exchange rates, optimal debt composition, and …...exchange rates, optimal debt composition, and...

45
Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide 2008-18 NOTE: Staff working papers in the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (FEDS) are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. The analysis and conclusions set forth are those of the authors and do not indicate concurrence by other members of the research staff or the Board of Governors. References in publications to the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (other than acknowledgement) should be cleared with the author(s) to protect the tentative character of these papers.

Upload: others

Post on 09-Feb-2020

11 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Finance and Economics Discussion SeriesDivisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs

Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging inSmall Open Economies

Jose Berrospide

2008-18

NOTE: Staff working papers in the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (FEDS) are preliminarymaterials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. The analysis and conclusions set forthare those of the authors and do not indicate concurrence by other members of the research staff or theBoard of Governors. References in publications to the Finance and Economics Discussion Series (other thanacknowledgement) should be cleared with the author(s) to protect the tentative character of these papers.

Page 2: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small

Open Economies

Jose Berrospide∗

January 2008

Abstract

This paper develops a model of the firm’s choice between debt denominated in local currency andthat denominated in foreign currency in a small open economy characterized by exchange raterisk and hedging possibilities. The model shows that the currency composition of debt and thelevel of hedging are endogenously determined as optimal firms’ responses to a tradeoff betweenthe lower cost of borrowing in foreign debt and the higher risk of such borrowing due to exchangerate uncertainty. Both the composition of debt and the level of hedging depend on commonfactors such as foreign exchange rate risk and the probability of financial default, interest rates,the size of firms’ net worth, and the costs of managing exchange rate risk. Results of the modelare broadly consistent with the lending and hedging behavior of the corporate sector in smallopen economies that recently experienced currency crises. In particular, unlike the predictionsof previous work in the literature on currency crises, the model can explain why the collapse ofthe fixed exchange rate regime in Brazil, in early 1999, caused no major change in the currencycomposition of debt of the corporate sector.

JEL Classification: F31, F34, F41, G18, G32.

Keywords: Exchange rate regime, Debt composition and Hedging.

∗Federal Reserve Board; telephone: (202) 452-3590, E-mail: [email protected]

The author wishes to thank Linda Tesar, Uday Rajan, Jing Zhang, Kathryn Dominguez, Chris House and participantsin the International Macro Lunch and the International Seminar at the University of Michigan for valuable advice.Financial support from the Center for International Business Education (CIBE) is gratefully acknowledged. Theviews expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the Board of Governors of the FederalReserve System or its staff.

Page 3: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

1 Introduction

Recent currency crises in East Asia and Latin America have been characterized by currency

mismatches between assets and liabilities, as well as inadequate hedging, in the balance sheets of

the corporate sector.1 Some researchers have argued that the mismatch between foreign currency

liabilities and domestic currency assets in firms’ balance sheets has been the root cause of the

large output collapses following currency depreciations (Krugman, 1999; Aghion, Bacchetta, and

Banerjee, 2001; and Schneider and Tornell, 2000). Under a fixed exchange rate regime, firms

view fixed exchange rates as a guarantee and thus fail to insure their foreign exposure.2 A direct

implication of this line of reasoning is that once the exchange rate is allowed to float, firms will

recognize their exposure, and foreign currency loans will be viewed as more costly so that firms

will reduce their currency mismatches by downsizing their foreign currency borrowing. Contrary to

this prediction, firm-level evidence from Brazil over the period 1997-2001 suggests that the collapse

of the fixed exchange rate regime in 1999 caused no major change in the currency composition of

corporate-sector debt. This paper attempts to explain this apparently surprising result.

To study this phenomenon, the paper develops a theoretical framework that examines the

firm’s choice of local and foreign currency debt in the presence of exchange rate risk and hedging

possibilities. The model shows that decisions about the currency composition of debt and the

optimal level of hedging are interrelated and depend on common factors such as exchange rate

risk and the probability of financial default, interest rates, the size of firms’ net worth, and the

costs of managing foreign currency risk. The key element driving the model’s results is the tradeoff

that firms face between the lower cost of borrowing in foreign currency and the higher risk of such

borrowing due to exchange rate uncertainty. When affordable, hedging reduces firms’ exposure to

currency risk and expands their capacity for borrowing in foreign currency. Thus, after a large

currency depreciation—say, the collapse of a fixed exchange rate regime—hedged firms are able to1A currency mismatch occurs when a large fraction of a firm’s debt is denominated in foreign currency while all

of its income and assets are denominated in domestic currency.2This implication is consistent with another strand in the literature, which emphasizes that a moral hazard problem

is introduced by the implicit bailout guarantees that the government provides when fixing the exchange rate. Theseguarantees bias the composition of debt toward foreign currency and eliminate incentives to hedge risk (Burnside,Eichenbaum, and Rebelo, 2001).

1

Page 4: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

maintain or even increase their access to foreign currency borrowing.

In the model, forward-looking firms make their borrowing decisions based on expectations of

currency depreciation. Thus, even under fixed exchange rates, as long as such firms perceive that

the regime is no longer credible, they will anticipate a future depreciation and will start managing

the devaluation risk by engaging in hedging activities. As seen in section 2, this strategy seems

to have been pursued by some firms in Brazil, which were hedged with currency derivatives even

during the fixed exchange rate regime. Furthermore, when financial markets provide enough tools

to mitigate the effects of the devaluation risk, the collapse of the fixed exchange rate may cause

only small changes in the currency composition of debt because, given the opportunity to hedge,

companies may not reduce their foreign currency debt after the devaluation.

The model’s predictions are broadly consistent with the lending and hedging behavior of

corporations in small open economies that recently faced currency crises. The theory advanced

by the model suggests that, when the economy moves from fixed to floating exchange rates, some

firms change their financing policies, and the population of firms exposed to foreign exchange risk

is altered. Firms with insufficient net worth and those unable to afford a hedge lose access to

capital markets. Firms with high enough net worth and those with an ability to hedge increase

their foreign debt. Firms that have intermediate net worth but are unable to hedge borrow less

in foreign currency, turn to domestic banks, and are monitored by such banks to maintain their

access to foreign capital markets. In a macroeconomic environment characterized by a moderate

probability of currency depreciation and inexpensive hedging, these changes in the population of

firms can offset each other so that the average currency composition of debt varies little across

regimes.

The paper builds on the Holmstrm and Tirole (1997) model of credit extended to the small

open economy. The analytical framework most closely related to this paper is that of Martinez

and Werner (2002). They also adapt the model of Holmstrm and Tirole to the case of the small

open economy and find that before the Mexican crisis of 1994, the decision to borrow in pesos

or dollars depended on the exchange rate regime to the extent that the government provided an

2

Page 5: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

implicit guarantee by fixing the exchange rate. However, the authors treat the exchange rate as a

deterministic variable, and no hedging strategies are discussed. In their model, as in most of the

previous literature, large amounts of foreign currency debt implicitly represent higher exposure to

exchange rate risk.

As mentioned earlier, previous theoretical models suggest that a large devaluation has a negative

effect on companies’ foreign currency borrowing and that it reduces currency mismatches. However,

empirical findings on the relationship between exchange rate regimes and currency mismatches in

corporate-sector balance sheets are mixed and still subject to debate. Some studies find that the

adoption of a floating regime reduces currency mismatches by decreasing foreign currency borrowing

and increasing levels of hedging, whereas others find that firms borrow even more after a currency

crisis.3 As Cowan, Hansen, and Herrera (2005) point out, many of the previous studies use the

ratio of foreign debt to total debt as an exogenous proxy for currency mismatches. Using data from

corporations in Chile, the authors argue that the lack of empirical consensus about the importance

of balance sheet effects results from the endogeneity of the currency composition of debt and not

from the absence of such effects. The model in the current paper accounts for the endogenous

determination of both the level of hedging and the currency composition of debt and helps explain

the apparent contradiction between theory and empirical evidence.4As demonstrated in the model,

hedging allows corporations, in the aggregate, to maintain their access to international capital

markets and to keep their currency composition of credit almost unchanged after a currency crisis.

The reminder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the motivating empirical

facts for the model, using firm-level data from Brazil. Section 3 describes the model of optimal3Empirical findings on currency mismatches and exchange rate exposure during fixed exchange rate regimes are in

Burnside et al (2001) in the Asian crisis, Tesar and Dominguez (2001) in 8 non-industrialized and emerging marketsand Bonomo et al (2003) a study of the financial data of selected Brazilian companies. In a different study of Brazilianfirms, Rossi (2004) finds that the adoption of a floating regime reduces the foreign vulnerability of the corporate sectorby negatively affecting firms’ foreign borrowing and positively affecting their hedging. However, Martinez and Werner(2002) find that firms in Mexico were able to increase their foreign debt borrowing after the crisis of 1995. Similarly,Allayannis et al (2002) find that nonfinancial firms in Asian countries were able to maintain substantial levels offoreign currency debt even after the currency crisis. But except for only a few studies, such as Rossi (2004) andAllayannis et al (2002), most research in the empirical literature used data only on the currency composition of debtat the firm level, as data on hedging are often not available or hard to collect.

4Accounting for endogeneity in the decision to hedge, Berrospide, Purnanandam, and Rajan (2007) show thathedging with currency derivatives increased the foreign debt capacity of firms in Brazil and allowed them to maintaintheir investment after the currency crisis.

3

Page 6: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

debt allocation and hedging at the firm level. Section 4 offers the main results of the model under

fixed and flexible exchange rates. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2 Empirical Evidence on Foreign Currency Exposure and

Hedging: Brazil, 1997-2001

This section examines firm-level data on Brazilian firms for the period 1997-2001, which covers the

two years before the currency crisis of 1999, the two years after, and the crisis year itself. Like other

Latin American countries, Brazil suffered unexpected reversals in capital flows after earlier crises

in Mexico (1994), East Asia (1997), and Russia (1998). In Brazil, the macroeconomic adjustment

caused by substantial capital outflows at the end of 1998 brought large and persistent swings in

the exchange rate that finally led to the collapse of the crawling peg and a sharp devaluation of its

currency, the real, in January 1999.

Firm-level data consist of financial information for a balanced panel of 145 nonfinancial

companies that were publicly traded on the Sao Paulo Stock Exchange (BOVESPA) over the

period 1997-2001.5 The information was taken directly from companies’ annual financial reports.

Data contain information on balance sheet variables such as the book value of assets, the currency

composition of debt, and shareholders’ equity. Data on hedging transactions were hand-collected

and consist of the year-end notional value of currency derivatives (forwards, futures, swaps, and

options), as reported in the explanatory notes to financial statements available at BOVESPA.

Financial and state-owned firms are excluded because of their different motivation for using currency

derivatives.

Table 1 illustrates the currency composition of firms’ debt and the extent of their hedging

activities across exchange rate regimes. As shown in the table, when the Brazilian economy

moved from a fixed to a floating exchange rate regime, there was no major change in the currency5The period was chosen because the corresponding data provide valuable information for a comparative analysis

of firms’ behavior regarding financing and risk-management policies before and after the currency crisis of 1999.Disclosure of information on derivatives was mandatory only after 1995.

4

Page 7: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

composition of debt, measured by the ratio of foreign debt to total debt.6 Over the sample, the

ratio remains stable at around 43 percent. Across firms grouped by size, the foreign debt ratio

seems to exhibit a similar pattern except for small firms that, on average, slightly decrease their

ratios. In contrast, the extent of hedging operations, approximated by the ratio of the notional

value of currency derivatives to foreign debt, increased from 5 percent in 1997 to 25 percent in

2001. Interestingly, the data show that hedging operations increased during the floating exchange

rate regime but had already been observed during the fixed exchange rate period, especially for

medium and large corporations. Large companies increased their hedging ratio, on average, from

6 percent during the fixed exchange rate regime to 22 percent during the floating regime. The

observation of hedging activities under fixed exchange rates indicates that even before the currency

crisis, and most likely after crisis episodes in East Asia and Russia, some firms indebted in foreign

currency were managing the devaluation risk by hedging their positions with currency derivatives.

As will be shown later, this behavior is consistent with the model’s predictions concerning the

hedging features of financing policies in small open economies subject to currency risk. Table 1

also suggests some evidence of costly hedging, as the increase in the hedging ratio occurred mostly

at large and medium-sized companies, whereas small firms appear to have hedged only a small

fraction of their foreign debt, even during the floating regime.7

An interesting feature regarding the hedging behavior of the corporate sector in Brazil is that

most financial hedging transactions involve currency swap contracts. Unlike large U.S. nonfinancial

corporations, which report currency forwards and options as the most commonly used tool to

manage exchange rate exposure, similar Brazilian firms seem to prefer currency swaps, which

effectively convert foreign debt into domestic debt through simultaneous transactions in the spot

and forward markets. Broad preference for currency swaps is also consistent with costly hedging,

as a swap reduces transaction costs by allowing companies to arrange with only one contract what6Even after correcting for the valuation effect of currency depreciation in the ratio of foreign debt to total debt,

there is still no major change in the currency composition of debt.7Chan-Lau (2005) reports that as of 2004 the cost of using currency forwards, measured by the bid-ask spread

as a percentage of the forward rate, was relatively high in Brazil (15 basis points) compared with the cost in otheremerging-market countries (8 basis points in both Chile and Korea).

5

Page 8: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

may otherwise take several transactions (for example, forward contracts) to replicate. 8

Table 2 shows the number of firms that held financial debt (in domestic currency, foreign

currency, or both), and the number of such firms that used currency derivatives, over the sample

period. These data also provide evidence of minor changes in the corporate sector’s borrowing

behavior. Some firms dropped out of the sample, and the number of firms that borrowed only in

domestic currency increased slightly during the floating regime. After the collapse of the exchange

rate regime, the number of firms that hedged with currency derivatives increased from 7 in 1997 to

40 in 2001. Interestingly, about 46 percent of the firms with foreign debt remained unhedged in 2001.

Overall, the evidence presented in this section seems to support the view that no significant changes

occurred in the borrowing patterns of the Brazilian corporate sector during the period 1997-2001—

that is, before, during, and after the currency crisis. Admittedly, obtaining a genuine measure

of the extent of firm-level hedging is difficult, and the previous observations about hedging refer

only to the use of currency derivatives. Firms may use hedging strategies other than derivatives,

such as holdings of assets denominated in foreign currency and revenues from exports, which are

not examined in the current analysis. That said, one point can be emphasized: The evidence

from the sample of Brazilian firms is contrary to the results predicted in previous research. After

the large depreciation that followed the collapse of the fixed exchange rate regime, firms still

borrowed significantly in foreign currency, and more companies hedged this debt by participating

in currency derivatives markets. As shown in the next section, the model’s predictions of optimal

debt composition and hedging levels are consistent with these empirical facts.8Bonomo, Martins, and Pinto (2003) point out that Brazilian firms prefer currency swaps because they can obtain

advantageous swap contracts from local banks. Banks, in turn, can offer these contracts because they are not exposedto exchange rate risk, as they hold government bonds indexed to the dollar in their portfolios. According to theseauthors, in the end, the hedge appears to be provided by the government through bank intermediation.

6

Page 9: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

3 A Model of the Optimal Currency Composition of Debt and

Hedging

Consider a small open economy described by a two-date model (t = 0, 1). The economy is

populated by a continuum of risk-neutral firms, domestic banks, and foreign banks. Firms are

run by wealth-constrained entrepreneurs who need to raise funds to cover their investment outlays.

Firms’ investment projects can be financed by borrowing in either domestic currency from local

banks or in foreign currency from foreign banks. Given the uncertainty about the exchange rate,

firms can choose to hedge their foreign exchange risk by signing forward contracts offered by local

banks. At t = 0, firms sign debt contracts and make investment, borrowing and hedging decisions.

At t = 1, exchange rate and investment returns are realized and claims are settled. Agents are

protected by limited liability so that no party can end up with negative payoffs.

3.1 Investment Projects

Each firm has access to a project requiring an investment of fixed size I, where I > 0 at t = 0;

at t = 1 the investment yields a verifiable return in domestic currency, R, in case of success and

nothing in case of failure. Firms differ only in their initial capital, A (which is publicly observable).

The distribution of firms is described by the cumulative distribution function, F (A). It is assumed

that A < I, so that firms need external funding to undertake their investments. Investment projects

are of three types, as described in Figure 1: good, with a high probability of success, PG; bad, with

a low probability of success, PB (PG > PB); or worse, also with a low probability of success.

The bad project gives the entrepreneur a low private benefit, b, and the worse project gives the

entrepreneur a high private benefit B, where B > b > 0. Firms face a moral hazard problem in

choosing a project. In the absence of proper incentives or outside monitoring, entrepreneurs can

divert resources by deliberately reducing a project’s probability of success (from PG to PB) to enjoy

the private benefit.

Local banks can monitor firms to reduce the moral hazard problem and eliminate the worse

7

Page 10: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Project Good Bad WorseProbabilityof success PG PB PB

Private Benefit 0 b B

Figure 1: Three Types of Investment ProjectsNote: For explanation of variables, refer to text.

project. Monitoring is costly so that local banks face a fixed cost, C, where C > 0. Foreign banks

are uninformed investors (that is, they are unable to monitor firms) and have access to alternative

projects that earn a gross rate of return, r∗, in international markets. Furthermore, it is assumed

that given the rate of return on investor capital in domestic currency, rf , only the good project has

a positive expected net present value (NPV), even if the private benefit of the firm is included in

the calculation:

PG R− rf I > 0 > PB R− rf I +B (1)

3.2 Financing decisions and exchange rate risk

In what follows, firms are represented by the index f , domestic banks by the index m, and foreign

banks by the index u. At t = 0, a representative firm invests all its funds, A, and signs debt

contracts to borrow from local banks an amount in domestic currency, Im, and from local banks

an amount in foreign currency, Iu, so that

A+ Im + sL Iu ≥ I (2)

where sL > 0 is the exchange rate at t = 0, quoted as sL units of domestic currency per unit of

foreign currency.9 Note that both the investment return and the exchange rate are uncertain,

a departure from the original credit model of Holmstrm and Tirole (1997). In addition to

9It is also assumed that the internal rate of return of investment projects exceeds the market rate, rf , which meansthat funds invested in the firm earn the external rate of return plus an amount due to the incentive effect. Moreover,there is no other source of funding (such as equity financing) in the model. As in emerging economies in Asia andLatin America, a large part of the funding for investments is provided in the form of bank loans.

8

Page 11: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

incorporating the moral hazard structure of that model, the current setup extends the firm’s

investment problem not only by having the firm borrow in foreign currency from international

capital markets but also by adding a new dimension to the problem—namely, there is the possibility

of default due to exchange rate risk, and firms use hedging activities to mitigate that risk.

Investment projects, then, are subject to two types of bad events: failure (economic default) or

bankruptcy due to currency-led default (financial default). Exchange rate fluctuations, therefore,

can turn solvent firms into bankrupt firms even when they undertake successful projects. It is

assumed that in the event of any type of default, firms’ creditors are left with nothing.10

For simplicity, consider only two possible states for the exchange rate: low (L) and high (H).

At t = 0, the exchange rate is sL. At t = 1, if the economy operates under a fixed exchange

rate regime, then s1 = sL. Under a floating exchange rate regime, the exchange rate can either

depreciate to sH > sL with probability q, or remain unchanged with probability 1 − q. To avoid

losses due to exchange rate fluctuations, companies may hedge their foreign exchange risk with

currency forward contracts.

Let F be the one-period forward exchange rate charged to the firm and defined as units of

domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. Given the possibility of economic and financial

default, it is assumed that forward markets are efficient so that F is the expected exchange rate at

t = 0 and is given by the following expression:11

F =

(1− q) sL + q sH if financially solvent in both states L,H

sL if financially solvent only in state L

sH if financially solvent only in state H

(3)

Note that sL ≤ F ≤ sH . Expression (3) states that the forward rate is adjusted according to the risk

of financial default so that overhedging (for example, infinite hedging in case of zero transaction

costs) is ruled out, as will be clear in the next paragraphs. Another important feature of the10For example, in case of financial default, the firm is declared bankrupt, and its residual value is completely used

to pay bankruptcy costs.11As shown later, the forward rate is related to interest rates according to a covered interest parity condition.

9

Page 12: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

hedging contract is that payments in either direction are contingent on the project’s success. In

other words, if the project fails and state L occurs, then the firm has nothing, so it pays nothing

on the hedging contract; if state H occurs, the firm receives no payment either. This particular

feature guarantees that a hedged firm will always be able to obtain a forward contract at the rate

F = (1− q) sL + q sH , which occurs because the hedging contract is offered by domestic banks so

that payments in both directions are netted out on average.12

Let h be the amount of forward contracts, in foreign currency, purchased by a firm, and let

φ be the transaction costs per unit of forward contract. For simplicity, let φ also be expressed in

domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. At t = 1, if the project succeeds, proceeds from

hedging operations in domestic currency are

ΠH = h (s1 − F )− φ |h| (4)

Note that firms in the model are forward-looking agents. They make their debt and hedging

decisions based on expectations of currency depreciation. Moreover, q can also be interpreted as

the probability of devaluation under fixed exchange rates when the regime is not credible. In that

case, q would be the conditional probability that the currency is devalued at t = 1 after having

been fixed at t = 0.

A debt contract must specify the amount borrowed from, and paid to, each lender under all

circumstances so that: 1) if the project fails, it pays zero to all parties; 2) at t = 1, if the project

succeeds and the firm is solvent, the parties divide the total proceeds, which consist of project

return R plus the proceeds from hedging operations (if any). Out of the total proceeds, the firm

receives Rf (s1) ≥ 0, domestic banks receive Rm ≥ 0, foreign banks receive s1Ru ≥ 0, and forward

sellers receive φ|h| ≥ 0.

Note that debt payments on the forward contract are made only if the project is successful

and the firm is solvent. Note also that debt payments to lenders are independent of the exchange12For simplicity, it is assumed that firms buy forward contracts from domestic banks other than those from which

they borrow so that the transaction costs of hedging do not represent revenues to domestic lenders.

10

Page 13: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

rate s1 provided that the firm is solvent. However, returns to the entrepreneur (the equity-holder)

depend on s1.

Financial default occurs at t = 1 when the firm, even if undertaking a successful investment,

cannot meet its financial obligations and goes bankrupt. Financial default is then given by the

following condition:

R−Rf (s1)−Rm(s1)− s1Ru(s1) + h(s1 − F )− φ|h| < 0 (5)

As mentioned above, the forward rate in expression (3) rules out overhedging. For example,

consider a firm that wants to buy a significantly large amount of forward contracts to increase its

expected payment when sH occurs; but default when sL occurs. Because the firm is solvent only

in state H, expression (5) becomes positive in state H but negative in state L. By setting F = sH ,

sellers of forward contracts eliminate incentives to overhedge, as a firm that overhedges receives

zero proceeds from the forward contract in the depreciation state.

The preceding analysis implies that the firm hedges its foreign exchange exposure to reduce the

possibility of financial default. Furthermore, a firm that is hedged ex ante cannot be insolvent, or

solvent in only one state. Because financial default may occur in either state L or H, let 1L and

1H be indicator variables such that

1H =

1 if solvent in state H

0 if default in state H

1L =

1 if solvent in state L

0 if default in state L(6)

Accordingly, expected cash flows to the entrepreneur with zero proceeds from hedging, when

11

Page 14: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

the firm invests in the good project are:

Rf (sH) =

PG [R−Rm − sH Ru] if solvent in state H

0 if default in state H

Rf (sL) =

PG [R−Rm − sL Ru] if solvent in state L

0 if default in state L(7)

3.3 Firm’s expected profits

At t = 0, a firm with initial capital A and investment I chooses the currency composition of its debt

(Im and Iu), creditors’ payments (Rm and Ru), its hedging amount (h) and its expected payments

Rf (sL) and Rf (sH) to maximize expected total profits:

E[ΠTOT ] = PG[1L(1−q)[R−Rm−sLRu]+1Hq[R−Rm−sHRu]−φ|h|]+rf (I−A−Im−sLIu) (8)

subject to resource constraints, incentive and participation constraints and non-negativity

constraints (for example limited liability).

In setting up the problem in this way, it is assumed that the firm undertakes only good projects

with probability of success PG. This assumption always holds because incentive constraints are

imposed and only good projects have NPV > 0, which means that if bad projects are undertaken,

no borrowing is obtained from creditors. Depending on the exchange rate realization, when the

firm is financially solvent, project return, R, and proceeds from hedging operations are distributed

among all the parties according to the following resource constraints:

Rf (sL) +Rm + sL Ru = R+ h (sL − F )− φ|h| (9)

12

Page 15: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Rf (sH) +Rm + sH Ru = R+ h (sH − F )− φ|h| (10)

When the firm defaults in state H or state L, it pays nothing to the other parties, and the

residual value covers bankruptcy costs.

Let 1m be an indicator variable such that 1m = 1 if the firm borrows from the local bank

(with monitoring) and 1m = 0 if the firm borrows directly from foreign banks and not from local

banks (without monitoring). Given the two possible states for the exchange rate, and the solvency

condition associated with them, the firm invests in a good project whenever it obtains an expected

payment greater than or equal to the expected payment of a bad project including private benefits.

In other words, the firm invests in the good project when:

PG [1L (1−q) Rf (sL)+1H q Rf (sH)] ≥ PB[1L (1−q) Rf (sL)+1H q Rf (sH)]+1mb+(1−1m)B (11)

This is the firm’s incentive constraint and can also be written as:

1L (1− q) Rf (sL) + 1H q Rf (sH) ≥ 1mb

∆p+ (1− 1m)

B

∆p(12)

where ∆p = PG − PB > 0.

3.4 Domestic bank lending

A local bank monitors the firm and finances the project whenever it receives an expected payment

sufficient to cover the fixed monitoring cost, C. The bank’s incentive constraint is given by

[1L (1− q) + 1H q] Rm ≥ 1mC

∆p(13)

The bank is willing to finance the project if it receives a net expected payment (net of monitoring

13

Page 16: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

costs) that is, at least, equal to the opportunity cost of its funds. The participation constraint for

the bank is given by

PG [1L (1− q) + 1H q] Rm − 1m C ≥ rf Im (14)

Let r be the domestic lending rate that local banks charge on Im funds lent to the firm, defined

as

r =PG [1L (1− q) + 1H q] Rm

Im(15)

The minimum domestic rate of return, r, that is acceptable for a bank that decides to finance

an investment project in domestic currency is determined by the condition

PG C

∆p− C = rf PG C

r∆p(16)

Expression (16) is obtained by combining conditions (13) through (15), all of them holding with

equality, and assuming that the bank lends to the project so that 1m = 1. This condition, in turn,

implies that

r = rf PG

PB(17)

Expression (17) states that the cost of domestic funds incorporates a risk premium relative to

the risk-free rate. At the minimum rate of return acceptable for a bank, the risk premium equals

the ratio of success probability of the good project to the success probability of the bad project.

Local banks can borrow and lend internationally and are able to replicate a forward contract.

Perfect competition and non-arbitrage conditions ensure that banks are indifferent toward two

available options: (1) lending in domestic currency at rf ; or (2) converting these funds, at t = 0,

into foreign currency at the spot rate sL; lending abroad in foreign currency, where the funds earn

r∗; and converting them back to domestic currency at the forward rate F . These transactions imply

14

Page 17: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

that

rf = r∗F

sL(18)

This is a covered interest rate parity condition and can also be expressed in terms of the domestic

lending rate, r, and the international rate, r∗, by plugging expression (18) into expression (17):13

r = r∗F

sL

PG

PB(19)

In this expression, F ≥ sL and PG > PB, so that the bank lending rate, r, is always greater than

the international interest rate, r∗. Thus, foreign debt is always preferred to domestic debt. The

result that foreign currency debt is a cheaper source of capital than domestic debt is due to the

moral hazard structure associated with investment projects. Intuitively, given that banks face a

fixed cost to monitor firms, the lending rate in domestic loans incorporates not only the expected

change in the exchange rate, given by the ratio F/sL, but also a risk premium due to asymmetric

information given by the ratio PG/PB. As a result, when necessary, firms minimize borrowing from

a local bank and obtain the rest of their funds from foreign lenders.

The firm will be able to borrow in foreign currency if foreign banks are promised an expected

payment greater than or equal to what they could obtain by investing their funds in international

capital markets at the rate r∗. The foreign bank participation constraint, in foreign currency, is

then

PG [1L (1− q) + 1H q] Ru ≥ r∗ Iu (20)13Covered interest rate parity and efficient markets hypothesis are certainly very strong and simplifying

assumptions. The incorporation of parameter φ, denoting the transaction costs involved in setting up a hedgingprogram, is intended to add some friction to the model and make it a more realistic representation of foreign exchangemarkets. In practice, these transaction costs are expressed as bid-ask spreads in forward and spot rate quotations.

15

Page 18: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

3.5 Firm’s profit maximization

The firm’s problem is to choose variables h, Im, Iu, Rm, Ru, Rf (sL), Rf (sH), given exogenous

parameters such as the firm’s initial assets A; its fixed investment, I; the foreign rate of return, r∗;

the probability of currency depreciation, q; and the cost of hedging, φ, in order to:

maximize E[ΠTOT ] =

PG[1L(1− q)[R−Rm − sLRu] + 1Hq[R−Rm − sHRu]− φ|h|] + rf (I −A− Im − sLIu)

subject to

A+ Im + sL Iu ≥ I (i)

If the firm is solvent, the following two conditions apply:

Rf (sL) +Rm + sL Ru = R+ h (sL − F )− φ|h| (ii)

Rf (sH) +Rm + sH Ru = R+ h (sH − F )− φ|h| (iii)

1L (1− q) Rf (sL) + 1H q Rf (sH) ≥ 1mb

∆p + (1− 1m) B∆p (iv)

[1L (1− q) + 1H q] Rm ≥ 1mC

∆p (v)

PG [1L (1− q) + 1H q] Rm − 1m C ≥ rf Im (vi)

PG [1L (1− q) + 1H q] Ru ≥ r∗ Iu (vii)

Rf (sH) ≥ 0 (viii)

Rf (sL) ≥ 0 (ix)

Conditions (i) through (iii) are resource constraints, conditions (iv) and (v) are the incentive

constraints for the firm and the domestic bank, conditions (vi) and (vii) are the participation

constraints for domestic and foreign banks, and conditions (viii) and (ix) are non-negativity

constraints for the firm’s payments. Only one of the two non-negativity constraints will be binding

when the firm defaults in one state of the exchange rate but is solvent in the other. Note that there

are nine constraints to solve for seven choice variables, which means that in equilibrium at least

seven constraints must be binding.

16

Page 19: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

3.6 Equilibrium

The determination of the equilibrium, as well as the closed-form solution for the currency

composition of debt and the optimal level of hedging are explained in detail in appendix 1. As

an illustration, consider that both borrowing and hedging decisions are endogenously determined

as optimal firms’ responses to a tradeoff between the lower cost of borrowing in foreign debt and

the higher risk of such borrowing due to exchange rate uncertainty. As explained earlier, foreign

currency debt is preferred to domestic debt so that the firm always tries to borrow directly from

foreign banks. The smaller the size of its initial assets, A, the more the firm demands from

international banks. Because exchange rate uncertainty makes foreign debt risky, foreign banks

demand that a firm have a minimum net worth and that it conduct hedging operations through

currency forwards to ensure that the firm is solvent enough to repay its debt. If the firm’s initial net

worth is insufficient to meet the foreign bank’s requirement, then the firm must be monitored and

must first borrow from domestic banks to be able to borrow from international markets. Depending

on the size of its net worth, the monitored firm may also need to hedge to demonstrate financial

solvency.

Given that the internal rate of return is greater than the external rate on firm capital,

entrepreneurs prefer to invest all their funds in the project. Therefore, constraint (i) in the firm’s

problem will be binding in most cases. The only time it will not be binding is when a firm must

borrow only in domestic currency from local banks. Recall that local banks must cover the fixed

monitoring costs when lending in domestic currency. This condition implies that, in equilibrium,

local banks lend all firms the same fixed amount in domestic currency. Therefore, when the firm

has a net worth insufficient to borrow only in foreign currency but high enough to borrow the fixed

amount in domestic currency, and the sources of funds exceed the size of the investment, then

constraint (i) is not binding and the firm must invest its excess funds at the market rate rf . This

situation is captured by the last term in the objective function of the firm’s maximization problem.

Another key feature of the model is that hedging decisions are perfectly observed by creditors.

An immediate implication is that firms have incentives to hedge their exchange rate risk to reduce

17

Page 20: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

the probability of financial default. When affordable, hedging increases expected profits by reducing

the cost of capital to the firm —that is, by expanding the possibility of borrowing in foreign currency

at a lower cost. The equilibrium level of hedging corresponds to any value within an optimal range

defined by constraints (ii), (iii), (viii) and (ix) as shown in the appendix. Depending on exogenous

parameters (in particular, q and φ) the minimum level of hedging in this range can be positive

or negative (negative hedging means that the firm sells forward contracts). As shown in what

follows, intermediate values of q and a small enough φ make the minimum level of hedging positive,

and a profit maximizing firm will always choose this minimum level. Let q be the probability of

depreciation that makes the minimum level of hedging equal to zero, and let φ be the transaction

cost in forward markets above which, for any given level of positive q, forward contracts are too

costly to provide insurance.14These two cutoff values for parameters q and φ allow one to identify

situations in which the firm optimally chooses not to hedge. When the probability of depreciation

is too high—say, when q > q (for example, under extreme exchange rate volatility)— firms will find

it optimal to choose a zero level of hedging. When hedging is too costly—say, when φ > φ—then

hedging, even if available, will not be affordable, and firms will also choose not to hedge.

A representative firm solves its profit maximization problem under two situations: when it

hedges enough to avoid financial default and when it does not hedge at all.15 Given that hedging

is necessary but not sufficient for financial solvency, a firm that has sufficiently high net worth can

borrow only small amounts of foreign currency debt and be financially solvent without hedging.

Therefore, when the firm does not hedge at all, there are two additional possibilities: The firm is

solvent even without hedging, or the firm defaults if it is not hedged. Each of these possibilities

exists for a monitored company that borrows in both currencies and for a company that borrows

only in foreign currency. These multiple cases imply that creditors demand different net worth

levels depending on the firm’s composition of credit and its hedging strategy.

Appendix 1 illustrates how to find these net worth requirements. For the purpose of analysis,14It can be shown that q = 1− ( b

∆psH

sH−sL)/(R− C

∆p) and φ = sH − F = (1− q)(sH − sL) respectively.

15Partly hedging is ruled out because, in the case of currency depreciation, this level of hedging is insufficient toavoid default, and so the firm is forced to default as if hedging were zero in the first place. When the costs of hedgingare sufficiently small but positive, the firm will prefer zero hedging to partly hedging.

18

Page 21: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

the following paragraphs outline a brief description of all such requirements. Lower-bar net worth

levels denote minimum net worth requirements for firms that are being monitored and that must

first borrow from domestic banks, and upper-bar net worth levels denote the requirements for firms

that borrow only from foreign banks. Accordingly, AH is the minimum net worth for an optimally

hedged firm that borrows in both domestic and foreign currency. Similarly, AH is the minimum

level of assets required for an optimally hedged firm that wants to borrow only in foreign currency

from international banks.

When the firm does not hedge and, as a result, is not solvent in state H, the minimum net

worth requirements are ANH and ANH for firms being monitored by local banks and for firms that

want to borrow directly from foreign banks respectively. For a firm to be solvent in state H even

if unhedged, the minimum net worth required by creditors is higher: ASNH if monitored by local

banks and ASNH if it wants to borrow only from foreign banks. An unhedged but solvent firm

faces the highest net worth requirements, whereas a firm that hedges to be solvent faces the lowest

such requirements. In equilibrium, depending on the size of the firm’s initial assets and its hedging

strategy, financing possibilities vary. To decide on the optimal currency composition of its debt

(for example, how much to borrow from each source) and the extent of hedging activities, the firm

compares its initial assets, A, with these cutoff levels.

4 Hedging Costs, Exchange Rate Risk, and the Segmentation of

Firms in Equilibrium

4.1 Equilibrium with costless hedging (φ = 0)

A costless hedging equilibrium can be thought of as a long-run equilibrium in which currency

forward markets are competitive and well developed so that the transaction costs in setting up a

hedging program are negligible. The next two results illustrate the optimal financing policies when

the economy operates in steady-state equilibrium under fixed exchange rates or under floating

exchange rates.

19

Page 22: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Lemma 1 In an economy with credible fixed exchange rates—that is, when q = 0—the optimal

strategy for a firm is to borrow in foreign currency without hedging.

Proof : Refer to appendix 2

This result explains why, for some firms, a fixed exchange rate biases the currency composition

of their debt toward foreign currency and eliminates incentives to operate in forward markets. By

fixing the exchange rate, the government provides the corporate sector with free risk management

by creating a perception of no foreign exchange risk. 16 Consequently, some firms that otherwise

would not be able to borrow at all, or some others that should be monitored to gain access to

international capital markets, are now able to obtain foreign currency debt without constraints.

This situation creates incentives for entrepreneurs to borrow extensively in foreign currency without

hedging and to maintain currency mismatches in their balance sheets. As predicted by the balance

sheet approach in the literature on currency crises, in the event of unexpected and large currency

depreciation, the corporate sector in this economy could face widespread bankruptcy.

Lemma 2 In an economy with floating exchange rates—that is, when 0 < q < q—the optimal

strategy, in equilibrium, for a firm with net worth A such that AH < A < ASNH or AH < A < ASNH

is to hedge its foreign currency debt enough, through currency forwards, to avoid bankruptcy.

Proof : Refer to appendix 2

According to this result, during a floating exchange rate regime or a noncredible fixed exchange

rate regime, a positive probability of currency depreciation creates incentives for a firm exposed

to exchange rate risk to hedge and reduce the possibility of financial default. By reducing the net

worth requirement, hedging allows companies to maintain or increase their funding from foreign

banks, even in the presence of currency risk. In the absence of transaction costs in forward markets,

hedging is always preferred to not hedging, and any firm that is insolvent in state H has incentives

to hedge its currency exposure enough to avoid financial default. This is the case when the firm

uses a mixture of domestic and foreign debt or when it borrows only in foreign currency. Note also16If hedging is costless and q = 0, then net worth ratios are at their lowest values, and those for hedged and

unhedged firms are equal, so that the firm is indifferent about how much it hedges because F = sL.

20

Page 23: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

that hedging is beneficial only for firms that are insolvent in state H; firms with net worth above

the minimum requirement for solvency in state H do not need to hedge.

The previous two results, in equilibrium, for an economy in which hedging is costless determine

a particular ordering of net worth requirements and define an equilibrium segmentation of firms

into different categories depending on their demand for bank loans and their hedging strategy, as

shown in figure 2. Well-capitalized firms, with net worth A > AH , finance their investment directly

in foreign currency from international banks. Poorly capitalized firms, with A < AH , cannot

invest at all since they have no access to any type of finance. Between these segments, somewhat

capitalized firms, with AH < A < AH , can invest only to the extent that they are monitored and

demand domestic bank loans. Firms in this monitoring region [AH , AH ] finance their investment

with a mixture of domestic and foreign debt. As already mentioned, whether firms hedge their

foreign debt or not depends on the size of their initial asset. Well-capitalized firms need not hedge

if A > ASNH but must hedge if A ∈ [AH , ASNH ]. Similarly, somewhat capitalized firms need not

hedge if A ∈ [ASNH , AH ] but must hedge if A ∈ [AH , ASNH ].

Although a typical firm in the monitoring region uses a mixture of domestic and foreign currency

debt to finance its investment, some firms in the region use only domestic currency debt. As

discussed earlier, firms with net worth A < AH but A + Im > I demand bank loans only in

domestic currency and invest their excess funds outside the firm at the market rate. The minimum

net worth requirement for these firms is AB, which is less than AH .

As shown in figure 2, firms in the monitoring region have different demands for bank loans and

different hedging strategies. Some firms borrow in domestic and foreign currency and must hedge,

whereas others borrow only in domestic currency and need not hedge. Note that in the equilibrium

segmentation, firms may borrow only in domestic currency after having the chance to borrow in

both currencies, but they may not reverse the order of that sequence of events. This feature of

the model is explained by the fact that domestic loans are more expensive and are supplied in a

fixed amount due to fixed monitoring costs. Therefore, firms in the monitoring region use the fixed

amount in domestic currency only after exhausting the possibility of borrowing in foreign currency;

21

Page 24: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

No credit

Only foreign debt

Domestic and foreign debt

f(A)

Not hedgedHedged

HASNHA SNHAHA

Only domestic

debt

Not hedged

0 AB

Monitoring Region

Hedged Not hedged

Net worth

Figure 2: Equilibrium segmentation of firms

Note: The equilibrium segmentation is determined by net worth, currency composition of debt,and hedging strategy. Variables represent minimum net worth requirements for firms and aredefined as follows: AH , for a firm that must hedge to be solvent and to borrow in domestic andforeign debt; ASNH , for a firm to be solvent even without hedging and to borrow in foreign debt;AB, for a firm to borrow only in domestic currency; AH , for a firm that must hedge to be solventand to borrow directly from foreign banks; ASNH , for a firm to be solvent even without hedgingand to borrow directly from foreign banks.

the extent of such borrowing depends on the size of a firm’s net worth. For firms in the monitoring

region, unlike firms that borrow only in foreign currency, bank monitoring makes the moral hazard

problem less severe.

Lemmas 1 and 2 are consistent with previous predictions in the literature on currency crisis.

In particular, they are consistent with the government guarantees approach, which highlights the

incentives to borrow extensively in foreign currency, without hedging, when the exchange rate is

fixed. When the exchange rate regime is flexible, or when the fixed exchange rate is not credible so

that firms anticipate a currency depreciation (q > 0), firms will manage the foreign exchange risk by

hedging enough to avoid financial default. Interestingly, the mechanism emphasized in the model is

22

Page 25: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

that, by lowering the net worth required by creditors for a given size of investment, hedging allows

firms to maintain or increase their access to foreign currency debt.

4.2 Equilibrium with costly hedging (φ ≥ 0)

In the previous analysis when φ = 0 net worth requirements ANH and ANH are irrelevant for

the hedging decision. But this is not the case when hedging is costly. The next result shows

that currency mismatches may arise during floating regimes because hedging opportunities, even if

available, can be unaffordable for all firms when transaction costs are sufficiently high.

Proposition 1 Given costly hedging and a positive probability of depreciation, the optimal

strategy for a firm in the monitoring region, regarding debt composition and hedging, depends

on q and φ such that

1. when q ≥ q, the firm borrows the least it can in domestic currency from local banks, borrows

the rest in foreign currency from foreign banks, and does not hedge its foreign debt.

2. when 0 < q < q and 0 < φ < (1 − q)(sH − sL), the firm finds it optimal to borrow the least

it can in domestic currency from local banks and the rest in foreign currency from foreign

banks; moreover,

2.1 if φ is small enough then the firm with AH < A < ASNH will always hedge its foreign

debt;

2.2 if φ is sufficiently high, then only some firms with ANH < A < ASNH will hedge their

foreign debt.

3. when φ ≥ (1 − q)(sH − sL), the firm finds it optimal to borrow the least it can in domestic

currency from local banks and the rest in foreign currency from foreign banks, and does not

hedge its foreign debt.

Proof : Refer to appendix 2

23

Page 26: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Figure 3 illustrates all different hedging possibilities implied by Proposition 1. Notice that the

minimum net worth requirement to obtain credit in both domestic and foreign currency varies

depending on parameters q and φ. In case (1), an extremely high probability of depreciation makes

the optimal hedging level zero so that no firm participates in currency forward markets. A similar

situation occurs in case (3), when some firms have incentives to hedge but forward contracts are too

expensive or nonexistent. Although these two situations seem similar in that firms do not hedge,

they are in fact different and have different interpretations. Intuitively, higher values of both q and

φ increase the net worth requirement, thereby making it harder to borrow in both domestic and

foreign currency. In case (1), q is too high and the firm is forced to borrow only small amounts in

foreign currency so that it is solvent in state H without hedging. In case (3), however, a firm that

is insolvent in state H is still able to borrow large amounts of foreign debt even when it cannot

afford to hedge. Such a firm has a currency mismatch in its balance sheet and would default if

state H occurred.

The second case in proposition 1 corresponds to intermediate values of q and φ, which create

incentives for firms to hedge. When transaction costs in hedging markets are small enough, any

firm that needs to hedge to be solvent will opt to hedge. This situation -shown in figure 3 as case

(2.1)— is similar to the result in Lemma 2. However, as the hedging cost increases, some firms have

incentives to borrow in both currencies but find it optimal not to hedge their foreign debt exposure.

In that case -shown in the figure as case (2.2)— ANH becomes the relevant cutoff level defining

the lower limit in the equilibrium segmentation. The proof of proposition 1 (refer to appendix 2)

describes the cutoff level A∗, below which firms do not hedge because hedging is too costly. These

firms would default in the event of currency depreciation. The situation in case (2.2) may be the

result of economies of scale in hedging operations: Companies with small net worth tend to be

highly leveraged and demand more foreign currency debt than larger firms; however, they cannot

cover this exposure because the level of hedging required turns out to be unaffordable. In contrast,

firms with higher net worth demand less foreign currency debt and require a lower level of hedging

to manage their foreign exchange risk even if forward contracts are expensive.

24

Page 27: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Case (1): q very high

Case (2.1): q moderate φ very small

Case (3): φ very high

SNHA

HA SNHA

Hedged

Not hedged No credit

NHA SNHA

SNHA

NHA

*A

No need to hedge

Net worth

Case (2.2): q very small φ moderate

No need to hedge

Net worth

Not hedged No credit

Net worth

No credit Hedged No need to hedge

No need to hedge

Net worth

No credit

Figure 3: Hedging strategies for firms in the monitoring region.Note: For explanation of each case, refer to text. Parameter q is the probability of currencydepreciation; parameter φ is the transaction cost per unit of forward contract. Other variablesrepresent net worth cutoff levels, defining hedging strategies, for firms that use a mixture of foreignand domestic debt. AH , is the minimum net worth requirement for a firm that must hedge to besolvent; ANH , is the minimum net worth requirement when the firm is not hedged and is insolventin state H; ASNH , is the minimum net worth requirement for a firm to be solvent even withouthedging, and A∗ is a specific net worth requirement for firms that must hedge when hedging ismoderately costly.

The preceding analysis shows that the equilibrium segmentation is determined by endogenous

net worth requirements, which, in turn, depend on parameters describing the macroeconomic

environment such as interest rates, exchange rates, the probability of currency depreciation, and

hedging costs. All these parameters are the same for every firm. Hence, every investment project

has a unique segmentation in equilibrium. Depending on its initial assets, a firm determines both

its debt composition and its hedging strategy by locating itself within the segmentation. The next

25

Page 28: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

result, described by proposition 2, illustrates how different exchange rate regimes and different

stages of development in forward markets affect the allocation of domestic and foreign debt and

the selection of a hedging strategy.

Proposition 2 When the economy moves from fixed (q = 0) to floating exchange rates and, in

the floating regime, 0 < q < q and φ < (1− q)(sH − sL), all else equal:

1. fewer firms obtain funding for their investment.

2. some firms that borrow only in foreign currency from international banks during the fixed

exchange rate increase their demand for domestic loans during the floating regime.

3. hedged firms remain able to borrow in both domestic and foreign currency, and increase their

foreign loans after the economy moves to floating exchange rates.

Proof : Refer to appendix 2

To illustrate these results, consider that in equilibrium, domestic currency borrowing, Im, is a

fixed amount, and each firm in the economy demands the same fixed amount from local banks.

The aggregate demand for domestic bank loans, Dm, is then

Dm(r∗, q) = [F (AH(r∗, q))− F (AH(r∗, q))]Im(r∗, q) (21)

where the individual demand, Im, is written as a decreasing function of both r∗ and q. The

aggregate demand for foreign currency loans is given by

Du(r∗, q) =∫ AH(r∗,q)

AH(r∗,q)[I − Im(r∗, q)−A]dF (A) +

∫ ∞AH(r∗,q)

[I −A]dF (A) (22)

Given perfect competition in the domestic banking sector, the supply of domestic funds is perfectly

elastic at the domestic lending rate, r, and the supply of foreign loans is perfectly elastic at the

international interest rate, r∗, which means that Dm and Du determine the aggregate amounts of

domestic and foreign lending in equilibrium.

26

Page 29: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

An increase in q has an ambiguous effect on Dm because both cutoff levels, AH(r∗, q) and

AH(r∗, q), increase, and there are two opposite effects. A first group of firms, those with insufficient

net worth and those unable to hedge, cannot borrow at all; therefore, they drop out of the market,

and Dm decreases. A second group of firms, those with insufficient net worth or an inability to

hedge, cannot borrow only in foreign currency; therefore, they turn to domestic banks, and Dm

increases.

An increase in q also has an ambiguous effect on Du. Firms that had previously borrowed in

foreign debt and then turned to domestic debt reduce their demand for foreign debt so that Du

drops. However, firms with intermediate net worth and those with the ability to hedge remain in

the monitoring region and increase their demand for foreign debt, as Im decreases for them; as a

result, Du increases. Notice that, by increasing the number of firms with access to foreign currency

debt, hedging facilitates the rise in Du, which compensates for, and may even surpass, the previous

decline so that the demand for foreign currency debt may end up increasing on net.

In summary, some firms borrow less in both currencies, and others borrow more in foreign

currency. The extent to which these changes in the population of firms affect the aggregate

currency composition of debt depends on the distribution function, F (A). Figure 4 illustrates

the joint implications of propositions 1 and 2 for changes in the population of firms exposed to

currency risk after the collapse of the fixed exchange rate regime. Note that, after the collapse of

the regime, all net worth requirements shift to the right except ASNH —the requirement for firms

that borrow directly from foreign banks and are solvent without hedging. This is the case because

ASNH does not depend on the probability of depreciation, which means that firms with very large

net worth are not concerned about currency risk when they borrow in foreign currency.

The switch to the floating regime shifts the monitoring region, which lies between AH and AH

to the right, thereby making it more difficult for firms to borrow in foreign currency. However,

firms that hedge are able to reduce their exposure, maintain their access to credit, and increase

their foreign currency debt. Changes in hedging behavior can be significant or small depending on

the size of q and φ. For example, as q increases and approaches q, the number of firms that hedge

27

Page 30: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Domestic and foreign debt Only foreign debt No credit

Not hedged Hedged Hedged Floating

Fixed

HA

HA HA

SNHA

BA

BA

SNHA

SNHA

Not hedged

Domestic and foreign debt Only foreign debt No credit

Not hedged Not hedged Not hedged Not hedged

HA

Net worth

Net worth SNHA

Figure 4: Changes in the equilibrium segmentation of firms from fixed to floating exchange ratesNote: For definition of variables that represent minimum net worth requirements, refer to note infigure 2.

with currency forwards decreases and can become very small if is sufficiently high as to prevent

some firms from hedging.

4.3 The Brazilian experience

As a final illustration, consider how the results of the model match up with the currency crisis in

Brazil in early 1999. The model’s results suggest that the lack of major changes in the borrowing

28

Page 31: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

behavior of the corporate sector in Brazil could have reflected a moderate increase in the probability

of currency depreciation and the existence of somewhat costless hedging. These outcomes, predicted

by the model, are corroborated by the data in tables 1 and 2. After the floating regime was

implemented in Brazil, the number of firms borrowing in both currencies declined, some firms

dropped out of the sample (8 firms did so in 1999), and the number of firms borrowing only in

domestic currency increased. Among the firms that continued borrowing in both currencies (for

example, firms in the monitoring region), many were able to increase their debt in foreign currency,

and the number of hedged firms increased (from 7 in 1997 to 40 in 2001). The increase in the

number of hedged firms was also consistent with a rise in the volume of hedging operations, from

5 percent to 25 percent, within the same period. These changes affecting the demand for domestic

and foreign currency debt seem to have offset each other. Even though the collapse of the fixed

exchange rate regime increased the risk of borrowing in foreign currency, hedging allowed many

firms to mitigate the risk and to maintain or increase their access to foreign debt so that the

aggregate currency composition of debt did not change significantly across regimes.

Needless to say, in the real world, various other aspects of the macroeconomic situation, as well

as firm-specific characteristics, affect the currency composition of lending and the hedging behavior

of firms. Moreover, in contrast to what the model assumes, a currency crisis most likely affects firms’

net worth so that the distribution of firms may not be constant across regimes. Furthermore, other

parameters, such as the probability of success and the investment payoff, R, are certainly different

across firms and are also affected by the collapse of the exchange rate regime. How companies

deal with higher foreign exchange risk depends on changes in these variables, which are treated

as invariant parameters in the model. For example, depending on specific characteristics such as

export status, type of ownership, or the existence of other sources of funding, firms can adopt

hedging strategies other than the use of currency forwards. Nevertheless, the model developed in

the paper suggests changes in the behavior of a representative firm, and effects on the population

of firms, that are broadly consistent with the empirical facts observed in recent currency crises in

small open economies and, in particular, in Brazil over the period 1997-2001.

29

Page 32: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

5 Conclusion

This paper seeks to understand the sources of currency mismatches in corporate-sector balance

sheets in countries that recently faced currency crises. It does so by introducing hedging decisions

in a model of optimal debt composition at the firm level. The model explains why some firms with

access to foreign currency debt hedge their currency exposure and others do not, as an optimal

response to appropriate incentives given by the macroeconomic environment. Under fixed exchange

rates, firms borrow extensively in foreign currency and do not hedge, as they have no incentives

to do so given that the government provides a type of free risk management. When the economy

adopts a floating exchange rate regime, firms have incentives to use currency forwards to hedge their

exposure to exchange rate risk and reduce the probability of financial default. Hedging reduces the

net worth required by creditors and thus allows hedged firms to maintain or expand their capacity

for borrowing in foreign capital markets.

Despite the obvious limitations of a partial-equilibrium analysis and some simplifying

assumptions, the model provides an analytical framework to determine endogenously the currency

composition of credit and the optimal degree of hedging at the firm level. In line with the

empirical evidence in Brazil during the period 1997-2001, the model predicts that, given a moderate

probability of currency depreciation and somewhat costless hedging, the changes in the population

of firms after the economy adopts a floating regime can offset each other so that the currency

composition of debt does not vary significantly across regimes.

The currency composition of debt remained stable in Brazil after the collapse of the exchange

rate regime, and costless hedging operations seemed to provide an effective vehicle to reduce foreign

exposure without affecting significantly the aggregate level of borrowing. The model highlights the

importance of the development of currency derivatives markets to help the corporate sector manage

the increase in foreign exchange risk resulting from macroeconomic shocks.

30

Page 33: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

References

[1] Aghion, P., Bacchetta, P. and A. Banerjee, 2004, A Corporate Balance-Sheet Approach to

Currency Crises, Journal of Economic Theory 113 (1), pp. 6-30

[2] Allayannis, G., G. Brown, and L. Klapper, 2002, Capital Structure and Financial Risk:

Evidence from Foreign Debt Use in East Asia, Journal of Finance 58(6), 2667-2709.

[3] Berrospide, Jose, Purnanandam A. and U. Rajan, 2007, Corporate Hedging, Investment and

Value, University of Michigan, Working Paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=1009657.

[4] Bonomo, Marco, Martins B. and R. Pinto, 2003, Debt Composition and Exchange Rate Balance

Sheet effects in Brazil: A Firm Level Analysis, Fundacao Getulio Vargas. Graduate School of

Economics, http://epge.fgv.br/portal/en/pesquisa/producao/4775.html.

[5] Burnside, C., Eichenbaum, M. and S. Rebelo, 2001, Hedging and Financial Fragility in Fixed

Exchange Rate Regimes, European Economic Review 45, pp. 1151–1193.

[6] Chan-Lau, Jorge, 2005, Hedging Foreign Exchange Risk in Chile: Markets and

Instruments, International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. 05/37, Washington:

www.imf.org/external/pubind.htm.

[7] Cowan, K. Hansen E. and L. Herrera, 2005, Currency Mismatches, Balance Sheet Effects and

Hedging in Chilean Non Financial Corporations, Central Bank of Chile, Working Paper 346.

Santiago: Central Bank of Chile, December, http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/chbbcchwp.

[8] Dominguez, K., and L. Tesar, 2001a, A Re-Examination of Exchange Rate Exposure, American

Economic Review, vol. 91 (May, Papers and Proceedings), pp. 396-99.

[9] Holmstrom, B. and J. Tirole, 1997, Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real

Sector, Quarterly Journal of Economics vol. 112 (August), pp. 663-91.

31

Page 34: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

[10] Krugman, P. , 1999, Balance Sheets, The Transfer Problem, and Financial Crises, in P. Isard,

A. Razin, and A. Rose (eds.), International Finance and Financial Crises, Essays in Honor of

Robert P. Flood, Kluwer, Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic, pp. 31-44.

[11] Martinez L. and A. Werner, 2002, The Exchange Rate Regime and the Currency Composition

of Corporate Debt: The Mexican experience, Journal of Development Economics vol. 69

(December), pp. 315-34.

[12] Rossi, Jose L. , 2004, Corporate Foreign Vulnerability, Financial Policies and the Exchange

Rate Regime: Evidence from Brazil, New Haven, Conn.: Yale University, mimeo.

[13] Schneider, M. and A. Tornell, 2000, Balance Sheet effects, Bailout Guarantees and Financial

Crises, NBER Working Paper No 8060. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic

Research, December, http://papers.nber.org.

32

Page 35: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Appendix 1: Model Solution

Determination of Equilibrium

There are four possible cases in the profit maximization problem of a representative firm. The

maximized objective function is different in each of the four cases:

A. 1H = 1 and 1L = 1 if the firm is solvent in both states

B. 1H = 1 and 1L = 0 if the firm is solvent only in state H

C. 1H = 0 and 1L = 1 if the firm is solvent only in state L

D. 1H = 0 and 1L = 0 if the firm is insolvent in both states

Case (D) is the uninteresting case and is ruled out, as no lender will lend the firm any amount,

thereby preventing the firm from undertaking the project. Moreover, given the features of the

hedging contracts, firms that are solvent in only one state of the exchange rate are firms that chose

h = 0. Therefore, expected profits for the remaining three cases are as follows

A. E[ΠTOT ] = PG[R−Rm − F Ru − φ|h|]

B. E[ΠTOT ] = PG[q(R−Rm − sH Ru)]

C. E[ΠTOT ] = PG[(1− q)(R−Rm − sL Ru)]

Case (B) is also ruled out because it is always dominated by case (A). To understant why this

statement is true, note that when φ = 0 for any 0 < q < 1, then sH > F and profits are greater

in case (A) than in case (B). When φ > 0, profits in case (B) will exceed those in case (A) only if

both q > q and φ > φ which, in turn, will make h = 0, in which case profits in case (B) will again

be smaller. Intuitively, when the firm is solvent in state H only, it is also solvent in both state H

and state L even without hedging. Moreover, given positive transaction costs, there is no reason to

hedge a positive amount when the firm is solvent in state H.17 Therefore, the only relevant cases17If solvent in state H, a firm can hedge only if hedging is negative—that is, when the firm sells forward contracts.

However, for any positive transaction cost φ, negative hedging is also dominated by zero hedging.

33

Page 36: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

to evaluate are (A) and (C), which means that in equilibrium the firm is always solvent in state L

(1L = 1) and case (C), insolvency in state H, happens only when the firm is not hedged at all.

Given that the firm is the residual claimant in debt contracts, constraints (v) through (vii) will

be binding. This is the case because, to maximize profits, the firm chooses the minimum payments

that make its creditors willing to participate financing the project.

A representative firm solves its maximization problem at t = 0 using the following algorithm:

1. Suppose that, given the lower cost of foreign debt, the firm decides to borrow directly from

foreign banks (1m = 0). Furthermore, suppose the firm judges itself as financially solvent

without hedging (1H = 1, 1L = 1 and h = 0). Conditions (v) and (vi) jointly determine

Im = 0 and Rm = 0. Given A and I, the firm finds Iu using (i), which holds with equality,

and then Ru is determined by (vii). Given that expected payments Rm and Ru are already

pinned down, constraint (iii) is used to verify whether the firm is solvent in state H. If it is,

then the firm can in fact borrow directly from foreign markets without hedging.

2. If the firm is insolvent in state H and decides not to hedge, foreign creditors adjust their

expected payment. Ru depends on q and is larger to compensate for the possibility of default.

Constraint (viii) is binding so that Rf (sH) = 0 (for example, if state H occurs, the residual

value of the firm covers bankruptcy costs). Constraint (ii) gives the firm’s own payment,

Rf (sL). If constraint (iv) is met, then borrowing in foreign currency without hedging is

feasible. Otherwise, the firm can still borrow directly from foreign markets but must use

forward contracts to reduce the possibility of default in state H.

3. If the firm hedges its foreign exchange risk with currency forwards, then constraints (ii) and

(iii), combined with constraints (viii) and (ix), determine an optimal range for hedging [h, h],

given by

sHRu +Rm −RsH − F − φ

≤ h ≤ R−Rm − sLRu

F − sL + φ

Profit maximization implies that for any positive and small φ, the firm chooses the minimum

34

Page 37: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

level to avoid default so that optimal hedging is h = h with Rm = 0. As a result, constraint

(viii) is binding and Rf (sH) = 0. Note that when φ = 0, there are multiple solutions for

the optimal hedge because the firm is indifferent about choosing any value within the range

[h, h]. If constraint (iv) is met, then borrowing in foreign currency and hedging are feasible.

The firm determines whether hedging is optimal or not by comparing the profits in this case

with those in the no-hedging case. If constraint (iv) is not met, then the firm cannot borrow

directly from foreign markets and must turn to domestic banks.

4. Suppose the firm borrows from domestic banks (1m = 1) and believes it is financially solvent

without hedging (1H = 1, 1L = 1 and h = 0). As before, constraints (v) and (vi) jointly

determine Im and Rm. These two variables are now,

Rm =C

∆p, Im =

PB

r∗sL

F

C

∆p

Note that when the firm is solvent in state H, Rm does not depend on q. Given I and A,

and having determined Im: if A + Im > I, then resource constraint (i) is not binding, the firm

borrows only in domestic currency, and invests excess funds I − A− Im at the market rate, rf . If

A+ Im ≤ I, then constraint (i) is binding, and the firm uses it to determine Iu so that the currency

composition of debt is established. As in steps (2) and (3) of this algorithm, the firm can borrow

now in both currencies without hedging if it is solvent in state H, or can it face higher payments

if it is insolvent in state H and does not hedge. Whether the firm must hedge or not depends on

exogenous parameters (in particular q and φ). The firm solves for its optimal hedging decision by

comparing the profits in each case. If the firm must hedge, the optimal range for hedging is [h, h]

with Rm > 0. As before, the minimum level h = h is chosen when φ > 0 or any level within [h, h]

when φ = 0. Finally, if constraint (iv) is not met, even with a positive level of hedging, then the

firm is poorly capitalized (it has insufficient net worth) and will not be able to borrow at all.

35

Page 38: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Determination of the firm’s minimum net worth requirements in equilibrium

To find the minimum net worth requirements under different hedging strategies, suppose that

instead of using its initial assets as an exogenous variable, the entrepreneur wants to determine the

size of A necessary to maximize expected profits and meet all constraints. Net worth A can then

be treated as an additional endogenous variable that the entrepreneur finds in equilibrium. The

entrepreneur compares A with the actual initial assets, renamed A0, to determine whether the firm

is solvent without hedging or whether it must borrow form local banks and be hedged.

1. The firm borrows a mixture of domestic and foreign currency debt (1m = 1) so that constraint

(i) is binding. There are three different cases:

a. The firm is solvent in both states only if it is hedged (1H = 1 and 1L = 1). Constraints

(ii) and (iii), combined with (viii) and (ix), define the range [h, h] for optimal hedging, h,

and for any positive and small transaction cost, φ, the firm chooses h = h. This condition

is equivalent to making constraint (viii) binding and (ix) nonbinding. Therefore, the firm

hedges enough to avoid default, and it receives zero cash flow in the devaluation state.

Given that constraints (i) through (viii) hold with equality, in equilibrium, the minimum

net worth required by foreign banks is

AH(r∗, q, φ) = I − PB

r∗sL

F

C

∆p− PG

r∗sL

F + φ[R− b+ C

∆p+

∆p(1− q)(sH − sL)]

b. The firm is solvent in both states even if it is not hedged (1H = 1, 1L = 1 and h = 0). This

situation requires higher net worth A. The criterion for solvency is that the firm can at

least pay its debt even if it must forgo its own expected payment during the depreciation

state—that is, Rf (sH) = 0. A firm will be able to invest if, in return, it expects to receive

higher payments during the nondepreciation state. Therefore, constraints (iv) and (ix)

are nonbinding. In equilibrium, the minimum net worth required by foreign banks is

ASNH(r∗) = I − PB

r∗sL

F

C

∆p− PG

r∗sL

sH[R− C

∆p]

36

Page 39: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

As is evident, when h > 0, AH < ASNH , which means that creditors demand higher net

worth than in the case when firms must hedge to be solvent.

c. The firm is insolvent if it is not hedged (1H = 0, 1L = 1 and h = 0). Since the firm

is insolvent in state H, constraint (iii) is ruled out and constraint (viii) is binding so

that Rf (sH) = 0. Moreover, constraint (ix) is nonbinding so that Rf (sL) > 0. The

equilibrium solution implies a minimum net worth

ANH(r∗, q) = I − PB

r∗sL

F

C

∆p− PG

r∗(1− q)[R− b+ C

∆p(1− q)]

2. The firm borrows only in foreign currency from international banks (1m = 0). This strategy

has also three cases:

a. The firm is solvent in both states if it is hedged (1H = 1 and 1L = 1). As before,

constraints (ii) and (iii), combined with constraints (viii) and (ix), define the range

[h, h] for optimal hedging, h. For any positive and small transaction cost, φ, the firm

chooses the minimum level to avoid default so that optimal hedging is h = h. This

result implies that constraint (viii) is binding and constraint (ix) is nonbinding. The

firm hedges enough to avoid default and it receives zero cash flow in the devaluation

state. In equilibrium, the minimum net worth required by foreign banks is

AH(r∗, q, φ) = I − PG

r∗sL

F + φ[R− B

∆p+

∆p(1− q)(sH − sL)]

b. The firm is solvent in both states even if it is not hedged (1H = 1, 1L = 1 and h = 0).

Intuitively, again, this firm has high enough net worth (that is, higher than the minimum

A when it must hedge to be solvent). As in the case of 1m = 1, now constraints (iv) and

(ix) are nonbinding. The equilibrium solutions implies a minimum net worth

ASNH(r∗) = I − PG

r∗sL

sHR

Note that when h > 0, AH < ASNH , which means that banks demand higher net worth

37

Page 40: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

than in the case when firms must hedged to be solvent.

c. The firm is insolvent if it is not hedged (1H = 0, 1L = 1 and h = 0). Because

constraint (ii) is ruled out and constraint (viii) is binding, Rf (sH) = 0. Constraint

(ix) is nonbinding so that Rf (sL) > 0. The minimum net worth requirement is,

ANH(r∗, q) = I − PG

r∗(1− q)[R− B

∆p(1− q)]

In all the previous cases, it is assumed that the monitoring technology is socially

valuable.18 As a result, AH < AH and ANH < ANH .

3. The firm borrows only in domestic currency from local banks (Ru = Iu = 0). It can be

shown that the firm is indifferent between hedging and not hedging if φ = 0. Hence, it can be

concluded that in this case the firm is always solvent and does not hedge because it does not

need to. Constraints (viii) and (ix) are nonbinding, and constraint (vii) is irrelevant. Profit-

maximizing firms pay domestic banks just the least amount banks demand to participate so

that constraints (v) and (vi) are binding and the only possible nonbinding constraint is (iv).

Therefore, if constraint (i) is made binding, the minimum net worth required by local banks

is now

AB(r∗, q) = I − PB

r∗sL

F

C

∆p

Note that AB > ASNH . Furthermore, it is assumed that monitoring costs are large enough

to guarantee that some firms will borrow in domestic debt. This assumption implies that

AB < AH . 19

18Monitoring is valuable when C[PG − sLFPB ] < PG[B − b]

19Small enough monitoring costs would imply that AB > AH , in which case firms would never borrow only indomestic currency because the net worth required to do so would be high enough to allow them to borrow only inforeign currency at a lower cost.

38

Page 41: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Appendix 2: Proofs

Proof of Lemma 1

If q = 0 and φ ≥ 0, then the net worth requirements for an unhedged firm are less than or equal to

those for a hedged firm —that is, ANH ≤ AH and ANH ≤ AH . Therefore, any profit-maximizing

firm with net worth A ≥ ANH borrows in both currencies and is solvent without hedging. Similarly,

any profit-maximizing firm with net worth A ≥ ANH borrows only in foreign currency and is solvent

without hedging. Therefore, regardless of φ, not hedging is optimal for any firm borrowing in foreign

currency. �

Proof of Lemma 2

When hedging is costless (φ = 0) and q > 0, a hedging firm faces a lower net worth requirement

than does a firm that decides not to hedge—that is, AH < ANH and AH < ANH . Consider

a profit-maximizing firm with net worth A such that AH < A < ASNH . If the firm’s net

worth is AH < A < ANH , then the firm borrows in both domestic and foreign currency and

must hedge; otherwise, it will not be able to borrow at all. If the firm’s net worth is instead

ANH < A < ASNH , then the firm borrows in domestic and foreign currency. If it decides not

to hedge, then Rm = C∆p(1−q) and Ru = r∗Iu

PG(1−q) , each of which is greater than Rm = C∆p and

Ru = r∗IuPG

, respectively, if the firm decides to hedge. Therefore, the optimal decision for the firm

is to hedge because, for a given amount of debt, hedging allows lower payments to creditors and,

thus, greater profits.

Consider a firm with net worth A such that AH < A < ASNH . By a similar argument, a firm

with net worth AH < A < ANH borrows in foreign currency only and must hedge; otherwise, it

will have to borrow in domestic currency first. A firms with net worth ANH < A < ASNH will also

hedge because, for a given amount of debt, hedging allows lower payments to foreign banks and

therefore, greater profits.�

39

Page 42: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Proof of Proposition 1

This proposition refers to monitored firms with A < AH . There are three different cases, depending

on parameters q and φ, so that each case will be separately proven.

1. When q ≥ q, (regardless of φ) ASNH ≤ AH < ANH so that the the minimum net worth in

the monitoring region is ASNH and any profit-maximizing firm within the monitoring region

is solvent in state H without hedging. Therefore, zero hedging is optimal.

2. When 0 < q < q and φ < (1− q)(sH − sL), AH < ANH and h > 0. Two possible cases arise:

2.1 If q is sufficiently high such that ANH > ASNH , then any profit-maximizing firm with

A > ASNH is solvent without hedging. A profit-maximizing firm with net worth A

such that AH < A < ASNH must hedge to be able to borrow in both currencies and

0 < φ < (1 − q)(sH − sL) guarantees that the optimal level of hedging is positive and

equal to h .

2.2 If q is sufficiently small such that both cutoff levels ANH and AH are smaller than

ASNH , then the hedging decision depends on whether AH < ANH or ANH < AH .

Define φ∗(q) = FRq−(F−sL)(R−b/∆p−c/∆p)(1−q)R−b/∆p−c/∆p−(sLb/∆p)/(sH−F ) as the cost of hedging for a given level

of q that makes AH = ANH . Then:

i. when φ < φ∗(q) < (1 − q)(sH − sL) then AH < ANH . Any profit-maximizing firm

with net worth A such that AH < A < ANH must hedge to be able to borrow in

domestic and foreign currency. This is similar to case 2.1.

ii. When φ∗(q) < φ < (1− q)(sH − sL), ANH < AH . Given parameters φ and q, there

exists a net worth A∗ with AH < A∗ < ASNH such that the profit-maximizing firm

is indifferent between hedging and not hedging so that:

∗ if ANH < A < AH , then the firm does not hedge because it is solvent without

hedging;

∗ if AH < A < A∗, then not hedging is preferred over hedging.

∗ if A∗ < A < ASNH , then hedging is preferred over not hedging.

40

Page 43: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

As is evident, not all firms with A > AH prefer to hedge; only those with A > A∗ will

do so. Therefore, only some firms with net worth A such that ANH < A < ASNH

will be hedged.

3. When φ ≥ (1− q)(sH − sL), optimal hedging is zero because, regardless of q, both ASNH and

ANH are lower than AH ; therefore, a profit-maximizing firm in the monitoring region can

borrow in domestic and foreign currency and be solvent without hedging. Depending on q,

the minimum net worth defining the lower limit of the monitoring region is ANH or ASNH .

Proof of Proposition 2

The results follow directly from the minimum net worth requirements that define the monitoring

region, AH and AH or ANH and ANH , depending on the size of the hedging costs. First, higher

q increases the cutoff net worth defining the lower limit of the monitoring region so that poorly

capitalized firms lose their funding, which implies that aggregate investment drops. Second, higher

q also increases the upper limit of the monitoring region so that some firms borrowing only in foreign

currency from international banks during the fixed exchange rate regime lie within the monitoring

region after q increases. As a result, fewer firms are able to borrow directly from foreign banks,

and those moving to the monitoring region demand more domestic debt from local banks. Finally,

firms that borrowed in both currencies during the fixed exchange rate regime and hedge after q

increases, remain in the monitoring region, borrow less in domestic currency, and more in foreign

currency. �

41

Page 44: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Table 1: Currency composition of debt for Brazilian firms and the extent of their hedging operations,by size of firm, 1997-2001 (in means)

Exchange rate regimeFixed Floating Average

Item 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Fixed FloatingForeign debt/Total debt 43.2 43.4 43.4 43.3 44.0 43.3 43.6

Small 32.2 23.3 24.2 24.6 18.7 27.7 22.5Medium 40.7 42.2 44.9 44.7 47.3 41.5 45.6Large 58.5 64.7 61.5 61.9 65.5 61.6 63.0

Currency derivatives/Foreign debt 4.9 4.5 3.3 6.0 24.5 4.7 11.3Small 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.0 0.0 1.0Medium 5.5 4.8 3.5 4.9 18.2 5.2 8.8Large 6.3 6.3 4.9 12.1 49.7 6.3 22.2

Note: Total debt is the sum of foreign and domestic debt, and both are measured in local currency.

Currency derivatives correspond to the notional value of forwards, futures, swaps and options.

The sample of firms is divided into quartiles according to total assets. Small firms constitute the

first quartile, medium firms the second and third quartiles, and large firms the fourth quartile.

Source: Financial annual reports and footnotes to financial statements of companies publicly traded

on the Sao Paulo Stock Exchange.

42

Page 45: Exchange Rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and …...Exchange rates, Optimal Debt Composition, and Hedging in Small Open Economies Jose Berrospide January 2008 Abstract This paper develops

Table 2: Number of Brazilian firms, by type of financial debt, and number of firms that hedgedwith currency derivatives, 1997-2001

Exchange rate regimeFixed Floating

Item 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001Total number of firms 145 145 145 145 145

Firms with no financial debt 0 5 8 8 6

Firms with only domestic debt 29 27 30 31 32

Firms with foreign and domestic debt 114 112 105 102 104Firms hedged using currency derivatives 6 16 14 19 40Firms not hedged 108 96 91 83 64

Firms with only foreign debt 2 1 2 4 3Firms hedged using currency derivatives 1 0 0 1 0Firms not hedged 1 1 2 3 3

Note: Firms with no financial debt are those that dropped out of the sample after 1997.

Source: Financial annual reports and footnotes to financial statements of companies

publicly traded on the Sao Paulo Stock Exchange.

43