sharing and tourism: the rise of new markets in transport

31
SHARING AND TOURISM: THE RISE OF NEW MARKETS IN TRANSPORT Documents de travail GREDEG GREDEG Working Papers Series Christian Longhi Marcello M. Mariani Sylvie Rochhia GREDEG WP No. 2016-01 http://www.gredeg.cnrs.fr/working-papers.html Les opinions exprimées dans la série des Documents de travail GREDEG sont celles des auteurs et ne reflèlent pas nécessairement celles de l’institution. Les documents n’ont pas été soumis à un rapport formel et sont donc inclus dans cette série pour obtenir des commentaires et encourager la discussion. Les droits sur les documents appartiennent aux auteurs. The views expressed in the GREDEG Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the institution. The Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate. Copyright belongs to the author(s).

Upload: doanduong

Post on 05-Jan-2017

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Sharing and TouriSm: The riSe of new markeTS in TranSporT

Documents de travail GREDEG GREDEG Working Papers Series

Christian LonghiMarcello M. MarianiSylvie Rochhia

GREDEG WP No. 2016-01http://www.gredeg.cnrs.fr/working-papers.html

Les opinions exprimées dans la série des Documents de travail GREDEG sont celles des auteurs et ne reflèlent pas nécessairement celles de l’institution. Les documents n’ont pas été soumis à un rapport formel et sont donc inclus dans cette série pour obtenir des commentaires et encourager la discussion. Les droits sur les documents appartiennent aux auteurs.

The views expressed in the GREDEG Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the institution. The Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate. Copyright belongs to the author(s).

Page 2: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport Christian Longhi1, Marcello M. Mariani2 and Sylvie Rochhia1

1University Nice Sophia Antipolis, GREDEG, CNRS, 250 rue A. Einstein, 06560 Valbonne France [email protected], [email protected] 2University of Bologna, Via Capo di Lucca, 34 – 40126, Bologna, Italy [email protected]

GREDEG Working Paper No. 2016-01

Abstract. This paper analyses the implications of sharing on tourists and tourism focusing on the transportation sector. The shifts from ownership to access, from products to services have induced dramatic changes triggered by the emergence of innovative marketplaces. The services offered by Knowledge Innovative Service Suppliers, start-ups at the origin of innovative marketplaces run through platforms allow the tourists to find solutions to run themselves their activities, bypassing the traditional tourism industry. The paper builds a taxonomy to apprehend the diversity attached to this growing platform economy, and uses this analytical framework to depict significant cases drawn from ridesharing or carsharing. Keywords. Sharing, platform economy, travel, transport, tourism industry.

JEL. L91, L83, L86, O33, O35

1. Introduction

This paper analyses the implications of “sharing” on the tourism industry. Through house, car or

ride sharing, the development of new services and applications, travels are becoming cheaper and

easier. Nevertheless the main argument for “sharing” is not restricted to competitive prices. Airbnb,

one of the leading actors reshaping the tourism sector for instance refers to its business model as

based on the desire of “another way of travel”. Indeed, tourism services have been traditionally

provided by service firms, hotels, restaurants, transport companies, taxis, travel guides. Nowadays

more and more people share with tourists not only their travel experiences but also their houses,

cars, boat, meals…, unlocking the value of underused assets and bypassing the established industry

(Bostman & Rogers, 2011).

Sharing is not limited to tourism. It crosses the whole society – banking, publishing, photos, music

Page 3: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

recording, movie making… –, but tourism has been one of the more impacted sector, as it has been

the case since the emergence of Internet and Information and Communication Technologies (ICT).

As emphasized by Buhalis & Law (2008: 610), “technological progress and tourism have been

going hand in hand for years”: most of the main innovative behaviours and activities have emerged

in the tourism industry. The Internet has induced deep changes in the knowledge bases and demand

in the tourism industry, as well as the entry of new actors and the definition of new rules. Tourism

as such is obviously not the locus of radical technological innovation. Nevertheless, innovative

technologies and knowledge bases have always been used to benefit from market opportunities

(Aldebert et al., 2011).

The Internet has also induced an in depth renewal of the industry (Buhalis & Zoge, 2007), not only

limited to the working of existing markets, but to the revolution of the organisation of the industry

(Mariani et al., 2014). Sharing is among others a last stage of this revolution. Indeed, sharing is as

old as mankind, but the recent developments of Internet and web 2.0, the creation of online

platforms have extended it from the private sphere to a global scale. So a new organisation of the

economic activities in which uses prevail on ownership has emerged.

Sharing has deeply impacted accommodation, transportation, leisure, visits, food… In the paper

the focus will be on transportation in which sharing has taken numerous forms. The issue is no

more ownership, but accessibility, access to shared cars (carsharing), to shared trips (ridesharing),

to other transportation means and resources (bikesharing), which impacts directly or indirectly

many sectors of the economies.

Transport is also very important as far as geo-localization, real-time applications, location-based

services are core elements of the innovative processes at work. With the Internet, the upsurge of

smartphones and dedicated applications is underlying changes in the tourism industry. Waves of

disruptive innovations borne by the entry of new actors have changed dramatically the composition

Page 4: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

and organisation of the tourism industry (Buhalis, 1998; Wade & Raffour, 2000, Buhalis & Law,

2008) and namely the transportation sector.

The numerous forms sharing takes in transport are reflected by the diversity of terms that can be

found in the literature, sharing economy, but also collaborative economy, collaborative

consumption, peer to peer economy, on demand economy, circular economy, the mesh … to quote

the main used. Are these terms different ways to address the same thing or very different things?

The paper provides an analytical framework to organize this diversity. As already emphasized, the

Web 2.0 and the online platforms underlie all these developments, but these platforms are not mere

web sites or mobile applications. They are in fact business models, new modes of organisations of

the markets, competing sometimes with the traditional actors of the tourism industry. An increased

demand for a destination does no more necessarily benefit to the traditional supply provided by the

industry. These business models are implemented by entrants we define as Knowledge Intensive

Service Suppliers, start-ups of the Web 2.0 era that have given birth to this new economic system

based on sharing of underused assets or services, for free or for a fee, directly from individuals.

The first part of the paper defines the platform economy, product of the innovative marketplaces

implemented by Knowledge Intensive Service Suppliers. Despite common basic features, diversity

is shown to be a main characteristic of the platforms. The second part of the paper builds a

taxonomy to apprehend the contrasted marketplaces running on transportation, and uses this

analytical framework to explore significant cases drawn from ridesharing or carsharing. The last

part concludes.

2. Sharing: definitions and issues at stake

2.1. Sharing in and sharing out

Page 5: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

The emergence of sharing is often associated with travel experiences, one could say “by tourists,

for tourists!”. For instance, in 1999 Casey Fenton planned to visit Iceland from Boston; after

finding an inexpensive flight, he sent randomly an email to a group of students of the University

of Iceland, asking for a free stay, to meet people and share experience. The number of invitations

gave “birth to the idea that people anywhere would want to share their homes with strangers (or,

as we like to call them, friends you haven't met yet)”1. Back to Boston, he began to develop the

CouchSurfing project to "surf" on couches by staying as a guest at a host's home, certainly the first

success story of sharing in the tourism domain. Most of the creators of this new economy are in

fact often depicted as individuals attempting to solve every day problems or wastes they have

themselves experienced, often in relation with tourism. In 2008 Garett Camp, Travis Kalanick and

Oscar Salazar visited Paris from San Francisco to attend LeWeb conference. They tried endlessly

to find taxis and failed to find one, a problem they equally experienced regularly in San Francisco.

Back in the Silicon Valley they created UberCab, a private driver service. Uber was launched in

San Francisco in 2009 to change the way transport is organized, and diffused rapidly in the whole

world, a world now qualified of ‘uberized’ in more and more activities. Another experience relates

to Brian Chesky, an unemployed graduate designer who moved to San Francisco in 2007. He

thought with its mate Joe Gebbia they could make some cash by housing attendees at an industrial

design conference in their apartment because of the well-known shortage of hotel during such

events going on in the city (Geron, 2013). The success of their initiative convinced them that a

potential market existed: “We were just trying to solve our own problem. After we solved our own

problem, we realized many other people want this.” (Brian Chesky, quoted in Geron, 2013). They

associated to Nathan Blecharczyk and created Airbnb to connect users with “airbed equipped

rooms to rent” with users looking to rent a space. Many other interesting experiences could be

1 The CouchSurfing story, http://about.couchsurfing.com/

Page 6: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

related. In this way the leaders of the rising platform economy were born and, together with them

new marketplaces were shaped.

These leaders were not ordinary tourists. They were embedded in knowledge-based economies,

endowed with enough knowledge to take advantage of their intuitions. Indeed the sharing economy

can be thought as one of the last consequences of development of the Internet and the ICT, an

achievement of the emergence of the Web 2.0. In this economy a necessary condition to develop

innovative activities is no more only availability of financial capital but of knowledge.

However, according Price (1975), sharing is not a form of reciprocity like the one we notice in

market exchange: “sharing is usually an unequal exchange, because some people are consistently

in a better position to give. Sharing is characterized by the attitude that each person will do what

is appropriate, not by an expectation of equivalent return as in reciprocity” (Price, 1975, 6).

Linked with others in this collective action, people are able to develop bonding and even solidarity.

Belk (2010) refers to “sharing in” when people share on an inclusive mode that is when they

include all those with they share in their aggregate extended self. Thus, “sharing in” allows to

create a sense of community through strong ties and bonding capital (Putnam, 2000). In the

“sharing out”, there is no sense of community or mutuality. It is likely that what is shared could be

replicate and divided. Weak ties and bridging capital are then characteristic of the sharing out.

“Sharing in and the expanded sense of self that it encompasses are characteristic of the sharing

prototype. A “time share” condo is sharing out and creates no bonds. Sharing a car within a couple

or family is generally a case of sharing in, while sharing a car within a large-scale commercial

car-sharing organization is more a case of sharing out” (Belk, 2010, 726). “Sharing out” goes

with the creation of innovative marketplaces assembling according different business models

multitudes of dispersed users. The economy underlying these activities will be called a platform

economy.

Page 7: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

2.2. Towards KISS and the platform economy

A basic explanation of the rise of the platform economy in tourism is the deeper and deeper

involvement of tourists – and more generally consumers – in the tourism industry. The industry

traditionally linked vertically the different actors, from suppliers and services providers to tourists,

according a strict top-down logic. The tourism goods are experience goods whose both utility and

quality are uncertain and only known ex post. With the development of the Internet the tourists

have built online communities to share experiences (Kozinets, 1999; Kim et al, 2004, Wang et al.,

2002), have assembled themselves their own bundles, becoming consum’actors, (Longhi, 2009),

have fed User Generated Contents sites (Longhi & Rochhia, 2015), creating value for large firms

such as Trip Advisor for instance.

Finally, the consumers moved into ‘prosumers’, invading the two sides of the tourism markets.

Tourism services have traditionally been provided by firms when more and more individuals are

proposing to share temporarily with tourists either what they own (homes or cars for instance) or

what they do (meals or visits for instance). This behaviour has resulted in an economic and social

system based on the sharing of underused assets or services, for free or for a fee, apparently directly

between individuals. The motives underlying the emergence of sharing are numerous. On the one

hand, the focus has been brought on the deep changes in the behaviour of consumers or citizens,

from individualistic towards more collaborative behaviours. The values shared in the Internet

communities – net neutrality, open source developments, crowdsourcing – have invaded the society

and are certainly under the re-emergence of ‘commons’ (Ostrom & Hess, 2007).

On the other hand, sharing, bartering, renting can be source of some additional revenue, the crisis,

the ecological awareness have outgrown the movements launched by some few internet

communities (Botsman & Rogers, 2011). These ideas of sharing have been hugely diffused in the

society, uses prevail henceforth on ownership, access to the goods depend on genuine needs, for

Page 8: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

what it is sometimes referred as "disownership" (Wang, 2013). The economic changes have been

massive, and have disrupted a lot of industries. So, sharing has moved from a community practice

into the distinctive business model of the 21st century, the “sharing out” implemented by the

platform economy.

The focus has often been the emergence of a collaborative consumption society (Felson & Spaeth,

1978; Botsman & Rogers, 2011), as if the firms, the markets were somewhat disappearing. In fact

this mesh of shared things (Gansky, 2012) affects not only the way one consumes but also the way

successful companies are built. Collaborative consumption refers indeed to innovative market

designs set up by start-ups which challenge the prevailing leaders of the industries, the dominant

organization of the markets. The incumbent firms will have to adapt their economic models to meet

the changes, to overcome rigidities that threaten their viability

The main features of the Web 2.0 explain its potential disruptive effects on the incumbent markets

and industries, and even on the whole society. Its characteristics and main principles have been

precisely defined by O’Reilly (2006). “Web 2.0 is the business revolution in the computer industry

caused by the move to the internet as platform”. Different lessons and principles have afterwards

been coined by O’Reilly (2006), for instance:

-leverage customer-self-service and algorithmic data management to reach out to the entire web,

to the edges and not just the centre, to the long tail and not just the head;

-network effects from user contributions are the key to market dominance in the Web 2.0 era;

-the service automatically gets better the more people use it;

-when commodity components are abundant, you can create value simply by assembling them in

novel or effective ways.

Web 2.0 has induced the entry of innovative start-ups that we define as Knowledge Intensive

Page 9: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Service Suppliers (KISS), providing platforms which allow members of distinct groups to share

experiences, advices or resources, to aggregate microscopic elements at a global scale (Longhi,

Rochhia, 2015). The platforms, characterised by price discrimination between groups and

intermediation services, “serve as matchmakers to facilitate exchange by making it easier for

members of each group to find each other” (Evans, 2011a: 138). The platform economy is the

consequence of a radical innovation, not technological but in this organisation of the markets and

the industry. Web 2.0 allows building applications that involve a maximum of network effects and

impact directly or indirectly on competition. The platform economy is indeed redesigning most of

the industry, not only tourism, shifting from products to (eco) systems.

This clash between products and platforms is the pivotal explanation of the present evolution of

the industries, and basically of tourism. The entrants do not compete directly on products, creating

features that differentiate them from others, but they compete indirectly with incumbent firms

providing the consumers tools to solve themselves their consumption problems through (often free)

access to dedicated platforms (Evans, 2011b; Choudary, 2014).

The successful platforms are the ones that have built the more network effects; these effects divert

the consumers from the traditional markets on the one hand, and select the winners from the

flourishing platform start-ups on the other hand, according to the ‘winner-takes-all’ principle

working under the Internet economy. This surge of technology start-ups finds its foundation in the

knowledge-based economy grown with the Internet, the so called "innovation in assembly”

principle of Web 2.0. The issue to develop activities is no more only availability of financial capital

but of knowledge. As far as many of the elements to build a platform are freely available on the

web, the issue is the capability to assemble them, the hardware being more and more easily

available and affordable.

Even more than sharing (Botsman & Rogers, 2011) or access-based consumption (Bardi &

Page 10: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Eckhardt, 2012), the platform economy seems to grasp the ongoing changes in the society, as in

the end the working of the whole thing depends on it. Sharing concerns individuals for which uses,

access to the goods or services prevails on ownership. Nevertheless exchanges, even for free, imply

a market place. The platforms have the capacity to aggregate dispersed resources globally to reach

a critical mass and benefit from the properties of the Internet, on which all the information is visible.

Through a platform, the single empty seat in my car can be reached as easily as the reservation

system of a national railway company or of a renting car company for a traveller making the same

journey than me.

The platform enables members of distinct groups to share, to transact with each other, and to realize

gains from trade by reducing the transactions costs of finding each other and inter-acting; so it is a

“market-maker” (Evans, 2011a). Interaction between people is the key issue; the platform connects

producers and consumers with each other. Producers can turn into consumers and vice versa,

depending of their present needs. In the traditional economy, producers and consumers had very

specific, different and sequential roles; this linear model is overthrown in the platform economy.

The Internet does not make any hierarchy; the large operators are no longer the only suppliers

globally visible on the markets. The net neutrality is a necessary condition of the viability of

businesses based on the exploration of the web, as far as for instance, “google will find the little

guy as easily as it finds the big guy” (Anderson, 2004).

The emergence of KISS is related to the aggregation of microscopic and fragmented actors in huge

communities or markets, each microscopic actor being equally reachable, and equally visible than

any other huge actor, according to the net neutrality principle. The more people involved and using

the platform, the more efficient the platform and the service provided, as described in the definition

of the Web 2.0. The platform appears as the organisation matching perfectly the principles of the

Internet, allowing network effects to be somewhat optimized.

Page 11: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

3. Collaborative transport sharing: paving new ways for tourism

3.1. A taxonomy of tourism platforms

Transportation services have been traditionally provided by large firms, even public monopolies

induced by the network infrastructure classical argument, or small private firms like taxis for

instance. Strict institutional regulations and rules have been a characteristic of the sector. Heavy

entry costs were in any case the other characteristic of the sector, lessening competition and

securing rents. Taxis for instance symbolize the main features of this economy.

Transportation aggregates most of the technological and social innovations that underlie the take-

off of the platform economy: the upsurge of the smartphones, moving the web from our desks to

our pockets (O’Reilly & Battelle, 2009), the progress of geolocalization and real-time online

exchanges allowing high interactivity and dynamic services. The resulting behaviour of tourists

has been grasped as “mobiquity” (Miranda, 2012), going with the rise of more and more ‘free

independent travellers’. When mass tourism was related to monopolies or large oligopolies,

massive vertically integrated firms, TUI for instance, the platform economy seems to be associated

to individuals and small, agile firms. The key factor of growth becomes the investment in

knowledge-based capital, that is investment in intangible assets such as digital information,

innovative property and organisation-specific competencies (OECD, 2014). KISS need some

technological and organisational capabilities to enable the building of absorptive capacity (Cohen

& Levinthal, 1990) and the ability to manage the platform. More than physical capital, knowledge

is pivotal as far as most of the pieces necessary to build the activity are freely available; assembly

towards an innovative purpose is the key to produce economic value. The assembly function also

depends on architectural knowledge (Henderson & Clark, 1990), which makes it possible to

Page 12: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

combine and integrate a large variety of services, tools and data within the design of a platform.

Contrary to the past, entry costs in physical capital are very low, allowing small innovative firms

to compete with traditional ones; large upheavals can be easily caused to the prevailing orders and

markets.

Indeed, they do not only provide innovative applications on our smartphones. The successful start-

ups are the ones that manage to set ‘communities’ up, to give rise to new behaviours, to handle

commons, to design new business models, to build new market designs, usually two-sided markets

bypassing the established industry. They can grow as huge actors of the tourism industry, the so-

called unicors for instance, whose valuation exceeds one billion dollars, massively fed by venture

capitalists.

Diversity is a key word of these innovative initiatives, which take different forms that are described

in the literature as sharing economy, peer to peer economy, collaborative economy, collaborative

consumption, on demand economy… But the platform economy is the basic analytical framework

that underlies these different forms and grasps the whole changes. A lot of platforms aggregating

microscopic actors have flourished in many different activities related to the tourism industry, some

of which have grown as global KISS. These KISS can be of two kinds, non-profit and for-profit,

providing different innovative market designs; nevertheless the same general features described

previously drive their dynamics (Longhi & Rochhia, 2015).

The ways the KISS and their associated platforms design solutions to solve various problems and

specific needs tourists face shape the ‘marketplaces’, the matching between the ‘haves’ and the

‘wants’ according the following Table 1.

Table1. A taxonomy of platforms

Page 13: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Peer to Peer

Providers to Peer

Non Profit

La Zooz

(Commons)

CityCarshare Autolib’ Sharette_SNCF La Roue Verte_Grand Lyon

(Public)

For Profit Blablacar Drivy Deways RelayRides

(Private)

Uber Zipcar Car2Go

(Private) Source: Adapted from Schor (2014)

The Table 1 highlights the different market designs the platforms shape in transportation, providing

solutions to the tourists.

The examples of platforms given in Table 1 refer to ridesharing, carsharing, on demand services.

Obviously the differences have not to be grasped regarding the nature of the travel services, but on

the economic model the KISS have implemented.

Regarding the non-profit cases, the platforms can be enacted by the users and considered as a

common. CouchSurfing for instance is the paradigmatic case of peer to peer non-profit platforms

(Longhi & Rochhia, 2015). To the best of our knowledge, a Couchsurfing experience equivalent

does not exist in transport. Nevertheless, some innovative market designs emerge which could

growth as commons. The most advanced is certainly La Zooz, an Israeli start-up, which explores

blockchains to build systems that do not need a central body between peers. La Zooz is a

decentralized transportation platform owned by the community; it synchronizes empty seats with

transportation needs in real-time2. The network effects will be the main determinant of the success

of La Zooz, which need plenty of drivers and riders to make the services and the digital currency

2 http://lazooz.org/

Page 14: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

valuable. People tend to treat the cars as objects they have in common and thus it is better to refer

to communal sharing (Price 1975, Fiske, 1992). Communal sharing is not so much widespread

because it « tends to be a communal act that links us to other people. It is not the only way in which

we may connect with others, but it is potentially powerful one creates feelings of solidarity and

bonding” (Belk, 2010, 717).

The other cases of non-profit platforms are usually associated to local governments or firms3,

which organize carsharing or ridesharing for their citizens or employees to solve problems of

congestion, pollution, car park… These cases are interesting, but they are local and the

communities of users do not include tourists. The remaining of the paper will thus be dedicated to

for-profit platforms, which have radically changed the tourism industry. These for-profit platforms

that can be of two kinds:

- Peer to peer, they gather a community of users, which provides the resources and

can share, usually for a fee, cars (Drivy) or rides (Blablacar) for instance. But the

platform is not a common, it is private and the way the matching is done depends

on an algorithm unknown to the community

- Providers to peer, offering on-demand services on which the resources are directly

(Zipcar) or indirectly (Uber through its drivers) belonging to the platforms. These

platforms are often associated to sharing, at odds in fact with the models they

implement.

These “peer-to-peer” or “business-to peer” marketplaces can also be characterized by profit

motives, price coordination, monetary exchange, self-interest, expectation of reciprocity, lack of

community sense. Pseudo-Sharing (Belk, 2014) often underlies the platform economy.

3 For instance: Seoul Korea, Grand Lyon France, Snecma, Renault IdF, Hilti in Ile de France….

Page 15: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

3.2. Platforms at work: competition and concentration

In transportation, the platform economy is born with the creation of hundreds of start-ups across

the world providing innovative solutions for long or short distance travels. The object is obviously

not to provide an exhaustive picture of this economy, but to highlight its main features and

principles through the consideration of some cases, start-ups and innovative market arrangements,

and to unveil the new landscape of the tourism industry.

A lot of these start-ups disappear rapidly, because their solutions or business models failed, they

did not gather enough users, or because they get acquired by more successful ones. The platform

economy is indeed characterized by important movements of concentration, fuelled by massive

network externalities.

The resulting ‘winner takes all’ principle is emphasized by the role of venture capitalists, which

have massively invested in these start-ups and somewhat driven the process of selection of the

winners. The movement emerged in the Silicon Valley but has rapidly spread across the world, to

Europe or China. Some start-ups succeed to raise important funds to improve their network the

services they provide, to enlarge the scope of their markets, often through acquisitions.

i. Ridesharing or carpooling is a market that has rapidly grown to become a serious

alternative to usual railways or transport companies. By increasing the occupancy rate of cars, it

should also be a real substitute to individual use of car for traveling (ADEME, 2015). Given the

multiplicity of initiatives the entry of actors with self-defined rules in regulated markets, it has even

be legally defined in France as “a common use of terrestrial motor vehicle by a non-professional

driver and one or several passengers, made for no fee but the division of costs, as part of a journey

that the driver makes for himself” (article L. 3132-1 of The Energy Transition Law).

Page 16: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Long-distance ridesharing is dominated in Europe by Blablacar, a start-up that has grown as the

world largest carpooling platform, gathering a community – not customers! – of more than 20

million of users across nineteen countries4 arranging more than two million rides per month with

an average car occupancy of 2.8 people (vs. 1.6 in average)5.

From 2004 the start-up began under the name covoiturage.fr to sell software platform solutions to

firms (e.g. MAIF, Ikea, Carrefour…) or local governments (e.g. Montrouge, France) intending to

encourage ridesharing amongst employees and citizens. It fed ‘providers to peers’ platform

arrangements subsidized by the providers and usually free for users. The limits of this market

appeared rapidly. The start-up developed a for-profit peer to peer platform, which became

Blablacar in 2013 to harmonize the brand all over the countries operated.

The business model adopted by Blablacar is the same of the one inaugurated by Airbnb. The

inscription of the users on the platform is free, as the value of the platform depends directly on the

number of users on the two sides of the market. Nevertheless, one side of the market - the most

important one regarding its viability or profitability - benefits from better conditions, which can be

free use. In ridesharing the platforms compete for drivers, which provide the resources, the unused

seats to share. The platform itself does not own or provide any resources, it organizes a marketplace

where drivers can find passengers and share the cost of the travel, and riders can find a seat to travel

for cheap compared to the traditional market. The seats have to be booked in advance, users get or

pay money every time they drive or ride, prices are posted by the drivers, and Blablacar charges

11% more on average to the riders. The more the ride is booked in advance, the less it is charged.

Even if hitchhiking has been a popular mode of travel, it was not common for most of the travelers

4 France, Spain, UK, Italia, Poland, Germany, Portugal, Benelux, Russia, Ukraine, Turkey, India, Mexico, Serbia, Romania, Croatia, Hungary 5 web-site Blablacar

Page 17: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

to share – for a fee – a travel with a stranger. Blablacar has created and generalized a new behavior

and changed the nature of a traditional trip in Europe, just as Airbnb for accommodation. Trust is

a necessary condition pivotal to the take-off of a platform implementing interactions between

individuals; besides; Blablacar presents itself as a “trusted community marketplace”6. Trust

between unknown users has to be gained by systems of reputation, the belonging to a community

and the adoption of its rules, the “ridesharer’s agreements”. The curation system is pivotal to the

success of peer to peer services. Blablacar has developed tools to create trust in its online

community, and created a framework names D.R.E.A.M.S. D. for Declared, declared information

is the foundation of a trusted online profile, users can declare a name, age, their preferences or even

give a quick description of themselves in their own words. R. for Rated, ratings have long been

used online because users trust content that has been created by a third party. E. for Engaged, it is

to believe that the other party will respect their engagement, the passengers have to financially

commit to their transaction via a pre-payment service (Blablacar advertises that the quality of its

service has increased since the adoption of this principle). A. for Activity-based, a successful

sharing service must be activity-based and enables a reactive exchange between users. M. for

Moderated, all information transferred by users of a sharing service must be third-party verified. S.

for Social, social networks allow users to connect their online identity with their real world identity,

be it socially, via Facebook, or professionally, via LinkedIn. Blablacar upgrades the active and well

rated members of its community as Ambassadors, secure, well organized, willing to chat during a

trip – the Blabla measurement – drivers that will thus attract more ride shares.

The twenty millions of users spread all over Europe creates a virtual network infrastructure

allowing reaching even not well served places from the Blablacar platform. This position of leader

has been fuelled by the venture capital funds, which helped the platform to lock and launch markets

6 https://www.blablacar.co.uk/blog/blablacar-about

Page 18: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

to create a global long distance ride-sharing network. Blablacar has successively raised 1.25 million

euros from ISAI in 2011, 10 million dollars from Accel Partners in 2012, 100 million dollars from

Index ventures in 2014, and 100 million dollars from blue-chip venture-capital firms including

ISAI, Index and Accel in 2015. These different rounds allowed the platform to grow

internationally, in India, Mexico though the development of its own platforms or through the

acquisition of local actors. In Europe they have allowed Blablacar to acquire PostoinAuto.it in

Italy, Podorozhniki in Russia, Rides in Mexico, AutoHop for the Eastern Europe, and also

Carpooling.com, the number two of the market and main competitor in Europe, cementing likely

its position there. The platform has finally made agreements with insurance firms, but also with the

travel assistance services ViaMichelin or Mappy for instance, where announcements in the

Blablacar platform are now proposed after each search for a trip, or even Vinci Autoroute, which

offers special tariffs to the Blablacar drivers.

Blablacar has grown as more than an alternative to traditional transport carriers for tourists. It offers

flexible and affordable services, which beside the regular tourists give access to travel to people

which could not afford before. It also allows joining places the servicing has been closed by

transport companies, especially railways. Its large international dimension creates a standard the

users are familiar with, and can indifferently be used across countries or in their domestic markets.

The community of users shares rides, and provides resources, when Blablacar is a for profit private

firm, a third party which allows transactions through an algorithm the community cannot access.

Along with the extent of its community, this algorithm is the core of the value of the firm, which

is more than 1.5 billion dollars end 2015.

Following the success of Blablacar and the long distance mobile applications in general, a lot of

start-ups offering short distance ridesharing have emerged7. Nevertheless, the short distance goes

7 For instance: Sharette, Karos, Wedrive, Instant System, Wayz-up, La Roue Verte….

Page 19: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

with low fares, a sustainable business model does not seem to emerge. These start-ups reproduce

the model Blablacar implemented at its birth, providing platform solutions to local governments or

large firms. The model that took-off in short distance travels do not refers to ridesharing solutions,

but more to on demand services, for-profit providers to peers in our framework. The leaders of this

market, Uber or Lyft are often described as the engines of sharing, but that is not exactly what they

are. When hailing a ride with the applications of those platforms, “drivers like you and me” (Uber)

or “your friend with a car” (Lyft) “spontaneously give you a lift” (Wundercar); in fact the users are

picked up by semi-professional drivers providing a taxi service (Pick & Dreher, 2015). Lyft

presents indeed itself as a “taxi and bus app alternative”, assuming frontal competition. The ride is

not “part of a journey that the driver makes for himself” as stated previously in the Law, it is a

journey the driver makes for yourself! Functioning like a taxi-service without the same

accreditation raises a lot of problems for these firms. They are born as start-ups in San Francisco

to become the heavy weights of the on-demand applications competing in the US market, fuelled

by funds raised by venture capital. Uber has grown has a global firm very rapidly, its growth being

largely based on evading regulations and breaking the laws, shifting the risk on to employees under

the guise of sharing (Schor, 2014). From its creation in 2009, the 50 billion dollars start-up has

expanded to more than 300 cities in 50 countries, facing very diverse rules, some of its services

being banned in Korea, France, Spain, Germany...

Uber drivers are independent contractors, there is “a rigorous screening process to verify that every

driver is insured and legally qualified to drive”8; this means that roughly anybody with a vehicle

license and a proper car can become an Uber driver. The on-demand platform have in fact entered

the market with self-defined new rules, when regular taxi drivers have to hold a vocational training

certificate, and also a license the cost is some 400 000 euros in Nice (France) for instance, little

8 www.uber.com

Page 20: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

more expensive than the car and smartphone necessary for the Uber drivers to start a business.

Uber does not own any physical resources like cars but controls one side of the market: the Uber

drivers are not sharing a ride, they are semi-professional workers, self-entrepreneurs who have

invested in their own car to meet the standard required by Uber, have to pay for the maintenance

and gaz…, when the rates and terms of the travels are fixed by the platform, which takes a cut on

the transactions. The market design implemented by Uber is a scheme to shift risks to the drivers

and to benefit from low fixed costs, and looks like a centralized market place. Uber pricing is

similar exclusively by Uber applications and never by the drivers directly. The platform uses an

automated algorithm to modify the price levels in case of surge, to attract more drivers and match

the demand. It can also decrease the prices to cope with competition. The price variations are not

under the control of the drivers, which have to adapt. The economic value is not in owning

resources but in managing the marketplace. As a knowledge-based supplier, Uber organizes

exchanges between owners of resources, seeking personal interest, and consumers of these resource

units. This two-sided market (Rochet & Tirole, 2006) plays an important role throughout the

economy by developing indirect network externalities and by minimizing transaction costs between

groups.

Uber is confronted indeed to different fronts regarding competition:

- The one of lower-costs start-ups like Lyft, Sidecar, Didi Kuadi for instance, he faced creating

some low cost services, UberPop for instance, which have been banned in different countries. Its

scope is global, Uber plans to operate more trips in China and India than in the US by the end of

2015.

- The one of the taxi companies, which organized to decrease drastically the prices. In Paris

(France) for instance, the platform decided to cut tariffs of 20 % from one day to the other to remain

Page 21: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

competitive, without any dialogue with its drivers. The result has been demonstrations and strikes

from these drivers because of decreasing earnings…

Passengers widely report a higher level of courtesy from Uber drivers than from taxicabs (Edelman

& Geradin, 2015). The on-demand applications implement indeed the reputation systems

characteristic of the platform economy to foster trust in the system. Users of the application can

rate drivers; in turn, drivers can rate users; the aim is to increase trust in the service, as well as is

quality. The passengers evaluate driver courtesy, vehicle condition…, can be asked about their

experience by the platform, which can deter opportunistic driver behavior, target for remediation

or even eliminate low-quality service providers. The same can apply to customers. The reputation

systems are thus serving the intended purpose, improving the service. Price is thus not the only

issue at stake; Uber has imposed a global standard for the quality of service the tourists expect on

a global scale. It is often difficult for local taxi companies to compete because they are not built on

the same models. Wherever it set up Uber has disturbed incumbent firms and questioned economic

models in the urban transport.

Uber is present in 300 cities, the economic core of the world economy. The sharing economy has

been associated to the leisure side of travels nevertheless the huge segment of business travel is

more and more targeted by Uber and other platforms. According to a report of CWT (2015), it

seems that the status quo between traditional carriers and platforms is bound to change, as “business

travelers vote with their feet and shift their travel patterns” (Velikova, 2014). Uber is indeed very

active in this market, and concludes agreements and partnerships with different firms and travel

management companies. The most important has been with Concur, which has more than 20 000

clients gathering 25 million travelers over 100 countries. With the integration between Concur and

Uber, business travelers will be able to request, ride, pay and expense each ride to the company

without additional work, travel managers will get more control and insight into ground

Page 22: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

transportation spend, will benefit from automated expense management, as well as have a better

way of tracking travelers location (Velikova, 2014). The business travel market is over 1 trillion

dollars a year, the past competition between Uber and taxis looks like a warm up, the changes of

the tourism travel industry are to come.

ii. Carsharing is another platform service more and more dedicated to tourists; it allows a

community to share cars rather than to own its own car. Cars are expensive underutilized

commodities; the average car is unused 90 % of the time, a waste value that can create a lot of

market opportunities, the forecasts relative to the market of sharing amount to billion dollars.

Zipcar has been some fifteen years ago among the first to develop a platform gathering a

community of users and allowing to shun car ownership and prefer flexible and affordable solutions

for access. The platform is a for-profit provider to peer solution, Zipcar owning and giving access

to the cars. Nevertheless, the model was very different from traditional rent-a-car services. Indeed

users are members approved to be involved in the service, reservation, pick-up and return is self-

service, time window is 24 hours a day, cars can be rented by the minute and by the hour, not only

by the day as with the rent-a-car, fuel costs are include in the rates (Danielis et al., 2012). The

members, 770 000, pay a monthly or annual membership fee and the effective time they reserve a

car, via Internet or mobile apps. The zipcars, a fleet of roughly 10 000 vehicles, more than 50

brands and models, have RFID transponders to lock and unlock the doors. The heavy weight

incumbents on the market pay attention to these developments; Avis Budget Group acquired Zipcar

in March 2013 for around 500 million dollars, to control traditional rental car as well as carsharing.

Zipcar could be considered as a semi-common (Fennell, 2011), as the members are part of a

community the fees are used to invest in the resources, even if for profit. The carsharing initiatives

are exploding, because of environmental problems on the one hand, of pivotal market issues on the

other hand.

Page 23: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

On the one hand thus, a lot of public initiatives have emerged to solve traffic and parking

congestion, pollution problems in the cities. Non-profit equivalents to Zipcar are available for the

citizens. City CarShare founded in 2001 in the San Francisco Bay Area for instance. It is the largest

non-profit carsharing service in the US. Public carsharing solutions are today available over a

thousand of cities across the world, in addition to bikesharing, Autolob’ for instance in France

offering small electric cars, GoGet, Mobizen more globally.

On the other hand, carsharing represents a huge market; its development highlights deep changes

in the preferences, the behaviours of the consumers; the emergence of new market designs related

to the most important industrial sector of our economies. Car manufacturers have been scared at

the idea to be the next Nokia or Kodak, the two undisputed technological leaders which have failed

not because of inadequate technological innovation, but because they had not seen the market

design evolutions, the rise of the platforms and open mobile applications. They begin to pay

attention to these evolutions, basically the general movement from products to services that is

driving the evolution of the markets as well as of the society.

Car manufacturers have thus introduced their own carsharing services, including Daimler's

Car2Go, BMW's DriveNow, Volkswagen's Quicar, Fiat’s Enjoy, General Motors’ Let’s Drive

NYC to give some examples, but Toyota, Peugeot, all manufacturers have experiences or projects

running, offering their members alternatives to owning a car, the possibility to access one when

needed and to pay its use per the minute. The rationale behind carsharing is simple, instead of

selling once a product, an expensive car, it becomes better to sell thousands of times a service, the

access to the same car.

Finally, carsharing for-profit peer to peer platforms have flourished everywhere, the equivalent of

Blablacar or Airbnb for cars, with the same features, network externalities, insurance, trust…, we

will not develop again here. The platform does not own any car, it simply allows the sharing of

Page 24: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

cars owned by individuals, users which make their vehicle available for other users to rent for a

period of time. Platforms like Relayrides, Zimride, Spride, Getaround, Drivy, Kolicar among the

numerous existing ones, have grown rapidly, the economic incentive to share the second-most-

valuable asset with a stranger may be compelling.

Carsharing for-profit peer to peer platforms dedicated to tourists have also grown in airports,

allowing travellers to rent their cars to tourists, approved members of the platform, when they are

themselves flying away from home for some days. The concept is developing also by the stations.

Given the prices of the parking areas the travellers have to bear, the carsharing solutions proposed

by these innovative start-ups, FlightCar, TravelerCar, Tripndrive, Carnimise for instance, have

been rapidly adopted. Easyjet is also developing its own service, easyCarClub. The platforms

usually offers the parking fees to the approved members (proofs of ownership, vehicle’s stats)

accepting to share their car when leaving, and pays some amount for each kilometer traveled when

their car is effectively rented. Approved members get the lowest rental rates of the market, 50 %

of the rent-a-car rates, and a free insurance. The platforms are free to join, as their business model

depends on the size of the community. They underlie market places in which car owners and car

renters do not meet, neither online nor offline.

Summing-up, the platform economy services have exploded, there are open to the tourists and it

has never been to easy and cheap to travel, to find information on the mass of competing solutions

existing on the markets, and to bypass the less convenient ones regarding price, environmental,

societal issues. Regarding transportation, sharing is no more a private matter; the scope of the

platform economy is amazing, involving start-ups, unicors, as well as the main actors of the sector.

Concentration and globalization are key words of the platform economy, both fuelled by the

network externalities attached to these market places. Consequently, the leaders of the global

economy, which are nowadays platform based, are concerned by these evolutions. Google will

Page 25: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

certainly the core of the travel economy to come. Google Maps, geolocalization, real-time services

are already the foundations of most of the platforms. Google Ventures, is very implicated and

invests in many start-ups; it invested besides 200 million dollars in Uber years ago and has been a

support to the growth of the former start-up. It is also present through Google Wallet, which allows

paying directly the journeys. Nevertheless Google is more and more directly involved. It has bought

Waze, the GPS powered, crowdsourcing, trafic-thwarting Israeli start-up for 1.1 billion dollars in

June 2013, and created recently RideWith, a short-distance ridesharing solution run via Waze. The

Waze community is involved in crowdsourcing, reporting mapping errors, traffic jams or accidents.

RideWith is experimented now in Israel. But the Waze community is global, and amounts to 70

million across the world… Finally Google is developing the Google Car, an autonomous self-

driving car capable of navigating without any human input, which can revolutionize car sharing.

Uber is consequently also investing a lot in the technology, and develop a partnership with the

Carnegie Mellon University of Pittsburgh to produce its own self-driving car, seemingly a

necessary condition not to be uberized. The whole car manufacturers have followed; both self-

driving car and carsharing platforms are a key of the competition in the car industry, a competition

the car traditional manufacturers will not necessarily win.

The platform economy is imposing access against ownership, the shift from the products to the

services has induced new market designs and new business models, changing the way to travel. In

the emerging global world of standardized services, the tourists can be autonomous. Through their

smartphones and their mobile applications, information, geolocalization, route planning, platform

travel services…, the tourists can travel their own way more and more easily. Their smartphones

will have thus soon wheels, Google and Apple cars driving them safely over unknown landscapes.

4. Conclusion

Page 26: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Building on transportation cases in tourism, the paper has disentangled the various approaches and

motives under sharing. The spreading of “sharing out” (Belk, 2010) as a significant substitute of

the traditional markets is gone with the steadily strengthening of a platform economy. The shifts

from ownership to access, from products to services are the bases for far-reaching economic

changes. These services have been implemented by Knowledge Innovative Service Suppliers, start-

ups at the origin of innovative marketplaces run through platforms, which allow the meeting

between the ‘haves’ and the ‘wants’ on a global scale. Sharing-out is a complex and plural

phenomenon, often encapsulated in a uniform model in the literature. The paper has shown that

diversity is in fact a basic feature of the platforms, as they can be non-profit, for-profit, the two

sides of the markets they link embodying also different actors and organisation of the marketplaces,

peer to peer, providers to peers…

The paper has rationalized this diversity and highlighted the common features, network

externalities and trust as central elements of the viability of the platforms, which link highly

dispersed individuals. The taxonomy proposed makes a conceptual contribution to both the

platform economy and the tourism management and marketing literature. Moreover, it provides

insights that might be relevant for both policy makers and managers.

The resulting economy can be interpreted in very different ways, depending where the focus is put.

Indeed, the platform economy has two dimensions, two levels which coexist, and have not

necessarily the same objectives, incentives; the ‘haves’ and the ‘wants’ aiming at sharing, and the

platforms often aiming at profit. The peer to peer exchanges can be seen as non-market

decentralized systems, where the resources are no more concentrated but dispersed across a

multitude of individuals, when the platforms necessary to aggregate the microscopic peers and to

organize the matching are more often seen as leading to a unprecedented concentration of the

activities in some hands, in line with the network externalities working on two-side markets. The

Page 27: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

two arguments are somewhat true, and this is one of the paradoxes of this new market economy.

The platform economy raises a lot of issues that would be worth exploring and are part of our

research agenda, but are impossible to tackle in this paper. They are often summarized as the shift

of the risks from the firms to the individuals, the worsening of social conditions and security, the

unfair behaviours regarding taxes and regulations, when other advocates platforms offer solutions

towards additional revenues for people, flexible and efficient market solutions for services,

pollution and congestion issues solving... Whatever the regards on the platform economy, its very

existence is clearly changing the whole society and also the way marketers and users of

transportation services might offer and customize their offerings on the basis of the new sharing

paradigm.

More and more affordable and efficient travel opportunities become available for tourist, as well

as for business travelers. The rise of new market designs from the entry of innovative actors

questions both the sharing of economic value and the regulation of the whole tourism industry.

How value is created and later apportioned among the multiple stakeholders in the transportation

sector deserve further attention. More than the sharing economy, the sharing of the economic value

is the key issue at stakes.

References

ADEME (2015). Leviers d’actions pour favoriser le covoiturage de courte distance, évaluation de l’impact sur les polluants atmosphériques et le CO2 – Leviers d’actions, benchmark et exploitation de l’enquête nationale Transports et déplacements (ENTD) – Etude réalisée par INDIGGO et EnvirOconsult. 233p.

Page 28: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Aldebert B., Dang R.J., & Longhi. C. (2011). Innovation in the Tourism Industry: The Case of Tourism@. Tourism Management, 32(5), 1204–1213.

Anderson C. (2004). The Long Tail. WIRED magazine. Issue 12.10, October, 1-5 Bardi F., & Eckhardt G.M. (2012). Access-based consumption: the case of car sharing. Journal of

Consumer Research, Vol. 39, 881-898.

Belk R. (2010). Sharing. The Journal of Consumer Research, Vol.36, n°5, 715-734.

Belk R. (2014). Sharing Versus Pseudo-Sharing in Web 2.0. Anthropologist, 18, 1, 7-23 Botsman R., & Rogers R. (2011). What's Mine is Yours: How Collaborative Consumption is

Changing the Way We Live. Collins, London

Buhalis D. (1998). Strategic use of information technologies in the tourism industry. Tourism Management, Vol. 19, No. 5, 409–421.

Buhalis D., & Law R. (2008). Progress in Information Technology and Tourism Management: 20 Years on and 10 Years after the Internet—The State of eTourism Research, Tourism Management, 29(4), 609–623.

Buhalis D., & Zoge M. (2007). The Strategic Impact of the Internet on the Tourism Industry. In M. Sigala, L. Mich, J. Murphy (eds), Information and Communication Technologies in Tourism 2007, 481–492. Wien: Springer-Verlag,

Choudary S. P. (2014). From social media to the sharing economy: the three drivers of business disruption. June 5. From Platform Thinking, http://platformed.info/

Cohen W., & Levinthal D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35 (1), 128-152.

CWT (2015). Faster, smarter, better? Emerging technologies and trends and their impact on managed travel, CWT Travel Management Institute, May

Danielis R., Rotaris L., & Valeri E. (2012.) Carsharing for tourists, Rivista Italiana di Economia Demografia e Statistica, Vol. LXVI-2, April, June, 103–119.

Edelman B.G., & Geradin D. (2015). Efficiencies and regulation: how should we regulate companies like Airbnb and Uber, working paper 16-026, Harvard Business School, September 15.

Evans D.S. (2011a). Platform Economics. Essays on Multi-Sided Businesses. Competition Policy International. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1974020

Evans D.S. (2011b). The Internet of Things How the Next Evolution of the Internet Is Changing Everything. CISCO White Paper, April, San Jose, 2011.

Felson M., & Spaeth J.L (1978). Community Structure and Collaborative Consumption: A routine

activity approach. American Behavioral Scientist, 21, 614–24. Fennell L.A (2011). Ostrom’s Law: Property Rights in the Commons. International Journal of the

Commons, Vol. 5, n°1, 9–27.

Fiske A.P. (1992). The Four Elementary Forms of Sociability: Framework for a Unified Theory of Social Relations. Psychological Review, Vol.99, n°4, 689–723.

Gansky L. (2012). The Mesh: Why the Future of Business is Sharing. Portfolio Penguin.

Page 29: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Geron T. (2013) Airbnb and The Unstoppable Rise Of The Share Economy, February 11, 2013 issue of Forbes, http://www.forbes.com/

Henderson R., & Clark K. (1990). Architectural Innovation: The Reconfiguration of Existing Product Technologies and the Failure of Established Firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 9–30.

Kim W.G., Lee C., & Hiemstra, S.J. (2004). Effects of an online community on customer loyalty and travel product purchases. Tourism Management, Vol.25 (3), June, 343–355.

Kozinets R.V. (1999). E-tribes and marketing: virtual communities of consumption and their strategic marketing implications. European Management Journal, 17 (3), 252–264.

Longhi C. (2009). Internet and Organisation of the Industry in Tourism: A Focus on the Distribution of Travel and Tourism Services. Int. J. Leisure and Tourism Marketing, 1(2), 131–151.

Longhi C., & Rochhia S. (2015). Long tails in the tourism industry: towards knowledge intensive service suppliers. Int. J. Leisure and Tourism Marketing, vol.4, n°3/4, 241-259.

Mariani M.M., Baggio R., Buhalis D. & Longhi C. (eds.) (2014). Tourism Management, Marketing and Development: the Importance of Networks and ICTs, New York, Palgrave.

Miranda S. (2012). Les nouveaux paradigmes du tourisme mobiquitaire. MBDS, University Nice Sophia Antipolis, mimeo

O’Reilly T. (2006). Web 2.0 Compact Definition: Trying Again. Radar, December 10, http://radar.oreilly.com/

O’Reilly T., & Battelle J. (2009). Web Squared: Web 2.0 Five Years On, Special Report. San Francisco: O’Reilly Media Techweb, 2009.

OECD (2014) Work on Science, Technology and Industry. Paris, 1-34.

Ostrom E., & Hess C. (2007). A Framework for Analyzing the Knowledge Commons. In Hess C. and Ostrom E. eds, Understanding Knowledge as a Commons. From Theory to Practice. The MIT Press.

Pick F., & Dreher J. (2015). Sustaining hierarchy –Uber isn’t sharing. Kings Review, May 5th. Price J.A. (1975). Sharing: The Integration of Intimate Economies. Anthropologica, News series,

Vol.17, n°1, 3-27.

Putnam R. (2000). Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster.

Rochet J-C, & Tirole J. (2006). Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report. The RAND Journal of Economics, Vol.35, n°3, 645-667.

Schor J. (2014). Debating the sharing economy, the Great Transition Initiative, working paper, October

Velikova M. (2014). How the sharing economy is reinventing business travel, Travlpeer, July 31

Wade Ph., & Raffour G. (2000). Tourisme et technologies de l’information et de la communication : le futur est déjà là, Rapport au Conseil National du Tourisme, http://www.tourisme.gouv.fr

Wang R. (2013). Monday’s musings: four elements for a #SharingEconomy biz model in #MatrixCommerce, May 26, Software Insider.

Wang Y., Yu Q., & Fesenmaier D.R. (2002). Defining the virtual tourist community: implications

Page 30: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

for tourism marketing. Tourism Management, 23, 407–417

Page 31: Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport

Documents De travail GreDeG parus en 2016GREDEG Working Papers Released in 2016

2016-01 Christian Longhi, Marcello M. Mariani & Sylvie Rochhia Sharing and Tourism: The Rise of New Markets in Transport