wharton-smu research center · 2005-04-15 · wharton-smu research center market segmentation,...

38
Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and Yihong Xia This project is funded by the Wharton-SMU Research Center, Singapore Management University

Upload: others

Post on 13-Mar-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Wharton-SMU Research Center

Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts

Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and Yihong Xia

This project is funded by the Wharton-SMU Research Center, Singapore Management University

Page 2: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Market Segmentation, Liquidity Spillover, and Closed-end

Country Fund Discounts∗

Justin Chan†, Ravi Jain‡and Yihong Xia§

March 28, 2005

∗Earlier drafts of the paper were circulated under the title “Illiquidity and Closed-End Country Fund Discounts.” We thankYakov Amihud, Doron Avramov, Marshall Blume, Michael Brennan, Jay Choi, Craig Doidge, Andrew Karolyi, Karen Lewis, Kai

Li, Francis Longstaff, Hong Yan, and participants at AFA 2005 Annual meeting, UCI, University of Toronto and the Wharton

Brown Bag Seminar for helpful comments. We also thank Zhihua Qiao, Huarong Tang, and Sehyun Yoo for excellent researchassistance and Lipper Funds for kindly providing relevant closed-end fund data. Jain gratefully acknowledges financial support

from CIBER at Temple University. Xia gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Wharton-SMU Research Center of

the Singapore Management University and the NASDAQ fellowship from the Rodney L. White Center at the Wharton School.†Finance Department, Lee Kong Chian School of Business, Singapore Management University, 469 Bukit Timah Road,

Singapore 259756. Phone: +(65) 6822-0718. Fax: +(65) 6822 0777. Email: [email protected].‡Finance Department, Fox School of Business and Management, Temple University, 205 Speakman Hall, Philadelphia, PA

19122. Phone: (215) 204-5672. Fax: (215) 204-1697. E-mail: [email protected].§Finance Department, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania; 2300 Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall; Philadelphia, PA

19104-6367. Phone: (215) 898-3004. Fax: (215) 898-6200. E-mail: [email protected].

Page 3: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Market Segmentation, Liquidity Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts

Abstract

In a segmented international capital market, illiquidity in the market in which the shares of a country

fund are traded affects only the share price of the fund (S), while illiquidity in the market in which

the underlying assets are traded affects only the fund net asset value (NAV ). In an integrated market,

illiquidity in one market can easily spill over to another and affect both the fund share price and its

underlying asset value. It follows that the closed-end country fund premium, P ≡ ln(S) − ln(NAV ),

is negatively (positively) affected by the share (asset) market illiquidity in segmented capital markets,

but has only an ambiguous association with either share or asset market illiquidity in an integrated

market. Empirical evidence from U.S.-traded single-country closed-end funds indeed shows a strong

negative (positive) association between the fund premium and the share (asset) market illiquidity, and

the relation is much stronger for funds investing in segmented markets. The results suggest that market

illiquidity plays a significant role in explaining both time series and cross-sectional variation in closed-

end country fund premia.

Page 4: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

I. Introduction

A closed-end fund is a firm that issues shares and uses the proceeds to invest in the shares of other

companies. A closed-end country fund is a fund that issues shares in one country such as the UK or the

US (the share or host market) and invests the proceeds in the shares of companies in a specific foreign

country such as Korea (the asset or home market). Closed-end funds have a fixed number of shares. In

general, fund shares are traded at prices (S) different from the net asset value per share (NAV ), which is

announced at regular intervals (usually weekly or daily). Defining P ≡ ln S − ln NAV , the fund is said

to sell at a premium (discount) when P > 0 (P < 0). In what follows, we shall refer only to the fund

premium noting that a discount is a negative fund premium.

Closed-end fund premia are often cited as evidence of limits to arbitrage and of investor irrationality.

In an influential paper, Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler (1990) identify four empirical regularities associated with

the fund premium: 1) closed-end fund shares are generally issued at a positive premium;1 2) they often

trade at a negative premium; 3) the premium varies widely over time and across funds; and 4) the share

price converges to NAV at liquidation or open-ending.

Theories based on frictions such as agency costs, taxes, market segmentation, and mis-valuation of

underlying assets have had some success in explaining the first two empirical regularities, but none can

account for the wide variation in premia over time and across funds. For example, Bonser-Neal, Brauer,

Neal, and Wheatley (1990) find a significant relation between premia on country funds and announcements

of changes in foreign investment restrictions, but investment restrictions can explain only large positive

premia. Ross (2002) argues that the average negative premium is related to management fees and dividends,

but Malkiel (1977) finds no correlation between US closed end fund premium and fund expense ratios.

Finally, Barclay et. al. (1993) examine the relation between block ownership and premia, and Wermers

et. al. (2004) investigate the dynamics of premia surrounding the event of management replacement, but

neither study explains the wide variation of fund premia across time or funds.

Explanations based on investor sentiment2 have had some success in accounting for the co-movement

of fund premia, but do not explain the wide variation in premia across different funds. The investor

1Weiss (1989) and Hanley, Lee, and Seguin (1994) provide empirical evidence of closed-end fund premium at the issuance,and initial price stabilization behavior provided by the lead underwriters. Cherkes (2003) argues that this special feature of buyers

paying the IPO costs via IPO over-pricing with the underwriters providing prolonged after-market price support as a supplement

to the IPO over-pricing is neither anti-competitive nor predatory.2See, for example, De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990) and Palomino (1996) for theoretical models. Lee,

Shleifer, and Thaler (1991), Hardouvelis, La Porta, and Wizman (1994), Kalibanoff, Lamont, and Wizman (1996), Bodurtha,

Kim, and Lee (1995), and Pontiff (1996, 1997) provide empirical evidence that the investment sentiment explains the comovementin closed-end fund discounts.

1

Page 5: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

sentiment hypothesis is based on the notion that closed-end fund shares are held mainly by individual

investors, many of whom are irrational and driven by sentiment. Although Gemmill and Thomas (2002)

find that retail-investor flows, which are used as a proxy for noise trader sentiment, lead to fluctuations

in premia, they reject the hypothesis that noise-trader risk is the cause of the long-run negative premia. In

addition, Dimson and Minio-Kozerski (1999) point out that the sentiment hypothesis is inconsistent with

the empirical evidence on UK closed-end funds, which are largely dominated by institutional investors.

Thus the wide cross-sectional and time series variation in fund premia remains largely unexplained.

In this paper we provide a simple explanation that is based on the liquidity of the markets in which the

shares and the assets of the funds are traded. Liquidity is a multi-dimensional attribute of an asset that

includes the cost of a transaction, the ability to trade promptly, the ease with which large quantities can be

traded, and the impact of trading on prices. Financial assets with similar, or even identical, payoffs often

differ in liquidity, and many studies have shown that illiquid assets tend to have lower prices and higher

returns.

An important feature of closed-end funds is that the shares and the underlying assets are close substi-

tutes, but are typically traded with different levels of liquidity. To the extent that liquidity affects asset

prices, we should expect premia to reflect the difference between the liquidity of the share market and that

of the asset market, and to vary over time as their relative market liquidity varies. In addition, the negative

relation between illiquidity and asset prices found in US bond and stock prices suggests that high share

market illiquidity is likely to reduce the share price and thus decrease the fund premium while high asset

market illiquidity is likely to reduce the asset value and thus increase the fund premium. Although this

is true of domestic as well as country funds, we restrict our analysis to country funds because the effect

of illiquidity on fund premia is clearer and easier to detect when the shares and the underlying assets are

traded in different markets.

We do not claim that liquidity is the only explanation for the wide variation of premia across time

and funds. Rather we show that asset and share market illiquidity have a statistically significant and

economically important relation to fund premia even after controlling for other variables such as the funds'

expense ratio, dividend yield, size, age, and a proxy for investor sentiment, and thus should be included

in models of closed end fund premia.

Using price and NAV data from August 1987 to December 2001 for 41 U.S.-traded closed-end single-

country funds, we show that illiquidity alone accounts for a large proportion of the variation in fund

premia: around 36% in the panel regression and 12% in the Fama-MacBeth regression. The relation

2

Page 6: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

between illiquidity and premia remains significant in the presence of all of the control variables that have

been proposed in previous studies, so it is unlikely that our illiquidity measures are proxying for other

known determinants of premia or discounts. Market illiquidity and the control variables together explain

over 60% of the variation in the premia over time; and across funds.

The association between premium and illiquidity is affected by the degree of market segmentation and

the ease with which liquidity shocks are transmitted between markets. We split the funds into two groups

according to the degree of integration between the share and the asset markets. The first group consists of

funds that invest in open economies whose markets are likely to be integrated with the US market, and the

second group consists of funds that invest in emerging markets which are mostly segmented from the US

market. We find that for the second group of funds, the share market illiquidity is negatively associated

with the premium while the asset market illiquidity is positively association with the fund premium. This

is consistent with our hypothesis that high asset market illiquidity is likely to reduce only the fund’s asset

value and therefore to increase the fund premium, while high illiquidity in the share market is likely

to reduce only the fund’s share price and therefore to decrease the fund premium if the asset market is

segmented from the share market. On the other hand, the association between the illiquidity of the two

markets and the fund premium is more mixed for funds investing in integrated markets. This is consistent

with investors being able to switch between the fund shares and its underlying asset portfolio, so that

liquidity in one market can easily spill over to the other.

Finally, like Elton, Gruber, and Busse (1998), we find no evidence that investor sentiment is a priced

factor for these country funds, casting further doubt on the “small investor sentiment” explanation of

closed-end fund premia or discounts.

These results provide further evidence of the negative effect of illiquidity on asset prices, and have

implications that extend beyond closed-end country funds. They provide an explanation for the effect

of location of trade on asset prices. For example, there are significant differences between the prices of

different classes of shares used by “Siamese-twin” companies such as Royal Dutch and Shell3 and also

between ADRs and their corresponding asset market shares. Our results suggest that liquidity differences

between the two markets may also explain these price differences. Indeed, Gagnon and Karolyi (2004)

also find that illiquidity in the US and the foreign market is significantly related to the price difference

between ADRs and their asset market counterparts.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section II, we motivate the empirical analysis

3See Bedi, Richards, and Tennant (2003) and the references therein for evidence on the price difference in different classes

of shares used by “Siamese-twin” companies.

3

Page 7: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

by linking liquidity in the share (U.S.) and the asset (foreign) markets to country fund premia. In section

III, we provide detailed information on the construction of the illiquidity measures for the share (U.S.) and

the asset (foreign) markets. In Section IV, we discuss the data on closed-end country fund premium and

other control variables and report summary statistics. In Section V, we report empirical findings and their

implications. Section VI summarizes and concludes the paper.

II. Market Segmentation and the Effect of Liquidity on Fund Premium

Theoretical studies of the effect of illiquidity on asset prices have yielded mixed results. While Kyle

(1985) and Allen and Gale (1996) show an important effect of illiquidity on asset prices, Constantinides

(1986) and Vayanos (1998) show that illiquidity in the form of transaction costs has a large effect on

asset turnover but only a very small effect on asset prices.4 Empirical studies consistently show, however,

that illiquidity depresses asset prices and leads to higher asset returns. In the bond market, on-the-run

Treasury bonds are more liquid and have higher prices than their off-the-run counterparts even though they

have very similar cash flows and characteristics; Treasury bonds have higher prices and greater liquidity

than similar government agency bonds even after controlling for coupon payment and default risk. For

example, Longstaff (2002) finds a large liquidity premium in Treasury bond prices by comparing Treasury

bond prices with prices of bonds issued by Refcorp, a U.S. Government agency, that are guaranteed by the

Treasury. In the stock market, Amihud (2002) shows that the aggregate stock returns are higher when the

market is less liquid. Amihud and Mendelson (1986), Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1996), and Brennan,

Chordia, and Subrahmanyam (1998) show that less liquid stocks tend to have higher returns.5 Finally,

Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) find that stock returns are related, not only to levels of liquidity, but also to

the covariance of returns with measures of market liquidity.

Consider now the effect of liquidity on the closed-end fund premium, which is defined as the difference

between log fund share price S and log fund asset value NAV : P ≡ lnS − ln NAV . When the asset

market is completely segmented from the share market, illiquidity in one market is confined to that market

alone. Since illiquidity is associated with lower asset prices, high share market illiquidity implies a lower

share price, S, but has no effect on asset value, NAV , which then leads to a lower fund premium, P . In

the opposite case, high asset market illiquidity implies a lower asset value, NAV , but has no effect on

4Other theoretical studies include Amihud and Mendelson (1986), Glosten (1989), Vayanos (2003), Huang (2003), Wang and

Vayanos (2003), and Longstaff (2004), among others.5Other empirical studies include Datar, Narayan and Radcliffe (1998), Chordia, Roll and Subrahmanyam (2000, 2001), and

Lo and Wang (2000), among others.

4

Page 8: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

the share price, S, which then leads to a higher fund premium, P .

The effect of illiquidity on P , however, is indeterminate if the share and the asset markets are integrated

and illiquidity in one market can transmit to another.6 In reality, some degree of integration between

markets exists and investors can, to some extent, substitute between investment in the closed end fund

and direct investment in the underlying asset. When one market suffers from high illiquidity, it is optimal

for investors to divert some of their demand for or supply of liquidity to another market: as a result, the

illiquidity in one market gets transmitted to another. Thus, illiquidity of the share or of the asset market

can affect both the fund price, S, and the fund asset value, NAV , leading to an ambiguous effect on

the fund premium, P . Since the degree of liquidity spillover and its effect on close substitutes traded in

different markets depend on the degree of market segmentation, we expect that the effect of illiquidity on

fund premium depends on the degree of integration of the fund’s asset market with its share market. In

particular, the clear-cut negative share market illiquidity effect and positive asset market illiquidity effect

on P holds only for funds investing in segmented markets, while the relation may be positive, negative or

zero for funds investing in integrated markets.

An interesting example of the effect of illiquidity is provided by the movement of fund premia around

the Asian Crisis in 1997-1998, when several Asian countries experienced a liquidity crunch, while the

share market (U.S.) was less affected. On June 26 1998, in the middle of the crisis, all funds investing

in Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand, Korea, and Russia were trading at large premia. At the same time, all

other funds, no matter whether they invested in emerging or developed markets, were trading at discounts.

Even funds invested in other Asian markets such as Taiwan, China, Hong Kong and India that were less

exposed to the crisis, traded at discounts. Cohen and Remolona (2001) report that prices of funds investing

in Asian Crisis countries and Russia moved from a discount before the crisis to a premium when the crisis

started, and the premium rose for all the funds during the crisis and then declined gradually or moved

back to a discount after the crisis.

III. Measures of Illiquidity

Our measure of illiquidity is related to Kyle’s (1985) lambda, which measures the effect of order flow on

prices. Amihud (2002) shows how to construct a Kyle-type measure of illiquidity using only daily returns

6For example, Newman and Rierson (2004) find strong evidence that the illiquidity in one corporate bond spills over to other

bonds in the same sector.

5

Page 9: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

and volume, which are readily available for almost every market.7

For each fund, we measure illiquidity each month for the fund itself, for the US market in which the

fund shares are traded, and for the corresponding foreign market in which the fund underlying assets are

traded. Following Amihud (2002), our illiquidity measure for stock i at month t in market c, ILi,c,t, is

defined as the average ratio of the absolute daily price change to a measure of the trading volume:

ILi,c,t =1Dt

Dt∑

d=1

|Ri,d|/V OLi,d, (1)

where Dt is the number of trading days in month t (approximately 21 days), Rid and V OLid are, respec-

tively, stock i’s daily return and daily volume in day d of month t. Foreign market Rid and V OLi,d are

measured in US dollars at the daily Datastream-reported foreign exchange rate. Unlike Amihud (2002)

who calculates illiquidity annually for stocks with at least 200 daily observations each year, we use only

around 21 days to calculate IL for each month, so that we can relate illiquidity to fund premia at a monthly

frequency.

The illiquidity of the shares of fund f in month t, ILf,t, is calculated using equation (1) from the

fund’s daily share price return and volume, and the illiquidity for the portfolio of all 41 funds is obtained

by averaging over the 41 individual funds' illiquidity ILf,t at each month t:

FILt ≡141

41∑

f=1

ILf,t.

The market wide illiquidity for the asset market (share market US) c, CILc,t (USILt), is calculated

as the equally weighted average of the illiquidity of all qualifying individual stocks in a representative

market index for that market:

CILc,t =1

Nc,t

Nc,t∑

i=1

ILi,c,t, (2)

where Nc,t is the number of stocks in the index of country c in month t. The qualifying stocks included in

7Many different measures of illiquidity have been used in empirical studies. For example, Amihud and Mendelson (1986) used

the quoted bid-ask spread on stock returns and Chalmers and Kadlec (1998) used the amortized effective spread as a measure of

liquidity. Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1996) measured illiquidity with the price response to signed order flow and with the fixedcost of trading based on continuous data on transaction and quotes, and Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) estimated liquidity cost

from signed volume related return reversals. Most of these liquidity measures require TAQ data, which are not readily available

in most foreign markets. Hasbrouck (2003) finds that the Amihud measure is highly correlated with the TAQ-based price impactmeasure in the U.S. market. In examining the short-run reversal and return illiquidity, Avramov et. al. (2005) also finds that

their results are virtually unchanged when the Amihud measure of illiquidity is replaced by other measures of illiquidity.

6

Page 10: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

the above calculation satisfy two criteria: (i) they must have trading volume greater than 1000 shares and

returns data available for at least 14 out of the 21 days in the month, and (ii) their estimated illiquidity

measure is not at the highest or lowest 5% tails of the distribution among stocks satisfying criterion (i).8

Daily data for prices, returns, and volumes on individual stocks from 8/7/1987 to 12/31/2001 in the

share (US) market are collected from CRSP, while the corresponding data for the foreign asset markets

are collected from Datastream. Table A1 lists the country funds and Table A2 lists the stock index that

was used to select the initial group of individual stocks whose returns and volumes are used to calculate

the market illiquidity for the share market and for the asset market of each of the 41 funds. For many

emerging markets, our illiquidity measure is available for a shorter sample period than the fund premium

data.

The time series of the logarithm of average fund illiquidity, lnFIL, and the share (US) market illiquidity,

lnUSIL, are plotted in Figure 1. There is a downward trend in the U.S. market illiquidity measure from

1990 to 1997 and then it stabilizes from 1997 to 2001. The average closed-end country fund illiquidity

tracked the U.S. market average illiquidity closely until 1997 but then moved up dramatically from 1997

to 2001. In the first half of the sample (August 1987 to the mid-1994), the average closed-end country

fund illiquidity was generally lower than the market average, implying that the closed-end country funds

had higher liquidity than the average stock in the NYSE. In contrast, the average illiquidity of the closed-

end country funds is higher than the market average throughout the second half of the sample, and the

difference between the two widens over time, implying an increasingly large “illiquidity cost” of investing

in closed-end country funds. Consistent with the implications of the figure, regressions of the average

fund illiquidity and the U.S. market illiquidity on time yield a significantly negative coefficient for the

U.S. market but significantly positive coefficient for the average fund illiquidity.

Illiquidity varies widely across asset markets possibly due to strikingly different levels of volume and

wide variation in the number of firms included in each market’s index. There is also a significant time

trend in the illiquidity of 20 of the 24 asset markets, with 11 of them negative and 9 of them positive.

8The measure of illiquidity for each individual stock is scaled by a multiplication of 106 . Criterion (ii) here is similar tocriterion (iv) in Amihud (2002). Our screening criteria are generally less stringent than those in Amihud (2002) due to the need

to calculate illiquidity for foreign and especially emerging markets.

7

Page 11: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

IV. Closed-end Country Fund Data

A. Fund Premium

We focus on U.S.-traded single country closed-end funds and, like most prior studies, exclude all ‘interna-

tional’ funds that are not identified with a single country. The Wall Street Journal reports at the beginning

of the week the closing price, the net asset value (NAV), and the discount, as of the last trading day of

the previous week, for all U.S.-traded closed-end funds. These data were collected for the last Friday of

each month from Dow Jones Interactive, for the 8/7/1987-12/31/2001 period. Observations on the last

Friday of each month are used in the analysis. There were only seven country closed-end funds prior to

August 1987 and only three prior to 1986, so the sample used in this study is very comprehensive. There

are altogether 47 single country funds trading in the U.S., and their underlying assets trade in 29 different

countries. Excluding the six funds that do not have enough data to calculate their asset market illiquidity,

we use the remaining 41 funds whose underlying assets trade in 24 different asset markets.

To avoid distortions associated with the flotation and winding up of closed end funds, we exclude

data for the first six months after the fund’s IPO9 and for one month preceding the announcement of a

liquidation, open-ending, or change in investment objective.10 The announcement date used for any such

change is the day on which the fund’s managers or board of directors propose a change in the structure

or in the investment objective of the fund. If shareholders propose a change, then the announcement date

is the date of approval by shareholders of such a change. This approach is used because shareholders

frequently propose changes but these are rarely successful. The announcement date is determined based on

news announcements and/or SEC filings. After this adjustment, there are at least 58 monthly observations

for all funds. A few funds, including the Germany Fund, the First Australia Fund and the Taiwan Fund,

have complete observations.

Thirty-three funds have negative average premia, and for most of them the average premium is below

-15%. For example, the New Germany (GF) and the First Philippine (FPF) funds have average premia

of almost -20%. Seven of the eight funds that have average positive premia invest in emerging markets

and mainly in Asia. JEQ (Japan Equity) is the only fund with an average positive premium that invests in

9Weiss (1989) finds that closed-end funds usually start out at a premium and that most of the price decline in closed-end funds

occurs between 30 and 100 days after the issue. Hanley, Lee and Seguin (1994) find substantial evidence of price stabilizationby lead underwriters during the first 100 days of issuance. Thus, in the initial trading period of a fund, the discount may have

an obvious deterministic trend.10Banerjee and Gangopadhyay (1997) report that when a closed-end fund approaches its windup date or turns open-ended, its

price converges to its NAV and thus its discount shrinks in a trended way.

8

Page 12: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

a developed market. The Indonesia fund (IF) has the largest average premium of about 18.2%, followed

by the Korea fund (KF) and the Thai fund (TTF) with an average premium of around 15%. These large

fund premia, especially those observed in the early sample period (before 1990), may be driven by capital

controls imposed in those countries11 as suggested in Bonser-Neal et. al. (1990). On the other hand, three

funds (Emerging Germany, New Germany, Growth Fund Spain), all of which invest in European countries

with virtually no capital controls, never had a positive premium throughout the period.

The time series variation in fund premium is large, and differs widely from fund to fund. The standard

deviation of the premium ranges from a low of 5% for the United Kingdom fund (UKM) to a high of 28%

for the Korea fund (KF), whose premium ranges from -41% to over 91%.

B. Control Variables

We also collect data on the following fund specific and country specific variables that have been found in

prior studies to be important determinants of the fund premium:

• Expense ratio (ExpRatio): Lipper reports the expense ratio (total annual expense divided by NAV)

of each fund at an annual frequency. We use the latest expense ratio available at the end of each

month as the expense ratio for that month. The expense ratio ranges from an average of 1% for

Japan Equity fund (JEQ) to a high of almost 2.8% for the Thai Capital fund (TC).

• Size (lnCap): The fund’s market capitalization (in millions of dollars) is obtained from CRSP.

Because this variable is highly skewed, we use its natural log in all of the tests. The average market

capitalization ranges from a low of $35.6 million for the Jakarta Growth Fund (JGF) to a high

of $581.4 million for the Mexico Fund (MXF), and 22 of the 41 funds have an average market

capitalization greater than $100 million.

• Age (lnAge): At the end of each month, each fund’s age is calculated as the natural log of the

number of years from its IPO date.

• Dividend yield (Divyld): The dividend yield is calculated as the CRSP reported dividends (excluding

capital gains dividends) paid by the fund in the prior 12-month period scaled by the end of month

NAV. Thirty-eight out of the 41 funds paid some dividends during this period, and the average

11We do not explicitly consider the effect of capital controls using government policy announcements as event dates, but instead

use the Edison-Warnock (2003) simple measure of capital control intensity as a control variable in our empirical analysis.

9

Page 13: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

dividend yield across all 41 funds is about 1.7% with the highest yield at 7.64% for the Mexico

Equity and Income Fund (MXE).

• Institutional ownership (InstOwn): Thomson Financial reports the institutional ownership for closed-

end funds at the end of each quarter based on 13(f) filings by institutions. We use the latest available

ownership data at the end of each month. On average, institutional ownership ranges from 4.2%

(GER) to about 28.6% (IIF), which is consistent with the majority of country fund shareholders

being individual investors.

• Edison-Warnock measure of capital control (EWS): Edison-Warnock (2003) construct measures of

the intensity of capital controls across 29 emerging markets based on restrictions on foreign ownership

of equities.12 They provide information on the extent and evolution of financial liberalization with

1 denoting complete capital control and 0 denoting the absence of capital control.

Twenty-six of the funds investing in thirteen different asset markets, all of which are in emerging

economies, have EWS measures greater than zero throughout the period and are classified as funds

investing in segmented markets. The remaining 15 funds investing in eleven different asset markets,

all of which are in open developed economies, have EWS measures equal to zero and are classified

as funds investing in integrated markets.

The average measure for the thirteen segmented markets ranges from a low of 0.11 for Argentina

to a high of 0.84 for India. For all countries except Russia, the measure exhibits a strong negative

trend, indicating that capital controls have been gradually reduced in all emerging asset markets

except for Russia.

• Share (US) market factor (USMKT): The concurrent monthly value weighted average return across

all stocks in NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ from CRSP is used to control for the market risk factor

in the share market.

• Asset (foreign) market factor (CMKT): The concurrent monthly total market index returns in local

currency for the twenty-four asset markets obtained from Datastream are used to control for the

market risk factor in the asset market.

• Foreign exchange appreciation rate (FXCHG): The concurrent monthly change in the foreign ex-

change rate between the US and the foreign country is measured as units of foreign currency per

12We thank Craig Doidge for suggesting this measure to us and Edison and Warnock for making this measure available on the

web page of the Federal Reserve Board - http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/2001/708/default.htm.

10

Page 14: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

US dollar and obtained from Datastream. This captures any movement in the fund premia caused

by the change in the foreign exchange rates.

• Average fund premium (AVGPrem): Following Bodurtha et. al. (1995), we calculate the arithmetic

average premium for all funds each month and denote this by ‘AVG.’ This variable is often used in

the literature as a proxy for small investor sentiment.

The average fund premium exhibits a clear time trend during the period. A regression of the average

discount on time yields a significantly negative coefficient and a large R2 (33%). Figure 2 plots the

average fund premium from August 1987 to December 2001. The premium fluctuates substantially:

at the start of the sample period, it is almost 13% but then drops rapidly to almost -13% in two

months around the crash of October 1987. In January 1990, the average fund premium reached a

high of over 28%. The large average premium in the early period was driven mainly by the large

premia of the two Asian country funds: the Korea fund and the Taiwan fund. Figures 1 and 2

show that as the average illiquidity of the funds increased relative to the U.S. market illiquidity, the

average fund premium went down.

Table I reports the details of the average premium, the natural log of fund average illiquidity and the

control variables. The average fund premium is about -6.6%: it is only about -3% for the funds investing

in segmented markets and -11% for funds investing in integrated markets. The average age for the funds

across all three groups is about 6 years, and the average age of funds investing in segmented markets (5.8

years) is slightly less than that (6.2 years) of funds investing in integrated markets.

The Edison-Warnock capital control measure for the 13 segmented markets is 0.58 on average. The

average fund has a market capitalization of $153.8 million. The average market capitalization is $177.4

million for funds investing in segmented markets and $123.2 million for funds investing in integrated

markets. The average dividend yield across all 41 funds is 1.95%, and it is 1.71% (2.45%) across the

26 (15) funds investing in segmented (integrated) markets. The average expense ratio across all 41 funds

is 1.83%, and it is 1.95% (1.64%) across the 26 (15) funds investing in segmented (integrated) markets.

Institutional investors own 13.7% of the country funds on average, and the institutional ownership is

around 16.2% (10.4%) for funds investing in segmented (integrated) markets.

In summary, funds investing in segmented markets generally have lower dividend yield, higher expense

ratio, and higher institutional ownership, but have much larger premia than those investing in integrated

markets. Additionally, segmented market funds generally invest in markets with higher average returns

and stronger capital controls.

11

Page 15: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

V. Empirical Analysis

In this section, we examine the relation between illiquidity and the premium of closed-end country funds.

In the first subsection, we examine the association between time series variation in the level of the closed-

end country fund premium and the variation in the share market illiquidity, the asset market illiquidity,

and the control variables. In the second subsection, we analyze how the cross-sectional variation in the

level of the closed-end country fund premium is related to illiquidity and other variables.

A. Illiquidity and Time Variation of Fund Premium

Table 2 reports averages of the time series correlations of the variables used in the empirical analysis.

There is a strong co-movement in the premia of different funds, as suggested by the correlation of 0.5

between the individual and average fund premium. On average, the individual fund premium is negatively

correlated with institutional ownership (-0.46) and age (-0.34), positively correlated with the asset market

capital control measure (0.36), the expense ratio (0.21), and asset market illiquidity (0.12). The other

correlations are all smaller than 0.1. Fund illiquidity is positively correlated with the illiquidity of both

the foreign asset market (0.29) and the U.S. share market (0.28). The large negative correlation between

fund illiquidity and fund size (-0.53) supports the practice of using asset size as a proxy for asset liquidity.

Fund illiquidity also negatively correlates with the average premium (-0.29), lending some preliminary

support for the hypothesis that funds with higher illiquidity tend to have lower fund price and thus lower

premium. The negative correlation between fund illiquidity and the foreign market capital control measure

suggests that funds investing in restricted markets can likely attract more investors and thus have higher

liquidity. In addition, fund illiquidity is slightly positively related to fund dividend yield (0.11), fund

expense ratio (0.17), and fund age (0.15). The large negative correlation between the US market illiquidity

and fund age (-0.54) indicates a gradually improving liquidity over time in the US market. In contrast, the

foreign market illiquidity has a small positive correlation with fund age. Returns in the foreign and the US

markets are positively correlated (0.39). The Edison-Warnock capital control measure (EWS) has a strong

negative correlation with fund age (-0.8), consistent with the fact that most foreign markets have gradually

loosened capital controls during this period. On the other hand, the positive correlation between EWS

and the average fund premium is consistent with the notion that restrictions on direct investment in some

foreign markets makes the corresponding closed-end country funds attractive to investors, which leads to

a higher fund premium for such funds. Larger funds and funds with higher institutional ownership tend to

have lower expense ratios as reflected by the negative correlations. Finally, the large negative correlation

12

Page 16: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

between the average fund premium and fund age implies that, on average, funds get deeper into discounts

with the passage of time.

To estimate the effect of the share and the asset market illiquidity on country fund premia, we estimate

a panel regression of fund premium on the share market illiquidity, the asset market illiquidity, and the

control variables:13

Pf,c,t = αf + β1lnUSILt + β2lnCILc,t + β3USMKTt + β4CMKTc,t + β5FXCHGc,t

+ β6EWSc,t + β7lnCapf,t + β8Divyldf,t + β9ExpRatiof,t + β10InstOwnf,t

+ β11AVGPremt + β12lnAgef,t, (3)

where αf is the fund fixed effect variable which captures fund specific characteristics that are not explained

by these control variables. The (fund invariant) average fund premium, AVGPrem, captures both investor

sentiment and the time fixed effect. The equation is estimated with and without the control variables.

Columns (1)-(4) of Table 3 report the regression results for all funds. When the fund premium is

regressed on the US and foreign market illiquidity, the two illiquidity variables explain 36.3% of the time

variation in fund premium, but the two coefficients are not significant at the 5% level. However, when

we add the average premium as an additional regressor in column (2) to take account of the time fixed

effect, not only does the regression R2 improve to 50.6%, but also all three regressors become highly

significant. Consistent with the negative illiquidity-asset price relation found in a single market, high US

market illiquidity is significantly associated with a lower fund price and thus a lower fund premium. On

the other hand, a higher asset market illiquidity is significantly associated with a lower fund NAV, and thus

a higher premium. Consistent with Bodurtha et. al. (1995), the coefficient estimate of 1.1 for ‘AVGPrem’

is close to one and highly significant. While this suggests a strong comovement among all country funds,

it is not yet clear that this comovement is necessarily driven by or reflects small investor sentiment.

In column (3), we report the result of a regression that includes all control variables except ‘AVGPrem’.

The R2 goes up to almost 58%, and both illiquidity variables, lnUSIL and lnCIL, remain significant with

the right sign. The other significant explanatory variables are FXCHG, EWS, Divyld, ExpRatio, InstOwn,

and lnAge. First, the fund premium is not significantly related to either the share or the asset market

factors, but it is positively and significantly related to the appreciation rate of dollar. Second, everything

13Both Amihud (2002) and Hasbrouck (2003) point out that while the Amihud measure of illiquidity works well for portfolios,it is very noisy and less reliable for individual stocks. In addition, lnFIL is highly correlated with the fund size. Therefore, lnFIL

is not included in this or the following Fama-MacBeth regressions.

13

Page 17: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

else constant, funds investing in markets with stronger capital controls tend to have a higher premium,

which is intuitive as limited direct investment drives up the demand for the country funds. Third, funds with

higher premia are also associated with higher dividend yields, higher expense ratios, but lower institutional

ownership. The significantly positive relation between fund premium and dividend yield is consistent

with the implication of the simple model proposed by Ross (2002). While the positive relation between

fund premium and the fund’s expense ratio is difficult to reconcile with the simple static expense-based

explanation for fund discounts, as it implies that funds with higher premium or lower discount tend to

have higher expense ratios, it is potentially consistent with the dynamic model of Berk and Stanton (2004)

in which managers whose funds are trading at a premium or a smaller discount have more bargaining

power to increase their compensation, and consequently, the fund expense. The negative relation between

fund premium and institutional ownership is consistent with two possible explanations: either institutional

investors are value investors who tend to buy “cheap” funds at deep discounts or, as suggested by Barclay

et. al. (1993), they are simply friends of entrenched managers and thus enable the existence of deeper

discounts.14 Finally, the fund premium is negatively and significantly associated with fund age so that

older funds tend to have a smaller premium or a larger discount.

When ‘AVGPrem’ is included in the regression in column (4), fund age is no longer significant, but

the coefficient estimates and statistical significance of all other variables remain virtually unchanged.

In columns (5)-(8), the regression is carried out for funds investing in segmented markets. Results for

this group of funds are very similar to those for all funds except for the coefficient on fund size. Contrary

to the widely documented positive relation, the coefficient on size is significantly negative. Size captures

two effects in this case. On the one hand, it is highly negatively correlated with the fund’s illiquidity,

so it is a good proxy for fund liquidity. As a result, larger funds tend to have higher liquidity (or lower

illiquidity) and thus higher fund premium, implying a positive relation between premium and size. On

the other hand, the size of funds investing in segmented markets also represents the US supply of the

investment opportunity in restricted foreign markets. Given the level of demand, smaller funds tend to

have lower supply and thus higher fund premium, implying a negative relation between premium and size.

The negative coefficient reported in column (8) suggests that the supply effect dominates.

In columns (9)-(12), the regression is carried out for funds investing in integrated markets. While both

lnUSIL and lnCIL are still highly significant, the coefficient on lnUSIL has changed from around -0.04

for all funds and -0.07 for segmented market funds to a positive 0.03. The positive sign is inconsistent

14A simple regression analysis shows that the change in fund premium is positively and significantly related to lagged institu-

tional ownership, providing support for the first hypothesis that institutional investors are likely to be value investors.

14

Page 18: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

with the hypothesis that higher US market illiquidity implies a lower fund price and thus a lower fund

premium, but is consistent with the hypothesis that illiquidity in the US market gets transmitted easily to

integrated (European and Japanese) asset markets so that US market illiquidity affects both fund price and

NAV resulting in an ambiguous effect on the fund premium.

To address the concern that the series may be nonstationary, we carry out unit root tests for residuals

from the panel regression. The panel unit root tests15 strongly reject the null of unit root, no matter whether

it is assumed to be specific to an individual series or to be common across all residual series.

In addition to the above unit root tests, we also check the robustness of the results by using detrended

data in the fixed effect panel regressions. The detrended variable is the residual from regressing the

corresponding raw variable on a time trend. The results are reported in Panel B of Table 3. Because the

data are already detrended, we exclude fund age from the regression. Results for all funds are reported

in columns (1)-(4). When the detrended US market and foreign market illiquidity variables are the

only regressors, both coefficient estimates remain highly significant with the right sign, providing strong

evidence that the association between market illiquidity and the time variation of fund premium is robust

to the removal of time trend in the data. When control variables are included in the regression, the fund

premium still positively and significantly varies with foreign market illiquidity, but has only an insignificant

relation with the US market illiquidity. The fund premium still moves positively with weaker asset market

currencies or a stronger dollar, and the strong comovement between individual fund premium and the

average premium remains in the detrended variables. While the coefficient on dividend yield (institutional

ownership) is still positive (negative) and significant, the other variables no longer have a significant

relation with fund premium. In particular, the detrended EWS has now virtually no relation with the fund

premium. The results with detrended data for segmented market funds are reported in columns (5)-(8).

The US market and the foreign market illiquidity alone account for about 13% of the time variation in

fund premium, and both variables remain highly significant with the right sign in the presence of control

variables. Except for ‘EWS’, the results for the other variables are broadly consistent with those obtained

using the raw data. The regressions are then repeated with detrended data for integrated market funds. The

results in column (9) suggest that the detrended illiquidity is no longer significantly associated with the

fund premium with a regression R2 of only about 1% and insignificant coefficient estimates. Similar to the

result from the raw data, the association between fund premium and the US market illiquidity is positive

and highly significant when control variables are added to the regression. The coefficient estimates on the

15Some recent studies such as Levin, Lin and Chu (2002) and Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003) suggest that panel-based unit root

tests have higher power than unit root tests based on individual time series.

15

Page 19: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

control variables are also mostly consistent with those reported in Panel A.

B. Illiquidity and Cross-sectional Variation of Fund Premium

The above regressions were carried out by considering the 41 funds jointly to take advantage of the

information across all funds and to enhance the power. Since the number of time periods is relatively large

as compared to the number of funds, we are able to examine the relation between the time series variation

in fund premia and the movement in illiquidity of the share and the asset markets. The panel regression,

however, implicitly assumes that regression coefficients are constant over time. To relax this assumption

and to examine the relation between the cross-sectional variation in fund premia and in the illiquidity of

the share and the asset markets, we carry out a Fama-MacBeth type of regression in this section.

Since the share market illiquidity is the same across all 41 funds, the level of the U.S. share market

illiquidity cannot be included as one of the regressors. Motivated by Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) who

find that expected stock returns are related cross-sectionally to the sensitivities of returns to fluctuations

in aggregate liquidity, we use the share-market illiquidity beta, βlnUSIL, in the Fama-MacBeth regression,

where βlnUSIL is obtained by regressing the fund premium on the natural log of US market illiquidity.

Following Gemmill and Thomas (2002), we define the noise-trader risk beta, βNoise, as the sensitivity

of the individual fund premium to the average premium and estimate it from regressing the fund premium

on the average fund premium. This variable is then used to replace the fund-invariant average fund

premium in the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regression. Finally, we replace the US market return with

the market risk beta, βUSMKT , which is estimated from a regression of the fund’s NAV return on the US

market return and captures the underlying asset’s systematic risk, in the regression.

Since our sample from 1987 to 2001 covers only about 14 years and many funds have data for a

shorter period, it is not feasible to estimate the betas using rolling windows of data. Thus, we estimate

βlnUSIL, βNoise, and βUSMKT using all available data in the first step.

The cross-sectional correlations for the average values of all variables are reported in Table 4. In

the cross section, the fund premium is still negatively (positively) correlated with institutional ownership

(expense ratio), but its correlation with the dividend yield is now negative. The fund illiquidity is almost

perfectly negatively correlated with the fund size and highly positively correlated with fund expense ratio

in the cross section. The fund’s US market illiquidity beta, βlnUSIL, and the fund’s market risk beta,

βUSMKT , are negatively correlated. On the other hand, βUSMKT is positively correlated with the noise-

trader risk beta, βNoise, suggesting that funds with higher underlying asset risk also tend to have higher

16

Page 20: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

noise-trader risk. Similar to the time series correlations, larger funds tend to have lower expense ratios and

higher institutional ownership. Funds with higher dividend yields are also older and have lower expense

ratios and smaller noise-trader risk. The large positive correlation between fund institutional ownership and

the fund’s noise-trader risk beta implies that funds more dominated by small investors tend to have lower

instead of higher noise-trader risk, which is the opposite of what the investor sentiment story predicts.

Next, we examine the following Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regression with time-invariant betas:

Pf,c,t = c0,t + c1,tβlnUSIL,f + c2,tlnCILc,t + c3,tβUSMKT,f + c4,tCMKTc,t + c5,tFXCHGc,t

+ c6,tEWSc,t + c7,tlnCapf,t + c8,tDivyldf,t + c9,tExpRatiof,t + c10,tInstOwnf,t

+ c11,tβNoise,f + c12,tlnAgef,t. (4)

The regression is carried out at each month t with at least 20 (15) observations for all funds and for funds

investing in segmented (integrated) markets.

The coefficient estimates ci (i = 0, · · · , 12) are time series averages of the corresponding cross-

sectional regression estimates ci = 1T

∑Tt=1 ci,t, where T is the number of months used in the cross-

sectional regression and is usually smaller than the total number of periods T = 173.

The general variance and covariance matrix of the vector of coefficient estimates, c ≡ [c0, · · · , c12], is

given by the sample variance of the mean of the cross-sectional regression estimates

σ2(c) =1T 2

k∑

j=−k

k − |j|k

Cov (ct, ct−j) ,

where ct = [c0,t, · · · , c12,t] and k = floor(4(T/100)2/9

),16 which yields heteroscedasticity and serial

correlation adjusted Newey-West standard errors for c.

Table 5 reports the Fama-MacBeth coefficient estimates with the robust Newey-West t−ratios in

brackets. When all funds are included in the regression, the US market illiquidity beta and the foreign

market illiquidity level explain an average of about 12% of the total cross-sectional variation in fund

premium. When the fund age is added to the regression, the R2 increases to 17%, and all the explanatory

variables are statistically significant at the 5% level. Consistent with the findings of Pastor and Stambaugh

(2003), funds with higher sensitivity to the US market illiquidity have a significantly lower premium,

16Newey and West (1987) only requires that k = o(T 1/4

), and we adopt the automatic selection of the lag formula in the

econometrics software Eviews. In our current setting, this formula leads to k = 3 which corresponds to a truncation at thequarterly frequency.

17

Page 21: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

and similar to our panel regression results, funds associated with lower asset market illiquidity have a

significantly higher premium. Contrary to the panel regression results, however, younger funds have lower

instead of higher premium in the cross section. The US market illiquidity beta (but not the level of the

asset market illiquidity) remains significant when additional control variables are added in the regression,

and they together explain almost 60% of the cross-sectional variation. The other significant results are:

1) The marginally significant negative coefficient on the foreign market return implies that fund premium

is lower when the asset market return is higher, which seems to suggest that the fund price fails to catch

up with the appreciation in the NAV when the foreign market goes up. 2) While the importance of size

has been noted in many previous studies, the negative sign here implies that larger funds tend to have

lower premium. This is consistent with the panel regression result, and provides further evidence that size

may also be a measure of the supply of restricted investment opportunities and thus relate negatively to

premium. 3) The highly significant and positive relation between fund premium and the Edison-Warnock

capital control measure is consistent with Bonser-Neal et. al. (1990) and the intuition that investors

actively seek closed-end funds that invest in restricted foreign markets. 4) The marginally significant

negative coefficient on the institutional ownership variable indicates that each one percent increase in

institutional ownership results in a 0.2 percent decrease in fund premium. This is consistent with Barclay

et. al. (1993) in that institutions may be friendly to entrenched managers and by voting against open-

ending proposals they enable the existence of deeper discounts, but it is also possible that institutional

investors hold more funds with deeper discounts because these funds are “cheaper” and thus represent

better investment opportunities. 5) Finally, similar to Elton et. al. (1998), we also find that the noise-

trader beta is not a significant explanatory variable for closed-end country fund premia so we reject the

notion that noise-trader risk is a priced factor.

Columns (5)-(8) report the results for funds investing in segmented markets. Results in columns (5)

and (6) are similar to those in (1) and (2) but with a higher average R2 of 18% and 26% respectively. The

differences between the results in columns (7) and (8) and those in columns (3) and (4) are summarized as

follows. First, the US market illiquidity beta is no longer significant but still has the intuitive negative sign.

On the other hand, the foreign market illiquidity has become significantly positive, which is consistent

with the sign in the panel regression and with the hypothesis that higher foreign market illiquidity is

associated with lower NAV and thus higher premium. Second, the US market return beta has replaced the

foreign market return to be a significant explanatory variable. The positive coefficient is surprising since

it indicates that investors are attracted to funds with higher market risk leading to higher fund premium.

18

Page 22: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Third, size is not a significant explanatory variable for cross-sectional variation in premium. This result,

together with the significant negative relation between size and premium for all funds reported in columns

(3)-(4), suggests that size helps explain the variation of premium between segmented and integrated funds,

but does not contribute to the variation of premium among segmented funds. Finally, the noise-trader beta

has become significantly and negatively related to fund premium, which is consistent with the notion that

funds with higher noise-trader risk are associated with a lower fund premium.

Columns (9)-(12) report the results for funds investing in integrated markets. A few new interesting

observations arise in this case. The results in columns (9) and (10) indicate that while the US market

illiquidity beta remains the dominant explanatory variable, the foreign market illiquidity is not significant

and is associated with the wrong sign for these funds. In addition, the coefficient for fund age is now

negative and significant, suggesting that older funds tend to have smaller premia or larger discounts.

Consistent with the findings of Pontiff (1996), Gemmill and Thomas (2002), and several other studies, the

coefficient on dividend yield is now significant and positive. Also consistent with the puzzling result in

Gemmill and Thomas (2002) based on UK closed-end fund data, we find a positive and highly significant

coefficient for the noise risk beta. The positive sign suggests, counter-intuitively, that investors are willing

to buy the fund at a higher fund premium or lower discount if the fund has higher noise-trader risk. It is

thus unlikely that the noise-trader risk is the cause of country fund discounts. Finally, the high R2 for this

group of 15 funds should be interpreted with caution as it is very likely caused by the lack of degrees of

freedom in the regression.

A comparison of results in columns (6) and (10) suggests that while both the share-market illiquidity

beta and the asset-market illiquidity level help explain the cross-sectional variation in fund premium for

funds investing in segmented markets, the share-market illiquidity beta is the more important variable for

funds investing in integrated markets.

In summary, market illiquidity plays an important role in both the time series and the cross-sectional

variation in the fund premium. Similar to the negative association between illiquidity and bond/stock

prices documented in single markets, results for funds investing in segmented markets are consistent with

the conjecture that asset (share) market illiquidity negatively affects fund NAV (price) and positively

(negatively) affects fund premium. On the other hand, results for funds investing in integrated markets

are consistent with the notion that illiquidity can easily spill over borders and lead to an ambiguous effect

on fund premium.

19

Page 23: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

VI. Conclusion

Closed-end country fund shares and underlying assets are close substitutes but are traded in different

markets with different illiquidity. To the extent that illiquidity affects asset prices, the time varying

deviation of fund price from fund NAV may well be driven by stochastic illiquidity in the two markets.

Using the price and NAV data of 41 US-traded single country closed-end funds, we examine how much

illiquidity of the US and of the foreign market explains the time series and cross-sectional variation in

fund premium.

Empirical results show that market illiquidity accounts for around 36% of the time series and 12% of the

cross-sectional variation in fund premium. In addition, fund premium has a significant and negative relation

with the share market illiquidity, and a significant but positive relation with the asset market illiquidity.

The effect of illiquidity on fund premium remains significant in the presence of control variables that

are used in previous studies to explain closed end fund premia, so market illiquidity provides a new and

economically important explanation for the wide time series as well as cross-sectional variation in fund

premium. Market illiquidity and control variables together explain over 60% of the premium variation

both over time and across funds. Therefore, the wide variation in fund premium is not puzzling at all.

20

Page 24: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table 1 Summary Statistics

This table reports the average value of the fund premium, illiquidity measures, and control variables for all funds, for funds investing

in segmented markets, and for funds investing in integrated markets.

All Funds Investing in Funds Investing in

Variables Funds Segmented Markets Integrated Markets

Number of funds 41 26 15

Premium (%) -6.55 -3.08 -11.02

Log Average Fund Illiquidity -2.31 -2.34 -2.48Log US Market Illiquidity -2.56 -2.56 -2.56

Log Average Foreign Market Illiquidity 9.23 7.25 9.99

US Market Return (% per month) 0.78 0.78 0.78Foreign Market Average Return (% per month) 1.67 2.34 0.71

Foreign Exchange Appreciation Rate (% per month) 0.66 1.02 0.17

Edison-Warnock Capital Control Measure (EWS) 0.36 0.58 0.00Market Capitalization (millions $) 153.8 177.4 123.2

Dividend Yield (% per year) 1.95 1.71 2.45

Expense Ratio (% per year) 1.83 1.95 1.64Institutional Ownership (%) 13.72 16.17 10.35

Age (years since IPO) 5.91 5.81 6.16

21

Page 25: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table 2 Time Series Correlations of Premium, Illiquidity, and Control Variables

This table reports the average of the time series correlation between the fund premium (Premium), the individual fund illiquidity (lnFIL), the share (lnUSIL) and the asset (lnCIL) market

illiquidity, and control variables, which include US and foreign market index return (USMKT and CMKT), the foreign exchange appreciation rate (FXCHG), the Edison-Warnock measure of capital

control (EWS), size (lnCAP), dividend yield (Divyld), expense ratio (ExpRatio), institutional ownership (InstOwn), the average fund premium across all funds which represents small investor

sentiment (AVGPrem), and fund age (lnAge). The pairwise correlations reported here are obtained in two steps. The time series correlation between any two variables is calculated first for each

fund, and then averaged across the 41 funds in the second step.

lnFIL lnUSIL lnCIL USMKT CMKT FXCHG EWS lnCAP Divyld ExpRatio InstOwn AVGPrem lnAge

Premium -0.07 0.05 0.12 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.36 -0.06 0.09 0.21 -0.46 0.51 -0.34

lnFIL 0.28 0.29 -0.07 -0.12 -0.01 -0.28 -0.53 0.11 0.17 -0.08 -0.29 0.15lnUSIL 0.07 -0.06 -0.07 -0.09 0.29 -0.27 0.15 0.22 -0.17 0.04 -0.54

lnCIL -0.04 -0.10 0.07 -0.20 -0.42 0.01 0.09 -0.20 -0.09 0.12

USMKT 0.39 -0.04 0.04 0.07 -0.02 -0.05 0.00 0.12 -0.02CMKT -0.04 0.02 0.13 -0.03 0.06 0.01 0.18 0.00

FXCHG -0.01 -0.07 0.01 -0.04 0.00 -0.01 0.04

EWS 0.13 0.10 0.04 -0.28 0.50 -0.80lnCAP -0.03 -0.35 0.37 0.04 0.12

Divyld -0.07 0.02 0.01 -0.05

ExpRatio -0.37 0.09 -0.22InstOwn -0.24 0.38

AVGPrem -0.58

22

Page 26: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table 3 Panel Data Regression of Fund Premium on the Share and the Asset Market Illiquidity

This table reports the regression of fund premium on the share and the asset market illiquidity as well as other control variables by pooling all the funds together and using the fund

fixed effect. Newey-West t−ratios reported in the bracket are adjusted for contemporaneous correlation, heteroscedasticity, and serial correlation with a lag of m = 4. The results are similar when

m = 12 or m = 24.

Panel A: Raw Data

Independent All Funds Segmented Market Funds Integrated Market Funds

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

lnUSIL 0.007 -0.013 -0.084 -0.040 -0.011 -0.031 -0.098 -0.067 0.028 0.012 -0.036 0.028[0.54] [-2.69] [-4.68] [-3.50] [-0.70] [-3.80] [-5.11] [-4.30] [2.50] [2.38] [-1.79] [2.70]

lnCIL 0.013 0.027 0.016 0.019 0.013 0.033 0.022 0.023 0.011 0.016 0.006 0.012

[1.52] [3.96] [2.12] [2.89] [1.12] [3.89] [2.26] [2.65] [3.18] [5.65] [1.44] [3.62]USMKT 0.115 0.080 0.158 0.124 -0.017 -0.025

[1.40] [1.97] [1.61] [1.68] [0.17] [-0.39]

CMKT 0.090 0.000 0.089 0.008 0.125 -0.028[1.80] [0.00] [1.65] [0.20] [1.91] [-0.68]

FXCHG 0.298 0.280 0.304 0.273 0.105 0.191

[4.22] [4.38] [4.30] [4.19] [1.08] [2.49]EWS 0.158 0.144 0.160 0.134

[5.54] [5.07] [4.89] [4.20]

lnCap -0.017 -0.021 -0.028 -0.046 0.023 0.046[-0.67] [-1.13] [-1.06] [-2.24] [0.85] [2.61]

Divyld 0.485 0.476 0.297 0.260 0.656 0.671

[4.65] [4.83] [2.14] [1.96] [5.61] [5.87]ExpRatio 0.054 0.052 0.051 0.050 0.042 0.033

[3.42] [4.97] [3.34] [4.94] [1.62] [2.11]

InstOwn -0.622 -0.539 -0.739 -0.632 -0.307 -0.280[-8.67] [-10.68] [-7.93] [8.24] [-3.77] [4.75]

AVGPrem 1.112 0.850 1.338 0.850 0.799 0.945

[33.75] [15.76] [21.69] [11.01] [13.60] [13.46]lnAge -0.079 0.003 -0.089 -0.023 -0.076 0.029

[-3.70] [0.21] [-3.81] [-1.35] [-2.82] [1.88]

Fund Fixed Effect Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y

R2 36.3 50.6 57.7 62.8 34.9 50.0 60.6 64.3 33.4 51.6 47.2 60.5

R2 35.7 50.1 57.1 62.3 34.3 49.5 60.0 63.8 32.8 51.1 46.4 59.9

# of Observations 4652 4652 3960 3960 2847 2847 2416 2416 1805 1805 1689 1689

23

Page 27: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table 3 (continued)

Panel B: Detrended Data

Independent All Funds Segmented Market Funds Integrated Market Funds

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

lnUSIL -0.055 -0.002 -0.060 -0.005 -0.088 -0.032 -0.080 -0.030 -0.003 0.048 -0.024 0.033[-3.79] [-0.27] [-4.46] [-0.51] [-6.22] [-4.64] [-6.10] [-2.27] [-0.15] [5.48] [-1.43] [3.48]

lnCIL 0.032 0.035 0.028 0.029 0.046 0.048 0.045 0.045 -0.002 0.000 -0.009 -0.006

[3.36] [4.31] [3.02] [3.70] [4.30] [5.44] [4.19] [4.71] [-0.29] [0.02] [-1.52] [-1.33]USMKT 0.058 0.023 0.105 0.064 -0.030 -0.027

[0.72] [0.70] [1.11] [1.10] [-0.31] [-0.44]

CMKT 0.121 0.029 0.130 0.052 0.114 -0.039[2.79] [0.99] [2.93] [1.64] [1.88] [-0.93]

FXCHG 0.287 0.282 0.289 0.273 0.113 0.210[4.61] [4.56] [4.58] [4.26] [1.12] [2.84]

EWS -0.062 -0.046 -0.063 -0.048

[-1.01] [0.83] [-1.06] [-0.91]lnCap 0.016 0.012 0.018 0.012 0.007 0.021

[0.83] [0.92] [0.84] [0.74] [0.24] [1.24]

Divyld 0.467 0.410 0.258 0.242 0.782 0.594[3.92] [3.74] [1.92] [1.88] [5.55] [5.01]

ExpRatio 0.030 0.023 0.041 0.034 0.033 0.020

[1.73] [1.76] [2.47] [2.69] [1.12] [1.09]InstOwn -0.434 -0.409 -0.481 -0.437 -0.336 -0.374

[-7.43] [-9.10] [-6.07] [-6.76] [-5.08] [-7.06]

AVGPrem 0.970 0.902 1.016 0.846 0.908 0.961[20.92] [16.42] [16.77] [10.62] [15.63] [16.34]

Fund Fixed Effect Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y YR2 7.2 20.1 19.7 30.9 13.1 23.9 27.3 34.8 0.9 22.0 11.4 32.9

R2 6.3 19.4 18.7 30.0 12.2 23.1 26.2 33.8 0.0 21.3 10.2 31.9

# of Observations 4652 4652 3960 3960 2847 2847 2416 2416 1805 1805 1689 1689

24

Page 28: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table 4 Cross-sectional Correlations of Premium, Illiquidity, and Control Variables

This table reports the cross-sectional correlation between the fund premium (Premium), the individual fund illiquidity (lnFIL), the US market illiquidity beta (βlnUSIL), the home mar-

ket illiquidity (lnCIL), and control variables, which include the US market return beta (βUSMKT ), the foreign market index return (CMKT), the foreign exchange appreciation rate (FXCHG), the

Edison-Warnock measure of capital control (EWS), size (lnCAP), dividend yield (Divyld), expense ratio (ExpRatio), institutional ownership (InstOwn), and the noise trader beta (βNoise). The

pairwise correlations reported here are obtained in two steps. First, the time series average of each variable is calculated, and second, the cross-sectional correlations across the 41 funds are obtained.

lnFIL βlnUSIL lnCIL βUSMKT CMKT FXCHG EWS lnCAP Divyld ExpRatio InstOwn βNoise lnAge

Premium 0.20 -0.17 0.05 -0.08 -0.12 0.01 0.19 -0.21 -0.24 0.24 -0.41 -0.02 0.13

lnFIL -0.26 0.20 -0.22 -0.14 0.03 0.00 -0.95 -0.14 0.65 -0.38 -0.15 -0.39

βlnUSIL -0.15 -0.48 0.19 0.20 -0.28 0.24 0.37 -0.18 0.15 0.11 0.42lnCIL -0.03 -0.16 0.11 0.17 -0.09 -0.24 0.31 0.32 0.17 -0.04

βUSMKT 0.08 0.06 0.53 0.17 -0.54 0.12 0.38 0.50 -0.32

CMKT 0.18 0.11 0.05 0.05 0.18 0.24 0.00 -0.02FXCHG 0.05 -0.05 -0.01 0.15 0.30 0.18 -0.07

EWS 0.06 -0.35 0.48 0.45 0.27 -0.21

lnCAP 0.18 -0.59 0.43 0.09 0.44Divyld -0.31 -0.13 -0.36 0.31

ExpRatio 0.09 0.06 -0.35

InstOwn 0.42 -0.03βNoise -0.25

25

Page 29: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table 5 Fama-MacBeth Cross-Sectional Regression of Fund Premium on Measures of the Share and the Asset Market Illiquidity

This table reports the results of the Fama-MacBeth regression of fund premium on the share market illiquidity beta, the asset market illiquidity and control variables. In the first stage,

the US market illiquidity (market return or noise trader) beta is obtained as the slope estimate in the time series univariate regression of the fund premium on US market illiquidity (US market return

or the average fund premium) using all available data. In the second stage, the cross-sectional fund premium is regressed on the share market illiquidity beta, the asset market illiquidity, and control

variables at each month t. Finally, the estimated coefficients from each month t are averaged to obtain the final coefficient estimates. The Newey-West robust t−ratios are reported in the brackets.

Independent All Funds Segmented Market Funds Integrated Market Funds

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Intercept -0.070 -0.235 -0.011 -0.065 -0.162 -0.495 -0.549 -0.413 -0.117 0.108 -0.276 -0.411[-4.53] [-3.63] [-0.14] [-1.22] [-3.99] [-3.69] [-3.04] [-3.17] [-3.19] [2.70] [-0.97] [-1.57]

βlnUSIL -0.133 -0.216 -0.018 -0.148 -0.255 -0.489 -0.089 -0.018 -0.676 -0.579 -0.671 -0.797

[-1.80] [-2.26] [-0.29] [-3.38] [-2.60] [-3.00] [-1.41] [-0.40] [-3.20] [-3.15] [-2.41] [-2.84]lnCIL 0.003 0.003 0.005 0.000 0.012 0.012 0.088 0.008 -0.001 0.000 -0.054 -0.002

[2.45] [2.23] [0.33] [0.09] [2.64] [2.96] [2.51] [2.14] [-1.13] [1.09] [-1.67] [-1.16]

βUSMKT -0.001 0.006 0.005 0.051 0.001 -0.031[-0.89] [0.48] [1.04] [2.31] [0.90] [-1.55]

CMKT -0.106 -0.182 -0.168 -0.209 -0.243 -0.002

[-1.23] [-1.93] [-1.16] [-1.28] [-1.06] [-0.01]FXCHG 0.407 0.275 0.503 0.267 1.029 0.327

[1.81] [1.30] [0.79] [0.44] [1.81] [0.81]

lnCap -0.038 -0.031 0.008 0.009 0.043 0.043[-3.57] [-3.49] [0.84] [0.99] [1.41] [1.56]

EWS 0.117 0.087 0.166 0.114[4.23] [3.76] [3.59] [2.96]

Divyld -0.185 -0.018 -0.183 -0.130 0.005 0.791

[-1.27] [-0.16] [-0.37] [-0.31] [0.01] [2.04]ExpRatio -0.012 0.003 0.029 0.027 0.087 0.065

[-1.04] [0.29] [1.65] [1.67] [1.25] [1.05]

InstOwn -0.176 -0.180 -0.361 -0.332 -0.810 -0.587[-1.73] [-1.90] [-2.26] [-2.14] [-2.84] [-2.71]

βNoise 0.013 -0.029 0.119

[0.91] [-2.21] [3.01]lnAge 0.061 0.059 0.055 0.154 0.109 0.072 -0.116 -0.028 -0.011

[2.83] [2.63] [3.47] [3.30] [3.03] [3.10] [-3.26] [-0.90] [-0.45]

Average R2 12.3 17.0 61.6 67.3 18.3 25.7 75.8 77.7 36.5 45.3 91.1 97.2

Average R2 6.0 7.7 38.9 45.3 10.6 14.5 52.7 52.3 26.0 30.3 66.9 84.6

No. of Periods 131 131 105 105 79 79 72 72 43 43 43 43

26

Page 30: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Figure 1

Time Series of Average Fund Illiquidity and the U.S. Market Illiquidity

This figure plots the logarithm of the U.S. market illiquidity, ln (USIL), and the logarithm of the average Amihud illiquidity, ln (FIL), acrossavailable closed-end country funds at the end of each month from August 1987 to December 2001.

1987.08 1989.08 1991.08 1993.08 1995.08 1997.08 1999.08 2001.08−4

−3.5

−3

−2.5

−2

−1.5

−1

−0.5

0

0.5

1

Fund Average IlliquidityUS Market Illiquidity

27

Page 31: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Figure 2

Time Series of Average Fund Premium

This figure plots the average premium, AVGPrem, across available closed-end country funds at the end of each month from August 1987 to

December 2001.

1987.08 1989.08 1991.08 1993.08 1995.08 1997.08 1999.08 2001.08−0.3

−0.2

−0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

28

Page 32: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

References

Allen, Franklin and Douglas Gale, 1994, Limited Market Participation and Volatility of Asset Prices,

American Economic Review 84, 933-955.

Amihud, Yakov, 2002, Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Cross-section and Time-series Effects, Journal of

Financial Markets 5, 31-56.

Amihud, Yakov, and Clifford M. Hurvich, 2003, Predictive Regressions: A Reduced-Bias Estimation

Method, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, forthcoming.

Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson, 1986, Asset Pricing and the Bid Ask Spread, Journal of Financial

Economics 17, 223-249.

Avramov, Doron, Tarun Chordia, and Amit Goyal, 2005, Liquidity and autocorrelations in individual stock

returns, working paper, University of Maryland.

Banerjee, Saumya, and Gora Gangopadhyay, 1997, Discounts in Closed-End Funds with Fixed Windup

Dates: Evidence From Thailand’s Stock Markets, mimeo, Brunel University.

Barclay, Michael J., Clifford G. Holderness, and Jeffrey Pontiff, 1993, Private benefits from block own-

ership and discounts on closed-end funds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 263-291.

Bedi, Jaideep, Anthony Richards, and Paul Tennant, 2003, The characteristics and trading behavior of

dual-listed companies, working paper, Reserve Bank of Australia.

Bekaert, Geert, and Michael Urias, 1996, Diversification, Integration and Emerging Market Closed-End

Funds, The Journal of Finance 51, 835-869.

Bodurtha, James N., Dong-Soon Kim, and Charles M.C. Lee, 1995, Closed-end Country Funds and U.S.

Market Sentiment, The Review of Financial Studies 8, 879-917.

Bonser-Neal, Catherine, Gregory Brauer, Robert Neal, and Simon Wheatley, 1990, International Investment

Restrictions and Closed-End Country Fund Prices, the Journal of Finance 45, 523-547.

Brauer, Gregory A., 1988, Closed-End Fund Shares’ Abnormal Returns and the Information Content of

Discounts and Premiums, The Journal of Finance 43, 113-127.

Brennan, Michael J., Tarun Chordia, and Avanindhar Subrahmanyam, 1998, Alternative factor speci-

fication, security characteristics, and the cross-section of expected stock returns, Journal of Financial

Economics 49, 345-373.

Brennan, Michael J., and Avanindhar Subrahmanyam, 1996, Market microstructure and asset pricing: on

the compensation for illiquidity in stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 41, 441-464.

Campbell, John, Andrew Lo, and Craig MacKinlay, 1997, The Econometrics of Financial Markets, Prince-

29

Page 33: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

ton University Press.

Campbell, John Y., Sanford J. Grossman, and Jiang Wang, 1993, Trading volume and serial correlation in

stock returns, Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 905-939.

Chen, Nai-fu, Raymond Kan, and Merton H. Miller, 1993, Are the Discounts on Closed-End Funds a

Sentiment Index?, The Journal of Finance 48, 795-800.

Cherkes, Martin, 2003, A positive theory of closed-end funds as an investment vehicle, working paper,

Princeton University.

Chordia, Tarun, Richard Roll, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 2000, Commonality in liquidity, Journal of

Financial Economics 56, 3-28.

Cohen, Benjamin H., and Eli M. Remolona, 2001, Information flows during the Asian Crisis: Evidence

from closed-end funds, Working Paper, Bank for International Settlements, Switzerland.

Constantinides, George, 1986, Capital market equilibrium with transaction costs, Journal of Political

Economy 94, 842-862.

Datar, Vinay T., Narayan Y. Naik, and Robert Radcliffe, 1998, Liquidity and asset returns: An alternative

test, Journal of Financial Markets 1, 203-219.

DeLong, J. Bradford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence Summers, and Robert J. Waldmann, 1990, Noise Trader

Risk in Financial Markets, Journal of Political Economy 98, 703-738.

Dimson, Elroy, and Carolina Minio-Kozerski, 1999, Closed-end funds: A survey, Financial Markets,

Institutions & Instruments, V. 8, N. 2, New York University Salomon Center.

Edison, Hali J., and Francis E. Warnock, 2003, A simple measure of the intensity of capital controls,

Journal of Empirical Finance 10, 81-103.

Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber, and Jeffrey A. Busse, 1998, Do Investors Care about Sentiment?,

Journal of Business 71, 477-500.

Gemmill, Gordon, and Dylan C. Thomas, 2002, Noise Trading, Costly Arbitrage, and Asset Prices:

Evidence from Closed-end Funds, The Journal of Finance 57, 2571-2594.

Gagnon, Louis, and G. Andrew Karolyi, 2004, Multi-Market Trading and Arbitrage, Working Paper, Ohio

State University.

Glosten, Lawrence, 1989, Insider trading, liquidity, and the role of the monopolist specialist, Journal of

Business 62, 211-235.

Hanley, Kathleen Weiss, Charles M. C. Lee, and Paul J. Seguin, 1994, The Marketing of Closed-end Fund

IPOs: Evidence from Transaction Data, Working Paper 94-21, Financial Institutions Center, The Wharton

30

Page 34: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

School, University of Pennsylvania.

Hardouvelis, Gikas, Rafael La Porta, and Thierry A. Wizman, 1994, What Moves the Discount on Country

Equity Funds?, The Internationalization of Equity Markets, ed. Jeffrey A. Frankel, University of Chicago

Press, 345 - 397.

Hasbrouck, Joel, 2003, Trading Costs and Returns for US Equities: The Evidence from Daily Data,

working paper, New York University.

Huang, Ming, 2003, Liquidity shocks and equilibrium liquidity premia, Journal of Economic Theory 109,

104-129.

Kalibanoff, Peter, Owen Lamont, Thierry A. Wizman, 1996, Investor Reaction to Salient News in Closed-

End Country Funds, NBER Working Paper 5588.

Kyle, Albert S., 1985, Continuous auctions and insider trading, Econometrica 53, 1315-1335.

Im, K.S., Pesaran, M.H. and Shin Y., 2003, Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels, Journal of

Econometrics 115, 53-74.

Lee, Charles, Andrei Shleifer, and Richard Thaler, 1990, Closed-End Mutual Funds, Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 4, 153-164.

Lee, Charles, Andrei Shleifer, and Richard Thaler, 1991, Investor Sentiment and the Closed-End Fund

Puzzle, Journal of Finance 46, 75-109.

Levin A., Lin C.F. and Chu C.S., 2002, Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and finite sample

properties, Journal of Econometrics 108, 1-24.

Lo, Andrew W., and Jiang Wang, 2000, Trading Volume: Definitions, Data Analysis, and Implications of

Portfolio Theory, Review of Financial Studies 13, 257-300.

Longstaff, Francis, 2002, The Flight-to-Liquidity Premium in U.S. Treasury Bond Prices, Journal of

Business, forthcoming.

Longstaff, Francis, 2004, Financial Claustrophobia: Asset Pricing in Illiquid Markets, working paper,

UCLA.

Malkiel, Burton G., 1977, The valuation of closed-end investment-company shares, The Journal of Finance

32, 847-858.

Newman, Yigal S., and Michael A. Rierson, 2004, Illiquidity spillovers: Theory and evidence from

European telecom bond issuance, working paper, Stanford University.

Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West, 1987, A simple positive semi-definite, heteroscedasticity and

autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix, Econometrica 55, 703-708.

31

Page 35: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Palomino, Frederic, 1996, Noise Trading in Small Markets, The Journal of Finance, 51, 1537-1550.

Pastor, Lubos, and Robert F. Stambaugh, 2003, Liquidity risk and expected stock returns, Journal of

Political Economy 111, 642-685.

Pontiff, Jeffrey, 1996, Costly Arbitrage: Evidence from Closed-End Funds, Quarterly Journal of Eco-

nomics, 111, 1135-1151.

Pontiff, Jeffrey, 1997, Excess volatility and closed-end funds, American Economic Review 87, 155-169.

Roll, Richard, 1984, A Simple Implicit Measure of the Effective Bid-Ask Spread in an Efficient Market,

Journal of Finance 39, 1127-1140.

Ross, Stephen A., 2002, A Neoclassical look at behavioral finance: closed end funds, European Financial

Management 8, 129-137.

Swaminathan, Bhaskaran, 1996, Time-Varying Expected Small Firm Returns and Closed-End Fund Dis-

counts, The Review of Financial Studies 9, 845-887.

Thompson, R., 1978, The information content of discounts and premiums on closed-end fund shares,

Journal of Financial Economics 6, 151-186.

Vayanos, Dimitri, 1998, Transaction costs and asset prices: a dynamic equilibrium model, Review of

Financial Studies 11, 1-58.

Wermers, Russ, Youchang Wu, and Josef Zechner, 2004, Closed-end fund governance, portfolio perfor-

mance, and the discount, working paper, University of Vienna.

Weiss, Kathleen, 1989, The Post-Offering Price Performance of Closed-End Funds, FinancialManagement,

Autumn, 1989, 57–67.

32

Page 36: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table A1 Information on Closed-end Single Country Funds Traded in the U.S.

This table provides information on all the U.S.-traded single country closed-end funds (CEF) in our sample. Funds investing in a region, or a sector, or primarily in commodities, are

not included. Weekly data on each fund’s closing price as of Friday (or the last trading day of the week), the net asset value (NAV), and the discount, are collected from the Wall Street Journal/Dow

Jones Interactive Service for all dates beginning August 7, 1987. During the period analyzed, several funds announced that they were either open-ending or liquidating or merging with another fund

or converting to a new closed-end fund with a different investment objective. The announcement date for these changes is the day on which the fund’s managers or board of directors propose

a change in the structure or investment objective of the fund. If a shareholder(s) proposes a change, then the announcement date is the date of approval by shareholders of such a change. The

announcement date is determined from news announcements and/or SEC filings.

Fund Fund IPO Raw Data Change of Structure or Investment Objective

No. Ticker Name Date From To Nature of Change Announcement Date

1 AF Argentina 10/22/1991 10/25/1991 12/14/2001 Open-ending 6/11/2001

2 BZF Brazil 3/31/1988 4/15/1988 12/28/20013 BZL Brazilian Equity 4/3/1992 4/10/1992 12/28/2001

4 CH Chile 10/26/1989 11/3/1989 12/28/2001

5 FAK Fidelity Advisor Korea 10/25/1994 11/4/1994 6/30/2000 Open-ending 3/17/20006 FPF First Philippine 11/8/1989 12/1/1989 12/28/2001

7 FRF France Growth 5/10/1990 5/18/1990 12/28/2001

8 FRG Emerging Germany Fund 3/29/1990 4/20/1990 4/23/1999 Open-ending 11/6/19989 GER Germany 7/18/1986 8/7/1987 12/28/2001

10 GF New Germany 1/14/1990 2/9/1990 12/28/2001

11 GSP Growth Fund Spain 2/14/1990 3/9/1990 12/11/1998 Open-ending 8/3/199812 IAF First Australia1 12/12/1985 8/7/1987 12/28/2001

13 IF Indonesia 3/1/1990 3/16/1990 12/28/2001

14 IFN India 2/1/1994 2/18/1994 12/28/200115 IGF India Growth 8/12/1988 8/26/1988 12/28/2001

16 IIF MSDW India2 2/1/1994 3/11/1994 12/28/2001

17 ISL First Israel 10/1/1992 10/30/1992 12/28/200118 ITA Italy 2/26/1986 8/7/1987 12/28/2001 Liquidating 11/21/2002

19 JEQ Japan Equity 7/24/1992 8/14/1992 12/28/2001

20 JFI Jardine Fleming India 3/1/1994 3/11/1994 12/28/2001

33

Page 37: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table A1 (continued)

Fund Fund IPO Raw Data Change of Structure or Investment ObjectiveNo. Ticker Name Date From To Nature of Change Announcement Date

21 JGF Jakarta Growth 4/16/1990 4/20/1990 6/8/2001 Merging with another CEF 10/11/2000

22 JOF Japan OTC Equity 3/14/1990 3/30/1990 12/28/2001

23 KEF Korea Equity 11/24/1993 12/3/1993 12/28/200124 KF Korea 8/22/1984 8/7/1987 12/28/2001

25 KIF Korean Investment 2/18/1992 3/13/1992 11/23/2001 Open-ending 9/14/2001

26 MEF Emerging Mexico 10/8/1990 10/12/1990 4/1/1999 Liquidating 10/26/199827 MF Malaysia 5/8/1987 8/7/1987 12/28/2001

28 MXE Mexico Equity and Income 8/14/1990 9/7/1990 12/28/200129 MXF Mexico 6/3/1981 8/7/1987 12/28/2001

30 OST Austria 9/21/1989 10/6/1989 12/28/2001

31 PGF Portugal 11/1/1989 12/29/1989 6/1/2001 Open-ending 8/20/199932 ROC ROC Taiwan 5/19/1989 5/19/1989 12/28/2001

33 SGF Singapore 7/24/1990 8/3/1990 12/28/2001

34 SNF Spain 6/21/1988 7/22/1988 12/28/200135 SWZ Swiss Helvetia3 8/19/1987 8/28/1987 12/28/2001

36 TC Thai Capital4 5/22/1990 6/8/1990 12/28/2001

37 TRF Templeton Russia 6/1/1995 9/15/1995 12/28/2001 Converting to New CEF 2/12/200238 TTF Thai 2/17/1988 2/26/1988 12/28/2001

39 TWN Taiwan 12/23/1986 8/7/1987 12/28/2001

40 TYW Taiwan Equity 7/1/1994 7/29/1994 5/5/2000 Liquidating 12/2/199941 UKM United Kingdom 8/6/1987 8/7/1987 4/23/1999 Liquidating/Open-ending 9/15/1998

1. Also known as Aberdeen Australia Equity

2. Also known as Morgan Stanley India

3. Also known as Helvetia fund4. The Thai Capital fund changed its ticker symbol from TC to TF on 3/16/2001

34

Page 38: Wharton-SMU Research Center · 2005-04-15 · Wharton-SMU Research Center Market Segmentation, Liquidity, Spillover, and Closed-end Country Fund Discounts Justin Chan, Ravi Jain and

Table A2 List of Stock Index or Market used to calculate the Amihud Illiquidity Measure

This table lists the name of each country and the corresponding stock index or market that was used to select the initial group of

individual stocks whose dollar returns and dollar volumes are used to calculate the Amihud market illiquidity measure as of the last Friday of

each month for all dates from 8/7/1987 to 12/31/2001, for which the necessary data are available on Datastream. The sample period corresponds

to the period of closed-end country fund discount data. The sample volatility of each country’s de-trended and de-meaned illiquidity is reported

in the last column.

Illiquidity Data

Country Stock Index/Market From To STD

Argentina MerVal 08/13/93 12/31/01 0.46

Australia All Ordinaries 06/22/88 12/31/01 0.65Austria ATX 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.70

Brazil Bovespa 07/22/94 12/31/01 0.79

Chile IGPA 07/21/89 12/31/01 0.55France CAC 40 05/16/89 12/31/01 0.44

Germany DAX 100 01/19/95 12/31/01 0.81

India BSE 500 01/19/95 12/31/01 0.44Indonesia Jakarta Composite 04/23/90 12/31/01 1.05

Israel TA-100 05/21/93 12/31/01 1.18

Italy MIBTel 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.84Japan Nikkei 225 12/20/90 12/31/01 0.40

Korea KOSPI 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.59

Malaysia KLSE Syariah 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.98Mexico INMEX 01/22/88 12/31/01 0.93

Philippines Manila All Shares 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.59

Portugal PSI-20 11/03/93 12/31/01 0.88Russia Moscow Times 09/26/95 12/31/01 0.81

Singapore Straits Times 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.59

Spain Madrid SE 02/22/90 12/31/01 0.59Switzerland SWI New Swiss 05/14/90 12/31/01 0.44

Taiwan FTAI: Taiwan Ordinary Securities 05/17/91 12/31/01 0.86Thailand SET 50 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.96

United Kingdom FTSE All-Share 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.78

United States of America NYSE 08/07/87 12/31/01 0.40

35