when enough is not enough: an exploratory analysis of corruption

54
S 3 H Working Paper Series Number 05: 2016 When Enough is Not Enough: An Exploratory Analysis of Corruption Behavior in Select Urban Populations Kh. Ayaz Ahmed Ather Maqsood Ahmed February 2016 School of Social Sciences and Humanities (S 3 H) National University of Sciences and Technology (NUST) Sector H-12, Islamabad, Pakistan

Upload: trinhthien

Post on 10-Feb-2017

229 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

S3H Working Paper Series

Number 05: 2016

When Enough is Not Enough:

An Exploratory Analysis of Corruption

Behavior in Select Urban Populations

Kh. Ayaz Ahmed

Ather Maqsood Ahmed

February 2016

School of Social Sciences and Humanities (S3H) National University of Sciences and Technology (NUST)

Sector H-12, Islamabad, Pakistan

S3H Working Paper Series

Faculty Editorial Committee

Dr. Zafar Mahmood (Head)

Dr. Najma Sadiq

Dr. Sehar Un Nisa Hassan

Dr. Lubaba Sadaf

Dr. Samina Naveed

Ms. Nazia Malik

S3H Working Paper Series

Number 05: 2016

When Enough is Not Enough:

An Exploratory Analysis of Corruption

Behavior in Select Urban Populations

Kh. Ayaz Ahmed Graduate, School of Social Sciences and Humanities, NUST

[email protected]

Ather Maqsood Ahmed Professor, School of Social Sciences & Humanities, NUST

[email protected]

February 2016

School of Social Sciences and Humanities (S3H)

National University of Sciences and Technology (NUST) Sector H-12, Islamabad, Pakistan

iii

Table of Contents

Abstract………………………………………………………………………... v

1. Introduction…………………………………………………………………… 1

2. Literature Review……………………………………………………………… 2

3. Theoretical Framework………………………………………………………… 8

3.1 Need vs Greed Corruption……………………………………………………... 8

3.2 Self-Selection and the Rational Choice Theory…………………………………. 11

3.3 The Decision-Making Process………………………………………………….. 15

4. Methodology…………………………………………………………………… 16

5. Results………………………………………………………………………….. 22

6. Discussion……………………………………………………………………… 28

7. Policy Implications……………………………………………………………... 31

8. Limitations and Further Research………………………………………………. 34

References……………………………………………………………………… 36

Appendix……………………………………………………………………….. 42

List of Tables

Table 1.1 Omnibus Tests of Model Coefficients…………………………………… 23

Table 1.2 Classification Table……………………………………………………… 23

Table 1.3 Regression Analysis……………………………………………………… 23

List of Figures

Figure 1.1 Neutral Preferences……………………………………………………… 12

Figure 1.2 Anti-Bribery Preferences………………………………………………… 13

Figure 1.3 Pro-Bribery Preferences………………………………………………….. 13

Figure 1.4 Involvement Model of Decision-Making………………………………… 15

Figure 1.5 Mediation Effect………………………………………………………… 27

v

Abstract

Corruption could be instigated by need or greed of an individual. Results of a survey conducted

during the research period, reveal that corruption is mainly motivated by greed in a study sample of

select urban populations, where higher socio-economic groups were found to be more likely to

indulge in unethical behavior, highlighting a probable ethical issue that may need to be addressed

vehemently. Moreover, results indicate that demographics such as gender and age do matter on the

choice to be corrupt, with males and younger aged individuals being more likely to be corrupt. This

highlights the need to pay greater focus on inculcating civic virtues, through effective parenting and

ethical training from an early age, in order to combat materialism and greed in a vulnerable

population. The need-greed differentiation also highlights corruption as a collective action problem

rather than a principal-agent problem, where a lack of ‘principled principals’ undermines efforts to

curb corruption and even moral heroism is hazardous. This is because when citizens are faced with

an opportunity to be corrupt, they justify the act by claiming that everyone else would do the same.

A large and consistent push is thus required to change the mindset of people to believe that other

actors, especially those at the helm of the system, will play fair.

Keywords: Need corruption, Greed corruption, Micro level survey, logistic regression

1

1. Introduction

Despite national and international efforts, anti-corruption programs have given mixed results,

especially in developing countries. At present, the key challenge for the anti-corruption movement is

to understand the varied success of tested programs in order to propose more effective ways to fight

the menace. While most efforts to curb corruption have relied heavily on country-level assessments

of overall levels of corruption, (usually measured by the frequency of paying bribes to a public

official) not much emphasis has been given to study the context and motivation behind the act.

More importantly, there has been a neglect in the literature on the moral aspects of the phenomenon

of corruption.

Most models of corruption and anti-corruption efforts revolve around the principal-agent

framework1 and have focused on economic, political, cultural and institutional approaches to analyze

the problem. This has led to large public sector reforms, particularly in terms of transparency,

accountability laws, decentralization of power, press freedom, privatization, and strengthening of the

civil society to act as active monitors. However, these systematic reforms have not been able to curb

corruption, especially in developing countries.

While all corrupt acts come under the same umbrella of corruption, the motives behind these acts

may be very different in nature. Corruption could be instigated by either need or greed of an

individual. It may not seem radical to claim that need corruption is highly prevalent because of the

level of poverty in Pakistan. Of greater concern is the prevalence of greed corruption. The

distinction between these two forms of corruption builds on the concept that motivations vary

between different settings. Similar to the extortive-collusive distinction in tax evasion models,

(Slemrod, 2006; Brunette and Weder, 2003) the basic motivators imply different relationships

between the actors involved. It is asserted that need corruption is built on extortion whereas greed

corruption on collusion (Bauhr and Nasiritousi, 2011). The motivation for paying a bribe, and the

obtrusiveness of corruption thus warrants further study to understand how different forces interplay

to develop (or undermine) the strength and engagement of “principals”.

1 The Principal-agent model analyzes the demand side of corruption and puts the onus on the bureaucrat for being corrupt and bribe-demanding. Corrective measures advocated by international anti-corruption agencies largely revolve around efforts to monitor public ‘agents’ by ‘principals’, no other than citizens or government bodies. For further insights, see Rose-Ackerman (1978, 1997); Klitgaard (1988).

2

Corruption is one of the biggest challenges that Pakistan faces. It has a notorious reputation as a

hindrance to overall economic development and growth. The consequences of letting corruption

persist may be disastrous for a country with an intricate economic, social and demographic profile

where approximately two-thirds of the population are under the age of thirty and the poor continue

to suffer as they are the ones who are denied the elements and resources necessary for economic

development. This vulnerable portion of society needs to be equipped and utilized in the most

effective manner in order to be able to reap the demographic dividend of the ‘Golden Age’ that the

nation has entered. If this youth bulge is neglected, the consequences may be inconceivable.

Additionally, there is a lack of empirical work which aims to understand corruption behavior from a

micro-level perspective. Studies on corruption in Pakistan are mostly based on aggregated macro-

level cross-country data, anecdotal assertions, media reports, press releases or court judgements.

This paper attempts to fill the void in the literature by adding empirical work on corruption behavior

from a micro-level perspective, through the design of an oblique research methodology.

Ascertaining the type of corruption at play-need or greed-may help unearth why many anti-

corruption programs fail and help propose alternative ways of tackling the problem.

We will be studying primary data gathered through surveys conducted in July 2014, on a select urban

sample. The survey2 was designed to capture demographics, socio-economic factors, psychographics,

and environmental factors which may influence an individual’s willingness to give or take a bribe.

Using qualitative response models that indicate probabilities of a discrete event to occur,

probabilistic regression techniques will be applied to examine factors that are more likely to increase

one’s willingness to bribe. More specifically, it examines whether the cause of corruption is rooted in

human weaknesses such as greed, by directly studying the individual, who may or may not be

motivated to bribe.

2. Literature Review

Previous empirical studies have entirely focused on finding cross-country differences in levels and

types of corruption using country-level corruption ratings. Apart from some notable contributions

to the topic, (Treisman, 2000; Swamy et al., 2001; Torgler and Valev, 2006; Mocan, 2008; Dong et al.,

2 For more information regarding the survey, please feel free to contact the authors.

3

2012; Lee, 2013) not much empirical work has been done on understanding corruption from a

micro-level perspective.

Socio-Economic Factors

Socio-economic factors are the primary determinant of whether corruption is motivated by need or

greed. Socio-economic status (SES) is determined mainly by factors such as income, education and

occupation. High SES societies are characterized by high income per capita, high education, and

higher occupational groups. Social pressures which may motivate an offender are more likely to arise

in low SES environments, particularly countries that lag behind in economic development.

Corruption is assumed to have a negative effect on economic development, and vice versa (Mauro,

1995), though the causality still remains a doubt. Treisman (2000) tests a number of hypotheses and

demonstrates that the level of corruption in a country is directly related to its level of economic

development, legal and cultural characteristics, at the macro level, as demonstrated in Equation (2.1):

( )

where, the extent of corruption in country j ( depends on its Legal (L) and Cultural (C)

attributes, and the level of economic development of the country (Econ). In a cross-section study of

developed and developing countries, Treisman (2000) finds that developing countries are perceived

to be more corrupt, with about 50-73% of the deviation in the perception indices explained solely by

income per capita.

Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2001) show that the quality of institutions and quality of human

life in the country directly affects economic development. These connections are illustrated in

Equation (2.2):

( )

where, economic development in country j is dependent on the extent of corruption in the country

as well as institutional (I), cultural characteristics, human capital measures (H), and legal attributes.

Substituting Equation (2) into (1) generates the macro-level reduced form as shown in equation

(2.3):

4

( )

Tavares (2005) regresses the Corruption Perception Index (CPI) on socio-economic and cultural

variables and finds similar results; the level of development of a country is the most important factor

in determining corruption levels. Developing countries are characterized by low per capita income,

which may be indicative of need corruption.

Moreover, an OECD study, finds a significant negative relationship between income per capita and

corruption. Countries with high income per capita rank better on the corruption perception index.

Low corruption may be considered as a luxury good in rich countries or it could be the case that low

corruption is a necessary condition to achieve high income per capita (OECD, 2011). As mentioned

earlier, societies where greed corruption is higher than need corruption, the effects of corruption are

widespread and not obtrusive, hence not that visible. Thus countries that may be inflicted with greed

corruption, may in fact do pretty well in corruption perception indices.

At the micro-level, corruption is determined by a rational cost-benefit analysis, as postulated by Becker

(1968). Personal characteristics and life-style attributes shape how individuals view risk, reward and effort of

indulging in corruption. If rewards outweigh the risks of getting apprehended, an individual is more

vulnerable to corruption.

Within this framework Mocan (2008) estimates equation (2.4):

( )

where, is the propensity of the ith individual who lives in country j to indulge or be a victim of

corruption, and represents personal characteristics of the individual. Using empirical data

gathered from 90,000 individuals from 49 countries, Mocan (2008) finds a non-linear relationship

between perceived corruption indices and the number of individuals asked for a bribe. The results

indicate that males, high income and highly educated individuals, and those living in larger cities are

more likely to be asked for a bribe. Moreover, marital status, legal origin of the country,

uninterrupted democracy, and the strength of institutions in the country were also important

determinants of corruption. These regressions were weighted and standard errors were adjusted

5

because country-specific variables do not vary much at the individual level for a large number of

cases.

Socio-economic status and ethics. Recent studies that attempt to gauge moral values in socio-

economic groups reveal that higher socio-economic groups are more likely to indulge in unethical

behavior as compared to lower groups. Piff et al. (2012) conducted seven experiments revealing that

those belonging to higher socio-economic groups were more likely to be involved in traffic

violations, lie while negotiating terms, and cheat to increase their chances of winning among other

observed unethical behavior. Mediator analysis of these results revealed that these tendencies are

partly accounted for by their favorable attitudes towards greed. This claim is further substantiated by

Cote, Piff and Willer (2013) who show how socio-economic status has an effect on perceptions of

right and wrong. Likewise, Trautmann, de Kuilen and Zeckhauser (2012), also find lower

condemnation of wrong behavior by higher socio-economic groups.

Psychographic Factors

Psychological factors and lifestyle choices such as temperament, desires, materialism,

adventurism/risk aversion, ethics, anti-social behavior, political interest and narcissistic behavior can

affect one’s decision to indulge in corruption. Not much empirical evidence is available on the

impact of the above factors on corruption except that risk averse people are less likely to justify

corruption (Dong et al 2012), corruption is rampant in ‘anti-social’ countries (OECD, 2011), and

political interest lowers perceived corruption and justifiability of corruption (Dong, 2008).

Cultural Factors

In a study of two countries that are poles apart, Nigeria and United States, Tsalikis and Nwachukwu

(1991) find that culture has an effect on how respondents viewed acts of bribery and extortion.

Husted (1999) studies this link by introducing Hofstede’s cultural dimensions, namely: power

distance, individualism, collectivism, and masculinity-femininity. The research confirmed that high

power distance, high masculinity, and high uncertainty avoidance are indicative of higher corruption.

The author concludes that corruption is not easy to eradicate because culture cannot be changed

overnight.

6

Gender differences. Cultural scientists such as Geert Hofstede claim that societies that are

characterized by masculinity, are by nature, more competitive and more ambitious in pursuit of

material wealth (Husted 1999). This particularly applies to males, who are considered as the primary

breadwinners of the household in such societies. There is evidence of a gender gap in

competitiveness, with males found to be more competitive than females (Niederle and Vesterlund,

2007). This contributes greatly to whether or not one may engage in unethical behavior such as

corruption.

While studying gender differences, Swamy et al. (2001)3 found that women were more likely to

condemn bribery, as compared to males. Moreover, based on a survey carried out in Georgia, the

authors found that male business owners are more likely to offer a bribe as compared to female

owners. These evidences support previous findings in different fields of studies, namely business

ethics and psychology, on the impact of gender on corruption (Eagly and Crowley, 1986; Ford and

Richardson, 1994).

However, Alhassan-Alolo (2007) finds that trends might have changed over time, with more women

entering the workforce. Using hypothetical scenarios and questions, he finds that females might not

show higher standards of ethical behavior, especially when exposed to environments with corrupt

opportunities and networks.

Contagious corruption. Using micro-level data from over 20 European countries, Lee and Guven

(2013) find strong contagion effects of corruption. Using a seemingly unrelated probit approach, the

author provides empirical evidence of how past experiences with corruption influence future

decisions and how the act of bribery is viewed. Thus a culture of bribery, as reflected by its

prevalence in a society and measured by past experiences, affects one’s willingness to bribe. Citizens

may thus rarely show any signs of guilt, while justifying bribery.

Likewise, Dong et al. (2012) use micro and macro-level data spanning almost 20 years to study

whether corruption is contagious. The authors found that the willingness to be corrupt is heavily

3 Swamy et al. (2001) use responses from the statement “someone accepting a bribe in the course of their duties” from the World Values Survey as their main measure of corruption. This measure is scored on a 1-10 scale where 1 indicates that the behavior can “never be justified” and 10 indicates that the behavior can “always be justified.”

7

influenced by perception of how other individuals in the society are likely to behave4. At the macro-

level, it is found that past levels of corruption also determine current corruption levels in countries.

Social capital. Social capital refers to the inclination of people to cooperate in terms of common

values and norms which foster civic engagement. Social capital includes elements such as

interpersonal trust, and social networks that can lower corruption by reducing transaction costs,

facilitating market exchanges, promoting collective action, consequently lowering opportunistic

behavior and corruption (Lopez et al, 1997; Grootaert, 2001).

However, these same elements do not always produce positive externalities and are also crucial for

opportunistic behavior to occur and hence could work to promote corruption (Fukuyama, 2001).

Harris (2007), uses the World Values Survey to prove empirically that bonding social capital has a

negative impact on perceived corruption, confirming the hypothesis that exclusive ties between

individuals increases the likelihood of corruption and nepotism. She argues that in exclusive groups,

freedom of members is reduced, and those defecting to norms might be excluded from the group

and would incur a social cost that is too high for the defector. Moreover, in some contained

communities, the access to social resources may be available only to members of a group and denied

to outsiders, who may then be subject to additional charges or bribes (Bjornskov, 2003).

Institutional Trust. Studies reveal that citizen’s perception of corruption has a negative impact on

institutional trust. Della Porta and Vannucci (1999) assert that corruption lowers trust in political

institutions, and as a result reinforces higher levels of corruption. In a study of Latin American

countries, Seligson (2002) shows how higher levels of perceived corruption have an impact on how

democratic regimes are viewed. Similarly, in Asian countries, Chang and Chu (2006) find that higher

levels of perceived corruption are directly related to lower levels of institutional trust. Moreover,

Rose, Mishler and Haerpfer (1998) also find that higher levels of corruption have a negative impact

on how political systems are viewed.

4 Dong et al. (2012) use responses to the question ‘perceived share of compatriots accepting a bribe’ to empirically

quantify the magnitude of such contagion effects. They find that if perceived corruption rises by one unit (1 = almost

none, 4 = almost all), the percentage of persons reporting that corruption is never justified falls between 3.8 and 5.1

percentage points.

8

3. Theoretical Framework

Corruption is widely defined as “the abuse of public office for private gain” (World Bank, 1997).

However, restricting corruption theories to the public sector and a principal-agent framework,

misses an important aspect of the phenomenon which jeopardizes most anti-corruption efforts. It is

important to note that corruption is not a feature of the public sphere only and neither is it always

initiated by a demander of bribes. Corruption has a supply side as well and the myth of individuals

being victimized by corrupt officials to pay bribes, calls for closer examination. Hence corruption

may be defined, in a very broad sense, as an illegitimate means to achieve a private goal. The

definition recognizes private gains as well as an abuse of power through illegitimate means.

3.1: Need vs Greed Corruption

In high corruption contexts, the differentiation between need and greed corruption is quite complex.

There is a very fine line that distinguishes between the two. It is important to note that these are two

extremes, black and white, and not all acts of corruption fall under either one end of the continuum.

There are shades of grey; the merits of which may be debated on a case to case basis. This is because

both need and greed are highly subjective in nature. Such cases do not fall under the scope of this

study and instead, we pay attention to objective forms of need and greed in order to better

understand the concept.

What is a need? A need is defined as anything, without which, one may not be able to fulfill basic

physiological requirements, such as air, water, food, clothing and shelter which may lead to an

undesirable outcome, such as dysfunction or death. A need is a need, only if everyone requires it to

function in society.

Poverty is a prominent feature of developing economies that lack risk-spreading mechanisms, such

as insurance markets, access to credit, and well-functioning labor markets (Schwenke, 2000). Such

economies are highly prone to risks such as unemployment, accidents and illnesses, which hurt the

poorer populations who may have to depend on corrupt practices as a coping mechanism. This

gives rise to need corruption, which occurs when an individual indulging in bribery, is motivated by

a genuine necessity, without which basic needs such as food or shelter are threatened. Stripping away

this coping mechanism may force the needy to indulge in other forms of crime such as burglary,

9

robbery or smuggling. As long as developing countries are plagued with poverty, need corruption

may exist and perhaps may be tolerated as well, if it is considered as a lesser evil.

In terms of legality, need corruption occurs when a bribe is paid to receive a benefit that one is

legally entitled to (Bauhr and Nasiritousi, 2011). When bribe-givers attempt to receive a service they

are legally entitled to, the bribe-taker may not be able to extort an exuberant amount of bribe. Thus

need corruption is considered analogous to petty corruption. It is comparable to an act of giving a

service tip to a waiter to perform speedy services.

Need corruption also helps us understand why many people who confess to have been part of a

corrupt deal claim that they were ‘victimized’ or the situation ‘forced’ them to act in such a way.

Some, who claim to be victimized, may be generally law-abiding citizens, however in matters where

they face genuine needs they may be inclined to step over moral principles (Mauro 1998). Offenders

are often seen justifying their actions, with claims such as ‘the system made me do it’ or by finding

permissibility in situations, where it was necessary to right some other wrong such as red tape or

bureaucratic inefficiencies. To them, corruption is a rule that is so deeply entrenched in the system

that if they did not comply, they would be the ‘losers’. Indeed, there are situations where it may be

justified, especially when the need for human survival requires individuals to overcome institutional

or legal barriers.

The assumptions that some of such offenders hold, that corruption has benefits in an inherently

inefficient market system which requires overhauling, is swept aside by leading writers such as

Robert Klitgaard. He asserts that such assumptions and claims that corruption can be beneficial to

the functioning of an unfair market mechanism, serves no other purpose but to hinder ongoing

development and anti-corruption efforts (Klitgaard, 1998b). The question of whether corruption is

ever morally acceptable is one that needs further scrutiny. As deontologists argue, it is not the

consequences of actions that make actions right or wrong, but the motives of the person.

Nonetheless, either party to a corrupt act, being aware of the detrimental impact on society or not,

effectively conspire to defraud the public through illegitimate means. So those who stand on moral

grounds effectively argue that two wrongs do not make one right.

What is greed? Greed is a selfish or excessive desire, driven by a sense of deprivation, for more

than is needed, in terms of money, food, or other possessions. Likewise, those inflicted with such

10

mentalities perceive that there might not be enough benefits to go around, and thus they should

indulge in a timely greedy act in order to benefit. For example, a greedy child will attempt to get the

biggest slice of the cake, and also try to be the first one to get it, as the child is inflicted with the

mentality that they might be left deprived from the benefits.

Greed corruption occurs when the motivation of taking a bribe is based on selfish desires. An

individual inflicted with a greedy mentality, perceives that if he/she does not indulge in corruption

and benefit from it, someone else will. Or that he/she may not be able to receive that benefit at all

because they cannot compete with other aspirants. Such scenarios are mostly present where the

demand of a public good is greater than its supply.

A greedy bribe-giver is one who wants to avail a service that he might not be legally entitled to (yet),

and thus instigates the bribing process. For example, a person bribes a public official, to receive a

benefit from a procurement contract. However, not all cases are as clear-cut as the previous

example. For instance, someone may supply a bribe such as speed money to get his/her application

for housing through on a priority basis, however that would require them to skip a queue. If the

person is not legally entitled to it, as yet, or does not fulfil the eligibility criteria, the act may be

classified as greed corruption.

Greed corruption is also asserted to be collusive in nature, where both the bribe-taker and bribe-

giver are considered as being in a position to fulfil selfish desires rather than necessities. In the case

of greed corruption, the bribe-taker demands bribes to enhance or maintain a lifestyle that is beyond

his/her means to do so, whereas the bribe-giver pays to receive an undue benefit. Such offenders are

possessed with the mentality to grab every single opportunity to either make extra income, achieve a

higher social standing or get hold of something they are not legally entitled to, as yet; just because

they can do it, and not because they need to do it.

This is why greed corruption is often termed analogous to ‘grand’ corruption’, which is built on

collusion, and is often unobtrusive because it is hidden and its costs are usually divided over a larger

amount of taxpayers. This is of greater concern because it includes larger amounts of money, due to

the larger risk involved because of the illegality of the act. This money is hoarded to avoid raising

suspicions and eventually may cause capital flight. Moreover, if corruption is indeed unobtrusive, the

11

effects may not be felt directly by actors (in the short run) and hence may not create enough

motivation for actors to engage in activities against corruption (Bauhr and Nasiritousi, 2011). As a

result, anticorruption measures will suffer from a lack of “principals”.

3.2 Self-Selection and the Rational Choice Theory

The theoretical foundations of all criminological theories are given by the Rational Choice model.

The economic approach to corruption begins with a fundamental assumption, which may be termed

as ethically dubious, whereby self-regarding behavior is the major determinate of human decision-

making. The reason why corruption occurs should be clearly understood as a means to either sustain

a certain life-style or enhance it. Labor market theorists stress that workers tend to self-select

themselves into sectors and jobs that they feel may maximize their returns (Roy, 1951; Borjas, 1987).

It is based on a rational computation of benefits and costs of using specific skillsets in the presence

of an enabling environment. Applying the theory of self-selection, individuals may commit bribery if

the perceived risks are sufficiently low compared to the rewards.

Risk and rewards can be tied into the utility function of an individual. The decision to bribe or not

to bribe, involves the maximization of a utility function. If the marginal utility gained from indulging

in bribery is greater than the marginal utility of refraining from bribery, the individual will bribe.

Kaffenberger (2012) provides a simple utility model, where utility is a function of Service receipt (S)

and moral reward for behaving legally (L):

U = U (S, L)

The marginal utility of both goods is positive:

The income constraint is defined as follows:

12

where, I is total income which is monetary income plus value of time, is the shadow price of

behaving legally, and is the shadow price of the service plus cost of bribes. These shadow prices

also reflect subjective risk and reward structures which are determined by a multitude of factors such

as cultural norms, moral standards, strength of anti-corruption bodies and punishment regimes, or

social taboos and stigmas. Lower corruption would imply lower shadow prices for both

commodities, and thus would enhance utility by expanding the income constraint outwards. The

individual would benefit by receiving higher service delivery at every point in the income constraint

for a certain level of legal behavior.

Assuming a Cobb-Douglas utility function, neutral preferences regarding bribe-paying would give

both S and L equal weights, producing a utility function as can be seen in Figure 1.1 on the

following page.

=

From this steady state, an individual’s life experiences, environment, culture and other factors affect

preferences and change the shape of the utility curves. For instance, moral and ethical training can

increase moral reward and thus make an individual prefer legal measures, placing a greater weight on

Figure 1.1 - Neutral Preferences (Kaffenberger, 2012: 24)

13

legal behavior (a < b), changing the shape of the utility function. The utility function of such

individuals (Figure 1.2) reflects risk aversion, where moral standards are high enough to impose a

larger loss in utility from being caught, than the rewards from indulging in bribery. An individual will

prefer a legal means as long as it provides a certain payoff even if it is a lower expected payoff than

Figure 1.2 – Anti-bribery Preferences (Kaffenberger, 2012: 26)

Figure 1.3 – Pro-bribery Preferences (Kaffenberger, 2012: 28)

14

behaving illegally. Even if the risks and rewards are equated, risk averse individuals may prefer not to

bribe because of loss aversion i.e. loss in utility has a greater negative impact on the individual than

the positive impact of an equal gain in utility (Kahneman and Traversky, 1979).

On the other hand, such factors may also have an opposite impact on preferences. For instance,

some societies may have higher levels of toleration for illegal activity, which lowers moral costs of

indulging in corruption. Such societies may also not be deterred by weak punishment regimes.

Individuals living in such societies place greater weights on service delivery (Figure 1.3), and lesser

weight on moral reward (a > b), and thus are more likely to bribe to maximize expected pay-off.

In high corruption societies, people may start to find more certainty in getting work done through

bribery than being uncertain about outcomes due to inefficiencies; especially when law enforcement

and anti-corruption bodies are not effectively implementing rules and regulations. This is further

aggravated when bribes become customary and part of the culture; as a tit-for-tat arrangement

between agents improving social standings amongst themselves.

In short, whether or not an individual tends towards corruption depends on subjective rates of risk

and reward which are shaped by individual experiences, environments, cultures and other factors.

Due to the fact that perceived risks and rewards are subjective in nature, the rational choice theory

supports the theory of self-selection. The labor force, thus, should be somewhat receptive of

opportunities where they could improve their lifestyles and future rewards. This influences the

decision-making process, by either increasing rewards or reducing risks, or vice versa.

The decision to offend is seen as a multi-stage decision process, where reasoning purely exists to

secure ‘generalized needs’ at least cost to the offender. A decision-making approach to crime

requires that a distinction between criminal involvement and criminal events be elucidated.

Involvement refers to the processes through which individuals determine their ‘readiness’ to be

involved to carry out a certain act, to continue and to desist. Involvement decisions are multi-stage,

extend over significant periods of time, and make use of large range of information. Whereas event

models, depict the further sequence of decision making that leads the individual to seek out

opportunities to carry out the act. These decisions are based on a relatively narrower scope of

variables than those in involvement models. In event models, the variables at play largely reflect

immediate situational factors in terms of effort, risks and rewards (Cornish and Clarke, 2000). We

15

focus on the involvement model, as that is where the ‘readiness’ or willingness to be corrupt is

formed.

3.3 The Decision-Making Process

The involvement process has two decision points: the decision to be ready, and the decision to

Figure 1.4 – Involvement Model of Decision-Making Borrowed from Cornish and Clarke (1985: 168)

16

commit the act. The first decision point involves identification of needs and desires, evaluation of

means in light of moral considerations, and the establishment of willingness. If criminal means are

selected, then the individual is said to be ready to offend. As seen in Figure 1.4, background factors

are at the helm of the decision-making process. Background factors include psychological factors,

socio-economic factors, demographic factors, and quality of upbringing. These background factors

are a crucial part of our study as these largely determine the motive behind the corrupt act.

Once, the motivation is determined, moral considerations come into play, which act as a self-

selection mechanism which trigger the crime. In a general theory of crime, Gottfredson and Hirschi

(1990) propose that the individual trait of self-control or restraint explains most deviations in human

behavior. The authors assert that, in pursuit of self-interest and given the opportunity to do so,

individuals lacking self-control may indulge in wide forms of crime. Self-control is what determines

whether an individual will transit from readiness to commission of crime.

Low self-control is a multi-dimensional term which is captured by behavior which reflects

impulsivity, short-term orientation, high propensity to consume, preference for leisure, self-

centeredness, risk-seeking potential and a volatile temper (Grasmick et al. 1993; Roach, 2009).

Preference is given to immediate benefits derived from consumption activity. As a result of a

neglected focus on long-term benefits, low self-control individuals suffer from poor friendships, low

success in educational and economic arenas, and unhappy marriages (Gottfredson and Hirschi,

1990). Susan Rose-Ackerman (1978) highlighted the importance of restraint in preventing

corruption, and such restraints find its roots in ethical considerations, namely honesty and a

commitment to democratic principles.

4. Methodology

Due to the increasing use of technology in processes, and collection of new data, many new

interesting insights are available on the phenomenon. However, the research has expanded out into

so many intellectual directions that studying corruption still remains a very perplexing job. It is a

challenging task, to measure the level of corruption in a society, as people prefer not to be part of

studies that attempt to gauge corruption or corruptibility. The sensitive nature of research in this

field requires the design of an oblique methodology. While some respondents will happily disclose

their perceptions about the extent of corruption in the society, not many are expected to confess

whether or not they would indulge in corruption, given a chance. The methodology adopted in this

17

paper is unique in the sense that no previous study (in our knowledge) has been carried out to

directly measure corruptibility from a micro-level perspective.

Only recently, in the past decade and a half, survey questionnaires have started being used as an

effective way to measure corruption. Researchers have empirically examined cross-country

differences in corruption, using micro-level surveys that feature questions on offering or accepting

bribes, past experiences and acceptability of various deviant behaviors. Depending on what

questions are asked and how the questions are framed, surveys can prove to be very useful to

understand corruption from a micro-level perspective. Surveys have allowed identification of where

corruption is most encountered by the population and also capture how various groups of

population perceive corruption. These have proven useful in helping evolve the debate on

corruption from anecdotal assertions to empirical evidence.

Keeping the above factors in mind, we have designed a survey which aims to study whether

corruption is influenced by need or greed. The survey allows measuring corruption and

corruptibility, in a manner not extensively used before. It allows measuring, to some extent, the

spread of corruption in society. For instance, it is highly unlikely that the same corrupt deal may be

witnessed by more than one person in a random sample. If over 60% of respondents have claimed

to have been in a corrupt act in the past year, or have at least witnessed a corrupt act, then it is not

radical to claim that corruption is indeed widespread.

Other than being able to give a quantifiable estimate on the extent of corruption present in a society,

the study primarily focuses on determining whether demographic, socio-economic, psychographic,

cultural and/or environmental factors matter in determining the extent to which a person is

susceptible to corruption. Doing so, it distinguishes between factors that may cause either, need or

greed corruption.

Model

As we saw from the involvement model of Cornish and Clarke (1985), the decision to offend is a

multi-stage process and a function of the following factors:

18

The decision to offend = ƒ(background factors, previous experiences and learning, generalized

needs, moral considerations, available solutions, and situational factors)

Background factors include socio-economic conditions, and psychological factors. Generalized

needs include social and culturally approved goals such as money, status or excitement. Moreover,

moral values play an important role as a self-selection mechanism, in determining whether or not a

person chooses a corrupt solution. Past experiences with corruption is found to have a significant

impact on one’s willingness to indulge in corruption as well as one’s views on corruption. Hence a

past experience with corruption can impact the decision-making process by enhancing available

solutions, thus making it more likely that an individual chooses a corrupt means to reach a goal. It is

possible that a person who has previously been involved in corruption, may indeed have lower

thresholds of morality, may justify corruption and thus may be inclined to indulge in a corrupt act

again. Situational factors include immediate factors present in an individual’s life that may influence

a corrupt decision.

Keeping the above in mind, we estimate variants in demographic, socio-economic, psychographic

and environmental factors at the micro-level. The decision to offend is captured by the responses to

the questions which ask the respondents whether or not they would give or take a bribe. This shows

the willingness of the respondent to indulge in corruption which can be translated into propensity or

probability of an individual to be corrupt.

We estimate the following:

… (4.1)

where, is the probability of the ith individual to indulge in corruption, represents personal

characteristics which include demographic, socio-economic and psychographic factors;

represents environmental factors faced by the individual; and represents experiences of the

individual with corruption.

We estimate multivariate probalistic models, where the probability of the discrete event of a

respondent willing to give or take a bribe (and hence be corrupt) can be modelled as a logit/probit

relationship.

19

Empirically, we estimate the following:

… (4.2)

{

}

where, X is a vector of personal responses of individual i,. The outcome variable, willingness to give

or take a bribe, takes on the value of one if individual i is willing to give or take a bribe and zero if

otherwise.

Estimation Technique

We ran multiple binary logistic regressions to have a closer look at the survey results to determine

what factors increase the probability of a respondent to self-select themselves towards corruption.

Binary logistic is a type of regression analysis where the dependent variable is a dichotomous dummy

variable. It is simply a non-linear transformation of the linear regression. The logistic distribution is

an S-shaped distribution function which is similar to the standard normal distribution and constrains

the probabilities to lie between 0 and 1. With the logistic transformation, we fit the model to the

data better. Once transformed, the log-odds become linear.

The model was built using backward and forward stepwise techniques, where individual variables are

added to the model one by one and its impact is studied on overall model fit and the existing

variables. This procedure is constructed by an iterative maximum likelihood procedure. It starts with

arbitrary values of the regression coefficients and constructs an initial model for predicting the

observed data. Then it evaluates errors in such prediction and changes the regression coefficients so

as to make the likelihood of the observed data greater under the new model. This process repeats

until the model converges, meaning the differences between the newest model and the previous

model are trivial. The idea is that you find and report as statistics the parameters that are most likely

to have produced the data. A rudimentary model was created to incorporate basics of the theoretical

model, to include personal characteristics, environmental factors and experience with corruption.

Corruption = ƒ (gender, age, years of schooling, household income, marital status, materialism,

bribe justification and institutional trust) … (4.3)

20

Age, years of schooling, and institutional trust are continuous variables, whereas dummies were

introduced for males, married respondents, materialists, those who felt income was inadequate, and

those who justified bribery. Household income was replaced by average monthly electricity

expenditure as it was a more suitable instrument to gauge socio-economic status as compared to

income which respondents are reluctant to share. So, in order to get a better understanding of the

effect of household income on the probability to indulge in bribery, we used ‘Average Electricity

Expenditure per month’ to create a new ordinal variable - socioeconomic status - based on usage,

the values of which range from 1-3, where 1 is the lowest socio-economic group, and 3 is the

highest. Lastly, materialism, measured on a 6 point scale, was transformed into a binary variable,

materialist, where 1 indicates presence of a materialistic personality and 0 otherwise.

Corruption = ƒ (male, age, age squared, years of schooling, socioeconomic status, income

inadequacy, married, materialist, bribe justification, and institutional trust) …(4.4)

Hypothesis

The study primarily studies determinants of corruption, while attempting to ascertain the type of

corruption, need or greed that is present in the society. Due to the extreme level of poverty in

Pakistan, need corruption is, without doubt, highly prevalent in society. What is of greater concern is

the prevalence of greed corruption. We test the following hypothesis:

: Corruption is not motivated by greed.

: Corruption is motivated by greed.

As mentioned earlier, the need-greed distinction is primarily derived by studying socioeconomic

factors impacting the individual. Income is the most influential factor determining this outcome.

Low income would increase the probability of being corrupt, as it introduces the element of need.

The lower the income, the higher the chances of need corruption. So if corruption is motivated by

need, we expect that corruption will reduce as people climb the ladder of socioeconomic status.

The definition of a need, as defined in this study, allows us to side-step classic economic theory

which asserts that needs increase with income. Even though it is true, in the sense that people move

21

up a hierarchy of needs5, we are more concerned with those who indulge in corruption because of

lack of basic and genuine needs. Moreover, as mentioned earlier, need is a highly subjective variable,

and we are only concerned about objective needs. In the following hypothesis, we are thus simply

trying to establish whether or not those who belong to higher socio-economic groups are more

willing to indulge in unethical behavior, as compared to those who are not so fortunate.

: Higher SES individuals are not more likely to be corrupt.

: Higher SES individuals are more likely to be corrupt.

Moreover, financial constraints perceived by the individual, such as the feeling that current income is

inadequate would increase the probability of a person to indulge in corruption as a source of

income. This could be a sign of either need or greed corruption. Need corruption occurs because of

this very feature of the thought process of the needy. However, it is important to note that greedy

people also feel that their income is not enough to sustain their current lifestyles. Enough is never

enough for people inflicted with such mentalities.

: Those who feel that their income is inadequate are not more likely to indulge in corruption.

: Those who feel that their income is inadequate are more likely to indulge in corruption.

Moreover, a materialistic outlook or a strong desire to always want more, may increase the likelihood

of a respondent to indulge in greed corruption. This is linked to the previous hypothesis, as it

attempts to ascertain the root of the desire for needing or wanting more.

: A materialistic personality does not increase the likelihood of being corrupt.

: A materialistic personality increases the likelihood of being corrupt.

Lastly, marriage is expected to have an impact on the probability of being corrupt. It could either

reduce corruption, by instilling a sense of responsibility and a fear of getting caught. Or it could

promote corruption as it increases social pressures from within the household. This form of

corruption could be either, need or greed corruption, depending on the nature of the social

pressures. Even though need corruption is somewhat justifiable, the decision of a needy person to

5 Maslow’s Hierarchy of needs establishes 5 levels of needs: Physiological, Safety, Love and belonging, Esteem and Self-actualization. He asserts that when one feels that their needs at a certain level are met, he/she advances on to a next set of needs, until reaching self-actualization.

22

get married is a matter that is questionable. On the other hand, the nature of the social pressures

could be entirely based on desires rather than necessities. Combining the above two hypotheses, we

are trying to ascertain whether or not there is a demonstration effect at play, and if so, how

significant is marital status in determining that outcome.

: A married person is not more likely to be corrupt.

: A married person is more likely to be corrupt.

Covariates

Gender - The probability of being corrupt is expected to be higher for males because of higher

exposure and opportunities, and achievement-oriented outlook of males.

Age - The relationship with age is expected to be positive for younger people and negative for those

who are older. Overall this relationship should be negative, which implies as a person grows older,

the probability of being corrupt reduces.

Years of schooling - Years of schooling is expected to reduce the probability of being corrupt as

more educated people are more aware of the social costs of corruption.

Trust in institutions – A lower trust in institutions can increase the probability of indulging in

corruption. Especially judicial trust and trust in anti-corruption bodies.

Bribe Justification – A respondent who justifies the use of proscribed means, is more likely to

indulge in corruption. A past experience with corruption may increase the probability of one

indulging in corruption again and also increase the probability that the person justifies the act. This

signifies a weakness in moral values.

5. Results

Almost a third of the variation in the responses were accurately captured by the model, and the null

hypothesis of the Hosmer and Lemeshow test – the model is fit – is not rejected. A test of model

coefficients (Table 1.1) reveals that the model is highly significant (p < 0.01). Moreover, Table 1.2

shows that the model predicted the right outcome nearly every three out of four times (71.1%).

23

Without the dependent variables, the model predicted the outcome 61.4% of the times. Hence, the

addition of variables has significantly improved the predictability of the model.

Table 1.1 - Omnibus Tests of Model Coefficients

Chi-square Df Sig.

Step 1

Step 39.925 10 .000

Block 39.925 10 .000

Model 39.925 10 .000

Table 1.2 – Classification Table

The estimates of multiple regressions are presented in Table 1.3 on the following page. The beta

coefficients represent log-odds of the outcome and the sign of the coefficient represents its

relationship with the outcome variable. The log-odds are not easy to interpret and only help in

building the statistical model to be tested. A better interpretation is carried out by looking at the

odds-ratio calculated by taking the exponential of the log-odds. A direct interpretation of the values

in this column is taken as ‘a unit increases in the independent variable increases the likelihood of

corruption by ‘Odd-ratio’ times.’ Or alternatively, subtracting 1 from the odds-ratio gives us the

likelihood in percentage terms. For categorical and binary variables, these can be directly be

interpreted as odds ratios between two different groups. Odds-ratios below 1 indicate a negative

relationship and may be interpreted by inversing the ratio.

Table 1.3 – Regression Analysis

Dependent variable = Corruption (defined as those willing to give or take a bribe)

DESCRIPTION Beta Odds-Ratio

CONSTANT 1.805 (.574)

6.080

MALE .804* (.068)

2.234

AGE -.233* (.173)

0.792

AGE^2 .003* (.169)

1.003

Observed

Predicted

Corruption Percentage Correct

0 1

Corruption 0 82 20 80.4

1 28 36 56.3

Overall Percentage 71.1

24

YEARS OF SCHOOLING -.126* (.090)

0.882

SOCIO-ECONOMIC STATUS .605* (.077)

1.831

INADEQUATE INCOME 1.289***

(.002) 3.631

MARRIED .924** (.036)

2.521

MATERIALIST .852** (.043)

2.345

BRIBE JUSTIFICATION .962** (.021)

2.618

INSTITUTIONAL TRUST -.478* (052.)

0.620

Nagelkerke R Square 0.290

Hosmer and Lemeshow Test 0.568 (p) Values in brackets represent p-values.

* - 10% significance level, ** - 5% significance level, *** - 1% significance level

Demographics

As theorized, males are found to be more likely to indulge in corruption than females. Being a male

respondent increases the likelihood of indulging in corruption by 2.234 times and is significant at the

10% level.

Age has a negative relationship with the outcome, implying that as age increases the likelihood of

being corrupt falls. A one-unit increase in age decreases the likelihood of indulging in corruption by

1.36 times. The variable age squared, which measures the rate of change in the variable age, is positive

which implies that as age increases, the likelihood of indulging in corruption decreases at an

increasing rate. However, both age and age squared are not statistically significant, possibly due to a

relatively small sample size.

Socio-economic Factors

Average electricity expenditure indicates the level of economic activity in the household, and is a

good proxy to gauge socio-economic status of a respondent. The results indicate that electricity

expenditure has a positive relationship with the outcome variable, which implies that as socio-

economic status of a household increases, the likelihood of the respondent to be corrupt also

increases. A unit increase in socio-economic status measured on a scale of 1-3, increases the

25

likelihood of corruption by 1.831 times. This is indicative of greed corruption. The second

hypothesis that higher SES individuals are not more likely to be corrupt, is hence rejected.

Inadequate Income. Respondents who believe that their income is inadequate to sustain their

lifestyles are also more likely to indulge in corruption, as compared to those who are satisfied and

feel that current income is adequate. Feeling income inadequacy increases the likelihood of indulging

in corruption by 3.631 times and this relationship is significant at the 1% level. The third hypothesis,

that those revealing income inadequacy are not more likely to be corrupt is rejected.

Years of Schooling. As advocated earlier, years of schooling has a negative relationship with

corruption, implying that as years of schooling increases the likelihood of indulging in corruption

reduces. A one-unit increase in the years of schooling decreases the likelihood of indulging in

corruption by 1.13 times. In other words, a one-unit increase in years of schooling reduces the odds

of indulging in corruption by 13%. This relationship is significant at the 10% level.

Psychographics

Materialism. Materialism is also found to have a positive relationship with corruption. Being a

materialist increases the likelihood of indulging in corruption by 2.345 times and is significant at the

5% level. The fourth hypothesis that a materialistic person is not more likely to indulge in corruption

is rejected.

Bribe Justification. Those who justify bribery also tend to be more likely to indulge in corrupt

behavior. Moreover, those who have indulged in corruption in the past are also more likely to justify

bribery. The likelihood of giving or taking a bribe is 2.618 times more than those who do not justify

the act. This relationship is significant at the 5% level.

Environmental Factors

Marital Status. Marital status is also found to be a significant variable impacting the decision to be

corrupt. Married respondents were found to be 2.521 more likely to indulge in corruption than those

with other marital statuses, significant at the 5% level. The fifth hypothesis that married respondents

are not more likely to indulge in corruption is rejected.

26

Institutional Trust. Trust in institutions is found to have a negative relationship with corruption,

implying that as trust in institutions increases, the likelihood of indulging in corruption decreases.

Measured on a 6-point scale, a one-unit increase in trust decreases the likelihood of indulging in

corruption by 1.61 times. Alternatively, the odds of indulging in corruption reduces by 61%, with

every one-unit increase in trust. This relationship is significant at the 10% level.

Moderation Analysis

A moderation analysis was also carried out to examine if there are any significant interactions

between the covariates. This analysis attempts to gauge whether the effect of an independent

variable on the outcome variable depends on another set of independent variables. For example, the

effect of marriage on corruptibility may depend on household size. Or effect of age on corruption

may depend on years of schooling.

A correlation matrix of all independent variables revealed that the following set of variables are

correlated: Age & Years of Schooling, Age & Married, Income inadequacy & SES. We tested for

interactions effects between these set of variables, however we found none. Moderation analysis was

also conducted on other possible and logical interactions to examine whether there are any uncalled

for effects6.

Mediation Analysis

A mediation analysis attempts to study whether there are mediator variables that impact the

outcome variable. A mediator can be any variable which is assumed to be an outcome of a causal

variable, and which may carry the influence of the causal variable onto the dependent variable. The

flow chart below explains how mediation works.

There are three pre-conditions to run such an analysis (Figure 1.5). Firstly, the predictor variable (X)

must be predicting the outcome (Y) significantly. Secondly, the predictor should also predict the

mediator (M) variable significantly. Lastly, the mediator variable should predict the outcome variable

controlling for the predictor variable. So paths a, b and c should be statistically significant. Path c’

shows the effect of the predictor on the outcome controlling for the mediator variable. If path c’

reveals that the addition of the mediator variable reduces the main effect of the predictor variable,

6 See Appendix for regression results with interaction terms.

27

then mediation has occurred. If path c’ indicates a non-significant relationship, that would imply

complete mediation.

From the regression analysis, we know that those who justify bribery are more likely to indulge in

corrupt behavior. This relationship may be mediated by a past experience with corruption. So those

who justify bribery, may have probably given or taken a bribe in the past, hence they may be more

likely to indulge in bribery again. The predictor variable, justifies bribe, predicts the outcome variable,

corruption, and the mediator variable, experience. Running a statistical analysis as advocated by Barron

and Kenny (1986), we find that introducing the mediator variable reduces the beta coefficient of the

predictor variable from 1.190 to 0.897. Hence we can assume that mediation has occurred. Further

statistical analysis using the Sobel Test, which requires unstandardized regression coefficients and

their respective standard errors, confirms the previous statement that the mediation is significant (p

< 0.05).

Similar to the mediation analysis of Piff et al. (2012), we attempted to check whether or not unethical

behavior in high socio-economic groups is partly mediated for by a favorable view of bribery. Most

authors have claimed that the first step of Barron and Kenny’s analysis may be over-ruled, and there

need not be a significant relationship between the predictor variable and the outcome variable to

start with, as long as the next two steps are significant i.e. predictor variable predicts the mediator,

and the mediator predicts the outcome variable controlling for the predictor variable. So although

Figure 1.5 – Mediation Effect

28

socio-economic status, in isolation, is not a significant predictor of indulging in corruption, we can

still test for mediation. The relationship between socio-economic status and bribe justification was

found to be positive and significant, indicating that higher socio-economic groups have a relatively

favorable view of bribery than those belonging to lower groups. We also found that bribe

justification is a healthy predictor of whether or not a person indulges in corruption. The last step of

the analysis reveals that there is a mediation effect, when socio-economic status is regressed against

the outcome variable controlling for bribe justification. The beta coefficient changes significantly as

re-affirmed by the Sobel Test (p < 0.05).

We also attempted to find mediation effects in other variables such as marriage and household size.

Married individuals were found to be more likely to indulge in corruption. This may be mediated by

the fact that marriage increases household size, increasing social pressures, which may in turn lead to

higher probability of indulging in corruption. However, statistical analysis reveal no mediation effect,

implying that household size does not have an indirect effect on how marriage effects the choice of

indulging in corruption.

Furthermore, the feeling of income inadequacy also increases the likelihood of indulging in

corruption. This relationship may be mediated by an individuals’ SES. Those who feel income is

inadequate, probably belong to lower SES groups, and hence are more likely to indulge in bribery.

However, again, we find no such mediation effect, indicating that SES groups do not have an

indirect effect on how income inadequacy effects the choice of indulging in corruption.

6. Discussion

The results in the previous section are quite revealing. All hypotheses tested were rejected, indicating

that corruption is mainly motivated by greed in the study sample. Using objective measures to gauge

SES, we find that higher SES groups were more likely to indulge in corrupt behavior. Moreover,

mediation analysis also revealed that this behavior is partially accounted for because of a more

positive outlook towards bribery.

It was also found that respondents who believe their income is inadequate are also more likely to be

corrupt. As we saw earlier, the feeling of income inadequacy was correlated with a strong sense of

desire to want more than one already has, even after getting what they need. This is a sign of greed

29

corruption, because greed is also defined as a selfish desire to always want more. It is important to

point out that the study sample is a relatively well-off group lying in upper middle income brackets

with average household income of PKR 150,000. About 58% of the sample revealed that their

income is still inadequate, which may point towards ungratefulness with what one currently is

endowed with.

Materialism and Demonstration Effect

While studying corruption and economic growth in Nigeria, Elijah (2007) concludes that a culture of

materialism and ‘get rich quick’ promotes corruption. We find similar results in the study where

respondents with materialistic personalities were found to be more likely to indulge in corruption.

Exposure from mass media has fueled the rising aspirations of the people, by publicizing the wealthy

and allowing a culture of flamboyant living to creep into the society. Heavily influenced by the

lifestyle of the West, the aspirations of the Pakistani society seem to be rising rapidly as well.

Moreover, the motivation behind these aspirations are mostly selfish rather than altruistic. A lob-

sided emphasis on the achievement of private goals at the expense of common goals is further

indicative of the use of proscribed means. It is important to note that rising aspirations per se are

not undesirable, and instead it is the rate of change in these goals which outpace the institutionalized

means, that is of greater concern (Anwar, 1980).

Additionally, more than half of the study sample revealed opportunistic behavior, whereas about

62.4% of respondents also revealed a relatively high discount rate, preferring consumption over

investment. In a society where today’s consumption is preferred over tomorrows’ – a high subjective

discount rate and high propensity to consume - people attempt to achieve their goals in the shortest

possible time. Individuals aspire and daydream of ways to instantly become rich. Opportunistic and

greedy individuals tend to be on the lookout for such opportunities to advance themselves.

However, due to a lack of emphasis on the institutional means to achieve cultural goals, deviations

occur. Hence, they may not hesitate to follow technically efficient means, for instance a bribe, rather

than institutionalized means, when the latter carry higher transaction costs. Over time, as this

practice continues, the technically efficient means may become widely accepted causing corruption

to be institutionalized as well.

30

It is also argued that corruption usually starts from the wealthy and powerful. Following the role-

model of the upper class, people from relatively lower classes also adopt similar means to attain

cultural goals. For example, when one of the richest businessmen of the country confesses on

national television that he uses money to ‘grease the wheels’ and get work done, this has a

trickledown effect on those looking for opportunities and shortcuts. Taking the wealthy as a

reference group, the common man then tries to become as close to this model as it is possible within

his limitations. The fantasy of living the same lifestyle may then cause the individual to employ the

same exploitative approach as adopted by their reference group, especially in the absence of an

effective opportunity structure (Anwar, 1980).

The demonstration effect has played a significant role in embedding such values. Robert Merton

hypothesized that some social structures create pressure upon people in society to indulge in deviant

behavior (Anwar, 1980). It cannot be denied that materialistic desires are derived from social norms

around an individual. There is certainly a high chance that a subordinate wishes to enjoy the luxuries

of the boss. Likewise, if owning a car is a culturally accepted goal then individuals lacking that luxury

will be pressurized to attain the goal, perhaps from within the household. Since we found married

individuals to be more likely to indulge in corruption, and a negative relationship of household size

with the outcome, we can conclude that social pressures arising from within the household have

nothing to do with the fulfilment of basic necessities. Instead, it may be the case that the

demonstration effect is strengthened, by a strong longing of the male breadwinner to fulfil his

partner’s desires for jewelry, cars, gadgets or perhaps an expensive honeymoon package. This trend

is even more so prominent in higher SES societies, where the membership of a closed group

requires ownership of expensive and flashy gadgets.

Do Demographics Matter?

Another revelation from the analysis is that demographics do matter when we study corruptibility.

Supported by many previous findings, gender does play an important role in determining whether or

not a person may indulge in corruption, with males found to be more corrupt than females. Keeping

this in mind, female quotas in organizations are hence very important to ensure a healthy gender

balance, to improve working environment and reduce opportunistic behavior.

31

Moreover, age was found to have a negative relationship with the willingness to indulge in

corruption. As age increases, the willingness to be corrupt reduces at an increasing rate. This is

possibly because with age comes maturity, which sparks the realization of the value of reputation

and credibility in society. Hence one would be deterred from any risky act that may damage their

image. Additionally, in monotheist societies, one may become more God-fearing as they approach

an inevitable end.

Cross-tabulations7 indicated that the age group of 26-35 years is highly vulnerable to corruption.

This age group represents those who have newly entered the workforce, and are at early stages of

their careers. They are generally ambitious, have lower self-control and are not that aware of the

cons of corruption and how it can affect their career. It is important to note that majority of these

lower aged respondents, who are susceptible to corruption, belong to higher SES groups. We do not

claim that lower aged individuals have high earnings just because they belong to higher SES groups.

Our findings may be in line with the age-income hypothesis where lower aged individuals are more

likely to have lower incomes and thus are more likely to indulge in corruption. This is because

individuals belonging to higher SES groups, with high household income, may possibly have lower

personal disposable income and thus are more likely to use their influence in society to indulge in

unethical behavior.

7. Policy Implications

Lack of ‘Principled Principals’

In high-corruption societies, where corruption becomes a societal norm, there will be a collective

action problem of the second order (Ostrom, 2000), which means that there will always be a lack of

principals ready to enforce legislation or act as whistleblowers. Most policies are formulated from

the perspective of the principal-agent framework, where it is assumed that honest principals are

ready to act in the best interest of the public and it is their inability to monitor agents that allows

opportunistic behavior to flourish. However, the principal-agent approach to address the issue of

corruption, which includes improving monitoring and transparency, might in fact risk increasing the

level of corruption by exposing more illegitimate acts, as it reinforces existing beliefs about the

prevalence of systemic corruption. If the fundamental conditions of why anti-corruption measures

7 See Appendix for Cross Tabulations.

32

are in place are not met, steps will be futile and will not give expected results, especially when those

expected to enforce legislation are either corrupt or afraid of the consequences of displaying moral

heroism.

In high-corruption societies, where corruption is already systemic, most people expect everyone else

to be corrupt, and thus are not motivated to act in good faith. It gives birth to a mentality where one

believes that if they do not benefit from corruption, someone else is bound to benefit from it. The

public kitty then becomes in factual sense, a public kitty, which everyone tries to steal from for their

own selfish reasons. As a result, a lack of ‘principled principals’ will cause monitoring and

punishment regimes to be futile, as no one may have any incentive to enforce legislation (Persson et

al, 2013).

Lax Institutional Trust

Trust in major institutions also dictate how a person may act or perceive others may act in a given

situation. For instance, high trust in the judiciary reflects the choice set of the individual to include

legal means when deciding how to address an issue. So when institutional trust deteriorates these

possible choice sets may be minimized to only include illegal means. Lack of trust thus may

transform an otherwise law-abiding citizen into a briber who may use networks to exploit rent-

seeking opportunities. So erosion in institutional trust has a worsening impact on corruption and

efforts to control it. Even though the direction of causality is still debated, it is known that mistrust

and corruption practically breathe life into each other creating vicious spirals, pushing the economy

to a high-corruption equilibrium (Cho and Kirwin, 2007). Moreover, a lack of trust in elected

governments, who promise to eradicate corruption, leads the public to reject these promises,

undermining the efforts of governments to fight corruption as a collective action problem.

Education

Corruption is a social phenomenon, which can be controlled if people learn what their rights and

duties are towards society. Practical measures, as advocated by experts such as Klitgaard (1998), to

control or prevent corruption in the shape of monitoring, transparency and accountability reforms,

are necessary conditions, but not sufficient to curb the menace in a high-corruption context. In this

sense, a sufficient condition that guarantees positive results, would be the inculcation of strong

democratic values and civic virtue, which becomes an impetus for attitudinal reforms. Since

33

education plays a significant role in the decision-making process, ethical training programs at early

stages of the career might be beneficial in instilling moral values and creating awareness of the social

costs of corruption and how it may impede career growth.

Such findings also highlight the need to be careful in selection and recruitment processes to root out

‘Bad Apples’ from the system. Mohammad Ali Jinnah, when consulted by the Royal Commission on

the issue of raising the upper age limit from 21 years to 24 years for recruitment in the Indian Civil

Service in 1913, replied that he did not support extension in the upper age limit by even a day. His

advice was to insulate, at a young age, those who choose to come into public service, from market-

oriented financial incentives, lest they get mal-adjusted in life. Public service jobs have lower salaries

because they come with prestige as well. So young individuals, already exposed to charms of money

may not be able to adjust to the lower salaries and be more likely to indulge in corruption.

This is of utmost importance because more than half of the population of Pakistan is under the age

of 24, and approximately two-thirds under the age of 30. The youth need to be utilized in the most

effective manner, in order to be able to reap the demographic dividend in this Golden Age that the

nation has entered into. If this youth bulge is neglected, the consequences will be disastrous. Policy

needs to focus on targeting and grooming the youth in schools, colleges and universities, through

programs such as awareness campaigns. Additionally, school enrollment ratios have to be drastically

improved so that education becomes a societal norm rather than corruption.

‘A New Game in Town’

Keeping in mind the logic of the collective action approach, the dominant approach would be to

change citizens’ beliefs about what other actors are likely to do when faced with an opportunity. A

radical change in mindset is required, so that most actors expect others to play fair. It is noteworthy

to point out that the most common excuse for corrupt behavior was that ‘others would do the

same’. Measures such as the establishment of ‘Bribe-Free Zones’ in busy public offices, may alter

public perception about norms in the specific area, forcing actors to behave in a conforming

manner.

Recent examples of Hong Kong and Singapore are inspiring as they made the shift from high-

corruption equilibriums to low-corruption equilibriums in a relatively short period of time. These

34

examples reveal what Linz and Stepan (1996) labeled as the “new game in town” which was

practically a blend of formal and informal tools of control. It was duly noted that honest officials

serving as role models at the helm of the system was a characteristic common to countries that have

successfully dealt with the problem.

In view of the current political scenario of Pakistan, indeed the movement by major political leaders

is eye-opening and helps in creating awareness of the range of problems facing the country; however

the message being given out might have a detrimental impact on the problem that needs to be

addressed. The negativity of the message that the helm of the system is maliciously corrupt, forcing

people not to pay taxes or utility bills, may encourage further corruption. When political leaders feel

that public sentiments are against them, making their re-election doubtful, they may be tempted to

be corrupt and loot the system in the little time that they have.

High profile cases of mega corruption are on a receding trend though, due to high social awareness,

media pressures and the strengthening of NAB. Using this as a healthy platform and a starting point,

a revolutionary movement, with a message to the public that most other people could actually be

trusted to be honest, may have a positive impact on one’s willingness to be corrupt. Realistically, this

would be no easy task. But if there is a time to tackle corruption, it is now, and as many studies have

pointed out, this phenomenon can only be dealt with by a large and consistent push.

8. Limitations and Further Research

A major limitation of the study is that the subjects chosen for the survey mostly belong to urban

locations, are those who understand English, and are relatively better off and well-educated. As this

does not reflect the profile of the universe, we cannot claim that our findings are generalizable to the

entire population. Hence the scope of the study is limited to select urban populations.

We also encountered multiple types of biases in the study. Conducting surveys that ask direct

questions on socially undesirable acts is not an easy task, hence we expected social desirability and

non-response bias. We attempted to minimize such biases by guaranteeing anonymity but we

received no guarantees of unbiased responses.

35

Moreover, the sample was biased towards younger aged respondents particularly males, who

revealed greater willingness to be part of the study. This was partly because younger aged

respondents were relatively more accessible and available to be part of the study. Likewise, female to

male ratios in workplaces is considerably low hence majority of the respondents were males.

There is also room for improvement in the survey questionnaire; redundant questions could be

replaced with more appropriate ones to improve content validity in terms of convergence and

divergence. Moreover, the quantification of qualitative variables and clarification of ambiguities

between need and greed corruption requires an inter-disciplinary approach which may bring in more

accurate results. Currently, there is no appropriate framework that exists in this regard, and this

study is only an attempt to relay one of the many possibilities of how the research question may be

tackled.

Considering the limitations above, this may be taken as an experiment and further research could

explore whether there are any significant differences between participants from different sections of

the society. For instance, the same survey conducted in a local language in rural areas, may yield

completely different results. This is because the definition and toleration of corruption varies

between cultures and social classes. In a country with multiple cultures, the diverse workplace and

rising migration trends require focused studies as such, which may give a better understanding of the

problem at hand. As it is, this study is expected to generate more heat than light. Nonetheless, we

can claim that the research highlights a few interesting findings, and does point to an area for further

research, often ignored by writers on the subject.

36

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J.A. (2001). The Colonial Origins of Comparative

Development: An Empirical Investigation. The American Economic Review, 91(5): 1369-1401. Retrieved

From: http://economics.mit.edu/files/4123.

Alhassan‐Alolo, N. (2007). Gender and Corruption: Testing the New Consensus. Public

Administration and Development, 27(3): 227-237. Retrieved from http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com

/doi/10.1002/pad.455/pdf.

Anwar, M., & Anwar, M. (1980). Socio-Economic Structure and Corruption: A Case Study of

Pakistan. Pakistan Economic and Social Review, 18(1): 34-44. Retrieved From:

http://www.jstor.org/stable/25824909.

Bauhr, M., & Nasiritousi, N. (2011). Why Pay Bribes? Collective Action and Anticorruption

Efforts. Qog Working Paper Series, 2011: 18. Retrieved From: http://www.qog.pol.gu.se

/digitalassets/1357/1357856_2011_18_bauhr_nasiritousi.pdf.

Becker, C. (1968). Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, Journal of Political Economy, 76(2).

Retrieved From: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1830482.

Borjas, G.J. (1987). Self-Selection and Earning Of Immigrants. The American Economic Review, 77(4):

531-553. Retrieved From: http://isites.harvard.edu/fs/docs/icb.topic803549.files/week%203-

september%2022/borjas_self.pdf.

Brunetti, A., & Weder, B. (2003). A Free Press Is Bad News For Corruption. Journal of Public

Economics, 87(7): 1801-1824. Retrieved From: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science /article/pii

/s0047272701001864.

Chang, E. C., & Chu, Y. H. (2006). Corruption and Trust: Exceptionalism in Asian

Democracies. Journal of Politics, 68(2): 259-271. Retrieved From: http://www.ginareinhardt.com/wp-

content/uploads/2012/01/chang-chu-corruption-and-trust.pdf.

Cho, W., & Kirwin, M.F. (2007). A Vicious Circle of Corruption and Mistrust in Institutions in Sub-

Saharan Africa: A Micro-Level Analysis. Afro-Barometer Working Paper, 2007: 71. Retrieved From:

http://www.afrobarometer.org/files/documents/working_papers/afropaperno71.pdf.

37

Clarke, R. V. (1995). Situational Crime Prevention. Crime and Justice, 19(3): 91-150. Retrieved From:

http://www.jstor.org/stable/1147596.

Clarke, R. V., & Cornish, D.B. (1985). Modeling Offenders' Decisions: A Framework for Research

and Policy. Crime and Justice, 6(4): 147-185. Retrieved From: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1147498.

Cornish, D. B., & Clarke, R.V. (2003). Opportunities, Precipitators and Criminal Decisions: A Reply

to Wortley's Critique of Situational Crime Prevention. Crime Prevention Studies, 16(2): 41-96. Retrieved

From: http://www.popcenter.org/responses/crime_prevention/pdfs/cornish%26clarke.pdf.

Côté, S., Piff, P.K., & Willer, R. (2013). For Whom Do The Ends Justify The Means? Social Class

and Utilitarian Moral Judgment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 104(3), 490. Retrieved From:

http://robbwiller.org/s/cotepiffwiller2013.pdf.

Della Porta, D., & Vannucci, A. (1999). Corrupt Exchanges: Actors, Resources, And Mechanisms

Of Political Corruption. Transaction Publishers, New York.

Dong, B., Dulleck, U., & Torgler, B. (2012). Conditional Corruption. Journal of Economic Psychology,

33(3): 609-627. Retrieved From: http://www.economics.uni-linz.ac.at/members /department/files

/researchseminar/ws09/torgler.pdf.

Eagly, A.H., & Crowley, M. (1986). Gender and Helping Behavior: A Meta-Analytic Review of the

Social Psychological Literature. Psychological Bulletin, 100(3): 283. Retrieved From:

http://psy.haifa.ac.il/~ep/students_post/projects/project_2/2009-10/gender%20 and %20 helping

%20 behavior.pdf.

Elijah, A. (2007). Effects of Corruption and Economic Reforms on Economic Growth and

Development: Lessons from Nigeria. African Economic Conference. Retrieved From:

http://repository.uneca.org/unecawebsite/sites/default/files/page_attachments/abiodun_elijah_ob

ayelu_0.pdf.

Ford, R.C., & Richardson, W.D. (1994). Ethical Decision Making: A Review of the Empirical

Literature. Journal of Business Ethics, 13(3), 205-221. Retrieved From: http://www.bus. ucf.edu/

faculty/rfolger/file.axd?file=2013%2f9%2fford%26richardson(1994)ethical+decision+making%2c+

review+of+the+empirical+literature.pdf.

38

Fukuyama, F. (2001). Social Capital, Civil Society and Development. Third World Quarterly, 22(1), 7-

20. Retrieved From: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/pdf/10.1080/713701144.

Grasmick, H.G., Tittle, C.R., Bursik, R.J., & Arneklev, B.J. (1993). Testing the Core Empirical

Implications of Gottfredson and Hirschi's General Theory of Crime. Journal of Research in Crime and

Delinquency, 30(1), 5-29. Retrieved From: http://faculty.buffalostate.edu /hennesda /article %201

%20testing%20the%20core%20of%20gtc.pdf.

Grootaert, C. (2001). Does Social Capital Help The Poor? A Synthesis of Findings from the Local

Level Institutions Studies in Bolivia, Burkina Faso, and Indonesia. Local Level Institutions Working

Paper Series, 10. Retrieved From:http://siteresources.worldbank.org/intsocialcapital/resources/local-

level-institutions-working-paper-series/lli-wps-10.pdf.

Gottfredson, M.R., & Hirschi, T. (1990). A General Theory of Crime. Stanford University Press.

Harris, D. (2007). Bonding Social Capital and Corruption: A Cross-National Empirical Analysis.

University of Cambridge, Department of Land Economics. Environmental Economy and Policy Research

Working Paper Series, 27. Retrieved From: http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/csgr /events

/conferences/conference2007/papers/harris.pdf.

Husted, B.W. (1999). Wealth, Culture, and Corruption. Journal of International Business Studies, 30(2):

339-359. Retrieved From: http://www.jstor.org/stable/155316.

Kaffenberger, M. (2012) The Effect Of Educational Attainment On Corruption Participation In

Sub-Saharan Africa. Graduate School of Vanderbilt University. Retrieved From:

http://etd.library.vanderbilt.edu/available/etd-03222012-205534/unrestricted/kaffenberger.pdf.

Klitgaard, R. (1988). Controlling Corruption. University of California Press.

Klitgaard, R. (1998a). International Cooperation Against Corruption. Finance & Development, 35(1).

Retrieved From: http://204.180.229.152/external/pubs/ft/fandd/1998/03/pdf/klitgaar.pdf.

Klitgaard, R. (1998b). Strategies Against Corruption. Presentation at Agencia Española De Cooperación

Internacional Foro Iberoamericano Sobre El Combate A La Corrupción, Santa Cruz De La Sierra, Jun, 15-16

Retrieved From: http://unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/documents/clad/clad0035403.pdf.

39

Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1997). Legal Determinants of External Finance.

The Journal of Finance, 52(3). Retrieved From: http://scholar.harvard.edu/ shleifer /files

/legaldeterminants.pdf.

Lee, W.S., & Guven, C. (2013). Engaging In Corruption: The Influence of Cultural Values and

Contagion Effects at the Microlevel. Journal of Economic Psychology, 39(24): 287-300. Retrieved From:

http://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/89856/1/dp7685.pdf.

Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3): 681-712.

Retrieved From: http://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/course131/mauro95.pdf.

Mauro, P. (1998). Corruption and the Composition of Government Expenditure. Journal of Public

Economics, 69(2): 263-279. Retrieved From: http://darp.lse.ac.uk/papersdb/mauro_(jpube_98).pdf.

Mocan, N. (2008). What Determines Corruption? International Evidence from Microdata. Economic

Inquiry, 46(4), 493-510. Retrieved From: http://econ.ucdenver.edu/beckman/econ6410/mocan.pdf.

Myrdal, G. (1968). Asian Drama, an Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations. Asian Drama, an Inquiry into

the Poverty of Nations.

Niederle, M. & Vesterlund, L (2007) Do Women Shy Away From Competition Too Much? The

Quarterly Journal of Economics. Retrieved From: http://www.pitt.edu/~vester/qje.pdf.

OECD (2011) Society at a Glance. OECD Social Indicators. Retrieved From:

http://www.oecd.org/berlin/47570337.pdf.

Ostrom, E. (2000). Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. The Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 14(3): 137-158. Retrieved From: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2646923.

Persson, A., Rothstein, B., & Teorell, J. (2013). Why Anticorruption Reforms Fail—Systemic

Corruption as A Collective Action Problem. Governance, 26(3), 449-471. Retrieved From:

http://weblaw.haifa.ac.il/en/judgesacademy/workshop3/documents/a/d/why%20anti-

corruption%20fail.pdf.

40

Piff, P.K., Stancato, D.M., Côté, S., Mendoza-Denton, R., & Keltner, D. (2012). Higher Social Class

Predicts Increased Unethical Behavior. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109(11), 4086-

4091. Retrieved From: http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/pmc3306667/.

Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978). Corruption: A Study in Political Economy. Academic Press, New York.

Rose-Ackerman, S. (1997). The Political Economy of Corruption. Corruption and the Global Economy.

Retrieved From: http://www.piie.com/publications/chapters_preview/12/2iie2334.pdf.

Rose, R., Mishler, W., & Haerpfer, C. (1998). Democracy and Its Alternatives: Understanding Post-

Communist Societies. JHU Press.

Roy, A.D. (1951). Some Thoughts on the Distribution of Earnings. Oxford Economic Papers, 3(2), 135-

146. Retrieved From: http://faculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7321/papers/roy.pdf.

Schwenke, S. (2000). The Moral Critique: Corruption in Developing Countries. Journal of Public and

International Affairs, 11(8): 137-156. Retrieved From: http://www.princeton.edu/jpia/past-issues-

1/2000/8.pdf.

Seligson, M.A. (2002). The Impact of Corruption on Regime Legitimacy: A Comparative Study of

Four Latin American Countries. The Journal of Politics, 64(2): 408-433. Retrieved From:

http://www.ginareinhardt.com/wp-content/uploads/2012/01/seligson-impact-of-corruption-on-

regime-legitimacy.pdf.

Slemrod, J. (2006). The Role of Misconceptions in Support for Regressive Tax Reform. National Tax

Journal, 59(1): 57-75. Retrieved From: http://www.brookings.edu/~/media /events

/2003/12/16taxes/20031216_slemrod.pdf.

Stepan, A.C., & Linz, J.J. (1996). Toward Consolidated Democracies. Journal of Democracy, 7(2), 14-33.

Retrieved From: http://repi.ulb.ac.be/sites/default/files/contenu/cours/linz-et-stepan1.pdf

Swamy, A., Knack, S., Lee, Y., & Azfar, O. (2001). Gender and Corruption. Journal of Development

Economics, 64(1): 25-55. Retrieved From: http://cde.williams.edu/wp-

content/uploads/2009/11/swamy_gender.pdf.

41

Tavares, S. (2005). Does Rapid Liberalization Increase Corruption? Public Economics, 0507003.

Retrieved From: http://econwpa.repec.org/eps/pe/papers/0507/0507003.pdf.

Torgler, B., & Dong, B. (2008). Corruption and Political Interest: Empirical Evidence at the Micro

Level. Crema Working Paper Series, 3. Retrieved From: http://www.econstor.eu/bitstream

/10419/40674/1/568803558.pdf.

Torgler, B., & Valev, N.T. (2006). Public Attitudes Toward Corruption and Tax Evasion:

Investigating the Role of Gender Over Time. Berkeley Program in Law & Economics, Working Paper

Series. University of Berkley. Retrieved From: https://escholarship.org/uc/item/3983136n.

Trautmann, S.T., Van De Kuilen, G., & Zeckhauser, R.J. (2012). Social Class and (Un) Ethical

Behavior: Evidence From A Large Population Sample. HKS Faculty Research Working Paper Series,

RWP12-019, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Retrieved From:

http://dash.harvard.edu/bitstream/handle/1/8832940/rwp12-019_zeckhauser.pdf?sequence=1.

Treisman, D. (2000). The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study. Journal of Public

Economics, 76(3), 399-457. Retrieved From: http://www.policyinnovations.org/ideas/policy_library

/data/01437/_res/id=sa_file1/treisman_causes_corruption.pdf.

Tsalikis, J., & Nwachukwu, O. (1991). A Comparison of Nigerian to American Views of Bribery and

Extortion in International Commerce. Journal of Business Ethics, 10(2), 85-98. Retrieved From:

http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2fbf00383612.

The World Bank (1997) Helping Countries Combat Corruption: The Role of the World Bank

Washington, DC: World Bank Group. Retrieved From: http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector

/anticorrupt/corruptn/corrptn.pdf.

42

Appendix

Cross-Tabulations

Age * Corruption

We created 5 different age groups with equal intervals: 16 to 25 (1), 26 to 35 (2), 36 to 45 (3), 46 to

55 (4), 56 and above (5).

Table 1a – CORRUPTION * AGEGROUP Crosstabulation

% within AGEGROUP

AGEGROUP Total

1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00

CORRUPTION 0 72.0% 58.8% 68.4% 60.0% 75.0% 62.4%

1 28.0% 41.2% 31.6% 40.0% 25.0% 37.6%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Education * Corruption

We created 5 different groups divided on the basis of years of schooling: 0 to 8 years (1), 9 to 12

years (2), 13 to 16 years (3), 17 to 18 years (4), and 19 years of schooling and above (5). These

groupings are based on the following categories: No education/Primary and secondary, higher

secondary, undergraduate, post-graduate, and doctorate level.

Table 1b – CORRUPTION * EDUCATIONAL GROUP Crosstabulation

% within EDUCATIONAL GROUP

EDUCATIONAL GROUP Total

1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00

CORRUPTION 0 100.0% 30.8% 60.2% 68.0% 77.8% 62.4%

1 69.2% 39.8% 32.0% 22.2% 37.6%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Income * Corruption

We created three different groups: 1 to 1500 (1), 1501 to 10000 (2), and 10001 and above. Group (1)

is considered as a lower income group, (2) is a middle income group whereas (3) is a higher income

group. Corruption is defined as those respondents who expressed their willingness to give or take a

bribe.

43

Table 1c - CORRUPTION * SOCIO-ECONOMIC STATUS Crosstabulation

% within SES

SES Total

1.00 2.00 3.00

CORRUPTION 0 72.2% 63.5% 56.3% 62.4%

1 27.8% 36.5% 43.8% 37.6%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Age Group * Socioeconomic Status * Corruption

Table 1d - CORRUPTION * AGEGROUP * SES Crosstabulation

% within AGEGROUP

SES AGEGROUP Total

1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00

1.00 CORRUPTION

0 100.0% 60.0% 75.0% 100.0% 72.2%

1 40.0% 25.0% 27.8%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

2.00 CORRUPTION

0 61.1% 62.1% 70.0% 64.3% 75.0% 63.5%

1 38.9% 37.9% 30.0% 35.7% 25.0% 36.5%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

3.00 CORRUPTION

0 100.0% 52.9% 60.0% 40.0% 56.3%

1 47.1% 40.0% 60.0% 43.8%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Total CORRUPTION

0 72.0% 58.8% 68.4% 60.0% 75.0% 62.4%

1 28.0% 41.2% 31.6% 40.0% 25.0% 37.6%

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

S3H Working Paper

01: 2014 Exploring New Pathways to Gender Equality in Education: Does ICT Matter? by

Ayesha Qaisrani and Ather Maqsood Ahmed (2014), 35 pp.

02: 2014 an Investigation into the Export Supply Determinants of Selected South Asian

Economies by Aleena Sajjad and Zafar Mahmood (2014), 33 pp.

03: 2014 Cultural Goods Trade as a Transformative Force in the Global Economy: A Case of

Pakistan by Saba Salim and Zafar Mahmood (2014), 32 pp.

04: 2014 Explaining Trends and Factors Affecting Export Diversification in ASEAN and

SAARC Regions: An Empirical Analysis by Shabana Noureen and Zafar Mahmood

(2014), 29 pp.

05: 2014 In Search of Exchange Rate Undershooting in Pakistan by Wajiha Haq and Iftikhar

Hussain Adil (2014), 20 pp.

01: 2015 A Time Series Analysis of Aggregate Consumption Function for Pakistan by Zakia

Zafar and Tanweer Ul Islam (2015), 13 pp.

02: 2015 Impact of Human Capital Investment on the Exports of Goods and Services: An

Analysis of Selected Outsourcing Countries by Samina Siddique and Zafar Mahmood

(2015), 31 pp.

03: 2015 Energy Demand Elasticity in Pakistan: An Inter-temporal Analysis from Household

Survey Data of PIHS 2001-02 and PSLM 2010-11 by Ashfaque H. Khan, Umer

Khalid and Lubna Shahnaz (2015), 34 pp.

04: 2015 The Size of Trade Misinvoicing in Pakistan by Tehseen Ahmed Qureshi and Zafar

Mahmood (2015), 31 pp.

05: 2015 Services Sector Liberalization and Its Impact on Services GDP Growth in Pakistan

by Maryam Mahfooz and Zafar Mahmood (2015), 30 pp.

06: 2015 Alternative to Kibor for Islamic Banking: A Case Study of Pakistan by Asaad Ismail

Ali and Zahid Siddique (2015), 25 pp.

07: 2015 Impact of Climatic Shocks on Child Human Capital: Evidence from Ethiopia, India,

Peru and Vietnam by Mina Zamand and Asma Hyder (2015), 27 pp.

08: 2015 Energy Related Carbon Dioxide Emissions in Pakistan: A Decomposition Analysis

Using LMDI by Arslan Khan and Faisal Jamil (2015), 20 pp.

09: 2015 Decomposition Analysis of Energy Consumption Growth in Pakistan during 1990-

2013 by Arbab Muhammad Shahzad and Faisal Jamil (2015), 24 pp.

10: 2015 Economic Rationality and Early Age Work-Education Choice: Rethinking the Links

by Zahid Sidique, Faisal Jamil and Ayesha Nazuk (2015), 22pp.

11: 2015 Trade Costs of Pakistan with its Major Trading Partners: Measurement and its

Determinants by Saba Altaf and Zafar Mahmood (2015), 32 pp.

01: 2016 The Statistical Value of Injury Risk in Construction and Manufacturing Sector of

Pakistan by Ahmad Mujtaba Khan and Asma Hyder (2016), 15 pp.

02: 2016 Socio-economic Determinants of Maternal Healthcare Behavior: Evidence from

Pakistan by Sadaf Munir Ahmad and Asma Hyder (2016), 19 pp.

03: 2016 Rising Debt: A Serious Threat to the National Security by Ashfaque H. Khan (2016),

31 pp.

04: 2016 Long-run Pricing Performance of Initial Public Offerings (IPOs) in Pakistan by

Muhammad Zubair Mumtaz and Ather Maqsood Ahmed (2016), 38 pp.