tilburg university political trade-off between growth and

32
Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and government consumption van der Ploeg, F.; van de Klundert, T.C.M.J. Publication date: 1991 Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal Citation for published version (APA): van der Ploeg, F., & van de Klundert, T. C. M. J. (1991). Political trade-off between growth and government consumption. (CentER Discussion Paper; Vol. 1991-11). Unknown Publisher. General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain • You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal Take down policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim. Download date: 16. Apr. 2022

Upload: others

Post on 16-Apr-2022

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

Tilburg University

Political trade-off between growth and government consumption

van der Ploeg, F.; van de Klundert, T.C.M.J.

Publication date:1991

Link to publication in Tilburg University Research Portal

Citation for published version (APA):van der Ploeg, F., & van de Klundert, T. C. M. J. (1991). Political trade-off between growth and governmentconsumption. (CentER Discussion Paper; Vol. 1991-11). Unknown Publisher.

General rightsCopyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright ownersand it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights.

• Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research. • You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain • You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal

Take down policyIf you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediatelyand investigate your claim.

Download date: 16. Apr. 2022

Page 2: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

CBM ~ ~ ~~- lscusslonR for a er

8414 --~c Research1991

11 iiu ii iiui iuiu uum i uo i iii i i iiui m u ii

Page 3: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

No. 9111

POLITICAL TRADE-OFF BETWEEN GROWTHAND GOVERNMENT CONSUNIPTION

Uy P1'CUCL'1C:K Vdll UCL' I'llJC~j

and Theo van de Klundert

March 1991

1SSN o924-~815

Page 4: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

POLITICAL TRADE-OFF BETWEEN GROWTH

AND GOVERNMENT CONSUMPTION

Frederick van der Ploeg Theo van de Klundert 't

January,1991

CentER, Tilburg University

Abstract

1'he eriects of ahort-sigbted poiiiiciana on ecuuu,uic g,~rw:1, en~

private conaumption are considered from the perspective oC the new

theories ot endogenous growth. Government conaumption crowda out

private consumptíon and reduces growth, but yields direct utility. Pro-

ductive government spending raiaea the marginal productivity of pri-

vate capital and thua raises growth. Politicians are faced with a prob-

ability of being removed from office which increases their rate of time

preference. Thia biases government apending in favour of consump-

tion and lowera economic growth. The paper also providea counter-

examplea to the claim that maximising growth is equivalent to max-

imiaing social welfare and ahowa that when congestion is important the

optimal rate of gtowth is leas.

'The suthote are gratefnl to Anton Mazkink for help with the numerical calculationa.

tMailing addtess: F. van der Ploeg, CentER, Tilburg Univeraity, P.O. Box 90153, 5000

LE Tilburg, The Netherlanda.

Page 5: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

Keywords: endogenous growth, government consumption, short-sightedpoliticiansJEL classiflcation: 110, 320

Contents

1 Introduction 1

2 Endogenous growth and productive government spending 3

3 Maximal growth is not necessarily efiicient 8

4 1~ade-off between government consumption and productivegovernment apending 10

5 Short-sighted politicians favour government consumption andreduce growth 14

8 Rival, excludable public goods 15

7 Conclusion 17

References 18

Page 6: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

1

1 Introduction

Governments in a number of industtial countries have been for some yearsunder pressure to lower the tax burden and to reduce the budget deficit.The only way to achieve both goals is to cut government spending. Ofcourse, politicians find this very hard to do and consequently try to cutitems o[ spending with a low political value. In practice, this means thatpoliticians find it much cheaper from an electoral point of view to cut gov-ernment investment than to cut government coneumption. For governmentconaumption there always is a very vocal constituency or lobby group whichis able to fight and resist cuts in expenditure. The fruits oí governmentinvestment do not occur until some time has passed and politicians are typi-cally to impatient to wait for that, being mostly interested in quick boosts toelectoral popularity. Politicians are typically short-sighted, especially whenthe probability of being removed from office is high. In view of the newtheories of endogenous growth, the objective of this paper is to show thatthe behaviour of short-sighted politicians promotes government consumptionand damages government investment and thus reduces the growth rate ofthe economy. This suggests that the political economy of budget cuts whichare under way in many oí the industrial economies jeopardises growth andweiiare. r,mpiricai evidence for such a pessimisiic view is given in Tauzi auuLutz (1990).

In order to have an interesting analysis of the political trade-off betweengovernment consumption on the one hand and government investment andgrowth on the other hand, it is essential to have at least four ingredients.First, taxes must be distortionary so that there is a sound economic rea-son to reduce the tax burden as far as is optimal. Second, the marginalproductivity of private capital and the economic growth rate must be en-dogenous and depend among other things on the national income share ofgovernment investment or productive government spending. Third, govern-ment consumption must yield direct utility tor otherwise it is impossible tohave an optimal trade-off with private consumption and government invest-ment. Fourth, the political discount rate may be higher than the social orprivate rate of time preference as politicians face uncertainty about electionoutcomes and thus have a shorter time horizon than households.

The new theories of endogenous growth abandon the assumption of di-minishing returns to capital and, instead, assume constant returns to scalewith respect to a broad measure of the capital stock (Romer, 1986, 1989;Lucas, 1988; Barro, 1990). This broad measure of the capital stock thus in-

Page 7: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

z

cludes the own capital stock, the capital stock of other firms and the stock ofgovernment capital. Such a meaaure allows for production externalities aris-ing fmm apill-overa of knowledge and ideas and for the efCect of productivegovernment spending on social infrastructure on the marginal productivityof private capital and growth. Consumers maximise life-time utility. Thegovernment has to make a trade-oR between a low tax rate, which reduceadistortions, and a high tax rate, which permits a larger national incomeshare of productive government spending and thua higher growth. In such aworld there are no transitional dynamics and maximising the growth rate ofthe economy is, as long as production functions are of the Cobb-Douglas va-riety, efficient in the sense that this corresponds to maximising social welfare(Barro, 1990; Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1990). However, if consumers alsovalue a high national income share of government consumption, maximisingthe growtL rate of the economy is no longer equivalent to maximising socialwelfare. The reason is that there is a second trade-off to be made, becausea higher shue of government consumption reduces prospects for growth un-der distortionary taxation. Since a government discount rate which is higherthan the household discount rate reduces growth, it can be shown that short-sighted politicians tend to jeopardise productive government spending onsocial infrastructure and thus growth in favour of government consumption.

Section 2 ptesents a aimple model of endogenous growth, social iniras-tructure and diatortionary taxation. Section 3 is based on Bazro (1990)and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1990) and shows that maximising growth isequivalent to maximising social welfare in a model with a Cobb-Douglas pro-duction function relating private output to private capital accumulation andproductive government epending on social infrastructure. However, for moregeneral production functions there is a trade-off between maximising growthand maximising the current level of private consumption so that maximis-ing growth is not neceasarily efficient. This point is demonstrated by somenumerical calculationa, which aze designed to illustrate the sensitivity of theresults with respect to the elasticity of substitution between private capi-tal and productive govetnment spending. Section 4 introduces outlays ongovernment consumption of rival, non-excludable public goods and showsthat, in general, maximising growth is not equivalent to maximising so-cial welfare, even when attention is restricted to Cobb-Douglas productionfunctions. Section 5 introduces short-sighted politicians with a higher dis-count rate than the one used by households and shows that this crowdsout productive government spending in favour of government consumptionand consequently reduces growth prospects. Section 6 briefly examines the

Page 8: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

3

various outcomes when the government consumee rival, excludable publicgoods. The main difference is that, tor a given national income ahaze ofgovernment consumption, the optimal national income share of governmentconsumption is lower and the ehare of productive government epending ishigher than with rival, non-excludable public goods. In fact, when publicgoods are rival and excludable, consumption of private and public goods canbe treated as a composite commodity so that the optimal national incomeshare of productive government spending equala the elasticity of output withrespect to productive government spending. Conversely, when congestion ef-fecte are important, the optimal share of productive government spendingand rate of growth are lower.

Section 7 concludes with a summary of results.

2 Endogenous growth and productive government

spending

Preferences of the representative household are characterised by an intertem-poral utility function of the form ~

U - J ~ exp(-pt)u(C(t))dt,0

(I)

where C denotes private consumption and p denotes the households' purerate of time preference. The instantaneous utility function has a constantelasticity of intertemporal substitution, o- -u'~Cu", that is u(C) -Ct-é ~(1- ó), o~ 1 or u(C) - log(C), o- 1. The representative householdmaximises ( 1) subject to its budget identity

Á(t) - r(t)A(t) ~ D(t) - C(t), ~lm exp[- Iv r(v')dv7A(v) - 0 (2)

where A and D denote wcalLh of and dividends received by households, and

~In Section 4 óoueehold utility also depende on the uational income ehare of government

coneumption. 1[ thie shsre entere the utility (unction in a eeparable [sehion, houeehold

behaviour ie unaffected.

Page 9: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

4

r denotes the market tate of interest, respectively. All labour income is fullydiversified, so private wealth (A) includes human capital. Dividends areexempt from taxation; instead firms are taxed. This yields

C(t)~C(t) - o[r(t) - p] (3)

so that households save and postpone consumption when the market rateof interest exceeds the pure rate of time preference, and more so when theelasticity of intertemporal substitution is high. The preaent-value budgetconstraint of the representative household then gives,for a constantinterestrate 2, the consumption function:

C(t) - [ap -4- (1 - o)r][A(t) ~ ~~ exp(-r(v - t))D(v)dv] (4)t

Private consumption is a constant proportion of non-human wealth plus thepresent value of future dividends. This proportion increases with the purerate of time preference.

Technology is characterised by a Cobb-Douglas production with constantreturns to scale with respect to ttte private capital stock, K, and the levelof productive government spending on infrastructure, S:

Y-(BK)aSr-tr, B 1 0, 0 G a G 1 (5)

where Y denotes output and B denotes the exogenous efficiency of privatecapital. One might expect the stock of productive government capital ratherthan the 8ow of productive government spending to affect private produc-tion, but this effect has been left out for analytical convenience. Firmsmaximise under perfect competition the present value of net aíter-tax rev-enues, so that the after-tax marginal productivity of capital must equal theuser cost of capital (i.e. the rental charge plus the depreciation charge):

,-a(1-r)aB~y~ a -r~6 (6)

'Later on it ~.ill become dear that in this model the intereet rate ie indeed conatant.

Page 10: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

5

where b denotes the depreciation rate of the capital stock. For simplicity,production externalities such as spill-overs of knowledge and learning bydoing are not considered. Firms make ptofits, becauae they obtain a returnon productive government spending for which they do not have to pay.These profita are handed back to householda, so that dividends are givenbyD-(1-r)Y-(rth)K.

The government levies distortionary taxes on income to finance spendingon public consumption, G, and on productive government spending:

GfS-rY. (7)

There is no government debt, so equilibrium in the capital market re-quires that A- K. This is a cloaed economy, so that equilibrium in thegoods market requires that private consumption plus government spendingon consumption goods and infrastructure plus private investment must equalproduction. This in turn must equal the national income:

CfGfSfKfáK-Y. (8)

It is possible to rewrite the model as a differential equation in the ratioof private conaumption to private capital, c- C~K:

~~c-o((1-r)aBs~ -p]-Bs~(1-g-s)~cf (1-a)6 (9)

where g- G~Y and s- S~Y. If there are only unanticipated, permanentshocks in g, s and r, there are no transitional dynamics and the saddlepointsolution oí the above model ia given by:

c(s,r)-CjK-op-(1-o)6}(1-oa)(1-r)Bs'ó (10)

x(s,r)- K -Y - Bs~(1-9-s)-c-6-

0[(1- r)aBs~ - 6 - p] (11)

Page 11: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

s

9f9-T (12)

Equation ( 10) gives the reduced-form consumption function. The first partof equation ( 11) is the Harrod-Domar rule, which says that the growth rateof the economy must equal the savings rate ( net of depreciation) dividedby the capital-output ratio. The second part of equation ( 11) is the Ram-sey rule for the growth in private consumption, which together with theHarrod-Domar rule can be solved to give equation ( 10). An increase in thenational income share of government spending requires a higher tax rate andthus crowds out the national income share of private consumption, so thereaze less resources available for saving and investment and the growth rateof the economy falls (a, G 0). Because the ratio of private consumptionto private capital falls (cr G 0), the level of private consumption falls onimpact. Subsequently, the growth rate of private consumption is lower aswell. However, if government spending is on inírastructure, the marginalproductivity of capital increases and this raises both the growth rate of theeconomy and the ratio of private consumption to private capital (x, 1 0and c, ~ 0 provided o G l~a). It follows that an increase in the nationalincome shaze of productive government spending increases on impact thelevel of private consumption and subsequently increases the growth rate ofprivate consumption as well. If households become more impatient ( higherp), the ratio of private consumption to private capital increases and thegrowth tate falls. These effects on the growth rate are magnified when theelasticity of intertemporal substitution is higher, because then householdsfind it easier to postpone consumption. Equation ( 12) is the governmentbudget constraint.

3 Maximal growth is not necessarily efficient

This section is concerned with choosing budgetary policies to mauimise so-cial welfare and develops some of the ideas in Bazro (1990) and Barro andSala-i-Martin (1990). For a given national income shaze of government con-sumption 3, the government chooses the tax rate and thus the national

3This assumption is relaxed in Sections 4 and 5.

Page 12: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

7

income share of productive government spending on infrastructure to max-imise the utility of the representatíve household. There is no populationgrowth. The government thus solves:

MaxJ~ exp (-(P -(1 - 1 )x(r - 9, r)]t) ~c(r - 9, r)K(0)]~-' dt (13).lo a

ifo~l,or

MaxJ

~ exp(-pt)[log(c(r - g, r)K(0)) t x(r - g, r)t]di (13')0

if o- 1. Since the initial capital stock is at any point of time historicallygiven, (13) and (13') are equivalent to, respectively:

Max c(r - 9, r)1-ó 0 0 1 14' P-(1-o)x(r-9,r)~ ~0-1~' ~ ( )

Maxrlog(c(r - 9, r))1 ~ (~(r - 9, r)1 ~- 1. (14')` P J ` PZ J

Utility is bounded ptovided that p~( 1 - ó)a. Maximisation gives rise tothe following first-order condition:

[P-(1-ó)~(r,g)]~~~(r'g))~fx,(r,g)-o (15)

where c(r, g) - c(r-g, r) and á(r,g) - a(r-g, r). It is clear from equations(10)-(12) that both é, - 0 and ir, - 0 when

r-r"-1-a(1-g) (16)

This means that, as long as a G l~o, maximising growth is equivalent tomaximising the ratio of private consumption to private capital and thusis equivalent to maximising social welfare. The optimal tax rate (16) isthe outcome of two opposing forces. A higher tax rate implies a higher

Page 13: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

R

national income share of productive government spending which stimulatesgrowth. However, a higher tax rate also increasea the distortionary impact oftaxation on private incentives to invest which slowa down economic growth'. The optimal tax rate increases and the optimal national income ehare ofproductive government spending,

s-s'-(1-a)(1-g), (17)

decreases when the national income share of government consumption in-creases. It is interesting that the optimal outcome is independent of house-hold preferences.

Note that, even when the government is short-sighted and adopts a dis-count rate higher than the household rate of time preference, the optimaloutcomes for the tax rate and shaze of social infrastructure are unaffected.

The reeult that maximising growth is equivalent to maximising socialwelfare is not robust to changes in the type of production function, even ifproduction remains characterised by constant returns to scale with respectto private capital and productive government spending. In general, thereis a trade-off between the rate of growth and the (initial) level of privateconsumption. For example, if equation (5) is replaced by a CES productionfunction,

Y-[a(ak')~ t( I - a)s"1~, n~ o, n ~ I (s~)

where e- (1-q)-t ~ 0 denotes the elasticity of substitution between privatecapital and productive government spending, one obtains:

~If non-diatortionazy lump-aum taxea are available, maximiaing growth requirea max-

imal taxation (r -~ 1, a-, 1- g). flowever, maximiaing the ratio of private con-

aumption to private capital requiree that the national iacome ahare of taxation ia lesa,

r- r' - va(I - a) G r' ~ 1, because the lump-sum character of taxation doea not dam-

age growth proapecta, leavea leae room tor private conaumption and thue the government

leviea leea taxea. Thia ahowa that with lumpaum taxee maximieing growtó ie inefl'icient.

Page 14: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

s

~n n ~c(s,r)-op-(1-o)b~(1-r) 1-o~a-

e~-1),B(s-a}a-1)

` (10')

a(s, r) - a L (1 - r)aB (as-a 1~- b - PJ . (11')

`s-~}a-1J

In general, c, - 0 and fr, - 0 do not yield the same value of r- r', unlessrl - 0. Maximising social welfaze requires equation (15) to hold and thus isnot necessarily equivalent to maximising growth or maximising the initiallevel of private consumption. Table 1 gives the results of some numericalcalculations.

Insert Table 1: Trade-off between growth and level of consumption

As the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (o) decreases from oneto a half, the rate of economic growth diminishes and the initial level ofprivate consumption increases irrespective of whether social welfare, growthor the initial level of private consumption is maximised. A reduction in oleads to a fall in the tax rate and share of productive government spendingwhen social welfare is maximised, but to an increase when the initial levelof private consumption is maximised. A reduction in o does not affect thevalue of the tax rate which maximises the rate of growth. A reduction in theelasticity of substitution (c) induces a higher tax rate and share of productivegovernment spending and a lower rate of growth, irrespective of whethersocial welfare, growth or the level of private consumption is maximised.The level of private consumption decreases or increases in all three casesdepending on whether o- 2 or a- 1. The most interesting aspect of Table1 is, however, that for c- z there is a trade-off between growth and the levelof private consumption. The share of productive government spending whichmaximises growth is 45.7 per cent and the share which maximises the level ofprivate consumption is only 35.7 per cent. The optimal share lies, of course,in between these two values, which points to a trade-off between the rateof growth and the level of private consumption. Barro (1990) had alreadynoted that, if the elasticity of substitution exceeds unity, the national incomeshare of productive government spending that maximises welfare exceeds thevalue that maximises the growth rate.

Page 15: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

lo

Departures from Cobb-Douglas production functions aze not the onlyreason why maximising growth need not be efficient. For example, whenprivate production depends on the stock of productive government capitalrather than on the level of productive government spending, it is possible toshow that maximising growth is no longer efficient either. Another exampleis when public goods are rival and excludable and household utility dependson the level of government consumption (see Section 6). However, in theremainder of this paper attention is restricted to Cobb-Douglas productionfunctions with productive government spending rather than the stock ofgovernment capital as an argument.

4 7ï~ade-off between government consumption and

productive government spending

Now assume that government yields direct utility for households. Considerthus the situation where the government maximises the political welfarefunction (cf. Barro, 1990):

W- J ~exp(-At)[u(C(t))1-7(g(t)~))dt, (3 1 0,0 c ry G 1. (1')0

The national income share of government consumption rather than thelevel of government consumption affects household utility. This may be jus-tified when government consumption ia a rival, non-excludable public goodwhich is subject to congestion s. Bazro and Sala-i-Martin (1990) argue thatmany public goods (e.g. national parks, roads, water and sewer systems,courts, and even national defense) are rival and non-excludable. A prob-lem is that most of these goods typically have the character of productivegovernment investment as well as of government consumption. An excep-tion is perhaps expenditures on national parks. In any case, most politicaldiscussions are focused on the optimal national income share of governmentconsumption. Ií the government is far-sighted and not threatened by beingremoved out oí ofïice, it adopts the same rate of time preference as house-holds (p - p) and W- U. Ilowever, in general politicians are short-sighted

SSection 6 connidere the case when the government conanmes rival, ezcludable public

goods.

Page 16: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

11

because they may be removed from office by rival politicians (~3 ~ p). Thedifference between the political rate oí discount and the private rate of dis-count may be interpreted as the probability of being removed from office.

If the intertemporal elasticity of subatitution is unity, utility is sepazablein the level of private consumption and the national income share of govern-ment conaumption so that household behaviour ie unaffected by the latter.In general, pteferences are not separable so that:

C(t)~C(t) - ( 1 - ry(1 - o)I[r(t) - P] (3')

C(t) -(ap-} (1 - ry)(1 - o)rl

[A(t) } f~exp[-r(v - t}]D(v)dv] (4')` 1 - 7(1 - a) J !e

rop -(1 - ry)(1 - o)ó f[1 - oa - ry(1 - 0)](1 - r)Bsó~c(s,r) - I` 1-ry(1-o)

(10")

~(s~ r) - `1 - 7(1 - v)) [(1 - r)aBs~ - á - P]. (11~~)

The main difference is that a greater preference for a high national íncomeshare of government consumption (ry) induces, for low elasticities of intertem-poral substitution (o C 1), private agents to postpone consumption and thusleads to a higher rate of growth.

The government chooses both g and r to maximise social welfare:

Max ~ [c(r - g' r)r-rygry]1- á ~~ a~, o~ 1s,, ,0-(1-7)(1-o)x(r-9,r) `0-1

(18)

Max ((1 - 7)log(c(r - 9, r)) f 71oB(g)1 } i(1 - 7)A(r - 9, r)1 a- 1.g., ` A J l a~ J,(18')

The optimal trade-off between the utility derived from a high level of privateconsumption and the utility derived from a high nationa] income share ofgovernment consumption yields equations (16), (17) and

Page 17: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

12

[Q-(1-ry)(1- ó)x(r,g)1 ~~~(~,g)~~ ~1~ ~ ~~~J t~a(r,g)-a(ls)( 9) ry 9

Note that equations (16) and (17) hold, irrespective of what the values ofthe political and private rates of discount aze.

To simplify matters, attention is for the time being focused at the case ofa unit elasticity of intertemporal substitution, so that equation (19) becomes

Q(~((T'~))~ t iry(r,9) f p`1 ry 7~ `9I - 0. (19~)

Hence, the marginal increase in utility of an additional unit oí governmentconsumption must equal the resulting fall in matginal utility of private con-sumption plus the present value of the resulting tall in the real growth rateof the economy.

Upon substitution of equation (17) into equation (19'), one obtains

Í~7 -(1-7)89~(1-a)(1-9)~~'~.a t (QI ~)

Substitution of equation (17) into equation (10) yields

(19~~)

c- P t aB((1 - a)(1 - 9))". (20)

Equations (19") and (20) can, as long as there is an interior solution, besolved to find the optimum values of the national income shares of privateand government consumption, c' and g', as functions oí p, (3, a, B and ry.

The remainder of this section analyses the case of far-sighted politicianswho are not threatened by being voted out of office (Q - p). The caseof short-sighted politicians is dealt with in Section 5. Figure 1 gives agraphic solution. It does not matter whether g, r or s is represented on thehorizontal axis, since once g is known r and s follow from (16) and (17).Equation (20) shows that the ratio of private consumption to private capitaldecreases with the national income share of government consumption andmust exceed the pure rate of time preference. The left-hand side of equation(19r) increases with c and approaches the asymptote (ryQ~a) as c tends to

Page 18: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

13

infinity. The right-hand side of (19") takes on the value zero when g- 0,then increases aA g incr~ascrs, roaches a maximum when g- a, subseqnenttydecreases as g increases, and finally takes on the value zero when g- 1.Combining both results gives a hump-ahaped relationship for equation (19" ),as portrayed in Figure 1. If ry is not too high, there are two points, E and A,satisfying equations (19") and (20). However, point A does not correspondto a maximum because it is on the part of the locus deacribing equation(19") which defines a negative relationship between c and g and thus pointA violates the second-order condition for a maximum s. It follows thatpoint E corresponds to the values of c and g, which maximise social welfare.Furthermore, the optimal value oí c exceeds p and that of g is less than a.

Insert Figure 1: Optimal trade-off between private consumption and gov-ernment consumption

An increase in preferences for rival, non-excludable public goods (y)moves equation (19n) down and shifts the equilibrium from E to E'. Hence,a greater desire for government consumption of rival, non-excludable goodsleads to a higher level of government spending on these goods, but leadsto a lower national income share of productive government spending and ahigher tax rate. The result is that both the ratio of private consumptionto private capital falls and the growth rate of the economy talls so that thelevel of private consumption falla on impact and subsequently growa at aslower rate. Also, the ratio of private capital to output increases. If there isno desire for Samuelson-style public goods (y - 0), one obtaina g' - 0 andr'-1-a.

Note that, when the government chooses the optimal trade-off betweenprivate and government consumption whilst ignoring the effects on growth,the national income share of government consumption and the tax rate willbe too high and the national income share of productive government spend-ing will be too low. The reason is that the negative effects of a high tax rateon the growth are not considered (the left-hand side of equation (19") is rycwhich is larger than before).

"At the valuea of r and g which maximiae eocial welfare, the lett-hand side of equation

(19') muet be decreasing in g. Since i0 is aleo decresaing in c, the optimum muat be on

the upwsrd-sloping part of equation (19") in Figure 1. Thie ia why point A has perverse

comparative etatica and doea not correapond to an optimum.

Page 19: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

14

5 Short-sighted politicians favour government con-

sumption and reduce growth

Section 4 focused on the case of far-sighted politicians with no threat ofbeing removed out of office and a discount rate equal to the one used byprivate agent (A - p). Here the consequences of short-sighted politicians(p ~ p) are considered, again for the time being for the case oï a unitelasticity of intertemporal substitution. The basic proposition will first bedemonstrated for the apecial case of no productive government apending oninfrastructure (a - 1, s- 0). In that case the ratio of private consumptionto private capital is given by the pure rate of time preference of households,c- p, and the growth rate ia given by x(r) -(1 - r)B - 6- p. Theoptimal trade-off between growth and government consumption requires that-(1-y)x'(r) -(jryu'(g) must hold, because the government sets the annuityvalue of the fall in growth arising from an increase in the tax rate equal tothe marginal utility of the resulting increase in government consumption.It follows that r' -(~ry~]B(1 - ry)] and x' - B-~3 (~) - 6 - p. Hence,when the priority the government attaches to a high national income shareof government consumption (ry) is high, the resulting tax rate is high and,as this distorts the rental price of capital, the growth rate is low. Themain lesson, however, to be drawn from this special case is that ahort-sighted politicians (~i higher than p) favour a higher national income shareof government consumption and thus levy a higher tax rate than far-sightedpoliticians. As a result, short-sighted politicians damage growth prospectsfor the economy 7.

In general, productive government spending on infrastructure boosta eco-nomic growth (a G I). The effects of short-sighted politicians can then bestbe seen írom examining the comparative statica of an increase in the gov-ernment discount rate on the equilibrium portrayed in Figure 1. The locusdescribing equation (20) shifta down, so that the optimum ehifts from Eto E'. Short-aighted politicians increase the national income share of gov-ernment consumption at the expense of private consumption. Basically,

~Within the context ot a model ot tax-emoothing and government debt, it can be

ahown that ahort-aighted politiciana [avour government coneumption at the expenae ot

government inveatment and thua run up debt and induce an eroeion o[ the net worth of

the public aector (van der Plceg, 1990).

Page 20: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

15

short-sighted politicians favour high tax rates (1 - a(1 - g)) and low na-tional income shares of productive government spending on infrastructure((1 - a)(1- g)) because from the electoral point of view they value high na-tional income shazes of government consumption more than a high growthrate of the economy. As a consequence, short-sighted politicians may beblamed both for low levels of private consumption and for low growth ratesof the economy. Note that when the desire for Samuelson-style public goodstends to zero (y -. 0), then g' -. 0 and r' -. 1- a irrespective of the valueof ~3 so that political effects eventually do not matter at all. Alternatively,equation (19n) shows that as governments become extremely far-sighted anddiscount very little (~i y 0), government consumption tends to zero (g -y 0)in which case the optimal tax rate and national income share of productivegovernment spending tend to 1- a as well.

The top panel of Table 2 presents numerical calculations designed to il-lustrate the sensitivity of the results of this and the previous section with re-spect to the elasticity ot intertemporal substitution. It is comforting to notethat, even if the elasticity oï intertemporal substitution differs from unity,short-aighted politicians favour a higher national income share of govern-ment consumption, a lower national income shaze of productive governmentspending and a higher tax rate and thus they can be blamed for a lowerlevel of private consumption, a lower growth rate and a lower level of wel-fare for citizens. As before, a lower elasticity of intertemporal substitutionleads to a lower rate of growth and to a higher level of private consumption;the government responds with a higher national income share of governmentconsumption and a lower share of productive government spending.

Insert Table 2: Short-sighted politicians damage growth prospects

6 Rival, excludable public goods

The analysis of Sections 4 and 5 assumes that public goods are rival andnon-excludable. Congestion means that it is the shase rather than the levelof government consumption which yields utility to households. However, ifcongestion is unimportant and public goods are rival and excludable, it isreasonable that the leve] of public consumption enters the political welfarefunction:

Page 21: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

ls

W - ~~exp(-~3t)(u(C(t)1-'G(t)ry)]dt, A,y ~ 0.0

The optimal values of g and r thus follow from:

~c(r - 9, r)1-7 (g(T - 9) ás9~ryj 1-é

M'~ (i3-~1-ó)A`(r-9,r)]~1-Jó~ a~l (21)

Maxl (1-7)log(c(T-9,T)~f71o8(9B(r-9)~)~}rA(rp~9,T)1 a- 1.

` ` J (21~)

The values of r and g defining the optimal trade-off between governmentconsumption and economic growth must for o- 1 satisíy:

A~(1 - y) (c((r 9))I } y`1 a aI lr 1 9~J } A,(T, 9) - 0 (22)

(j((1-y)rcg(T,9)I} `ry~-y`l aa~ `T 1 ~1 }A9(T,9)-0 (23)

l `(,9) 9 9

It is clear that, for a given level o( g, maximising growth is no longer equiv-alent to maximising the ratio of private consumption to private capital anda fortiori thus not equivalent to maximising social welfare. This means thatequations (16) and (17) do not follow from equation (22). Instead, it iseasy to prove from equations (lOT), (11"), (22) and (23) that s' - 1- aand r' - 1- a-}- g. This result holds irrespective of what the values ofthe political and social rates of discount are and of what the elasticity ofintertemporal substitution is. The intuition is that, when public goods arerival and excludable, private and public goods can be treated as a compositecommodity and the Composite Commodity Theorem then says that one canmaximise social welfare with respect to this composite commodity and thenational income ehare of productive government spending.

Page 22: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

17

The optimal national income share of government consumption and theoptimal tax rate depend on political preferences, to be precise the polit-ical rate of discount and the weight given to public rather than privateconsumption (p and y), as well as on private preferences (p) and on tech-nology (a). Furthermore, x, and c, must be negative so that the opti-mal tax rate exceeds the one which prevails when it is the national incomeshare rather than the level of government consumption that affects welfare(r' - 1-~fg ~ 1-~(1-g)). Similarly, thenationalincomeshareofproduc-tive government spending is higher than before (s' - 1-a ~(1-a)(1-g)).The reason is that the government no longer chooses the optimal tax rate tomaximise economic growth and the ratio of private consumption to privatecapital, but that it gces beyond this. The government also considers thebeneficial effect on welfaze of a marginal increase in the tax rate and the na-tional income share of productive government spending on the productivityof capital and consequently on the rate of economic growth and welfare. Ineffect, a higher rate of growth permits, for a given national income share, ahigher level of government consumption and this increases welfare.

Table 2 presents some numerical calculations to illustrate the robustnessof the results. When there is no congestion the optimal share of productivegovernment spending is higher, the optimal share of government consump-tion is lower and consequently the growth rate is higher than when there isno congestion, irrespective of whether the elasticity of intertemporal substi-tution exceeds or is less than unity.

7 Conclusion

The implications of the new theories of endogenous growth for the optimaldetermination of the national income sharea of government consumption andof productive government apending on infrastructure have been analysed.Economic growth is in these new theories no longer constrained by the sumoí population growth and the exogenous growth on labour productivity,but is endogenous when output is proportional to a broad measure of thecapital stock. Economic growth then depends positively on the nationalincome share of productive government spending in as far as this increasesthe marginal productivity of private capital and negatively on the tax rateas this teduces the return on private capital. If government consumptiondces not yield direct utility and the production function is of the Cobb-Douglas variety, maximising gtowth is equivalent to maximising the ratio of

Page 23: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

18

private consumption to private capital and thus to maximising social welfare.The resulting optimal tax rate increases less than proportionally with thenational income share of government consumption, but only depends onlechnology and not on óousehold prefereuces.

This latter result is not robust under at least three circumstances. Thefirst occurs when production functions are more general (e.g. of the CESvariety). When the elasticity of substitution between private capital andproductive government spending is less than unity, the tax rate and shareof productive government spending are higher when growth is maximisedthan when the current level of private consumption is maximised. The sec-ond circumstance occurs when government capital rather than productivegovernment spending affects private production. The final one occurs whengovernment consumption affects social welfare directly. In general, thereis a trade-off between the current levels of private and~or public consump-tion and the rate of growth of the economy so that maximal growth is notnecessarily efficient.

If public goods are rival and non-excludable (e.g. when congestion is im-portant), it is reasonable that a high national income share of governmentconsumption contributes to social welfare. If public goods are rival and ex-cludable, congestion is not important and consequently the optimal growthrate ia higher than when public goods are rival and non-excludable. Thepoint is that when congestion ie perceived to be unimportant the govern-ment finds it optimal to have a higher national income share oí productivegovernment spending and a lower share of government consumption, becausethe adverse effects on growth and congestion are not internalised.

Politicians are short-sighted, especially when the probability of beingremoved from office is high. This distorts their optimal policies in favourof higher government consumption at the expense of lower productive gov-ernment spending on infrastructure and higher taxes. As a result, the be-haviour of short-sighted politicians reduces the growth rate of the economyand jeopardises welfare of citizens.

References

Barro, Robert J. (1990). Government spending in a simplemodel of endogenous growth, Journalof Politica! Economy,98, S103-S125.

Page 24: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

19

Ilarro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin 1990. Public financein models of economic growth, mimeo, líarvard University.

Lucas, Robert E. (1988). On the mechanism of economic devel-opment, Journal oj Monetnry Economics, 22, 3-42.

Plceg, Frederick van der (L990). Short-sighted politicians anderosion of government assets, CentER discussion paper No.9069, Tilburg University.

Romer, Paul M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth,Journal oJ Political Economy, 94, 1002-1037.

Romer, Paul M. (1989). Capital accumulation in the theory oflong-run growth, in Robert J. IIarro (ed.), Modern DusinessCycle Theory, 1[arvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Tanzi, Vittorio and Mark S. Lutz (1990). Interest rates andgovernment debt: Are the linkages global rather than na-tional?, presented to the symposium on 7'he Polilica! Fcan-omy oj Goveniment De6l, De Nederlandsche IIank, Amster-dam, June 1990.

Figure 1: Optimal trade-o(f between private consumption and goverumentconsumption

~ ~ ~(~~"l~ir~tinn (20)

~ ,~` `~ eciualion ( ly"j

i `

U q~ r~,~ ~ ~~

Page 25: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

20

Table 1: Trade-off between growth and level of consumption

a - o - 1E-; E- 1 E- 1 E- 1

Max UU -83.99 -26.119 60.017 345.72c 0.174 0.237 0.122 0.010a 0.043 0.137 0.090 0.274s 0.411 0.15 0.438 0.15

Ma~c CU -91.88 -26.119 1.146 345.72c 0.181 0.237 0.151 0.010a 0.035 0.137 0.048 0.274s 0.358 0.15 0.316 0.15

Max aU -88.41 -26.119 58.886 345.72c 0.161 0.237 0.115 0.010a 0.045 0.137 0.091 0.274s 0.457 0.15 0.457 0.15

Note: g- 0.25,r - s~-g,p - 0.025,8 - l,a - 0.8,6 - 0.

Page 26: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

21

Table 2: Short-sighted politicians damage growth prospects

Rival Non-Excludable Public Goodso - 1 0 - 1

Q-P Q-2P Q-P Q-2PW -39.313 -32.401 199.796 25.813U -39.313 -39.436 199.796 51.627c 0.196 0.189 0.126 0.121g 0.233 0.257 0.045 0.087s 0.153 0.149 0.191 0.183r 0.386 0.405 0.236 0.269a 0.188 0.180 0.379 0.357

Rival Excludable Public Goodso- 0-1

Q-P Q-2P Q-P Q-2PW -27.221 -24.413 500.640 95.817U -27.221 -27.248 500.640 494.975c 0.201 0.198 0.129 0.126g 0.208 0.220 0.023 0.045s 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2r 0.408 0.420 0.223 0.245a 0.194 0.190 0.391 0.379

Note: p- 0.025, y - 0.5, B - 1, a- 0.8, e- 1, ó- 0.

Page 27: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

Discussion Paper Series, CentER, Tilburg University, The Netherlands:

(For previous papers please consult previous discussion papers.)

No. Author(s)

8954 A. Kapteyn,S. van de Geer,H. van de Stadt andT. Wansbeek

8955 L. zou

8956 P.Kooreman andA. Kapteyn

8957 E. van Damme

9001 A. van Scest,P. Kooreman andA. Kapteyn

9002 J.R. Magnus andB. Pesaren

9003 J. DriFfill endC. Schultz

9004 M. McAleer,M.H. Pesaran andA. Bera

9005 Th. ten Raa sndM.F.J. Steel

9006 M. McAleer andC.R. McKenzie

9007 J. Osiewalski andM.F.J. Steel

9008 G.W. Imbens

9009 G.W. Imbens

9010 P. Deschamps

9011 w. Guth andE. van Damme

9012 A. Horsley endA. Wrobel

Title

Interdependent Preferences: An EconometricAnalysis

Ownership Structure and Efficiency: AnIncentive Mechanism Approach

On the Empirical Implementation of Some GameTheoretic Models of Household Labor Supply

Signaling and Forward Induction in a MarketEntry ContextCoherency end Regularity of Demend Systemswith Equality and Inequality Constraints

Forecasting, Misspecification and Unit Roots:The Case of AR(1) Versus ARMA(1,1)

Wage Setting and Stabilization Policy in aGame with Renegotiation

Alternative Approaches to Testing Non-NestedModels with Autocorrelated Disturbances: AnApplication to Models of U.S. Unemployment

A Stochastic Analysis of an Input-QutputModel: Comment

Keynesian and New Classical Models ofUnemployment Revisited

Semi-Conjugate Prior Densities in Multi-variate t Regression Models

Duration Models with Time-VaryingCcefficients

An Efficient Method of Moments Estimatorfor Discrete Choice Models with Choice-BasedSampling

Expectations and Intertemporal Separabilityin an Empirical Model of Consumption andInvestment under Uncertainty

Gorby Games - A Game Theoretic Analysis ofDisarmament Campaigns and the DefenseEfficiency-Hypothesis

The Existence of an Equilibrium Densityfor Marginal Cost Prices, and the Solutionto the Shifting-Peak Problem

Page 28: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

No. Author(s)

9013 A. Horaley endA. Wrobel

9014 A. Horsley andA. Wrobel

9015 A. van den Elzen,G. van der Laan andD. Talman

9016 P. Deschamps

9017 B.J. Christensenand N.M. Kiefer

9018 M. Verbeek andTh. Nijman

9019 J.R. Magnus andB. Pesaran

9020 A. Robson

902]. J.R. Magnus andB. Pesaran

9022 K. Kamiya andD. Talman

9023 W. Emons

9oz4 c. Dang

9025 K. Kamiys andD. Talman

9026 P. Skott

9027 c. Dang andD. Talman

9028 J. Bai, A.J. Jakemanand M. McAleer

Title

The Closedness of the Free-D[sposal Nullof a Production Set

The Continuity of the Equilibrium PriceDensity: The Case of Symmetric Joint Costs,and a Solution to the Shifting-PatternProblem

An Adjustment Process for an ExchangeEconomy with Linear Production Technologies

On Fractional Demand Systems and BudgetShare Positivity

The Exact Likelihood Function for anEmpirical Job Search Model

Testing for Selectivity Bias in Panel DataModels

Evaluation of Moments of Ratios of QuadraticForms in Normal Variables and RelatedStatistics

Status, the Distribution of Wealth, Socialend Private Attitudes to Risk

Evaluation of Moments of Quadratic Forms lnNormal Variables

Linear Stationary Point Problems

Good Times, Bad Times, and Vertical UpstreamIntegration

The D-Triangulation for Simplicial HomotopyAlgor~thms for Computing Solutions ofNonlinear Equations

Variable Dimension Simplicial Algorithm forBalanced Games

Efficiency Wages, Mark-Up Pricing andEffective Demand

The D-Triangulation in Simplicial VariableDimension Algorithms for Computing Solutionsof Nonlinear Equations

Discrimination Between Nested Two- and Three-Parameter Distributions: An Application toModela of Air Pollution

9029 Th. ven de Klundert Crowding out end the Wealth of Nations

Page 29: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

No. Author(s)

9030 Th. ven de Klundertand R. Gradus

9031 A. Weber

9G32 J. Osiewalski andM. Steel

9033 C. R. WicheraSquares

9034 C. de VriesProcesses

9G35 M.R. Baye.D.W. Jensen and Q. Li

9036 J. Driffill

9G3~ F. van der Ploeg

9038 A. Robson

9039 A. Robson

904o M.R. Baye, G. Tianand J. Zhou

9041 M. Burnovsky andI. Zang

9042 P.J. Deschamps

9043 S. Chib, J. Osiewalskiand M. Steel

9044 H.A. Keuzenkamp

9045 I.M. Bomze andE.E.C. van Damme

9046 E. ven Damme

Title

Optimal Government Debt under DistortionaryTaxation

The Credibility of Monetary Target Announce-ments: An Empirical Evaluation

Robust Bayesian Inference in EllipticalRegression Models

The Linear-Algebraic Structure of Least

On the Relation between GARCH and Stable

Aggregation and the "Random Objective"Justification for Disturbances in CompleteDemand Systems

The Term Structure of Interest Rates:Structural Stability and Macroeconomic PolicyChanges in the UK

Budgetary Aspects of Economic snd MonetaryIntegration in Europe

Existence of Nash Equilibrium in MixedStrategies for Games where Payoffs Need notBe Continuous in Pure Strategies

An "Informationally Robust Equilibrium" forTwo-Person Nonzero-Sum Games

The Existence of Pure-Strategy NashEquilibrium in Games with Payoffs that arenot Quasiconcave

"Costless" Indirect Regulation of Monopolieswith Substantial Entry Cost

Joint Tests for Regularity andAutocorrelatíon in Allocation Systems

Posterior Inference on the Degrees of FreedomParameter in Multivariate-t Regression Models

The Probability Approach in Economic Method-ology: On the Relation between Hasvelmo's

Legacy and the Methodology of Economics

A Dynamical Characterization of Evolution-arily Stable States

On Dominance Solvable Games and EquilibriumSelection Theories

Page 30: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

No. Author(s)

9G47 J. Driffill

9048 A.J.J. Talman9049 H.A. Keuzenkamp and

F. van der Plceg

9050 C. Dang andA.J.J. Talman

9051 M. Baye, D. Kovenockand C. de Vries

9G52 H. Carlsson andE. van Damme

9053 M. Baye anaD. Kovenock

9054 Th. van de Klundert

9G55 P. Kooreman

9056 R. Bartels andD.G. Fiebig

9057 M.R. Veall andK.F. Zimmermann

9058 R. Bartels andD.G. Fiebig

9059 F. van der Ploeg

9060 H. Bester

9061 F. van der Ploeg

9G62 E. Bennett andE. van Damme

9063 S. Chib, J. Osiewalskiand M. Steel

9064 M. Verbeek andTh. Nijman

Title

Changes in Regime and the Term Structure:A Note

General Equilibrium ProgrammingSaving, Investment, Government Finance andthe Current Account: The Dutch Experience

The D-Triangulation in Simplicial VariableDimension Algorithms on the Unit Simplex forComputing Fixed Points

The All-Pay Auction with Complete Information

Global Games and Equilibrium Selection

How to Sell a Pickup Truck: "Beat-or-Pay"Advertiaements as Facilitating Devices

The Ultimate Consequences of the New GrowthTheory; An Introduction to the Views of M.Fitzgerald Scott

Nonparametric Bounds on the RegressionCoefficients when an Explanatory Variable isCategorized

Integrating Direct Metering and ConditionalDemand Analysis for Estimating End-Use Loads

Evaluating Pseudo-RZ's for Binary ProbitModels

More on the Grouped HeteroskedasticityModel

Channels of International Policy Transmission

The Role of Collateral in a Model of DebtRenegotiation

Macroeconomic Policy Coordination during theVarious Phases of Economic and MonetaryIntegration in Europe

Demand Commitment Bargaining: - The Case ofApex Games

Regression Models under Competing CovarianceMatrices: A Bayesian Perspective

Can Cohort Data Be Treated as Genuine PanelDataT

Page 31: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

No. Author(s)

9065 F. van der Plcegand A. de Zeeuw

9066 F.C. Drost andTh. E. Nijman

9067 Y. Dai and D. Talman

9068 Th. Nijman andR. Beetsma

9069 F. van der Ploeg

9070 E. van Damme9071 J. Eichberger,

H. Haller and F. Milne

9072 C. Alogoskoufis andF. van der Ploeg

9073 x.C. Fung

9101 A. van Soest

9102 A. Barten andM. McAleer

9103 A. Weber

9104 G. Alogoskoufis andF. van der Ploeg

91G5 R.M.W.J. Beetsma

9106 C.N. Teulings

9107 E. van Damme

9108 E. van Damme9109 G. Alogoskoufis and

F. van der Ploeg

9110 L. Samuelson

9111 F. van der Plceg andTh. van de Klundert

Title

International Aspects of Pollution Control

Temporal Aggregation of GARCH Processes

Linear Stationary Point Problems on UnboundedPolyhedra

Empirical Tests of a Simple Pricing Model forSugar Futures

Short-Sighted Politicians and Erosion ofGovernment Assets

Fair Division under Asymmetric Information

Naive Bayesian Learning in 2 x 2 MatrixGames

Endogenous Growth and Overlapping Generations

Strategic Industriel Policy for Cournot andBertrand Oligopoly: Management-LaborCooperation as a Possible Solution to theMarket Structure DilemmaMinimum Wages, Earnings and Employment

Comparing the Empirical Performance ofAlternative Demand Systems

EMS Credibility

Debts, Defícits and Growth in InterdependentEconomies

Bands and Statistical Propcrties of EMSExchange Rates

The Diverging Effects of the Business Cycleon the Expected Duration of Job Search

Refinements of Nash Equilibrium

Equilibrium Selection in 2 x 2 Games

Money and Growth Revisited

Dominated Strategies and Commom Knowledge

Political Trade-off between Growth andGovernment Consumption

Page 32: Tilburg University Political trade-off between growth and

pn Rnx an~~~ ~nnn I F TII RI IRC~ THF NFTHFRLANDSBibliotheek K. U. BrabantW ii~ u ~m~~ a Ni i~~~iuuui

.