majorization (not only) in inequality measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8...

48
0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ, Abt. Quantitative Methoden – Universit¨ at Basel

Upload: others

Post on 24-Aug-2020

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.00.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

p

L(p)

Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement

Christian KleiberWWZ, Abt. Quantitative Methoden – Universitat Basel

Page 2: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Introduction

How can we measure

�inequality, variability, diversity, disorder (‘chaos’), . . . ?

Numerous proposals in statistics, economics, physics, biology, ecology, etc.

Many parallel developments.

C Kleiber 2 U Basel

Page 3: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Outline

• Introduction

• Majorization

• Majorization and inequality measurement

• Lorenz order

• Majorization and the Lorenz order: Applications

– mathematics– statistics– economics– political science– chemistry

C Kleiber 3 U Basel

Page 4: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization

Given two vectors

x = (x1, . . . , xn), y = (y1, . . . , yn)

of equal length n with

n∑i=1

xi =n∑i=1

yi

define majorization as

x ≥M y :⇐⇒k∑i=1

x(i:n) ≥k∑i=1

y(i:n), k = 1, . . . , n− 1.

Here x(1:n) ≥ x(2:n) ≥ · · · ≥ x(n:n) (decreasing rearrangement).

C Kleiber 4 U Basel

Page 5: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization

Examples.

(1, 1, 1, 1) ≤M (2, 1, 1, 0) ≤M (3, 1, 0, 0) ≤M (4, 0, 0, 0)

Note: ordering irrelevant, we also have

(1, 1, 1, 1) ≤M (0, 2, 1, 1) ≤M (1, 0, 0, 3) ≤M (0, 4, 0, 0)

More general example:

(x, x, . . . , x) ≤M (x1, x2, . . . , xn) ≤M (x1 + x2 + · · ·+ xn, 0, . . . , 0)

Basic properties best explained in terms of income (re)distribution.

C Kleiber 5 U Basel

Page 6: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization

Interpretation. comparison of income distributions

• identical total incomes (majorization describes distributive aspects)

• identical size of populations

Transition from x to y is result of finitely many “Robin Hood transfers”:

Majorization and transfers. The following are equivalent

• x ≥M y

• y = T1T2 · · ·Tm x , with Ti matrix representing ‘elementary transfers’,T = εI + (1− ε)P (P ‘elementary’ permutation matrix)

C Kleiber 6 U Basel

Page 7: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization

Pioneers.

• R. F. Muirhead (1903)

• M. O. Lorenz (1905)

• H. Dalton (1920)

• I. Schur (1923)

• G. H. Hardy, J. E. Littlewood and G. Polya (1929, 1934)

C Kleiber 7 U Basel

Page 8: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization

C Kleiber 8 U Basel

Page 9: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization

Some references.

PM Alberti and A Uhlmann (1981). Stochasticity and Partial Order, Verlag der Wis-senschaften.

BC Arnold (1987). Majorization and the Lorenz Order, Springer-Verlag.

GH Hardy, JE Littlewood and G Polya (1934). Inequalities, Cambridge.

AW Marshall and I Olkin (1979). Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and Its Appli-cations, Academic Press.

[2nd ed., with BC Arnold . . . has been announced since 2004.]

C Kleiber 9 U Basel

Page 10: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization and inequality measurement

Axiomatic approach to inequality measurement.

For a scalar measure of inequality I , require (at least) the following properties:

• I(x) = I(λx) for λ > 0 (homogeneity of degree 0)

• for x ≥M y must have I(x) ≥ I(y) (Schur convexity)

• I((x, x)) = I(x) (population principle)

C Kleiber 10 U Basel

Page 11: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization and inequality measurement

Inequality measures. (selective list)

• GiniG = 2 · concentration area

• coefficient of variation (squared)

CV =1n

∑i

(xix− 1)2

• Theil

T =1n

∑i

xix

logxix

• Atkinson

Aε = 1−

{1n

∑i

(xix

)1−ε}1/(1−ε)

C Kleiber 11 U Basel

Page 12: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization and inequality measurement

Schur functions.

• g Schur convex iff x ≥M y ⇒ g(x) ≥ g(y)

• g Schur concave iff x ≥M y ⇒ g(x) ≤ g(y)

Terminology very unfortunate . . . Schur monotonicity more appropriate.

HLP characterization. (HLP 1934) The following are equivalent

• x ≥M y

• y = Px , P doubly stochastic matrix

•∑i h(xi) ≥

∑i h(yi) for all (continuous) convex functions h

C Kleiber 12 U Basel

Page 13: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization and inequality measurement

Remark on terminology.

Why ‘convex’?

For f convex, composite function

g(x) :=∑i

f(xi)

is Schur convex.

Also various representations involving doubly stochastic matrices, specific convex func-tions, etc.

C Kleiber 13 U Basel

Page 14: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Majorization and inequality measurement

How to recognize Schur concave/convex functions?

Schur’s (1923) criterion:

Continuously differentiable (permutation symmetric) g is Schur convex (concave) if forall i, j

(xi − xj)(∂g(x)∂xi

− ∂g(x)∂xj

)≥ (≤) 0

C Kleiber 14 U Basel

Page 15: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

The Lorenz order

Majorization not sufficiently general for many tasks:

• identical population size?

• identical total incomes?

Suggestion of Max Otto Lorenz (1905):

For x = (x1, . . . , xn), xi ≥ 0,∑ni=1 xi > 0, define Lorenz curve via linear inter-

polation of (xi:n increasingly ordered)

L

(k

n

)=∑ki=1 xi:n∑ni=1 xi:n

, k = 0, 1, . . . , n.

Interpretation:

“poorest k/n · 100% possess∑ki=1 xi:n/

∑ni=1 xi:n of total income” etc.

C Kleiber 15 U Basel

Page 16: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

The Lorenz order

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

x = (1,3,5,11)

p

L(p)

C Kleiber 16 U Basel

Page 17: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

The Lorenz order

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

a) modern

u

L(u)

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

b) Lorenz (1905)

L(u)

u

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

c) Chatelain (1907)

u

L(u)

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

d) ROC style

u

L(u)

C Kleiber 17 U Basel

Page 18: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

The Lorenz order

Lorenz curve [general version]. (Pietra 1915, Piesch 1967, Gastwirth 1971)For non-negative X with 0 < E(X) <∞

LX(u) =1

E(X)

∫ u

0

F−1X (t) dt , u ∈ [0, 1].

Properties.

• L continuous on [0, 1], with L(0) = 0 and L(1) = 1,

• L monotonically increasing, and

• L convex.

Lorenz order. X1 more unequal (. . . or more spread out . . . or more variable) thanX2 in the Lorenz sense, if L1(u) ≤ L2(u) for all u ∈ [0, 1], i.e.

X1 ≥L X2 :⇐⇒ L1 ≤ L2.

C Kleiber 18 U Basel

Page 19: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

The Lorenz order

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Lorenz curves

x

x^2

C Kleiber 19 U Basel

Page 20: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

The Lorenz order

0 1 2 3 4

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

x

C Kleiber 20 U Basel

Page 21: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Applications

‘Random’ paper from recent issue of J. Multivariate Analysis:

Kochar and Xu (2010) show that for independent Xi ∼ Exp(λi) (exponential distri-bution):

If (1/λ1, . . . , 1/λn) ≥M (1/λ∗1, . . . , 1/λ∗n), then

n∑i=1

Xλi ≥Ln∑i=1

Xλ∗i

Note: majorization and Lorenz order.

C Kleiber 21 U Basel

Page 22: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Applications

• Mathematics, statistics, actuarial science

– eigenvalues and diagonal elements of matrices– distribution of quadratic forms– inequalities for special functions– comparing distributions of aggregate losses (= random sums)– power functions of tests in multivariate analysis– . . .

• Social sciences

– tax progression and income redistribution– Condorcet jury theorems– “fair representation” in parliaments– . . .

C Kleiber 22 U Basel

Page 23: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Applications

• Often variations on the main theme:

– majorization of transfomations (logarithms, ...)– weak majorization (super- or submajorization)– . . .

• Especially Lorenz ordering results often require background on further stochasticorders to exploit interrelations

– there are hundreds of stochastic orders instatistics, economics, reliability theory, actuarial science, . . .

– Examples includestochastic dominance (of various orders), convex order, increasing con-vex/concave order, star-shaped order, mean residual life (or mean excess) order,hazard rate order, likelihood ratio order, excess wealth order, total time on test,superadditive order, . . .

C Kleiber 23 U Basel

Page 24: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Applications

Not every analytic inequality is a consequence of the Schur conve-

xity of some function, but enough are to make familiarity with ma-

jorization/Schur convexity a nece[s]sary part of the required back-

ground of a respectable mathematical analyst.

BC Arnold (1987, p. 15)

C Kleiber 24 U Basel

Page 25: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Schur-Horn theorem

Problem. Relation between eigenvalues λi and diagonal elements aii of a symmetricmatrix A?

Note tr (A) =∑j λj hence majorization meaningful.

Schur (1923) shows

(a11, a22, . . . , ann) ≤M (λ1, λ2, . . . , λn)

This implies Hadamard’s inequality:

For any real, symmetric matrix

∏i

aii ≥∏i

λi

C Kleiber 25 U Basel

Page 26: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Schur-Horn theorem

But there is more:

Schur-Horn theorem.

Let a, b ∈ Rn with a ≤M b.

Then there exists a real, symmetric matrix A with diagonal a and eigenvalues b.

Recent abstract version: majorization of sequences implies existence of compact ope-rator with suitable eigenvalues, etc.

C Kleiber 26 U Basel

Page 27: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Taxes and incomes

Framework. Given

vector of incomes x = (x1, . . . , xn)

tax schedule t(x)

Call {1− t(x)}x after-tax income (“residual income”)

Goal. Comparison of before- and after-tax incomes wrt. inequality.

Majorization not applicable because

∑i

xi 6=∑i

{1− t(xi)}xi

Use Lorenz order instead.

Question. What does a ‘Lorenz-equalizing’ tax look like?

C Kleiber 27 U Basel

Page 28: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Taxes and incomes

Theorem. (Eichhorn, Funke, Richter, J. Mathematical Economics 1984)

x ≥L {1− t(x)}x

iff

• t(x) increasing and

• {1− t(x)}x increasing.

Interpretation: Income tax is inequality-reducing iff

• progressive and

• incentive preserving.

C Kleiber 28 U Basel

Page 29: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Framework. Jury of n experts faces binary decision

Let Xi ∈ {0, 1} decision of expert i and pi = P (Xi = 1), i = 1, . . . , n.

Call pi competence/ability of expert i. Consider number of correct decisions

S :=n∑i=1

Xi

If all experts equally competent (pi ≡ p) and independent,

P (S ≥ k) =n∑i=k

(n

i

)pi(1− p)n−i,

a binomial probability.

Decision is via majority voting.To avoid ties, set n = 2m+ 1, hence k = m+ 1.

C Kleiber 29 U Basel

Page 30: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,
Page 31: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Setting of classical CJT.

• two alternatives

• common preferences (one alternative is superior in the light of full information)

• independent decisions

• homogeneous competences

• decision rule is simple majority voting

C Kleiber 31 U Basel

Page 32: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Classical CJTs. (Boland, JRSS D / The Statistician 1989)

Non-asymptotic CJT:

Under majority voting with p > 1/2 (“experts”)

P (S ≥ m+ 1) > p

Proof: use Beta integral representation of binomial probabilities

P (S ≥ m+ 1) =1

B(m+ 1,m+ 1)

∫ p

0

tm(1− t)mdt

There is also an asymptotic CJT, but not needed here.

C Kleiber 32 U Basel

Page 33: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

prob

P(S

≥4)

n = 7 , k = 4

C Kleiber 33 U Basel

Page 34: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Extensions of basic version.

• supermajority voting (also called special majority voting)

• heterogeneous experts

• dependent experts (“opinion leaders”)

• juries of different sizes

• direct vs indirect majority voting (→ US presidential elections)

C Kleiber 34 U Basel

Page 35: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Framework. Jury J characterized by vector of probabilities (“competences”)

p = (p1, . . . , pn) ∈ [0, 1]n

Question. Given 2 juries J1 und J2 of equal size, with characteristics p1 and p2,when will J1 do better? Need conditions for

P (S1 ≥ m+ 1) ≥ P (S2 ≥ m+ 1) for pi ∈ P ⊆ [0, 1]n

• New problem: distribution of sums of independent, but not identically distributedBernoulli variables

• Goal: stochastic comparisons with e.g. binomial distribution

• Classical paper in statistical literature: Hoeffding (Ann. Math. Stat. 1956)

C Kleiber 35 U Basel

Page 36: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

In Hoeffding 1956 purely probabilistic point of view.

Sums of heterogeneous Bernoullis arise in many contexts

• CJTs

• reliability of “k out of n” systems (unequal default probabilities)

• portfolios of credit risks

• . . .

C Kleiber 36 U Basel

Page 37: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,
Page 38: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Point of reference. average competence p

Hoeffding (1956). Let k > 0 with p ≥ k/n. Then

P (S ≥ k) ≥n∑i=k

(n

i

)pi(1− p)n−i

This gives

Boland’s CJT. (Boland 1989)

Let n ≥ 3, p ≥ 1/2 + 1/(2n). Then

P (S ≥ m+ 1) > p

C Kleiber 38 U Basel

Page 39: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Visualization via Lorenz curves

L

(k

n

)=∑ki=1 xi:n∑ni=1 xi:n

, k = 0, 1, . . . , n,

where xi:n ith smallest income → consider probabilities as incomes

Example: n = 9, p = 0.8 > 1/2 + 3/18 (Boland’s condition)

[1] 1.0 1.0 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.6

[1] 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.6

C Kleiber 39 U Basel

Page 40: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Lorenz curve

p

L(p)

C Kleiber 40 U Basel

Page 41: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Generalization of Hoeffding’s inequality:

Gleser’s inequality. (Ann. Prob. 1975) Let p1 ≥M p2. Then

P (S ≤ k|p1) ≤ P (S ≤ k|p2), k ≤ bnp− 2c

This gives

CJT under heterogeneity. Let n ≥ 7 and p ≥ 1/2+5/(2n). If p1 ≥M p2 then

P (S ≥ m+ 1|p1) ≥ P (S ≥ m+ 1|p2)

Note: need large p for superiority of majority voting!

C Kleiber 41 U Basel

Page 42: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Condorcet jury theorems

Further generalization of Hoeffding’s inequality:

Boland and Proschan’s inequality. (Ann. Prob. 1983) Let p1 ≥M p2. Then

P (S ≤ k|p1) ≤ P (S ≤ k|p2), all pi ∈ [(k − 1)/(n− 1), 1]n

This gives

CJT under heterogeneity. Let pi ∈ [1/2, 1]n with p1 ≥M p2. Then

P (S ≥ m+ 1|p1) ≥ P (S ≥ m+ 1|p2)

This differs from Gleser’s inequality!

Can be generalized to supermajority voting.

C Kleiber 42 U Basel

Page 43: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Credit risks

Framework. n credit risks Xi described by sizes ai, i = 1, . . . , n, and (possiblydistinct) default probabilities pi.

Quantities of interest:

• number of defaults∑iXi, Xi ∼ Bin(1, pi)

• aggregate losses∑i aiXi, Xi ∼ Bin(1, pi)

Result on number of defaults.

If p(1) ≥M p(2) and risks independent, then

Var(∑i

Xi|p(1)) ≤ Var(∑i

Xi|p(2))

Proof: variance is Schur concave in p

Can also use Hoeffding etc bounds ... but they provide lower bounds on probabilities.

C Kleiber 43 U Basel

Page 44: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Credit risks

Result on aggregate losses.

This requires assumption on ais. Suppose ai decreasing in pi. Assume

aipi ≈ const. =: a

hence consider

∑aiXi = a

∑ 1piXi, wlog a = 1

If p(1) ≥M p(2) and risks independent, then

Var(∑i

aiXi|p(1)) ≥ Var(∑i

aiXi|p(2))

Proof: variance is Schur concave in p

C Kleiber 44 U Basel

Page 45: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Inequalities for special functions

Large literature on monotonicity properties of gamma and beta functions.

Regularized incomplete beta function

I(t) =B(p, q, t)B(p, q)

=

∫ t0sp−1(1− s)q−1ds

B(p, q)

B(p, q, t) is (lower) incomplete beta function,B(p, q) = B(p, q, 1) = Γ(p)Γ(q)/Γ(p+ q).

Note that I(t) defines a CDF – the beta distribution.

Monotonicity property. (Furman, Kleiber, Zitikis 20xx)

We have monotonicity of certain compositions,

I(p1 + c, q1, I−1(p1, q1, t)) ≤ I(p2 + c, q2, I

−1(p2, q2, t)) for all t ∈ (0, 1).

iff p2 ≥ p1 and q2 ≤ q1, c > 0.

C Kleiber 45 U Basel

Page 46: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Inequalities for special functions

Problem equivalent to characterizing Lorenz order within family of beta distributions.

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

u

L(u)

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

uL(

u)

C Kleiber 46 U Basel

Page 47: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Conclusion

• Majorization has many applications, not only in mathematics

• Lorenz order is less widely known but potentially more useful

• Lorenz curve is useful for visualizing majorization inequalities . . . and for hypothesi-zing theorems (!)

• Many majorization and Lorenz ordering results remain to be discovered!

C Kleiber 47 U Basel

Page 48: Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement · 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 p L(p) Majorization (not only) in Inequality Measurement Christian Kleiber WWZ,

Example: Chemistry

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

bubble sizes

p

L(p)

C Kleiber 48 U Basel