run, women, run! female candidates and term limits: a .../67531/metadc... · term limits are one of...

121
APPROVED: Regina Branton, Major Professor Valerie Martinez-Ebers, Committee Member Elizabeth Oldmixon, Committee Member Tony Carey, Jr., Committee Member Jae-Jae Spoon, Committee Member Matthew Eshbaugh-Soha, Chair of the Department of Political Science David Holdeman, Dean of the College of Arts and Sciences Victor Prybutok, Vice Provost of the Toulouse Graduate School RUN, WOMEN, RUN! FEMALE CANDIDATES AND TERM LIMITS: A STATE-LEVEL ANALYSIS Samantha Pettey Dissertation Prepared for the Degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY UNIVERSITY OF NORTH TEXAS August 2016

Upload: others

Post on 28-Sep-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

APPROVED: Regina Branton, Major Professor Valerie Martinez-Ebers, Committee

Member Elizabeth Oldmixon, Committee Member Tony Carey, Jr., Committee Member Jae-Jae Spoon, Committee Member Matthew Eshbaugh-Soha, Chair of the

Department of Political Science David Holdeman, Dean of the College of

Arts and Sciences Victor Prybutok, Vice Provost of the

Toulouse Graduate School

RUN, WOMEN, RUN! FEMALE CANDIDATES AND TERM LIMITS:

A STATE-LEVEL ANALYSIS

Samantha Pettey

Dissertation Prepared for the Degree of

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

UNIVERSITY OF NORTH TEXAS

August 2016

Page 2: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Pettey, Samantha. Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A

State-Level Analysis. Doctor of Philosophy (Political Science), August 2016, 114 pp., 19

tables, 8 figures, chapter bibliographies.

This dissertation seeks to explain the puzzle in the state politics literature which

expects females to benefit from the enactment of term limits, but initial research finds

the number of female in office decreases after the implementation of term limits.

Examining this puzzle involves three separate stand-alone chapters which explore female

candidate emergence (1), success rates (2), and women-friendly state legislative districts

(3). The goal of the dissertation is to reconcile the puzzle while adding insight into how

female candidates behave at the state-level. Overall, I find that term limits increases

female descriptive representation by increasing the likelihood a female candidate will run

and win an election.

Page 3: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Copyright 2016

by

Samantha Pettey

ii

Page 4: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I thank my family, especially my parents, for being the greatest pair of role models.

Also, for your unending support, faith, and love throughout my education, and life. To my

sisters Amanda and Rebecca: thank-you both for your support, and humoring my love of

politics since an early age by playing ‘political radio talk’.

I want to thank Regina Branton for her mentorship and guidance throughout my

graduate career and the dissertation process. I am also indebted to Jae-Jae Spoon, Elizabeth

Oldmixon, Valerie Martinez-Ebers, and Tony Carey Jr. for all the comments, feedback, and

thought-provoking questions, which significantly improved earlier drafts of this dissertation.

I also want to thank friends for understanding, and supporting this long journey.

And to friends here at University of North Texas: thank-you for creating a productive and

enjoyable environment. Many of you helped me along the way with prioritizing, feedback,

support, and laughs.

iii

Page 5: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS iii

LIST OF TABLES v

LIST OF FIGURES vi

CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION 1

CHAPTER 2 FEMALE CANDIDATE EMERGENCE 9

CHAPTER 3 FEMALE CANDIDATE SUCCESS 41

CHAPTER 4 WOMEN-FRIENDLY DISTRICTS 71

CHAPTER 5 CONCLUSION 110

iv

Page 6: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

LIST OF TABLES

Page

1.1 Term-Limit Bans 4

2.1 Term-Limited States 24

2.2 Descriptive Statistics for Female Emergence and Term Limits 25

2.3 Distribution of Candidates and Term Limits 26

2.4 Difference in Differences 30

2.5 Likelihood Candidate is a Female 31

2.6 Predicted Probabilities for Democrats 33

2.7 Predicted Probabilities for Democrats in Open Seats 33

2.8 Predicted Probabilities for Republicans 34

2.9 Predicted Probabilities for Republicans in Open Seats 34

3.1 Descriptive Statistics for Female Success and Term Limits 56

3.2 Descriptive Statistics for Male Success and Term Limits 56

3.3 Logistical Regression of Democratic Candidate Success 59

3.4 Predicted Probabilities for Female Democrats 60

3.5 Logistical Regression of Republican Candidate Success 63

3.6 Predicted Probabilities for Female Republicans 65

4.1 State Legislative District Descriptives 86

4.2 Logistical Regression of Female Candidate Emergence 89

4.3 Logistical Regression of Female Success 93

v

Page 7: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

LIST OF FIGURES

Page

Figure 3.1. Female Democrat Success 61

Figure 3.2. Female Republican Success 64

Figure 4.1. Core Democratic Female Emergence 90

Figure 4.2. Core Republican Female Emergence 91

Figure 4.3. Swing Democratic Female Emergence 92

Figure 4.4. Swing Republican Female Emergence 92

Figure 4.5. Core Democratic Female Success 95

Figure 4.6. Core Republican Female Success 95

vi

Page 8: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

CHAPTER 1

INTRODUCTION

Term limits are one of the most significant institutional changes to take place since

the modernization of state legislatures (Kurtz, Cain and Niemi 2007). Term limits are an

institutional change that mainly started as citizen initiatives in the states. Citizens were

unhappy with their career politicians (at the state and Congressional-level) and wanted

term limits in order to remove longtime politicians from office. Since the implementation

of term limits is fairly new, continuing to study the effect they have on state legislators is

important.

Studying the effect term limits have on female state legislators is arguably the most

important contribution this dissertation makes to the field. Studying women in office is

important since females are underrepresented in government. Despite making up an equal

portion of the population, women do not have political parity. Descriptive representation is

important since studies find women politicians bring a different viewpoint and style to the

legislative table. Further, this difference is significant because scholars find women politicians

are better at politically representing women (Swers 2002, Osborne 2012). If term limits have

an impact on descriptive representation, positive or negative, the consequences are important

to understand and study.

Below, I provide a brief discussion of the term limit movement in the U.S. Then, I

followup with an example from a state, Florida, to show how the dissertation tries to explain

the positive effect term limits seem to have on females. Lastly, I provide a roadmap for each

substantive chapter by briefly discussing the theory and findings.

1

Page 9: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Term Limits

Generally speaking there are three main arguments supporters of term limits use

to emphasize why term limits are good. The first deals with elections, the second with

politicians and the last argument relates to lobbyists and special interest groups. The first

argument claims elections will become more competitive if there are term limits. The ratio-

nale comes from the advantage incumbents receive when running for reelection. Incumbents

have name recognition and usually more money at their disposal, which helps better their

chances of winning reelection. In the official voter guide, supporters of the term limits in

California described state legislative turnover as less than The British House of Lords and

the Soviet Legislature (Ballotpedia 2016).

On the other hand, opponents of terms limits argue by limiting the term of politicians,

citizens are losing their right to choose. If a politician is successful at their job and popular

with constituents, taking this person out of the election is bad for the democratic process.

Term limits can prevent the best, or most preferable candidate from seeking office again.

The second argument relates to elections and the types of candidates in the race.

Those in favor of term limits argue career politicians are bad. Therefore, term limits can

help eliminate career politicians and bring in a different type of legislator— one who is

a citizen, not a politician (Price 1992). Supporters of term limits argued taxpayers and

consumers are ruled by a small, elite class. And what is best for democracy is a ruling class

of people, by the people (Ballotpedia 2016).

Opponents argue opening up the pool of candidates is not a good thing because term

limits incentivize the wealthy to run. Term limits incentivize the wealthy to run since being

a legislator in a term limited state is only a temporary job. Most people cannot afford to

2

Page 10: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

leave their job to work a few years, but a person who is wealthy may be able to temporarily

leave their job. Therefore, the new politicians will be wealthy and ‘out of touch’ with the

majority of their constituents.

The last argument supporters make is that special interests have too much control

over politicians. This is bad for the democratic process because the people are ignored.

Supporters argue that term limits will stop the close relationships politicians have with

lobbyists. This would force politicians to do what is best for their constituents and not what

is best by special interests.

On the other hand, opponents of term limits argue the opposite—state legislators will

become more reliant on special interests and lobbyist because the lobbyist are constant and

more familiar with the system. The argument is term limits create so much turnover that

many norms within the chamber are lost and committee chairs become less qualified. Since

legislators lack experience, they are forced to rely on lobbyists.

Consecutive versus Lifetime Bans

The limits placed on legislators varies by states and are either consecutive or lifetime

bans. The latter is much more strict on legislative terms and does not allow legislators to

serve in office after a maximum year is reached. For example, California, enacted term limits

in 1990 as a lifetime ban on legislators. In California, a legislator can only serve up to twelve

years in either chamber. The time can be split between both chambers or served all in one

but a legislator cannot serve more than twelve years.

Consecutive bans are generally less strict than lifetime bans. In general, the limit on

the legislator is for a certain number of years. Most states do this by chamber; i.e. serve

eight consecutive years in the lower chamber then the legislator is allowed to serve another

3

Page 11: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

eight in the upper chamber (or vice versa). Different from a lifetime ban, after a set time

period (usually two years) away from the legislature, the legislator can run again. If the

legislator runs again and wins, the clock is reset. Table 1.1 below lists all the states with

their ban limit in years as well as the type.

Limit in Years Consecutive Lifetime

6 House / 8 Senate – MI8 Total NE –8 House / 8 Senate AZ, CO, FL, ME, MT, OH, SD MO12 Total – CA, OK12 House / 12 Senate LA NV16 Total – AR

Source: NCSL 2014: ‘The Term-Limited States’

Table 1.1: Term-Limit Bans

Florida

The 2016 Florida State Legislature is ranked 25th amongst all 50 states in terms of

the proportion of women serving in the legislature (both chambers). Females make up 25%

of the legislature; 23% in the lower chamber.

In 1992 Florida voters overwhelming supported term limits on their state officials.

76.8% of voters were in favor of a ballot initiative making a constitutional amendment to

impose term limits. A statewide campaign from term limits supporters used the slogan

“Throw the Rascals Out” and “Eight is Enough”. The Florida Constitution now states that

legislators (and cabinet members) are limited to a term of eight years in a given chamber.

The limits in Florida are consecutive and therefore once a legislator is term out of one

chamber they can run for election in the other chamber and serve another eight years.

Sen. Rene Garcia (R) recently said, “We are a representative democracy and we

should be making sure that it is the elected officials who move agendas forward, and not the

4

Page 12: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

lobbyists,” (Miami Herald, 2015). A concern by the legislators in Florida is the amount of

power unelected persons have on the political process. In particular, opponents such as Sen.

Garcia argue special interests donate to campaigns and have more control over the agenda

and policy-making in the legislature.

Further, opponents argue there are vast issues and changes that have taken place,

not for the better, on the daily operations and functioning of the chambers.

SJ 0902 and HJR 711: Term Limits, were jointly filed on 11/18/2015 in the Florida

Senate and House, respectively. The bills seek to amend the state constitution and increase

the number of years a legislator can serve from eight to twelve years. Thus far there has been

no floor action on either of the bills. Yet, this is not the first time legislators have tried to

extend terms from eight to twelve years. In 2005, both chambers overwhelming supported,

and passed, a legislatively referred constitutional amendment (LRCA) to appear on the

2006 ballot (Ballotpedia 2016). The ballot measure was repealed before the election when

voters began calling their representatives because they were unhappy with the possibility of

extending legislative term limits. Ultimately, the proposal never made the 2006 ballot so the

actual sentiments of voters can only be presumed (Tallahassee Democrat, 2006).

Female Descriptive Representation in Florida

The last election year before term limits took effect in Florida was 1998 and 50 females

ran for office in the lower house. In 2000, the first year of impact, 61 females ran for office.

Statewide, term limits created 83 vacancies in the 120 person house. While the number of

females emerging for office increased in the first year term limits took effect, the number

of female candidates emerging since the initial year has decreased and ranges from 44-53

females running in a given election year. Pre term limits, the number of females running

5

Page 13: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

for the office ranged from a low of 35 in 1990 to a high of 56 in 1996. The mean percent of

female candidates pre term limits is about 25% and post term limits this number increases

to 27%. The emergence chapter discusses my theory as to why there is a post term limit

increase in the number/percent of women running for office.

In terms of female descriptive representation, the number of women in the lower

chamber pre and post term limits has remained fairly stagnant. Yet, as Chapter 2 discusses,

party plays an important role. Term limits create an environment favorable to Republican

candidates. After term limits were implemented in Florida, Republican females nearly double

their numbers in office. For example, in 1990, 8 Republican women held office and this

number increases to 18 in 2000. On the other hand, female Democrats were hurt by term

limits. Pre term limits, female Democratic numbers were consistently averaging 20 a year

but post term limits, the number of women in office drops to an average of 15 a year.

Dissertation Chapter Outline

Chapter 1 explores how term limits effect the eligibility pool of candidates running

for office. The main research question is “Do term limits influence the emergence of female

state legislative candidates?” Examining the number of women running for office is important

since descriptive representation cannot happen if there is not a substantial pool of female

candidates willing to run. I argue term limits have a positive effect on the number of females

running for office since term limits change the incentive structure for running. Since term

limits place a limit on time in office, candidates, specifically women, who do not want to be

career politicians may consider running for office when term limits are present. I find, when

compared to states without term limits, females are more likely to run in states with term

limits.

6

Page 14: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Chapter 2 is complimentary to the current literature on term limits and females. I

look at the question of “Do term limits help or hinder female descriptive representation in

state legislatures?” Most studies on the effect term limits have on women post term limits are

limited in scope due to lack of time. I reexamine female descriptive representation and look at

the effect term limits have on women over multiple time periods. I argue professionalization

of the legislature matters and that term limits effect female Republican and Democrats

differently. I find term limits have a positive effect on female Republicans and a negative

effect on female Democrats. Female Republicans are more successful at winning in term

limited states while female Democrats are more successful at winning in non-term limited

states.

Chapter 3 is a combination of chapters 1 and 2. I answer the research questions,

“Do certain district demographics favor female candidates and How do term limits affect

the women-friendliness of a district?”. Building off work looking at district demographics, I

explore the set of characteristics at the state-level that make a district more women-friendly.

I find districts that are more urban, diverse, democratic, educated, wealthy, and have more

women in the workforce are more likely to be areas where females emerge and win. I also

find term limits do not have a statistically significant impact on the women-friendliness of a

district.

7

Page 15: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

[1] Ballotpedia. 2016. “Florida 2006 Ballot Measures”. Retrieved on March 6, 2016 from:https://ballotpedia.org/Florida_2006_ballot_measures.

[2] Cannon, Steve. 2015 “Florida Legislators Propose Increasing Term Limits” Retrieved on March6, 2016 from: http://www.miamiherald.com/news/politics-government/state-politics/article45621033.html#storylink=cpy.

[3] Carey, John M., Richard G. Niemi, and Lynda W. Powell.2000. Term limits in state legislatures.University of Michigan Press.

[4] Deslatte, Aaron. 2006. “Term-Limit Extension Removed from Ballot” Retrieved on March 7, 2016from: https://www.aproundtable.org/news.cfm?NEWS_ID=1269&issuecode=term.

[5] Osborn L, Tracy. 2012. How Women Represent Women: Political Parties, Gender and Representationin the State Legislatures. Oxford University Press.

[6] Price, Charles M. 1992. “The Guillotine Comes to California: Term-Limit Politics in the Golden Sate.” inLimiting Legislative Terms meds Gerald Benjamin and Michael J. Malbin. Washington, D.C.: CQ Press.

[7] Swers, Michele. 2002. The Difference Women Make. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

8

Chapter Bibliography

Page 16: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

CHAPTER 2

FEMALE CANDIDATE EMERGENCE

Abstract

This chapter examines the effect of gender differences on emergence rates in state

legislative elections as a function of term limits. Initial research finds a negative relationship

between term limits and female representation. I offer a candidate-level theory and empir-

ical approach to reevaluate how term limits impact female representation overtime. Using

candidate data in all 50 states from 1990-2000, I find that females are more likely to run for

office in states that implement term limits.

Introduction

The lack of females in office has long been the subject of normative concern for

scholars. Theories on descriptive representation claim the makeup of legislative bodies should

reflect the demographics of the public. Politicians better represent their constituents if they

resemble the populace’s gender, race, social and economic status. Scholars theorize the

importance of descriptive representation and its implications for society because females

bring different issues, experiences and viewpoints to the political table (Swers 2002; Swindt-

Bayer and Mishler 2005; Osborn 2012). For example, Schwindt-Bayer and Mishler (2005)

find legislation will be more favorable towards women with a more representative sample

of females in Congress because male politicians rarely offer the same types of legislation

as females, especially those particularly relating to women’s issues. The logic follows that,

increasing the percentage of women in politics leads to more favorable policies for women

(Swers 2002; Schwindt-Bayer and Mishler 2005; Osborn 2012).

In the United States, female descriptive representation has been, and continues to be,

9

Page 17: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

much lower than male descriptive representation at all levels of government. Currently, at

the state level, female representation ranges from a low of 12% in Louisiana to a high of 41%

in Colorado. The average percent of females in all 50 state legislatures is only 24.2% (CAWP

2014; NCSL 2014). Not only is the current percent low but the percentage of females in state

legislative branches has become rather stagnant. Since the 1990s there has not been a large

growth in the percent of females in office (Norander and Wilcox 2012). Given that a large

amount of policy-making is delegated to the states, the lack of female representation across

all states is troublesome (Carroll 2013).

Studying female candidates at the state level is important for furthering our overall

understanding of women and politics. More specifically, research providing a greater under-

standing of when and why females run for office, or emerge as candidates, is a critical stage

in the process towards understanding the unequal representation between males and females

at all levels of government.

I intend to add insight into existing institutional theories on the underrepresentation

of women in office by examining the impact of term limits on female candidate emergence

in state legislative general elections (Bernstein 1986; Ferry 1994; Carroll and Jenkins 2001).

Conventional wisdom suggests open seats will help females gain descriptive representation

since females fair as well as men in elections. Term limits provide more open seats which

suggests females have more opportunities to enter into office (Burrell 1994; Darcy, Welch and

Clark 1994; Fox 2000; Seltzer et al. 1997). Yet, studies conducted after the implementation

of term limits find the greater number of open seats actually had negative consequences for

female descriptive representation (Carroll and Jenkins 2001, Bernstein and Chada 2003).

Here, I revisit this research to try and bridge the puzzling findings resulting in a negative

10

Page 18: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

impact on overall female numbers in office. I directly test whether or not term limits have a

causal impact on women running for office using a pre-post experimental design. I find term

limits have a positive impact on the number of females running for office. States with term

limits are more likely to have females running in elections.

This paper proceeds as follows. First, I provide a discussion of the extant literature

in regards to female candidate emergence and term limits. Next, I theorize my expectations

on how term limits will impact female candidate emergence. Then, I introduce the data and

methods used to test my hypothesis and conclude with a short discussion of the findings and

implications of this study.

Previous Literature

Generally speaking, the majority of research on women and politics is conducted at

the national-level. Implications from these studies are not directly transferable to state-

level research because female descriptive representation varies across state. As previously

discussed, some states have a legislative branch with fairly equal percentages of men and

women while others are composed of a super-majority of men. There are two areas of research

I will address below; emergence and term limits. Both fields of study have progressed without

taking much consideration into how one may influence the other. Below is a brief discussion

on the current state of each literature.

Emergence

A particular thread of the women and politics literature focuses on how and why

women run for office (Fox and Lawless 2004; Fulton 2004; Carroll and Sanbonmatsu 2013).

In other words, why do some female candidates emerge and run for election while other

potential candidates do not? Before there can be parity, there have to be females who are

11

Page 19: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

willing to run for office and ultimately win their campaign. As previously discussed, female

representation at all levels of government is minimal at best and the lack of female emergence

as candidates is one explanation for the gender disparity reflected in government.

There are four main factors scholars identify that inhibit the emergence of female

candidates. One explanation points to institutional factors acting as barriers to emergence.

The second looks at socialization and sociological factors that may influence a females’ chance

at running for office. A third approach examines ambition levels of potential candidates. The

fourth approach examines political factors that impact who runs for office. Each approaches

hinges on the assumption that females face greater challenges and bear greater costs when

seeking political office.

Institutional Barriers

From an institutional perspective, the low rates of women descriptive representation

in the United States are explained by two main theories: the incumbency advantage and

eligibility pool. Incumbency advantage posits that incumbents’ high reelection rates reduce

opposition and leave little opportunity for new candidates to compete (Carroll and Jenkins

2001; Darcy, Welch, and Clark 1994; Jacobson 2000; Burrell 1992). Therefore, since males

already hold the majority of seats, coupled with the fact that winning reelection is generally

easier than winning as a challenger, males will continue to hold a majority of seats. As such,

females will enter office at a glacial pace because the incumbency advantage is so significant.

Furthermore, research finds female candidates at the congressional level to be just as likely

to win elections as men; indicating that females are not at an electoral disadvantage per se,

but the high incumbency rate continues to keep females out of office (Burrell 1994; Darcy,

Welch, and Clark 1994; Fox 2000; Seltzer et al. 1997).

12

Page 20: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

A second institutional constraint is the female candidate eligibility pool is smaller

than the male candidate pool. The eligibility pool, or where the majority of candidates

emerge from, consists mainly of positions in law and business.1 Women in Congress tend to

emerge from careers in teaching, social work, and healthcare without a background in politics

rather than the typical ‘political’ fields previously mentioned (Clark 1994; Dolan, Deckman

and Swers 2007; Carroll and Sanbonmatsu, 2013). The assumption is there are more males

in elected office because males occupy a majority of the jobs from which candidates emerge

(Fox and Lawless 2004). Gertzog (2002) notes the female eligibility pool is changing and an

increasing number of females congressional candidates have previous office-holding experience

and backgrounds in law and business. Females emerging at the national level with previous

office-holding experience generally progress from state legislatures. Therefore, an analysis of

state legislatures will further research at multiple levels of government.

Sociological Factors

Second, extant literature suggests there are sociological, cultural norms at play which

keep females from seeking office. First, women are less likely to be socialized to run for

political office (Fox and Lawless 2004). In other words, males are conditioned early on and

are encouraged more often than females to run for office. Political conditioning research also

suggests that women who are engaged in politics are more likely to emerge and run for office

at any level (Welch 1977; Fox and Lawless 2004). Furthermore, women are more likely to be

engaged in politics if issues are salient to them (Campbell and Wolbrecht 2006). Therefore,

an increase in descriptive representation may potentially lead to more women’s issues being

discussed, which will then influence more females to be actively engaged and interested in

1Men also receive more encouragement than females at a younger age to enter fields that are more likely tolead to political careers such as law and business (Fox and Lawless, 2004)

13

Page 21: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

politics which may ultimately increase the likelihood of females running for office.

Furthermore, women tend to have a disproportionate share of family responsibilities

(Fox and Lawless 2004). Not only that, women see private, family commitments as conflicting

with public commitments and this has changed little overtime (Lee 1976, Saprio 1982; Burrell

1994; Carroll and Sanbonmatsu 2013). It is important to note these cultural gender norms

that seem to place time constraints on future candidates do not seem to inhibit other areas

of female political involvement; women are just as, if not more, likely to be engaged in local,

community-level politics. Therefore, sociological based time constraint theories cannot be a

sufficient explanation to a lack of female emergence (Beckwith 1986; Bennett and Bennett

1989; Burns Schulman and Verba 2001).

Ambition

Third, research finds ambition levels differ by gender; specifically, women’s ambition

levels are inherently lower than males. The gender differences in political ambition levels

is in part due to the fact that women perceive themselves to be less qualified than men

to run for office (Fox and Lawless 2004; Fulton et al. 2006). The most extensive research

on candidate ambition is ‘The Citizen Political Ambition Study’, conducted by Fox and

Lawless (2004). The study targets males and females who are in positions that tend to lead

to political careers, i.e. potential candidates in the elligibility pool. The survey targeted

ambition levels by asking questions of qualification, desire to run for office, etc. One of the

conclusions of the survey is ambition is the sufficient explanation for low numbers of females

in office because within the eligibility pool of potential candidates, females are not willing

to run for office due to low levels of political ambition and this pattern has not changed

overtime (Fox, Lawless and Feeley 2001; Fox and Lawless 2004).

14

Page 22: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Political Factors

Last, there are political factors that influence whether or not a person will run for

office. Research finds parties have a large and significant impact on whether a female will

run for office. Most female candidates do not consider running for office until they are

approached by a party leader. Without recruitment, the majority of females had never

seriously considered running for office. There are more women in office when women are

actively recruited; whether by party or political organization (Sanbonmatsu 2006; Carroll

and Sanbonmatsu 2013). And while some literature finds women are less likely to be recruited

(Fox and Lawless 2004), an increase in party recruitment of females, should increase the

overall number of females in office.

Term Limits

Term limits are an important institutional attribute that may serve as a bridge be-

tween emergence and descriptive representation by creating more open seats. Term limits

in state legislatures place restrictions on the number of times an official can serve in office.2

States began enacting term limits in the early 1990s as a way to force government turnover.

Many citizens were displeased with the lack of effective governance at the state level and

wanted to stop incumbents from running for office (Reed and Schansberg 1995; Thompsson

and Moncrief 1993).

While states with term limits enacted a different set of limits upon their legislators,

the main premise is that an incumbent cannot continue running for office term after term.

For example, Oklahoma has a twelve-year lifetime limit across both chambers. Therefore,

2Since the 1990s, 21 states have passed legislation for term limits but 6 states have repealed them. Termlimits were generally passed via citizen initiatives and in 4 states (Massachusetts, Oregon, Washington andWyoming) the state supreme courts repealed the term limits and in 2 states (Idaho and Utah) the statelegislature repealed the term limits (NCSL 2014)

15

Page 23: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

if a person runs and wins election in the lower chamber and serves for twelve years, they

are unable to hold office in the upper chamber. Other states, such as California, imposes

term limits for each chamber allowing a politician to term out of one chamber (the act of

no longer being able to run for office) and then run in the other chamber until they are

termed out there. There is also another variation in term limits where the limits are only

set consecutively. In other words, in a state like Colorado, a person can hold office for eight

years in the lower chamber an then take an election period off and then run and win their

seat back for another eight years (Farmer, Rausch and Green 2003; NCSL 2014).

Prior to the enactment of term limits, most researchers hypothesized term limits

would be beneficial for females. Term limits act as a way to combat the incumbency ad-

vantage and create open seat elections. These open seats would allow females to have more

opportunities to run for office. Overall, there was wide consensus that term limits should

have positive effects on female descriptive representation (Carroll and Jenkins 2001; Darcy

Welch and Clark 1994; Ferry 1994; Crane 1995; Thompson and Moncrief 1993).

Yet, when term limits began to take effect, researchers found term limits did not seem

to have the intended effects on women in office (Carroll and Jenkins 2001; Bernstein and

Chada 2003). In fact, in 1998, seven states had their first round of termed out politicians

which opened up 215 seats across all seven states. Women before being termed out held 58

of those 215 seats and post-1998 election only 53 women held seats. In reality, term limits

actually hindered women’s overall numbers in state legislatures because there was a net loss

of 5 seats for women (Bernstein and Chada 2003).

In a cross-sectional analysis of the impact term limits had for the year 1998, scholars

find an overall negative impact on females but there was variation by state. Some states,

16

Page 24: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

such as Arizona and Arkansas, saw minor gains in the number or females in office but most

suffered, which reflected in a declining number of females in office (Carroll and Jenkins

2001). Yet, what explains these differences across states? Further research on descriptive

representation and term limits has been limited since the initial term limit waves took place.

Given that there is limited research on the long term impact of term limit effects, further

research is needed to resolve the conflicting evidence that would suggest term limits help

females but in practice they seem to be another disadvantage for females.

Emergence and Term Limits Theory

The literature on candidate emergence and term limits offer conflicting explanations

on the expectations of female emergence. On the one hand, the emergence literature finds

there are numerous barriers inhibiting women from running for office such as family respon-

sibilities, incumbency advantage, lack of political recruitment and ambition as well as a lack

of females in the eligibility pool. On the other hand, it is thought open seats created by

term limits are the perfect opportunity for females to gain office. Initial studies did not

find evidence to support the term limit assumptions but scholars posited there may still be

hope that term limits could have positive implications on female descriptive representation

(Carroll and Jenkins 2001; Bernstein and Chada 2003).

Here, I develop a theoretical argument reconciling these two areas of literature and

the puzzle that term limits create open seats, but have not increased the overall number

of females in office. The term limits literature mainly focuses on overall success of female

candidates and largely ignores the impact term limits may have on candidate emergence.

Perhaps women are running for office more frequently in the term limited states, but are not

winning elections. I incorporate expectations about open seats from term limits literature

17

Page 25: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

and eligibility pool assumptions from the emergence literature to develop a general argument

regarding female candidate emergence in term limited states. I expect open seats help females

gain office, but the initial impact of term limits negatively impacted female descriptive

representation. Specifically in this chapter, I argue that over time term limits influence

female candidate emergence.

Open Seats

Existing research regarding female descriptive representation is concerned with aggre-

gate levels of female success. As discussed, a critical stage of analysis is candidate emergence.

The only way females will win office and gain parity is if they run. All else being equal,

in terms of electoral outcomes, term limits can only be effective if the number of female

candidates running within the states increases. For example, if there are more open seats

(created by term limits or not) and the same number, or fewer, females running for office,

then open seats will not have a positive impact on the number of females in office. This idea

is especially important in term limited states since the nature of term limits creates more

open seats.

Conventional wisdom suggests more open seats will lead to more women in office,

however, without increased female candidate emergence, there will not be an overall increase

of women in office. Carroll and Jenkins (2001) show that in states with term limits, the

number of female officeholders decreased when term limits were enacted. However, it is

possible this finding may be due to lower levels of female candidate emergence. The lack of

female candidate emergence is apparent in Carroll and Jenkins’ (2001) finding that females

did not run in a large number of primary elections for either party.

The greater number of open seats created by term limits provide potential female

18

Page 26: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

candidates with more opportunities to emerge. Since an incumbent cannot continuously

run, the overall likelihood of winning an election will increase for new candidates. Further,

Fulton et al (2004) find women are more likely to run in races they perceive their chances of

winning to be high. Open seats, created by term limits or otherwise, offer a better chance at

winning an election than running against an incumbent. Therefore, states with open seats

created by term limits should see an overall increase in the number of female candidates

emerging because opportunity costs of losing are lower.

Eligibility Pool

The presence of term limits may influence more females to emerge and run as can-

didates in state legislative elections. This is due to the fact that with term limits, politics

is not necessarily a career path. In a 2008 CAWP Recruitment Study by Carroll, Sanbon-

matsu and Walsh, nearly 43% of women in the lower chamber of the state legislatures had

no previous officeholding experience. Further, and more importantly, nearly 73% of females

in the lower house claimed their decision to run for office was not done as a stepping stone

towards higher office. The study also finds that nearly 79% of woman in the lower chamber

reported having an occupation that allows for sufficient time and flexibility to hold office was

important when considering their run for office. These findings suggest that many females

in state legislatures do not plan on being career politicians. And therefore, term limits may

allow more opportunities for potential candidates to run and hold office and still avoid being

career politicians.

Term limits create more opportunities for potential candidates who do not want to

be career politicians since a majority of women report they do not see the state legislature

as a stepping stone. Term limits may add a little extra incentive to run for office since the

19

Page 27: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

length of time someone can spend in office is limited. Thus, term limits create a unique

opportunity for non career politicians to serve short term in office to make policy changes3

and then leave after they are termed out.

Furthermore, term limits may also have a positive impact on female politicians who

want to be career politicians. Term limits provide a structured timeline for how long one can

legally stay in office before they move on to the next level of government. For example, a

female may desire to move out of the lower chamber in the state legislature but no opportu-

nities exist in the upper chamber. States that have term limits in both chambers have more

open seats and, therefore, greater opportunities for new candidates to run for office. Term

limits provide an opportunity for females to gain more experience and exposure; especially

for females who may want to progress into federal office after they have termed out of their

state legislature.

Party recruitment is important for increasing movement from eligibility to female

candidates (Fox and Lawless 2004; Sanbonmatsu, 2006). If party recruitment in term limited

states rises, there should be more female candidates emerging. The 2008 CAWP recruitment

study reports that nearly 55% of women in the lower chamber were actively recruited by

a party leader. Further, women organizations may also impact the likelihood of a female

running for office. Nearly 22% of women in the lower chamber were encouraged to run for

office by women organizations. While, many women organizations are quite successful at the

national level, there is still room for improvement and growth at the state-level (Bernstein

and Chada 2003). The state-level is arguably an important strategic focus for parties and

organizations since females are becoming more progressively ambitious and likely to run for

3Also in the 2008 CAWP recruitment study, 35% of women in the lower chamber report their decision torun was based on concern about one or more specific policy issue

20

Page 28: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

national office if they have previous office-holding experience.

The initial studies on term limits reported parties and women organizations did not

actively seek female candidates (Bernstein and Chada 2003). Yet perhaps some of these

organizations and parties did recruit candidates but were not successful in convincing females

to run. Or the case may be parties and organizations did not exactly know the best strategies

for recruiting candidates when term limits first took effect. Given the fact females are more

likely to run when asked, (Fox and Lawless 2004; Sanbonmatsu 2006) it is only a matter of

time before more females will be asked to run for office. The entire candidate pool has to

grow in term limited states, otherwise no one will run. Therefore parties and organizations

must have some strategy at hand to increase candidate recruitment levels (for male and

females alike).

In sum, taking into consideration the constraints and variation in the use of term

limits across states, one should not expect a drastic increase of women in office in states

with term limits. Rather, the number of women in office will likely rise fairly steadily

overtime as more officials are forced to vacate the state legislature. There may be loss in

the short term as research finds (Carroll and Jenkins 2001; Bernstein and Chada 2003), but

this should not be the norm. Open seats will gradually increase as incumbents are termed

out. Furthermore, term limited states will only increase the number of women in office if

the number of women running for office increases. Term limits having a positive impact on

the likelihood a female will run for office is the first stage in the process of increasing the

number of females in office.

Therefore,

H1: Term limits increase the likelihood of female candidate emergence.

21

Page 29: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Data

To examine the hypothesis, I utilize a candidate-level data set. The candidate data

comes from the State Legislative Election Returns: 1967-2010 (ICPSR 2014). The dataset

captures candidate-level state legislative elections and includes election results, term length,

type of legislative election, incumbency status and party identification. The large time span

allows me to better test the impact of term limits on female candidate emergence. I conduct

the analysis across all 50 states at the candidate-level in the general election (discussed more

below) using a quasi natural experiment design. I examine the years from 1990-2010, both

pre and post term limits, across all candidates meeting the standard 5% threshold (Canon

1978) using states without term limits as the control group.

The ICPSR data does not contain the candidate’s gender and, therefore, I have coded

each candidate’s gender. As a robustness check I have also utilized the CAWP (Center for

American Women and Politics) database as a cross-reference. CAWP provides a list of

the total number of females who ran in an election for each state. After coding the ICPSR

dataset to include gender, I looked to the CAWP dataset to examine any discrepancies. When

there were discrepancies between ICPSR and CAWP I then cross-referenced the Secretary

of State’s original election results (when available) to fix or confirm the findings from my

dataset. Further, in a handful of cases where the Secretary of State’s election results were

not readily available and discrepancies existed, I searched newspaper articles for gender

candidate cues.4

While the ICPSR dataset contains a large number of election periods, I will only use

the time period from 1990-2010. Since 1996-2000 is the time frame in which most states first

4In the cases where I could not determine the gender of a candidate I did not include these cases in themodels. Some were missing first names in the original ICPSR study and I could not determine first names.The missing candidates make up <3% of the total observations

22

Page 30: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

experience the impact of term limited officials, the time frame allows a roughly equal pre

and post number of election cycles. The analysis for this time period will therefore capture

a considerable amount of elections both before and after term limits took effect in states.

Further, the candidate-level dataset is quite large over a 20 year time frame and produces

roughly 80,000 observations.5

Design

As briefly mentioned, the enactment of term limits provides the unique opportunity

of an intervention point for an experimental design. Further, Mooney (2009) addresses a

major concern when treating term limits as a natural experiments: exogeneity. To model a

causal relationship, there needs to be random assignment of the treatment and control group.

To test for random assignment, Mooney (2009) ran a test of the top state-level explanatory

variables and finds that there is no statistically significant difference between states with

term limits and states without term limits. For example, state-level population, ideology,

and electoral turnout rates do not predict the adoption of term limits. Therefore, term limits

can be treated as a natural experiment because the states with and without term limits have

no statistically significant differences between them. The treatment group for the design

includes all the states that enacted term limits and the control group includes all the states

that have not enacted term limits.

The enactment of term limits happened at different points in time across the states.

Term limits first took effect in a handful of states in the late 1990s and continued to be

enacted at random through the 2000s. As such, there will be multiple intervention points

5Some states allow candidate fusion; candidates can run under multiple party identifications in the sameelection. For these cases, I use the party ID which received the most votes. For example if Jane Smithran as a Republican and received 10,000 votes and as a Democrat with 5,000 votes I drop the Democraticidentification and Jane Smith is coded as a Republican for the election year.

23

Page 31: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

that are unique to the state enacting the term limits. Using panel-level data, I am less likely

to violate the assumption that an unobservable/unmeasurable variable has an impact on my

main independent variable, term limits. This is important when determining a causal link

between term limits and the dependent variable. Table 2.1 provides a list of the term limited

states (which have not been repealed). The table provides the year in which the term limits

were enacted and the year in which the first round of legislators were forced to leave due to

term limits .

State Year Enacted Year of Impact

Maine 1993 1996California 1990 1996Colorado 1990 1998Arkansas*ˆ 1992 1998Michigan 1992 1998Florida 1992 2000Ohio 1992 2000South Dakota* 1992 2000Montana 1992 2000Arizona* 1992 2000Missouri 1992 2002Oklahoma 1990 2004Nebraska 2000 2006Louisiana 1995 2007Nevada 1996 2010

Source: NCSL 2014: ‘The Term-Limited States’∗ States with multimember districts.

ˆ Arkansas eliminated multimember districts after their 2000 election

Table 2.1: Term-Limited States

Variables

Dependent

The dependent variable is female candidate emergence, which is based on a dichoto-

mous variable where ‘1’ is a female candidate and ‘0’ is a male candidate. Table 2.2 reports

24

Page 32: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

the descriptive statistics on the number of female candidates in the sample. Between 1990-

2010 female candidates made up 26% of the total candidates running for office. Table 2.2

provides further descriptive statistics showing the distribution of the data based on candi-

date gender and term limits. At first glance, females are more prevalent in term limited

states, making up 28% of the candidates versus non-term limited seats where females are

only 25.9% of the candidates.

Variable Number Percent of Sample

Female Candidates 24,537 26.30%Male Candidates 68,380 73.30%Non Term Limit Seats 79,029 85.54%Term Limit Seats 13,888 14.46%

Table 2.2: Descriptive Statistics for Female Emergence and Term Limits

Independent Variable

The main explanatory variable of interest is term limits. States with term limits are

coded ‘1’ and all states without term limits are coded ‘0’. Since, the intervention points

will be scattered due to states implementing term limits in different years, each state with

term limits will be coded to reflect the year in which that state’s term limits take effect.

States with term limits are coded as ‘0’ until they implement term limits. Table 2.3 shows

the distribution for states with and without term limits. Approximately 15% of candidates

run in term limited seats. Whereas non term limited seats make up about 85% of the total

sample (The non-term limited seats include states with enacted term limits but elections

before they were implemented). Again, since this is candidate level-data with a focus on

candidate emergence, these numbers represent the distribution of candidates running in the

term limited and non-term limited races (not the total number of available seats).

25

Page 33: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Variable No Term Limits Term Limits

Female Candidates 20,646 (25.9%) 3,891 (28%)Male Candidates 58,383 (73.9%) 9,997 (71.2%)

Table 2.3: Distribution of Candidates and Term Limits

Control Variables

The model includes several candidate-level and district level controls. The first control

is for open seat where ‘1’ is when a candidate runs in a district with an open seat and ‘0’

is when an incumbent is running within that district. As extant research and my theory

suggests, open seats decrease institutional barriers for women to enter office so I expect open

seats to have a positive impact on likelihood a female will run for office.

Research also finds women are more successful when they compete in multimember

districts (MMD) (Carroll 1994; Darcy, Welch, and Clark 1994; Rule 1990). This is due to the

fact that there are more opportunities to win a seat and it is not a zero-sum game. A handful

of state legislatures use multimember districts in their elections rather than single-member

districts. To measure MMDs, I use the District Type variable which differentiates between

the types of districts. The variable is coded as a dummy for purposes of this study where

‘0’ is a single-member district and ‘1’ is a multimember district.

Incumbents have an advantage in elections, even at the state-level. Incumbents are

more likely to win their elections and is an important variable to include in the model. Here,

incumbent is coded so a ‘0’ is a non incumbent and ‘1’ is an incumbent candidate. As with

all literature, I expect incumbency to have a negative impact on female candidate emergence.

Incumbents inhibit females from winning office and may keep them from running completely

due to the costs associated with running a campaign, especially one where the challeneger

is expected to lose against an incumbent. While congressional literature finds women have

26

Page 34: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

an increasing tendency to run as challengers against female incumbents (see Lawless and

Pearson 2008), much of the literature finds incumbents dissuade candidates from emerging.

Another important control variable is party. Research finds female candidates tend

to emerge and hold seats in office more often as Democrats than Republicans. Republicans

are coded as ‘0’ and I expect that Democrats, coded as ‘1’, will have a positive impact on

the number of female candidates.

I also include a control for term length. Given my theory that term limits may attract

females who do not wish to be career politicians, I expect there to be a negative relationship

between the length of a term in office and female emergence. Females should be more likely

to emerge in states with fewer years in a term; the longer a term, the less likely a female will

emerge.

A measure of competitiveness is also important; especially since females are less likely

to run for office if they perceive their chances of winning to be low. As a crude measure of

competitiveness I will include the Number of Candidates in each election. While this is not

a direct measure of whether a campaign is competitive or not because it does not include

the types of candidates running6, Lawless and Pearson (2008) find females tend to be in

elections where they are facing more than one person of opposition. While a majority of

races are unopposed or have only two candidates, capturing opposition, especially if there is

zero opposition, is an important to control.

Lastly, I include a measure of legislative professionalism. I use the Squire index

which is a value between 0 and 1 assigned to states based on their level of professionalization

within the legislature. Values closer to 0 are the least professional and values closest to 1

6i.e whether or not the candidate is a a qualified candidate and is more likely to win than a non-qualitycandidate. Non quality, meaning a candidate has little to no relevant experience in politics. Usually specifiedas previous officeholding experience at some level of government

27

Page 35: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

are the most professional (see Squire 1992). I expect professionalization to have a negative

impact on the likelihood a female candidate will emerge. This measure is capturing my

theoretical argument that women are more likely to emerge when they do not want to be

career politicians; therefore, when professionalism increases, female emergence will decrease.

Method

I employ two methods to test my hypothesis that term limits increase female candidate

emergence. The first is a difference in differences method. Difference in differences allows

time invariant covariates to be factored out, while incorporating overall exogenous shocks or

trends in the system. Many state-level variables can be controlled for, such as population,

ideology and turnout. There are, however, other unobservable factors such as candidate

ambition levels or time spent on family responsibilities that cannot be measured. While,

these factors should remain fairly constant overtime they are not easily measured without

extensive survey data.

The difference in differences method is shown below. Equation 1 represents the model

for states with term limits. Term limits serve as an intervention point and the difference

before and after term limits were implemented is provided. The model keeps all variables

constant while the unobservable/time-invariant, ai, factors are already factored out. Equa-

tion 2 represents the control group: states without term limits. Equation 3 represents the

difference between the treatment and control groups: states with term limits and states lack-

ing term limits. The error terms are also differenced so this better captures overall shocks

to the system and can capture any general trends. If there is a difference found in equation

3, then term limits have a causal impact on women emergence.

28

Page 36: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

∆yiTL = δ0 + β + ∆uiTL (1)

∗where ∆yiTL denotes the difference in y for states with term limits

∆yiNTL = δ0 + β + ∆uiNTL (2)

∗ where ∆yiNTL denotes the difference in y for states without term limits

∆yiTL − ∆yiNTL = β + (∆uiTL − ∆uiNTL) (3)

*where y is the mean number of women emerging

I also run a logistical regression model to examine the impact term limits have on

the likelihood a female candidate will run for office. The unit of analysis for the logit model

is the candidate-year. Therefore, candidates will appear in the model for every election

cycle they run in as a new observation. The logit model allows me to control for election

specific variables previously discussed (control variables) while also controlling for time.

Where difference in differences examines the difference in emergence between male and female

candidates in states, the logistical regression aims to capture and predict the likelihood a

candidate is a female based on the electoral environment at the individual level; i.e. term

limits, partisanships, district type, etc.

Results

A simple difference in difference test shows there is some difference in emergence rates

between male and female candidates in states with term limits. While the difference is minor,

the results suggest term limits increase the mean number of female candidates running for

office. Table 2.4 provides evidence of this relationship within and across states. States with

term limits see a small increase in the number of females emerging while states without term

limits do not see a major increase.

29

Page 37: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Female Emergence Mean Standard Error

Pre Term Limits (e) 0.243 0.004Post Term Limits (e) 0.267 0.004∆yiTL = 0.024Pre Term Limits (c) .240 0.003Post Term Limits (c) 0.258 0.002∆yiNTL = 0.018∆yiTL − ∆yiNTL = 0.006

Table 2.4: Difference in Differences

The control group, states without term limits, saw an increase in the overall percent

of females running for office post term limits (1996) by 1.8%. While the experimental group,

states with term limits, saw an increase in the overall percentage of females running increase

by 2.4%. Substantively, this shows term limits increase the overall percentage of females

running for office by about .6%. While the percent seems rather small, this .6% increases

equates to roughly 10 more females running for office. For example, between 1994 and 2000,

Ohio (a state with term limits), there was a .06 difference in the mean number of females

running for office. Looking at the total numbers for the state show 41 females ran for office

in 1996 and this number increased to 52 in 2000.

Yet, the likelihood of a female emerging on an individual level is important to un-

derstand as well; the mean provided in the difference in differences is important but the

logit model shows more of the individual-level factors that impact the likelihood a candidate

will be female. Table 2.5, below, shows the results of the model, which also supports the

hypothesis that term limits increase the likelihood a candidate female will emerge. While lo-

gistical regressions are not directly interpretable without predicted probability models, term

limits is in the expected direction and is statistically significant. Furthermore, the open seat

variable, consistent with the literature, finds that women are more likely to emerge in open

30

Page 38: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

seat races.

Variable Model 1 Model 2

Term Limit 0.101 (0.033) 0.103 (0.033)Open Seat 0.054 (0.023) 0.053 (0.023)District Type 0.296 (0.034) 0.279 (0.036)Incumbent -0.068 (0.026) -0.069 (0.027)Party ID 0.458 (0.029) 0.459 (0.029)Term Length -0.151 (0.028) -0.154 (0.028)Number Candidates 0.043 (0.020) 0.055 (0.020)Professionalism (Squire) - -0.168 (0.109)Constant -1.064 (0.064) -1.025 (0.070)n =88288

Table 2.5: Likelihood Candidate is a Female

Furthermore, the control variables are all in the expected direction with statistical

significance at the typical .05 level. The model is consistent with literature that suggests

women are more likely to run in multimember districts; here Table 2.5 shows a positive

significant value since the baseline category is a single-member district. The results also

show the negative impact the incumbency advantage has on female candidates. Since the

incumbency advantage is so great I expected a negative relationship between incumbents

and female candidates. Research already finds there are fewer females in office as well as

the candidate pool- therefore, incumbent should have a negative relationship with female

candidate likelihood. Furthermore, the baseline categories for the model are Republicans

and consistent with past literature, a Democratic party identification has a positive and

significant impact on the likelihood a candidate will be female.

For Model 2, professionalism in is in the expected direction, but is not statistically

significant at conventional levels. Of note though is that the model stays consistent and all

other variables are still significant and in the expected direction. Model 2 is a good robustness

check, controlling for differences across legislative chambers, but since professionalism was

31

Page 39: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

insignificant, I will use Model 1 for predicted probabilities.

While the direction and impact are important, predicted probabilities for the model

provide substantively interpretable results. Tables 6 and 7 provide predicted probabilities

for when a candidate is Democrat and Tables 8 and 9 provide the predicted probabilities

for Republican candidates. All the predicted probabilities values are set based on the most

likely of cases, rather than an overall mean which oftentimes captures unlikely cases (such as

a 2.5 year term). Therefore, competition is set at 1 (to represent 1 opponent), term length

is set to the average, which is 2 years, open seat is to the average which is 0 and then I vary

incumbency and district type to further analyze the relationship. To further analyze the

impact open seats tables, 7 for Democrats and 9 for Republicans, present the impact open

seats have on female emergence in term limited states.

Table 2.6 shows significant differences between term limited and non term limited

states for Democrats. Candidates are more likely to be female in multimember districts and

all around more likely to emerge in term limited states. The predicted probabilities also

show the impact term limits have on non-incumbents. As theorized, non incumbents in term

limits states have a higher probability of being female than non incumbents in non term

limited states. The impact on non incumbents is important to note since term limits lower

the incumbency advantage. Female non incumbents in term limited states emerge 32% of

the time versus 30% of the time in non term limited states. This advantage is even more

apparent in MMDs where females in term limited states emerge about 39% of the time versus

36% in non term limited states.

32

Page 40: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Female Emergence Incumbent Non Incumbent

Single Member DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.284 (0.007) 0.308 (0.006)Term Limits 0.305 (0.008) 0.320 (0.008)Multimember DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.348 (0.009) 0.364 (0.008)Term Limits 0.371 (0.012) 0.388 (0.011)

All margins are significant at p < .05 Std error provided in parentheses

Table 2.6: Predicted Probabilities for Democrats

Female Emergence Open Seat

Single Member DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.317 (0.009)Term Limits 0.339 (0.011)Multimember DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.384 (0.012)Term Limits 0.408 (0.014)

All margins are significant at p < .05 Std error provided in parentheses

Table 2.7: Predicted Probabilities for Democrats in Open Seats

Table 2.77 finds open seat races in term limited states provide an added boost for

female emergence. In single member districts, under term limited seats, females emerge

nearly 34% of the time versus about 32% of the time in states without term limits. These

values, are statistically different and the conventional 95% confidence bands do not overlap.

Further, women in multimember districts also are more likely to emerge in states with term

limits. In MMDs, female emergence is nearly 41% versus 38% of the time in non term

limited states. These predicted probabilities are consistent with past literature on MMDs

and consistent with my theory that term limits in fact do provide an bit of an extra incentive

for women to seek office.

7Predicted probabilities- setting the number of candidates in race to 2 and incumbent to zero. Further, Iexamine this variation by SMDs v MMDs

33

Page 41: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table 2.8 reports the predicted probabilities for Republicans. Here the predicted

probabilities are comparatively lower than the Democratic ones, which is expected given

Democratic female candidate trends. The literature finds females are much more likely to

emerge and ultimately win office under the Democratic party. In any case, the Republican

model still shows a difference between term limited and non term limited states. The prob-

ability is already low for female emergence, but term limits do seem to provide incentive

for female emergence; especially for non incumbents. Female non incumbents in SMD term

limited states make up 23% of the emerging candidates versus 21% in non term limited

states. Further and consistent with the Democratic predicted probabilities, MMDs offer an

advantage to non incumbents and females emerge about 29% of the time in term limited

states versus 25% of the time in non term limited states.

Female Emergence Incumbent Non Incumbent

Single Member DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.201 (0.006) 0.212 (0.005)Term Limits 0.218 (0.007) 0.230 (0.007)Multimember DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.252 (0.008) 0.255 (0.007)Term Limits 0.272 (0.010) 0.286 (0.010)

All margins are significant at p < .05 Std error provided in parentheses

Table 2.8: Predicted Probabilities for Republicans

Female Emergence Open Seat

Single Member DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.227 (0.008)Term Limits 0.245 (0.009)Multimember DistrictsNo Term Limits 0.283 (0.010)Term Limits 0.304 (0.012)

All margins are significant at p < .05 Std error provided in parentheses

Table 2.9: Predicted Probabilities for Republicans in Open Seats

34

Page 42: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Further, Table 2.9 is also consistent with the previous findings and show Republican

females are more likely to emerge in states with term limits. In non term limited, open seat

races, about 23% of candidates are female while females are about 25% of candidates in

term limited, open seat races. This 2% difference is also present in MMDs where Republican

females are more likely to run in term limited states, 30%, versus 28% in non term limited

states.

While the predicted probabilities indicate term limits raise the likelihood a candidate

will be a female, I also checked the confidence intervals on each of the reported predicted

probabilities to make sure the differences are significant. While all differences were signifi-

cant with 90% confidence bands, the most significant difference was found in single-member

districts with non-incumbents (with 95% confidence bands), term limits had the most sig-

nificant impact for this combination of factors. This supports my theory and sheds a bit

more light on the conventional wisdom of the incumbency advantage and term limits. The

results suggest term limits have an impact at some level. I expect the impact to grow slowly

overtime as more open seats become available and more candidates run in order to fill the

growing number of seats.

Conclusions and Implications

Currently, females make up only 24 percent of state legislators in the United States.

This is concerning given a 2009 CAWP study that indicates the growth of female candidates

at the state legislative level has remained fairly stagnant since 1997. Since about half of

women in higher office begin their political career at lower levels of government, this stag-

nation in female state legislators is an important area of research to study. If the number

of women in state legislatures does not increase and/or gain parity, to generally reflect the

35

Page 43: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

population descriptively, the implications for descriptive and substantive representation is

concerning at the state and national level.

This chapter offers a theoretical explanation on how the institutional feature of term

limits may have an impact on the number of female candidates deciding to run for office.

Initial studies on term limits suggest term limits have negative and undesirable effects on the

total numbers of females in office. Using a candidate-level dataset and experimental design

on all 50 states, I find that term limits have some minor, positive impacts on the number

of females running for office. Further, the findings suggest term limits are more likely to

increase female emergence than open seats. Women are more likely to emerge in open seats

in states with term limits. This suggests open seats in term limited states are different,

perhaps in incentive structure as my theory suggests, than open seats in non term limited

seats. More research teasing out the relationship between open seats in term limited states

is needed.

Overall, these findings are important because the initial findings on term limits may

not be a problematic for females as expected. A greater number of female candidates can

lead to a greater number or females in office. The next chapter reexamines the initial puzzle

of whether or not term limits increase female descriptive representation.

There is still great room for additional research, especially with the dataset. The

more data on a candidate available, the better fit the model will be. Better data on women

candidates, such as candidate quality, campaign financing, etc. may add insight as to how

term limits impact the eligibility pool in which women emerge. In the future, I intend to

conduct further research on the types of women running for office and pipeline politics.

Initial studies on term limits find the type and quality of officeholders has not changed much

36

Page 44: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

ı.e., while there has been turnover, the age and background of politicians has not changed

(Moncreif, Powell and Storey 2007). Yet, I argue in this chapter the incentive structure for

office changes. Therefore, the type of candidate emerging may be different than who wins

and the implications for how these ‘outsider’ candidates may impact an election is interesting

to explore. Teasing out this relationship with some case studies is a worthwhile step forward

to answering these questions.

Furthermore, implications for national representation of women in office are worth

considering. The impact of term limits and the type of candidate attracted to the legislatures

are likely to have an impact beyond the state level. If term limited states are attracting

candidates who do not want to be career politicians, this may negatively impact female

recruitment success for congressional races. Take for example, the possibility of a candidate

originally seeking office in the state with no intentions of being a career politician and leaving

after their term has expired—the candidate may go back to their previous career, or perhaps

they will seek higher office. If this candidate is female and decides no to run for higher office,

overtime, descriptive representation at the national level may be negatively impacted.

37

Page 45: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

[1] Allebaugh, Dalene, and Neil Pinney. 2003. “The Real Costs of Term Limits: Comparative Study ofCompetition and Electoral Costs.” in The test of time: Coping with legislative term limits.

[2] Bledsoe, Timothy and Mary Herring. 1990. “Victims of Circumstance: Women in Pursuit of PoliticalOffice.” The American Political Science Review. 84:213-223.

[3] Burrell, Barbara C. 1994. A Woman’s Place Is in the House: Campaigning for Congress in the FeministEra. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

[4] Canon, Bradley. 1978. “Factionalism in the South: A test of theory and a revisitation of V. O. Key.”American Journal of Political Science. 22:833-48.

[5] Carey, John M., Richard G. Niemi, and Lynda W. Powell.2000. Term limits in state legislatures.University of Michigan Press.

[6] Carroll, Susan and Kira Sanbonmatsu. 2013. More Women Can Run: Gender and Pathways to theState Legislatures. Oxford University Press.

[7] Carroll, Susan and Krista Jenkins. 2001. “Do Term Limits Help Women Get Elected?” Social ScienceQuarterly. 82/1.

[8] Census Bureau. 2012.

[9] Center for American Women and Politics. 2012. “Women in State Legislatures? Fact Sheet”:www.cawp.rutgers.edu

[10] Crane, Edward H. 1995. “Testimony before the Subcommittee on the Constitution, Committee on theJudiciary, U.S. Senate.”

[11] Darcy, R, Susan Welch and Janet Clark. 1994. Women, Elections, and Representation. 2nd Edition.Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.

[12] Dolan, Kathleen. 2004. Voting for Women: How the Public Evaluates Women Candidates. Boulder,CO: Westview.

[13] Dolan, Kathleen. 2009. “The Impact of Gender Stereotyped Evaluations on Supoport for WomenCandidates.” Political Behavior. 32:69-88.

[14] Elder, Laurel. 2012. “The Partisan Gap among Women State Legislators.” Journal of Women, Politicsand Policy. 33:65-85.

[15] Ferry, Jonathan. 1994. “Women, Minorities and Term Limits: American’s Path to a RepresentativeCongress”. U.S. Term Limits Foundation Outlook Series.

[16] Fowler, Linda. 1992. A Comment on Competition and Careers. In Gerald Benjamin and Michael J.Lambin. eds., Lmiting Legislative Terms Washington, DC: CQ Press.

[17] Fox, Richard L. 2000. “Gender and Congressional Elections.” In Gender and American Politics: Women,Men, and the Political Process, eds. Sue Tolleson Rinehart and Jyl J. Josephson. Armonk, NY: M.E.Sharpe.

[18] Fox, Richard and Jennifer Lawless. 2004. “Entering the Arena? Gender and the Decision to Run forOffice.” American Journal of Political Science. 48:264-280.

[19] Fulton, Sarah et, al. 2006. “The Sense of a Women: Gender Ambition, and The Decision to Run forCongress”. Political Research Quarterly. 59: 235-248.

38

Chapter Bibliography

Page 46: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

[20] Fulton, Sarah. 2012. “Running Backwards and in High Heels: The Gendered Quality Gap andIncumbent Electoral Success.” Political Research Quarterly. 20:1-12.

[21] Gershon, Sarah. 2012. “When Race, Gender, and the Media Intersect: Campaign News Coverage ofMinority Congresswomen” Journal of Women and Politics. 33:105-125.

[22] Gertzog, Irwin. 2002. Women’s Changing Pathways to the US House of Representatives. University ofOklahoma Press.

[23] Huddy, Leonie, and Nayda Terkildsen. 1993. “Gender Stereotypes and the Perception of Male andFemale Candidates.” American Journal of Political Science. 37: 119-47.

[24] Kazee, Thomas.1994. “Who Runs for Congress ?” Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly.

[25] Kahn, Kim Fridkin. 1992. ”Does Being Male Help? An Investigation of the Effects of Candidate Genderand Campaign Coverage on Evaluations of U.S Senate Candidates” Journal of Politics 54: 497-517.

[26] King, David and Richard E. Matland. 2003. “Sex and the Grand Old Party: An ExperimentalInvestigation of the Effect of Candidate Sex on Support for a Republican Candidate.” AmericanPolitics Research. 31: 595-612.

[27] Klarner, Carl, William Berry, Thomas Carsey, Malcolm Jewell, Richard Niemi, Lynda Powell,and James Snyder. State Legislative Election Returns (1967-2010). ICPSR34297-v1. Ann Ar-bor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2013-01-11.doi:10.3886/ICPSR34297.v1

[28] Koch, Jeffrey. 2000. “Do Citizens Apply Gender Stereotypes to Infer Candidates’ Ideological Orienta-tions?” Journal of Politics 62: 414-29.

[29] Koch, Jeffrey. 2002. “Gender Stereotypes and Citizens’ Impressions of House Candidates’ IdeologicalOrientations.” American Journal of Political Science. 46(2), 453-462.

[30] Milyo, Jeffrey and Samantha Schosberg. 2000. “Gender Bias and Selection Bias in House Elections.”Public Choice. 105:41-59.

[31] Moncrief, Gary, Lynda W. Powell, and Tim Storey. 2007. “Composition of Legislatures”. in InstitutionalChange in American Politics: The Case of Term Limits. eds. Karl Kurtz, Bruce Cain, and RichardNiemi. The University of Michigan Press.

[32] Mooney, Christopher. 2009. “Term Limits as a Boon to Legislative Scholarship: A Review.” StatePolitics and Policy Quarterly. 9:204- 228.

[33] National Conference of State Legislatures. 2011 “Legislative Term Limits Overview?http://www.ncsl.org/ .

[34] Osborn L, Tracy. 2012. How Women Represent Women: Political Parties, Gender and Representationin the State Legislatures. Oxford University Press.

[35] Palmer, Barbara and Dennis Simon. 2005. “When Women Run Against Women: The Hidden Influenceof Female Incumbents in Elections to the U.S. House of Representatives, 1956-2002.” Gender andPolitics. 1:39-63.

[36] Palmer, Barbara and Dennis Simon. 2006. Breaking the Political Glass Ceiling: Women and Congres-sional Elections. New York: Routlege.

[37] Sanbonmatsu, Kira. 2006. ”Where women run.” Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

[38] Sanbonmatsu, Kira, Susan J. Carroll, and Debbie Walsh. Center for American Women and Politics(CAWP) Recruitment Studies, 2008. ICPSR35244-v1. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for

39

Page 47: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Political and Social Research [distributor], 2015-05-13. http://doi.org/10.3886/ICPSR35244.v1.

[39] Sanbonmatsu, Kira and Kathleen Dolan. 2009. “Do Gender Stereotypes Transcend Party?” PoliticalResearch Quarterly 62: 485-494.

[40] Schwindt-Bayer, L. A. and Mishler, W. 2005. “An Integrated Model of Women?s Representation.” TheJournal of Politics. 67/2: 407-428.

[41] Seltzer, Richard A., Jody Newman, and Melissa Voorhees Leighton. 1997. Sex as a Political Variable:Women as Candidates and Voters in U.S. Elections. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

[42] Swers, Michele. 2002. The Difference Women Make. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

[43] Werner and Mayer. 2007. Public Election Funding, Competition, and candidate Gender.

40

Page 48: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

CHAPTER 3

FEMALE CANDIDATE SUCCESS

Abstract

In this chapter, I offer further insight into the lack of females in state legislative office.

While scholars point to the incumbency advantage as the main reason for a lack of descriptive

representation (see: Carroll and Jenkins 2001; Darcy, Welch, and Clark 1994; Jacobson 2000;

Burrell 1992), the implementation of term limits provides a unique opportunity to study the

success of women in office. I argue, using the state politics and the women and politics

literature, term limits are more beneficial for Republican females than Democratic females.

To test my theory, I look at the interactive effect between professionalization, term limits

and female candidates. To do so, I examine state legislative electoral outcomes in general

elections to the lower house (1990-2010) using a logistical regression. The results indicate

that as professionalism increases, female Democrats are less likely to win in term limited

states than non term limited states. Female Republicans on the other hand are more likely

to win their seat as professionalism decreases in term limited states than non term limited

states.

Introduction

The early 1990s experienced a wave of state-level ballot initiatives targeting term

limits for elected state officials. Citizens were frustrated with their politicians and believed

the implementation of term limits would help alleviate the lack of responsiveness at the

state-level by forcing long term politicians to leave office. Term limits successfully passed in

41

Page 49: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

21 states1 via ballot initiative (Farmer, Rausch and Green 2003). Women in politics scholars

hypothesized term limits would be the start of a new era, as they would allow more women to

enter office (Ferry 1994; Crane 1995). Yet, subsequent research finds term limits decreases

the number of women in state legislative office (Carroll and Jenkins 2001; Bernstein and

Chada 2003). This chapter explores the discrepancy in expectations by reexamining theo-

retical and empirical questions surrounding the impact term limits have on female descriptive

representation.

Term limits provide a unique institutional tool employed in a handful of states, which

can provide the path necessary to bring parity amongst males and females in office. Females

are far from being equally represented in state legislatures and only make up about 24% of

the total state legislators (NCSL 2015). Descriptive representation has long been a normative

concern in political science based on principles of representative democracy.

While extant literature addresses many concerns with the lack of female represen-

tation, the research since the ‘Year of the Women’ focuses largely on the national level of

government (Carroll and Sanbonmatsu 2013). Yet recently, focus has shifted back to female

descriptive representation at the state-level (Carroll and Sanbonmatsu 2013). Research at

the state-level is important because state legislatures serve as a step along the political am-

bition ladder for most politicians.2 Furthermore, states play a large role on the livelihood

of citizens and deal with many policy issues. Therefore, having descriptive representation in

state legislatures is important for having women’s issues placed on the agenda (Swers 2002;

Osborn 2012).

1Between 1997-2004 6 states repealed term limits via the State Supreme Court or Legislature. Now, only 15states have term limits.

249% of the 113th Congress were former state legislators (NCSL 2013).

42

Page 50: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

In this chapter, I seek to offer further insight regarding the lack of female descriptive

representation. Given the puzzling findings between term limit expectations and female de-

scriptive representation, I present a study analyzing term limits as an intervention point in a

quasi-natural experiment. This design allows a better comparison between female descriptive

representation in states with term limits and states without term limits.

This chapter proceeds as follows: I first discuss the extant literature on the historically

low levels of female descriptive representation and the term limits literature with regard to

female descriptive representation. Next, I offer a theoretical argument regarding term limits,

professionalization, party identification and females. Then, I present my hypotheses and

discuss the research design. Finally, I present the findings and reflect with conclusions and

implications.

Females in Office

Assuming there is a sizable pool of eligible female candidates (as discussed in the

previous chapter), it is reasonable to ask what is the causal mechanism that has resulted

in continued low levels of female descriptive representation. Candidate emergence is an

important stage to analyze, but election outcomes, when females win or lose, are important

too. An increase in descriptive representation rests on the ability of females to win office,

not just run for office. This section will focus on the current research explaining constraints

on female office-seekers

Since the 1990s, the overall percentage of females in office has remained fairly stag-

nant (CAWP 2012). Yet, there is large variation in descriptive representation across the

50 state legislatures. There are some states, like Colorado, which has a legislative branch

with fairly equal percentages of men and women. Yet, there are states, like Louisiana, which

43

Page 51: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

are composed of a super-majority of men.3 Below, I offer a discussion on the current state

of women and state politics literature. I discuss the factors that influence the variation of

female descriptive representation across the U.S. states. I begin a discussion of voter bias

and media bias against female candidates, then present the institutional constraint litera-

ture, and lastly discuss findings regarding the impact term limits have on female descriptive

representation.

Voter Bias

Voters may have a bias against female candidates placing women at a disadvantage.

The literature points to two main public perceptions that may influence vote choice: Voter

attitudes towards the acceptance of female candidates, and whether or not voters use stereo-

types about female candidates in their decision calculus.

First, in regards to voter attitudes towards female candidates, is whether or not

females should hold office. Historically, politics was a man’s game and women were not

allowed to vote. Further, the few women who were appointed or elected served as tokens

rather than serious politicians (see Foerstel and Foerstel, 1996). Voter attitudes on female

politicians have changed. At the Congressional level, scholars find women to be just as likely

to win elections as men indicating that when women run, they win (Burrell 1994; Darcy,

Welch, and Clark 1994; Fox 2000; Seltzer et al. 1997). The public has become much more

accepting of the idea that a female can hold political office. Yet, some bias still exists since

one in five voters believe men are emotionally better-suited for politics (Lynch and Dolan

2013; Lynch and Dolan 2014).

Secondly, and arguably the most prevalent biases against female candidates, are the

3Colorado has 42 women in office accounting for 42% of the total legislature while Louisiana currently has17 women in office which accounts for about 12% of the total legislature.

44

Page 52: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

stereotypes voters use. Extant research finds the public holds stereotypes about both male

and female candidates in regards to personality traits and issue competency (see Lynch and

Dolan 2014).

Personality traits deal with how the public views candidates in terms of personal

characteristics. Generally speaking, voters view females as more compassionate and honest

while men are viewed as more experienced and better leaders (Alexander and Andersen 1993;

Burrell 2008; Huddy and Terkildsen 1993; Kahn 1996; King and Matland 2003; Lawless 2004;

Leeper 1991; Paul and Smith 2008; Sapiro 1981). Yet, scholars find voters view experience,

rather than honesty and compassion (i.e the stereotypes associated with men) as better

qualities for an elected official (Huddy and Terkildsen 1993; Lawless 2004; Rosenwasser and

Dean 1989). Therefore, despite the positive personality traits voters associate with females,

these traits are not as valued and may work against female candidates.

Issue competency bias is also present in voters’ decision calculus. Extant literature

finds the public perceives women and men to be better at specific, and different issues

(Alexander and Anderson 1993; Huddy and Terkildsen 1993; Kahn 1992; Koch 2000; Law-

less 2004). Female politicians are better at dealing with issues involving social welfare such

as healthcare, education and poverty. Men are viewed as competent in handling economic

and foreign policy issues (Koch 2000; Sanbonmatsu 2002). Depending on the political envi-

ronment surrounding any given election, these issue competency biases may help, hinder or

have no impact on a female’s chance at winning office.

Media Bias

The media can reinforce and perpetuate stereotypes about female candidates. Fram-

ing, or how the media tries to change the fundamental way a person thinks about an issue,

45

Page 53: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

is a tool used by the media when covering female candidates (Fulton 2011). The media

portrays males and females differently and the coverage tends to place males in a favorable

light (Kahn 1992). The media examines women candidates through a feminine lens and

emphasizes trivial facts rather than what the candidate plans to achieve if elected; i.e. the

media often comments on what Hilary Clinton is wearing and if she is having a bad hair

day rather than Clinton’s policy stance (Fulton 2011). When the media portrays women

as feminine, this may cue latent gender stereotypes people hold towards female candidates

(Palmer and Simon 2005).

A prime example of media coverage reinforcing gender stereotypes is the former Mas-

sachusetts governor Jane Swift’s time in office from 2001-2003 (CAWP 2015). While in

office, Swift was in the hospital while pregnant with twins. The media coverage of her hos-

pital visit was harsh and she was often referred to as a “supermom on a power trip”. Swift

was regularly criticized for having young children while holding office and was frequently

asked during press conferences who was watching her children. Such news coverage rein-

forces the idea to voters that women are not suited for the political sphere because their

primary responsibilities lie in the home (Palmer and Simon 2006; McGlen et al 2011).

Institutional Constraints

Moving away from voter and media bias, there are also institutional barriers that

hinder female descriptive representation. Below is a discussion on how the institutional

environment has a negative effect on female descriptive representation.

Incumbency Advantage

Incumbents have high success rates when they run for reelection (Erikson 1971). In-

cumbency advantage posits incumbents high reelection rates reduce opposition and leave

46

Page 54: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

little opportunity for non incumbents to compete. Congressional-level research on the in-

cumbency advantage finds incumbents enjoy this advantage due to helping constituents with

casework (Fenno 1977), redistricting and a weakened sense of party identification (Erikson

1972) as well as an ability to deter candidates from running (Cox and Katz 1996; Jacob-

son and Kernell 1983; Gordon, Huber, and Landa 2007). Therefore, an increase in women

in office is inhibited by male incumbents who continue to run and win office at high rates

(Burrell 1992; Darcy, Welch, and Clark 1994; Cox and Katz 1996; Jacobson 2000; Carroll

and Jenkins 2001).

The incumbent reelection rate across all state lower house legislatures is around 50%

and has been fairly stagnant since the 1970s (Ansolabehere and Snyder 2002). While the

state-level incumbency advantage is not as pronounced as the federal government, the ad-

vantage persists. While incumbency almost guarantees an easy win for politicians (males

and females alike), the fact remains that overall, the incumbency advantage serves as an

institutional constraint against females (Burrell 1992, Fox and Lawless 2004). The incum-

bency advantage is particularly harmful against increasing female descriptive representation

since most levels of government are currently composed of men.

Electoral Competition

Another institutional factor perpetuating low levels of female descriptive representa-

tion is the finding that women candidates face more competition than males (Lawless 2004;

Palmer and Simon 2006; Lawless and Pearson 2008). While this research is mainly limited

to the Congressional-level, studies find women face more competition in all types of races;

i.e. as an incumbent, challenger or in open seat races (Lawless and Pearson 2008). In other

words, once in the race, female candidates have to work harder than male candidates because

47

Page 55: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

females face a more competitive electoral environment. Women are also less likely to run

unopposed and the number of female versus female races is increasing (Lawless and Pearson

2008). When a female faces a female in a general election only one can win. If the number

of females running is constant, female descriptive representation has a greater chance of

increasing when female candidates run against males, rather than other females.

The previously discussed literatures focuses on how voter, media bias, and the insti-

tutional environment negatively affects female descriptive representation. Next, I discuss the

literature on term limits which tends to highlight the positive effect an institutional change

can have on female candidates. Below I discuss the term limits literature as it relates to

female descriptive representation.

Term Limits

Term limits are an institutional attribute that place restrictions on the number of

times an elected official can run for reelection.4 The expectation amongst scholars was that

term limits would have positive effects on female descriptive representation because they

create a greater number of open seats (Burrell 1992; Ferry 1994; Crane 1995). Essentially,

term limits serve to reduce the incumbency advantage. Congressional research shows open

seats are the best way for women to enter the arena. As such, term limits create greater

opportunities for new candidates to emerge (Carroll and Jenkins 2001; Ferry 1994; Crane

1995). Yet, initial studies on term limits find a negative impact on female descriptive repre-

sentation. While variation existed across the term limited states, there was a general decline

in the number of women in office within the newly term limited states (Carroll and Jenkins

2001; Bernstein and Chada 2003).

4Since the 1990s, 21 states have passed legislation for term limits but 6 states have repealed them.

48

Page 56: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Since term limits are a more contemporary and significant institutional change, schol-

ars have researched their impact on legislatures, legislator behavior as well as candidates5.

Term limits do not seem to translate into more competitive elections (Allebaugh and Pinney

2003). Further, extant research finds term limits have little to no impact on the demo-

graphic composition of legislatures— term limits have not created a new pool of candidates

and therefore, legislators have the same demographic, ideological and partisan character-

istics as they did pre-term limit implementation (Gilmour and Rothstein 1994; Reed and

Schansberg 1996; Carey, Niemi and Powell 1998; Carey et al 2006).

Yet, other empirical studies find the partisan makeup of the term limited state leg-

islatures changed (Meinke and Hasecke 2003). Term limited states tend to become more

Republican post term limits implementation. Theoretically, this is because Republicans are

more likely to take on costs with higher risk. In elections, initial costs to run are high and

there is no guarantee of success or a long term payout (Fowler 1992: Kazee 1994). Further,

opportunity costs to enter politics are different for each party and are dependent on the pro-

fessionalization of the legislature. Republicans tend to have majorities in citizen legislatures

and Democrats do well in professional legislatures (Fiorina 1994; 1996). Meinke and Hasecke

(2003) argue term limits create a “partial reversal of professionalization” (901) which alters

the incentives for legislators and creates an environment favoring Republican candidates.

I propose these studies may be missing a larger pattern. The initial implementation of

term limits may not have an immediate impact on the type of candidates running for office-

whether it be candidates’ quality or gender. A study comparing term limited states to non

term limited states using a series of elections overtime may add insight into a broader effect

5see: Farmer, Rausch, and Green 2003) for a comprehensive study on how term limits effect legislativeperformance in the chamber, the effect of lobbyist as well as leadership.

49

Page 57: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

term limits have on candidates and female descriptive representation. Below, I offer a theory

linking the findings in the women and politics literature to the state politics literature. I

look at the incentive structure created by term limits and how this affects female descriptive

representation in state legislative.

Theory on Term Limits and Female Success

The previous chapter discusses emergence an important first step when considering

female descriptive representation. I find term limits increase the likelihood a female will

emerge as a candidate. My findings suggest that despite initial studies on term limits showing

females lost seats in office, there is evidence that more female candidates are emerging in

states with term limits. Therefore, if females continue to run (and win, discussed in the

chapter), descriptive representation should increase in term limited states. Since the number

of females emerging has increased in term limited states, the next step is to examine whether

the increased number of female candidates emerges increases the likelihood a female wins.

The Gradual Impact of Term Limits

The decrease in female descriptive representation in term limited states is rather puz-

zling since open seats create more opportunities for women to gain office. With term limits,

the incumbency advantage is no longer a major institutional constraint against potential

female candidates. Incumbents are forced out and this creates open seats. Yet, post imple-

mentation, females lost seats previously held by women, thus, decreasing the overall number

of females in state legislatures (Bernstein and Chada 2003). Term limits forced females who

had attained office to leave and no new females replaced them (Carroll and Jenkins 2001).

These findings suggest the conventional wisdom surrounding female descriptive representa-

tion and open seats may be incorrect. Or that not enough time has passed and eventually

50

Page 58: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

females will become aware of open seats and run for office (whether it be personal choice to

seek office or recruitment efforts by parties, organizations, etc.).

Therefore, a short-term decline may not actually contradict the conventional wisdom.

Since institutional changes tend to have a gradual effect, a single cross-sectional analysis does

not provide enough variation in time to determine whether term limits have a negative or

positive impact on female descriptive representation. Term limits, and the open seats they

create, can still increase female descriptive representation if examined over more than one

election cycle.

Party Identification

Beyond the glacial pace term limits may have on female descriptive representation,

the party of the female candidate is also likely to have an effect on descriptive representation.

Party plays a large roll in understanding female descriptive representation because there is

variation in female candidate success rates across the parties. Examining female Democrats

and Republicans as similar, in terms of paths and incentives to office, assumes there is

no difference in female success rates across parties. Studying the two parties separately is

important for further understanding of different paths to office for female candidates (Carroll

and Zerilli 1993; Dolan and Ford 1998; Sanbonmatsu, 2002). The differences across party

are important since the total number of females in all state legislatures for 2015 varies by

party. The majority of female legislators are Democrats (60%), and 30% of female legislators

are Republicans (NCSL 2015).6

Previous research finds women in term limited states initially lost seats but there

were states where females gained seats. Looking at the party of the female candidates can

6There are 4 females from a third party and 10 females from Nebraska where elections are non-partisan.

51

Page 59: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

help explain these mixed findings. If term limits create an incentive structure that is more

conducive to a Republican candidates (Fiorina 1994; 1996), term limits can help increase

female descriptive representation. A loss in the aggregate may be because female candidates

are generally Democrat and fewer female Democrats won after term limits. Yet, term limits

may have caused a greater number of female Republicans to run and win.

Since most females in office are Democrats, term limits should not have a significant

impact on their success. While term limits may have initially decreased the number of women

in office, the overall percent of female Democrats is still fairly high, and stagnant. As of 2016,

about 60% of female legislators are Democrats and about 40% are Republicans (NCSL). The

female Democratic candidate pool seems to be much richer than the Republican pool since

there are more female Democrats than there are female Republicans. Therefore, despite

term limits, a significant number of female Democrats are willing to run (as evidence from

Chapter 1) and replace females leaving due to term limits.

Therefore,

H1: Female Republicans in term limited states will have higher success rates than female

Republicans in non term limited states.

H2: Term limits will have no impact on the success rates of Democratic female candidates.

The variation across states may be explained by the level of professionalization in the

legislature as well as the political environment in which female candidates run. The political

environment in which female candidates run also has an impact on whether party identifi-

cation will help or hinder their chances of success. Below I discuss how professionalization

and term limits affect female candidates within each party.7

7Chapter 3 of the Dissertation discusses more of the political environment aspects; mainly the districtdemographics but also open seats in ‘core’ or ‘safe’ Republican/Democrat districts versus competitive/swingdistricts.

52

Page 60: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

The research on whether more professional legislatures have a greater number of

females is mixed, (see Squire 1992; Sanbonmatsu 2002). I examine the interactive effect

term limits and professionalization have on female descriptive representation by considering

how the interaction effects each party differently.

Since more professionalized legislatures8 favor Democrats (Fiorina 1994; 1996), the

impact of term limits on female descriptive representation in a highly professionalized legisla-

ture should be negative, but minimal. The number of females in professionalized legislatures

is likely to be high and compromised of mainly female Democrats rather than female Re-

publicans. Further, a more professionalized legislature with term limits will have fewer

Democratic females post term limits. If term limits create an environment more friendly to

Republican candidates, the number of female Democrats will likely decrease.

Citizen legislatures9 are comprised of more Republicans than Democrats (NCSL

2015). In general, these legislatures have fewer females overall since Republican females

do not have as many seats as Democratic females. The incentive structure for candidates

does not change much with the implementation of term limits since the legislature is already

a part-time job. As such, this environment creates one that is more favorable to female

Republicans and less favorable to female Democrats. There are fewer female Democrats in

these citizen legislatures so term limits are unlikely to have any effect on the descriptive

representation of female Democrats.

Hybrid legislatures fall somewhere in between the highly and less professionalized

legislatures and (NCSL 2015) will likely see the biggest change in female descriptive rep-

8Professional legislatures tend to be full-time, well paid, and have a large number of staff available (NCSL2015; Squire 1992).

9Citizen legislatures are generally part-time, low pay, and have a small staff available to legislators (ibid).

53

Page 61: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

resentation. Female politicians in these legislatures may or may not be career politicians.

Therefore, implementing term limits may have a negative effect on the overall number of

females in office— especially for career politicians. The nature of term limits makes the

legislature become a bit less professionalized which will decrease the number of Democrats

(Meinke and Hasecke 2003). The number of female Democrats is likely to decrease while the

number of female Republicans should stay relatively constant.

Therefore, the overall effect of professionalization, and the interactive effect between

term limits and professionalization, is hypothesized as:

H3: As professionalization increases, female Democratic descriptive representation increases.

H3a Female Democratic descriptive representation decreases as professionalization increases

and term limits are implemented.

H4: As professionalization increases, female Republican descriptive representation decreases.

H4a Female Republican descriptive representation increases as professionalization decreases

and term limits are implemented.

Data and Design

As with the emergence chapter, I use a candidate-level dataset of general elections

to test my hypotheses and add state-level variables for controls. I use the State Legislative

Election Returns (SLER): 1967-2010 (ICPSR 2014) to capture candidate-level state legisla-

tive elections. The large time span offers the opportunity to better understand the impact of

term limits on female descriptive representation. Using a quasi-natural experimental design

examining both pre and post term limits across all state legislatures, states without term

limits are the control group.

I coded each candidate’s gender and cross-referenced with CAWP (Center for Ameri-

54

Page 62: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

can Women and Politics) and NCSL (National Conference of State Legislatures) to check the

total number of female candidates and female legislators by year. If there were discrepancies

between ICPSR and CAWP, I relied on each State’s Election returns to edit or confirm the

data.

The time period for this analysis is 1990-2010. The data captures 1992, the year of

women, and also a considerable amount of time both pre and post term limits took effect in

states (The first wave of term limits began in 1998). Capturing the year of the women in the

dataset is important since 1992 was a year which greatly increased the number of women in

office nationally. Lastly, my design uses 49 states10 and each district within the states for

this analysis to capture systemwide trends.

Method

To test the hypotheses I run two logistical regressions that predict the likelihood of

a winner in a general election: One for Democrats and one for Republicans. This allows me

to analyze how female descriptive representation within each party is unique. Since these

models are dichotomous, using an estimation tool such as the logit model will allow me

to capture the likelihood a winner is female. For the models, the unit of analysis is the

candidate-year. Each candidate, for each election year, is an observation. I also run and

discuss predicted probabilities to substantively interpret the results.

Variables

Dependent

The dependent variable is candidate success. The variable measures each candidate

individually where ‘0’ is a loss and ‘1’ is when the candidate won. Table 3.1 reports the

10I eliminate Nebraska from the models since the elections are nonpartisan

55

Page 63: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

success rate of all the female candidates in the sample. For all states, about 60% of females

run and win their seat. In term limited states, 54% of females won and in non term limited

states, 60% of females won their race. While these are descriptive statistics, the pattern

suggests candidates do not win as often in term limited states (similar for male candidates).

Table 3.2 reports the descriptive statistics for male winners, which shows men only winning

about 55% of the time in term limited states.

Variable Number Percent

Overall Win 14,494 59.07%Overall Loss 10,043 40.93%Term Limit Win 2,107 54.15%Term Limit Loss 1,784 45.85%No Term Limit Win 12,387 60.00%No Term Limit Loss 8,259 40.00%

Table 3.1: Descriptive Statistics for Female Success and Term Limits

Variable Number Percent

Overall Win 35,118 60.15%Overall Loss 23,265 39.85%Term Limit Win 5,596 55.98%Term Limit Loss 4,401 44.02%No Term Limit Win 23,265 60.15%No Term Limit Loss 35,118 39.85%

Table 3.2: Descriptive Statistics for Male Success and Term Limits

Independent Variables

The first explanatory variable is term limits which is coded ‘1’ for states with term

limits and states without term limits are coded ‘0’. States are coded as ‘0’ until the im-

plementation of term limits for that particular state begins. I expect term limits to have a

positive effect on candidate success.

Candidate gender is the second main independent variable. Gender is coded as ‘0’

for males and ‘1’ for females. I also include an interaction between term limits and female

56

Page 64: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

candidates to examine how females are specifically affected by term limits. I hypothesized

(H1 & H2) term limits will have a positive effect on female Republicans and no effect on

female Democrats.

Professionalization is third explanatory variable. The measure is from the Squire

index and comes from Vanderbilt University’s State Politics and Judiciary dataset. The

measure is a continuous variable from 0-1 where 0 is the least professionalized and 1 is the

most professionalized. The measure takes into account whether the legislature is full-time

versus part-time, how much legislators are paid, staff size, etc. For more details on the mea-

sure, see Squire 1992. I expect professionalization to have a positive effect on Democrats

and a negative effect on Republicans. I also include an interaction between professionaliza-

tion and female candidate to test hypotheses H3 & H4. I expect professionalization to be

positively linked to female Democratic descriptive representation and negatively linked to

female Republican descriptive representation.

A 3-way interaction between female candidates, term limits, and professionalization

is included in both Republican and Democratic models. I expect term limits in more profes-

sionalized states to have a negative impact on female Democratic descriptive representation.

As professionalization decreases I expect female Republican descriptive representation to

increase.11

Controls

Incumbency is an important control variable to include in the models. Even with the

enactment of term limits there will be incumbents with a high electability rate. Incumbency

is coded as a dichotomous variable where ‘0’ is a non-incumbent and ‘1’ is an incumbent. I

11The relationship between the 3-way interaction will be discussed more thoroughly through post estimationpredicted probabilities

57

Page 65: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

expect incumbency to have a positive impact on the success rates of candidates.

I also include a control for open seats where ‘0’ is a seat with an incumbent running

and ‘1’ is an open seat. Term limits create open seats but it is important to control for open

seats in non term limited states. I expect open seats to have a positive impact on candidate

success rates.

To control for the electoral competitiveness of a seat I use two measures. The first is

unopposed coded as ‘1’ if the candidate ran unopposed, ‘0’ if otherwise. The second measure

is the margin of victory for the winning candidate. A higher margin of victory indicates the

race was less competitive.

Lastly, I include a control for the district type which is a variable based on single

member versus multimember districts12 The variable is coded as ‘0’ for single member dis-

tricts and ‘1’ for multimember districts. I expect this variable to be positive, indicating

multimember districts are beneficial for candidate success rates.

Results

Table 3.3 reports the results for the four Democratic Models with roust standard

errors clustered around each candidate.13 Model 1 includes no interaction terms and Models

2-4 include interaction terms. Model 1 serves as a test for the extant literature on how term

limits, and professionalization affect the success of Democratic candidates. Model 1 finds

term limits have a significant and negative effect on Democratic candidate success. In term

limited states, Democrats are less likely to win; this is consistent with literature finding term

12States with MMDs: Alaska, Arizona*, Arkansas, Georgia, Idaho*, Indiana, Maryland, New Hampshire,New Jersey*, North Carolina, North Dakota*, South Dakota*, Vermont, Washington*, West Virginia,Wyoming. Note: states with stars are two-member districts (NCSL 2016) while other states may haveall or only some MMDs.

13I also ran each model clustered around the state legislative district and the results were consistent.

58

Page 66: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

limits favor a more Republican legislature. Model 1 also supports the state politics literature

findings that professionalized legislatures favor Democrats. The direction on the Squire

measure is positive and significant indicating as professionalization increases, Democratic

candidate success increases. Further, Model 1 also shows being a female positively and

significantly increases the likelihood of success.

Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Term Limit -0.183* (0.046) -0.178* (0.054) -0.184* (0.046) -0.145 (0.093)Female Candidate 0.111* (0.038) 0.114* (0.044) 0.045 (0.070) -0.002 (0.081)Professionalism (Squire) 0.439* (0.122) 0.440* (0.122) 0.346* (0.144) 0.387* (0.167)Term*Female – -0.014 (0.090) – 0.124 (0.162)Female*Professional – – 0.298 (0.259) 0.531 (0.313)Term Limit*Professional – – – -0.137 (0.313)Term*Female*Professional – – – -0.637 (0.548)Incumbent 4.940* (0.055) 4.940* (0.055) 4.940* (0.55) 4.942* (0.055)Open Seat 2.596* (0.050) 2.596* (0.050) 2.596* (0.050) 2.599* (0.050)Unopposed 5.0517* (0.722) 5.052* (0.722) 5.049* (0.722) 5.049* (0.722)Margin of Victory 0.022* (0.001) 0.022* (0.001) 0.022* (0.001) 0.022* (0.001)District Type 0.058 (0.089) 0.058 (0.089) 0.058 (0.089) 0.062 (0.089)Constant -2.981* (0.092) -2.982* (0.092) -2.961 (0.094) -2.978* (0.097)

n =36855R2=0.54

Controls for election years included in the model but suppressed from the table

Table 3.3: Logistical Regression of Democratic Candidate Success

Model 2 tests hypothesis 2 which states term limits will have no effect on female

Democrats. Hypothesis 2 is supported since the interactive effect between term limits and

female candidates is not statistically significant. Term limits are negative and statistically

significant, and female is positive and significant, but there is not an interactive relationship.

Further, the model is consistent with Model 1. Professionalism has a significant and positive

relationship on Democratic success.

Models 3 and 4 test hypothesis 3. Hypothesis 3 expects a positive relationship be-

tween professionalization and female candidates. Model 3 does not fully support hypothesis

59

Page 67: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

3. While the coefficient is in the expected direction, the significance falls just outside the

conventional .05 level. Hypothesis 3a deals with the negative interactive effect term limits

have on female candidates and professionalization. As I hypothesize, the interaction is in

the expected direction and just on the cusp of significance. The interactive relationship sup-

ports my theoretical argument that term limits change the incentive structure in a way that

does not favor Democrats— especially female Democrats. When term limits are present,

professionalization decreases and the likelihood a Democratic female will win the election

decreases.

Since logistical regression outputs are not directly interpretable, I run predicted prob-

abilities for models to further interpret the results. I run the predicted probabilities based

on Model 4 to more closely examine how the relationship between term limits and female

Democrats changes with level of professionalization. Further, I set margin of victory to the

mean, which is 42.71%; district type to single member districts, for seats that are open and

not unopposed. I vary the level of professionalization to reflect a citizen legislature (set

to .100 on Squire), a hybrid (.300) and professional (.600). Table 3.4 and Figure 1 below

presents the results for these predicted probabilities.

Female Winner Citizen Legislature Hybrid Professionalized

No Term Limits 0.619 (0.011) 0.639 (0.010) 0.669 (0.014)Term Limits 0.575 (0.014) 0.596 (0.013) 0.627 (0.015)

All margins are significant at p < .05 Std error provided in parentheses

Table 3.4: Predicted Probabilities for Female Democrats

60

Page 68: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Figure 3.1. Female Democrat Success

Table 3.4 provides further evidence to support hypothesis 3 and 3a. As professional-

ization increases, the probability a female will win the seat increases. The predicted proba-

bilities also indicate that at the same level of professionalization, women in the term limited

states are less successful at winning their seat in office. In a citizen legislature, a female is

predicted to win the seat 62% of the time versus 58% of the time for a female in a term

limited state. The difference is also present in hybrid legislatures. Females in states with

no term limits have a 64% predicted probability and females in term limited state only have

a 59% predicted probability to win the seat. Lastly, in professionalized legislatures, female

Democrats are also at a disadvantage in term limited states. In state without term limits the

predicted probability a female will win the election is about 70% compared to states with

term limits where the probability is at 63%.

Figure 3.1 graphically shows the effect term limits and professionalization have on the

probably a female Democrat will win. The table provides confidence intervals to further show

61

Page 69: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

the statistically significant differences between term limits and non term limits. Further,

the figure also shows the differences across levels of professionalization are also significant.

Female Democrats in citizen legislatures have the lowest probability of winning and this

probability is statistically different from the hybrid as well as the most professional.

Overall, Table 3.4 and Figure 3.1 indicate that highly professionalized legislatures in

states without term limits are where female Democrats are the most successful. Females are

least likely to win their seat in states with citizen legislatures and term limits. Further, the

predicted probabilities show female Democrats are more likely to win in states without term

limits. A female candidate’s likelihood of success increases as professionalization increases,

but term limits decrease their likelihood of winning. The margin between term limited and

non term limited states is about 5% for each level of professionalization. The margin between

a citizen legislature, no term limits, and a professionalized, with term limits, is only about

1% point. The small margin further indicates that term limits have a negative effect on

female candidates and this relationship is an interactive one based in part on the level of

professionalization.

Moving to the Republican candidates, Table 3.5 below also includes 4 models based

on the same explanatory and control variables as the Democratic candidate models. The

standard errors are robust standard errors clustered around the candidate. Model 1 is the

simple model that does not include any interactions. Term limits do not have a statistically

significant impact on the likelihood a Republican will win. While the direction is positive

indicating term limits seem to help the likelihood for a Republican win, the level of statistical

significance falls just outside the traditional levels of significance. Further, being a female

candidate does not have a statistically significant effect on the likelihood the success. This

62

Page 70: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

finding seems to suggest being a female Republican neither increases or decreases the likeli-

hood of success. Since professionalization is significant and in a negative direction, Model 1

supports the extant literature finding Republicans are likely to win seats in legislatures with

lower levels of professionalization.

Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Term Limit 0.063 (0.047) 0.136* (0.052) 0.064 (0.047) 0.005 (0.089)Female Candidate -0.003 (0.043) 0.069 (0.048) 0.039 (0.079) 0.022 (0.090)Professionalism (Squire) -0.495* (0.122) -0.491* (0.122) -0.455* (0.137) -0.637* (0.164)Term*Female – -0.347* (0.104) – -0.101 (0.164)Female*Professional – – -0.190 (0.287) 0.219 (0.337)Term Limit*Professional – – – 0.557 (0.296)Term*Female*Professional – – – -1.014 (0.606)Incumbent 5.012* (0.055) 5.014* (0.055) 5.012* (0.055) 5.015* (0.055)Open Seat 2.407* (0.042) 2.408* (0.043) 2.407* (0.043) 2.406* (0.043)Unopposed 7.504* (1.010) 7.504* (1.001) 7.504* (1.001) 7.501* (1.010)Margin of Victory -0.008* (0.001) -0.008* (0.001) -0.008* (0.001) -0.008* (0.001)District Type 0.046 (0.085) 0.043 (0.085) 0.045 (0.085) 0.040 (0.085)Constant -2.375* (0.088) -2.392* (0.088) -2.384* (0.089) -2.355* (0.093)

n =34436R2=0.54

Robust standard errors clustered around legislative districtControls for election years included in the model but suppressed from the table

Table 3.5: Logistical Regression of Republican Candidate Success

Model 2 provides the results for hypothesis 1 which speculates female Republicans

in term limited states will have a higher likelihood of winning. The negative and statis-

tically significant coefficient on the interaction indicates the hypothesis is not supported.

Republican females in term limited states are less likely to win.

Models 3 and 4 relate to hypotheses 4 and 4a dealing with professionalization and

likelihood of winning. Hypothesis 4 states that as professionalization increases, female suc-

cess will decrease. Model 3 shows the interactive relationship between female candidates

63

Page 71: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

and professionalization. The direction is negative and in the expected direction, but the

relationship is not significant, and the interaction is just outside the cusp of significance.

Model 4 presents the 3-way interaction between term limits, female candidates and profes-

sionalization. Hypothesis 4a states that term limits, and lower levels of professionalization

will help female candidates win and is supported by the model. The negative coefficient

(indicating a lower level of professionalization, which is favorable to Republicans) increases

the likelihood a female will win office. The 3-way interaction is in the expected direction

and is statistically significant at a .10 level.

To interpret the results beyond direction and statistical significance, Table 3.6 and

Figure 3.2 provide the predicted probabilities for Republican females varying by level of

professionalization. As with the Democratic predicted probabilities, the the results are for

open, single member districts in opposed seats and the margin of victory is set to the mean

at 40% for Republicans.

Figure 3.2. Female Republican Success

64

Page 72: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Female Winner Citizen Legislature Hybrid Professionalized

No Term Limits 0.501 (0.011) 0.477 (0.012) 0.440 (0.016)Term Limits 0.517 (0.015) 0.493 (0.014) 0.455 (0.017)

All margins are significant at p < .05 Std error provided in parentheses

Table 3.6: Predicted Probabilities for Female Republicans

Table 3.6 and Figure 3.2 above show further support for hypothesis 4a. In general, as

professionalization in the legislature increases, the predicted probability for female success

decreases. Further, term limits have a positive effect on the predicted probabilities for female

candidates success. Overall, females have a higher predicted probability for success in states

with term limits.

In citizen legislatures, females are predicted to win about 50% of the time in non term

limited states versus about 52% of the time in term limited states. This pattern continues

for hybrid legislatures where females are predicted to win about 48% of the time in non term

limited states versus 50% of the time in term limited states. Lastly, female Republicans have

a 44% predicted probability of winning in highly professionalized, non term limited states

and about a 46% probability in term limited states.

Figure 3.2 includes 95% confidence intervals for each level of professionalization.

Model 4 is significant at the .10 level so there is some overlap in the intervals. Overall,

across levels of professionalization, the probability of a female winning is statistically sig-

nificant. Females are less likely to win in the highly professionalized legislatures and their

probability of success is significantly lower when compared to both hybrid and citizen leg-

islatures. The difference term limits make within legislatures is only significant at the .10

level. The difference between term limits and no term limits, as discussed in Table 3.6’s

results, is only about 2% for each level of professionalization.

65

Page 73: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Lastly, across both Democratic and Republican models, all control variables were in

the expected direction. Incumbency, open seat and unopposed races were all positive and

highly significant. Margin of victory is negative and also statistically significant. For both

the Democratic and Republican models, the only control variable not statistically signifiant

is the district type variable which controls for the multimember districts.14

Conclusions and Implications

This chapter discusses the next step in the process of female descriptive representation

in the states; election outcomes. The first chapter finds term limits have a positive effect

on the likelihood a female candidate will emerge, and this chapter presents results on the

likelihood a female will win. Using state politics literature, which looks at incentive structures

for candidates in term limited states, and women in politics literature, which finds when

women run they win, I develop a theory suggesting term limits will increase female descriptive

representation. Further, I examine this by party and find term limits increase the likelihood

a female Republican will win office but decrease the likelihood a female Democrat will win.

Overall, the results compliment congressional literature that finds when women run,

they win. This seems to be the case at the state-level since women are likely to win their

seat 50% of the time, and even more likely if the female is a Democrat. Female Democrats

are predicted to win at high rates (term limits or no term limits, their predicted success

rates range from 58%-67%) and female Republicans are also predicted to win in the range of

about 44%-52%. Further, term limits increase the likelihood a female Republican will win,

14The Appendix includes a logistical regression for Republicans and Democrats in the same model. Toavoid a 4-way interaction, the dependent variable is female winner and party identification replaces femalecandidate. The results are consistent and the new three way interaction between party, term limits andprofessionalization is positive but not statistically significant. These findings are further indication thatmodels separating Republican and Democratic females are useful since Republican females tend to be washedout by Democratic female effects.

66

Page 74: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

by about 2%, suggesting term limits can increase descriptive representation of women.

Term limits have a negative effect on female Democrats but their likelihood of winning

is still high. The high predicted probabilities of success implies that if female Democrats

continue to run, they will continue to win. Since Democratic females hold more seats than

Republican females, term limits should increase the descriptive representation overall. Im-

plications on the long term effect of term limits on descriptive representation should continue

to be examined since parties may adapt new strategies in order to adapt. For example, if

Republican females do well in term limited states, a new strategy may be to actively recruit

more female Republicans to office.

Future research should look to explain the large difference in success rates between fe-

male Republicans and female Democrats. Explanations on the likelihood of female candidate

success differences may be due to strategic candidate entry, campaign finance differences, or

even candidate quality. A more nuanced look at some of these campaign-level/ candidate

specific explanatory factors may be useful.

The next chapter will examine a new set of explanatory variables to determine if

location effects the likelihood a female will emerge and win office. I theorize on how district

demographics such as urbanization, education levels, etc. play a role in the emergence as

well as descriptive representation of female candidates.

67

Page 75: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

[1] Allebaugh, Dalene, and Neil Pinney. 2003. ”The Real Costs of Term Limits: Comparative Study ofCompetition and Electoral Costs.” in The test of time: Coping with legislative term limits.

[2] Ansolabehere, Stephen, and James M. Snyder Jr. 2002. “The incumbency advantage in US elections:An analysis of state and federal offices, 1942-2000.” Election Law Journal 1.3: 315-338.

[3] Bledsoe, Timothy and Mary Herring. 1990. “Victims of Circumstance: Women in Pursuit of PoliticalOffice.” The American Political Science Review. 84:213-223.

[4] Burrell, Barbara C. 1994. A Woman’s Place Is in the House: Campaigning for Congress in the FeministEra. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

[5] Carey, John M., Richard G. Niemi, and Lynda W. Powell.2000. Term limits in state legislatures.University of Michigan Press.

[6] Carroll, Susan J., and Linda MG Zerilli. 1993. “Feminist challenges to political science.” Politicalscience: The state of the discipline II: 55-76.

[7] Carroll, Susan and Krista Jenkins. 2001. “Do Term Limits Help Women Get Elected?” Social ScienceQuarterly. 82/1.

[8] Census Bureau. 2012.

[9] Center for American Women and Politics. 2012. “Women in State Legislatures? Fact Sheet”:www.cawp.rutgers.edu .

[10] Cox and Katz. 1996. “Why did the incumbency advantage in U.S. House elections grow?” AJPS 40:478-497.

[11] Crane, Edward H. 1995. “Testimony before the Subcommittee on the Constitution, Committee on theJudiciary, U.S. Senate.”

[12] Darcy, R, Susan Welch and Janet Clark. 1994. Women, Elections, and Representation. 2nd Edition.Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.

[13] Dolan, Kathleen. 2004. Voting for Women: How the Public Evaluates Women Candidates. Boulder,CO: Westview.

[14] Dolan, Kathleen, and Lynne E. Ford. 1998. “Are All Women State Legislators Alike?.” Women andelective office: Past, present, and future: 73-86.

[15] Dolan, Kathleen. 2009. “The Impact of Gender Stereotyped Evaluations on Support for WomenCandidates.” Political Behavior. 32:69-88.

[16] Elder, Laurel. 2012. “The Partisan Gap among Women State Legislators.” Journal of Women, Politicsand Policy. 33:65-85.

[17] Erikson, Robert. 1971. “The Advantage of Incumbency in Congressional Elections”.Polity. 3: 395-405.

[18] Farmer, R., Rausch, J.D. and Green, J.C., 2003. The test of time: Coping with legislative term limits.Lexington Books.

[19] Ferry, Jonathan. 1994. “Women, Minorities and Term Limits: American’s Path to a RepresentativeCongress”. U.S. Term Limits Foundation Outlook Series.

[20] Fiorina. 1977. “The Case of the Vanishing marginals: The bureaucracy did it” American Political

68

Chapter Bibliography

Page 76: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Science Review. 71:177-81.

[21] Fowler, Linda.1992. A Comment on Competition and Careers. In Gerald Benjamin and Michael J.Lambin. eds., Limiting Legislative Terms Washington, DC: CQ Press.

[22] Foerstel, Karen, and Herbert N. Foerstel. 1996. Climbing the hill: Gender conflict in Congress.Greenwood Publishing Group.

[23] Fox, Richard L. 2000. “Gender and Congressional Elections.” In Gender and American Politics:Women, Men, and the Political Process, eds. Sue Tolleson Rinehart and Jyl J. Josephson. Armonk,NY: M.E. Sharpe.

[24] Fox, Richard and Jennifer Lawless. 2004. “Entering the Arena? Gender and the Decision to Run forOffice.” American Journal of Political Science. 48:264-280.

[25] Fulton, Sarah et, al. 2006. “The Sense of a Women: Gender Ambition, and The Decision to Run forCongress”. Political Research Quarterly. 59: 235-248.

[26] Fulton, Sarah. 2012. “Running Backwards and in High Heels: The Gendered Quality Gap andIncumbent Electoral Success.” Political Research Quarterly. 20:1-12.

[27] Gershon, Sarah. 2012. “When Race, Gender, and the Media Intersect: Campaign News Coverage ofMinority Congresswomen” Journal of Women and Politics. 33:105-125.

[28] Gordon, Sanford C., Gregory A. Huber, and Dimitri Landa. 2007. “Challenger entry and voterlearning.” American Political Science Review 2: 303-320.

[29] Huddy, Leonie, and Nayda Terkildsen. 1993. “Gender Stereotypes and the Perception of Male andFemale Candidates.” American Journal of Political Science. 37: 119-47.

[30] Jacobson and Kernell. 1983. “Strategy and choice in Congressional elections.”

[31] Kazee, Thomas.1994. “Who Runs for Congress ?” Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly.

[32] Kahn, Kim Fridkin. 1992. ”Does Being Male Help? An Investigation of the Effects of Candidate Genderand Campaign Coverage on Evaluations of U.S Senate Candidates” Journal of Politics 54: 497-517.

[33] King, David and Richard E. Matland. 2003. “Sex and the Grand Old Party: An ExperimentalInvestigation of the Effect of Candidate Sex on Support for a Republican Candidate.” AmericanPolitics Research. 31: 595-612.

[34] Koch, Jeffrey. 2000. “Do Citizens Apply Gender Stereotypes to Infer Candidates’ Ideological Orienta-tions?” Journal of Politics 62: 414-29.

[35] Koch, Jeffrey. 2002. “Gender Stereotypes and Citizens’ Impressions of House Candidates’ IdeologicalOrientations.” American Journal of Political Science. 46(2), 453-462.

[36] Lindquist, S. A. 2007. “State Politics and the Judiciary Codebook. Predictability and the Rule of Law:Overruling Decisions in State Supreme Courts.” Nashville, TN: National Science Foundation GrantSES #0550618.

[37] McDermott, Monika L. 1997. “Voting cues in low-information elections: Candidate gender as a socialinformation variable in contemporary United States elections.” American Journal of Political Science:270-283.

[38] Meinke, Scott R., and Edward B. Hasecke. 2003. “Term limits, professionalization, and partisan controlin US state legislatures.” Journal of Politics 65: 898-908.

[39] Milyo, Jeffrey and Samantha Schosberg. 2000. “Gender Bias and Selection Bias in House Elections.”

69

Page 77: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Public Choice. 105:41-59.

[40] Mooney, Christopher. 2009. “Term Limits as a Boon to Legislative Scholarship: A Review.” StatePolitics and Policy Quarterly. 9:204- 228.

[41] National Conference of State Legislatures. 2011 “Legislative Term Limits Overview?http://www.ncsl.org/ .

[42] Osborn L, Tracy. 2012. How Women Represent Women: Political Parties, Gender and Representationin the State Legislatures. Oxford University Press.

[43] Palmer, Barbara and Dennis Simon. 2005. “When Women Run Against Women: The Hidden Influenceof Female Incumbents in Elections to the U.S. House of Representatives, 1956-2002.” Gender andPolitics. 1:39-63.

[44] Palmer, Barbara and Dennis Simon. 2006. Breaking the Political Glass Ceiling: Women and Congres-sional Elections. New York: Routlege.

[45] Reed, W. Robert, and D. Eric Schansberg. 1996. ”An analysis of the impact of congressional termlimits on turnover and party balance.” In Legislative Term Limits: Public Choice Perspectives, pp.129-143. Springer Netherlands.

[46] Rosenwasser, Shirley Miller, and Norma G. Dean. 1989. “Gender role and political office.” Psychologyof Women Quarterly 13: 77-85.

[47] Sanbonmatsu, Kira. 2002. “Political parties and the recruitment of women to state legislatures.”Journal of Politics 64: 791-809.

[48] Sanbonmatsu, Kira. 2006. Where women run. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

[49] Sanbonmatsu, Kira and Kathleen Dolan. 2009. “Do Gender Stereotypes Transcend Party?” PoliticalResearch Quarterly 62: 485-494.

[50] Schwindt-Bayer, L. A. and Mishler, W. 2005. “An Integrated Model of Women?s Representation.” TheJournal of Politics. 67/2: 407-428.

[51] Seltzer, Richard A., Jody Newman, and Melissa Voorhees Leighton. 1997. Sex as a Political Variable:Women as Candidates and Voters in U.S. Elections. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

[52] Swers, Michele. 2002. The Difference Women Make. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

[53] Werner and Mayer. 2007. Public Election Funding, Competition, and candidate Gender.

70

Page 78: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

CHAPTER 4

WOMEN-FRIENDLY DISTRICTS

Abstract

This chapter explores the possibility of women-friendly districts in U.S. state legis-

latures. Examining the lower chamber in each state, I model the theory after Palmer and

Simon’s (2006) seminal work on congressional women-friendly districts. Further, I theorize

on how each state’s electoral variations have the possibility of helping districts become more

women friendly. Using logistical regression, I find women-friendly districts are present in the

states and as districts become more women-friendly, females are more likely to run and win

office.

Introduction

The first and second chapter examine the positive effect term limits have on female

candidates. Specifically, I examine whether term limits change the incentive structure for

candidates to seek and win office. The findings suggest, contrary to initial studies (Carroll

and Jenkins 2001; Bernstein and Chad 2003), that term limits are beneficial to females. Term

limits increase the likelihood of female candidate emergence and success in a term limited

states. While the two previous chapters focused mainly on the candidate-level electoral

context of the race, this chapter includes district demographics as part of picture.

As previously discussed in the first two chapters, the number of females in state

legislatures has become rather stagnant since the early 1990s. Yet, there is exists a puzzle

in that there are difference across the states– women are gaining seats overtime in some

states but losing seats in other states. For example, as of 2015, Vermont’s legislature is 41%

females. The percent of females has increased by about 10% over the last ten years, which is

71

Page 79: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

counter to the overall pattern of stagnation seen across all 50 states (CAWP 2015). Further,

women hold the most seats in western states that include Colorado, Washington, Oregon,

Montana, Arizona and Nevada (CAWP 2015). These patterns across the states should be

explored to determine whether or not this stagnation in descriptive representation is likely

to continue.

At the congressional level, Palmer and Simon (2006) created an index which uses

district demographic variables to predict the ‘women-friendliness’ of a district. The idea is

that certain districts are historically better for women since women in these districts tend

to run and win at higher rates than women in other districts. Palmer and Simon (2006) find

that when a congressional district has a high average income, a more educated population,

is geographically small and in a racially diverse and urban area, female candidates are much

more likely to win office. This chapter seeks to expand our understanding of what constitutes

a ‘women-friendly’ electoral environment by examining state legislative elections. I explore

whether district variation in demographics, as well as state legislative variation(in the form of

professionalization and term limits) also help explain where female candidates are emerging

and winning.

Further, I will determine whether term limited states are more or less women-friendly.

Since results from chapter one and two indicate that women are more likely to run and win

in term limited states, I propose there may be a positive interactive relationship between

term limits and women-friendly districts. Term limited districts with high levels of women-

friendliness, will be more likely to have female candidates emerge and win than non term

limited districts.

This chapter proceeds as follows, I will discuss the extant literature on demographic

72

Page 80: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

characteristics effecting female descriptive representation in state legislatures. Next, I of-

fer a theory that incorporates how state legislative characteristics such as term limits and

professionalization condition the impact the friendliness of a district has on emergence and

descriptive representation. Then, I discuss the design and method I use to test my theory.

Then I run a series of logistical regressions with predicted probabilities to substantively in-

terpret how female candidates are effected by the women-friendliness of a district. Lastly, I

conclude with a brief discussion of the results and implications this chapter has on future

work.

Literature

Fenno’s (1978) observational study emphasizes the important effect of district demo-

graphic characteristics on a representative’s behavior. Each representative recognizes their

district has a unique set of demographic characteristics and that these differences matter for

reelection. The representatives emphasize geography, diversity, jobs, and incomes; Most of

which Palmer and Simon (2006) use in predicting women-friendly districts and will also be

discussed in this chapter.1

Below, I discuss four of the main explanations in the extant literature for why can-

didates tend to emerge and win office in recognizable patterns. Utilizing both state, and

congressional level literature, the focus is how the geography, party, diversity, and socioe-

conomic make-up of state legislative districts influence candidates and their election into

office.

1Rule’s (1981) cross-national analysis focuses on state legislatures and is an early study pointing to contextualdistrict factors that influence females and where they run for office.

73

Page 81: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Political Culture

Political culture is an underlying explanation for regional similarities and differences

across the states (Elazar 1966). And while there is large debate over the measures and with-

standing of distinct political cultures, Elazar’s (1966) three state political culture classifica-

tion is still the leading typology. The three political cultures are Traditionalistic, Moralistic,

and Individualistic. In the context of women in office, states with the same political culture

have similar patterns of women gaining and maintaining office overtime.

Traditionalistic states are typically southern states where social connectedness mat-

ters and politics is for the elite. Further, party politics is not particularly strong and the

driving force behind recruitment; rather, families are seen as the important recruitment

ground for future candidates (Elazar 1966; 1984). Women in these states have seen the most

growth in female legislators overtime (Norrander and Wilcox 2014). Women gaining seats in

the more traditionalistic states such as Texas and Alabama is most likely due to the fact that

their numbers were so few to begin with, there is a lot of ground to be covered.2 For example,

Texas and Alabama’s legislatures were 16% and 5% in 1993, respectively. Both were lower

than the national average of around 20% at the time. By 2015, the percents increased to

20% and 14%, respectively. Again, both states are still below the overall average of 24%

females legislatures, but are increasing overtime (Norrander and Wilcox 2014; CAWP 2015).

States that have a Moralistic political culture are usually northern states, where

politics is for the good of society and politicians are public servants (Elazar 1966). Women

have done well gaining office in Moralistic states (Norrander and Wilcox 2014). For example,

Vermont and Colorado are both moralistic and regularly rank in the top 10 states for their

2Explanations for few females in office, especially in the South sometimes center around the idea that femaleswere late to be included in the political system. This is generally measured by voter participation (Cassel1979)

74

Page 82: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

high numbers of women in office. While these states have higher numbers of women in office,

they are much more stagnant. Colorado is also a term limited state and after an initial loss

in female descriptive representation, women now make up an all time high of 42% of the

seats in the state. Yet, some Moralistic states have decreased their overall number of women

in office. In 1993 Washington (not term limited) had 39% females in office, but in 2015, this

number decreases to 34% (Norrander and Wilcox 2014; CAWP 2015).

The last type of political culture is the Individualistic culture. Individualistic states

usually have traditional political party organizations, and politics is generally a game of

personal gains (Elazar 1966). Traditional party organizations in these states do not favor

females since there is a reluctance to recruit and endorse female candidates (Sanbonmatsu

2002; Norrander and Wilcox 2014). One example of a state characterized as individualistic

is Ohio. The percent of women in the legislature was particularly low (11-13% throughout

the late 1980s, early 1990s) until the mid 1990s when the percent hovered around 24. After

the implementation of term limits in 2000, the percent of females increased, decreased and

has now steadily increased since 2008 with women making up 25% of the legislature in 2015

(CAWP 2015). In general, individualistic states have also seen increases in the number of

women in office overtime.

Party

Extant literature finds party identification serves as a main cue for voters (Campbell

et al 1960; Flanigan and Zingale 1994, 2002; Lau and Redlawsk 2001; Lau and Sears 1986;

Rahn 1993). A majority of the time, Republican voters vote Republican and Democrats vote

Democrat. Yet, research finds voters view the parties through a gendered lens and there is an

intersection between the two (Anderson, Lewis and Baird 2011). Therefore, party alone is not

75

Page 83: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

able to predict the women-friendliness of a district (Palmer and Simon 2006). Overall, voter

stereotypes of a candidate’s sex is rather complex (Anderson, Lewis and Baird 2011) and

therefore, party is an important part of the picture for predicting women-friendly districts.

Demographics

At the congressional level, research varies as to whether or not the racial diversity

of a district impacts the number of women in office. Burrell (1984) finds racial diversity

in districts have no impact on women candidates. Other studies find women do better in

districts with a more racially diverse population (Welch 1985; Palmer Simon 2006). Lastly,

research also finds women of color do well in majority-minority districts (Bedolla, Tate and

Wong 2014).

Further, urbanization and population density also effect female descriptive represen-

tation. Democratic candidates tend to win elections in densely populated, urban areas and

Republican candidates fair better in rural districts that are larger in geographic scope (Lang,

Sanchez, Berube 2008; Palmer and Simon 2006). In particular, female House members tend

to represent more urban districts (Burrell 1992; Darcy and Schramm 1977; Diamond 1977;

Rule 1981; Welch 1985; Welch et al. 1985; but see Kirkpatrick 1974; Werner 1966). Women

fair better in urban areas due to an ease in recruitment efforts because there are more poten-

tial female candidates in the area (Darcy and Schramm 1977) as well as a larger number of

seats available (Rule 1981). Further, women are perceived as being ‘better’ fit to deal social

welfare issues (Rule 1981; Koch 2000; Dolan 2009; Fulton 2011) and these issues tend to be

of great concern in urban areas, giving females an edge (Rule 1981).

76

Page 84: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Socioeconomic Factors

Socioeconomic factors within districts are shown to predict electoral outcomes. Amongst

them are average income, education levels within the district, marriage statistics as well as

occupations (blue-collar versus white-collar). Historically, Republicans were rather success-

ful in districts with high incomes because people with lower incomes were much more likely to

support Democratic candidates. Recent literature finds this pattern is not so clear anymore

because wealthy districts are also known to support Democratic candidates and vice versa

(Frank 2004; Gelman 2009). In regards to women in office and wealth of district, research

finds women in Congress are more likely to be elected from wealthier districts (Burrell 1994;

Nechemias 1987; Rule 1981; Welch 1985; Palmer and Simon 2006).

Education is also an important district characterization. Overtime, the education

levels of Americans has increased (also leading to a decrease in blue-collar workers). Specif-

ically, the number of of high school drop outs has decreased while the number of college

educated adults has increased (Census 2015). Female candidates are more likely to emerge

and win in areas with higher levels of education. Studies suggest this is the case because more

educated populations do not hold traditional views on women’s roles (Welch and Sigelman

1982; Arceneaux 2001; Palmer and Simon 2006). Research also finds women who run for

office are highly educated (Fox and Lawless 2004) Further, income and education are highly,

and positively correlated— since women are more likely to win office in wealthier districts,

they are also more likely to emerge and gain office in more educated districts (Palmer and

Simon 2006).

77

Page 85: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Electoral Variations

A point of departure from Palmer and Simon’s (2006) study on women-friendly dis-

tricts is to include a discussion on how the electoral makeup of the state’s legislature impacts

the friendliness of a district.

Literature on the impact the professionalization of the legislature has on women’s

numbers in office (largely discussed in chapter 2) has mixed findings. Squire (1992) finds the

professionalization of the legislature has little to no impact on women’s numbers in office but

Sanbonmatsu (2002) finds mixed evidence for whether professionalization impacts women’s

numbers in office. Further, my analysis in chapters one and two suggest as professionalization

increases, women’s numbers decrease. Since the findings seem to be mixed, including a

discussion on how professionalization may impact female candidates and teasing out the

relationship in further analysis is important.

Lastly, this dissertation stresses the importance of term limits on the likelihood of

female candidate emergence and success. Conventional wisdom suspects term limits will

increase female descriptive representation because females do well winning open seats. Yet,

initial studies found term limits negatively impact female numbers in office (Carroll and

Jenkins 2001; Bernstein and Chadha 2004). The theory and analysis in the previous two

chapters provides long term evidence supporting the conventional wisdom that term limits

increase female candidate emergence as well as overall numbers in office. Further, looking at

the term limited states as a whole, of the 15 states, only two (Maine and Arizona) experienced

decreases levels of women in office from 1993 to 2011 (Norrander and Wilcox 2014). The

differences in the overall percentage lost for both these states is rather small. Maine had a

3% difference and Arizona had a 1% loss in female descriptive representation.

78

Page 86: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Women-Friendly State Legislative Districts Theory

Palmer and Simon (2006) find women-friendly districts are distinct from party-friendly

districts. I theorize demographic characteristics making for a women-friendly district at the

state-level are similar to the congressional-level demographics. Since politicians tend to

follow a pipeline into office and gradually work their way up through the system, similar

women-friendly demographics across levels of government is a reasonable claim. Therefore,

if districts are women friendly at the congressional level, the women who were more easily

elected to Congress likely came from state legislatures with similar electability features. Be-

low I form a theory which combines demographic characteristics with institutional features

within a district and how they are likely to positively effect the women-friendliness of a

district.

District Demographics

The partisan makeup of a district is likely to effect the women-friendliness of the

district. Female Democrats make up the majority of female officeholders and therefore it

is likely these women are being elected from districts leaning more Democratic. A district

leaning Democratic is likely to increase the women-friendliness of a district but it is not

the only factor correlated with increasing whether a female candidate runs/wins. Women

friendly and party friendly are different since female Republicans can benefit from voter

stereotypes and run and win in districts favoring the Democratic Party.

Further, not all open seats (created by term limits or not) are created equally. In other

words, some open seats may be safe Democratic seats while others may be safe Republican

seats and still others seats may be competitive seats where the party in charge alternates

frequently (despite the makeup of the legislature and how ‘Democratic versus Republican’

79

Page 87: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

it is). If a Republican seats opens, a female might not run since females are more likely to

run as Democrats. Further, if a Democratic safe seat opens, the chances of a female running

and winning may be higher since there are more female Democrats. Examining women-

friendliness in a way that captures safe versus competitive seats is important. Women across

both parties should be more successful in safe (or core) districts with high levels of women-

friendliness.

Palmer and Simon (2006) find a racially diverse district is more likely to be women-

friendly. A racially diverse district is more likely to lean Democratic in elections, especially

given that a majority of African American voters are Democrats. Given the previous chap-

ter’s discussion on voter ideological stereotypes, a liberal leaning district may help women,

especially those running as a Democrat. Furthermore, extant research finds female (and

black) legislators tend to represent black interests (see: Thomas and Welch 1991; Swers

1998; Canon 1999; Carroll 2001; Tate 2003) Therefore, minority voters may assume women

are better at representing their interests and will be more likely to elect women.

More urban areas are likely to be more women-friendly. Urban, metropolitan areas

are likely to have a larger concern for social welfare issues. Women are viewed as better suited

to handle issues of social policy which can give them an advantage in elections. Therefore,

an area that is likely to place emphasis on social policy concerns, such as urban areas, may

be more willing to elect a female over a male.

Lastly, education, income levels, and women in the workforce in a district are likely

to be important contributing factors to the women-friendliness of a district. Education levels

and income are positively correlated since the likelihood of making more money increases as

education levels increase. Districts with high levels of education, women in the workforce,

80

Page 88: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

and/or income will be more likely to be women friendly. Educated populations have more

women working and hold less traditional views of women, which help dissipate stereotypes

voters may hold over whether women are qualified to run for office. Further, women in these

areas are likely to be educated, which may foster an environment in which females are active,

and aware of politics–making women more likely to be recruited in these areas and willing

to run for office.

Institutional Variation: Professionalization and Term Limits

The level of professionalization within a state may also condition the impact of dis-

trict’s level of women-friendliness. I suspect, as professionalization in a legislature increases,

the women friendliness in a district will decrease. This is largely due to research suggesting

women seem to be less likely to run and hold office in more professionalized legislatures.

Evidence from chapter one suggests as professionalism increases, women are less likely to

emerge. Also, chapter two finds higher levels of professionalization is beneficial for Demo-

cratic females but not Republican females.

I expect the implementation of term limits to have a positive effect on the women-

friendliness of a district. Term limits leads to higher turnover within legislatures. Since the

incumbency advantage is lessened by the implementation of term limits, females will have

more opportunities to run and win elections in districts with termed-out legislators. Running

and winning against an established incumbent is difficult; term limits decrease the electoral

advantage incumbents normally enjoy term after term.

Further, results from chapters one and two stand as further evidence that term limits

are increasing the number of females emerging and winning. An environment which creates

the opportunity for more females to run and win is one that is ‘women-friendly’ and should

81

Page 89: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

therefore have a positive impact on the level of friendliness seen within each district.

Most importantly, is the conditional relationship term limits have on women-friendly

districts. Since the findings in the previous chapters suggest term limits increase female

emergence and success, I expect when term limits are interacted with women-friendly dis-

tricts, these districts provide females an even greater advantage. For example, in comparing

districts that are not women-friendly, having term limits increases the likelihood a female

will emerge and win than they otherwise would have in a non term limited district. Further, I

expect this relationship in the most women-friendly districts as well. Females in term limited

states will be much more likely to emerge and win than in the non-term limited states.

This interaction is important since not all vacant term limited seats are women-

friendly. Given the research finding women lost seats in the initial implementation of term

limits, it is important to examine the nature of the vacant seats. There are some geographic

areas as previously discussed that women are historically left out. Term limits conditioned on

the women-friendliness of a district is a unique way to examine the relationship between term

limits and female emergence and success. While term limits may provide a small increase

in the likelihood a female candidate will emerge and win, the likelihood of winning a term

limited seat will increase more as the women-friendliness of a district increases. Essentially,

where a female candidate runs matters and running in districts that are more women-friendly

(especially when term limited) increases the likelihood of success.

Therefore:

H1: As a state legislative districts becomes more women-friendly, the likelihood a female

candidate will emerge increases.

H2: As a state legislative districts becomes more women-friendly, the likelihood a female

82

Page 90: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

candidate will win increases.

H3: Female candidate emergence increases as the women-friendliness of a district increases,

and term limits are implemented.

H4: Female candidate success increases as the women-friendliness of a district increases, and

term limits are implemented.

Data and Design

The unit of analysis is the candidate-year and I examine general elections in single

member districts. To measure the effect women-friendly districts have on female candidates,

I use an original dataset that combines candidate-level data with state legislative district

data. The candidate-level data comes largely from the State Legislative Election Returns

(SLER): 1967-2010 (ICPSR 2014). For this analysis, I use the time period from 2000-20103

and coded each candidate’s gender into the SLER dataset.4 The state legislative district

demographics data comes from the U.S. Census Bureau. Using the 2000 Sample Data on

State-Legislative Districts (Lower House), I compiled urbanization, diversity, income, women

in the workforce, and education into a dataset which was then merged with the SLER data.

Method

To test the hypotheses, I first ran a series of means tests to determine the difference

across parties as well as across gender (See Appendix). Palmer and Simon (2006) note

women-friendly districts are unique from party-friendly districts, and the difference in means

tests determines which explanatory variables are unique to gender. For presentation of the

3I use this single time period of 2000-2010 to control for redistricting.

4As a robustness check, I reference CAWP (Center for American Women and Politics) and NCSL (NationalConference of State Legislatures) databases to check total women candidates and women in office by year.

83

Page 91: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

effect women-friendly districts have on female emergence and success, I compile a women-

friendly district variable for each party and run two logistical regression models. I follow-up

with predicted probabilities for a more substantive interpretation of the effect women-friendly

districts have on female emergence and success.

Variables

Dependent

The dependent variable for the first model is female candidate emergence. This is a

dichotomous variables which measures the sex of a candidate running in the general election.

Males are coded ‘0’ and females are coded ‘1’. The second model’s dependent variable is

female winners. This variable is also dichotomous where a candidate who is female and won

the general election is coded ‘1’ and male winners are coded ‘0’.

Independent Variables

The first explanatory variable is the women-friendly district variable. I use six

district-level variables to compile the ‘women-friendly district’ variable: percent democratic

vote share, percent black, urbanization, average income, education (percent holding college

degree), and percent women in the workforce. The women-friendly district variable is a count

variable ranging from 0-7 with 0 being the least friendly and 7 being the most friendly.5 The

variable is a difference between the national average and district average. For example, if

the national urban average in core Democratic districts is 50% and an individual district is

over 50%, then the district is more women-friendly in regards to urbanization than other

districts. This process is done for each of the six variables and then summed to create the

5All districts outside of the South are considered more women-friendly and are also a part of the women-friendly district count. For example, all state districts not in the South will be at least 1 on the women-friendlydistrict variable.

84

Page 92: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

0-7 count variable.

The variable is compiled separately for each party after determining core Democratic

and core Republican districts. There are six election periods for the time span of this data6.

A core district is one in which the party won at least five of the six election periods7 in

the study (2000-2010). A district is also considered a core district if the term length of

the legislature is four years8 (versus two) and the party won at least 2 of the three election

periods.

The next set of districts are the swing districts. Swing districts are districts that are

not core Democratic or core Republican districts. A district is a swing district if each party

won the seat anywhere from 2-4 times. For example, in a two year term legislature, a swing

district could be one where Democrats won the seat 2 times and a Republican won the seat

the other 4 elections.

Table 4.1 below shows the distribution of core Democratic, core Republican seat, and

swing seats. Core Democratic seats make up about 34% of the sample and core Republican

seats make up about 30% of the sample. The majority of seats are in swing districts and make

up about 36% of the sample. Since the data is candidate-level, the distribution represents

the total number of candidates running in the core districts, rather than the number of core

districts. This also explains the larger number of candidates in swing districts; theoretically

these seats are likely to be more competitive and less likely to have no opposition. Core

Democratic and Republican districts are likely to be less competitive– having a larger number

of unopposed races.

6The election periods are: 2000, 2002, 2004, 2006, 2008, 2010

7For states where terms are two years.

8The election periods for these states are generally 2000, 2004, 2008.

85

Page 93: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

District Frequency Percent

Core Democratic 17,242 33.85%Core Republican 15,416 30.26%Swing District 18,286 35.89%

Table 4.1: State Legislative District Descriptives

Term limits is the second main independent variable and is coded ‘1’ for states with

term limits and ‘0’ for state without term limits. States will be coded as ‘0’ until their

implementation of term limits for that particular state begins. Therefore, there is not set

year for when the term limited states will be coded to ‘1’ and the value is dependent upon

implementation.

The last independent variable is an interaction between women-friendly districts and

term limits. I expect a positive interactive relationship between term limits and women-

friendly districts. Term limits increase the likelihood a female will emerge and win a seat

across each level of of the women-friendly district variable.

Controls

The first three controls are in both emergence and success models. This first control

in both models is incumbent. It is a dichotomous variable where ‘0’ is a non-incumbent and

‘1’ is an incumbent. The second control is open seat. This is a dichotomous variable coded ‘0’

for a seat where an incumbent is running and ‘1’ if the seat is vacant and has no incumbent

running. Lastly, professionalization is a measure is from the Squire index and comes from

Vanderbilt University’s State Politics and Judiciary dataset. The measure is a 0-1 interval

where 0 is the least professionalized and 1 is the most professionalized. The measure takes

into account whether the legislature is full-time versus part-time, how much legislators are

paid, staff size, etc. For more details on the measure see Squire 1992. As literature, and

86

Page 94: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

my theory states, I expect highly professionalized states to have a negative impact on the

overall women-friendliness of districts.

The next set of control variables are also in both emergence and success model.

They are Elazar’s (1966) three classifications for a state’s political culture: Individualistic,

Moralistic and Traditionalistic. To measure these, I created two dummy variables. The first

is Individualistic and the second is Traditionalistic. Therefore, Moralistic is the baseline

category.

The last two controls are in the success models which capture to electoral environment

surrounding the race. The first is unopposed which is a dichotomous variable. This variable

is coded as ‘0’ for races in which at least two candidates run for office and ‘1’ where a

candidate runs in an uncontested seat. The second is margin of victory which is an interval

variable capturing the percent difference in vote share between the winning candidate and

the losing candidate(s).

Results

Table 4.2 provides the logistical regression analysis for female candidate emergence.

The table has a column for each party model: core and swing districts. The women-friendly

district variable is positive and signifiant for each model. This means that as a district

becomes more women-friendly (i.e.; more democratic, diverse, urban, educated, wealthier,

women working, non Southern state), a female candidate is more likely to emerge. The

political culture variables are also statistically significant and in the expected direction for

the core districts; political culture does not have a statistically significant impact on female

emergence in the swing districts. Further, the last set of state-level variables, term limits and

87

Page 95: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

professionalization, do not have a statistically significant effect on female emergence.9 The

models indicate that women-friendly districts are present in state-legislative districts and

have a positive effect on the likelihood of a female candidate emerging. To further interpret

the effect women-friendly district have on female emergence, I provide predicted probabilities

below.

9In the simple models with no interaction, women friendly district variable is significant in all models butterm limits are on the cusp of significance.

88

Page 96: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Variable Core Republican Core Democrat Swing Republican Swing Democrat

Women Friendly District 0.148* (0.028) 0.157* (0.028) 0.063* (0.017) 0.080* (0.019)Individualistic -0.191* (0.075) -0.337* (0.075) -0.087 (0.077) -0.075 (0.077)Traditionalistic -0.221* (0.082) -0.170* (0.089) -0.160 (0.078) -0.123 (0.079)Term Limit 0.157 (0.166) -0.084 (0.150) -0.169 (0.156) -0.062 (0.137)Professionalism (Squire) -0.052 (0.257) -0.141 (0.232) -0.423 (0.276) -0.354 (0.276)Term Limit*WFD -0.052 (0.047) 0.052 (0.048) 0.049 (0.043) 0.020 (0.043)Incumbent -0.381* (0.065) 0.391* (0.061) 0.105* (0.046) 0.091* (0.046)Open Seat -0.202* (0.053) 0.352* (0.054) 0.068 (0.051) 0.062 (0.051)Constant -1.500* (0.118) -1.464* (0.124) -1.009* (0.093) -1.038* (0.090)

n =15020 n =16895 n=17919 n=17919

Robust standard errors clustered around legislative districtControls for election years included in the model but suppressed from the table

(See Appendix for full model with year dummies)

Table 4.2: Logistical Regression of Female Candidate Emergence

89

Page 97: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Figure 4.1. Core Democratic Female Emergence

.2.3

.4.5

Prob

abilit

y C

andi

date

is F

emal

e

0 2 4 6Democratic Women Friendly District

Female Democratic Emergence

Figure 4.1 shows the predicted probabilities for female candidate emergence in open

seat races in term limited states10. The women-friendly district variable ranges from 0-7 and

women are more likely to emerge in districts that are more women-friendly. In the least

women-friendly district, 0, a female democratic candidate is predicted to emerge around

24% of the time versus a women-friendly district, at 6, a female is likely to emerge about

46% of the time in these core Democratic districts.

10The political culture for all the predicted probabilities is set to Moralistic and other variables are setto their mean. Consistent with hypothesis 2, the Moralistic political culture is the most women-friendly.Females in Moralistic states are predicted to emerge about 3% more than in Individualist or Traditionalisticstates.

90

Page 98: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Figure 4.2. Core Republican Female Emergence

.15

.2.2

5.3

.35

.4Pr

obab

ility

Can

dida

te is

Fem

ale

0 2 4 6Republican Women Friendly Districts

Republican Female Emergence

Predicted probabilities for female Republican emergence are in Figure 4.2. As with

the Democratic women-friendly districts, the probability a female Republican will emerge

increases as the district becomes more women-friendly. Republican females are predicted to

emerge around 34% of the time in most women-friendly core Republican districts versus only

18% of the time in the least women-friendly districts.

Women-friendly districts are also present across the swing districts. As Figure 4.3

and 4.4 indicate, female emergence increases, for Democrats and Republicans, as a district

becomes more women-friendly. Women emerge around 30-33% of the time in districts that

have 4 to 6 ‘women-friendly’ features. On the low end of the women-friendly scale, females

emerge around 24-26% of the time. Overall, districts that have more women-friendly features

(more urban, diverse, higher education, higher income, more women in the workforce, and

higher democratic vote share) have more females emerge as candidates. The next set of

models and figures examine the relationship between women-friendly districts and female

91

Page 99: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

success.

Figure 4.3. Swing Democratic Female Emergence

.2.2

5.3

.35

.4Pr

obab

ility

Can

dida

te is

Fem

ale

0 2 4 6Democratic Women Friendly Districts

Swing Districts: Democratic

Figure 4.4. Swing Republican Female Emergence

.2.2

5.3

.35

Prob

abilit

y C

andi

date

is F

emal

e

0 2 4 6Republican Women Friendly Districts

Swing Districts: Republican

92

Page 100: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Variable Core Republican Core Democrat Swing Republican Swing Democrat

Women Friendly District 0.173* (0.046) 0.140* (0.039) 0.043 (0.027) 0.034 (0.029)Individualistic 0.001 (0.106) -0.214* (0.089) -0.145 (0.106) -0.140 (0.107)Traditionalistic -0.137 (0.132) -0.253* (0.113) -0.310* (0.123) -0.315* (0.124)Term Limit 0.033 (0.251) -0.058 (0.200) -0.227 (0.222) -0.193 (0.192)Professionalism (Squire) 0.496 (0.354) -0.211 (0.264) -0.365 (0.384) -0.272 (0.380)Term Limit*WFD -0.018 (0.069) 0.022 (0.061) 0.064 (0.058) 0.060 (0.060)Incumbent 6.358* (0.233) 6.541* (0.190) 3.320* (0.133) 3.319* (0.133)Open Seat 3.097* (0.186) 3.349* (0.145) 1.605* (0.116) 1.604* (0.116)Unopposed 4.163* (0.650) 3.724* (0.338) 2.935* (0.487) 2.936* (0.486)Margin of Victory 0.023* (0.003) 0.012* (0.002) 0.016* (0.002) 0.016* (0.002)Constant -6.272* (0.341) -5.458* (0.233) -3.438* (0.221) -3.388* (0.212)

n =7599 n =9463 n=5842 n=5842

Robust standard errors clustered around legislative districtControls for election years included in the model but suppressed from the table

(See Appendix for full model with year dummies)

Table 4.3: Logistical Regression of Female Success

93

Page 101: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table 4.3 is the results for the likelihood a female will win. Consistent with the

emergence model and hypotheses, females are more likely to win as the women-friendliness

of a district increases. In the core Democratic and Republican models, the women-friendly

district variable is positive and signifiant. For the swing districts, the women-friendly district

variable is in the expected direction and on the cusp of significance11. Also of note, the

interaction between term limits and women-friendly districts is in the expected direction for

each of the models but not statistically significant at conventional levels. The interactive

effect between term limits and women-friendly districts is on the cusp of significance in the

swing district models implying term limits have a greater, positive effect for female winners

in the swing districts. Further, the political culture variables are in the expected direction12;

moralistic is the base line and traditionalistic and individualistic have a negative effect on

the likelihood a female will win a seat.

As with the emergence models, I run predicted probabilities to substantively interpret

the effect women-friendly districts, and term limits have on female candidate success. The

predicted probabilities are for term limited, Moralistic states with all other variables set to

their mean.13 Figures 4.5 and 4.6 show how an increase in a district’s women-friendliness also

increases the probability of female candidate success. Figure 4.5 shows Democratic females

win about 20% of the time in districts that are least women-friendly versus about 38-41% of

the time in the most women-friendly districts.

11In the simple model with no interaction between women-friendly district and term limits, the women-friendly district variable is significant and in the expected direction across all model

12with the exception of individualistic in the Republican model.

13Female candidates are more successful in Moralistic states. They are predicted to win about 3% more ateach level of the women-friendly variable in comparison to the Individualists and Traditionalistic states.

94

Page 102: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Figure 4.5. Core Democratic Female Success

.1.2

.3.4

.5Pr

obab

ility

a Fe

mal

e W

ins

0 2 4 6Democratic Women-Friendly District

Democratic Female Success

Figure 4.6. Core Republican Female Success

.1.1

5.2

.25

.3Pr

obab

ility

a Fe

mal

e W

ins

0 2 4 6Republican Women-Friendly District

Republican Female Success

Figure 4.6 above shows female Republican success increases as a district becomes

more women-friendly. At the lower end of the women-friendly scale, the probability of a

female Republican winning a seat is low–around 11%. The probability of success is nearly

95

Page 103: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

tripled in the most women-friendly districts. The probability of female success rates are

around 25-29% in districts with 6-7 women-friendly characteristics.14

Conclusions and Implications

The chapter finds Palmer and Simon’s (2006) women-friendly districts are also present

at the state-level. The same demographic characteristics are present in each of the models;

women run and win more seats in areas that are more diverse, more urban, more democratic,

more educated, have higher levels of income, more women in the workforce and are outside

the South. Further, the political culture of a state matters. Women are more likely to run and

win in Moralistic political culture states than they are in Individualistic or Traditionalistic

states. Contrary to my hypothesis, term limits do not seem to have a positive interactive

effect with women-friendly districts to increase female emergence and success. The borderline

significance findings may be due to the majority of females running and winning in mid-range

women-friendly districts (i.e. with 3-5 features). With fewer women running and winning in

the least and most friendly districts, this may be washing out some effects term limits might

have on women-friendliness.

Results from the chapter show that even in the most women-friendly districts, female

candidates win less than 50% of the races in these districts. The likelihood of emerging

and winning increases as women-friendliness increases, but even the most women-friendly

districts do not guarantee a female winner; Especially if a female does not run. Overall, the

results for descriptive representation at the state-level are promising since women are more

likely to run and win in the women-friendly districts. Yet, what about the districts that are

14I do not include predicted probabilities for female success rates in swing districts since women-friendlydistricts are not statistically significant in the model. Success rates for female Democrats and Republicansin the swing districts range from 20-25% but the confidence intervals cross at all levels of the women-friendlydistrict variable

96

Page 104: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

not women-friendly? The implications for descriptive representation of women in districts

that do not produce female candidates or winners is something to consider.

In the future, inclusion of states with multi-member districts is a great opportunity to

further examine women-friendly districts in the states. Further, the current women-friendly

district measure weighs all points of the women-friendly district variables the same. Women

may be more successful in highly urbanized areas versus highly diverse areas. For example, in

some districts, urbanization might matter for female emergence more than diversity within

the district. Perhaps, this is what is happening in the swing districts where the women-

friendly district variable was not statistically significant. The seats in the swing districts

are much more competitive and perhaps a women-friendly district variable looks different

in these districts; i.e being in the South might matter more and may hurt women more in

swing districts than the core districts.

97

Page 105: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

[1] Bedolla, Lisa, Katherine Tate and Janelle Wong. 2014. “Inedible Effects: The Impact of Women ofColor in the U.S. Congress.” in Women and Elective Office: Past, Present, and Future” eds. Thomas,Sue and Clyde Wilcox. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

[2] Burrell, Barbara C. 1994. A Woman’s Place Is in the House: Campaigning for Congress in the FeministEra. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

[3] Campbell, Angus, et al. 1960. The American Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

[4] Carroll, Susan and Krista Jenkins. 2001. “Do Term Limits Help Women Get Elected?” Social ScienceQuarterly. 82/1.

[5] Census Bureau. 2012.

[6] Center for American Women and Politics. 2012. “Women in State Legislatures? Fact Sheet”:www.cawp.rutgers.edu.

[7] Darcy, R, Susan Welch and Janet Clark. 1994. Women, Elections, and Representation. 2nd Edition.Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.

[8] Darcy, R. and Sarah Slavin Schramm. 1977. “When Women Run against Men,? Public OpinionQuarterly 41: 1-12.

[9] Dolan, Kathleen. 2004. Voting for Women: How the Public Evaluates Women Candidates. Boulder,CO: Westview.

[10] Dolan, Kathleen.2009. “The Impact of Gender Stereotyped Evaluations on Supoport for WomenCandidates.” Political Behavior. 32:69-88.

[11] Elazar, Daniel. 1966. American Federalism: A View from the States. New York: Crowell.

[12] Fenno, Richard. 1978. Home Style: House Members in Their Districts. Boston: Little Brown.

[13] Flanigan, William and Nancy Zingale. 1994. Political Behavior of the American Electorate, 8th edition.Washington, DC: CQ Press.

[14] Flanigan, William and Nancy Zingale. 2002. Political Behavior of the American Electorate, 10th editionWashington, DC: CQ Press.

[15] Fox, Richard L. 2000. “Gender and Congressional Elections.” In Gender and American Politics: Women,Men, and the Political Process, eds. Sue Tolleson Rinehart and Jyl J. Josephson. Armonk, NY: M.E.Sharpe.

[16] Fox, Richard and Jennifer Lawless. 2004. “Entering the Arena? Gender and the Decision to Run forOffice.” American Journal of Political Science. 48:264-280.

[17] Frank, Thomas. 2004. What’s the Matter with Kansas? New York: Metropolitan Books.

[18] Fulton, Sarah et, al. 2006. “The Sense of a Women: Gender Ambition, and The Decision to Run forCongress”. Political Research Quarterly. 59: 235-248.

[19] Fulton, Sarah. 2012. “Running Backwards and in High Heels: The Gendered Quality Gap andIncumbent Electoral Success.” Political Research Quarterly. 20:1-12.

[20] Gelman, Andrew. 2009. Red State, Blue State, Rich State, Poor State. Princeton: Princeton UniversityPress.

98

Chapter Bibliography

Page 106: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

[21] Koch, Jeffrey. 2000. “Do Citizens Apply Gender Stereotypes to Infer Candidates’ Ideological Orienta-tions?” Journal of Politics 62: 414-29.

[22] Koch, Jeffrey. 2002. “Gender Stereotypes and Citizens’ Impressions of House Candidates’ IdeologicalOrientations.” American Journal of Political Science. 46(2), 453-462.

[23] Lau, Richard and David Redlawsk. 2001. “Advantages and Disadvantages of Cognitive Heuristics inPolitical Decision Making”. American Journal of Political Science 45: 951-71.

[24] Matland, R.E., Studlar, D.T., 2004.“Determinants of Legislative Turnover: a Cross-National Analysis.”British Journal of Political Science. 34: 87-108.

[25] National Conference of State Legislatures. 2011 “Legislative Term Limits Overview?”http://www.ncsl.org/.

[26] Norrander, Barbara and Clyde Wilcox. 2014. “Trend in the Geography of Women in the U.S. StateLegislatures.” in Women and Elective Office: Past, Present, and Future” eds. Thomas, Sue and ClydeWilcox. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

[27] Palmer, Barbara and Dennis Simon. 2005. “When Women Run Against Women: The Hidden Influenceof Female Incumbents in Elections to the U.S. House of Representatives, 1956-2002.” Gender andPolitics. 1:39-63.

[28] Palmer, Barbara and Dennis Simon. 2006. Breaking the Political Glass Ceiling: Women and Congres-sional Elections. New York: Routlege.

[29] Rahn, Wendy. 1993. “The Role of Partisan Stereotypes in Information Processing about PoliticalCandidates”. American Journal of Political Science 37: 472-96.

[30] Rule, Wilma. 1981. “Why Women Don’t Run: The Critical and Contextual Factors in Women’sLegislative Recruitment”. Western Political Quarterly 34:60-77.

[31] Sanbonmatsu, Kira.2006. “Where women run.” Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

[32] Sanbonmatsu, Kira and Kathleen Dolan. 2009. “Do Gender Stereotypes Transcend Party?” PoliticalResearch Quarterly 62: 485-494.

[33] Schreiber, Ronnie. 2014. “Conservative Women Run for Office.” in Women and Elective Office: Past,Present, and Future” eds. Thomas, Sue and Clyde Wilcox. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

[34] Swers, Michele. 1998. “Are Congresswomen More Likely to Vote for Women’s Issue Bills than TheirMale Colleagues?” Legislative Studies Quarterly 23(3): 435-448.

[35] Swers, Michele. 2002. The Difference Women Make. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

[36] Thomas, Sue and Clyde Wilcox. 2014. Women and Elective Office: Past, Present, and Future” NewYork, NY: Oxford University Press.

[37] Werner, Emmy. 1966. “Women in Congress: 1917-1964.” Western Political Quarterly 19: 16-30.

99

Page 107: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Appendix

Table 1 below is a difference of means test for female winners. The difference of means

test is run for both parties to determine if the set of variables that make up the women-

friendly district variable are significantly different with each party. In other words, the

difference of means test is a robustness check to confirm women-friendly districts are different

from a party-friendly district. Table 1 confirms that across both parties the differences are

significant. The only variable not significant is the percent black in a district (diversity) for

Republicans.

100

Page 108: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.1 : Party-Friendly versus Women-FriendlyVariable Male Republican Female Republican Male Democrat Female Democrat

Party 25.63 27.34* 75.92 74.48*Diversity 4.48 4.33 14.03 16.46*Urban 0.64 0.69* 0.75 0.81*Income 45278.53 46579.92* 38392.49 40126.96*Women in Workforce 59.77 60.32* 57.58 59.76*Education 16.3 17.63* 13.79 16.1*South 0.31 0.25* 0.32 0.24*

101

Page 109: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table 2 shows the results for the female emergence logit model using district demo-

graphics. The model controls for election year (not reported in table) and clusters around

the state legislative district. Table 2 supports the results in the difference of means test in

Table 1 above and finds each variable is in the expected direction. State districts that are

more diverse, more urban, and have higher levels of education will be more friendly towards

women. Each of these variables are in the expected direction15.

Further, districts with a higher levels of Democratic vote share are more women-

friendly. The party variable captures this and a positive direction indicates a higher demo-

cratic vote share. MMDs and term limits also increase women-friendliness and professional-

ization will decrease women-friendliness. Each of these variables are in the expected direction

and statistically significant. Lastly, the political culture variables are also in the expected

direction and statistically significant. Females are less likely to emerge in individualistic and

traditionalistic political cultures, in comparison to the moralistic political culture, which is

the baseline in the model.

15Income and education were highly correlated at about .60. I then ran a model with education and womenin the workforce which were also highly correlated at .51. Therefore, in the final models I use education anddrop income and women in the workforce to reduce multicollinearity

102

Page 110: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.2: Likelihood Candidate is a Female

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

Party 0.004* 0.001Urbanization 0.002* 0.001Black 0.009* 0.001Individualistic -0.296* 0.044Traditionalistic -0.372* 0.050Education 0.022* 0.003Term Limits 0.083* 0.038District Type 0.166* 0.046Professionalization -0.250* 0.147Constant -1.657* 0.069n =46324

The next analysis is on the likelihood of a female winner is in Table 3 below. As

with the emergence model, females are winning seats that are more urban and educated.

Further, females are winning seats in more diverse districts and also districts with a higher

democratic vote share. Each of these variables are in the expected positive direction and are

statistically significant at the traditional .05 level.

Further, women are more likely to win seats in MMDs and less likely to win seats

as the professionalization of the legislature increases. The model also shows women are less

likely to win seats in term limited states. Taken in consideration with the emergence model,

the analyses show women are more likely to run in these term limited states but are less

likely to win the seat.

103

Page 111: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.3: Likelihood Winner is a Female

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

Party 0.011* 0.001Urbanization 0.002* 0.001Black 0.013* 0.002Individualistic -0.133* 0.051Traditionalistic -0.080 0.058Education 0.020* 0.003Term Limits -0.224* 0.045District Type 0.114* 0.054Professionalization -0.550* 0.174Constant -1.968* 0.102n =26253

The next set of tables below are the tables presented in the paper with the election

years included.

Table A.4: Core Democrat: Female Emergence

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

dem women friendly avg .1565631 .0282458individualistic pc -.3365629 .0748279traditionalistic pc -.170424 .0890139term limit -.0836265 .1504956termlimit wfdem .0516483 .0480877legprof squire -.1411437 .2323934incumbent .3911542 .0605985open seat .3518542 .0538863elect 2000 -.0912832 .0557684elect 2002 -.1284345 .0507623elect 2004 -.0258399 .0485041elect 2006 -.0543958 .0451579elect 2008 -.0474389 .0394987cons -1.463704 .1237331

104

Page 112: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.5: Swing Democrat: Female Emergence

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

dem women friendly avg .0797918 .0190978individualistic pc -.0745123 .077107traditionalistic pc -.1226604 .0787729term limit -.0623158 .137266termlimit wfdem .0201905 .0431716legprof squire -.3544942 .2757757incumbent .091498 .0461193open seat .0620944 .0511741elect 2000 -.1714078 .0588112elect 2002 -.2322726 .0553721elect 2004 -.1707884 .0533979elect 2006 -.0349468 .0462753elect 2008 -.0363515 .04327cons -1.038344 .0899591

Table A.6: Core Republican: Female Emergence

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

rep women friendly avg .147747 .0276422individualistic pc -.1913911 .075356traditionalistic pc -.2212877 .0816072term limit .1568898 .1659367termlimit wfrep -.0342328 .0474659legprof squire -.0520752 .257339incumbent -.3812159 .0654788open seat -.2016688 .0533414elect 2000 .0468717 .0663321elect 2002 .0179355 .0624462elect 2004 -.0479129 .0606049elect 2006 -.0027185 .0564105elect 2008 -.0220036 .0507171cons -1.349211 .126791

105

Page 113: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.7: Swing Republican: Female Emergence

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

rep women friendly avg .0638575 .0169588individualistic pc -.0872312 .0771295traditionalistic pc -.1600073 .0781087term limit -.1691452 .1557498termlimit wfrep .049498 .043242legprof squire -.4233907 .2758529incumbent .1051049 .0460237open seat .0678409 .0511774elect 2000 -.1611315 .0582281elect 2002 -.2277087 .0550821elect 2004 -.172 .0534261elect 2006 -.0342929 .0461984elect 2008 -.0350461 .0432426cons -1.008653 .0925727

Table A.8: Core Republican: Female Success

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

female cand -.5002398 .0701227rep women friendly avg .0273552 .0095952individualistic pc .0148918 .0166657traditionalistic pc .049343 .0221703term limit -.0095145 .0502801termlimit wfrep -.0034838 .0132543legprof squire -.0010355 .0601022incumbent 6.215262 .1654569open seat 3.059142 .0842767unopposed 5.475893 .678396margin victory .0008582 .0005891elect 2000 .0533524 .0255042elect 2002 -.0147778 .0268848elect 2004 -.002193 .0233656elect 2006 .0179845 .0255359elect 2008 .0235038 .0240681cons -3.138546 .101559

106

Page 114: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.9: Core Democrat: Female Success

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

female cand .3450051 .0663762dem women friendly avg -.0405944 .0094148individualistic pc .0317028 .0231128traditionalistic pc -.0453398 .0336459term limit -.079386 .0423397termlimit wfdem .0185845 .0139668legprof squire .0088317 .0645849incumbent 6.255734 .1457224open seat 3.074011 .0757197unopposed 4.058447 .3333078margin victory .0037032 .0006704elect 2000 .0039934 .0265013elect 2002 -.0445716 .0249698elect 2004 -.0038756 .0240392elect 2006 -.1049973 .0285525elect 2008 -.0538214 .0272173cons -3.232047 .0834231

107

Page 115: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.10: Swing Republican: Female Success

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

female cand .0573801 .0567672rep women friendly avg -.0105447 .0044935individualistic pc -.0153122 .0145414traditionalistic pc -.0549274 .030834term limit -.1849904 .0438697termlimit wfrep .0330612 .0110045legprof squire .0991332 .0541343incumbent 3.199984 .0941815open seat 1.519908 .0498495unopposed 4.009929 .4750092margin victory .0013476 .0004078elect 2000 -.0219494 .0199121elect 2002 -.0250504 .0201461elect 2004 .02788 .0186179elect 2006 -.0932389 .026431elect 2008 .0291471 .0182408cons -1.588223 .0564312

108

Page 116: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Table A.11: Swing Democrat: Female Success

Variable Coefficient Standard Error

female cand .0582481 .0567276dem women friendly avg -.0188258 .0050216individualistic pc -.0181286 .0146655traditionalistic pc -.0667596 .032422term limit -.1850051 .0414143termlimit wfdem .0377782 .0130036legprof squire .1139771 .0543251incumbent 3.200017 .0941845open seat 1.521311 .0498454unopposed 4.013425 .4744298margin victory .0014195 .0004185elect 2000 -.0208039 .0199954elect 2002 -.024844 .0201764elect 2004 .0280286 .0186432elect 2006 -.0931715 .0263905elect 2008 .0292412 .0182321cons -1.569373 .0560399

109

Page 117: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

CHAPTER 5

CONCLUSION

The puzzle which inspired this dissertation was two-fold. This first puzzle is that

women make up an equal portion of the population but are underrepresented in government.

I was particularly interested in the underrepresentation of women in state legislatures. The

number of women has increased overtime since the 1970s but became stagnant in the late

1990s. To help understand why there is stagnation but also variation across the states, I

looked to institutional features—mainly term limits. Further, I wanted to examine literature

that may explain why women run and win office (rather than literature that keeps women

out of office). Term limits were this unique institutional change that happened in the 1990s

(around the time of stagnation) to help try and resolve the puzzle of why female descriptive

representation is so low.

The second puzzle involves term limits and their effect on legislators. Research finds

women are successful in open seat races. Since term limits create a large number of open

seats, scholars theorized that term limits would have a positive effect on female descriptive

representation. Yet as discussed throughout the dissertation, initial studies on term limits

found that there was a negative effect on female descriptive representation. Women who

were in office left due to term limits and no women replaced them. Exploring the possible

reasons why the conventional wisdom and initial research were at odds was an important

motivator for the dissertation.

In general, in the dissertation I find term limits have a positive effect on female

candidates. Term limits create more open seats and allow new candidates to seek office. The

emergence chapter finds females are much more likely to emerge as candidates after term

110

Page 118: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

limits are implemented. This is consistent with congressional literature which finds women

are more likely to run in open seat races since their chances of winning are higher when they

are not a challenger to an incumbent.

The female success chapter finds term limits positively effect female descriptive repre-

sentation for Republican females and negatively for Democratic females. Female Republicans

are about 2% more likely to win in term limited legislatures. Female Democrats are about

5% less likely to win in term limited states. Overall though, female Democrats, despite term

limits, are very successful and are still likely to win their race over 50% of the time. Female

Republicans on the other hand are helped by term limits but their success rates are not as

high as female Democrats. This implies that female descriptive representation has the poten-

tial to increase overtime as more female Republicans gain office. Lastly, the women-friendly

district chapter is a first look at how state legislative districts (in the lower house) can have

a certain set of demographics that make them more likely to elect female candidates. I find

support for women-friendly districts for both Republican and Democratic parties. Females

are more likely to emerge and win seats as districts become more women-friendly. The key

demographics making up a women-friendly district are: high levels of income, education,

women in the workforce, more democratic, more urban, and diverse. The analysis in the

chapter does not find and interactive effect between term limits and women-friendly districts.

In other words, a district does not become more women-friendly when in term limited states.

Implications

Term limits affect female descriptive representation in parties differently. Overall, I

find term limits increase the likelihood a female candidate (both Democrat and Republican)

will emerge. Yet, I find term limits increase female Republican success but decreases female

111

Page 119: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

Democratic success. The implications of such for Democrats, and female Democrats are

important to consider. A closer look at party-friendly and district-friendly seats post term

limits may provide insight. For example, if term limits do cause a “partial reversal in

professionalization” (Meinke and Hasecke 2003), favoring Republicans, are core Democratic

districts becoming swing districts, or Republican districts? If term limits do cause safe

Democratic districts to become less safe, this hurts the Democratic party, which in turn

hurts female Democrats. Overall, if term limits are hurting the Democratic party, and

females, this may decrease female descriptive representation overtime given the majority of

successful female candidates are Democrats.

On the other hand, something to consider is if Republicans, specifically female Re-

publicans, are taking advantage of term limits. If Democratic females are emerging, but

winning less in term limited states understanding the reason why they are losing is critical.

Are Democrats recruiting candidates they do not think can win or are Republican candi-

dates post term limits better suited (qualified, financially or otherwise) to win? Oftentimes,

researchers discuss the possibility of sacrificial lambs (See Canon 1992) Essentially, it is a

candidate that will likely not win the election but are run anyway. Generally sacrificial lambs

run against incumbents, rather than in open seats created by term limits. Term limits may

be increasing the number of sacrificial lambs in a race.

One last implication, and not directly pursued in this work, is whether or not term

limits positively effect substantive representation of women. I conclude term limits have the

potential to increase descriptive representation. Specifically since female Republicans are

more successful at winning post term limits. Policy from legislatures that are comprised of a

majority of Republicans will likely to substantially different than legislatures with equal num-

112

Page 120: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

bers of Democrats/Republicans. Further, policies that favor women tend to come from the

Democratic party since the party typically supports the expansion of social welfare programs

(amongst other policies)— especially those which support women and children. Therefore,

an interesting implication to consider is the type of policies coming from legislatures with

more female Republicans in them.

Future Research

In terms of future research, there is still a vast amount of work that can be done on

females in the states. I intend to complete a few research projects that will build upon the

current chapters. In terms of candidate emergence, future research will examine more of

the parties within the states and see how they have adapted strategies post term limits. I

speculate in the emergence chapter that parties (and female recruitment agencies) will adapt

new recruitment strategies in term limited states. In order to test my theory, I would like to

conduct some surveys of state legislators and party organizations in the term limited states.

The surveys will try and understand if the new legislators have different motivations for

running and specifically whether term limits were an incentive to run for office. Further, I

am interested in knowing whether or not some state parties seek out female candidates for

office post term limits.

In terms of female descriptive representation, future research will look into what

women do once termed out of office. After term limits, are these women going to the state

senate or Congress? Or, in states with consecutive term limits are women going back to

the lower house after the designated time away? These questions are important to look into

because depending on where women end up after term limits has the potential to increase

(or decrease) female descriptive representation at other levels of government. Further, where

113

Page 121: Run, Women, Run! Female Candidates and Term Limits: A .../67531/metadc... · Term limits are one of the most signi cant institutional changes to take place since the modernization

women go after term limits may also add insight into the original motivations to run for

offIce. For example, if term limits are desirable to women because it is a temporary political

position, women should not seek office after being termed out.

Lastly, work on women-friendly districts in the states is fairly new. Furthering the

nuances of the women-friendly district variable, as previously discussed, will be a valuable

addition to the field. Linking the state women-friendly district variable to the congressional

women-friendly districts is one future project I plan to investigate. Exploring the similarities

and differences between the women-friendly districts, especially the swing districts, may be

useful for increasing female descriptive representation. For example, if there a areas where

districts are women-friendly in the lower house, upper house, and Congress these may be good

areas for women’s groups or parties to actively recruit women. This is especially important

if the district is is a state with term limits. Overall, an active eligibility pool of females

who will run and win races in term limited states is important for increasing descriptive

representation.

114