyalty, c*. This means that the V-firmwould be better off if it give what R-firm

would achieve as a first-mover to induceR-firm to join the pool. Because point SQ

is outside the frontier this allocation that ' guarantees R-firm enough to join cannot be achieved by splitting the pool revenue according to patents. It must be achieved in form of a transfer payment.

Discriminatory Licensing Rule The pool frontier is con-

strained by the non- discriminatory licensing rule. Without this constraint, it is pos-

sible to increase joint profit even

more. Specifically, the pool chooses two royalty rates, cM and

cv, cooperatively to maximize n. Jomt profit (3). This is achieved

Page 7: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

The Consortium Standard and Patent Pools 351

with cfi=-li- and cvC=O. The insider (V-

firm) pays zero royalty. The joint profit

achieved is -g-. The Nash Bargaining Set

(feasible set) is,

(g ( 7z:i? , rrv) l z'v + n:R f{:-).

The disagreement point is the independentlicensing point (fiR, fiv). Then the Nash

Bargaining Solution is,

7u9[B-;g2, z.NB-;gi.

This allocation is acceptable to the R-firm.

But can be achieved only by having thepool charge different prices. This is very

attractive to the R-firm but not to theV-firm since rrv"B < rri

Note that c">cRC+cvC. Discriminatory

treatment of R and V firms result in lower

royalty than the revenue maximizing non-

discriminatory royalty payment. Howeverit is higher than the non-discriminatoryprofit maximizing royalty. With discrimi-

natory royalty, V firm pays no royalty.With non-discriminatory royalty, burden is

shifted from M firm to V firm'O).

4. Analysis of RAND Conditions

In this section we explore what theRAND condition achieves, given that thecooperation among firms for a standard is

secured.

We start with the model with threetypes of firms:V, M and R. We nowassume the number of firms of each typeare v, m and r respectively. Both V and M

-firms must obtain a license from the pool

to produce. We denote T-firm's output byqT, price by PT, and profit by zT. Vertical

firm's profit comes from both royalty and

production :

cQ rrv = (Pv-c)qv+ v+r'where Q=vqv+mqM is the total output.M-firm has no royalty revenue : 7Tha = (PM rm C) qM,

while R-firm has only royalty revenue :

cQ 7CR === v+r'We assume the same type of firms behaveidentically.

We consider a two stage game: theroyalty fee c is set by the pool in the first

stage. In the second stage, firms that manu-

facture choose prices (outputs) non-cooperatively. We assume zero manufac-turing cost so that the only cost will be the

Iicense royalty, c. We consider twoextreme cases : when products are perfect

substitutes (homogeneous product) andwhen each firm is a local monopolist. The

first case would correspond to the case

where the firm specific complementaryassets, i.e. assets complementary to the

standard technology such as manufactur-ing know-how, are not important. Thesecond case would correspond to the case

where the standard can support a number

of applications for which each firmdevelops specialized complementaryassetsii>.

Perfect competition in manufacturing Here we assume that there is no verti-cally intetrated firm (v=O) for simplicity.

In this case, Bertrand competition with

homogeneous goods results in marginalcost pricing,

PM = C.Given marginal cost pricing in manufactur-

ing, there is no markup so that there is no

inefficiency due to double marginalization

when a patent pool is successful in bun-

dling all complementary patents. Theprofit of a research firm is given by,

- cQ 7tk ・ rThe pool chooses the royalty rate (c") to

maximize Qc subject to competition withalternative standards. The RAND condi-tions require the pool to apply the rate c"

to all licensees. In the case of Bertrand

competition in manufacturing, this nondis-

criminatory application of the royalty rate

insures the efficient manufacturing. Only a

Page 8: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

352 ff esfirm with the lowest manufacturing costserves the market. It also generates the

maximum profit for R & D. Thus, non-discrimination is feasible and efficient.

Let us go back one step further andconsider the member firm i's R & D invest-

ment decision (lei). We assume that such

investment improves the quality of thestandard. Each firm has the following ex-

ante profit:

max Q(ki, k2, ''', kr) c - fe,.

rUnder the revenue sharing scheme whererevenue is divided equally among mem-bers, each firm can obtain only one r-th of

the increased' licensing revenue from qual-

ity improvement of the standard as result

of investment. Thus such a scheme causes

a large scale underinvestment in R & Dcompared to what is collectively opti-mal'2). The degree of underinvestment will

be very large when the pool membership is

large. This inefficiency obviously handi-

caps the consortium standard relative to a

closed standard sponsored by a single firm.

The only solution is to allocate pool reve-

nue according to contribution to the pool

revenue. Some scheme to evaluate the con-

tribution of each patent must be devised to

address this underinvestment problem.Given such an underinvestment problem,there is no economic ground for a govern-

ment to suppress the royalty rate agreedby the pool'3). Such intervention only exac-

erbates the underinvestment problem.

Local monopoly Assume that each firm serves its ownmarket, i.e., each firm is a monopolist in its

own market. Each firm chooses the profitmaximization price, for a given royalty c.

Thus there is a positive markup for amanufacturing firm and for a manufactur-ing operation of a vertically integrated

firm. Any positive per use charge causesthe problem of double marginalization.

In this case, non-discriminatory licens-

ing does not ensure ex-post manufacturing

blF ee

efficiency. The perceived marginal cost is

lower for an insider vertically integrated

firm than the outsider manufacturing firm,

since it perceives the gain from outputexpansion both from its sales of output and

through royalty income :

gqrrV. = oZ. (P (qv) qv) -(1- ,t . )c・

Thus, the non-discriminatory applicationof royalty in fact does not insure the effi-

cient entry in manufacturing. However, the

advantage of being an insider becomessmaller as the number of the members ofthe patent pool increases. In the case where

a number of firms supplying technologiesto a patent pool is large, this effect can be

negligible.

Let us look at the determination of the

level of royalty. As analyzed in Section 3,

three types of firms have different interests

regarding the level of royalty, c. Sinceprice is chosen optimally for each c, by the

Envelope Theorem, we have, 1 0(Qc) arr. a. =-qV+v+r oc ' We can make several observations.First the outsider manufacturing firmwants the minimal price, since the second

term does not exist. The insider research

firm wants a higher price, since there is no

first term. The vertically integrated firm is

in the middle ground. It wants to balance

its production profit and royalty revenue.

The outcome would mainly depend on thenegotiations between insider manufactur-

ing firms, and insider research firms, as

well as on competition with the other stan-

dards.

Secondly, higher royalty increasesreward to R & D but exacerbates theproblem of double marginalization. Thezero price for technology is the most effi-

cient price ex-post but it gives no return on

R & D by research firms. Thus, there is a

clear trade-off between ex-post efficiency

and ex-ante incentive. Given the dilution

problem of R & D incentive identifiedabove, there seems to be no good ground

Page 9: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

l

The Consortium Standard and Patent Pools 353for a government to suppress the royalty

even though it is high due to double mar-

ginalization. The solution to the tradeoff

cannot come from the government inter-vention in pricing. Instead, a lump-sumpayment to the insider research firm mayalleviate the above inefficiency. Buy-out of

the IPR of the research firms would be an

alternative, although such financingscheme may not be easily available for atechnology coalition.

While we discussed the effect on man-

ufacturing efficiency of non-discri-minatory licensing policy, we have notdiscussed why this might be beneficial in

the context of dynamic competition. Car-lton and Gertner (2003) have argued that

one advantage of an open source system to

a proprietary system is that it makes it

possible for anyone to make improve-ments. The system is able to improve orpermutate according to needs more easily.

Although a consortium standard dependson patented technology, its commitment to

give access to anyone who requires at a"reasonable" price allows outsiders toimprove the technology as with the open

system.

5. Conclusion

We have identified two possible obsta-

cles to a successful implementation patent

pools : free riding and bargaining failure.

Once the standard has been established, it

is not possible to exclude a firm with an

essential patent from accessing thedemand for the standard (i.e. collecting

royalty from the users of the patent).Patents can only be used to control access

to the technologies implementing the stan-

dard. We have also shown that the non-cooperative outcomes of licensing are not

achievable by transfer of rents by perpatent split. This is because the royaltyalone cannot both increase patent revenue

and allocate rents among heterogeneousmembers at the same time. Thus, while it is

easy to argue why a patent pool bundling

complementary patents are socially desir-able, the reality is that patent pools can be

difficult to organize and to maintain.

Our results suggest that both theRAND licensing scheme and the way toallocate rents among pool members needto be changed to accommodate the hetero-

geneous membership. The heterogeneity of

membership makes the "reasonable" roy-alty policy more difficult to implement.This is because the relationship between

royalty rate and revenue differs betweenresearch firms that only have patent reve-

nue and vertically integrated firms that

also have production profit as well aspatent revenue. One might think that char-

ging sufficiently high royalty will transfer

production profit from vertical firms toresearch firms in addition. Unfortunately

this transfer also reduces the size of the

total pool revenue by compounding theharm of double-marginalization. Thus it is

impossible to transfer enough revenue tomake it profitable for a research firm to

join a pool instead licensing independently.

This result suggests that there should be

extra distribution to research firms tocompensate for the lack of productionprofits. Requiring all members of the pool

to be treated equally could be a source of

patent pool's failure.

The system of allocating pool rentsaccording to patent numbers is also detri-

mental to innovation. Firms may signifi-cantly underinvest in quality of the stan-

dard since it is unable to obtain appropri-

ate return on its R & D investment. Im-proving the dynamic incentive of the con-

sortium standard will be important, since

it may have to compete with a ciosedproprietary standard, which may have ahandicap in innovation but has an clearadvantage in appropriation.

Finally let us turn to policy issues.Although it is very important for a compe-

tition authority to deter the formation of a

pools which are anticompetitive, it would

be detrimental to competition and innova-

Page 10: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

1

354 me estion for a government to condition theapproval of the pool on low royalty rate.

Once the pool is judged to be a bundle of

complementary patents, it should be free to

set the royalty rate. On the other hand, a

government intervention may be warrant-ed to prevent the free riding on the pool by

an outsider which surfaces after the stan-

dard is set.

(The Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, and Department of Economics, University of Auckland /Institute of Innovation Research, Hitotsubashi University)

Appendix 1 : Proof of Proposition 1

Propotition 1. waen c*, nt, zv* are thePatent Pool revenue maximizing mpally andProfts, and c-R, cA- frR, jiv are equilibrium

mpalties and Pwfits when R- and Vtfirms set

them indePencienteL then

c* (i) C"< C-R+ C- V, C'SR> C- V, CAR> 2 ,

(ii) fiR + fiv< nt + nv*, itv< fi v*.

Let the inverse demand be P(q). Wedenote by qm(7) the monopoly profit whenmarginal cost is 7. That is, it is the solution

to the first-order condition,

max (P (q) - 7) q・ qWe denote by cm, the royalty rate that maxi-

mizes revenue 7'qm(7). We assume that thesecond-order condition,

2cqin(c)+qh'(c)gO, (4)so that it satisfies, the first-order condition,

q.(cm)+cmqh(cm) = O. (5) The profits of R- and V-firms when theyconstitute the patent pool are,

7u? (c) - -S-(qm(c) +qm(-S')),

rrv (c) - -S-qm(c) +(P(qm('S')--S)qm(mS-)・

Royalty c* maximizes pool revenue and sat-isfies,

c'(qh(c') +tqh( C2" ))+qm (c")

+q.( C2*)-O. (6)Claim 1.

cm<c*<2cm.Proof. It follows from (5) and (6). Z The profits when the two firms set roy-

- eealties independently are,

ztf(cR, cv) = cR (qm(cR +cv) +qm(cR)),

n"(cR, cv) = cvqm(cv+cR)+(P(qm(cR))-cR) qnt(cR).

Denote by BR(cv) and Bv(cR) the best-response correspondences when firms setroyalties independently. They are solutions to

the two first-order conditions

07i)6 == cR(qh(cR+cv)+qh(cR)) 0CR +qm(cR+cv)+qm(cR) == O, (7) orre = cvqh(cR +cv) +qm(cR +cv) = O. OcvClaim 2.

-1<Bk(c,)<O, -1</3e(c.)<O.Proof.

027uS = qh(cR + cv) + cRqm(cR + cv) KO, 0CVOCR 02ntf = cRqh' (cR + cv) +2qh(cR +cv) Ocft

+cRqh'(cR)+2+2qh(cR)<O. The inequalities follow from (4). Since

Bk=-oc02,o7rfc.1Oo2c7i.f2,

and qh(cR +cv) <O, so that the ratio must be

greater than -1. D CIaim 3. Bv (O) == cm, BR (O) = cm. Proof. Substituting cR =cnt and cv=O into (7)

yields

2qm (cm) + cm2qh(cm) . This is zero from (5) implying BR(O)=cm.

Similarly for Bv. D CIaim 4. (i)cR=BR(cv) intersects the line cR

+cv=c' below the line cR=cv (45 dagree line).

(ii) cv=Bv(cR) intersects the line cR==cv

c* above cR=Cv= 2・

(iii) inte7section of cR==BR(cv) and the line cR =cv is northeast (higher along the 45

degree line) of intersection of cv=Bv(cR)

and the line cR=cv. Proof. We first show 66caj lc.-c.-s' = c"qin(c")+ C2' qh( C2' )qm(c*)

+q.( C2' )- C2* qh(c") - - C2' qh(c*) >O.

The last inequality follows from (6). This implies part (i).

Denote the intersection of cR=:19R(cv) and line cR+cv=c* by (c-R, c*- c-R). Since

this is on BR,

Page 11: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

The Consortium Standard and Patent Pools

22 7r;S( c-R, c- v) + na c-R, cA v)

= ( cAR+ c- v) qm( c-R+ c- v)

+P(qm ( cAR) ) q. ( cAR) .

Since c"< cm, the first term is an increasing

function on the interval (c-R+ cAv, c*). The

second term is a decreasing function and c-R

c*>

qm (c*) + c'Rqfu (c") + c-Rqh( c-R) +q. ( c-R)

- o.Since c-R< cm, the sum of the last two termsis positive from(5). The sum of the first two

terms must be negative and we have

4m(C") C-R < - qh(c*) '

c*Since < c"R, we have 2 oacrr.Vi 1,.=..=s* = q.(c*) + C2* qh(c*) >o.

This implies part (ii).

Suppose cR=BR(cv) intersects line cR=cv at cR=cv=z. It must satisfy (7) :

qm (2z) +zqh(2z) +qm (z) +zqh(z) = O.

The sum of last two terms must be positivesince z< cm. Thus we have one lc.-c.-z=qm (2z) +zqh(2z) <O. 0cv

This shows part (iii). D The proceeding claims are summarizedin Figure 2. The part (i) of the proposition

follows : Nash Equilibrium lies below the 45

c*degree line, it is above the line cR+cv= 2,and to the left of the point RY. To show part (ii) of the proposition, we

first calculate the total of the firm profits:

z)? (c*) + nv (c*) = c*qm (c*)

+P(qm( C* ))q.( C* ),

2c- v) + 7ve( c-R

ity of

To

note

. This implies 7o? (c') + zv (c') > zi5( cAR,

, cAv). This implies first inequal-

proposition's part (ii) .

show the second inequality, first wethat n<-S-, -S-) is decreasing in c:

orr(s・g)

0c

= 7}(q

This implies

c== cv =-2- (45

h

7Z'f(CR, Cv)

degree line)

(C) C+ q. (c) -q.( C

at the intersection of 45 line and B

7

is decreasing along cR

.So profit is lower

v than at cR

))<o.

355

C*=cv= 2.Since ne(cR,cv) is decreasing in

cR along Bv, profit is lower at iE than at the

intersection. Thus we have the second in-equality.

Notes 1) We are indebted to comments from Yoshi-hito Yasaki, Akira Okada and other participants of

"IT Innovation Workshop," Hitotsubashi Univer-

sity, March 2004, and Institute of EconomicResearch Seminar as well as research assistance of

Naotoshi Tsukada. 2) See Klein (1997) for the recent articulation

of the policy of the US antitrust authority towardpatent pools. See Gilber (2002) and Priest (1977)

for a historical overview of the U. S. policy toward

patent pools.

3) There is an example of a standard bodywhich maintains free IPR policy such as W3C. SeeLemley (2002) for a comprehensive review of licen-

sing policies of standard bodies.

4) For instance, if the product market is a Cournot

duopoly with linear demand 1-Q, Q, total output,

then qh(Zici+r)=(1-Zici-2r+r')/3 where 7and 7' are this firm and rival's respective firmspecific non-license marginal costs.

5) We write Rle(qk, q-k) for generality, includ-

ing heterogenous goods. If firms producedhomogenous goods, then q-h=2."-=i"-.k qJ.

6) The above analysis assumed the Nash equi-librium of simultaneous pricing by the pool and the

outsider. It is possible that the outsider moves first

in price setting, since there is a first mover advan-

tage. This is explored in Section 3.

7) There is no market interaction between M

and V firms: V-firm has no incentive to raiseroyalty to raise rival's cost. See end of this section

for details.

8) V-firm's royalty revenue comes only fromthe M-firm and does not include own output. SoV-firm chooses output equal to the monopoly out-put when marginal cost is cR, i. eo, qM(cR) and not

qv(cR).

9) Exact definition is in the proof.

10) Of course these trade-offs will differ when

there is downstrearn market interaction. For adiscussion of downstream oligopoly, see ?

11) Rernarks regarding the case of downstream

oligopoly at end of previous section would applyhere also.

12) The benchmark is the investment when thestandard is controlled by a single firm. Such firm

may overinvest or underinvest in the quality of the

standard, depending on the relationship betweenthe valuation of a marginal consu;ner and that of a

average consumer. 13) Note that any dynamic concern of pricing,

such as penetration pricing for promoting the diffu-

'

Page 12: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

究研済経356

で」邸」」①OO一口哨①門請口ΦOh戸口O」}」①↑口①日タ㊤姻〉㊤餌hハ∪〔【…⑰①①H^〇一㊤口づh“のO己ロ邸餌.出切㊤」邸QO一口嘱㊤【){一㊤Oh【口O」申』Φ細90日≧㊤哨〉㊤餌h{∪〔[…ミ09.ミ留§.ミミミ\\、§べ

        .oQ①①一 、㊤一」①4日①りΦ〔【トあ①自①①納田,国

ミ09.稔寒暑魅薯.ミミミ\\、零雨べ …(NOON)螂ρ邸bo邸7[一8旨。の

.【OOα①[【りOり唱①り5ρ唄旨U口Oり

ωり口㊤り邸q }O ①旨邸』の ①幽一 口O ので口①自㊤で

の㊤コ一邸あO旨 }O  口Oお邸りO=“  ①』臼、.N

(①[ρ邸一刷邸〉邸の刷り口①己口①O」bゆ邸[邸」①ヨ邸【

.の已h①り①【ρ邸ΦΦhbの邸

-馴ρ邸Φθ戸田ObρΦ口Oり口O似島OΦ』一、」①〉①≧・O】田)訳一.Oの刷一口①

』=邸口祠コ8‘U刷汐銚一日口①壷口①q①で口璃①の口①り哨【

ロワ

mqh咽申h①ρ口h①己[【㊤‘U申O-一邸q【邸嘱θ口①のω㊤唱Φ娼哨幹旨Φりh㊤qΦり邸餌あり【邸あO出湯h邸口口二日の.σq

(の

?@』5一り邸}コロ邸d口

(旧も昌

(三8ho申憲国

で口邸 のの邸Ω-眺ρ 〇一 ①[ρ邸 の」Oρ【口㊤芝 .H

ωり口㊤θ邸自 【邸眉口①のりり① ㊤調一 =<

.訳頃。励哨あ出戸あO餌①〉写邸【コ日コ9門ロコ日哨×邸芝,一

一一 .ω旨O田圃旨㊤αO QO)ω8」唱 O円一口①閉山 O。う

O。う

.ω門口」㊤制あ」O刊邸口一日【」りω刷で

-口O震  ℃¢邸  ①【ρ邸自Oの邸①」  .h旧邸旧  口〇  一口O日邸α  [邸5

-儲①のの①あ蝦邸溜り邸ρ9口邸」b心〇一Φ①の口Φり=」O一口O刷り邸bの哨一ρO口く.可

①の5邸{りω¢O【判邸口・でOhO>邸舶,紹のO[q< ,Oう

(」

@唱Oり㊤℃」O」㊤あ邸【α

,【OOO㊤幽剃〇一で㊤一コρ刷h一口Oり

」①OOO.寸鵠}O口出口口O」【口5已哨口姻d自邸」冨哨≧^の』㊤唱Oり①唱Q>∩

oり

鼬竫@θ邸α 舶O ①h邸幽ω ㊤調一 口O uワで口①q①で

唱口邸の」㊤』邸【α∩〉∩廟O①O顎qの①【邸ω醤㊤q①幽一}O訳寸唱口邸⇔の唱∩

口邸q邸h}Oあ口邸q日OQ

の㊤嘱一一『5眺O」  }O  員O唄り邸りO=邸  ①ぶ」U .N

〔【

r∩h①ロゆトO.輪}Oの①凋【邸あOh)あ出邸訊O」Oθ一口①門口認門口日09.N

」OUり嘱〉 い邸β哨』o噛O]「 冒㊤口」邸>P

,⇒一8℃

ω一口①日戸α[邸田口①のの①

.」Φり}帽Φ」①』一go己[属①一のh邸Φ眺-頃』O廟眺訓[邸り旧邸日Oり5邸

ωご日唄』ギ  巨り嘱」一り㊤一ハ円  哨素の哨ρ5の

QD@①H

・口①Ω㊤℃口璃 ①の口Oり馴 口肖り の日」唄旧 ‘り自国 ,H

①」コ一口}で¢邸一¢ΦのΦ旨q①‘醤一【<

津①口Φ」 で旧邸 卜OON .一6う .りΦ∩【[冨ロコロ5旨 ωりり邸」り口OQ①‘」『 .一

-細別芝帆邸り嘱幽の口のθσさ芝.嘱目り邸り回国

邸ρヨ。。o↑

.(O㊤)∩〉∩

.の【口」ΦU眺」OUO口哨d口哨」りの哨唱

-口O口  で口邸  ①一〇邸口Oの邸①」  、』嘱邸}  口O  日口①一邸α  H5コ冨

-口Φのの①あ口邸図Q邸ρ-り口σ」」bρ〇一Φ①の口ΦQ=」O戸口O娼邸bo=ρO自く。寸

,①のコ邸【り oり口O唄一一℃口Oり ①一ρ邸旨O>邸}り。励Od日 ♂N ,σつ

,【OOq㊤謂一〇幹勺㊤幹5ρ哨」刊口Oり

のり口①り邸qH邸娼口①のωΦ①」ロリ5山

(.

・【OのQの哨唱hΦαゆO,紛で口邸OOON.円

の一口①一邸α旧O」㊤ρd日コロ①謂一旧O口O霜りロコ}邸

.のりの哨で ㊤調細舶O.㊤旨「当り邸}

,自邸『嗣Oの邸鴎紛OθのqO」唱二り哨』㌧臣、細哨ロコ旨Oq卜紛申O①①駒d日コd[【

90口の嘱のΦ唱[邸眺O」申O口O唱邸りO=邸Φ』「[,Nーコロ邸日Φ‘幹』O申の一口①一邸αゆ⑦

-哨口胃口出Oθ一りΦ嶋ρ5の.℃[Oの』①眺邸【q調り邸①』O}①り=αb心口嘱=ωの

.訟琶①で

.の」㊤あ邸一Ω 〔【〉{H }O ㊤旨コUQ邸}

り㊤口①』幹}O訳蛉,oつ旧Oの㊤冨【邸あO」)あ出邸あOhO一一口ω日り嘱【口門口OQ,N

。Q

@曾

一二①α①で口嘱①の口㊤り嘱一 口口り の己口」媒 幽り同国 .H

-5口邸旨①調9』O}ωり口①一邸αめ一一

.の」邸㊤匪OHの旧[口」㊤日一りσコ旨一口Oり①‘配[,円

」①㊤口O帽自帆病目Oの.のα=哨ぶ山

の身蜜山

、(Q。。)∩〉∩

.司のOり 一邸口O咽り一でで邸 O口 一邸

でΦでで邸①ρ自邸8のり口①り邸α【邸お蝦①のの①で口邸の」Oω口①Q哨一き①7【.寸

,(訳のN

口置調の①」OF口あρ㊤ω邸㊤」り口唄O二一〇口)の㊤一邸h℃口気の門口」①一眺出邸嵩O」

廟Oり口Φd日で口㊤d[[邸①【ρ邸自Oの邸①hO一剃り①「ρコの麟θ口①り邸山O嵩O廟り」O山

り口㊤り邸山NIO国色芝園口邸申OΦ}=①幽り」O申の唱O哨」Φ口」邸①眺-㊤〉娼

㊤〉刷のの①QリコのhO鴇き㊤口㊤」 Oり↓』bの哨h ①』日㊤〉邸幽のΦ㊤の口①り刷日 ,6う

.り日国(.cqOON、一,自邸hロ一〇」噛O頃.N輪℃自邸、NOON.H.口邸hOり」O嘱」α

幽り刷[【≧ }O ‘口O胡四) あΦお嘱【囲』邸α邸り bρ口嘱唱Oり㊤唱 で口鳴 bり口唱唱Oり

.一〇〇q㊤二細Oりで㊤日5ρ唄hの口Oり

-貿㊤頼りOρb心口馴〉σ5調のりリコでOh山旨㊤【口5の口OQOりのΦ=q口邸一嘱唱5.〉姻口5一.ωd口」頃㎝㎝詞一【口①」

のθ口Φり邸O }O Φ」邸』の ①函幹 口O ので口①OΦで

旨①q㊤紛の⇒}O眺望邸あOh<,制刷口5①でOQ①唱調9σさΦhO}OO,寸紛

-」コリ …㊤刊邸O哨9冨」邸α口口りり蝦㊤

ω㊤冨一〇コあO旨 胴O .口O冨邸QO=邸  ①』↑ ,N

のh阿の一刀出邸あO」①』り.ωθリコ唱O」畠b◎口回℃Oり①でeqlO治山芝」O国,N

山σ5q【邸覧自①のの㊤口邸の邸刷り邸宅り

.⇒据①で

,O寸㊤hΦ>Oあ=口Φ」』二り

.の旨旨出2僑d日」娼  匿口邸  で目ぐ、…白石の」①〉

卜8H

-口㊤α①田口唄㊤の口①り呂 口苅り の目」娼 』り質実 .一

…ω一口ωり邸α  卜㎝ あ=邸口哨bの哨」()

唱¢邸 ゆ一 〇り申【邸』口唱口即さO円 d口O」}の哨 ⊂[【」の一りり邸」り口OQ①』〔[ .一

-哨ロコ一^の日」占冠。うHあ=邸口嘱ごの馴」○

<日O国』≧

、N O国璽薯

.oセ一』Φ60

の琶9邸山

』り=O山bの口刷の口①O哨日

田①ρ目Φ】≧

.口一日でく

詰①詞σ日・5Z

oロ一〇〇畠陶↓口①●酪∩ で』鳴唱目539q懸り目①り①一嗣 ”N×哨で昌①自q<

Page 13: The Consortium Standard and Patent Poolsi'hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/20102/1/kei... · ing failure inherent in patent pools and explore possible solutions. Coalition

1

The Consortium Standard and Patent

sion of a standard, can be internalized by a patent

pool.

14) The licensing of certified essential patents

will be undertaken by separate licensing companies

("Platform Companies") which are specific to a

particular radio access technology e. g. W-CDMA,

cdma2000, TD-CDMA, etc. The members of thePlatform Companies are the owners of certifiedessential patents,

15) The Platform Company for the 3G systems

based on the W-CDMA technology was formed inSeptember 2003 (PlatformWCDMA Limited or"PlatformWCDMA"). PlatformWCDMA willoffer licenses under the W-CDMA Patent Licensing

Programme which was launched officially on the 24

March 2004. The W-CDMA Patent Licensing Pro-gramme became effective 1 January 2004.

References

ft ma fi ce (2OO2) FNg}Meeue fx- cJ) ii):¥manJt]J : .{7F- tz

s ・ 7o-7vaffzae?] rmuwak*s eg 3s gee 3e, pp. 43-48.

Aoki, Reiko and Sadao Nagaoka (2004) "The Consortium Standard and Patent Pools," PIE Discussion Paper Series, 222, Institute of Eco-

nomic Research, Hitotsubashi University.

Axelrod, Robert, Will Mitchel, Robert E. Thomas D. Scett Bennet and Erhard Bruderer (1995) "Coalition Formation in Standard-setting Alli-

ances," Management Science, Vol.41, No. 9, pp.

1493-1508.

Belleflamme Paul (2002) "Stable Coalition Struc-

tures with Open Membership and Asymmetric Firms," (inmes and Economic Behavior, Vol.30,

Pools 357 No. 1, pp. I-21.

Carlten Dennis W. and Robert H. Gertner (2003)

innovation ]Floliay and the Econonay, volume 3,

Chapter Intellectual Property, Antitrust, and Strategic Behavior, National Bureau of Eco- nomic Research, MIT Press.Gilbert Richard (2002) "Antitrust for Patent Pools :

A Century of Evolution," Stanford 7'lachnolagy

Law Review, forthcoming.Klein Joel I. (1997) "Cross-licensing and Antitrust

Law," Address before the America Intellectual Property Law Association.Lemley Mark A. (2002) "Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations," Calij?)nia Law Review, Vol.90, No.6, pp.1889- 1980.

Lerner Joshua and Jean Tirole (2004) "Efficient

Patent Pools," Amen'can Econmic Review, Vol, 94, pp. 691-711.

Nagaoka Sadao (2004) "Policy Issues in Efficient

Collaboration through a Patent Pool," Hitotsuba-

shi University. 'Nalebuff Barry (2000) "Competing Against Bun-

dles," Yale School of Management Working Paper, No. ES-02.Priest George (1977) "Cartels and Patent License

Arrangements," lburnal of Law and Etonomies, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 302-37Z

Shapiro Carl (2001) "Navigating the Patent Thicket:Cross License, Patent Pools and Standard-Setting," in innovation R)liay and the

Etonomp, edited by Adam Jaffe, Joshua Lerner, and Scott Stern, MIT Press.

/

1

/

1