final one nos

Upload: vinayakgunda

Post on 13-Apr-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    1/37

    1

    1. AGRICULTURE IN THE WTO

    Agriculture has traditionally benefited from special arrangements which

    sheltered it from the full impact of GATT disciplines. Even today, in theWTO agricultural policies are covered by a separate agreement that, to a

    degree, still shelters it from generally applicable rules.

    A variety of political, social, economic and cultural arguments are used to

    ustify this special treatment. The main ustification is the need to guarantee,

    over time, stable food supplies in a world of fluctuating harvests and

    potential famines.

    The scope of the traditional agricultural !e"ception# was to some e"tent

    limited by the $ruguay %ound agreements& WTO 'embers agreed upon aset of principles and disciplines that were designed to help liberali(e

    international trade in agricultural products.

    The $ruguay %ound achieved two things in relation to agriculture. )t

    introduced specific disciplines on mar*et access, domestic support and

    e"port subsidies. At the same time it too* away the !fig leaf# behind which

    agriculture had been hiding from the full force of general GATT disciplines.

    The Agreement on Agriculture see*s to reduce restrictions on trade in

    agricultural products by introducing disciplines to+

    increase mar*et access&

    reduce domestic support measures&

    reduce subsidi(ed e"ports.

    This 'odule e"amines each of the three disciplines in turn and the other

    provisions of theAgreement on Agriculture.

    Other WTO agreements also discipline trade in agricultural products. Those

    with the biggest impact on trade in agricultural products are+ the GATT

    1-& the Agreement on Safeguards or the Safeguards Agreement& theAgreement on Import Licensing Procedures or the Import Licensing

    Agreement& the Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and

    Phytosanitary Measures or the SPS Agreement& the Agreement on

    Technical Barriers to Trade or the TBT Agreement and, theAgreement on

    Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights or the TRIPs

    Agreement.

    These agreements, along with the Agreement on Subsidies and

    Counterailing Measures or the SCM Agreement and the Agreement on

    Implementation of Article !I of the "ATT #$$% or the AntidumpingAgreement are also briefly e"amined.

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    2/37

    2. THE AGREEMENT ON AGRICULTURE

    Objectives On completion of this section, the reader should be able to describe

    the main disciplines that were introduced by the Agreement on

    Agriculture on trade in agricultural products and, in particular, the

    provisions of the Agreement on Agriculture on market access,

    domestic support and export subsidies.

    2.1 Introduction

    TheAgreement on Agriculture is one of the *ey agreements within the WTO

    system. )ts importance is reflected by its presence as the first Agreement

    anne"ed to the 'arra*esh Agreement establishing the WTO.

    The Agreement on Agriculture is fairly short, with only 1 Articles and /

    Anne"es. The 1 Articles are rather surprisingly divided into 10 hapters.

    This form of the Agreement on Agricultureprobably reflects the sensitivity

    of the sector and the difficulty in achieving agreement among WTO

    'embers.

    The specific agricultural commitments made by WTO 'embers are not

    found in the Agreement on Agriculture, but in Article )) !ountry

    2chedules# of the GATT 1-. 3oth the Agreement on Agriculture and the

    ountry 2chedules must be e"amined together to understand a WTO'ember4s commitments on agriculture.

    TheAgreement on Agriculture applies to agricultural products. Agricultural

    products are defined in Anne" 1 of the Agreement on Agriculture. This

    definition ma*es reference to the 5armoni(ed 2ystem of product

    classification. )n practice, agricultural products are those within hapters 1

    to - of the 5armoni(ed 2ystem less fish and fish products, as well as some

    specific products which come from the soil. 6orestry products are not

    included.

    The definition of agricultural product covers not only basic agricultural

    products such as wheat, mil* and live animals, but the products derived from

    them such as bread, butter, oil and meat, as well as all processed agricultural

    products such as chocolate, yoghurt and sausages. The coverage also

    includes wines, spirits and tobacco products, fibres such as cotton, wool and

    sil*, and raw animal s*ins destined for leather production.

    The Agreement on Agriculture has three main parts+ 7art ))) on mar*et

    access& 7art )8 on domestic support 9subsidies: and 7art 8 on e"port

    subsidies. Each of these parts are e"amined in turn.

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    3/37

    0

    2.2 Market Access

    2.2.1 Introduction

    'ar*et access simply means the right which e"porters have to access a

    foreign mar*et. The WTO agreements allow WTO 'embers to protect theirmar*ets. )n practice !mar*et access# refers to the ways in which that

    protection can be implemented. )n the WTO framewor* it is a legalistic

    term indicating the government;imposed conditions under which a product

    may enter a country and be released for free circulation within that country

    under normal conditions.

    The specific border measures to protect mar*ets allowed under the

    Agreement on Agriculture are tariffs and tariff rate &uotas. A tariff is a

    duty or ta". Although there are several different forms of tariffs, the maor

    ones used in agriculture are ad alorem 9calculated as a percentage of thevalue of the goods:, specific 9a unit ta" based on

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    4/37

    -

    The process of tariffication is not straightforward. Economists argue as to

    the appropriate methodology. )n theory it is simple. The tariff e

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    5/37

    /

    A Country Schedule is a list of specific commitments to proide mar(et

    access and national treatment for the products on the terms and conditions

    specified in the schedule.

    'any e"porting developing countries, which did not, or were not able to

    underta*e detailed e"aminations of the drafts, found themselves faced with

    prohibitively high tariffs on the products which they intended to e"port.

    3ecause of the use of a reference period when the difference between the

    world mar*et price and the domestic price was wide, tariffication, in many

    cases, resulted in high tariffs anyway. )n addition, some WTO 'embers set

    lower tariffs on raw materials and higher tariffs on processed agricultural

    products so as to protect domestic processing industries. These three !side

    effects# of tariffication are *nown as !dirty tariffication#, !tariff pea(s# and

    !tariff escalation#.

    5owever, most of the principal agricultural e"porting 'embers considered

    that, even if the process of tariffication resulted in high tariffs, the benefits

    of fi"ing tariffs and removing variable levies outweighed the disadvantages.

    Dirty tariffication is the use, during the tariffication process, of

    artificially- high domestic prices and artificially-lo+ +orld mar(et prices in

    order to set a particular tariff at a leel higher than it should be

    Tariff peaks are considered to be rates set higher than the rates acrossthe same product group or product sector /or some products, +hich

    goernments consider 0sensitie1, tariff rates remain ery high.

    If a country +ants to protect its processing or manufacturing industry, it can

    set lo+ tariffs on the imported ra+ materials used by the industry )cutting

    the industry2s costs* and set higher tariffs on finished products to protect the

    goods produced by its domestic processing industry This is (no+n as tariff

    escalation

    The tariffs agreed at the end of the negotiations were then included in eachWTO 'ember4s ountry 2chedule. The legal status of a WTO 'ember4s

    2chedule of oncessions was addressed by the Appellate 3ody in the 3C 4

    Computer 3&uipment case, where it was held that+

    )5* a Schedule is )5* an integral part of the "ATT #$$% )5* Therefore, the

    concessions proided for in that Schedule are part of the terms of the treaty

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    6/37

    >

    As such, the only rules +hich may be applied in interpreting the meaning of

    a concession are the general rules of treaty interpretation set out in the

    !ienna Conention6

    )n the Canada 4 7airy dispute, the Appellate 3ody also recogni(edthat+

    )5* although Canada2s commitment on fluid mil( +as made

    unilaterally, both Canada and the 8nited States understood that this

    commitment represented a continuation by Canada of current access

    opportunities )5*9

    The Appellate 3ody in the :orea 4 7airy case insisted on the fact that the

    WTO agreements are !one treaty# and therefore all provisions 9including theountry 2chedules: ought to be interpreted harmoniously and in an effective

    manner, in order to ensure that no clause or provision is reduced to

    !inutility#.

    The 7anel %eport in the :orea 4 !arious Measures on Beef dispute

    proceeded to a determination of the obligations of the %epublic of @orea

    under !the WTO Agreement as a whole# with regard to each measure and

    concluded+

    :orea2s Schedule does not constitute an e'ception to other "ATTproisions, but rather &ualifies :orea2s obligations under the ;Tanuary #$$.#=

    The 7anel and the Appellate 3ody in the Chile 4 Price Band System dispute

    did not thin* that the provisions of Article -. of the Agreement on

    Agriculture should be read to include only those specific measures that were

    singled out to be converted into ordinary customs duties by negotiating

    partners in the course of the $ruguay %ound. )n particular, the Appellate

    3ody stated that+

    The +ording of footnote # to the Agreement on Agriculture confirms our

    interpretation The footnote imparts meaning to Article %= by enumerating

    e'amples of 0measures of the (ind +hich hae been re&uired to be

    conerted1, and +hich Members must not maintain, reert to, or resort to,

    from the date

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    8/37

    B

    of the entry into force of the ;T< Agreement Specifically, and as both

    participants agree, the use of the +ord 0include1 in the footnote indicates

    that the list of measures is illustratie, not e'haustie And, clearly, the

    e'istence of footnote # suggests that there +ill be 0measures of the (ind

    +hich hae been re&uired to be conerted1 that +ere not specificallyidentified during the 8ruguay Round negotiations Thus, in our ie+, the

    illustratie nature of this list lends support to our interpretation that the

    measures coered by Article %= are not limited only to those that +ere

    actually conerted, or +ere re&uested to be conerted, into ordinary customs

    duties during the 8ruguay Round#?

    6urthermore, the Appellate 3ody in the Chile 4 Price Band System dispute

    noted that+

    )5* Article %= not only prohibits 0similar border measures1 from beingapplied to some products, or to some shipments of some products +ith lo+

    transaction alues, or the imposition of duties on some products in an

    amount beyond the leel of a bound tariff rate Article %= prohibits the

    application of such 0similar border measures1 to all products in all cases#%

    Therefore, the most important commitment underta*en by WTO 'embers in

    the mar*et access area during the $ruguay %ound was the comprehensive

    tariffication of all border measures.

    The non;tariff border measures which were re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    9/37

    Variable import levies are comple' systems of import surcharge They are

    aimed at ensuring that the price of a product in the domestic mar(et remains

    unchanged regardless of price fluctuations in e'porting countries

    Discretionary import licensing is the re&uirement to obtain a permit to

    import a product This normally inoles an administratie procedure

    re&uiring the submission of an application or other documentation to the

    releant administratie body as a condition for importing

    Through voluntary eport restraints! a country agrees to limit its e'ports to

    another country to an agreed ma'imum +ithin a certain period

    Agricultural state trading enterprises are enterprises +hich hae been

    granted e'clusie or special rights, or priileges that are not aailable tocommercial firms, thus distorting trade in a competitie mar(et

    The prohibition of border protection measures other than tariffs is absolute.

    All border measures other than !normal customs duties# are no longer

    permitted.

    )n the Chile 4 Price Band System dispute, hile had argued that the

    obligations in Article -. only relate to non-tariffbarriers, whereas !the 732

    only covers the payment of customs duties#.

    The 7anel and the Appellate 3ody reected this position. The Appellate

    3ody found that+

    Thus, the obligation in Article %= not to 0maintain, resort to, or reert to

    any measures of the (ind +hich hae been re&uired to be conerted into

    ordinary customs duties1 applies from the date of the entry into force of the

    ;T< Agreement - regardless of +hether or not a Member conerted any

    such measures into ordinary customs duties before the conclusion of the

    8ruguay Round The mere fact that no trading partner of a Member singled

    out a specific 0measure of the (ind1 by the end of the 8ruguay Round by

    re&uesting that it be conerted into ordinary customs duties, does not mean

    that such a measure en@oys immunity from challenge in ;T< dispute

    settlement The obligation 0not to maintain1 such measures

    underscores that Members must not continue to apply measures coered by

    Article %= from the date of entry into force of the ;T< Agreement

    )5* Chile2s price band system is a measure 0similar1 to 0ariable import

    leies1 or 0minimum import prices1 +ithin the meaning of Article %= and

    footnote # of the Agreement on Agriculture In other +ords, the fact that the

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    10/37

    1?

    duties that result from the application of Chile2s price band system ta(e the

    same form as 0ordinary customs duties1 does not imply that the underlying

    measure is consistent +ith Article %= of the Agreement on Agriculture #$

    5owever, Article -. of the Agreement on Agriculture does not prevent the

    use of non;tariff import restrictions consistent with the provisions of the

    GATT

    1- or other WTO agreements which are applicable to general trade in

    goods 9industrial or agricultural:. 2uch trade;restrictive measures include

    those maintained under the balance;of;payment provisions 9Article C)C of

    the GATT1-:, general e"ceptions 9Article CC of the GATT 1-:, the SPS

    Agreement,

    the TBT Agreement, or other general, non;specific WTO

    provisions.

    Anne" / to the Agreement on Agriculture provides a maor e"ception with

    respect to the general tariffication re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    11/37

    11

    2.2.5 Tariff Reductions

    WTO 'embers agreed in the $ruguay %ound that once the tariffs were

    fi"ed, they would agree to reduce these tariffs over time, i.e., over si" to ten

    years starting on the date of the coming into effect of the 'arra*eshAgreement in1/. The tariff reductions were fi"ed at the time of the conclusion of the

    $ruguay %ound and are also set out in each WTO 'ember4s ountry2chedule.

    Developed country 'embers agreed to reduce, over a si";year

    period beginning in 1/, their tariffs on agricultural products

    by

    0> per cent on average, with a minimum cut of 1/ per cent for

    any product.

    6or developing countries, the cuts are - and 1? per cent

    respectively, to be implemented over ten years.

    east;developed country 'embers were re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    12/37

    1

    A tariff"rate quota )TR* is a t+o-leelled tariff +hereby the tariff rate

    charged depends on the olume of imports A lo+er )in-&uota* tariff is

    charged on imports +ithin the &uota olume A higher )oer-&uota* tariff is

    charged on imports in e'cess of the &uota olume

    The value of a

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    13/37

    10

    ?9 ;T< Members currently hae a combined total of #?6$ tariff-rate

    &uotas in their commitments

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    14/37

    1-

    the price of the imports of that product, as determined on the

    basis of the c.i.f. import price of the shipment concerned falls

    below a trigger price e;1BB reference

    price for the product concerned.

    There are therefore two alternative grounds for invo*ing the special

    safeguard provision+ surges in the volume of imports and falling import

    prices. 5owever, not every rise in the volume or every fall in the price of

    imports entitles countries to resort to Article /. )n each case, there are set

    threshold levels, which are called !volume triggers# or !price triggers#.

    Article /.B of the Agreement on Agriculture providesthat+

    ;here measures are ta(en in conformity +ith paragraphs # through 6aboe, Members underta(e not to hae recourse, in respect of such

    measures, to the proisions of paragraphs #)a* and ? of Article EIE of the

    "ATT #$$% or paragraph = of Article 9 of the Agreement on Safeguards

    Thus, a WTO 'ember may choose between the special safeguard measures

    under Article / of the Agreement on Agriculture or the general safeguards

    under the GATT 1- Article C)C in accordance with the implementation

    re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    15/37

    1/

    ?9 ;T< Members currently hae resered the right to use a combined

    total of D,F6= special safeguards on agricultural products

    2.2.8.1 $mport %rice Trigger

    The price safeguard provisions are set out in Articles /.1 9b: and /./ of the

    Agriculture Agreement Article /.19b: provides specific conditions for

    special safeguard provisions related to price in addition to the two general

    conditions of Article /.1. )f the mar*et entry price 9e"pressed in terms of

    domestic currency: falls below a trigger price, the provisions of Article /./

    come into play and an additional duty may be applicable to the shipment in

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    16/37

    1>

    2.2.8.2 $mport Volume Trigger

    As with price safeguards, volume special safeguards have their legal basis in

    Article / of the Agreement on Agriculture. Article /.19a: provides that a

    special additional duty may be imposed if the annual volume of imports ofthe product e"ceeds a trigger level. Article /.- provides that the !volume

    trigger level# is to be calculated on the basis of imports as a percentage of

    domestic consumption 9last three years of available data:, a figure referred

    to as !mar*et access opportunities#. This figure gives a base trigger level.

    )n broad terms, the higher the share of imports in domestic production, the

    lower the trigger level. 6or e"ample, where the shares of imports is less than

    1? per cent of domestic consumption for the three preceding years, the base

    trigger amount is set at 1/ per cent. )n contrast, where the shares are greater

    than 0? per cent, the base trigger level is 1?/ per cent.

    2.2.9 Dispute Settlement

    In the dispute E = 7oultry );TH7SD$*=6 Brail complained about the

    allocation of an 3C tariff-rate &uota for froen poultry meat and the use by

    the 3C of a special safeguard measure under the Agreement on

    Agriculture The dispute inoled the interpretation of the 3C2s tariff

    schedule and its relationship +ith a separate bilateral agreement bet+een

    the 3C and Brail, +hich proided for a global annual duty-free tariff-rate

    &uota for froen poultry meat Brail argued that as a result of the

    agreement, the tariff-rate &uota should be allocated e'clusiely to Brail andnot shared on an M/J basis +ith other ;T< Members The ;T< Panel

    found, and the Appellate Body upheld, the Panel2s finding that the

    agreement +as not part of ;T< la+ and therefore could not be applied

    directly as la+ in ;T< dispute resolution /urther, the Appellate Body

    interpreted the releant 3C Tariff Schedule As the 3C +as bound by its

    tariff schedule +hich proided for M/J non- discriminatory treatment,

    Brail could not see( preferential treatment on the basis of tariff

    concessions negotiated bilaterally The Appellate Body also found that the

    3C2s administration of this tariff &uota did not iolate the ;T;BB average levels, and

    reducing it by ? per cent over si" years up to ??? for developed country

    'embers or by 10 per cent over 1? years up to ??- for developing country'embers.

    Domestic support reduction concerns total agriculture spending and not

    commodity;by;commodity reductions. )n other words, WTO 'embers have

    not underta*en to reduce the support granted to each product or product

    category by ? per cent. Thus, under the Agreement on Agriculture, WTO

    'embers which save on subsidies in one agricultural sector can increase

    domestic subsidies in another sector so long as the total subsidi(ation does

    not e"ceed the overall ceiling on subsidisation to which a WTO 'ember has

    committed itself in the country schedule.

    The ma"imum levels of domestic support are bound in the WTO, and 0?

    WTO 'embers have made commitments to reduce their trade;distorting

    domestic supports in the !Amber 3o"#.

    )n the case of WTO 'embers with no scheduled reduction commitments,

    the level of domestic support not covered by one or another of the

    e"ception categories must not e"ceed the specified de minimis levels 9/ per

    cent of the value of production for developed countries and 1? per cent of

    the value of production for developing countries:.

    east developed countries are not re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    20/37

    ?

    producers of that product, or non-product-specific support proided in

    faour of agricultural producers in general

    Even though the reduction commitments are applicable generally over allagricultural commodities, the calculation of A'2 is made on the basis of the

    spending on specific commodities during a reference period. The two basic

    criteria for valuing support are its effect on prices and its cost to the

    government. 3oth budgetary outlays 9i.e., the money spent by governments

    to support a product: and revenue foregone by governments or their agents,

    whether at national or sub;national level, are included in the A'2

    calculation.

    Anne" 0 of the Agreement on Agriculture provides that three types of

    support are to be included in the calculation+

    mar*et price support measures, the most important type of non

    e"empt measures can be provided either through administered

    prices 9involving transfers from consumers: or through certain

    types of direct payments from governments, and is calculated

    on the basis of the gap between a fi"ed e"ternal reference price

    and the applied domestic administered price multiplied by the

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    21/37

    1

    Total Aggregate 'easurement of Support is the sum of all domestic

    support proided in faour of agricultural producers, calculated as the sum

    of all AMS and e&uialent measurement of support )3MS* for agricultural

    products

    7art )8 of the 2chedules of ommitments specifies each WTO 'ember4s

    Annual 3ound ommitments, which are constituted by a 3ase Total A'2

    9support provided during the base period 1B>;BB:, a urrent Total A'2

    9commitments during any year of the implementation period: and its 6inal

    3ound ommitments, which is the continuation of the urrent Total A'2 in

    all years after the end of the implementation period.

    )n any year of the implementation period, the urrent Total A'2 value of

    non;e"empt measures must not e"ceed the scheduled Total A'2 limit as

    specified in each WTO 'ember4s 2chedule for that year. )n other words,domestic support e"ceeding the reduction commitments levels is prohibited.

    3.2.1. (quivalent 'easurement of Support

    %ules for calculating the !3&uialent Measurement of Support# 9E'2: are

    set out in Anne" - of the Agreement on Agriculture. These rules are used

    when it is not practicable to calculate a product;specific A'2 by using the

    methodology set out in Anne" 0.

    (quivalent measurement of support is a fall-bac( concept employed +hen

    AMS cannot be used It is defined as the annual leel of support, e'pressed

    in monetary terms, proided to producers of a specific agricultural product

    through the application of one or more support measures, +hich cannot be

    calculated in accordance to the AMS methodology

    6or e"ample, this can be the case for mar*et price support measures which

    cannot be calculated by applying the A'2 method, because no e"ternal

    reference price can be determined. )n that case, an e and in Anne" of the Agreement on

    Agriculture. E"empted measures are e"cluded from the A'2 calculation.

    WTO 'embers must claim and ustify the benefit of the e"emption. )n the

    absence of such a claim, all domestic support programmes are automatically

    considered as !Amber 3o"# measures and counted in the calculation of the

    WTO 'ember4s total A'2. )n other words, whatever support is notspecifically e"cluded from reduction commitments is presumed to be

    included

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    22/37

    Any measure not shown to satisfy the conditions for e"emption underAnne"

    or Article > of theAgreement on Agriculture is re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    23/37

    0

    Domestic food aid programmes

    A second type of aid is made up of domestic food aid programmes for

    people in need, provided that products are brought from producers !at

    mar*et prices#. Aid for public storage of agricultural products for foodsecurity purposes is classified in the same group.

    Direct payments

    A third category of !Green 3o"# aid is represented by direct payments. The

    Agreement on Agriculturepermits an unlimited number of different forms of

    direct payments made to agricultural producers to be e"empted from

    reduction commitments. A first series of direct payments consists of aid for

    developing agricultural structures+ retirement programmes, granted on

    conditions that the land is no longer in use within three years following the

    granting of aid& aid encouraging producers to cease their activitiespermanently or to change over to non;agricultural activities, provided that

    the producers totally and permanently retire from production& or

    investment aid for producers undergoing !obectively demonstrated

    structural disadvantages#.

    De;coupled income support measures 9i.e., measures which are not related to

    current levels of production or prices: are also classified in the !Green 3o"#.

    )n order to benefit from this possibility, the amounts paid shall not be related

    to the

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    24/37

    -

    %elief from natural disasters

    7ayments for relief from natural disasters are also included in the !Green

    3o"#. These payments are allowed only if producers show a production

    loss that e"ceeds 0? per cent of the average of production and willcompensate for not more than the total cost of replacing production loss.

    Article .1 of the Agreement on Agriculture provides that WTO 'embers

    are under an obligation to ensure that all !Green 3o"# measures are

    maintained in conformity with the conditions set out under Anne" . Any

    measure not shown to satisfy the conditions for e"emption is re./ of the

    Agreement on Agriculture. )t covers any support measure that would

    normally be in the !Amber 3o"#, but which is placed in the !3lue 3o"# if

    the support also re./ of the Agreement on Agriculture e"empts from

    reduction commitments certain direct payments to farmers which are tied to

    production; limiting programmes.

    The following criteria must be

    fulfilled+

    payments are directly paid out from the government budget to

    the producers&

    payments are conditional upon some form of production;

    limiting re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    25/37

    /

    rural development, which are an integral part of the development

    programmes of developing countries.

    Developmental measures are+

    investment subsidies which are generally available to

    agriculture in developing countries&

    agricultural input subsidies generally available to low;income

    or resource;poor producers&

    domestic support to producers to encourage diversification

    from growing illicit narcotic crops.

    3.2.2. De 'inimis Support

    WTO 'embers are not obliged to include de minimis support in their urrentTotal A'2.

    7e minimis support is defined as+

    product;specific domestic support not e"ceeding / per cent of

    the WTO 'ember4s total value of production of the

    agricultural product in

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    26/37

    >

    !"MAR#E T A CC ES S BA RRIE RSAgricultural protection and subsidies account for about two;

    thirds of the trade distortion caused by government policies.

    And most of the distor; tion traceable to agricultural policies

    is generated by import barriers. 6or

    that reason, negotiating wider mar*et access in agriculture iscritical

    to the success of the Doha %ound.1

    The World Trade Organi(ation 9WTO: Agriculture 6ramewor*Agreement of

    Huly ??- calls for significant tariff cuts using a tiered formula thatimposes larger percentage cuts in higher tariffs. 92ee table 1 for a

    summary of all of the provisions.: This proposed approach is a vast

    improvement over the average;cut formula applied in the $ruguay

    %ound Agreement on Agriculture, which allows countries to meet

    their commitments through large proportional reductions in tariffs

    that were already low and small reductions in high tariffs.The new formula still will re

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    27/37

    Table 1. Summary of the market access provisions of theWTO Framework Areement on Ariculture

    Tariff cuts I2ubstantial improvement in mar*et access throughtariff reductions from bound rates.I2ingle approach for all countries+ tiered formula to

    ensureprogressivity. Types of commitments

    within bands and number of bands to beTariff rate

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    28/37

    B

    ooperation and Development 9OED: is protected by T%s.

    2tudies show that preferences to developing countries barely begin

    to compensate for these high levels of protection 93renton and

    )*e(u*i ??/:.Widespread use of specific tariffs in developed countries

    9whic h ma*e up two;thirds of their agricultural tariffs: obscure

    actual levels of protection, because specific duties are generally

    higher than the simpler and more transparent ad alorem tariffs that

    are generally used in developing countries 9figure :. The use of

    specific tariffs causes a bias against developing countries

    because it results in higher tariffs on lower;priced imports. Evenmore important are the cyclical implications of such tariff

    structures+ as world price go down, specific tariffs go up when

    e"pressed in percentage terms. While conversion of specific tariffs

    into ad alorem form would be desirable in principle, it would

    raise many of the dangers that emerged in the conversion of

    nontariff barriers into tariffs during the $ruguay %ound. To avoid

    another round of !dirty tariffication# through large, covert increases

    in protection, it will be important during the conversion of specific

    tariffs to include in the modalities governing the negotiations a

    provision to ensure that a transparent approach is followed9similar to paragraph of the 5arbinson Draft:.

    "igure 1. #eveloping country exports have surged in

    nontraditional products with low protection

    Comosition o$ de%e&oin' countries e(orts) ercent

    *+

    ,+ -./-

    !+-..-

    0+ 1++-

    1+

    -+

    +

    Troic a&

    2 roduc tsTem erat e

    2 roduc ts

    S ea$ood) 3ruit s

    ) 4 e'et a5&e s

    and 3&o6ers

    Ot7er

    2 roc es sed

    2 roduc ts

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    29/37

    Fiure 2. Specific !uties hi!e hih protection

    2ercent

    8+

    *+

    ,+A%era'e Ad 4a&orem

    Tari$$ E9ui%a&ent

    !+

    0+ A%era'e Ad 4a&orem

    Tari$$

    1+

    -+

    +

    A us tra&ia US E U :ordan

    SourceK World 3an* ??0.

    Tariffs are typically higher for processed raw materials

    9figure 0:. 3y discouraging diversification into value;added and

    processed productsJareas in which trade is e"panding rapidlyJ

    such escalation punishes investors in developing countries who

    see* to add value to production for e"port. )t also help s account

    for developing countries4 generally po or penetration

    of developed;country mar*ets in processed foods.

    Two other *ey features of agricultural tariffs are the large

    difference between bound and applied rates and their e"tremely

    high pea*s. The first feature, *nown as !binding overhang# 9figure-:, means that a larger reduction in bound rates must be made

    before applied rates change. 5igh pea*s result in large differences

    between average rates and ma"imum tariff rates 9called !tariff

    dispersion#: in developed countries 9table :, compared with

    developing countries, which are characteri(ed by low tariffdispersion. Developing countries have higher average agricultural

    tariffs than industrial countries, but the level of protection in

    developed countries is higher than average tariffs 9figure /:

    because of the prevalence of tariff pea*s+ ust a few tariff lines

    protect most of domestic production in high; income countries.

    One conse

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    30/37

    0:.

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    31/37

    *+

    ,+

    3ina&!+

    Intermediate

    0+

    1+ Ra6

    -+

    +;UA D Canada :aan US EU Lar'e Ot7er Lo

    6er M id d & e M idd & e

    Inco me Income Income C

    ountri es

    anada -.1 0B.? 10./

    Hapan 1?. /?.? 1?.1

    $nited 2tates . 0/?.? >./

    European $nion 1.? /?>.0 .0

    %epublic of @orea 0. 1.? 1?.

    3ra(il 10. //.? /.>

    osta %ica 1-. 1/-.? 1B.?

    'orocco >.- 0>./ ?.>

    )ndonesia B. 1?.? /.>

    'alawi 1>./ /.? B./

    Togo 1/.> ?.? >.1

    $ganda 10.> 1/.? 0.

    Sou rceK A* soy ??/ .

    Fiure 3. Tariffs escalate for final pro!ucts

    A%era'e tari$$s) ercent

    *+

    ,+

    !+

    Intermediate

    0+

    3ina&

    1+ Ra6

    -+

    +;UAD Canada :aan US EU Lar'

    e M id

    d&e

    Income

    Countries

    Ot7er

    M idd&

    e Inco

    me

    Countries

    Lo6er

    Income

    Countries

    SourceK World 3an* ??0.

    Table 2. Tarfiff "eaks an! #ariance in Selecte! $ountries %percent&

    $ountry or %roup &verage 'ariff (aximum 'ariff )tandard #eviation

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    32/37

    'ariff rate

    *uotasTariff rate

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    33/37

    %ice 0/3eef and sheepmeat 1B

    2ugar B

    Oilseeds

    7or* and poultry >

    Dairy products /

    oarse grains /

    Wheat -

    Other processed food 1

    Total 1??

    The tiered approach of the 6ramewor* Agreement ensures

    some degree of harmoni(ation of national systems of agricultural

    tariffs 9although much less than could be achieved using a 2wissformula that not only reduces higher tariffs more than lower tariffs

    but also has a common ma"imum tariff for all countries:. 3ut the

    tiered formula poses some critical design issuesJamong them the

    placement of the bands, the depth of cuts, and the presence or

    absence of a tariff cap. %ecogni(ing these issues, the G;? proposal

    of Huly B, ??/, proposes a tariff cap of 1?? percent for developed

    countries and 1/? percent for developing countries. 2cenarios

    analy(ed by the World 3an* 9Hean, aborde and 'artin ??/: show

    that only formulas that bring about very deep cuts in bound rates

    will have a substantial impact on average applied tariffs and henceon mar*et access, particularly when allowance is made for some

    degree of slippage from designations of 2ensitive and 2pecial

    7roducts. A progressive tariff reduction formula that imposed cuts

    of -/, ?, and

    / percent in bound tariffs in developed countries would reduce the

    average tariffs facing developing countries from 1/ percent to 1?

    percentJan important gain in mar*et access, but only one;third of

    the way to complete liberali(ation.

    The need to limit the number of tariff lines for 2ensitive

    7roducts is also recogni(ed in the G;? proposal. The scenario

    analysis of the World 3an* found e"traordinary sensitivity of theresults to self;selected 2ensitive and 2pecial 7roducts. 6or

    e"ample, if percent of tariff lines are e"cluded from reductions as

    2ensitive 7roducts and a further percent as 2pecial 7roducts in

    developing

    Table 3. $ommo!ity contributions to lobal welfare cost of

    foo! an! aricultural subsi!ies an! tariffs

    )hare of total welfare cost of

    protection +percent

    Source+ $npublish ed GTA7 mod el resu lt s b y @. An d erson and E. 8alen (u ela, World 3an*

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    34/37

    -1+

    -++

    Bound/+

    *+A&ied

    !+

    1+

    +

    A Uic o on k?e

    A 5 A n a a

    US A C EAN nire

    SST a

    aan ndier

    (anadaS U T

    ur @ E3 ksi t :I

    #o a'7

    -!+

    -1+

    Market rice suort-++

    /+

    A%era'e Tari$$s*+

    !+

    1+

    +

    :aan EU Nor6 a? Canada US Hun'ar ? Me(ico

    Fiure '. (oun! tariffs e)cee! applie! rates

    Bound and a&ied tari$$s on a'ricu&ture) ercent

    -1+

    -++

    Bound/+

    *+

    !+

    1+

    +

    A&ied

    Fiure *. (or!er protection an! averae tariffs for

    selecte! countries

    Border rotection and a%era'e tari$$s $or se&ected countries) ercent

    -!+

    -1+

    -++

    /+

    *+

    Market rice suort

    A%era'e Tari$$s

    !+

    1+

    +

    :aan EU Nor6 a? Canada US Hun'ar ? Me(ico Turke?

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    35/37

    - ++

    . +

    /+USA

    8+ G@1+

    *+ EU

    , +

    ! +

    0 +

    1+ G@-+

    - +

    +

    8 +

    *+USA

    , +

    EU! +

    G@1+

    0 +

    1 +

    -+G@-+

    +

    + -+ 1+ 0+ ! + ,+ * + 8+ /+ . + - + + - - + -1+ -0 + - !+

    2roosed cut

    - ++

    /+USA

    8 +

    * +

    , +

    ! +

    0 +

    1 +

    - +

    +

    G@1+

    EU

    G@-+

    + -+ 1+ 0+ !+ ,+ *+ 8+ /+ .+ -++ - -+ - 1 + -0 + -!+ - , +

    Initia& Tari$$

    Source% Marcos :ank) Institute $or Internationa& Trade Ne'otiations ) 1++,"

    Fiure +. (an!s an! $uts for ,evelopin $ountries- "roposals

    2roosed cut

    8 +

    *+USA

    , +

    ! +

    0 +

    EU

    G@1+

    1 +

    -+G@-+

    +

    + -+ 1+ 0+ ! + ,+ * + 8+ /+ . + - + + - - + -1+ -0 + - !+ - , +

    Initia& Tari$$ Source% Marcos :ank) Institute $or Internationa& Trade Ne'otiations ) 1++,"

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    36/37

    countries, the liberali(ation of applied duties is reduced by two;

    thirds overall and much more in anada, Hapan, and %epublic of

    @orea. The cut in applied tariffs falls even moreJby B? percent. A

    tariff cap would help reduce the losses to liberali(ation resulting

    from designations of 2ensitive and 2pecial 7roducts,

    particularly by bringing about substantial reductions on cereals.

    learly, if the Doha %ound is to be successful in increasing mar*et

    access, it will be important to ensure 9a: that only a small share of

    products is accorded special treatment, 9b: that substantial

    reductions in protection are made even on these products, or 9c:

    that the number of products is restricted in a more meaningful waythan by restricting the number of tariff lines.

    Another design issue related to the simple tiered formula is the

    discontinuities between bands that can result from a system of

    higher cuts for tariffs in bands with higher tariff rates. Assume, for

    e"ample, a tariff threshold of ? percent. )f there were a 1?

    percentage point difference between the rates of cut, tariffs ust

    over that threshold would end up nearly 1? percentage points below

    tariffs at the threshold. One possible solution to this problem is to

    implement a tiered formula similar to that of a progressive income

    ta", whereby higher marginal rates of reduction are made on tariffsin higher tariff bands. Another possibility is a rate of cut that

    increases with the height of the tariff.%ecent reform proposals by the $.2. 9??/:, the G;? 9??/:, the E$ 9??/:and the

    G;1? 9??/: have elaborated considerably on the 6ramewor*.

    These proposals specify tiered formulas for tariff reduction with

    ma"imum reduction rates in industrial countries of ? percent, /

    percent, >? percent and -/ percent respectively. )n developing

    countries, the cuts are smaller, and increases in cuts ta*e place from

    higher tariff levels. The relationship between the proposed cuts is

    shown in figures > and . The proposals also differ crucially inthe number of !sensitive#products allowed& the $.2. proposed1 percent of tariff lines, the E$ has proposed B percent and the G;1?

    has proposed 1? or 1/ percent. Hean, aborde and 'artin 9??/:

    show that even percent of sensitive products can almost

    eliminate the mar*et access gains resulting form a tiered formula.

  • 7/27/2019 Final One Nos

    37/37

    -olicy

    options

    )f governments wish to promote development through increased

    mar*et access, they have several options+L imit the number of tariff lines in the 2ensitive and 2pecial

    7roduct categories.%esearch shows that placing ust percent of tariff lines in thosecategoriescan eviscerate the benefits of trade liberali(ation.

    L )mpose a tariff cap at the 1?? percent level suggestedby the G;? to overcome the effects of tariff pea*s, binding overhang,and gaps between applied tariffsand the protection actually provided.

    L )mpose an overall reduction in average tariffs to ensure that the tiered approachis effective and as a further guard against the adverse effects of the 2ensitive and2pecial 7roduct categories.

    L 3uild progressivity into every tariff band to ensure reduction in

    tariff escalation and avoid discontinuities or overlap betweentariffs in the bands.L onvert all specific tariffs into ad alorem e