trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · using these trading cost...

58
Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency trading markets * YASHAR HEYDARI BARARDEHI Department of Economics University of Illinois 214 David Kinley Hall 1407 W. Gregory Urbana IL 61801 DAN BERNHARDT Department of Economics University of Illinois 214 David Kinley Hall 1407 W. Gregory Urbana IL 61801 RYAN J. DAVIES § Finance Division Babson College 220 Tomasso Hall Babson Park MA 02457 September 14, 2014 * ©2013 Barardehi, Bernhardt, Davies. We are grateful for comments received from seminar participants at the University of Illinois and the Boston Area Finance Symposium. Yashar Heydari Barardehi is grate- ful for support from Paul Boltz Fellowship. Ryan Davies acknowledges support from the Babson Faculty Research Fund. Tel: +1-217-819-6478. email: [email protected] Tel: +1-217-244-5708. email: [email protected] § Tel: +1-781-239-5345. email: [email protected]

Upload: others

Post on 26-Sep-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Trading costs and priced illiquidity in highfrequency trading markets∗

YASHAR HEYDARI BARARDEHI†

Department of EconomicsUniversity of Illinois

214 David Kinley Hall1407 W. GregoryUrbana IL 61801

DAN BERNHARDT‡

Department of EconomicsUniversity of Illinois

214 David Kinley Hall1407 W. GregoryUrbana IL 61801

RYAN J. DAVIES§

Finance DivisionBabson College

220 Tomasso HallBabson Park MA 02457

September 14, 2014

∗©2013 Barardehi, Bernhardt, Davies. We are grateful for comments received from seminar participantsat the University of Illinois and the Boston Area Finance Symposium. Yashar Heydari Barardehi is grate-ful for support from Paul Boltz Fellowship. Ryan Davies acknowledges support from the Babson FacultyResearch Fund.†Tel: +1-217-819-6478. email: [email protected]‡Tel: +1-217-244-5708. email: [email protected]§Tel: +1-781-239-5345. email: [email protected]

Page 2: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency trading markets

Abstract

Decimalization, regulatory changes, and technological advances have transformedstock markets, shrinking bid-ask spreads, driving down depth, and causing institutionalinvestors to employ order-splitting algorithms. We develop a stock-specific measure ofmarket activity for this environment by calculating the time it takes for sequencesof trades each worth a fixed percent of a firm’s market capitalization to execute—shorter durations indicate more active markets. As market activity rises so do tradesizes and signed order imbalances; but price impacts fall for small and mid-sized firms;and for large firms, price impacts exhibit a single-peaked relationship with marketactivity. Most variation in market activity reflects endogenous variation in liquidityprovision/consumption; and not information arrival. We instrument for this endogene-ity and uncover predictable, uniform trading costs/market activity relationships acrossstocks—with trading costs falling by 5–8 basis points as instrumented market activ-ity rises. Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmentedCAPM, we find that they outperform standard measures (bid-ask spreads, Amihud’smeasure), and that liquidity premia have not declined.

Page 3: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Equity markets have experienced revolutionary changes in the past two decades. Prior

to 1997, stock prices were quoted in eighths, and trading costs and liquidity provision were

driven by this large tick size. Today, the typical tick size is a penny, and limit order book

depth near the inside quotes has collapsed. Dedicated specialists no longer provide tradi-

tional market making services. Instead, those services are largely provided by “high frequency

traders” who use complex computer algorithms to submit thousands of small, fleeting orders

throughout the day. As a result, average trade sizes and inside bid-ask spreads are now tiny,

and traditional measures of trading costs and liquidity no longer describe the concerns of

institutional traders1 who seek to minimize trading costs by splitting their large orders into

many smaller orders that are dynamically submitted over time and across trading venues.

These changes lead us to ask: in today’s markets, what drives variations in market ac-

tivity? Is it costlier to establish or unwind positions when markets are active or inactive?

What market conditions predict when trading costs will be higher or lower? And, which

illiquidity measures for individual stocks explain their pricing?

A priori, the answers are unclear: More active markets may have more participants, but

markets may be more active precisely because some participants have acquired information;

markets may appear more active just because liquidity provision is unusually high, inducing

agents to consume it aggressively; and the nature of illiquidity risk about which institutional

traders care is unclear, as they may be able to time trades according to market conditions.

To answer questions such as these, one needs a measure of market activity that controls

for dynamic order splitting and division of orders against the book. Our new trade-based

measure of market activity groups consecutive trades together into a sequence of trades with

a cumulative dollar value of a fixed amount (e.g., 0.04% of a firm’s market capitalization).

Once a stock’s target dollar value is reached, we start over, grouping the next set of consec-

utive trades until their cumulative dollar value reaches its target value, continuing in this

way iteratively over a year. We measure market activity by the time it takes for a trade

1Blume and Keim (2012) report that the share of institutional ownership in U.S. equity markets was67% at the end of 2010.

1

Page 4: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

sequence to reach its target dollar value—shorter durations indicate more active markets.

Controlling for the dollar value of a sequence lets us isolate the effects of market activity

from that of trading volume. That is, while volume and price volatility are highly positively

correlated (as Andersen and Bondarenko (2014) emphasize), this relation does not inform

an institutional trader about how the costs of unwinding a given position vary with market

activity. By choosing target dollar values that are neither too large nor too small, we address

concerns both about aggregating over multiple activity levels due to excessively large targets,

and mis-attributing variation in market activity due to excessively small targets.

With our stock-specific market activity measure in hand, we establish how fundamentals

vary with market activity. We first show that both trade size and signed trade imbalance

rise with market activity. In particular, on average, as the duration of a trade sequence for

a stock falls, so does the number of trades comprising the sequence—and given the same

dollar-volume, fewer trades reflect larger trades. So, too, using the Lee and Ready (1991)

algorithm to identify the share of value-weighted trades in a trade sequence that is buyer- or

seller-initiated (whichever is highest), we find that as market activity rises, trade becomes

less balanced. These changes are large, especially in highly active markets. For example,

going from least to most active markets, signed trade imbalances rise by roughly 20%, and

for smaller stocks, mean trade sizes double.

It is not surprising that more active markets correspond with more aggressive trading.

The classical models of speculation in financial markets (Kyle (1985), Glosten (1993)) pre-

dict precisely this: speculators with substantial private information will establish larger

positions, submitting larger, liquidity consuming, orders that cause market activity, signed

trade imbalance, and trade sizes all to rise.

But, a very different explanation for these phenomena exists. Liquidity provision may

be time-varying and certain times may feature more depth available near inside quotes than

others. When the market is unusually liquid on one side, institutional traders respond ag-

gressively, submitting larger market orders that are filled at these “good” prices. As a result,

2

Page 5: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

the corresponding trade sequences have shorter durations, with fewer trades and less bal-

anced signed trade. In contrast, with little depth, institutional traders consume less liquidity

via market orders, and supply more via limit orders in order to reduce price impacts.2 The

result is longer durations, more balanced signed trade (reflecting a more even mix between

demanding and supplying liquidity), and more trades comprising a trade sequence.

To distinguish between these very different explanations, we look at price impacts. Clas-

sical models of speculation predict that more aggressive trading should result in larger price

impacts; but, if endogenous consumption of unusually high depth at “good” prices is the

primary driver, then price impacts should fall as market activity rises. We measure price

impact by both the average absolute value of the return over a trade sequence at a given

market activity level, and the average annual standard deviation of those returns.

For small and mid-sized stocks, trade sizes and percent trade imbalances rise with mar-

ket activity, but both measures of price impacts fall sharply—declines on the order of 40%.

These relationships are especially steep at very high market activity levels. Thus, even though

volatility is positively associated with dollar volume and market activity, the opposite rela-

tionship holds once one controls for the level of volume. In contrast, for larger stocks, price

impacts peak at intermediate market activity levels, and, indeed, the standard deviation of

returns is smallest when markets are least active.

To investigate these price impact patterns more deeply, we calculate percentile statistics

of returns by activity level and then compute return percentile differences, rπ− r1−π, e.g., the

75th-25th percentile difference. For small and mid-sized stocks these differences fall uniformly

as market activity rises. In contrast, for larger stocks, extreme return percentile differences

(e.g., r.95−r.05) widen as market activity rises, but differences of less extreme percentiles (e.g.,

r.75−r.25) either shrink with market activity or are single-peaked functions of market activity.

The uniformly negative relationship between price impacts and market activity for small

2See, for example, Bloomfield et al. (2005), Goettler, Parlour and Rajan (2005), Hollifield, Miller andSandas (2004), and Hollifield et al. (2006) and Easley et al. (2012).

3

Page 6: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

and mid-sized stocks indicates that time-varying endogenous consumption and provision of

liquidity is the primary driver of variation in market activity, not information. In contrast,

the fat tails of the return distribution in active markets of large stocks suggests that, in

unusual times, significant information arrival drives some higher market activity, but, in

normal times, market activity mostly reflects variation in liquidity. Cumulatively, these

findings indicate that the classic models of informed trade no longer describe outcomes in

today’s stock markets. Rather, high frequency variation in market fundamentals for a given

stock are driven primarily by endogenous responses of traders to the time-varying levels of

liquidity extant.

These important findings still leave one seeking more. An institutional investor seeking to

minimize the costs of establishing or unwinding a large position cannot exploit information

arrival to which it is not privy, and may have difficulty forecasting when liquidity provision

will be “unusually high”. One wants to control for endogeneity and information arrival to

make causal inferences about how market activity affects trading costs. That is, one wants to

isolate primitive market activity/trading cost relationships that are stable and predictable.

To do this, we use the number of trades filling the previous trade sequence to instrument

for the duration of the current trade sequence (current market activity). The observation

underlying our choice of instrument is that liquidity persists over time—present and past

states of the order book are positively correlated. The endogenous composition of current

orders, however, hinges only on the contemporaneous state of the order book, which strongly

covaries with current activity. Effects of past order book states on current price impacts

only transmit via the current state. Using instrumented market activity also filters out the

variation associated with information arrival which is, presumably, unpredictable.

For each stock, we first regress log duration on a polynomial of lagged trade frequency,

annually. Over 95% of these regressions have significant F statistics, with large positive

coefficients, indicating that the fitted values of these regressions can serve as “instrumented”

levels of activity. In contrast, the analogous regressions using lagged trade frequency to pre-

4

Page 7: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

dict signed trade imbalance yield far fewer significant F statistics; and signed trade imbalance

is far less correlated with instrumented market activity than with raw market activity.

Instrumented market activity yields very stable and uniform trading costs/market ac-

tivity relationships across all firm sizes. Instrumenting flattens the price impact/activity

relationship for small stocks by roughly 75%; but for larger stocks, price impact/activity re-

lationship becomes monotone and, indeed, it becomes steeper. The result is that, regardless

of firm size, average price impacts fall uniformly by five to eight basis points as predicted

market conditions rise from least active to most active levels. The costs of trading smaller

stocks are more sensitive to predicted market activity levels, but the relative (percentage)

variations in trading costs are qualitatively identical for all stock sizes. Our regression results

indicate that institutional traders can successfully time when they establish or unwind posi-

tions to reduce trading costs by meaningful amounts. We also find that while bid-ask spreads

have fallen uniformly in more recent years, the predictable components of trading costs have

not: the costs of unwinding positions in large market capitalization stocks have fallen, but

those for small and medium sized stocks have risen, especially in very active markets.

Our ability to relate trading costs to market activity and the cross-sectional attributes of

firms leads us to investigate whether we can shed light on how illiquidity is priced. We ask:

which illiquidity measure best captures the concerns of traders? and, how have the return

premia demanded by traders for taking positions in less liquid stocks evolved?

We start by creating a new measure of individual stock liquidity, BBD, by scaling our

price impact measure by the dollar amount traded. The measure is based on a rolling average

of the per-dollar price impact of trading a fixed proportion of a stock’s market capitalization

at a given level of market activity to account for the varying nature of trading costs. In

essence, BBD is a trade-time analogue of Amihud’s (2002) temporal measure of liquidity

that isolates different market conditions.

A priori, it is not clear how institutions will price trading cost risks in equity markets.

For very illiquid securities such as corporate debt, concerns that markets might dry up likely

5

Page 8: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

dictate liquidity premia. After all, it was such dry ups that led to the failures of Long-Term

Capital Management and Lehman Brothers. Equity markets, however, are so liquid that

the liquidity considerations of institutional traders may reflect expected price impacts when

unwinding positions in “standard times”, where they can time trades in accordance with

predicted market activity.

Regardless of which raw or instrumented market activity levels we use to calculate BBD,

it is priced in an augmented capital asset pricing model. Furthermore, these liquidity mea-

sures are robust: similar liquidity premia obtain when we use different market activity levels

to constructBBD. We compareBBD with standard liquidity measures—average percentage

bid-ask spreads and Amihud’s per dollar price impact. We also consider a high frequency

version of Amihud’s measure constructed at hourly rather than daily frequencies. In the

2001–2012 post-decimalization era, each of these measures is priced on its own. To compare

the measures, we employ the residuals from the regression of one measure on a second in the

pricing regressions. The BBD residual is always priced, whereas the other residuals are not.

Splitting the sample over time reveals that the superior performance of BBD reflects

more recent years following the implementation of RegNMS and the resulting increase in

high frequency trading, dynamic order splitting and trading volumes. Even though bid-ask

spreads have fallen in recent years, implied liquidity premia have increased, regardless of the

liquidity measure used. The cumulative evidence indicates that our trade-time based notion

of liquidity better captures liquidity in today’s markets.

Our paper is organized as follows. We next discuss related research. Section I develops our

market activity measure. Section II establishes how different fundamentals vary with market

activity. Section III evaluates different illiquidity measures in an asset pricing model. Sec-

tion IV concludes. An appendix explores calendar time relationships between volatility and

market activity, and shows our results are robust to different error structure specifications.

6

Page 9: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

A Related Literature

Trade time and market dynamics. Mapping asset market dynamics onto trade-time

space is not a new idea. Dufour and Engle (2000) examine the duration between successive

trades and show that price adjustments are faster when trading intensity is high (i.e., du-

rations are short). They argue that periods of high trade intensity indicate the presence of

informed trading and conclude that these periods correspond to periods of market illiquidity.

Engle and Russell (1998) and Engle (2000) develop related models of autoregressive condi-

tional duration (ACD), which provide semi-parametric estimates of trade intensities based

on trade arrival rates. ACD models are designed primarily to estimate the expected cost

and time to execute a single order, submitted within a very short time frame, and not the

cost of a series of orders submitted over longer periods of time.

In modern markets, the information content of one trade is likely small; and consecu-

tive trades may represent a single trading decision, where a larger order has been crossed

against multiple smaller orders in the book. To account for these features, Gourieroux et

al. (1999) measure market activity by the time it takes the market to execute an exogenous

level of volume or dollar volume. They focus on the evolution of market activity over the

trading day on Paris Bourse for a single stock over 18 trading days, exploring the average

time duration to unwind a fixed position at different times. They find activity peaks at

times corresponding to the opening of the London Stock Exchange and the NYSE. Easley et

al. (2012) are similarly motivated to group consecutive trades across time according to the

time required to trade an exogenous level of order flow. Within each group, they use the

sign of price changes over one-minute periods to infer buyer-initiated versus seller-initiated

trades, creating a measure of volume “toxicity”, VPIN, the high frequency analogue to their

probability of informed trading (PIN) measure.

Our findings highlight a tension between concerns about using and consuming liquidity,

and identification of the probabilities of informed trade off of a competitive (zero-profit) limit

order pricing construction. If liquidity provision is competitive, then traders might as well

7

Page 10: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

always consume liquidity—it is because markets are sometimes more illiquid than others that

traders choose sometimes to consume and sometimes to supply liquidity (see also Andersen

and Bondarenko (2014)).

Feldhutter (2012) develops the notion of an imputed roundtrip trade, based on the em-

pirical feature that trades in corporate bonds often occur infrequently, but when they do

trade, there are often several trades in a short period of time. He argues that these trades

are likely linked and should be considered together when measuring trading costs.

Relation between market activity and liquidity. There has been a long debate about

the relation between market activity and liquidity. Demsetz (1968) finds that more active

stocks tended to be more liquid, and argues that more frequent trading is associated with

low dealer costs. Lippman and McCall (1986) argue that active markets have a lower op-

portunity cost of searching and are thus more liquid. Jones (2002) and Fujimoto (2004) find

no relation between liquidity measures and changes, or shocks, in turnover. Johnson (2008)

develops a model in which volume is positively related to liquidity risk, rather than liquidity,

and provides supporting evidence from U.S. government bond markets.

Liquidity Measures. Amihud and Mendelson (1986) show that when the standard tick

size was one-eighth, bid-ask spreads were priced and were a reasonable measure of liquidity.

Other quote-based liquidity measures include effective bid-ask spreads, the Roll (1984) mea-

sure, and Hasbrouck’s Gibbs estimate.3 Lesmond et al. (1999) argue that periods of zero

returns may represent an absence of informed trading, and as such, these periods tend to

correspond with a high cost of informed trading.

Variants of Kyle’s λ (Kyle (1985)) have also been used as a liquidity measure (see, e.g.,

Glosten and Harris (1988), Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1996), or Pastor and Stambaugh

(2003)). Bernhardt and Hughson (2002) estimate price impacts using a structural model

whose equilibrium, unlike Kyle’s, explicitly incorporates orders that are not pooled.

3Effective bid-ask spreads measure the spread between the trade price and quote midpoint. Roll (1984)focuses on how the tick size induces negative correlation in prices. Hasbrouck (2009) proposes a Bayesianplatform to generate a Gibbs estimate of Roll’s effective trading cost indicator.

8

Page 11: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Chordia et al. (2010), Angel et al. (2011), Kim and Murphy (2013), and others have ques-

tioned the accuracy and feasibility of many existing liquidity measures in a high frequency

trading world with tiny spreads and little depth at the inside quote. Holden and Jacobsen

(2014) document realized dollar spreads and share depth as low as 0.88¢ and 564 shares,

respectively, for a sample of randomly selected stocks in 2008. Today, liquidity concerns do

not revolve around avoiding minimum price ticks, so spreads do not capture liquidity from

that perspective. Order-splitting makes consecutive trades dependent (Hasbrouck (2009),

Easley et al. (2012)) and interpretations of estimates of λ heroic. Moreover, the high vol-

ume results in few instances of zero returns (Mazza (2013)). Further, the increased use of

hidden orders makes it difficult to accurately measure depth—a key parameter for many

order-based liquidity measures. Deuskar and Johnson (2012) propose a measure of liquidity

that uses information from the cumulative depth in the limit order book, rather than just

the inside quote. Unfortunately, using limit order book information is not feasible for most

applications. Moreover, this measure imperfectly captures dynamic order splitting.

In light of these issues, a new generation of liquidity measures has been developed based

on volume, rather than orders. These measures are less affected by dynamic order-splitting.

The most widely used is Amihud’s (2002) measure, which is based on the ratio of absolute

daily returns divided by daily dollar volume. This measure has been truly useful at explain-

ing the cross-section of returns, and indeed in time series (Amihud (2002) and Jones (2002)).

Goyenko et al. (2009) show that Amihud’s measure remains useful in the post-decimalization

era. With increased high frequency trading, however, such low frequency measures may lose

valuable information by aggregating across heterogeneous market activity conditions.

Acharya and Pedersen (2005) incorporate a portfolio-level aggregate of the Amihud liq-

uidity measure in a market model and argue that premia can be explained by covariations of

stock liquidity with market-wide return and this liquidity proxy. Akbas et al. (2011) extend

Acharya and Pederson (2005) by adding a measure of idiosyncratic liquidity volatility. They

show it is priced in the presence of systematic liquidity risk. These papers are related to

9

Page 12: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

research on the commonality of market-wide liquidity (e.g., Chordia et al. (2000) or Sadka

(2006)). In contrast, our focus is developing a new, robust measure of firm-specific liquidity.

Finally, we note that while conventional liquidity measures such as bid-ask spreads have

likely become flawed, they may still be sufficiently correlated with “true” liquidity that they

can serve as useful empirical proxies. As such, a contribution of our paper is to develop a

liquidity measure that relates liquidity to market activity, and to explore the extent to which

conventional measures can proxy for market-activity based liquidity measures.

I Measuring Market Activity

To start, we define a trade sequence and explain how we use the duration of a trade

sequence to measure market activity. Each year, we number trades in stock j sequentially,

using index nj. For trade nj, we use τj(nj), Qj(nj) and Pj(nj) to denote respectively, (i) its

time measured in seconds from the beginning of the year, (ii) its size (in shares), and (iii) its

price. We construct our market activity measure by calculating the time it takes to execute

a sequence of consecutive trades that have an aggregate value of at least Vj,t for stock j in

month t. Thus, a shorter duration indicates a more active market. For the reasons detailed

below, we set Vj,t to be proportional to stock j’s market capitalization at the end of the

previous month, Mj,t−1. The first trade sequence begins with the first trade of the year, and

each subsequent trade sequence begins with the first trade following the previous sequence.

Figure 1 illustrates a typical pattern.

Formally, we iteratively solve for the last trade of the kth trade sequence, k = {1, 2, 3, . . .}, as:

nkj = argminn∗

n∗∑

n=nk−1j +1

PCj (n)×Qj(n)

∣∣∣∣∣∣∣n∗∑

n=nk−1j +1

PCj (n)×Qj(n) ≥ Vj,t

, (1)

where n0j = 0 and the value of aggregate trades is measured using the previous day’s closing

10

Page 13: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

A: Dollar volume

0

Dollar

volu

me

Time

B: Cumulative dollar volume

dur(k−1) dur(k) dur(k+1)

V

0

Cum

ultiv

e d

olla

r volu

me

Time

Figure 1: An illustration of how we measure the durations of trade sequenceswith an aggregate value of at least Vj,t.

price, PCj (nj).

4 Then we obtain the duration of the kth trade sequence,

durj(k) = τj(nkj )− τj(nk−1j + 1), (2)

the corresponding return,

rj(k) =Pj(n

kj )

Pj(nk−1j + 1)

− 1, (3)

and the dollar value of the sequence,

DV OLj(k) =∑nk

j

n=nk−1j +1

PCj (n)×Qj(n). (4)

4The last quoted bid-ask midpoint is used when the closing price is not available.

11

Page 14: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

The per-dollar price impact for stock j of the kth trade sequence is

DIMPj(k) =|rj(k)|

DV OLj(k). (5)

Notice that we adjust returns by DV OLj(k), rather than Vj,t, since the size of the last trade,

nkj , typically exceeds the quantity required to deliver a cumulative value of Vj,t.

We construct trade sequences that span multiple trading days. However, since overnight

price adjustments could bias our empirical results, we exclude any sequence that spans mul-

tiple trading days (our estimates are robust to relaxing this exclusion). Constructing, but

excluding, overnight trade sequences ensures a random starting (ending) point for the first

(last) trade sequence of a given day, precluding any possible systematic bias associated with

always beginning (ending) the first (last) trade sequence at the open (close).

We sort the remaining trade sequences for stock j in month t into ten equally-sized

groups i according to their duration, where i = 1 has the shortest durations (highest market

activity) and i = 10 has the longest durations (lowest market activity). Each year, we also

sort firms into market capitalization deciles.

We can now compare the market impact of unwinding a given position at different market

activity levels. We employ two market impact measures:

• Price impact: Each year, for each stock, we calculate the mean of the absolute return

of each trade sequence in a given duration group. We then average these annual mean

absolute returns across years for all stocks in a given size decile.5

• Return volatility: Each year, for each stock, we calculate the standard deviation of the

return of trade sequences in each duration group. We then average these annual return

standard deviations across years for stocks in a given size decile. Computing annual

standard deviations before averaging minimizes temporal aggregation concerns.

Later, we use a scaled 3-month rolling average of the price impact measure, DIMPj(k), for

5Averaging stock-specific moments makes the average independent of number of sequences per stock.

12

Page 15: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

different subsets of trade sequences, as a priced liquidity measure, BBDj,t.

Choice of Vj,t. We focus on the market impact and the time to execute a sequence of

orders that for a firm j have an aggregate value Vj,t equal to θ% of its market capitalization

at the end of the previous month, Mj,t−1. Our base formulation using θ = 0.04 generates

a median duration (across stocks and years) of roughly 20 minutes. A robustness analysis

verifies that our qualitative findings are not driven by the choice of θ: qualitatively similar

findings obtain using θ = 0.03 or θ = 0.05.

Several considerations enter our choice of specification: (i) the positions are large enough

to be relevant for institutional traders, and to control for dynamic order splitting and divi-

sion of orders against the book; (ii) the positions are not so large that a single trade sequence

spans different market activity levels; (iii) the proportional specification captures the feature

that institutional traders tend to establish larger positions in larger firms, and it facilitates

cross-stock comparisons; (iv) the proportional specification flattens out the distribution of

durations across market capitalizations (see Figure 2). As a result, durations of small market

capitalization stocks are not too much longer, delivering enough observations for our empir-

ical analysis: we drop stock-year observations for stocks without enough trade sequences in

the year to avoid small sample issues, and setting θ = 0.04 ensures that we do not lose too

many stock-year observations, even in early years. In contrast, a fixed dollar-amount chosen

based on a medium-sized stock’s market capitalization would deliver too few observations

for small-cap firms, and far too many for large-cap firms.6

Comparisons with Gourieroux et al. (1999) and Easley et al. (2012). As in these

papers, we group individual trades together to deal with division of orders against the book,

dynamic order submission strategies, and so on. There are, however, important distinctions

between these approaches and ours. Easley et al. (2012) divide daily volume for a stock into

6Easley, et al. (2012) bundle trades into volume groups with size equal to 1/50 of annual daily tradevolume. This approach comes close to equalizing the number of bundles across stocks within and acrossyears, but bundle sizes expand sharply over time due to the explosion in trading volume. In contrast, ourapproach roughly preserves bundle size across years.

13

Page 16: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

50 roughly equally-sized bundles—meaning that they have different volume cutoffs on differ-

ent trading days. Importantly, with the explosion of trading volumes over the past decade,

the dollar values of these bundles have also exploded. This creates problems if one wants to

assess how trading costs have evolved over time, or to aggregate over time. Similar issues

arise with comparisons of stocks with different levels of market capitalization, or, of stocks

with similar market capitalizations, but different levels of market activity. In contrast, we

set our target dollar-volume to be a proportion of the firm’s market-capitalization. Thus, the

time durations of our trade sequences control for variations in clock-time speed; we find much

shorter time durations of trade sequences in more recent years with temporally comparable

dollar values. This feature facilitates temporal comparisons and temporal aggregation across

roughly homogeneous entities; and by controlling for market capitalization, one can, for ex-

ample, convert our characterizations into analyses of the costs of trading fixed dollar amounts.

Gourieroux et al. (1999) compute the time durations of fixed dollar positions. One con-

cern is that they use contemporaneous price to measure individual trade values, so their

notion of trade duration of fixed dollar positions is affected by intra-day price movements.

Ceteris paribus, this means that, on average, durations are shorter when prices move up,

and longer when they move down. To deal with this, we use the previous day’s closing price

to calculate trade values, so that durations of trade sequences are independent of contem-

poraneous price movements, allowing clean comparisons of the relationship between market

activity and trading costs.

A Data

Our sample period runs from January 1, 2001 to December 31, 2012. Each year, we con-

struct a sample of U.S.-based NYSE-listed ordinary common shares (CRSP share codes 10

and 11). We drop a stock-year observation if it has less than 800 trade sequences in the year,

or if the stock had a closing price7 below $1.00 on any trading day in the year. Monthly

7The average of the closing bid and ask prices is used if a last trade price is not available.

14

Page 17: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

market capitalizations of firms come from the CRSP monthly stock file. We sort stocks into

size-based deciles using their market capitalizations on the first trading day of a year. We

use the previous day’s closing price from the CRSP daily stock file to compute dollar volumes

so that duration measurements are not biased by any associated price impact.8

We calculate CAPM beta, βj,t, for stock j in month t by regressing excess weekly stock

returns (versus the weekly secondary market 6-month Treasury bill rate) against the excess

weekly market return, over the previous two-year period (t−24 to t−1). The market return,

rmktt is based on an equally-weighted portfolio of the stocks in our sample in that month. If a

stock is not listed over the previous 24 months, we employ the longest time period available,

requiring at least 26 weekly observations, where we drop the initial observation to avoid a

listing effect.9 Firm j’s book-to-market ratio, BMj,t−1, is given by its book value per share,

obtained from Compustat, divided by its share price, at the end of month t− 1.

We obtain trade prices, quantities and time stamps from the consolidated trade history in

the NYSE TAQ database. We consider all stock trades on U.S.-based trading venues during

regular market hours, i.e., between 9:30AM and 4:00PM (EST), together with trades corre-

sponding to delayed reporting of market-on-close orders that are executed after 4:00PM.10

We exclude trade sequences with absolute returns that exceed 10%. We calculate percentage

bid-ask spreads using the TAQ National Best Bid and Offer (NBBO) series on WRDS.

Table I presents annual summary sample statistics. Median stock prices largely mimic

overall market performance. The median annual number of trade sequences increases three-

fold over the sample period, reaching a peak of 6,305 in 2009 due to the lower market

capitalizations after the 2008 financial crisis. Notice that median market capitalizations are

almost equal in 2001 and 2009—the values of Vj,t are similar in those years. Despite this, the

median number of trade sequences is much higher in 2009, highlighting the large increase in

8Since we exclude trade sequences spanning more than one trading day, we do not need to adjust rj(k)for stock splits or dividend distributions.

9We discard the few observations where the estimated CAPM beta exceeds 10 or is less than −3.10These trades are flagged“MOC” in TAQ data.

15

Page 18: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Table I: Year-by-year summary statistics of the final sample. The closing shareprice, book-to-market ratio and log of market capitalization are reported as the mediansof their monthly values. $-spreads are the median time-weighted dollar bid-ask spread atthe NBBO. The last column reports the median number of trade sequences (each with anaggregate value of at least Vj,t) in a year across stocks.

Year # of Stocks Share Price Book-to-Market ln(Market Cap) $-spreads # of Sequences2001 1,091 26.50 0.47 21.14 0.072 2,2882002 1,181 24.78 0.49 21.11 0.052 2,5632003 1,170 23.62 0.53 20.98 0.035 2,7522004 1,277 28.86 0.45 21.28 0.031 2,9682005 1,268 30.95 0.43 21.41 0.030 3,3172006 1,277 32.75 0.41 21.53 0.030 3,8552007 1,255 33.70 0.41 21.63 0.029 4,9072008 1,277 24.28 0.53 21.31 0.030 6,2832009 1,198 19.62 0.67 21.11 0.023 6,3052010 1,192 24.95 0.55 21.37 0.020 5,2002011 1,183 28.66 0.50 21.54 0.022 5,0502012 1,169 29.09 0.52 21.52 0.024 4,296

trade volumes. Median dollar-spreads fall from 7.2¢ in 2001 to 2.4¢ in 2012.

B Overview of market activity measure

We first overview basic features of our market activity measure. Figure 2 illustrates how du-

rations of trade sequences vary over time and firm size. In a given year, duration and firm size

have a U-shaped relationship: while larger stocks are more actively traded, Vj,t is proportional

to firm size, which flattens the duration/firm size relationship, especially in recent years. The

very large positions for which we calculate durations for the largest stocks drive their longer

durations; and the modest trading activity for small stocks drives their longer durations.

Overall, the number of trade sequences does not vary wildly with market capitalization.

Durations tend to fall over time, consistent with the rise in market activity. The average

median duration for the second size decile of stocks falls from 33 minutes in 2001 to 26

minutes in 2012; while that for the largest stocks goes from 42 to 26 minutes. Durations are

shortest in 2009 due to the depressed market valuations in that year.

16

Page 19: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

5

15

25

35

45

Size decile

Av

era

ge

me

dia

n d

ura

tio

n (

min

ute

s)

Year

Figure 2: Duration of trade sequences by year and by firm size. The figurereports the average median duration (in minutes) of a sequence of trades with a cumulativeaggregate value of at least 0.04% of a firm’s market capitalization. The median duration isfirst calculated on a stock-by-stock basis, and then the average is taken across stocks withina size decile in a year. Size decile 1 contains the smallest firms; decile 10 contains the largest.

We next investigate how the distribution of durations is related to firm size. Figure 3 plots

the cumulative distribution functions (CDFs) of durations over the entire sample period for

representative small, medium and large market capitalization stocks: Hanger, Inc. (HGR),

Archer Daniels Midland Co. (ADM), and International Business Machines Corp. (IBM). All

three stocks have durations that are as short as a few seconds and as long as one hundred

minutes. The large firm (IBM) has far more evenly-distributed durations (its PDF has thin-

ner tails). In contrast, ADM and HGR have many more short durations (about 80% are less

than 40 minutes). HGR has fatter probability density function tails than ADM, indicating

greater contributions from very short and very long durations.

Because a single stock may be unrepresentative, we next compute CDFs of durations at

the stock size decile level, averaging across stocks in the decile. Figure 4 presents the esti-

mated CDFs for the three smallest and three largest size-deciles. Consistent with Figure 3,

Figure 4 shows the distributions for large stocks are far less skewed than those for small

stocks. To address the possibility that the distribution of the full sample could mix the tem-

17

Page 20: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

0

.2

.4

.6

.8

1

Cum

ulat

ive

Pro

babi

lity

0 20 40 60 80 100Duration (minutes)

ADM HGR IBM

Figure 3: Distribution of durations of trade sequences for three representativestocks. The figure plots the cumulative distribution functions of durations (in minutes)for International Business Machines Corp. (IBM), Archer Daniels Midland Co. (ADM),and Hanger, Inc. (HGR) from January 1, 2001 to December 31, 2012. Durations are basedon the elapsed time for a sequence of trades with a cumulative aggregate value of at least0.04% of the firm’s market capitalization.

poral effects of increasing market activity with the cross-sectional properties, we decompose

the sample into early and late years. The distributions of durations are more skewed in early

years. More generally, the qualitative pattern that CDFs of durations are more skewed for

smaller firms holds on a year-by-year basis, indicating greater variation in their activity levels.

II Analysis

Market activity, signed trade imbalances and trade size. We begin our substantial

analysis by documenting a well-known, but poorly understood, relationships between mar-

ket activity, signed trade imbalances and trade sizes. We use the Lee and Ready (1991)

algorithm to identify buyer- and seller-initiated trades.11 We define signed trade imbalance

11A trade is marked buyer-initiated (seller-initiated) if the execution price is above (below) the mid-pointquoted price. If the execution and mid-quote prices are the same, the trade is marked buyer-initiated(seller-initiated) if the execution price increased (decreased) with respect to the most recent trade.

18

Page 21: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

A-1

:S

mal

lfi

rms,

2001

-201

2A

-2:

Sm

all

firm

s,20

01–2

006

A-3

:S

mal

lfi

rms,

2007

–201

2

020406080100

Percentile

05

01

00

15

0T

rad

e d

ura

tio

n (

min

ute

s)

Siz

e d

ecile

1S

ize

de

cile

2S

ize

de

cile

3

020406080100

Percentile

05

01

00

15

0T

rad

e d

ura

tio

n (

min

ute

s)

Siz

e d

ecile

1S

ize

de

cile

2S

ize

de

cile

3

020406080100

Percentile

05

01

00

15

0T

rad

e d

ura

tio

n (

min

ute

s)

Siz

e d

ecile

1S

ize

de

cile

2S

ize

de

cile

3

B-1

:L

arg

efi

rms,

2001-2

012

B-2

:L

arge

firm

s,20

01–2

006

B-3

:L

arge

firm

s,20

07–2

012

020406080100

Percentile

02

04

06

08

01

00

Tra

de

du

ratio

n (

min

ute

s)

Siz

e d

ecile

8S

ize

de

cile

9S

ize

de

cile

10

020406080100

Percentile

02

04

06

08

01

00

Tra

de

du

ratio

n (

min

ute

s)

Siz

e d

ecile

8S

ize

de

cile

9S

ize

de

cile

10

020406080100

Percentile

02

04

06

08

01

00

Tra

de

du

ratio

n (

min

ute

s)

Siz

e d

ecile

8S

ize

de

cile

9S

ize

de

cile

10

Fig

ure

4:E

mp

iric

al

cum

ula

tive

densi

tyfu

nct

ions

of

dura

tion

by

size

deci

le.

Dura

tion

sar

eco

mpute

dbas

edon

θ=

0.04

and

thei

rC

DF

sar

epre

sente

dfo

rtw

osu

bse

tsof

larg

ean

dsm

all

stock

s,ov

erth

een

tire

per

iod

(200

1–20

12),

and

the

earl

y(2

001-

2006

)an

dla

ter

(200

7–20

12)

sub-p

erio

ds.

To

calc

ula

teth

eC

DF

ofdura

tion

sfo

rst

ockj

inye

ary,

ever

ym

onth

,w

efirs

tso

rtdura

tion

sin

to20

buck

ets,

each

conta

inin

g5%

ofob

serv

atio

ns.

Then

we

pool

buck

ets

acro

ssdiff

eren

tm

onth

s.T

he

med

ian

ofth

ese

dura

tion

sco

rres

pon

ds

toth

equan

tile

stat

isti

cfa

llin

gat

the

mid

poi

nt

ofth

atdura

tion

buck

et.

For

exam

ple

,th

em

edia

nin

the

pool

edbuck

etof

shor

test

5%es

tim

ates

quan

tile

stat

isti

c2.

5%;

that

for

nex

tbuck

etes

tim

ates

quan

tile

stat

isti

c7.

5%;

etc.

For

each

dura

tion

buck

et,

we

aver

age

the

stock

-sp

ecifi

cquan

tile

stat

isti

ces

tim

ates

over

year

san

dst

ock

sin

size

dec

ilex

.P

lott

ing

thes

eav

erag

esag

ainst

thei

rre

leva

nt

per

centi

lep

oints

,fo

rea

chsi

zep

ortf

olio

,yie

lds

the

empir

ical

CD

Fof

dura

tion

sco

ndit

ional

onfirm

size

.

19

Page 22: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

as the share of value-weighted trades out of the total dollar volume in a trade sequence that

is buyer- or seller-initiated (whichever is highest). We also look at how trade size relates to

market activity. To do this, we examine the relation between the number of trades that fill

a trade sequence and market activity—given the same dollar-volume comprising durations

at different levels of market activity, fewer trades reflect larger trades.

Figure 5 shows that (i) average signed trade imbalances rise with market activity—more

active markets feature more aggressive trading on one side of the market; (ii) average signed

trade imbalances rise especially sharply in highly active (short duration) markets; (iii) trade

sizes sharply rise with market activity; (iv) average signed trade imbalances decline with firm

size; and (v) changes in these measures become especially sharp in highly active markets.

The changes in these measures are large: going from least to most active markets, signed

trade imbalances rise by roughly 20%, and for smaller stocks, mean trade sizes double.

By themselves, these facts seem innocuous. Classical models of speculation (e.g., Kyle

(1985), Glosten (1993)) would suggest that signed trade imbalances and trade sizes should

rise with market activity: speculators with substantial private fundamental information will

establish substantial positions based on that information, demanding liquidity by submitting

larger market orders, which will cause market activity, signed trade imbalance, and trade

sizes all to rise.

But, those fundamentals can covary for very different reasons. If liquidity provision is

time varying—if markets are more liquid (“deeper” near good inside quotes) at some times

than others—then traders will respond endogenously to the extant liquidity in their order

composition. If liquidity is unusually high on one side, large traders submit larger market

orders that are filled at these prices, resulting in (i) higher market activity, (ii) fewer trades

comprising a trade sequence, and (iii) higher signed trade imbalances. In contrast, if depth

is modest, an institutional trader seeking to establish or unwind a large position must weigh

how to consume the limited liquidity available via market orders, and how much liquidity to

provide via limit orders in order to reduce price impacts, and the extent to which to delay

20

Page 23: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Small firms Large firms

.55

.6.6

5.7

.75

.8

Ave

rag

e s

ign

ed

tra

de

im

ba

lan

ce

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 1 Size decile 2 Size decile 3

.55

.6.6

5.7

.75

.8

Ave

rag

e s

ign

ed

tra

de

im

ba

lan

ce

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 8 Size decile 9 Size decile 10

02

55

07

51

00

Ave

rag

e n

um

be

r o

f tr

ad

es

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 1 Size decile 2 Size decile 3

05

00

10

00

15

00

Ave

rag

e n

um

be

r o

f tr

ad

es

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 8 Size decile 9 Size decile 10

Figure 5: Average signed dollar-volume and average number of trades by durationgroup. Average signed trade imbalance and average number of trades for trade sequenceswith cumulative value of 0.04% of market capitalization in 2001–2012 versus market activitylevel for the three deciles of smallest and largest stocks. Reported average signed tradeimbalance and average number of trades are, respectively, the average of firm-specificannual mean estimated signed trade imbalance and number of trades (realized over tradesequences), computed per duration group. The average of means is taken across all firms ina given size decile, over the entire sample period by activity level.

submitting orders until liquidity improves. As a result: (i) durations are longer, (ii) more

trades comprise a trade sequence, and (iii) signed trade is more balanced.

Market activity and price impacts. Thus, both information arrival and endogenous liq-

uidity provision choices can lead to higher signed trade imbalances and larger trades in more

active markets. The question becomes: which is it? Reflection suggests how to get at an-

swers: if higher signed trade imbalances reflect information arrival, then price impacts should

rise with market activity; but if high signed trade imbalances reflect endogenous consumption

of unusually high depth at good prices, then price impacts should fall with market activity.

21

Page 24: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Small firms Large firms

.3.4

.5.6

.7.8

Ave

rag

e a

bso

lute

re

turn

(%

)

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 1 Size decile 2 Size decile 3

.24

.26

.28

.3.3

2.3

4

Ave

rag

e a

bso

lute

re

turn

(%

)

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 8 Size decile 9 Size decile 10

.6.8

11

.2

Ave

rag

e r

etu

rn s

tan

da

rd d

evia

tio

n (

%)

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 1 Size decile 2 Size decile 3

.4.4

2.4

4.4

6.4

8

Ave

rag

e r

etu

rn s

tan

da

rd d

evia

tio

n (

%)

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 8 Size decile 9 Size decile 10

Figure 6: Average absolute return and return volatility by duration group.Market impacts of θ = 0.04% of market capitalization in 2001–2012 versus market activitylevel for the three deciles of smallest and largest stocks. The reported average price impactis the average of firm-specific monthly means of absolute returns (realized over tradesequences), computed per duration group. Reported average return volatility is the averageof firm-specific monthly standard deviations of returns (realized over trade sequences),computed per duration group. The averages of means and standard deviations are takenover all firms in a given size decile, over the entire sample period by activity level.

Figure 6 shows how our two market impact measures vary with market activity. For small

and mid-sized stocks, both mean absolute returns and the standard deviation of returns12 fall

sharply as market activity rises.13 This activity-impact relationship is quite pronounced for

smaller firms. For the decile of smallest firms, the price impact of the same dollar volume rises

by almost 50% as markets go from highest to lowest activity levels. This finding indicates

12In the Appendix, we calculate the implied calendar time volatility were the market activity to stayconstant over a fixed time interval (e.g., a trading day). This approach is a better way to measure activityover time because it does not mix different levels of activity that might arise over a non-trivial interval oftime. We show that the implied calendar time volatility rises with market activity.

13The unreported patterns for mid-sized stocks (4 ≤ x ≤ 7) are similar to those of smaller stocks.

22

Page 25: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

that for small and mid-sized firms, time varying liquidity provision and consumption drive the

market activity/trade size/signed trade imbalance relationships, and not information arrival.

In contrast, for larger stocks, market impacts do not fall monotonically as market activity

rises. Instead, they peak at relatively high market activity levels. For the decile of largest

firms, market impacts are smallest when markets are least active. Volatility falls off sharply

in less active markets, dropping over 20% from its peak. The patterns for larger stocks reflect

that the tails of their return distributions are quite fat in active markets—suggesting that

for large stocks, information arrival sometimes boosts market activity.14

To affirm these conclusions, we order observed returns for a stock within each duration

group over a year. We then find annual percentile statistics for the return within each dura-

tion (activity) group, on a stock-by-stock basis. Next, we average these percentile statistics

across all stock-years by duration group to obtain the average return, rπ for a percentile π.

Finally, we calculate inter-percentile ranges (e.g., r.99−r.01). Figure 7 depicts the relationship

between inter-percentile ranges and market activity for the smallest and largest firms.

For larger stocks, (i) the interpercentile range r.99−r.01 is highest when markets are most

active—extreme returns are most likely in active markets, and least likely in inactive mar-

kets, reflecting that substantial information arrival results in more active markets; but (ii)

the interpercentile ranges of intermediate percentile statistics (e.g., r.75 − r.25) rise slightly

as activity rises from low to intermediate activity levels, before declining non-trivially as

activity rises at high activity levels, indicating that endogenous liquidity consumption also

drives these price impacts. This combination underlies the single-peak patterns of average

mean returns and return volatility in market activity for large stocks. In contrast, for small

firms, all inter-percentile ranges narrow uniformly as market activity rises.

Thus, endogenous liquidity provision and consumption seems to drive market activity

14In unreported results, we find that trade sequences with longer durations are more likely to start or endnear midday (between 11:45AM and 2:00PM), whereas those with shorter durations are more likely near thebeginning and end of trading days. To ensure that observed patterns are not a time-of-day phenomenon, werepeat the analysis conditioning on the start and end times of trade sequences, for three equally-long windowsover a trading day corresponding to early-, mid-, and late-day. We find similar patterns in each window.

23

Page 26: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Smallest size decile (x = 1) Largest size decile (x = 10)

02

46

Ave

rage

ret

urn

(%)

Low Medium HIghActivity level

r.99−r.01 r.95−r.05 r.75−r.25

.51

1.5

22.

53

Ave

rage

ret

urn

(%)

Low Medium HighActivity level

r.99−r.01 r.95−r.05 r.75−r.25

Figure 7: Estimated interpercentile ranges for realized returns by duration group.Plot of the interpercentile ranges of the distribution of realized returns for different marketactivity levels. The percentile statistics of returns (realized over trade sequences) are firstcomputed stock-by-stock, annually, for each duration group, and then averaged acrossstocks/years. Finally, the differences between selected average percentile statistics (r.99−r.01,r.95− r.05, and r.75− r.25) are computed by activity group. Durations are based on θ = 0.04.

patterns for small and mid-sized firms. For these stocks, price impacts are uniformly smaller

in active markets. This is inconsistent with information arrival driving market impacts. In-

stead, this evidence together with the evidence that the signed trade imbalances also rise

with market activity indicates that active markets are driven by traders choosing to quickly

consume unusually high depth near good inner quotes. In contrast, for large stocks, time-

varying liquidity provision seems to drive the market impact-market activity relationship in

“normal” times (captured by less extreme percentile differences); while in “unusual” times,

high information arrival results in active markets and high price impacts.

To affirm these conclusions, Figure 8 presents the relationship between signed trade im-

balances and (i) mean absolute returns, (ii) return volatility, and (iii) mean number of trades

in a trade sequence. Save for the largest stocks, price impacts and mean number of trades

fall as signed trade imbalance rises.15

In sum, for small and mid-sized stocks, more aggressive trading on one side of the market

is associated with higher market activity, but smaller price impacts. These patterns are

15In unreported results, we verify that these results hold within each level of market activity.

24

Page 27: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Small firms Large firms

.3.4

.5.6

.7

Ave

rag

e a

bso

lute

re

turn

(%

)

.24

.26

.28

.3.3

2.3

4

Ave

rag

e a

bso

lute

re

turn

(%

)

.6.7

.8.9

11

.1

Ave

rag

e r

etu

rn s

tan

da

rd d

evia

tio

n (

%)

.4.4

2.4

4.4

6

Ave

rag

e r

etu

rn s

tan

da

rd d

evia

tio

n (

%)

025

50

75

100

Avera

ge n

um

ber

of tr

ades

Low HighSigned trade imbalance

Size decile 1 Size decile 2 Size decile 3

0500

1000

1500

Avera

ge n

um

ber

of tr

ades

Low HighSigned trade imbalance

Size decile 8 Size decile 9 Size decile 10

Figure 8: Average absolute return, return volatility, and average number oftrades by signed trade imbalance group. Average absolute return, average returnvolatility, and mean number of trades for a trade sequence with cumulative value equalto 0.04% of market capitalization in 2001–2012 versus signed trade imbalance for decilesof smaller and larger stocks. We first sort trade sequences into ten equally-sized groupsof percent signed trades, every month. The reported averages are the sample averages offirm-specific annually-computed mean absolute return, return standard deviation, and meanrealized depth (all assessed over sequences), computed per signed trade imbalance group.The averages of means are taken across all firms in a given size decile, over the entire sampleperiod by signed trade imbalance level.

inconsistent with the predictions of classical models of speculation—Kyle-style competitive

dealership markets and Glosten-style competitive limit order markets. In the former, in-

formed traders optimally choose market order sizes, and dealers set an asset’s price equal to

25

Page 28: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

its expected value given the information in net order flow. In the latter, each informed trader

chooses the size of his limit order when competitive liquidity providers price limit orders to

break even conditional on the information contained in the fact that their limit orders were

filled. In both of these settings, larger orders or greater net order flows, i.e., greater signed

trade imbalance, have greater price impacts—the opposite of what we document.

A key premise of these models is that market liquidity is invariant: traders do not have to

choose between consuming and supplying liquidity when establishing or unwinding positions.

In contrast, our findings highlight the impact of time-varying, imperfectly competitive liq-

uidity provision, and the consequences for traders’ choices of how much liquidity to consume

and provide (see, for example, Goettler, Parlour and Rajan (2005), Hollifield, Miller and

Sandas (2004), and Hollifield et al. (2006)). For most stocks, the impacts of the endogenous

choice of order type in response to extant liquidity dominate the predicted relationships

between signed flow, market activity and price impact of standard models of speculation.

Controlling for information arrival and endogenous liquidity consumption. An in-

stitutional investor seeking to establish or unwind a large position would like to time trading

according to market activity in order to minimize trading costs. Such an investor, however,

presumably cannot exploit information arrival to which it is not privy, nor predict when

liquidity provision on the other side of the market will be “unusually high”. This leads us

to try to separate the impacts of information arrival and the endogenous consumption and

provision of liquidity, in order to isolate more primitive market activity/trading cost rela-

tionships that are more stable and predictable. We seek to identify predictable variation in

“real” market activity that may reflect, for example, variation in general investor interest in

trading a stock, and see how trading costs vary with predicted market activity conditions.

To control for endogeneity and information arrival, we use the number of trades filling

the previous trade sequence to instrument for the duration of current trade sequence (cur-

rent market activity). The observation underlying our choice of instrument is that liquidity

persists over time—present and past states of the order book are positively correlated. The

26

Page 29: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

endogenous composition of orders, however, hinges only on the contemporaneous state of the

order book, which strongly covaries with current activity as a result. Any effects of past states

of the order book on the current price impact only transmit via the current state of the book.

Using instrumented market activity also filters out the variation associated with information

arrival which is, presumably, unpredictable.16 We next present evidence that cumulatively

indicates that the number of trades in the previous sequence is a valid instrument.

For each stock, we first regress the natural logarithm of duration on a quadratic polyno-

mial of the number of trades in the previous trade sequence, annually (fitting these regres-

sions annually accounts for temporal changes in order sizes).17 The fitted values of these

regressions serve as instrumented levels of activity. We then sort the monthly samples by

instrumented activity and investigate relationships just as we did with raw durations.

To document the instrument’s merits, we start by estimating the linear correlation be-

tween current duration and the number of trades filling the previous trade sequence for each

stock-year. The empirical distribution of this statistic reveals the significance of the correla-

tion parameter for a typical stock. The top row of Figure 9 shows this empirical distribution

for different-sized firms. The correlation coefficient is positive and large for a typical stock in

each size category. Its average rises from 0.2 for small stocks to 0.25 for large stocks. Thus,

past liquidity predicts current activity, especially for larger stocks.

The bottom row of Figure 9 presents the empirical distributions of the F -statistics for the

significance of the first stage log-polynomial regressions at the stock-year level. Over 95%

of the F-statistics exceed 10, indicating that the past number of trades is a valid statistical

instrument for market activity (Staiger and Stock (1997) suggest that F = 10 is a reasonable

cutoff when there is one instrument).

One might be concerned that this persistence could be mirrored by equal persistence

16Recall that we provide evidence that information arrival is more pronounced for larger firms in moreactive market conditions.

17Linear or higher order polynomial specifications lead to similar results; but the quadratic specificationhas the strongest first stage fit.

27

Page 30: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Sm

all

stock

s(D

ecil

es1

to3)

Mid

-siz

edst

ock

s(D

ecil

es4

to7)

Lar

gest

ock

s(D

ecil

es8

to10

)01234

Density

−.5

0.5

1C

orr

ela

tio

n b

etw

ee

n d

ura

tio

n a

nd

la

gg

ed

eff

ective

de

pth

01234Density

−.2

0.2

.4.6

.8C

orr

ela

tio

n b

etw

ee

n d

ura

tio

n a

nd

la

gg

ed

nu

mb

er

of

tra

de

s

01234Density

−.2

0.2

.4.6

.8C

orr

ela

tio

n b

etw

ee

n d

ura

tio

n a

nd

la

gg

ed

nu

mb

er

of

tra

de

s

Sm

all

stock

s(D

ecil

es1

to3)

Mid

-siz

edst

ock

s(D

ecil

es4

to7)

Lar

gest

ock

s(D

ecil

es8

to10

)

0.001.002.003.004.005Density

01

00

20

03

00

40

05

00

F−

sta

tistic

0.001.002.003.004.005Density

01

00

20

03

00

40

05

00

F−

sta

tistic

0.001.002.003.004.005Density

01

00

20

03

00

40

05

00

F−

sta

tistic

Fig

ure

9:E

mp

iric

al

dis

trib

uti

on

of

linear

corr

ela

tions

and

log-p

oly

nom

ialF

-sta

tist

ics

by

size

deci

le.

Inth

eto

pgr

aphs,

for

each

stock

-yea

rob

serv

atio

n,

we

find

the

the

corr

elat

ion

bet

wee

ncu

rren

tdura

tion

and

lagg

ednum

ber

oftr

ades

.T

he

kern

elden

sity

ofth

ese

corr

elat

ion

coeffi

cien

tsis

esti

mat

edby

size

grou

ps.

Inth

eb

otto

mgr

aphs,

for

each

stock

-yea

rob

serv

atio

n,

the

curr

ent

log

dura

tion

isre

gres

sed

ona

quad

rati

cp

olynom

ial

ofth

ela

gged

effec

tive

dep

than

dth

eco

rre-

spon

din

gF

-sta

tist

icis

obta

ined

.W

eth

enes

tim

ate,

by

size

grou

ps,

the

kern

elden

sity

for

the

empir

ical

dis

trib

uti

ons

ofth

eF

-sta

tist

ics.

The

vert

ical

das

hed

lines

indic

ateF

-sta

tist

ics

equal

to10

.V

alues

grea

ter

than

250

are

omit

ted

for

vis

ual

clar

ity.

28

Page 31: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

in the endogenous provision and consumption of liquidity, which would render futile our

efforts to distinguish between them. To establish that this is not so, we first calculate the

analogous first stage regressions with signed trade imbalance, rather than market activity,

as the endogenous variable. In these unreported results, only about 75% of the associated

F -statistics exceed 10, indicating a weaker relationship between past number of trades and

signed trade imbalance than that with activity.

Our next validation step explores how signed trade imbalances vary with the levels of

activity and instrumented activity. If the endogenous consumption and provision of liquidity

can be predicted in the same way as market activity then these two patterns should be sim-

ilar. To see whether this is so, we first sort the monthly samples of each stock into deciles of

instrumented activity. In each decile, we find the annual mean signed trade imbalance, on

a stock-by-stock basis. Lastly, we calculate the averages of those means across stocks and

years by instrumented activity level. We do the same exercise sorting initially on activity,

in order to compare the patterns of interest. To ensure this comparison is statistically valid,

we restrict the analysis to stocks whose first stage regression F -statistics exceed 10.

Figure 10 shows that signed trade imbalances still co-vary with instrumented market ac-

tivity. However, this association is much weaker than that with the level of market activity

itself. Concretely, the relative change in average signed trade imbalance as market activity

rises from its lowest level to its highest is at least twice what it is as instrumented market

activity goes from its lowest level to its highest. In sharp contrast, we now show that instru-

mentation has dramatic effects on trading cost/market (instrumented) activity relationships.

Figure 11 presents the relationship between mean price impacts and instrumented market

activity—detailing how trading costs vary with predictable components of market activity.

Instrumentation delivers consistent patterns between trading costs and predicted activity for

all stock size groups. For smaller stocks, the relationship between trading costs and predicted

market activity becomes far flatter than the relationship between price impact and actual

market activity—the difference in price impacts between inactive and active markets falls

29

Page 32: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Siz

ed

ecil

e1

Siz

ed

ecil

e2

Siz

ed

ecil

e3

.55.6.65.7.75.8

Average signed trade imbalance

Low

High

Activity/I

nstr

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

atio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.55.6.65.7.75.8

Average signed trade imbalance

Low

High

Activity/I

nstr

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.55.6.65.7.75.8

Average signed trade imbalance

Low

High

Activity/I

nstr

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

Siz

ed

ecil

e8

Siz

ed

ecil

e9

Siz

ed

ecil

e10

.55.6.65.7.75.8

Average signed trade imbalance

Low

High

Activity/I

nstr

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.55.6.65.7.75.8

Average signed trade imbalance

Low

High

Activity/I

nstr

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.55.6.65.7.75.8

Average signed trade imbalance

Low

High

Activity/I

nstr

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

Fig

ure

10:

Avera

ge

signed

trade

by

inst

rum

ente

dact

ivit

y(d

ura

tion)

gro

up.

Ave

rage

sign

edtr

ade

imbal

ance

of0.

04%

ofm

arke

tca

pit

aliz

atio

nin

2001

–201

2ve

rsus

inst

rum

ente

dac

tivit

yle

vel

for

the

dec

iles

ofsm

alle

ran

dla

rger

stock

s.T

he

rep

orte

dav

erag

esi

gned

-dol

lar

volu

me

isth

eav

erag

eof

firm

-sp

ecifi

can

nual

mea

ndol

lar-

wei

ghte

dpro

por

tion

ofbuy-

(sel

l-)

orie

nte

dtr

ades

(rea

lize

dov

ertr

ade

sequen

ces)

,co

mpute

dp

erin

stru

men

ted

acti

vit

ygr

oup.

The

aver

age

ofm

eans

ista

ken

acro

ssal

lfirm

sin

agi

ven

size

dec

ile,

over

the

enti

resa

mple

per

iod

by

inst

rum

ente

dac

tivit

ygr

oup.

Ave

rage

sign

edtr

ade

atea

chgr

oup

ofac

tivit

yis

dis

pla

yed

tohig

hligh

tdiff

eren

ces.

Sto

ck-y

ear

obse

rvat

ions

wit

hfirs

tst

age

regr

essi

onF

-sta

tist

ics

less

than

10ar

edro

pp

ed.

30

Page 33: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Siz

ed

ecil

e1

Siz

ed

ecil

e2

Siz

ed

ecil

e3

.3.4.5.6.7.8Average absolute return (%)

Low

High

Activity/I

nstr

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.3.4.5.6.7.8Average absolute return (%)

Low

High

Activity /

In

str

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.3.4.5.6.7.8Average absolute return (%)

Low

High

Activity /

In

str

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

Siz

ed

ecil

e8

Siz

ed

ecil

e9

Siz

ed

ecil

e10

.25.27.29.31.33.35Average absolute return (%)

Low

High

Activity /

In

str

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.25.27.29.31.33.35Average absolute return (%)

Low

High

Activity /

In

str

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

.25.27.29.31.33.35Average absolute return (%)

Low

High

Activity /

In

str

um

en

ted

activity

No

in

str

um

en

tatio

nW

ith

in

str

um

en

tatio

n

Fig

ure

11:

Avera

ge

ab

solu

tere

turn

by

inst

rum

ente

dact

ivit

ygro

up.

Ave

rage

abso

lute

retu

rnof

0.04

%of

mar

ket-

cap

in20

01–2

012

vers

us

inst

rum

ente

dac

tivit

yle

vel

for

the

dec

iles

ofsm

alle

ran

dla

rger

stock

s.T

he

rep

orte

dav

erag

eab

solu

tere

turn

isth

eav

erag

eof

firm

-sp

ecifi

can

nual

mea

nab

solu

tere

turn

(rea

lize

dov

ertr

ade

sequen

ces)

,co

mpute

dp

erin

stru

men

ted

acti

vit

ygr

oup.

The

aver

age

ofm

eans

ista

ken

acro

ssal

lfirm

sin

agi

ven

size

dec

ile,

over

the

enti

resa

mple

per

iod

by

inst

rum

ente

dac

tivit

yle

vel.

Ave

rage

abso

lute

retu

rnve

rsus

acti

vit

yis

also

dis

pla

yed

tohig

hligh

tdiff

eren

ces.

Sto

ck-y

ear

obse

rvat

ions

wit

hfirs

tst

age

regr

essi

onF

-sta

tist

ics

bel

ow10

are

dro

pp

ed.

31

Page 34: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

from about 30 basis points to about 7. This finding, in part, highlights the apparently more

pronounced market-chasing of liquidity providing orders in less active markets of smaller

stocks that lead to large cumulative price impacts. For larger stocks, instrumentation has

dramatic effects: the non-monotone relationship between activity and price impact vanishes.

Instead, the average price impact falls as instrumented market activity rises, just like with

smaller stocks. Moreover, the difference between the peak and trough of the trading cost ac-

tivity relationship rises. Although trading costs are higher for smaller stocks, the percentage

decline in trading costs as we go from less active to more active predicted market conditions

is qualitatively the same for all stock size groups.

This uniform relationship indicates that the instrumentation removes the effects of infor-

mation arrival and endogenous liquidity consumption, which varies sharply with stock size.

Indeed, by contrasting the activity/price impact relationships with and without instrumenta-

tion, one can identify the key roles that the contemporaneous choice of order type and infor-

mation arrival play to shape the relationships between market impacts and trading activity.

Temporal changes. Figure 12 plots the ratio of trading costs during the later (2007–2012)

and earlier (2001–2006) time periods at different levels of instrumented market activity. This

time decomposition corresponds to the massive structural changes in U.S. equity markets

which occurred after the implementation of RegNMS in 2006. While bid-ask spreads are

smaller in later years, the evolution of the costs of trading large positions of relevance to in-

stitutional traders is more nuanced. First, while the costs of trading larger stocks have fallen

in more recent years, at each predicted market activity level, the costs of trading small stocks

have risen (the ratio of costs uniformly exceeds one for the decile of smallest stocks, and it ex-

ceeds one in active markets for small and mid-sized firms). Second, the sensitivity of trading

costs to predicted market activity has fallen for small stocks, but risen for very large stocks.

Regression Analysis. We now augment this non-parametric analysis with a formal regres-

sion analysis, estimating the relationship between trading costs and instrumented market ac-

tivity. To standardize measurements across stocks and simplify interpretations, each month

32

Page 35: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Avera

ge

pri

ce

imp

acts

A-1

:S

mall

stock

sA

-2:

Mid

-siz

edst

ock

sA

-3:

Lar

gest

ock

s.75.85.951.051.15

Ratio of trading costs

Low

High

Instr

um

en

ted

activity le

ve

l

Siz

e d

ecile

1S

ize

de

cile

2S

ize

de

cile

3

.75.85.951.051.15

Ratio of trading costs

Low

High

Instr

um

en

ted

activity le

ve

l

Siz

e d

ecile

4S

ize

de

cile

5S

ize

de

cile

6S

ize

de

cile

7

.75.85.951.051.15

Ratio of trading costs

Low

High

Instr

um

en

ted

activity le

ve

l

Siz

e d

ecile

8S

ize

de

cile

9S

ize

de

cile

10

Avera

ge

retu

rnvola

tility

B-1

:S

mall

stock

sB

-2:

Mid

-siz

edst

ock

sB

-3:

Lar

gest

ock

s

.75.85.951.051.15

Ratio of trading costs

Low

High

Instr

um

en

ted

activity le

ve

l

Siz

e d

ecile

1S

ize

de

cile

2S

ize

de

cile

3

.75.85.951.051.15

Ratio of trading costs

Low

High

Instr

um

en

ted

activity le

ve

l

Siz

e d

ecile

4S

ize

de

cile

5S

ize

de

cile

6S

ize

de

cile

7

.75.85.951.051.15

Ratio of trading costs

Low

High

Instr

um

en

ted

activity le

ve

l

Siz

e d

ecile

8S

ize

de

cile

9S

ize

de

cile

10

Fig

ure

12:

Tra

din

gco

sts

in2007–2012

rela

tive

totr

adin

gco

sts

in2001–2006.

The

plo

tssh

owth

era

tio

ofav

erag

etr

adin

gco

sts

in(2

007–

2012

)to

aver

age

trad

ing

cost

sin

(200

1–20

06),

atdiff

eren

tle

vels

ofin

stru

men

ted

mar

ket

acti

vit

yfo

rdec

iles

ofsm

alle

ran

dla

rger

stock

s.T

he

aver

age

abso

lute

retu

rnis

the

aver

age

offirm

-sp

ecifi

can

nual

mea

nab

solu

tere

turn

(rea

lize

dov

ertr

ade

sequen

ces)

,co

mpute

dp

erin

stru

men

ted

acti

vit

ygr

oup.

The

aver

age

ofm

eans

ista

ken

acro

ssal

lfirm

sin

agi

ven

size

dec

ile,

wit

hin

each

sub-p

erio

dby

inst

rum

ente

dac

tivit

ygr

oup.

Tra

de

sequen

ces

are

calc

ula

ted

bas

edon

0.04

%of

mar

ket

capit

aliz

atio

n.

33

Page 36: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

we sort a stock’s trade sequences from longest to shortest durations to generate percentiles

of instrumented activity on a monthly basis.18 We employ two types of regression analyses:

1. We regress the absolute return (in basis points) realized over a trade sequence on the

corresponding instrumented activity percentile, per stock-year. To make inferences,

we use the empirical distributions of the slope coefficients from these regressions. We

treat these point estimates as a random sample. Relying on the central limit theorem,

we use the sample mean and standard deviation of slope point estimates to construct

confidence intervals for the average slope for a given size decile.

2. We pool observations across stocks in a size decile over time, inversely weighting ob-

servations for a stock by the number of trade sequences it has in the year (to account

for heterogeneity across stocks in the number of trade sequences). For each decile, we

then regress absolute returns (in basis points) on instrumented activity percentile.

The mean stock-specific slope in the first approach and the point estimate of the slope in

the second, measure by how much (in basis points) trading costs change as instrumented

activity rises from the 1st percentile to the 99th.

Table II shows that both estimation methods deliver qualitatively identical sensitivities

of trading costs to market activity at a given size decile. The estimates indicate that trading

costs fall as instrumented activity rises—the trading costs of establishing or unwinding a

position equal to 0.04% of a stock’s market capitalization fall by 4–8 basis points going from

a market with the least predicted activity to one with the greatest predicted activity. In it

relative terms, price impacts rise by about 12% as one goes from markets with the greatest

predicted activity to the those with the least. The estimates also reveal that the predicted

cost saving from trading in active markets is greater for smaller stocks—the sensitivity of

trading costs to activity roughly doubles as one goes from the largest decile of stocks to the

18Thus, if a stock has 200 trade sequences in a month, the longest duration becomes percentile 0.5, andthe shortest duration becomes percentile 100.

34

Page 37: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Table II: Sensitivity of trading costs to the variation in instrumented activity. For

each stock-year observation, the absolute return realized over a trade sequence is regressed on

the corresponding activity percentile. The empirical distributions of these point estimates within

each size decile are employed to draw statistical inference. The sampling distribution is assumed

to follow a student t distribution (panel A). Observations are pooled across stocks within a size

decile. Absolute return is regressed on the corresponding activity percentile; partial regression

outputs are reported (panel B). The point estimates reflect the amount by which trading costs

change as instrumented market activity rises from lowest to highest percentile.

Panel A: Stock level estimates Panel B: Size group level estimatesSize decile Mean slope Std. Dev. 95% CI Estimate Std. Err. 95% CI

1 −7.91 13.90 (−8.64,−7.18) −7.60 0.14 (−7.86,−7.33)2 −8.23 11.27 (−8.82−7.65) −7.92 0.09 (−8.10,−7.74)3 −7.29 8.43 (−7.73,−6.86) −7.13 0.07 (−7.26,−7.00)4 −6.99 7.25 (−7.37,−6.62) −6.93 0.06 (−7.05,−6.81)5 −6.29 6.40 (−6.62,−5.95) −6.23 0.05 (−6.33,−6.13)6 −5.60 5.75 (−5.90,−5.30) −5.58 0.05 (−5.67,−5.48)7 −5.37 5.50 (−5.65,−5.09) −5.41 0.04 (−5.49,−5.32)8 −5.19 5.45 (−5.47,−4.91) −5.20 0.04 (−5.28,−5.12)9 −4.95 5.25 (−5.22,−4.68) −4.97 0.04 (−5.05,−4.88)10 −3.98 5.79 (−4.28,−3.68) −4.15 0.05 (−4.25,−4.04)

smallest. These findings are consistent with our non-parametric findings illustrated in Fig-

ure 11. Moreover, we predict market activity using a relatively simple prediction procedure.

Thus, these trading cost savings presumably constitute a lower bound on potential savings,

as investors may employ more sophisticated methods to predict market activity than our

simple procedure.

III Priced liquidity

The revolutionary changes in the design of equity markets and the way institutions opti-

mally trade large positions may mean that traditional liquidity measures no longer capture

the impact of individual stock liquidity on asset prices. We now investigate whether our

trade time liquidity measures better measure the impact of liquidity on asset prices, and, if

so, which one is best. A priori, it is not obvious which market activity levels matter “most”

35

Page 38: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

to traders who care about price impacts of unwinding positions—price impacts are higher

in less active markets, but institutional traders may be able to time trades in accordance

with market activity. We now show that our trade time liquidity measures better measure

the impact of liquidity on asset prices than traditional measures, and that estimates do not

qualitatively hinge on which of our trade time liquidity measures is used.

We consider nine variants of our liquidity measure, based on different sorts of the trade

sequences on a monthly, stock-by-stock basis. The first sort focuses on only the 40% of trade

sequences with medium levels of signed trade imbalance, which crudely controls for the level

of signed trade imbalance. Within these trade sequences, we sort by activity level (duration).

The other two sorts are conducted over all trade sequences: we sort observations into low,

medium, and high levels of instrumented market activity or raw market activity.

Sort Category Sort Criteria for Trade Sequences

ζ = 1 Lowest 30% of activity levels, medium signed trade imbalanceζ = 2 Middle 40% of activity levels, medium signed trade imbalanceζ = 3 Highest 30% of activity levels, medium signed trade imbalance

ζ = 4 Lowest 30% of instrumented activity levelζ = 5 Middle 40% of instrumented activity levelζ = 6 Highest 30% of instrumented activity level

ζ = 7 Lowest 30% of activity levelζ = 8 Middle 40% of activity levelζ = 9 Highest 30% of activity level

Our trade-time liquidity measure using sort category ζ for stock j in month t, BBDζj,t, is

the average per-dollar absolute returns (scaled by 106) of stock j’s trade sequences in that

category, during the 3-month period ending the last day of month t.

We estimate an augmented CAPM that includes book-to-market, size, and the BBD

liquidity measure as pricing factors:

rj,t − rft = γ0 + γ1βj,t(rmktt − rft ) + γ2BMj,t−1 + γ3Ln(Mj,t−1) + γ4BBD

ζj,t−1 (6)

+120∑m=4

γm5 Dumm + γ6∆(Y IR)j,t + εj,t,

where ∆(Y IR)j,t denotes the change (from month t − 1) in the difference between the in-

36

Page 39: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

dustry and market return rmktt , where stock j is excluded when computing the return of the

industry to which stock j belongs. Dumm = 1 if j is observed in month m and is 0 other-

wise.19 These monthly dummies capture any common variation in excess returns resulting,

for example, from changes in the trading environment.

We use GLS estimation with stock fixed effects in the error term. This strategy helps

identify excess return differences caused by unobserved temporally-constant firm attributes.

We allow for firm clusters and estimate robust standard errors to avoid downward biases in

standard error estimates that might result from firm-specific serial correlations in the error

term.20 We control for time-specific error term autocorrelations using ∆(Y IR): ∆(Y IR)

captures common industry shocks that could lead to contemporaneously correlated errors

for stocks in the same industry. In the appendix, we establish robustness of our findings to

alternative ways of dealing with the error term structure. As in Amihud (2002), we drop the

top 1% of observations according to the liquidity factor(s) each month.21 We only drop the

highest values since the measure is positive by construction and has a positively skewed dis-

tribution. Trimming the upper tail helps avoid spurious results driven by the high variability

of extreme observations.22

Table III presents estimates of (6) using each of our nine sort criteria (ζ). All coefficients

have the expected signs and are statistically significant. Regardless of which sort criteria is

used, the coefficient of BBDt−1 is positive and significant, and the overall explanatory power

of each regression is similar. BBD reflects the price impact per million dollars. Substituting

in the median level of BBD yields the monthly return premium that investors demand on

average for facing the cost of possibly unwinding a million dollar position of a typical stock

19The sample period begins in April 2001, due to our three-month rolling window construction.20Petersen (2009) discusses the benefits of this estimation strategy.21Amihud (2002) also trims the bottom 1%; this has no qualitative effects on estimates. We also obtain

similar estimates with alternative trimming thresholds (e.g., top 2% or top 5%).22We also perform these estimates within subsamples of size and time. Each year, we decompose the

samples into three size categories according to their beginning-of-the-year market capitalizations. Then weestimate (6) for each size category in sub-periods 2001–2006 and 2007–2012. The results are qualitativelysimilar to those reported here, with the caveat that the coefficient of illiquidity for the subsample of largestocks becomes insignificant (likely due to the small sample size).

37

Page 40: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Tab

leII

I:A

ugm

ente

dC

AP

Min

cludin

gtr

ade-t

ime

liquid

ity

measu

re.

The

table

rep

orts

esti

mat

ion

resu

lts

for

(6)

usi

ng

the

trim

med

sam

ple

,w

her

eth

eer

ror

term

allo

ws

for

stock

fixed

effec

ts.

Sta

ndar

der

rors

are

clust

ered

atth

est

ock

leve

l.M

onth

dum

mie

sca

ptu

rean

yco

mm

onva

riat

ion

inex

cess

retu

rns.

β(rmkt

t−rf t

)is

the

pro

duct

ofth

efirm

’sm

arke

tb

eta

and

exce

ssm

onth

lyre

turn

bas

edon

mon

thly

hol

din

gp

erio

dre

turn

sfr

omC

RSP

and

1-m

onth

trea

sury

bills

.BM

t−1

isth

epre

vio

us

per

iod’s

Book

-to-

Mar

ket

rati

o.Ln

(Mt−

1)

isth

enat

ura

llo

gari

thm

ofth

efirm

’sm

arke

tca

pit

aliz

atio

nat

the

end

ofpre

vio

us

mon

th.BBDt−

1is

the

pre

vio

us

mon

th’s

trad

e-ti

me

liquid

ity

mea

sure

com

pute

dac

cord

ing

todiff

eren

tζ’s

bas

edon

θ=

0.04

.Sym

bol

s∗ ,∗∗

,an

d∗∗∗

den

ote

sign

ifica

nce

at10

%,

5%,

and

1%le

vels

,re

spec

tive

ly.

Sta

ndar

der

rors

are

rep

orte

din

par

enth

eses

.P

rem

ium

isth

epro

duct

ofth

eBBD

coeffi

cien

tan

dth

eav

erag

eof

the

corr

esp

ondin

gliquid

ity

mea

sure

.

Act

ivit

yat

med

ium

ord

erfl

owIn

stru

men

ted

acti

vit

yA

ctiv

ity

Low

Med

ium

Hig

hL

owM

ediu

mH

igh

Low

Med

ium

Hig

hC

o-va

riat

=1

ζ=

=3

ζ=

=5

ζ=

=7

ζ=

=9

β(rmkt

t−rf t

)0.

704∗∗∗

0.70

2∗∗∗

0.70

4∗∗∗

0.70

9∗∗∗

0.70

5∗∗∗

0.70

3∗∗∗

0.70

7∗∗∗

0.70

2∗∗∗

0.70

8∗∗∗

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

(0.0

20)

BM

t−1

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

5∗∗∗

0.00

4∗∗∗

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

Ln

(Mt−

1)

−0.

021∗∗∗−

0.02

0∗∗∗−

0.02

1∗∗∗−

0.02

1∗∗∗−

0.02

0∗∗∗−

0.02

1∗∗∗−

0.02

1∗∗∗−

0.02

0∗∗∗−

0.02

1∗∗∗

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

BBDζ t−

10.

144∗∗∗

0.18

8∗∗∗

0.18

8∗∗∗

0.20

9∗∗∗

0.22

6∗∗∗

0.22

4∗∗∗

0.16

4∗∗∗

0.21

3∗∗∗

0.21

4∗∗∗

(0.0

26)

(0.0

29)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

28)

(0.0

32)

(0.0

38)

Log

-lik

elih

ood

1377

7913

7899

1381

6713

7574

1376

3213

7673

1375

1913

7769

1385

42R

20.

320.

320.

320.

320.

320.

320.

320.

320.

32O

bse

rvat

ion

s16

1187

1611

8016

1172

1600

5116

0047

1600

4616

0560

1611

8416

1189

Pre

miu

m(b

ps)

6.4

7.7

6.7

8.1

8.1

7.4

7.1

8.4

6.8

38

Page 41: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

relative to a hypothetical “perfectly liquid” stock. The average monthly premium across

different BBD versions is 7.4bp, and the premium is similar for each BBD measure.23

Comparisons with other liquidity measures. We next compare the improvements in

asset pricing models that obtain from including our liquidity measure with the improvements

obtained from including commonly-used liquidity measures—Amihud (2002), dollar spreads,

and percentage spreads. The standard Amihud illiquidity measure aggregates information

over a trading day and hence may not capture the valuable intraday information in our mea-

sure. This property leads us to consider a high-frequency version of Amihud based on hourly

observations of price changes and dollar volume. Using this alternative measure ensures

that the superior performance of BBD that we document is not due to excessive temporal

aggregation in the daily Amihud measure.

To calculate the standard (low-frequency) Amihud measure (AML), we first compute the

daily per-dollar price impact for each stock j on each day q, DIMPj(q) =|rj(q)|

DV OLj(q), where

rj(q) is the return on day q, and DV OLj(q) is the daily volume. The low-frequency Amihud

measure for stock j in month t is given by the average of DIMPj(q) over trading days q in

the 3-month period ending on the last day of month t, scaled up by 106.

The high-frequency analogue of the Amihud measure, AMHj,t, is calculated as follows.

First, we calculate the hourly per-dollar price impact for a stock as the absolute hourly re-

alized return divided by the corresponding executed hourly dollar-volume.Daily averages of

these hourly price impacts produce daily per-dollar price impacts. The high-frequency Ami-

hud measure for stock j in month t equals the average of the daily per-dollar price impacts

over trading days q in the 3-month period ending on the last day of month t, scaled by 106.

Average dollar bid-ask spreads (DSP ) and percentage bid-ask spreads (PSP ) are calcu-

lated using a time-weighted average of spreads based on the NBBO at a one-second frequency,

23In unreported results, we find that the log-likelihood is maximized by liquidity measures that placemore weight on active markets. This finding suggests that traders may have the ability to time some oftheir trading to occur in more active markets. The log-likelihood, however, is quite flat, indicating that themeasures contain roughly the same amount of information.

39

Page 42: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

0.1

.2.3

.4S

pre

ads a

nd A

mih

ud (

low

fre

q)

.002

.004

.006

.008

.01

.012

BB

D a

nd A

mih

ud (

hig

h fre

q)

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

BBD(ζ = 3)

BBD(ζ = 2)

BBD(ζ = 1) Amihud (high frequency)

Amihud (low frequency)

Percentage bid−ask spreads

Figure 13: Monthly median values of alternative liquidity measures over time.The BBD measure (based on θ = 0.04) is calculated over long (ζ = 1), medium (ζ = 2)and short (ζ = 3) durations, when signed order flow is in the middle 40% of a month’sobservations. Also shown is the high frequency Amihud measure (AMH), the low frequencyAmihud measure (AML) and percentage bid-ask spreads (PSP ).

on a daily basis. We calculate a rolling 3-month average of spreads to be consistent with

the other measures. Hence, for stock j, the spread used in month t is the simple average of

DSP or PSP observed in months t− 1, t− 2, and t− 3, denoted DSPj,t−1 and PSPj,t−1.

Figure 13 plots the monthly median value of each liquidity measure. The measures are

highly correlated and display similar temporal variation. The simple average sample corre-

lations between BBD and PSP , AML, and AMH are 0.77, 0.80, and 0.66, respectively.24

Notably, the BBD measures vary more than the other measures.

Table IV summarizes estimates of (6) using these alternative liquidity measures in place

24Average correlations are computed across different versions of BBD.

40

Page 43: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

of BBD (using the same error term structure and trimming criteria). Dollar bid-ask spreads

is the only alternative liquidity measure that is not significant (at α = 0.1), and thus our

subsequent analysis compares BBD with the priced measures: AML, AMH, and PSP .

Table IV: Augmented CAPM using standard liquidity measures. The table reportspanel estimates of (6) using AML, AMH, PSP , and DSP . Month dummies capturecommon variation caused by market condition changes, i.e., by common variation in excessreturns over time. Standard errors are clustered at the stock level. Stock fixed effectscapture any fixed heteroskedasticity. Observations in the top 1% tail of the liquiditymeasure are excluded if levels of independent variables are used. Symbols ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗

denote significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Co-variate Estimates

β(rmktt − rft ) 0.708∗∗∗ 0.710∗∗∗ 0.701∗∗∗ 0.709∗∗∗

(0.020) (0.021) (0.020) (0.021) )BMt−1 0.006∗∗∗ 0.005∗∗∗ 0.005∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)Ln(Mt−1) −0.024∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.020∗∗∗ −0.026∗∗∗

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)AMLt−1 0.155∗∗∗

(0.041)AMHt−1 0.011∗∗∗

(0.003)PSPt−1 0.049∗∗∗

(0.005)DSPt−1 0.008

(0.027)

Log-likelihood 136897 136499 137913 134589Within–R2 0.31 0.31 0.32 0.31

Observations 161264 160998 161054 160992

The liquidity measures are highly correlated. A pricing regression that includes BBD

and another liquidity measure will have multicollinearity issues.25 To address this, we de-

compose orthogonally each alternative measure, F ∈ {AML,AMH,PSP}, with respect to

25In unreported results, we find that if both BBD and another liquidity risk measure are included inthe same regression, the coefficient on BBD is positive and statistically significant, while that on the otherliquidity measure is negative and insignificant. However, the high correlation in the measures means thatone should interpret such results with caution.

41

Page 44: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

BBD, by obtaining the residuals zF

tj and zF

tj from the regressions:

BBDj,t = α1 + α2Fj,t + zF

tj, (7)

Fj,t = α′1 + α′2BBDj,t + zF

tj. (8)

We then estimate (6) with zF

tj or zF

tj as an explanatory variable in place of the liquidity factor.

Table V: Augmented CAPM with orthogonal components of our trade-time liquiditymeasures and low-frequency Amihud measure. The table reports panel estimation resultsfor (6) using the full sample. Standard errors are clustered at the stock level. Stock fixed effectscapture any fixed heteroskedasticity. Month dummies capture any common variation caused bymarket condition changes. We separately present results based on BBD measures correspondingto high, medium and low market activity levels, when order flow is medium (ζ = 1, 2, 3). Durationsare generated based on θ = 0.04. Observations in the upper 1% tail of BBD or AML in amonth are excluded. Stocks with less than 800 trade sequences in a year are excluded from thatyear’s data. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. Symbols ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ denotesignificance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Activity at medium order flowCo-variate Low (ζ = 1) Medium (ζ = 2) High (ζ = 3)

β(rmt − rft ) 0.706∗∗∗ 0.708∗∗∗ 0.705∗∗∗ 0.708∗∗∗ 0.706∗∗∗ 0.709∗∗∗

(0.020) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.020) (0.021)

BMt−1 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.005∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)

Ln(Mt−1) −0.023∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.023∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.023∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

zAML

t−1 0.187∗∗ 0.230∗∗∗ 0.221∗∗∗

(0.046) (0.051) (0.049)

zAML

t−1 −0.183∗∗ −0.199∗∗ −0.158∗∗

(0.079) (0.080) (0.068)

Within-R2 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32Observations 160640 160640 160668 160668 160585 160585

Tables V–VII indicate that BBD is more informative about stock liquidity than either the

Amihud measure or percentage spreads. By construction, Cov(zF

jt, Fjt) = Cov(zF

jt, BBDjt) =

0. Thus, the positive and significant estimates of the coefficients on zF

t−1, given different lev-

els of activity, imply that the illiquidity components that are not measured by F , but are

42

Page 45: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Table VI: Augmented CAPM with orthogonal components of our trade-time liquiditymeasures and high-frequency Amihud measure. The table reports panel estimation resultsfor (6) using the full sample. Standard errors are clustered at the stock level. Stock fixed effectscapture any fixed heteroskedasticity. Month dummies capture any common variation caused bymarket condition changes. We separately present results based on BBD measures correspondingto high, medium and low market activity levels when order flow is medium (ζ = 1, 2, 3). Durationsare generated given on θ = 0.04. Observations in the upper 1% tail of BBD or AMH in amonth are excluded. Stocks with less than 800 trade sequences in a year are excluded from thatyear’s data. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. Symbols ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ denotesignificance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Activity at medium order flowCo-variate Low (ζ = 1) Medium (ζ = 2) High (ζ = 3)

β(rmt − rft ) 0.708∗∗∗ 0.711∗∗∗ 0.706∗∗∗ 0.711∗∗∗ 0.707∗∗∗ 0.712∗∗∗

(0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021) (0.021)

BMt−1 0.005∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.005∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.005∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)

Ln(Mt−1) −0.023∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.023∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.022∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

zAMH

t−1 0.111∗∗ 0.141∗∗∗ 0.150∗∗∗

(0.025) (0.029) (0.032)

zAMH

t−1 −0.002 −0.003 −0.003(0.003) (0.003) (0.003)

Within-R2 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32Observations 160283 160283 160281 160281 160229 160229

captured by BBD, reflect valuable information for investors. In contrast, the negative or in-

significant coefficients for zF

t−1 in all pricing regressions suggest that AML, AMH, and PSP

contain little information about the illiquidity component that is not already captured by

BBD. The differences between the coefficients of zF

t−1 and zF

t−1 indicate that BBD is corre-

lated with the unobserved liquidity factor more strongly than the other measures are. These

results reveal the value-added of our trade-time liquidity measure vis a vis these widely-used

standard liquidity measures. The robustness of γ1, γ2, and γ3 when we substitute zF

t−1 for

zF

t−1, implies that BBD is nearly orthogonal to the other asset pricing factors in the model.26

26In unreported results, we verify that the residual analysis yields qualitatively similar findings for theother six versions of BBD, i.e., those corresponding to ζ ∈ {4, . . . , 9}.

43

Page 46: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Table VII: Augmented CAPM with orthogonal components of our trade-time liquiditymeasures and percentage bid-ask spreads. The table reports panel estimation results for(6) using the full sample. Standard errors are clustered at the stock level. Stock fixed effects areintroduced to capture any fixed heteroskedasticity. Month dummies are included to capture anycommon variation caused by market condition changes. We separately present results based onBBD measures corresponding to high, medium and low market activity levels when order flow ismedium (ζ = 1, 2, 3). Durations are generated given on θ = 0.04. Observations in the upper 1%tail of BBD or PSP in a month are excluded. Stocks with less than 800 trade sequences in a yearare excluded from that year’s data. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. Symbols∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Activity at medium order flowCo-variate Low (ζ = 1) Medium (ζ = 2) High (ζ = 3)

β(rmt − rft ) 0.702∗∗∗ 0.704∗∗∗ 0.702∗∗∗ 0.704∗∗∗ 0.701∗∗∗ 0.704∗∗∗

(0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020)

BMt−1 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)

Ln(Mt−1) −0.024∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.024∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.024∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

zPSP

t−1 0.069∗∗ 0.106∗∗∗ 0.125∗∗∗

(0.035) (0.039) (0.046)

zPSP

t−1 0.010 0.004 0.002(0.008) (0.008) (0.009)

Within-R2 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32Observations 160407 160407 160398 160398 160345 160345

We posited at the outset that in recent years, issues with standard liquidity measures have

grown, making it more important to employ alternative liquidity measures such as our trade-

time liquidity measures. To investigate this, we first explore the changes in priced illiquidity

by estimating (6) across two sub-samples: (i) from April 2001 to December 2006, and (ii)

from January 2007 to December 2012. We consider three versions of the BBD measure, com-

puted based on ζ = 1, 2, 3, and three standard liquidity measures, AML, AMH, and PSP .

Table VIII shows that the BBD coefficients are statistically significant in both sub-

periods, and even more strongly in the most recent sub-period. In contrast, each Amihud

measure ceases to be significant in one of the sub-periods. As mentioned earlier, each of these

44

Page 47: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Tab

leV

III:

Su

bsa

mp

leest

imati

on

of

au

gm

ente

dC

AP

Mw

ith

diff

ere

nt

liqu

idit

ym

easu

res.

Th

eta

ble

rep

orts

pan

eles

tim

atio

nre

sult

sof

(6)

for

two

sub

sam

ple

s:A

pri

l20

01–D

ec20

06an

dJan

2007

–Dec

2012

.S

tan

dar

der

rors

are

clu

ster

edat

the

stock

leve

l.S

tock

fixed

effec

tsar

ein

trod

uce

dto

cap

ture

any

fixed

het

eros

ked

asti

city

.M

onth

du

mm

ies

are

incl

ud

edto

cap

ture

any

com

mon

vari

atio

nca

use

dby

mark

etco

nd

itio

nch

ange

s.T

he

firs

tth

ree

colu

mn

sof

agi

ven

sub-s

amp

lep

rese

nt

resu

lts

for

ourBBD

mea

sure

sb

ase

don

hig

h,

med

ium

,an

dlo

wle

vel

sof

mar

ket

acti

vit

yw

hen

ord

erfl

owis

med

ium

(ζ=

1,2,3

)an

dar

eb

ased

onθ

=0.

04.

Th

efi

nal

thre

eco

lum

ns

ofa

pan

elp

rese

nt

esti

mat

ion

resu

lts

for

the

stan

dar

dli

qu

idit

ym

easu

res,AML

,AMH

,an

dPSP

.O

bse

rvat

ion

sin

the

upp

er1%

tail

ofth

ere

leva

nt

liqu

idit

ym

easu

rear

eex

clu

ded

.S

tock

sw

ith

less

than

800

trad

ese

qu

ence

sin

aye

arar

eex

clu

ded

from

that

year

’sd

ata

.R

ob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsar

ere

por

ted

inp

aren

thes

es.

Th

esy

mb

ols∗ ,∗∗

,an

d∗∗∗

den

ote

sign

ifica

nce

at10

%,

5%

,an

d1%

leve

ls,

resp

ecti

vel

y.

Co-

vari

ate

Apri

l20

01–D

ecem

ber

2006

Jan

uar

y20

07–D

ecem

ber

2012

β(rm t−rf t

)0.

685∗∗∗

0.68

1∗∗∗

0.68

6∗∗∗

0.68

7∗∗∗

0.68

7∗∗∗

0.68

4∗∗∗

0.70

2∗∗∗

0.70

1∗∗∗

0.70

0∗∗∗

0.70

5∗∗∗

0.70

8∗∗∗

0.69

6∗∗∗

(0.0

26)

(0.0

26)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

26)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

26)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

26)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

26)

BM

t−1

0.00

8∗∗∗

0.00

8∗∗∗

0.00

9∗∗∗

0.00

9∗∗∗

0.00

9∗∗∗

0.00

8∗∗∗

0.00

4∗∗

0.00

4∗∗

0.00

4∗∗

0.00

5∗∗

0.00

4∗∗

0.00

4∗∗

(0.0

04)

(0.0

04)

(0.0

04)

0.00

4)(0

.004

)(0

.004

)(0

.002

)(0

.002

)(0

.002

)(0

.002

)(0

.002

)(0

.002

)

Ln

(Mt−

1)

−0.

042∗∗∗−

0.04

2∗∗∗−

0.04

3∗∗∗−

0.04

3∗∗∗−

0.04

4∗∗∗−

0.03

8∗∗∗−

0.04

8∗∗∗−

0.04

7∗∗∗−

0.04

7∗∗∗−

0.05

2∗∗∗−

0.05

3∗∗∗−

0.04

7∗∗∗

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

03)

BBD

(ζ=

1)t−

10.

083∗∗

0.18

2∗∗∗

(0.0

34)

(0.0

45)

BBD

(ζ=

2)t−

10.

118∗∗∗

0.21

0∗∗∗

(0.0

41)

(0.0

47)

BBD

(ζ=

3)t−

10.

066∗

0.25

0∗∗∗

(0.0

39)

(0.0

58)

AMLt−

10.

049

0.22

3∗∗

(0.0

41)

(0.1

03)

AMHt−

10.

005∗

0.03

7(0

.003

)(0

.025

)

PSPt−

10.

040∗∗∗

0.07

2∗∗∗

(0.0

07)

(0.0

16)

Wit

hin

-R2

0.26

0.26

0.26

0.26

0.26

0.26

0.36

0.37

0.37

0.36

0.36

0.36

Obse

rvat

ions

7918

579

183

7917

479

208

7919

679

082

8200

281

997

8199

882

056

8180

281

972

Pre

miu

m(b

ps)

4.2

5.5

2.7

0.7

0.2

55.0

6.3

7.3

7.5

1.9

0.9

74.1

45

Page 48: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Tab

leIX

:Il

liqu

idit

ycoeffi

cie

nts

inC

AP

Mest

imate

s,com

pare

din

the

two

sub

-peri

od

s,aft

er

ort

hogon

al

decom

posi

-ti

on

.T

he

tab

lere

por

tsp

an

eles

tim

atio

np

arti

alre

sult

sof

(6)

for

two

sub

sam

ple

s,A

pri

l20

01–D

ec20

06an

dJan

2007

–Dec

2012

.S

tan

-d

ard

erro

rsar

ecl

ust

ered

atth

est

ock

level

.S

tock

fixed

effec

tsar

ein

trod

uce

dto

cap

ture

any

fixed

het

eros

ked

asti

city

.M

onth

du

mm

ies

are

incl

ud

edto

cap

ture

any

com

mon

vari

atio

nca

use

dby

mar

ket

con

dit

ion

chan

ges.

Th

eco

effici

ents

ofzF t−

1an

dzF t−

1ar

ere

por

ted

,w

her

eth

ree

vers

ion

sofBBD

(ζ=

1,2,3

)ar

eco

ntr

aste

dag

ain

stth

eth

ree

stan

dar

dli

qu

idit

ym

easu

res.

Ob

serv

atio

ns

inth

eu

pp

er1%

tail

ofth

ere

leva

nt

liqu

idit

ym

easu

res

are

excl

ud

ed.

Sto

cks

wit

hle

ssth

an80

0tr

ade

sequ

ence

sin

aye

arar

eex

clu

ded

from

that

year

’sd

ata.

Ro-

bu

stst

and

ard

erro

rsar

ere

por

ted

inp

aren

thes

es.

Th

esy

mb

ols∗ ,∗∗

,an

d∗∗∗

den

ote

sign

ifica

nce

at10

%,5%

,an

d1%

leve

ls,re

spec

tive

ly.

BBD

vsAML

Co-

vari

ate

Apri

l20

01–D

ecem

ber

2006

Jan

uar

y20

07–D

ecem

ber

2012

ζ=

=2

ζ=

=1

ζ=

=3

zAM

L

t−1

0.18

4∗∗∗

0.19

9∗∗∗

0.08

9∗0.

144

0.23

1∗∗

0.33

2∗∗∗

(0.0

58)

(0.0

68)

(0.0

47)

(0.0

94)

(0.0

97)

(0.1

00)

zAM

L

t−1

−0.

243∗∗∗

−0.

210∗∗

−0.

059

−0.

100

−0.

219

−0.

382∗

(0.0

85)

(0.0

90)

(0.0

60)

(0.2

27)

(0.2

21)

(0.2

03)

BBD

vsAMH

Co-

vari

ate

Apri

l20

01–D

ecem

ber

2006

Jan

uar

y20

07–D

ecem

ber

2012

ζ=

=2

ζ=

=1

ζ=

=3

zAM

H

t−1

0.05

5∗∗

0.06

9∗∗

0.02

70.

169∗∗

0.23

9∗∗∗

0.30

1∗∗∗

(0.0

26)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

29)

(0.0

66)

(0.0

65)

(0.0

72)

zAM

H

t−1

0.00

10.

001

0.00

3−

0.04

5−

0.06

7∗−

0.07

9∗∗

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

37)

BBD

vsPSP

Co-

vari

ate

Apri

l20

01–D

ecem

ber

2006

Jan

uar

y20

07–D

ecem

ber

2012

ζ=

=2

ζ=

=1

ζ=

=3

zPSP

t−1

−0.

092∗∗

−0.

093∗∗

−0.

149∗∗∗

0.17

9∗∗∗

0.25

3∗∗∗

0.33

6∗∗∗

(0.0

45)

(0.0

47)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

60)

(0.0

63)

(0.0

77)

zPSP

t−1

0.03

9∗∗∗

0.03

7∗∗∗

0.04

2∗∗∗

−0.

045∗∗

−0.

062∗∗∗

−0.

83∗∗∗

(0.0

09)

(0.0

09)

(0.0

07)

(0.0

22)

(0.0

21)

(0.0

24)

46

Page 49: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

measures is, to some extent, correlated with the true idiosyncratic stock illiquidity, and as

such, with one another. Accordingly, we estimate (6) using the residuals zF

t−1 and zF

t−1 from

the orthogonal decompositions in the two sub-periods of early and recent years. We consider

three versions of BBD, based on ζ = 1, 2, 3, and three standard liquidity measures, AML,

AMH, and PSP . Since the coefficients of the other pricing variables remain stable across

the sub-periods, Table IX reports only the coefficients on the illiquidity variables.

After filtering BBD’s covariation with commonly-used liquidity measures, BBD con-

tains significant incremental information about liquidity, particularly in more recent years.

In the period 2007-2012, the BBD residuals are priced, while the residuals from the standard

illiquidity measures (both Amihud measures, and percentage bid-ask spreads) are not. In

the earlier period, the only residual liquidity measure priced is percentage bid-ask spreads

(PSP ). These findings indicate that the relative qualities of standard liquidity measures

have deteriorated over time as trading volume has exploded, bid-ask spreads have fallen

and trading strategies have taken on dynamic dimensions. The residual analysis provides

convincing evidence that our BBD trade-time liquidity measures best capture liquidity risk

in today’s trading environments. We also find that despite huge increases in trading volume,

liquidity premia have not fallen post RegNMS.

IV Conclusion

In today’s high frequency trading world, bid-ask spreads are tiny and depth modest. Tra-

ditional measures of trading costs and liquidity no longer describe concerns of institutional

traders who have responded to the massive changes in market structure by dividing orders

into many smaller orders that are dynamically submitted over time and across trading venues.

Our first contribution is to develop a measure of market activity that accounts for dy-

namic order splitting and division of orders against the book. We first characterize the

relative activity of a market for a stock by calculating the duration to unwind a position

worth a fixed share of the market capitalization for that stock—a more active market is one

47

Page 50: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

where durations are shorter.

We establish that, consistent with classic models of speculation, as market activity rises,

so do both mean trade size and signed order imbalance—market activity is positively as-

sociated with more aggressive trading. But, the endogenous choices by traders of whether

to consume or provide liquidity may also account for such patterns—traders respond to

more depth near good inside quotes by submitting larger market orders. To distinguish

between these competing explanations we characterize how price impacts vary with mar-

ket conditions. We find that for small and mid-sized firms, price impacts fall with market

activity—indicating that endogenous order composition drives their market activity pat-

terns. In contrast, for larger firms, price impacts first rise and then fall with market activity.

Further investigation reveals that for large stocks, information arrival drives activity and

market impacts at “unusual” times, but endogenous order composition is the primary force

at other times. This evidence suggests that classical models of speculation no longer describe

trading in today’s high frequency financial markets.

We then isolate market activity-trading cost relationships that are stable and predictable.

To do this, we instrument for the duration of the current trade sequence (current market

activity) using the number of trades filling the previous trade sequence. We establish the

validity of this instrument—it controls for both information arrival and the endogenous com-

position of orders. We find that, regardless of firm size, trading costs uniformly fall as instru-

mented market activity rises. The decline in trading costs of 5 to 8 basis points as trading

activity goes from its lowest predicted level to its highest is meaningful, and can be exploited

by institutional traders. The percentage savings on trading costs from trading in more active

markets are comparable for different firm sizes, with higher absolute gains for smaller stocks.

We then use per-dollar versions of this price impact at different activity levels as market

time measures of liquidity (BBD), and explore whether it captures the liquidity concerns of

institutional traders. We estimate an augmented CAPM asset pricing model that includes

book-to-market, size, and our trade activity-based liquidity measures as additional pricing

48

Page 51: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

factors. These BBD liquidity measures are consistently priced, and deliver qualitatively

similar liquidity premia. Further, BBD better captures priced liquidity concerns than clas-

sical measures (low- and high-frequency versions of Amihud’s measure or bid-ask spread),

especially in recent years where trading volumes have exploded. This finding highlights the

importance of using measures that capture market conditions, and the success of our measure

at doing so.

Despite increases in trading volumes driven by algorithmic and high frequency trading,

liquidity premiums have increased in recent years. It is possible that some market partici-

pants perceive higher liquidity risk due to the fleeting nature of automated market making,

with little human intervention and largely inaccessible quotes that last for less than a second.

Understanding liquidity provision and risk in this context is especially relevant to the ongoing

debate about the role of high frequency trading and recent calls to limit its role in the market.

V References

Acharya, V.V., L.H. Pedersen (2005). Asset pricing with liquidity risk. Journal of Financial

Economics 77(2), 375–410.

Akbas, F., W.J. Armstrong, R. Petkova (2011). Idiosyncratic volatility of liquidity and

expected stock returns. Working paper, Purdue University.

Amihud, Y. (2002). Illiquidity and stock returns: cross-section and time-series effects. Jour-

nal of Financial Markets 5(1), 31–56.

Amihud, Y., H. Mendelson (1986). Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. Journal of Finan-

cial Economics 17(2), 223–249.

Andersen, T.G., O. Bondarenko (2014). VPIN and the Flash Crash. Journal of Financial

Markets 17, 1–46.

Angel, J., L. Harris, C. Spatt (2011). Equity Trading in the 21st Century. Quarterly Journal

of Finance 1, 1–53.

49

Page 52: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Bernhardt D., E. Hughson (2002). Intraday trade in dealership markets. European Economic

Review 46(9), 1697–1732.

Blume M.E., D.B. Keim (2012). Institutional investors and stock market liquidity: trends

and relationships. Working paper, University of Pennsylvania.

Brennan, M.J., A. Subrahmanyam (1996). Market microstructure and asset pricing: On the

compensation for illiquidity in stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 41, 441–464.

Cameron, A.C., J.B. Gelbach, D.L. Miller (2008). Bootstrap-based improvements for infer-

ence with clustered errors. Review of Economics and Statistics 90(3), 414–427.

Chordia, T., R. Roll, A. Subrahmanyam (2000). Commonality in liquidity. Journal of

Financial Economics 56, 3–28.

Chordia, T., R. Roll, A. Subrahmanyam (2011). Recent trends in trading activity and

market quality. Journal of Financial Economics 101(2), 243–263.

Corwin, S.A., P. Stulz (2012). A simple way to estimate bid-ask spreads from daily high

and low prices. Journal of Finance 67(2), 719–759.

Demsetz, H. (1968). The cost of transacting. Quarterly Journal of Economics 82, 33–53.

Deuskar, P., T.C. Johnson (2011). Market liquidity and flow-driven risk. Review of Financial

Studies 24(3), 721–753.

Dufour A., R.F. Engle (2000). Time and the price impact of trade. Journal of Finance 55(6),

2467–2498.

Easley D., M.M. Lopez de Pardo, M. O’Hara (2012). Flow toxicity and liquidity in a high

frequency world. Review of Financial Studies 25(5), 1457–1493.

Engle, R.F. (2000). The econometrics of ultra-high frequency data. Econometrica 1, 1–22.

Engle, R.F., J.R. Russell (1998). Autoregressive conditional duration: A new model for

irregularly spaced transaction data. Econometrica 66, 1127–1162.

Fama, E.F., J.D. MacBeth (1973). Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal

50

Page 53: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

of Political Economy 81(3), 607–636.

Feldhutter, P. (2012). The same bond at different prices: Identifying search frictions and

selling pressures. Review of Financial Studies 25(4), 1155–1206.

Fujimoto, A. (2004). Macroeconomic sources of systematic liquidity. Working paper. Uni-

versity of Alberta.

Goettler, R., C. Parlour and U. Rajan (2005). Equilibrium in a Dynamic Limit order market,

Journal of Finance 60(5), 2149–2192.

Glosten, L., L. Harris (1988). Estimating the components of the bid-ask spread. Journal of

Financial Economics 21, 123–142.

Gourieroux, C., J. Jasiak, G. Le Fol (1999). Intra-day market activity. Journal of Financial

Markets 2, 193–226.

Goyenko, R.Y., C.W. Holden, C.A. Trzcinka (2009). Do liquidity measures measure liquid-

ity? Journal of Financial Economics 92(2), 153–181.

Hasbrouck, J. (2009). Trading costs and returns for U.S. equities: Estimating effective costs

from daily data. Journal of Finance 64(3), 1445–1477.

Holden, C.W. (2009). New low-frequency spread measures. Journal of Financial Markets

12, 778–813.

Holden, C.W., S.E. Jacobsen (2014). Liquidity measurement problems in fast, competitive

markets: Expensive and cheap solutions. Journal of Finance, 69(4), 1747–1785.

Hollifield, B., R. Miller, and P. Sandas (2004). Empirical Analysis of Limit Order Markets.

Review of Economic Studies 71(4): 1027–1063.

Hollifield, B., R. Miller, P. Sandas, and J. Slive (2006). Estimating the gains from trade in

limit order markets. Journal of Finance 61(6): 2753–2804.

Johnson, T.C. (2008). Volume, liquidity, and liquidity risk. Journal of Financial Economics

87, 388–417.

51

Page 54: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

Jones, C.M. (2002). A century of stock market liquidity and trading costs. Working paper,

Columbia University.

Kim, S., D. Murphy (2013). The impact of high-frequency trading on stock market liquidity

measures. Working paper, Northwestern University.

Kyle, A.S. (1985). Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53(6), 1315–1335.

Lee, C.M.C., M.J. Ready (1991). Inferring trade direction from intraday data. Journal of

Finance 46(2), 733–746.

Lesmond, D.A., J.P. Ogden, C.A. Trczinka (1999). A new estimate of transaction costs.

Review of Financial Studies 12(5), 1113–1141.

Lippman, S.A., J.J. McCall (1986). An operational measure of liquidity. American Economic

Review 76, 43–55.

Mazza, P. (2013). Rethinking zero returns in the liquidity puzzle of a limit order market.

Working paper, Catholic University of Louvain.

Nichols, A., M.E. Schaffer (2007). Clustered standard errors in stata. Working paper, United

Kingdom Stata Users’ Group Meetings 2007.

Pastor, L., R.F. Stambaugh (2003). Liquidity risk and price discovery. Journal of Political

Economy 111(3), 642–685.

Petersen, M.A. (2009). Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: Comparing

approaches. Review of Financial Studies 22(1), 435–480.

Roll, R. (1984). A simple implicit measure of the effective bid-ask spread in an efficient

market. Journal of Finance 39, 1127–1139.

Sadka, R. (2006). Momentum and post-earnings-announcement drift anomalies: The role of

liquidity risk. Journal of Financial Economics 80, 309–349.

Staiger, D. and J.H. Stock (1997). Instrumental variable regressions with weak instruments.

Econometrica 65(3), 557–586.

52

Page 55: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

VI Appendix

Calendar time relationships. A positive relationship between volatility and market ac-

tivity exists in calendar time. To illustrate, we estimate the return volatility that would

result if a given level of market activity was maintained for an entire trading day. We first

estimate implied return volatilities for a given level of market (instrumented) activity.27 For

a given year y and stock j, we calculate the return variance and average duration (in sec-

onds) of trade sequences belonging to (instrumented) activity level i. Using these values,

and assuming independent price movements across different trade sequences, we estimate the

corresponding calendar day return standard deviation for a given market activity level as:

SDi (y, j) =

√(Return variance of trade sequences)× (number of seconds in trading day)

Average duration in seconds of trade sequences.

Size decile estimates are obtained by averaging SDi (y, j) across all stocks in size decile x.

Figure 14 shows that estimated daily return volatility rises sharply at high levels of mar-

ket activity.28 Daily return volatility, however, only rises with instrumented activity at about

20% of the rate with raw market activity. This finding suggests that the strong relation be-

tween market activity and daily volatility largely reflects the endogenous nature of market

activity. We also see that average daily return volatility varies with firm size—even using

instrumented activity, average daily return volatility is over twice as high for the smallest

stocks as for the largest.

Robustness to Error Structure. We impose a robust standard error structure with firm

level clusters. Our approach follows Petersen (2009) and accounts for potential cross-firm

and cross-time correlations that may be present in the panel data error terms. Failing to

account for these correlations would lead to underestimated standard errors. To account for

common fixed firm and time effects, we estimate a fixed-effect model using generalized least

27To ensure consistency, we only consider stocks whose first stage regressions when instrumenting haveF -statistics that exceed 10.

28An analogous exercise for yearly subsamples reveals similar patterns. Daily return volatility is generallyhigher in 2001 and 2009.

53

Page 56: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

B: Small firms A: Large firms

05

10

15

Ave

rag

e d

aily

re

turn

vo

latilit

y (

%)

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 1 Size decile 2 Size decile 3

12

34

5

Ave

rag

e d

aily

re

turn

vo

latilit

y (

%)

Low HighActivity level

Size decile 8 Size decile 9 Size decile 10

2.5

33

.54

4.5

Ave

rag

e d

aily

re

turn

vo

latilit

y (

%)

Low HighInstrumented activity level

Size decile 1 Size decile 2 Size decile 3

1.6

1.8

22

.22

.4

Ave

rag

e d

aily

re

turn

vo

latilit

y (

%)

Low HighInstrumented activity level

Size decile 8 Size decile 9 Size decile 10

Figure 14: Average daily return volatility by market activity group. Averagereturn volatility of 0.04% of market capitalization in 2001–2012 versus market activitylevel for the three deciles of smallest and largest stocks. The reported average daily returnvolatility is the average of firm-specific annually computed daily standard deviations ofreturns SDi (y, j), computed per duration group. The average of daily standard deviations istaken across all firms in a given size decile, over the entire sample period, by activity level.

squares (GLS) with month dummies.

We also consider two other potential error term correlations: non-fixed time and non-fixed

firm effects. Non-fixed firm effects are those causing temporal autocorrelations in a given

firm’s error term. Such effects can arise when a shock to stock j persists (e.g., the effect of a

technology shock on stock’s j’s performance, which decays over time). Non-fixed time effects

make error terms of different firms related in a given period of time where the correlation

differs for different pairs of firms (see Petersen (2009) or Cameron et al. (2008)). These

effects can arise when industry-specific shocks affect most firms in an industry similarly,

54

Page 57: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

leaving firms in other industries unaffected.

Fama and MacBeth (1973) adjust for non-fixed time effects by running cross-sectional

regressions period by period. Point estimates from different cross-sections give the empirical

distributions of parameters of interest. Further statistical inference using the Fama-MacBeth

method is based on the averages and standard deviations of empirical distributions, and

hence requires temporal independence of cross-sectional point estimates to obtain unbiased

estimates. Alas, extensive time dependence in our sample precludes using this approach.29

Some estimation strategies call for multi-dimensional clustering when a researcher sus-

pects errors to correlate in multiple dimensions (Cameron, et al. (2008)). To the best of our

knowledge, however, techniques that allow for multi-dimensional and non-nested clustered

error terms have been developed only for ordinary least squares (OLS) estimation. OLS

estimation using panel data is equivalent to pooling the information content of different pe-

riods about a given individual. Such aggregation is inappropriate here. Instead, we employ

the fixed-effects GLS approach as our main estimation strategy. In unreported results, we

estimate model (6) using OLS while clustering by firm, time, and both. Standard errors of

estimates given two dimensional clustering are only modestly larger (less than 40% higher)

than when we account for firm clusters only.

It is inappropriate to try to control for non-fixed time effects by clustering by time when

we use fixed-effects GLS, since the unbalanced nature of the panel makes the clusters non-

nested. Most significantly, the set of stocks in a given market decile varies non-trivially

over time. With non-nested clusters it is not clear which periods’ cross-stock error term

autocorrelations may cause upward biases in estimated standard errors. These concerns lead

us to introduce industry-specific shocks to control for non-fixed time effects associated with

shocks that affect firms within an industry similarly.

Using four-digit GIC industry codes, we identify about 65 industries per month. For each

29Petersen (2009) highlights downward biases in Fama-MacBeth estimated standard errors in the presenceof firm effects.

55

Page 58: Trading costs and priced illiquidity in high frequency ...€¦ · Using these trading cost measures as illiquidity measures in an augmented CAPM, we nd that they outperform standard

firm j, we compute the associated average industry returns on a monthly basis excluding its

own return. To de-trend, we find the excess industry return against the equally weighted

monthly average return. The first difference of the monthly industry excess return is added

to model (6), as a proxy of non-fixed time effects. Adding this variable to the model de-

creases the coefficient of the CAPM component by about 10%, but does not qualitatively

alter other parameter estimates or standard errors.30

An alternative approach to dealing with non-fixed time effects is to model the serial

correlation of error terms parametrically. Accordingly, we consider error terms that follow

an AR(1) process, εj,t = ρεj,t−1 + νj,t−1, with νit ∼ iidN(0,Σ2ν). We estimate model (6)

with this additional error structure using a fixed-effects GLS strategy. As when we cluster

at the firm level, the autoregressive specification of errors does not affect point estimates.

Furthermore, regardless of the liquidity measure employed, the associated standard errors

are slightly smaller than those reported in Table III.

Overall, these findings support our modeling approach of allowing for firm clustering,

along with stock fixed effects and time dummies. This approach mitigates the downward

biases in estimated standard errors. One need not cluster in the time dimension since the

CAPM term and time dummies capture most commonalities in the time variation of stock

excess returns.

30Nichols and Schaffer (2007) note that with differently-sized clusters, inference could be an issue. Whilehave differently-sized clusters, we have so many firm level clusters that asymptotic properties should hold.

56