essays in volatility modeling and option pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · essays in volatility modeling...

135
Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing by Mathieu Fournier A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy « Joseph L. Rotman School of Management » University of Toronto © Copyright by Mathieu Fournier 2014

Upload: others

Post on 11-Mar-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing

by

Mathieu Fournier

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements

for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

« Joseph L. Rotman School of Management »

University of Toronto

© Copyright by Mathieu Fournier 2014

Page 2: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

Abstracts

Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing

Mathieu Fournier

Doctor of Philosophy

Graduate Department of Joseph L. Rotman School of Management

University of Toronto

2014

The common thread that runs through my research is the implication of volatility

dynamics for option pricing. In the �rst chapter of this thesis, my co-authors and I study

the presence of a factor structure in equity options. A principal component analysis of

equity options reveals a strong factor structure. Guided by this �nding, we develop an

equity option valuation model that captures this factor structure. The model allows for

stochastic volatility in the market return and also in the idiosyncratic component of equity

returns. The model has a series of predictions relating individual �rm�s beta to patterns

in implied volatilities. The equity option data support the cross-sectional implications

of the estimated model. In the second chapter, I focus on the impact of intermediaries�

risk sharing capacity on index options. I examine how inventory risk and market-maker

wealth jointly determine the value of index options through their e¤ects on the variance

risk premium. My analysis shows that part of the variance risk premium compensates

option market-makers for their exposure to market variance. Based on these �ndings, I

develop a theoretical model in which market variance is stochastic and the representative

market-maker accumulates inventory over time by absorbing end-users� net demand for

index options. Starting from the market-maker�s optimal trading strategy, I derive an

explicit formula linking the variance risk premium to inventory risk and market-maker

wealth. The model predicts that the variance risk premium is in�uenced by the ratio of

inventory risk to the market-maker�s wealth. Estimating the model on S&P 500 index

returns and options, I �nd that it performs well.

ii

Page 3: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

Dedication

To my parents and my family.

.

iii

Page 4: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

Acknowledgements

I would like to express my gratitude to my supervisor, Peter Christo¤ersen for his continual

guidance. I am also grateful to my committee members Redouane Elkamhi, Christian

Gouriéroux, Chayawat Ornthanalai, and Jason Wei for their many insights and advices.

This work was supported by the Rotman School of Management.

.

iv

Page 5: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

Contents

1 The Factor Structure in Equity Options 1

1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

1.2 Common Factors in Equity Option Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4

1.2.1 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

1.2.2 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

1.2.3 Other Stylized Facts in the Cross-Section of Equity Option Prices . 8

1.3 Equity Option Valuation Using a Single-Factor Structure . . . . . . . . . . 9

1.4 Model Properties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

1.4.1 Factor Structure and Equity Option Sensitivities . . . . . . . . . . . 14

1.4.2 Factor Structure and Equity Option Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

1.4.3 The Relative Pricing of Index and Equity Options . . . . . . . . . . 17

1.4.4 The Level of Equity Option Volatility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

1.4.5 Equity Option Skews . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

1.4.6 The Term Structure of Equity Volatility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

1.5 Estimation and Fit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

1.5.1 Estimation Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

1.5.2 Parameter Estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

1.5.3 Model Fit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

1.5.4 Equity Betas and Equity Option IVs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

1.5.5 Option-Implied and Regression Betas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

1.5.6 The Cross-Section of Idiosyncratic Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

1.6 Summary and Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

v

Page 6: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

2 Inventory Risk, Market-Maker Wealth, and the Variance Risk Premium 67

2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67

2.2 Empirical Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72

2.2.1 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72

2.2.2 De�nition of Main Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73

2.2.3 Methodology and Predictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77

2.2.4 Control Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78

2.2.5 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80

2.2.6 The Financial Crisis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82

2.3 The Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83

2.4 Model Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86

2.4.1 The Structure of the Variance Risk Premium . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86

2.4.2 Market-Maker Optimal Wealth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88

2.4.3 Risk-Neutral Dynamics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89

2.5 Estimation and Fit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90

2.5.1 Estimation Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90

2.5.2 Parameter Estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92

2.5.3 Index Option Fit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94

2.5.4 Economic Magnitude . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96

2.6 Summary and Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98

vi

Page 7: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

List of Tables

2.1 Companies, Tickers and Option Contracts p 60

2.2 Summary Statistics on Implied Volatility 1996-2010 p 61

2.3 Principal Component from Principal Component Analysis of Equity Implied p 62

Volatility

2.4 Model Parameters and Properties. Index and Equity Options p 63

2.5 Model Fit for Index and Equity Put Options p 64

2.6 Idiosyncratic Variance Correlation Matrix p 65

2.7 (A1) Principal Component (PC) Loadings for IV Level, Moneyness Slope, p 66

and Maturity Slope

3.1 Descriptive Statistics p 117

3.2 Implied Volatility, Market-Makers�Inventory, and Delta-Hedged Gains p 118

and Losses by Moneyness and Maturity for SPX Options

3.3 Time-Series Regressions of the One-month of Log-Variance Risk Premium p 119

3.4A Time-Series Regressions of the Term Structure of Log-Variance Risk p 120

Premia. 1997-2011

3.4B Time-Series Regressions of the Term Structure of Variance Risk p 121

Premia. 1997-2011

3.5 Statistics of the Return Distribution of Delta-Hedged Near-the-Money Options p 122

3.6 Return Statistics and Parameter Coe¢ cients for CEV and Heston (1993) p 123

from MLIS. 1997-2011

3.7 Inventory Risk and Market-Maker0s Wealth Parameters, Heston(1993)0s p 124

Variance Risk Premium Coe¢ cient, and SIVSE. 1997-2011

vii

Page 8: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

3.8 Model Fit Based on 131,838 SPX Put Options. 1997-2011 p 125

viii

Page 9: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

List of Figures

2.1 At-the-MoneyImpliedVolatility.Six Firms and the S&P 500 Index p 49

2.2 Implied Volatility Level, Moneyness and Term Slope. S&P 500 Index and p 50

the First Principal Component from 29 Firms

2.3 Market Delta and Vega of Equity Call Options p 51

2.4 Expected Excess Returns on Equity Options p 52

2.5 Beta and Implied Volatility Across Moneyness and Maturity p 53

2.6A Average Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Volatility Smile.High p 54

Volatility (black) and Low Volatility (grey) Days (Panel A)

2.6B Average Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Volatility Smile.High p 55

Volatility (black) and Low Volatility (grey) Days (Panel B)

2.7A Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Term Structures for At-the- p 56

Money Implied Volatility. Upward-Sloping (grey) and Downward-Sloping

(black) Days (Panel A)

2.7B Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Term Structures for At-the- p 57

Money Implied Volatility. Upward-Sloping (grey) and Downward-Sloping

(black) Days (Panel B)

2.8 Implied Volatility Levels, Moneyness Slopes, and Term Structure Slopes p 58

Scatter Plotted Against Beta. 29 Firms

2.9 Regression-based Betas versus Option-Implied Beta. 29 Firms p 59

3.1 S&P 500 Index, Variance Risk Premium, and Delta-Hedged Gains and p 111

Losses of Near-the-Money Options

3.2 CBOE VIX Index and Market-Makers�Inventory Risk p 112

ix

Page 10: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

3.3 Market-Makers�Daily and Cumulative Pro�ts and Losses, and p 113

Market-Makers�Bid-Ask Spread Revenue

3.4 Filtered Spot Volatilities Using Daily S&P 500 Returns p 114

3.5 One-Month Variance Risk Premium, IVRMSE, and Implied p 115

Volatility Smile by Model

3.6 The Dollar Response of Index Options to Inventory Risk and p 116

Market-Maker0s Wealth

x

Page 11: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

1

Chapter 1

The Factor Structure in Equity Options

1.1 Introduction

In their path-breaking study, Black and Scholes (1973) show that when valuing equity

options in a constant volatility CAPM setting, the beta of the stock does not matter.

Consequently, standard equity option valuation models make no attempt at modeling the

factor structure in the equity market. Typically, a stochastic process is assumed for each

underlying equity price and the option is priced on this stochastic process, ignoring any links

the underlying equity price may have with other equity prices through common factors.

Seminal papers in this vein include Wiggins (1987), Hull and White (1987), and Heston

(1993), Bakshi, Cao and Chen (1997), and Bates (2000, 2008). We show that in a CAPM

setting with stochastic volatility, the beta does indeed matter for equity option prices. We

�nd strong support for this factor structure in a large-scale empirical investigation using

equity option prices.

When considering a single stock option, ignoring an underlying factor structure may

be relatively harmless. However, in portfolio applications it is crucial to understand links

between the underlying stocks. Risk managers need to understand the total exposure to the

underlying risk factors in a portfolio of stocks and stock options. Equity portfolio managers

who use equity options to hedge large downside moves in individual stocks need to know

their overall market exposure. Dispersion traders who sell (expensive) index options and

buy (cheaper) equity options need to understand the market exposure of individual equity

options. See for example Driessen, Maenhout, and Vilkov (2009) for evidence on the market

Page 12: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

2

exposure of equity options.

Our empirical analysis of more than three quarters of a million index option prices

and 11 million equity option prices reveals a very strong factor structure. We study three

characteristics of option prices: short-term implied volatility (IV) levels, the slope of IV

curves across option moneyness, and the slope of IV curves across option maturity.

First, we compute the daily time series of implied volatility levels (IV) on the stocks

in the Dow Jones Industrials Average and extract their principal components. The �rst

common component explains 77% of the cross-sectional variation in IV levels and the com-

mon component has an 92% correlation with the short-term implied volatility constructed

from S&P 500 index options. The level of short-term equity option IV appears to be

characterized by a common factor.

Second, a principal component analysis of equity option IV moneyness, known as the

option skew, reveals a signi�cant common component as well. 77% of the variation in

the skew across equities is captured by the �rst principal component. Furthermore, this

common component has a correlation of 64% with the skew of market index options. Third,

60% of the variation in the term structure of equity IV is explained by the �rst principal

component. This component has a correlation of 80% with the IV term slope from S&P

500 index options.

We use the �ndings from the principal component analysis as guidance to develop a

structural model of equity option prices that incorporates a market factor structure. In

line with well-known empirical facts in the literature on index options (see for example

Bakshi, Cao and Chen, 1997; Heston and Nandi, 2000; Bates, 2000; and Jones, 2003),

the model allows for mean-reverting stochastic volatility and correlated shocks to returns

and volatility. Motivated by the principal component analysis, we allow for idiosyncratic

shocks to equity returns which also have mean-reverting stochastic volatility and a separate

leverage e¤ect.

Individual equity returns are linked to the market index using a standard linear factor

model with a constant factor loading. In the resulting two-factor stochastic volatility

Page 13: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

3

model, the equity option price is driven by the beta of the stock, the market variance risk

premium, and the market and idiosyncratic variance dynamics.1 The model belongs to the

a¢ ne class, which yields closed-form option pricing formulas. It can be extended to allowing

for market-wide and idiosyncratic jumps.2 Our model shows that equity option sensitivities

and expected returns will depend on beta. It also explains why at-the-money index options

appear to be relatively more expensive than at-the-money options on individual stocks.

The model has three important cross-sectional implications. First, it predicts that

�rms with higher betas have higher implied volatilities. Second, it predicts that �rms

with higher betas have steeper moneyness slopes. Third, higher beta �rms are expected to

have a greater positive (negative) slope when the market variance term-structure is upward

(downward) sloping.

We develop a convenient approach to estimating the model using option data. When

estimating the model on the �rms in the Dow-Jones index, we �nd that it provides a good

�t to observed equity option prices, and the cross-sectional implications of the model are

supported by the data. While it is not the main focus of this paper, our model provides

option-implied estimates of market betas, which is a topic of recent interest, studied by for

example Chang, Christo¤ersen, Jacobs, and Vainberg (2012), and Buss and Vilkov (2012).

Multiple applications in asset pricing and corporate �nance require estimates of beta, such

as cost of capital estimation, performance evaluation, portfolio selection, and abnormal

return measurement.

Our paper is also related to the recent empirical literature on equity options. Dennis and

Mayhew (2002) investigate the relationship between �rm characteristics and risk-neutral

skewness. Bakshi and Kapadia (2003) investigate the volatility risk premium for equity

options. Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003) derive a skew law for individual stocks,

decomposing individual return skewness into a systematic and idiosyncratic component.

1Existing studies of two-factor SV models mainly focus on index options and do not model a factorstructure in returns. See Taylor and Xu (1994), Bates (2000), and Christo¤ersen, Heston and Jacobs(2009) among others.

2Pan (2002), Broadie, Chernov, and Johannes (2007), and Bates (2008) among others have documentedthe importance of modeling jumps in index options.

Page 14: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

4

They �nd that individual �rms display much less (negative) option-implied skewness than

the market index. Duan and Wei (2009) use a version of the model in Bakshi, Kapadia,

and Madan (2003) to relate individual stocks�implied volatilities to systematic risk, and

empirically relate systematic risk to implied volatilities. Bakshi, Cao, and Zhong (2012) in-

vestigate the performance of jump models for equity option valuation. Engle and Figlewski

(2012) develop time series models of implied volatilities and study their correlation dynam-

ics. Kelly, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2013) use the model in our paper to study the

pricing of implicit government guarantees to the banking sector. Finally, Carr and Madan

(2012) develop a Levy-based model with factor structure.

Our paper is also related to recent theoretical advances. Mo and Wu (2007) develop

an international CAPM model which has features similar to our model. Elkamhi and

Ornthanalai (2010) develop a bivariate discrete-time GARCH model to extract the market

jump risk premia implicit in individual equity option prices. Finally, Serban, Lehoczky,

and Seppi (2008) develop a non-a¢ ne model to investigate the relative pricing of index and

equity options.

The reminder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we describe the data

set and present the principal components analysis. In Section 3 we develop the theoretical

model. Section 4 highlights a number of cross-sectional implications of the model. In

Section 5 we estimate the model and investigate its �t to observed index and equity option

prices. Section 6 concludes. The appendix contains the proofs of the propositions.

1.2 Common Factors in Equity Option Prices

In this section we �rst introduce the data set used in our study. We then look for evidence

of commonality in three crucial features of the cross-section of equity options: Implied

volatility levels, moneyness slopes (or skews), and volatility term structures. We rely on a

principal component analysis (PCA) of the �rm-speci�c levels of short-term at-the-money

implied volatility (IV), the slope of IV with respect to option moneyness, and the slope of

IV with respect to option maturity. The results of this model-free investigation will help

Page 15: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

5

identify desirable features of a factor model of equity option prices.

1.2.1 Data

We rely on end-of-day implied volatility surface data from OptionMetrics starting on Jan-

uary 4, 1996 and ending on October 29, 2010. We use the S&P 500 index to proxy for

the market factor. For our sample of individual equities, we choose the �rms in the Dow

Jones Industrial Average index at the end of the sample. Of the 30 �rms in the index we

excluded Kraft Foods for which data are not available throughout the sample.

The implied volatility surfaces contain options with more than 30 days and less than

365 days to maturity (DTM). We �lter out options that have moneyness (spot price over

strike price) less than 0:7 and larger than 1:3, those that do not satisfy the usual arbitrage

conditions, those with implied volatility less than 5% and greater than 150%, and those for

which the present value of dividends is larger than 4% of the stock price. For each option

maturity, interest rates are estimated by linear interpolation using zero coupon Treasury

yields. Dividends are obtained from OptionMetrics and are assumed to be known during

the life of each option. For each option we discount future dividends from the current spot

price.

The S&P 500 index options are European, but the individual equity options are Amer-

ican style, and their prices may be in�uenced by early exercise premiums. OptionMetrics

therefore uses binomial trees to compute implied volatility for equity options. Using these

implied volatilities, we can treat all options as European-style in the analysis below.

Table 1 presents the number of option contracts, the number of calls and puts, the aver-

age days-to-maturity, and the average implied volatility. We have a total of 775; 670 index

options and on average 758; 976 equity options per �rm. The average implied volatility

for the market is 20:65% during the sample period. Cisco has the highest average implied

volatility (40:68%) while Johnson & Johnson has the lowest average implied volatility

(22:79%). Table 1 also shows that the data set is balanced with respect to the number of

calls and puts.

Page 16: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

6

Table 2 reports the average, minimum, and maximum implied volatility, as well as the

average option vega. Note that the index option vega is much higher than the equity vegas

simply because the S&P500 index values are much larger than the typical stock price.

Figure 1 plots the daily average short-term (30 < DTM < 60) at-the-money (0:95 <

S=K < 1:05) implied volatility (IV) for six �rms (black lines) as well as for the S&P 500

index (grey lines). Figure 1 shows that the variation in the short-term at-the-money (ATM)

equity volatility for each �rm is highly related to S&P 500 volatility.

1.2.2 Methodology

We want to assess the extent to which the time-varying volatilities of equities share one or

more common components. In order to gauge the degree of commonality in risk-neutral

volatilities, we need daily estimates of the level and slope of the implied volatility curve,

and of the slope of the term structure of implied volatility for all �rms and the index. To

obtain these estimates, we run the following regression for �rm j for each day t;

IVj;l;t = aj;t + bj;t ��Sjt =Kj;l

�+ cj;t � (DTMj;l) + �j;l;t; (1.1)

where l denotes an option available for �rm j on day t. The regressors are standardized

each day by subtracting the mean and dividing by the standard deviation. We run the

same regression on index option IVs. We interpret aj;t as a measure of the level of implied

volatilities of �rm j on day t. Similarly, bj;t captures the slope of implied volatility curve,

while cj;t proxies for the slope of the term structure of implied volatility.

Once the regression coe¢ cients have been estimated on each day and for each �rm, we

run a PCA analysis on each of the matrices faj;tg, fbj;tg, and fcj;tg. Table 3 contains the

results from the PCA analysis and Figure 2 plots the �rst principal component as well as

the time series of the corresponding index option coe¢ cients, aI;t, bI;t, and cI;t.

Page 17: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

7

Common Factors in the Level of Implied Equity Volatility

Panel A in Table 3 contains the results for implied volatility levels. We show the average,

minimum, and maximum loading across �rms for each component. We also report the

total variation captured as well as the correlation of each component with S&P 500 IV.

The results in Panel A of Table 3 are quite striking. The �rst component captures 77%

of the total cross-sectional variation in the level of IV and it has a 92% correlation with

the S&P 500 index IV. This suggests that the equity IVs have a very strong common

component that is highly correlated with index option IVs.

Panel A in Figure 2 shows the time series of IV levels for index options. Panel B plots

the time series of the �rst PCA component of equity IV. The strong relationship between

the two series is readily apparent.

The second PCA component in Panel A of Table 3 explains 13% of the total variation

and the third component explains 2%. The average loadings on these two components are

close to zero. The explanatory power of the second PCA component suggests the need for

a second, �rm-speci�c, source of variation in equity volatility.

Table A.1 in the Appendix reports the individual loadings for each �rm on each factor.

Table A.1 shows that the loadings on the �rst component are positive for all 29 �rms, illus-

trating the pervasive nature of the common factor. The loadings on the second component

take on a wide range of positive and negative values.

Common Factors in the Moneyness Slope

Panel B in Table 3 contains the results for IV moneyness slopes. The moneyness slopes

contain a signi�cant degree of co-movement. The �rst principal component explains 77% of

cross-sectional variation in the moneyness slope. The second and third components explain

6% and 4% respectively and their average loadings are close to zero.

Panel B also shows that the �rst principal component has a 64% correlation with the

moneyness slope of S&P 500 implied volatility. Equity moneyness slope dynamics clearly

seem driven to a non-trivial extent by the market moneyness slope.

Page 18: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

8

Panel C in Figure 2 plots the S&P 500 index IV moneyness slope in the top panel

and the �rst principal component from the equity moneyness slopes is shown in Panel D.

The relationship between the �rst principal component and the market moneyness slope

is readily apparent, but not as strong as for the volatility level in Panels A and B. Table

A.1 in the appendix shows that the �rst component has positive loadings on all 29 �rms

whereas the second and third components have positive and negative loadings for di¤erent

�rms.

Common Factors in the Term Structure Slope

Panel C in Table 3 contains the results for IV term structure slopes. The variation in the

term structure slope captured by the �rst principal component is 60%, which is lower than

for spot volatility (Panel A) and the moneyness slope (Panel B). The correlation between

the �rst component and the term slope of S&P 500 index option IV is 80%, which is higher

than for the moneyness slope in Panel B but lower than for the variance level in Panel A.

The second and third components capture 14% and 5% of the variation respectively and

the wide range of loadings on this factor suggest a scope for �rm-speci�c variation in the

IV term structure for equity options.

Panel E in Figure 2 plots the S&P 500 index IV term structure slope in the top panel

and the �rst principal component from the equity term slopes is shown in Panel F. Most

of the spikes in the S&P 500 term structure slope are clearly evident in the �rst princi-

pal component as well. Table A.1 in the Appendix show that the loadings on the �rst

component are positive for all 29 �rms.

We conclude that the market volatility term structure captures a substantial share of

the variation in equity volatility term structures.

1.2.3 Other Stylized Facts in the Cross-Section of Equity Option Prices

The literature on equity options has documented a number of important cross-sectional

stylized facts. Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003) derive a skew law for individual stocks,

Page 19: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

9

decomposing individual return skewness into a systematic and idiosyncratic component.

They theoretically investigate and empirically document the relationship between risk-

neutral market and equity skewness, which a¤ects the relationship between the moneyness

slope for equity and index options. They �nd that the volatility smile for the market

index is on average more negatively sloped than volatility smiles for individual �rms. They

also show that the more negatively skewed the risk-neutral distribution, the steeper the

volatility smile. Finally, they �nd that the risk-neutral equity distributions are on average

less skewed to the left than index distributions. Duan and Wei (2009) build on Bakshi,

Kapadia, and Madan (2003) to relate implied volatilities to systematic risk.

Some studies document cross-sectional relationships between either betas or systematic

risk, estimated using historical data, and characteristics of the equity IVs. Dennis and

Mayhew (2002) �nd that option-implied skewness tends to be more negative for stocks

with larger betas. Duan and Wei (2009) �nd that the level of implied equity volatility

is related to the systematic risk of the �rm and that the slope of the implied volatility

curve is related to systematic risk as well. Finally, Driessen, Maenhout, and Vilkov (2009)

�nd a large negative index variance risk premium, but �nd no evidence of a negative risk

premium on individual variance risk.

These �ndings are at �rst blush not directly related to the �ndings of the PCA analysis

above, which merely documents a strong factor structure of various aspects of implied

equity volatilities. We next outline a structural equity option modeling approach with a

factor structure that captures the results from the PCA analysis outlined above, but is

also able to match the cross-sectional relationships between betas and implied volatilities

documented by these studies.

1.3 Equity Option Valuation Using a Single-Factor Structure

We model an equity market consisting of n �rms driven by a single market factor, It. The

individual stock prices are denoted by Sjt , for j = 1; 2; :::; n. Investors also have access to

a risk-free bond which pays a return of r.

Page 20: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

10

The market factor evolves according to the process

dItIt= (r + �I)dt+ �I;tdW

(I;1)t ; (1.2)

where �I is the instantaneous market risk premium and where volatility is stochastic and

follows the standard square root process

d�2I;t = �I(�I � �2I;t)dt+ �I�I;tdW(I;2)t : (1.3)

As in Heston (1993), �I denotes the long-run variance, �I captures the speed of mean

reversion of �2I;t to �I , and �I measures volatility of volatility. The innovations to the market

factor return and volatility are correlated with coe¢ cient �I . Conventional estimates of �I

are negative and large capturing the so-called leverage e¤ect in aggregate market returns.

Individual equity prices are driven by the market factor as well as an idiosyncratic term

which also has stochastic volatility

dSjt

Sjt� rdt = �jdt+ �j

�dItIt� rdt

�+ �j;tdW

(j;1)t (1.4)

d�2j;t = �j(�j � �2j;t)dt+ �j�j;tdW(j;2)t ; (1.5)

where �j denotes the excess return and �j is the market beta of �rm j.

The innovations to idiosyncratic returns and volatility are correlated with coe¢ cient �j .

As suggested by the skew laws derived in Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003), asymmetry

of the idiosyncratic return component is required to explain the di¤erences in the price

structure of individual equity and index options. Note that this model of the equity market

has a total of 2(n+ 1) innovations.

To develop more intuition for the model, de�ne total spot variance for �rm j at time t

by

Vj;t � �2j�2I;t + �

2j;t: (1.6)

Page 21: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

11

Note that our single-factor stochastic volatility (SV) model for the market index in (1.3)

along with the single-factor SV model for idiosyncratic volatility in (1.5) implies a two-

factor SV model for total equity volatility in (1.6). Two-factor SV models have been stud-

ied in Taylor and Xu (1994), Bates (2000), and Christo¤ersen, Heston and Jacobs (2009),

among others. None of these papers models the factor structure in returns that we capture

through the �j , which allows us to separate total equity variance into a systematic and

an idiosyncratic part. When the market and idiosyncratic variances have di¤erent physi-

cal dynamics and/or carry di¤erent risk premia, beta will have important cross-sectional

implications for the pricing of equity options, which is the central focus of our work.

In order to use our stochastic volatility model of the equity market for option valuation

we need to de�ne a stochastic discount factor (SDF). We assume a standard SDF of the

linear form

dMt

Mt= �rdt�

� (I;1)t dW

(I;1)t +

(I;2)t dW

(I;2)t

��Xj

� (j;1)t dW

(j;1)t +

(j;2)t dW

(j;2)t

�; (1.7)

where t �h (I;1)t ;

(I;2)t ; :::;

(j;1)t ;

(j;2)t

icontains the market prices of risk. Given the SDF

in (2.14), the change-of-measure from the physical (P ) distribution to the risk-neutral (Q)

distribution has the exponential form

dQ

dP(t) �Mt exp(rt) = exp

��tR0

udWu �1

2

tR0

0udDW;W

0Eu u

�; (1.8)

where the vector Wu contains the 2(n + 1) innovations for each of the n �rms and the

market, and d h:; :i is the covariance operator.

Note that the correlation between W (I;1)t and W (I;2)

t and between W (j;1)t and W (j;2)

t

imply that the prices of market and idiosyncratic variance risk are (I;2)t + �I (I;1)t and

(j;2)t + �j

(j;1)t ; respectively. In the spirit of Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985) and Heston

Page 22: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

12

(1993), among others, we assume a price of market variance risk of the form

(I;2)t + �I

(I;1)t = �I�I;t:

We also assume that the idiosyncratic variance risk is not priced, so that

(j;2)t + �j

(j;1)t = 0;

although this restriction could be relaxed while still obtaining closed-form option prices.

Together the above assumptions yield the following result.

Proposition 1 Given the change-of-measure in (1.8) the processes governing the market

factor and equity returns under the Q-measure are given by

dItIt

= rdt+ �I;td ~W(I;1)t (1.9)

dSjt

Sjt= rdt+ �j

�dItIt� rdt

�+ �j;td ~W

(j;1)t ; (1.10)

and the Q-processes governing the market and idiosyncratic variances are

d�2I;t = ~�I

�~�I � �2I;t

�dt+ �I�I;td ~W

(I;2)t (1.11)

d�2j;t = �j��j � �2j;t

�dt+ �j�j;td ~W

(j;2)t ; (1.12)

with ~�I = �I +�I�I ; ~�I =�I�I~�I, and where d ~Wt denotes the risk-neutral counterpart of dWt

satisfying d ~Wt = dWt + dDW;W

0Et t. The prices of risk are given by

(I;1)t =

�I � �I�I�2I;t�I;t(1� �2I)

and (I;2)t =�I�

2I;t � �I�I

�I;t(1� �2I)(1.13)

(j;1)t =

�j�j;t(1� �2j )

and (j;2)t = ��j�j

�j;t(1� �2j ): (1.14)

The risk-neutral conditional characteristic function ~�j(� ; u; �j) for the equity price, S

jT , is

Page 23: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

13

given by

~�j(� ; u; �j) � EQt

hexp

�iu ln

�SjT

��i(1.15)

=�Sjt

�iuexp

�iur� �

�A(� ; u; �j) +B(� ; u)

�� C(� ; u; �j)�2I;t �D(� ; u)�2j;t

�;

where � = T � t and the expressions for A�� ; u; �j

�, B (� ; u), C

�� ; u; �j

�, and D (� ; u) are

provided in Appendix A.

Proof. See Appendix A.

This proposition provides several insights. Note that the market factor structure is

preserved under Q. Furthermore, the market beta is the same under the risk-neutral and

physical distributions. This result makes betas estimated from option data appropriate for

applications such as capital budgeting. Duan and Wei (2009) argue that the risk-neutral

and objective betas should be the same. The risk-neutral betas in the model in Serban,

Lehoczky and Seppi (2008) are also identical to the physical betas, and they document

empirically that risk-neutral and physical betas are economically and statistically close for

most stocks.

It is also worth noting that in our modeling framework, higher moments and their

premiums, as de�ned by the di¤erence between the moment under P and Q, are a¤ected

by the drift adjustment in the variance processes. We will discuss this further in the next

section.

Our model is developed within an a¢ ne framework, which implies that the characteristic

function for the logarithm of the index level and the logarithm of the equity price can both

be derived analytically. The characteristic function for the index is identical to that in

Heston (1993). Given the characteristic function in (1.15) for the equity price, the price of

a European equity call option with strike price K and maturity � = T � t is

Cjt (Sjt ;K; � ; �j) = Sjt�

j1(�j)�Ke�r��

j2(�j); (1.16)

Page 24: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

14

where the risk-neutral probabilities �j1(�j) and �j2(�j) are de�ned by

�j1(�j) =1

2+e�r�

�Sjt

1Z0

Re

"e�iu lnK~�

j(� ; u� i; �j)iu

#du (1.17)

�j2(�j) =1

2+1

1Z0

Re

"e�iu lnK~�

j �� ; u; �j

�iu

#du: (1.18)

While these integrals must be evaluated numerically, they are well-behaved and can be

computed quickly.

1.4 Model Properties

In this section we derive a number of important cross-sectional implications from the model

and investigate if the model captures the stylized facts documented in Section ??. We will

also draw some key implications of the model for equity option sensitivities and expected

returns, as well as for the relative pricing of equity and index options. For convenience we

assume that beta is positive for all �rms below. This is not required by the model but it

simpli�es the interpretation of certain expressions.

1.4.1 Factor Structure and Equity Option Sensitivities

The principal component analysis in Section ?? has revealed a strong factor structure

in equity options, and indicated that the most important factor is closely related to the

dynamics of market index options. In our model, equity option prices are partly driven by

changes in the market index price and in market variance. Classic equity option valuation

models do not provide guidance on how equity option prices respond to changes in market

index variables, but our model has clear implications for the sensitivity of equity option

prices with respect to market level and market variance. To better understand how market

variables a¤ect individual equity options, the following result is useful.

Proposition 2 For a derivative contract f j written on the stock price, Sjt , the sensitivity

Page 25: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

15

of f j with respect to the index level, It (the market delta), is given by

@f j

@It=@f j

@Sjt

SjtIt�j :

The sensitivity of f j with respect to the market variance (the market vega) is given by

@f j

@�2I;t=

@f j

@Vj;t�2j :

Proof. See Appendix B.

This proposition shows that the beta of the �rm in a straightforward way provides the

link between the usual stock price delta @fj

@Sjtand the market delta, @f

j

@It, and the link between

the usual equity vega, @fj

@Vj;t, and the market vega @fj

@�2I;t. Note of course that high-beta �rms

will have equity option prices that are more sensitive to changes in the index level and in

market variance.

This result allows market participants with portfolios of equity options on di¤erent

�rms to measure and manage their total exposure to the index level and to the market

variance. It also allows investors engaged in dispersion trading, who sell index options

and buy equity options, to measure and manage their overall exposure to market risk and

market variance risk.

Figure 3 plots the market sensitivities from model option prices. Each line has a

di¤erent beta but the same amount of unconditional total equity variance de�ned by ~Vj �

�2j~�I + �j = 0:1. We set the current spot variance to �2I;t = 0:01 and Vj;t = 0:05, and de�ne

the idiosyncratic variance as the residual �2j;t = Vj;t��2j�2I;t. The market index parameters

are ~�I = 5; ~�I = 0:04; �I = 0:5; �I = �0:8; and the individual equity parameters are

�j = 1; �j = 0:4; and �j = 0. The risk-free rate is 4% per year and option maturity is

3 months. Additionally, we set Sjt =It = 0:1. We plot the market delta (top panel) and

the market vega (bottom panel) against moneyness for �rms with di¤erent betas. The top

panel of Figure 3 shows that the di¤erences in market deltas across �rms with di¤erent

Page 26: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

16

betas can be substantial for ATM and ITM call options. The bottom panel of Figure 3

shows that the di¤erences in market vega are also substantial�particularly for ATM calls

where the option exposure to total variance is the largest.

1.4.2 Factor Structure and Equity Option Returns

So far we have focused on option price levels and their sensitivities. It is also instructive to

see the model�s implications for expected equity option returns. The following proposition

provides an expression for the expected (P -measure) equity option return as a function of

the expected market return.3

Proposition 3 For a derivative f j written on the stock price, Sjt , the expected excess

return on the derivative contract is given by:

1

dtEPt

�df j

f j� rdt

�=

@f j

@Sjt

Sjtf j��j + �j�I

�dt

=@f j

@Sjt

Sjtf j�j +

@f j

@Sjt

Sjtf j�j�I

=@f j

@Sjt

Sjtf j�j +

@f j

@It

Itf j�I ;

where @fj

@Itis given in Proposition 2.

Proof. See Appendix C.

The model thus decomposes the excess return on the option into two parts: The delta

of the equity option and the beta of the stock. Put di¤erently, equity options provide

investors with two sources of leverage: First, the beta with respect to the market, and

second, the elasticity of the option price with respect to changes in the stock price.

In Figure 4 we use the parameter values from Figure 3 and set the equity market risk

premium �I equal to 0:075:We plot the expected excess return on equity call options (top

3Recent empirical work on equity and index option returns includes Broadie, Chernov, and Johannes(2009), Goyal and Saretto (2009), Constantinides, Czerwonko, Jackwerth, and Perrakis (2011), Vasquez(2011), and Jones and Wang (2012).

Page 27: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

17

panel) and on put options (bottom panel) in percent per day against moneyness for �rms

with di¤erent betas. The top panel of Figure 4 shows that the di¤erences in expected call

returns across �rms with di¤erent betas can be substantial for OTM calls where option

leverage in general is highest. The bottom panel of Figure 4 shows that put option expected

excess returns (which are always negative) also vary most across �rms with di¤erent betas

when the put options are OTM. In general the di¤erences in expected excess returns across

betas are smaller for put options (bottom panel) than for call options (top panel).

1.4.3 The Relative Pricing of Index and Equity Options

The factor structure in our model combined with the market variance premium also has

implications for the relative pricing of index and equity options. A negative variance risk

premium implies that EQt [�2I;t:T ] > EPt [�

2I;t:T ], where the expected integrated market index

variance under P and Q is de�ned by

EPt [�2I;t:T ] � EPt

24 TZt

�2I;sds

35 and EQt [�2I;t:T ] � EQt

24 TZt

�2I;sds

35 : (1.19)

This combined with our assumption that idiosyncratic volatility is not priced, so that

EQt [�2j;t:T ] = EPt [�

2j;t:T ], implies we can write

�2j +EPt [�

2j;t:T ]

EPt [�2I;t:T ]

> �2j +EQt [�

2j;t:T ]

EQt [�2I;t:T ]

:

Multiplying by both denominators yields

��2jE

Pt [�

2I;t:T ] + E

Pt [�

2j;t:T ]

�EQt [�

2I;t:T ] >

h�2jE

Qt [�

2I;t:T ] + E

Qt [�

2j;t:T ]

iEPt [�

2I;t:T ]

, EPt [Vj;t:T ]EQt [�

2I;t:T ] > EQt [Vj;t:T ]E

Pt [�

2I;t:T ];

Page 28: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

18

which in turn enables us to write

EQt [�2I;t:T ]

EPt [�2I;t:T ]

>EQt [Vj;t:T ]

EPt [Vj;t:T ]; (1.20)

where EQt [Vj;t:T ] and EPt [Vj;t:T ] denote expected integrated �rm variance under P and Q.

Our model therefore implies that the variance risk premium will be smaller in equity

options than in market index options so that a variance swap (or an at-the-money option)

on the market index will be relatively more expensive than a variance swap (or an at-

the-money option) on the individual equity. This is in line with the empirical evidence in

Bakshi, Kapadia and Madan (2003) among others.

1.4.4 The Level of Equity Option Volatility

Duan and Wei (2009) show empirically that �rms with higher systematic risk have a higher

level of risk-neutral variance. We now investigate if our model is consistent with this

empirical �nding.

Recall from above that the total spot variance for �rm j at time t is de�ned by

Vj;t � �2j�2I;t + �

2j;t:

By decomposing the P -expectation into integrated market variance and idiosyncratic vari-

ance, we have

EPt [Vj;t:T ] = �2jEPt [�

2I;t:T ] + E

Pt [�

2j;t:T ]:

Given our model, the expectation of the integrated total variance for equity j under Q

is

EQt [Vj;t:T ] = �2jEQt [�

2I;t:T ] + E

Qt [�

2j;t:T ] = �2jE

Qt [�

2I;t:T ] + E

Pt [�

2j;t:T ]:

where the second equation holds when idiosyncratic risk is not priced.

For any two �rms having the same level of expected total variance under the P -measure

Page 29: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

19

(EPt [V1;t:T ] = EPt [V2;t:T ]) we have

EPt [�21;t:T ]� EPt [�22;t:T ] = �(�21 � �22)EPt [�2I;t:T ]:

Therefore

EQt [V1;t:T ]� EQt [V2;t:T ] = (�21 � �22)E

Qt [�

2I;t:T ] +

�EQt [�

21;t:T ]� E

Qt [�

22;t:T ]

�= (�21 � �22)E

Qt [�

2I;t:T ] +

�EPt [�

21;t:T ]� EPt [�22;t:T ]

�= (�21 � �22)

�EQt [�

2I;t:T ]� EPt [�2I;t:T ]

�:

When the market variance premium is negative, we have ~�I > �I which implies that

EQt [�2I;t:T ] > EPt [�

2I;t:T ]. We therefore have that

�1 > �2 , EQt [V1;t:T ] > EQt [V2;t:T ]:

We conclude that the model is consistent with the �nding in Duan and Wei (2009) that

�rms with high betas tend to have a high level of risk-neutral variance.

1.4.5 Equity Option Skews

To help understand the slope of the equity option implied volatility moneyness curve in our

model, the next proposition shows how beta and index skewness impact equity skewness.

Proposition 4 The conditional total skewness of the integrated returns of �rm j under

P , denoted by TSkPj , is given by

TSkPj;t:T � SkP

Z T

t

dSju

Sju

!= �3j �

EPt [�

2I;t:T ]

EPt [Vj;t:T ]

!3=2� SkPI;t:T +

EPt [�

2j;t:T ]

EPt [Vj;t:T ]

!3=2� SkPj;t:T :

(1.21)

The conditional total skewness of the integrated returns of �rm j under Q, denoted by

Page 30: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

20

TSkQj , is given by

TSkQj;t:T � SkQ

Z T

t

dSju

Sju

!= �3j �

EQt [�

2I;t:T ]

EQt [Vj;t:T ]

!3=2� SkQI;t:T +

EQt [�

2j;t:T ]

EQt [Vj;t:T ]

!3=2� SkQj;t:T ;

(1.22)

where SkI;t:T = Sk�R TtdIsIs

�and Skj;t:T = Sk

�R Tt �j;sdW

(j;1)s

�is the market and idiosyn-

cratic �rm j skewness, respectively.

Proof. See Appendix D.

This result shows that �j matters for determining �rm j�s conditional total skewness

and thus the moneyness slope of its implied volatility curve.

Equation (1.22) shows that under the risk neutral measure, �j a¤ects the slope of the

equity implied volatility curve through TSkQj;t:T by a¤ecting the loading on the market

skewness. To see this, consider two �rms with the same expected total variance under Q so

that EQt [V1;t:T ] = EQt [V2;t:T ] which implies EQt [�

2I;t:T ]=E

Qt [V1;t:T ] = EQt [�

2I;t:T ]=E

Qt [V2;t:T ].

When �1 > �2, Firm 1 has a greater loading on index risk-neutral skewness and �rm 2

has a greater loading on idiosyncratic skewness. When the index Q-distribution is more

negatively skewed than the idiosyncratic equity distribution, as found empirically in Bakshi,

Kapadia, and Madan (2003), then our model predicts that higher-beta �rms will have

more negatively skewed Q-distributions. Note that this prediction is in line with the cross-

sectional empirical �ndings of Duan and Wei (2009) and Dennis and Mayhew (2002).

The top panel of Figure 5 plots the implied Black-Scholes volatility from model option

prices based on the parameter values from Figure 3. The top panel in Figure 5 shows that

beta has a substantial impact on the moneyness slope of equity IV even when keeping the

total variance constant: The higher the beta, the larger the moneyness slope.

The factor structure in our model combined with the market variance premium also

has implications for the relative importance for total skewness of the market factor under

Page 31: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

21

the Q measure and under the P measure. We can rewrite (1.20) to get

EQt [�2I;t:T ]

EQt [Vj;t:T ]>EPt [�

2I;t:T ]

EPt [Vj;t:T ]: (1.23)

Our model therefore implies that the loading of total equity skewness, TSkj;t:T , on

market skewness, SkI;t:T , is higher under the Qmeasure in (1.22) than under the P measure

in (1.21). This in turn shows that the model can potentially capture the strong commonality

in moneyness slopes across �rms documented in Section ??.

Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003) discuss how market skewness in�uences total eq-

uity skewness relative to idiosyncratic skewness. Duan and Wei (2009) highlight the impor-

tance of systematic risk for explaining the cross-section of equity options. We contribute by

showing the role of beta in determining total equity skewness in a fully-speci�ed dynamic

stochastic volatility model. Our results highlight that the negative market variance risk

premium, a robust stylized fact, is critical for explaining the cross-sectional impact of beta.

1.4.6 The Term Structure of Equity Volatility

Our model implies the following two-component term-structure of equity variance

EQt [Vj;t:T ] =��2j~�I + �j

�+ �2j

��2I;t � ~�I

�e�~�I(T�t) +

��2j;t � �j

�e��j(T�t): (1.24)

This expression shows how the term structure of market variance a¤ects the term structure

of variance for �rm j. Given di¤erent systematic and idiosyncratic mean reversion speeds

(~�I 6= �j), �j has important implications for the term-structure of volatilities. In the

empirical work below, we �nd that the risk-neutral idiosyncratic variance process is more

persistent than the market variance. When the idiosyncratic variance process is more

persistent (~�I > �j), higher values of beta imply a faster reversion toward the �rst term

in (1.24), the unconditional total variance ( ~Vj = �2j~�I + �j). As a result, when the market

variance process is less persistent than the idiosyncratic variance, �rms with higher betas

are likely to have steeper volatility term-structures. In other words, higher beta �rms

Page 32: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

22

are expected to have a greater positive (negative) term structure slope when the market

variance term-structure is upward (downward) sloping.

The bottom panel of Figure 5 plots the implied Black-Scholes volatility from model

prices against option maturity. Each line has a di¤erent beta but the same amount of

unconditional total equity variance ~Vj = �2j~�I + �j = 0:1. We set the current spot variance

to �2I;t = 0:01 and Vj;t = 0:05, and de�ne the idiosyncratic variance as the residual �2j;t =

Vj;t � �2j�2I;t. The parameter values are as in Figure 3. The bottom panel of Figure 5

shows that beta has a non-trivial e¤ect on the IV term structure: The higher the beta, the

steeper the term structure when the term structure is upward sloping.

In summary, our model makes a number of qualitative predictions for the role of the

market variance risk premium and beta for the pricing of individual equity options: First,

equity option sensitivities and expected returns will depend on beta. Second, at-the-money

index options will be relatively more expensive than at-the-money options on individual

stocks. Third, higher beta stocks will have higher option values even when keeping the

physical volatility �xed. Fourth, stocks with higher beta will have implied volatility curves

with steeper moneyness slopes. Finally, stocks with higher betas will revert more quickly

to the long-run implied volatility.

We now estimate our model on index and equity options in order to quantify the role

of beta in equity option valuation.

1.5 Estimation and Fit

In this section, we �rst describe our estimation methodology. Subsequently we report on

parameter estimates and model �t. Finally we relate the estimated betas to patterns in

observed equity option IVs.

1.5.1 Estimation Methodology

Several approaches have been proposed in the literature for estimating stochastic volatility

models. Jacquier, Polson, and Rossi (1994) use Markov Chain Monte Carlo to estimate

Page 33: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

23

a discrete-time stochastic volatility model. Pan (2002) uses GMM to estimate the objec-

tive and risk neutral parameters from returns and option prices. Serban, Lehoczky, and

Seppi�s (2008) estimation strategy is based on simulated maximum likelihood using the

EM algorithm and a particle �lter.

Another approach treats the latent volatility states as parameters to be estimated and

thus avoids �ltering the latent volatility factor. This strategy has been adopted by Bates

(2000) and Santa-Clara and Yan (2010) among others. We follow this strand of literature.

Recall that we need to estimate two vectors of latent variables f�2I;t, �2j;tg and two sets

of structural parameters f�I , �jg, where �I � f~�I ; ~�I ; �I ; �Ig and �j � f�j ; �j ; �j ; �j ; �jg.

Our methodology involves two main steps.

In the �rst step, we estimate the market index dynamicn�I ; �

2I;t

obased on S&P 500

option prices alone. In the second step, we use equity options for �rm j only, we take the

market index dynamic as given, and we estimate the �rm-speci�c dynamicsn�j ; �

2j;t

ofor

each �rm conditional on estimates ofn�I ; �

2I;t

o. This step-wise estimation procedure is

not fully econometrically e¢ cient but it enables us to estimate our model for 29 equities

while ensuring that the same dynamic is imposed for the market-wide index for each of

the 29 �rms. We have con�rmed that this estimating technique has good �nite sample

properties in a Monte Carlo study which is available from the authors upon request.

Each of the two main steps contains an iterative procedure which we now describe in

detail.

Step 1: Parameter Estimation for the Index

Given a set of starting values, �0I , for the structural parameters characterizing the index,

we �rst estimate the spot market variance each day by solving

�2I;t = argmin�2I;t

NI;tXm=1

(CI;t;m � Cm(�0I ; �2I;t))2=V ega2I;t;m, for t = 1; 2; :::; T; (1.25)

Page 34: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

24

where CI;t;m is the market price of index option contract m on day t, Cm(�I ; �2I;t) is

the model index option price, NI;t is the number of index contracts available on day t;

and V egaI;t;m is the Black-Scholes sensitivity of the index option price with respect to

volatility evaluated at the implied volatility. These vega-weighted dollar price errors are

a good approximation to implied volatility errors and the computational cost involved is

much lower.4

Once the set of T market spot variances is obtained, we solve for the set of parameters

characterizing the index dynamic as follows

�I = argmin�I

NIXm;t

(CI;t;m � Cm(�I ; �2I;t))2=V ega2I;t;m, (1.26)

where NI �PTt NI;t represents the total number of index option contracts available.

We iterate between (1.25) and (1.26) until the improvement in �t is negligible, which

typically requires 5-10 iterations.

Step 2: Parameter Estimation for Individual Equities

Given an initial value �0j and the estimated �2I;t and �I we can estimate the spot equity

variance each day by solving

�2j;t = argmin�2j;t

Nj;tXm=1

(Cj;t;m � Cm(�0j ; �I ; �2I;t; �2j;t))2=V ega2j;t;m, for t = 1; 2; :::T; (1.27)

where Cj;t;m is the price of equity option m for �rm j with price t, Cm(�j ;�I ; �2I;t; �2j;t)

is the model equity option price, Nj;t is the number of equity contracts available on day t;

and V egaj;t;m is the Black-Scholes Vega of the equity option.

Once the set of T market spot variances is obtained, we solve for the set of parameters

4This approximation has been used in Carr and Wu (2007) and Trolle and Schwartz (2009) among others.

Page 35: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

25

characterizing the equity dynamic as follows

�j = argmin�j

NjXm;t

(Cj;t;m � Cm(�j ; �I ; �2I;t; �2j;t))=V ega2j;t;m; (1.28)

where Nj �PTt Nj;t is the total number of contracts available for security j.

We again iterate between (1.27) and (1.28) until the improvement in �t is negligible.

We repeat this estimation procedure for each of the 29 �rms in our data set.

1.5.2 Parameter Estimates

This section presents estimation results for the market index and the 29 �rms for the

1996-2010 period. In order to speed up estimation, we restrict attention to put options

with moneyness in the range 0:9 � S=K � 1:1 and maturities of 2, 4, and 6 months.

We estimate the structural parameters in the model on a panel data set consisting of the

options available on the �rst Wednesday of each month. We end up using a total of 150; 455

equity options and 6; 147 index options when estimating the structural parameters. We

estimate the spot variances on each trading day thus using more than 3:1 million equity

options and 128; 532 index options.

Table 4 reports estimates of the structural parameters that characterize the dynamics

of the systematic variance and the idiosyncratic variance, as well as estimates of the betas.

The top row shows estimates for the S&P 500 index.

The unconditional risk-neutral market index variance ~�I = 0:0610 corresponds to

24:70% volatility per year. Based on the average index spot variance path for the sample,

1T

PTt=1 �

2I;t, we obtain a volatility of 22:23%. The idiosyncratic �j estimates range from

0:0018 for American Express to 0:0586 for Cisco.

The estimate of the mean-reversion parameter for the market index variance ~�I is equal

to 1:13, which corresponds to a daily variance persistence of 1� 1:13=365 = 0:9969 which

is very high, consistent with the existing literature. The idiosyncratic �j range from 0:15

for Bank of America to 1:29 for Merck, indicating that idiosyncratic volatility is highly

Page 36: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

26

persistent as well. Only �ve �rms in the sample (JP Morgan, Hewlett-Packard, Intel, IBM,

and Merck) have an idiosyncratic variance process that is less persistent than the market

variance.

Our estimate of the volatility of variance parameter, �I , for the market is 0:371 which

is in line with the estimates found by Bakshi, Cao and Chen (1997), Bates (2000) and Pan

(2002). The volatility of the idiosyncratic variance, �j , is on average 0:180 and ranges from

0:054 for American Express to 0:333 for Cisco.

The estimate of �I is strongly negative (�0:855), capturing the so-called leverage e¤ect

in the index. The idiosyncratic �j are negative for all �rms except one, ranging from �0:724

for Bank of America to +0:297 for Exxon Mobil.

The estimates of beta are reasonable and vary from 0:70 for Johnson & Johnson to 1:24

for American Express. The average beta across the 29 �rms is 0:99. We will analyze the

beta estimates in more detail below.

The average total spot volatility (ATSV) for �rm j is computed as

ATSV =

vuut 1

T

TXt=1

Vj;t =

vuut 1

T

TXt=1

��2j�

2I;t + �

2j;t

�:

Comparing the beta column with the ATSV column in Table 4 shows that ATSV is generally

high when beta is high.

The �nal column of Table 4 reports the systematic risk ratio (SSR) for each �rm. It is

computed from the spot variances as follows

SSR =

PTt=1 �

2j�2I;tPT

t=1

��2j�

2I;t + �

2j;t

� :Table 4 shows that the systematic risk ratio varies from close to 32% for Hewlett-Packard to

above 70% for Exxon Mobile. The systematic risk ratio is 46% on average, indicating that

the estimated factor structure is strongly present in the equity option data. Comparison

of the beta column with the SSR column in Table 4 shows that �rms with similar betas

Page 37: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

27

can have radically di¤erent SSR and, vice versa, �rms with very di¤erent betas can have

roughly similar SSRs. This �nding of course suggests a key role for the idiosyncratic

variance dynamic in the model.

1.5.3 Model Fit

We measure model �t using the root mean squared error (RMSE) based on the vegas,

which is consistent with the criterion function used in estimation

Vega RMSE �r1

N

XN

m;t(Cm;t � Cm;t(�))2=V ega2m;t:

We also report the implied volatility RMSE de�ned as

IVRMSE �r1

N

XN

m;t(IVm;t � IV (Cm;t(�)))2;

where IVm;t denotes market IV for option m on day t and IV (Cm;t(�)) denotes model IV.

We use Black-Scholes to compute IV for both model and market prices.

Table 5 reports model �t for the market index and for each of the 29 �rms. We report

results for all contracts, as well as separate results for in- and out-of-the-money puts, and

for 2-month and 6-month at-the-money (ATM) contracts. We also report the IVRMSE

divided by the average market IV in order to assess relative IV �t. Several interesting

�ndings emerge from Table 5.

� First, the Vega RMSE approximates the IVMRSE closely for the index and for all

�rms. This suggests that using Vega RMSE in estimation does not bias the IVRMSE

results.

� Second, the average IVRMSE across �rms is 1:20% and the relative IV (IVRMSE/Average

IV) is 4:05% on average. The �t is very similar across �rms. Overall the �t of the

model is thus quite good across �rms. The best pricing performance for equity op-

tions is obtained for Coca Cola with an IVRMSE of 0:95%. The worst �t is for

Page 38: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

28

General Electric with an IVRMSE of 1:64%. Based on the relative IVRMSE, the

best �t is for Intel with 2:90% and the worst is again for GE with 5:66%.

� Third, the average IVRMSE �t across �rms for ITM puts is 1:17% and for OTM puts

it is 1:23%. Using this metric the model �ts ITM and OTM puts roughly equally

well.

� Fourth, the average IVRMSE �t across �rms for 2-month ATM options is 1:10% and

for 6-month ATM options it is 1:08%. The model thus �ts 2-month and 6-month

ATM options equally well on average.

Figure 6 reports the market IV (solid) and model IV (dashed) averaged over time for

di¤erent moneyness categories for each �rm. The black lines (left axis) show the average

on days with above-average IV and the grey lines (right axis) show the average for days

with below-average IV. Moneyness is on the horizontal axis, measured by S=K, with ITM

puts shown on the left side and OTM puts on the right side. Figure 6.A reports on the �rst

15 �rms and Figure 6.B reports on the remaining 14 �rms as well as the index. Note that

in order to properly see the di¤erent patterns across �rms, the vertical axis scale di¤ers in

each subplot, but the range of implied volatility values is kept �xed at 10% across �rms to

facilitate comparisons.

Figure 6 shows that the smiles computed using market prices vary considerably across

�rms, both in terms of level and shape. It is noteworthy that for many of these large

�rms, the smile looks more like an asymmetric smirk�especially on low-volatility days (grey

lines). The IV bias by moneyness are small in general across �rms and no large outliers

are apparent. The model tends to slightly underprice OTM equity puts when volatility is

high (black lines). This is not the case when volatility is low (grey lines).

The smirk is of course a strong stylized fact for index options and it is evident in the

bottom-right panel of Figure 6.B. Comparing with the other panels con�rms the �nding in

Bakshi, Kapadia and Madan (2003) that the market index is generally more (negatively)

skewed than individual �rms. Note that when allowing for a large negative �I ; the Heston

Page 39: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

29

(1993) model is able to �t the relatively expensive OTM index put options quite well, but

it still has a small bias and requires additional negative skewness. This could be achieved

by including jumps in returns (Bates, 2000).

Figure 7 reports for each �rm the average (over time) implied volatility as a func-

tion of time to maturity (in years). We split the data set into two groups: Days with

upward-sloping IV term structure and days with downward-sloping IV term structure. We

then compute the median slope on the upward-sloping days and the median slope on the

downward-sloping days. In Figure 7 we report the average market IVs (solid lines) as

well as the average model IVs (dashed lines) on the days with higher-than-median upward-

sloping term structure (grey lines) and on the days with lower-than-median downward-

sloping term structure (black lines). This is done because on many days the term structure

is roughly �at and thus uninteresting. The downward-sloping black lines use the left axis

and the upward-sloping grey lines use the right axis. In order to facilitate comparison

between model and market IVs the level of IVs di¤er between the left and right axis and

they di¤er across �rms. For ease of comparison between term structures the di¤erence

between the minimum and maximum on each axis is �xed at 10% across all �rms.

Figure 7 shows that the term structure of IV di¤ers considerably across �rms. Some

�rms such as Hewlett-Packard tend to mean-revert rather quickly, whereas other �rms such

as 3M have much more persistent term structures. Generally, across �rms, the downward

sloping black lines appear to be steeper than the upward sloping grey lines. This pattern

is matched by the model. It is also worth noting that the model is able to capture the

strong persistence in IV quite well: Figure 7 does not reveal any systematic model biases

in the term structure of IVs. The two-factor stochastic volatility structure of our equity

model is clearly helpful in this regard.

We conclude from Table 5 and Figures 6 and 7 that the model �ts the observed equity

option data quite well. Encouraged by this �nding, we next analyze in some detail how

the estimated betas are related to observed patterns in equity option IVs.

Page 40: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

30

1.5.4 Equity Betas and Equity Option IVs

The three main cross-sectional predictions of our model, as discussed in Section ??, are as

follows:

1. Firms with higher betas have higher risk-neutral variance.

2. Firms with higher betas have steeper moneyness slopes. This is equivalent to stating

that �rms with higher betas are characterized by more negative skewness.

3. Firms with higher betas have steeper positive volatility term structures when the term

structure is upward sloping, and steeper negative volatility term structures when the

term structure is downward sloping.

We now document if these theoretical model implications are supported by the estimates

for the 29 Dow-Jones �rms. Consider �rst the level of option-implied volatility. In the top

panel of Figure 8, we scatter plot the time-averaged intercepts from the implied volatility

regression in (1.1), 1TPTt=1 aj;t against the beta estimates from Table 4 for each �rm j. We

then run a regression on the 29 points in the scatter and assess the signi�cance and �t.

The slope has a t-statistic of 6:81 and the regression �t (R2) is quite high at 63%. The

regression line shows the positive relationship between the estimated betas and the average

implied volatility observed in the market prices of equity options.

In the middle panel of Figure 8, we scatter plot the moneyness slope coe¢ cients from

the IV regression in (1.1), 1TPTt=1 bj;t against the beta estimate from Table 4 for each �rm

j. In the moneyness slope regression, the sensitivity to beta has a t-statistic of 4:66 and

an R2 of 45%. The middle panel of Figure 8 clearly shows that higher beta estimates are

associated with steeper slopes of the IV moneyness smile.

Finally, in the bottom panel of Figure 8 we scatter plot the absolute value of the term

structure slope coe¢ cients from (1.1), 1TPTt=1 cj;t against the beta estimate from Table 4

for each �rm. In the term slope regression, the sensitivity to beta has a t-statistic of 4:90

and the R2 is 47%. Panel C shows that higher betas are associated with higher absolute

Page 41: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

31

slopes of the term structure in equity IVs: Firms with high betas will tend to have a term

structure of implied volatility curve that decays more quickly to the unconditional level of

volatility compared with �rms with low betas.

We conclude that the cross-sectional relation between our estimates of beta and the

model-free measures of IV level, slope, and term structure is consistent with the three main

model predictions from Section ??.

1.5.5 Option-Implied and Regression Betas

As discussed in section ??, the betas estimated from options seem reasonable. They vary

from 0:70 for Johnson & Johnson to 1:24 for American Express and the average beta across

the 29 �rms is 0:99. To provide additional perspective we also compute regression-based

OLS betas for the same 29 �rms. To be consistent with the option-based estimate, we

estimate a constant beta using daily return data for the entire sample from 1996 to 2010.

The OLS beta is 0:97 on average across �rms.

The top panel of Figure 9 provides a scatter plot of OLS betas versus option-implied

betas. The black line shows the result of a cross-sectional regression of the OLS betas on

the option-implied betas. A number of important conclusions obtain. First, the option-

implied betas are positively correlated with the OLS betas. In fact, the relation between

the two beta estimates is very strong, which is evidenced by the high R-square of the

regression (84%) and the fact that the top panel of Figure 9 contains very few outliers.

Second, option-implied betas have a smaller dispersion (15%) than historical betas (31%).

Note that this larger dispersion of the historical betas yields a regression slope larger than

one and a negative regression intercept when regressing historical beta on option implied

beta.

The pattern of betas in the top panel of Figure 9 is also interesting in light of the well-

known �nite sample biases in estimating OLS betas, and the common practice of shrinking

the betas toward one to account for this bias. To reduce the potential small-sample bias in

OLS beta, we follow Vasicek (1973) and shrink the raw time-series estimate of beta toward

Page 42: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

32

the cross-sectional mean according to

�SHj = ! � �OLSj + (1� !) � 1;

where �OLSj is the OLS beta estimate. Following Vasicek (1973) and Frazzini and Pedersen

(2013), among others, we set ! = 0:6.

When we plot the betas with shrinkage versus the option-implied betas in the bottom

panel of Figure 9, the results are perhaps even more striking. Note how the 45� degree line

(in grey) now almost perfectly lines up with the �tted line (in black) obtained by regressing

the betas with shrinkage on the option-implied betas.

We conclude that overall the relationship between regression-based and option-implied

beta is surprisingly strong. It may prove interesting to see if this relationship also holds

for betas computed over shorter windows of options and returns. We leave that for future

work.

1.5.6 The Cross-Section of Idiosyncratic Risk

A number of recent studies investigate co-movements between �rm-level volatilities. Engle

and Figlewski (2012) model the dynamics of correlations between implied volatilities, and

investigate the role of VIX as a factor in explaining �rm-level implied volatilities. Schürho¤

and Ziegler (2010) study the relative pricing of equity and index variance swaps. Kelly,

Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2012) show that there is a strong factor structure in �rm-

level historical volatility, distinct from the common variation in returns. Surprisingly, they

�nd that idiosyncratic volatility contains a factor structure similar to the one in total

volatility.

Motivated by these �ndings, Table 6 presents the correlation matrix between the idio-

syncratic variances for the 29 �rms estimated from the model. Clearly, Table 6 con�rms the

results of Kelly, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2012), which are obtained using historical

returns data.

Page 43: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

33

While Table 6 may be interpreted as suggesting the need for a richer factor model, note

that the results of Kelly, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2012) are robust to the inclusion

of additional known factors. Note also that while correlated idiosyncratic variances signal

the presence of additional factors, it is not necessarily the case that these additional factors

are priced in equity options.

1.6 Summary and Conclusions

Principal component analysis reveals a strong factor structure in equity options. The �rst

common component explains 77% of the cross-sectional variation in IV and the common

component has a 92% correlation with the short-term implied volatility constructed from

S&P 500 index options. Furthermore, 77% of the variation in the equity skew is captured

by the �rst principal component. This common component has a correlation of 64% with

the skew of market index options. Also, 60% of the variation in the term structure of

equity IV is explained by the �rst principal component. This component has a correlation

of 80% with the term slope of the option IV from S&P500 index options.

Motivated by the �ndings from the principal component analysis, we develop a struc-

tural model of equity option prices that incorporates a market factor. The model allows

for mean-reverting stochastic volatility and correlated shocks to returns and volatility. Mo-

tivated by the principal components analysis, we allow for idiosyncratic shocks to equity

prices which also have mean-reverting stochastic volatility and a separate leverage e¤ect.

Individual equity returns are linked to the market index using a standard linear factor

model with a constant beta factor loading. We derive closed-form option pricing formulas

as well as results for option hedging and option expected returns. The model has three

important cross-sectional implications: higher beta stocks have higher option values for a

given physical volatility �xed, higher beta stocks have implied volatility curves with steeper

moneyness slopes, and higher beta stocks revert more quickly to the mean long-run implied

volatility.

We develop a convenient estimation method for estimation and �ltering based on option

Page 44: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

34

prices. When estimating the model on the �rms in the Dow-Jones index, we �nd that it

provides a good �t to observed equity option prices. Moreover, we show that the estimates

strongly con�rm the three main cross-sectional model implications.

Several issues are left for future research. First, it would be interesting to empirically

study the implications of our models for option price sensitivities and option returns.

Second, it may be useful to extend the model, for instance by allowing for two stochastic

volatility factors in the market price process, as in Bates (2000), or by allowing for jumps

in the market price (Bates, 2008; Bollerslev and Todorov, 2011). Third, combining option

information with high-frequency returns when estimating the parameters in our model

following Andersen, Fusari and Todorov (2013) may lead to better estimates of the spot

volatility process and of beta (see also Patton and Verardo, 2012; Hansen, Lunde, and

Voev, 2012). Joint estimation on returns and options will also allow us to identify the

variance risk premium. Finally, characterizing the time-variation in option-implied betas

would be of signi�cant interest.

Appendix

This appendix collects proofs of the propositions.

A.1 Proof of Proposition 1. Part 1: Risk-Neutral Distribution

First, de�ne the stochastic exponential �(:)

�tR0

!0udWu

�� exp

�tR0

!0udWu �

1

2

tR0

!0udDW;W

0Eu!u

�; (1.29)

where !u is a 2(n+1) real or complex valued vector adapted to the Brownian �ltration (see

Protter (1990) p. 85). Given the de�nition of �(:), we can express the change-of-measure

(1.8) asdQ

dP(t) = �

��tR0

0udWu

�; (1.30)

Page 45: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

35

where Wu �hW(I;1)u ;W

(I;2)u ; :::;W

(j;1)u ;W

(j;2)u

i0and u �

h (I;1)u ;

(I;2)u ; :::;

(j;1)u ;

(j;2)u

i0are

the vectors of innovations and market prices of risk, respectively. Given (1.4) and the

de�nition of �(:), we can write

Sjt

Sj0= �

�tR0

�j�I;udW(I;1)u +

tR0

�j;udW(j;1)u

�exp((r + �j + �j�I)t): (1.31)

By imposing the no-arbitrage condition on the individual equity prices, Sjt , we must have

EPs

"Sjt

Sjs

dQdP (t)dQdP (s)

exp(�r(t� s))#= 1, R(t) � Sjt

Sj0

dQ

dP(t) exp(�rt) is a P -martingale.

Therefore, Sjt �s no-arbitrage condition constrain the process R(t) to be a P -martingale.

Note that we have omitted the superscript j in the de�nition of R(t). Given (1.30) and

(1.31), R(t) can be orthogonalized in the following manner R(t) = F (t)G(t) where

F (t) � exp((�j + �j�I)t)�

�tR0

�j�I;udW(I;1)u

��

��tR0

(I;1)u dW (I;1)u �

tR0

(I;2)u dW (I;2)u

�(1.32)

�tR0

�j;udW(j;1)u

��

��tR0

(j;1)u dW (j;1)u �

tR0

(j;2)u dW (j;2)u

�;

and

G(t) � �

0@�Xk=2j;I

�tR0

(k;1)u dW (k;1)u +

tR0

(k;2)u dW (k;2)u

�1A :

where in order to decompose dQdP (t) and Sjt =S

j0 we have used �(Xt + Yt) = �(Xt)�(Yt)

for orthogonal processes. By properties of stochastic exponentials, we know that �(:)

are P -martingales which implies that G(t) is a P -martingale. Since F (t) and G(t) are

independent, R(t) will be a P -martingale if and only if F (t) is a P -martingale. Using the

result �(Xt)�(Yt) = �(Xt + Yt) exp(hX;Y it) to rewrite (1.32), we have

�tR0

�j�I;udW(I;1)u

��

��tR0

(I;1)u dW (I;1)u �

tR0

(I;2)u dW (I;2)u

�= �

�tR0

��j�I;u � (I;1)u

�dW (I;1)

u �tR0

(I;2)u dW (I;2)u

�exp

��tR0

�j�I;u

� (I;1)u + �I

(I;2)u

�du

�;

Page 46: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

36

and

�tR0

�j;udW(j;1)u

��

��tR0

(j;1)u dW (j;1)u �

tR0

(j;2)u dW (j;2)u

�= �

�tR0

��j;u � (j;1)u

�dW (j;1)

u �tR0

(j;2)u dW (j;2)u

�exp

��tR0

�j;u

� (j;1)u + �j

(j;2)u

�du

�:

Combining the previous expressions with (1.32), we see that F (t) will be a P -martingale

whenever

exp

��tR0

�j�I;u

� (I;1)u + �I

(I;2)u

�du

�exp

��tR0

�j;u

� (j;1)u + �j

(j;2)u

�du

�exp((�j+�j�I)t) = 1;

which is satis�ed when

�I � �I;t( (I;1)t + �I

(I;2)t ) = 0 dP dt a:s: (1.33)

�j � �j;t( (j;1)t + �j (j;2)t ) = 0 dP dt a:s:; (1.34)

where denotes the product of the two measures and where (1.33) is the no-arbitrage

condition for the market index obtained by imposing EPs

�ItIs

dQdP(t)

dQdP(s)exp(�r(t� s))

�= 1.

Following for example Heston (1993), we assume that the market price of variance risks

are proportional to their spot volatilities �I;t and �j;t, that is

(I;2)t + �I

(I;1)t = �I�I;t (1.35)

(j;2)t + �j

(j;1)t = �j�j;t: (1.36)

Solving (1.33), (1.34), (1.35), and (1.36) restricting attention to the subset of solutions

satisfying �j = 0; where idiosyncratic variance risk is not priced, we have

(I;1)t =

�I � �I�I�2I;t�I;t(1� �2I)

and (I;2)t =

�I�2I;t � �I�I

�I;t(1� �2I)(1.37)

Page 47: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

37

(j;1)t =

�j�j;t(1� �2j )

and (j;2)t = �

�j�j

�j;t(1� �2j ): (1.38)

Given (1.37) and (1.38), an application of the Girsanov�s theorem delivers the risk-neutral

Brownian motions d ~Wt = dWt + dDW;W

0Et t where

d ~W(I;1)t = dW

(I;1)t +

��I�I;t

�dt (1.39)

d ~W(I;2)t = dW

(I;2)t + (�I�I;t) dt (1.40)

d ~W(j;1)t = dW

(j;1)t +

��j�j;t

�dt (1.41)

d ~W(j;2)t = dW

(j;2)t : (1.42)

The previous results can now be used to risk-neutralize the processes (1.2) to (1.5) and

obtain (1.9), (1.10), (1.11), and (1.12). For the market factor using (1.39) in (1.2) and

(1.40) in (1.3), we have

dItIt

= (r + �I)dt+ �I;tdW(I;1)t

= (r + �I)dt+ �I;t

�d ~W

(I;1)t � �I

�I;tdt

�= rdt+ �I;td ~W

(I;1)t ; (1.43)

and

d�2I;t = �I(�I � �2I;t)dt+ �I�I;tdW(I;2)t

= �I(�I � �2I;t)dt+ �I�I;t�d ~W

(I;2)t � �I�I;tdt

�= ~�I

�~�I � �2I;t

�dt+ �I�I;td ~W

(I;2)t ; (1.44)

where ~�I = �I + �I�I and ~�I =�I�I~�I. Using a similar argument, we can show that

dSjt

Sjt� rdt = �j

�dItIt� rdt

�+ �j;td ~W

(j;1)t (1.45)

d�2j;t = �j(�j � �2j;t)dt+ �j�j;td ~W(j;2)t : (1.46)

Page 48: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

38

A.2 Proof of Proposition 1. Part 2: Equity Characteristic Function

For ease of notation, we de�ne the integrated Brownian ~W 1�k;t:T

�TRt

�k;ud ~W(k;1)u and the

integrated variance �2k;t:T �TRt

�2k;udu for k 2 fI; jg. Given the Q-processes, one can apply

Ito�s lemma to ln(Sjt ) and obtain (after integration) the following expression for individual

equity log-returns

ln

SjTSjt

!= r� � 1

2

��2j;t:T + �

2j�2I;t:T

�+ ~W 1

�j;t:T+ �j ~W

1�I;t:T

; (1.47)

where � = T � t. Therefore, the conditional characteristic function of the risk-neutral

log-returns takes the form

~�LR �

� ; u; �j�= EQt

�exp

�iu

�r� � 1

2

��2j;t:T + �

2j�2I;t:T

�+ ~W 1

�j;t:T+ �j ~W

1�I;t:T

���:

(1.48)

Using the de�nition of the stochastic exponential �(�) in (1.29), we have

��� ~W 1

�k;t:T

�= exp

�� ~W 1

�k;t:T� (�)

2

2

D~W 1�k; ~W 1

�k

Et:T

�= exp

�� ~W 1

�k;t:T� 12�2�2k;t:T

�;

(1.49)

for k 2 fj; Ig, which allows us to write (1.48) as

~�LR �

� ; u; �j�= exp(iur�) � (1.50)

EQt

h��iu�i ~W

1�I;t:T

���iu ~W 1

�j;t:T

�exp

���g1(u; �j)�

2I;t:T + g2(u)�

2j;t:T

��i

where g1(u; �j) =iu2 �

2j (1� iu) and g2(u) = iu

2 (1� iu). Following Carr and Wu (2004) and

Detemple and Rindisbacher (2010), we de�ne the following change-of-measure

dC

dQ(t) � �

�iu�j ~W

1�I;0:t

���iu ~W 1

�j;0:t

�: (1.51)

Page 49: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

39

Combining (1.50) with the change of measure (1.51), we can write

~�LR �

� ; u; �j�= exp(iur�)EQt

"dCdQ(T )

dCdQ(t)

exp���g1(u; �j)�

2I;t:T + g2(u)�

2j;t:T

��#

) ~�LR �

� ; u; �j�= exp(iur�)ECt

�exp(�g1(u; �j)�2I;t:T )

�ECt

�exp

��g2(u)�2j;t:T

��: (1.52)

Given an extension of the Girsanov theorem to the complex plane, under the C-measure

we have

dWC;(I;2)t = d ~W

(I;2)t � (iu�I�j�I;t)dt

dWC;(j;2)t = d ~W

(j;2)t � (iu�j�j;t)dt:

As a result,

d�2k;t = �Ck (�Ck � �2k;t)dt+ �k�k;tdW

C;(k;2)t (1.53)

where

�CI = ~�I � iu�I�j�I ; �CI =~�I~�I

�CI; �Cj = �j � iu�j�j ; and �Cj =

�j�j

�Cj:

We can now make use of the closed-form solution for the moment generating function of

ECt [exp��g(u)�2t:T

�] to obtain the following expression for ~�

LR(�);

~�LR �

� ; u; �j�= exp

�iur� �

�A(� ; u; �j) +B(� ; u)

�� C(� ; u; �j)�2I;t �D(� ; u)�2j;t

�;

(1.54)

with

A(� ; u; �j) =~�I~�I

�2I

(2 ln

(1�

1(u; �j)� �CI21(u; �j)

�1� e�1(u;�j)�

�!+�1(u; �j)� �CI

��

)(1.55)

Page 50: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

40

B(� ; u) =�j�j

�2j

(2 ln

1�

2(u)� �Cj22(u)

�1� e�2(u)�

�!+�2(u)� �Cj

��

)(1.56)

C�� ; u; �j

�=

2(1� e�1(u;�j)� )g1(u; �j)

21(u; �j)��1(u; �j)� �CI

� �1� e�1(u;�j)�

� (1.57)

D(� ; u) =2(1� e�2(u)� )g2(u)

22(u)��2(u)� �Cj

� �1� e�2(u)�

� ; (1.58)

and where

1(u; �j) =q(�CI )

2 + 2�2Ig1(u; �j) and 2(u) =q(�Cj )

2 + 2�2jg2(u);

with

g1(u; �j) =iu

2�2j (1� iu) and g2(u) =

iu

2(1� iu);

and

�CI = ~�I � iu�I�j�I and �Cj = �j � iu�j�j

Using the fact that ~�j �� ; u; �j

�= eiu ln(S

jt )~�

LR �� ; u; �j

�, the previous equations can be

used to compute the price of a European call option written on Sj .

B. Proof of Proposition 2

Within our model, the index price (It) takes the following form under the risk-neutral

measure

It = I0 exp�rt� 1

2�2I;0:t + ~W 1

�I;0:t

�:

Taking the derivative of the index price It with respect to �j ~W1�I;0:t

gives

@It

@�j ~W1�I;0:t

=@It

@ ~W 1�I;0:t

@ ~W 1�I;0:t

@�j ~W1�I;0:t

=@It

@ ~W 1�I;0:t

@�j ~W

1�I;0:t

@ ~W 1�I;0:t

!�1=It�j;

Page 51: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

41

where the second equality makes use of the inverse function theorem which holds as long

as �j 6= 0. Moreover, as long as It 6= 0 the inverse function theorem also implies that

@�j ~W1�I;0:t

@It=

@It

@�j ~W1�I;0:t

!�1=�jIt: (1.59)

Furthermore, within our model the equity price is given by

Sjt = Sj0 exp(rt�1

2

��2j;0:t + �

2j�2I;0:t

�+ ~W 1

�j;0:t + �j~W 1�I;0:t

);

which implies@Sjt

@�j ~W1�I;0:t

= Sjt : (1.60)

Combining (1.59) and (1.60) implies

@Sjt@It

=@Sjt

@�j ~W1�I;0:t

@�j ~W1�I;0:t

@It=SjtIt�j :

Therefore, for any derivative f j written on Sj the sensitivity of f j with respect to market

value, It (market delta), is

@f j

@It=@f j

@Sjt

@Sjt@It

=@f j

@Sjt

SjtIt�j : (1.61)

For the sensitivity of f j with respect to market variance (market vega), we have

@f j

@�2I;t=

@f j

@Vj;t

@Vj;t@�2I;t

=@f j

@Vj;t

@(�2j�2I;t + �

2j;t)

@�2I;t=

@f j

@Vj;t�2j :

C. Proof of Proposition 3

The proof of this proposition is adapted from Broadie, Chernov, and Johannes (2009) to

our set-up. By application of Ito�s lemma to the derivative contract f j written on Sj ,

Page 52: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

42

combined with the pricing PDE, allows us to write the dynamic of df j under P as

df j =nrf j � f jSrS

jt � f

jVj�2j ~�I(

~�I � �2I;t) + ~�j(~�j � �2j;t)odt

+f jSdSjt + f

jVjdVj;t

, df j =nrf j � f jSrS

jt � f

jVj�2j ~�I(

~�I � �2I;t) + �j(�j � �2j;t)odt (1.62)

+f jSdSjt + f

jVjdVj;t:

where f jx denotes the partial derivative of f j with respect to x. Note that in the previous

equation, we have assumed that idiosyncratic risk is not priced, which is consistent with

Proposition 1 (i.e. ~�j = �j and ~�j = �j). Moreover,

EPt [dSjt ]

dt= (r + �j + �j�I)S

jt

EPt [dVj;t]

dt= �2j�I

��I � �2I;t

�+ �j(�j � �2j;t):

(1.63)

Consequently, combining (1.62) and (1.63) leads to

1

dtEPt

�df j

f j� rdt

�=

f jSf jEPt

hdSjt � rS

jt dti+f jVjf j�2jE

Pt

hd�2I;t � ~�I(~�I � �2I;t)dt

i+f jVjf jEPt

�d�2j;t � �j(�j � �2j;t)dt

�;

which simpli�es to

1

dtEPt

�df j

f j� rdt

�= f jS

Sjtf j��j + �j�I

�+ f jVj

�2jf j(~�I~�I � �I�I): (1.64)

As in Heston (1993), our risk neutralization implies that ~�I~�I = �I�I . Consequently, we

obtain1

dtEPt

�df j

f j� rdt

�= f jS

Sjtf j��j + �j�I

�=@f j

@Sjt

Sjtf j�j +

@f j

@It

Itf j�I ;

Page 53: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

43

where the second equation uses the result in Proposition 2.

D. Proof of Proposition 4

The following argument is derived under the P measure; however, a similar argument can

be developed under the Qmeasure. Given the de�nition of skewness, the total (conditional)

skewness of the integrated return of �rm j is

SkP

R Tt

dSju

Sju

!�

EPt

��R TtdSjuSju� EPt

hR TtdSjuSju

i�3��EPt

��R TtdSjuSju� EPt

hR TtdSjuSju

i�2��3=2 : (1.65)

Given that R Tt

dSju

Sju� EPt

"R Tt

dSju

Sju

#= �jW

1�I;t:T

+W 1�j;t:T

;

equation (1.65) can be simpli�ed to

SkP

R Tt

dSju

Sju

!=

EPt

���jW

1�I;t:T

+W 1�j;t:T

�3��EPt

���jW

1�I;t:T

+W 1�j;t:T

�2��3=2 :

By the properties of Ito integrals and the independence of W (I;1) and W (j;1), we have

EPt

���jW

1�I;t:T

+W 1�j;t:T

�2�= �2j � EPt

��2I;t:T

�+ EPt

��2j;t:T

�= EPt [Vj;t:T ];

and

EPt

���jW

1�I;t:T

+W 1�j;t:T

�3�= �3j � EPt

��W 1�I;t:T

�3�+ EPt

��W 1�j;t:T

�3�:

Page 54: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

44

Consequently, the total (conditional) skewness of the integrated return of �rm j takes the

form

SkP

R Tt

dSju

Sju

!= �3j

EPt

��W 1�I;t:T

�3��EPt [Vj;t:T ]

�3=2 +

EPt

��W 1�j;t:T

�3��EPt [Vj;t:T ]

�3=2 (1.66)

= sign(�j) � �3j � EPt [�

2I;t:T ]

EPt [Vj;t:T ]

!3=2�EPt

��W 1�I;t:T

�3��EPt [�

2I;t:T ]

�3=2 +0@EPt

h�2j;t:T

iEPt [Vj;t:T ]

1A3=2 � EPt��W 1�j;t:T

�3��EPt

h�2j;t:T

i�3=2 :For positive beta �rms, we obtain

SkP

R Tt

dSju

Sju

!= �3j �

EPt [�

2I;t:T ]

EPt [Vj;t:T ]

!3=2� SkPI;t:T +

EPt [�

2j;t:T ]

EPt [Vj;t:T ]

!3=2� SkPj;t:T ; (1.67)

where

SkPI;t:T = SkP�R T

t

dIsIs

�and SkPj;t:T = SkP

�R Tt �j;sdW

(j;1)s

�are the market and idiosyncratic skewness, respectively.

Page 55: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

45

ReferencesAndersen, T., Fusari, N., Todorov, V., (2013) Parametric Inference and Dynamic State

Recovery from Option Panels, Working Paper, Northwestern University.

Bakshi, G., Cao, C., Chen, Z. (1997) Empirical performance of alternative option pric-

ing models, Journal of Finance, 52, 2003�2050.

Bakshi, G., Cao, C., Zhong, Z. (2012) Assessing models of individual equity option

prices, Working Paper, University of Maryland

Bakshi, G., Kapadia, N. (2003) Delta-hedged gains and the negative market volatility

risk premium, Review of Financial Studies, 16, 527�566.

Bakshi, G., Kapadia, N., Madan, D. (2003) Stock return characteristics, skew laws, and

di¤erential pricing of individual equity options, Review of Financial Studies, 10, 101�143.

Bates, D. (2000) Post-�87 crash fears in the S&P500 futures option market, Journal of

Econometrics, 94, 181�238.

Bates, D. (2008) The market for crash risk, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,

32, 2291-2321.

Black, F., Scholes, M. (1973) Valuation of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of

Political Economy, 81, 637�654.

Bollerslev, T., Todorov, B. (2011) Tails, fears, and risk premia, Journal of Finance, 66,

2165�2211.

Broadie, M., Chernov, M., Johannes, M. (2007) Model speci�cation and risk premiums:

Evidence from futures options, Journal of Finance, 62, 1453�1490.

Broadie, M. Chernov, M., Johannes, M. (2009) Understanding index option returns,

Review of Financial Studies, 22, 4493�4529.

Buss, A., Vilkov, G., (2012) Measuring equity risk with option-implied correlations,

Review of Financial Studies, 25, 3113�3140.

Carr, P., Madan, D. (2012) Factor models for option pricing, Asia-Paci�c Financial

Markets, 19, 319�329.

Page 56: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

46

Carr, P., Wu, L. (2004) Time-changed Lévy processes and option pricing, Journal of

Financial Economics, 71, 113�141.

Carr, P., Wu, L. (2007) Stochastic skew in currency options, Journal of Financial

Economics, 86, 213�247.

Chang, B.Y, Christo¤ersen, P., Jacobs, K., Vainberg, G. (2012) Option-implied mea-

sures of equity risk, Review of Finance, 16, 385�428.

Christo¤ersen, P., Heston, S., Jacobs, K. (2009) The shape and term structure of the

index option smirk: Why multifactor stochastic volatility models work so well, Management

Science, 55, 1914�1932.

Constantinides, G., Czerwonko, M., Jackwerth, J., Perrakis, S. (2011) Are options on

index futures pro�table for risk averse investors? Empirical evidence, Journal of Finance,

66, 1407�1437.

Cox, J., Ingersoll, J., Ross, S. (1985) A theory of the term structure of interest rates,

Econometrica, 53, 385�408.

Dennis, P., Mayhew, S. (2002) Risk-neutral skewness: Evidence from stock options,

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 37, 471�93.

Detemple, J. B., Rindisbacher, M. (2010) Dynamic asset allocation: Portfolio decom-

position formula and applications, Review of Financial Studies, 23, p 25�100.

Driessen, J., Maenhout, P., Vilkov, G. (2009) The price of correlation risk: Evidence

from equity options, Journal of Finance, 64, 1377�1406.

Duan, J-C., Wei, J. (2009) Systematic risk and the price structure of individual equity

options, Review of Financial Studies, 22, 1981�2006.

Elkamhi, R., Ornthanalai, C. (2010) Market jump risk and the price structure of indi-

vidual equity options, Working Paper, Rotman School, University of Toronto.

Engle, R. and Figlewski, S. (2012) Modeling the dynamics of correlations among implied

volatilities, Working Paper, Stern School, New York University.

Frazzini, A. and Pedersen, L. H. (2013) Betting against beta, Journal of Financial

Economics, forthcoming.

Page 57: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

47

Goyal A., Saretto A. (2009) Cross-section of option returns and volatility. Journal of

Financial Economics, 94, 310�326.

Hansen, P., Lunde, A., Voev, V. (2012) Realized beta GARCH: A multivariate GARCH

model with realized measures of volatility and co-volatility, Journal of Applied Economet-

rics, forthcoming.

Heston, S. (1993) Closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility, with ap-

plication to bond and currency options, Review of Financial Studies, 6, 327�343.

Heston, S., Nandi, S. (2000) A closed-form GARCH option pricing model, Review of

Financial Studies, 13, 585�626.

Hull, J., White, A. (1987) The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatilities,

Journal of Finance, 42, 281�300.

Jacquier, E., Polson, N.G., Rossi, P.E. (1994) Bayesian analysis of stochastic volatility

models (with discussion), Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 12, 371�417.

Jones, C. (2003) The dynamics of stochastic volatility: Evidence from underlying and

options markets, Journal of Econometrics, 116, 181�224.

Jones, C., Wang, T. (2012) The term structure of equity option implied volatility,

Working Paper, USC Marshall.

Kelly, B., Lustig, H., Van Nieuwerburgh, S. (2013) Too-systemic-to-fail: What option

markets imply about sector-wide government guarantees, Working Paper, NYU Stern.

Kelly, B., Lustig, H., Van Nieuwerburgh, S. (2012) The volatility factor structure,

Working Paper, NYU Stern.

Mo, H., Wu, L. (2007) International capital asset pricing: Evidence from options,

Journal of Empirical Finance, 14, 465�498.

Pan, J. (2002) The jump risk premia implicit in options: Evidence from an integrated

time series study, Journal of Financial Economics, 63, 3�50.

Patton, A., Verardo, M. (2012) Does beta move with news? Firm-speci�c information

�ows and learning about pro�tability, Review of Financial Studies, 25, 2789�2839.

Protter, P. (1990) Stochastic integration and di¤erential equations, Springer-Verlag.

Page 58: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

48

Santa-Clara, P., Yan, S. (2010) Crashes, volatility, and the equity premium: Lessons

from S&P500 options, Review of Economics and Statistics, 92, 435�451.

Schürho¤, N., Ziegler, A. (2010) The pricing of systematic and idiosyncratic variance

risk, Working Paper, University of Zurich.

Serban, M., Lehoczky, J., Seppi, D. (2008) Cross-sectional stock option pricing and

factor models of returns, Working Paper, CMU.

Taylor, S., Xu, X. (1994) The term structure of volatility implied by foreign exchange

options, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 29, 57-74.

Trolle, A., Schwartz, E. (2009) Unspanned stochastic volatility and the pricing of com-

modity derivatives, Review of Financial Studies, 22, 4423�4461.

Vasicek, O. A. (1973) A Note on using cross-sectional information in Bayesian estima-

tion of security betas, Journal of Finance, 28, 1233�1239.

Vasquez, A. (2011) Volatility term structure and the cross-section of option returns,

Working Paper, ITAM.

Wiggins, J. (1987) Option values under stochastic volatility: Theory and empirical

evidence, Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 351�372.

Page 59: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

49

Figure 1: At-the-Money Implied Volatility. Six Firms and the S&P 500 Index

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

20

40

60

80

100A

TM Im

plie

d V

ol.

Boeing

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

20

40

60

80

100Coca Cola

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

20

40

60

80

100

ATM

 Impl

ied 

Vol

.

Home Depot

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

20

40

60

80

100Merck

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

20

40

60

80

100

ATM

 Impl

ied 

Vol

.

Proctor & Gamble

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

20

40

60

80

100Walmart

Notes to Figure: We plot the time series of implied volatility for six �rms (black) and the

S&P 500 index (grey). On each day we use contracts with between 30 and 60 days to

maturity and a moneyness (S=K) between 0:95 and 1:05. For every trading day and every

security, we average the available implied volatilities to obtain an estimate of at-the-money

implied volatility.

Page 60: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

50

Figure 2: Implied Volatility Level, Moneyness and Term Slope.

S&P 500 Index and the First Principal Component from 29 Firms

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 201010

20

30

40

50

60

IV L

evel

Panel A: S&P500 IV Level

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 201010

20

30

40

50

60

IV L

evel

Panel B: 1st PC of Equity IV Level

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 20100

2

4

6

8

IV M

oney

ness

 Slo

pe

Panel C: S&P500 IV Moneyness Slope

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 20100

2

4

6

8

IV M

oney

ness

 Slo

pe

Panel D: 1st PC of Equity IV Moneyness Slope

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010­8

­6

­4

­2

0

2

IV T

erm

 Slo

pe

Panel E: S&P500 IV Term Slope

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010­8

­6

­4

­2

0

2

IV T

erm

 Slo

pe

Panel F: 1st PC of Equity IV Term Slope

Notes to Figure: Panel A plots the implied volatility level from S&P 500 index options.

Panel B plots the �rst principal component (1st PC) of implied volatility levels from options

on 29 equities in the Dow-Jones index. Panel C plots the slope of implied volatility with

respect to moneyness from short-term S&P 500 index options. Panel D plots the 1st PC of

the implied volatility moneyness slopes from options on the 29 equities. Panel E plots the

slope of the implied volatility term structure from S&P 500 index options. Panel F plots

the 1st PC of the implied volatility term structure from options on the 29 equities.

Page 61: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

51

Figure 3: Market Delta and Vega of Equity Call Options

0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.40

0.05

0.1

0.15 M

arke

t Del

taMarket Delta of Equity Call Options

 Beta = 1.3

 Beta = 1

 Beta = 0.7

0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.81.80

4

8

12

Moneyness (S/K)

 Mar

ket V

ega

Market Vega of Equity Call Options

Notes to Figure: We plot the sensitivity of equity options to changes in market level (market

delta) and market volatility (market vega). Each line has a di¤erent beta but the same

amount of unconditional total equity variance ~Vj = �2j~�I + �j = 0:1. We set the current

spot variance to �2I;t = 0:01 and Vj;t = 0:05, and de�ne the idiosyncratic variance as the

residual �2j;t = Vj;t � �2j�2I;t. The market index parameters are ~�I = 5; ~�I = 0:04; �I =

0:5; �I = �0:8; and the individual equity parameters are �j = 1; �j = 0:4; and �j = 0.

The risk-free rate is 4% per year, option maturity is 3 months, and we set Sjt =It = 0:1:

Page 62: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

52

Figure 4: Expected Excess Returns on Equity Options

0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.40

0.3

0.6

0.9

1.2

1.5D

aily

 Exc

ess R

etur

n (%

)Call Option Excess Return

 Beta = 1.3

 Beta = 1

 Beta = 0.7

0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4­0.5

­0.4

­0.3

­0.2

­0.1

00

Moneyness (S/K)

Dai

ly E

xces

s Ret

urn 

(%)

Put Option Excess Return

Notes to Figure: We plot expected excess returns in percent per day on call and put options

using the model. Each line has a di¤erent beta but the same amount of unconditional total

equity variance ~Vj = �2j~�I + �j = 0:1. We set the current spot variance to �2I;t = 0:01 and

Vj;t = 0:05, and de�ne the idiosyncratic variance as the residual �2j;t = Vj;t � �2j�2I;t. The

market index parameters are ~�I = 5; ~�I = 0:04; �I = 0:5; �I = �0:8; �I = 0:075; and the

individual equity parameters are �j = 1; �j = 0:4; �j = 0, and �j = 0. The risk-free rate

is 4% per year and option maturity is 3 months.

Page 63: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

53

Figure 5: Beta and Implied Volatility Across Moneyness and Maturity

0.8 0.85 0.9 0.95 1 1.05 1.1 1.15 1.222

24

26

28

30

32

Moneyness (S/K)

 Impl

ied 

Vola

tility

Beta and Implied Volatility Across Moneyness

0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 322

24

26

28

30

32

Years

 Impl

ied 

Vola

tility

Beta and the At­the­Money Implied Volatility Term­Structure

 Beta = 1.3

 Beta = 1

 Beta = 0.7

Notes to Figure: The top panel plots option implied volatility (IV) from model prices with

3 months to maturity against moneyness (S=K). The bottom panel plots model IV for

at-the-money options against time-to-maturity in years. Each line has a di¤erent beta but

the same amount of unconditional total equity variance ~Vj = �2j~�I + �j = 0:1. We set the

current spot variance to �2I;t = 0:01 and Vj;t = 0:05, and de�ne the idiosyncratic variance as

the residual �2j;t = Vj;t��2j�2I;t. The market index parameters are ~�I = 5; ~�I = 0:04; �I =

0:5; �I = �0:8; and the individual equity parameters are �j = 1; �j = 0:4; and �j = 0.

The risk-free rate is 4% per year.

Page 64: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

54

Figure 6.A: Average Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Volatility Smile.

High Volatility (black) and Low Volatility (grey) Days

0.9 1 1.138

43

48

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

26

31

36Alcoa

0.9 1 1.136

41

46

20

25

30American Express

0.9 1 1.134

39

44

17

22

27Bank of America

0.9 1 1.130

35

40

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

23

28

33Boeing

0.9 1 1.132

37

42

25

30

35Caterpillar

0.9 1 1.136

41

46

20

25

30JP Morgan

0.9 1 1.122

27

32

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

19

24

29Chevron

0.9 1 1.144

49

54

27

32

37Cisco

0.9 1 1.127

32

37

18

23

28AT&T

0.9 1 1.123

28

33

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

15

20

25Coca Cola

0.9 1 1.132

37

42

22

27

32Disney

0.9 1 1.127

32

37

20

25

30Dupont

0.9 1 1.121

26

31

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

18

23

28Exxon Mobil

Moneyness (S/K)0.9 1 1.1

30

35

40

18

23

28General Electric

Moneyness (S/K)0.9 1 1.1

37

42

47

27

32

37Hewlett­Packard

Moneyness (S/K)

Notes to Figure: We plot the market IV (solid) and model IV (dashed) averaged over time

for di¤erent moneyness categories for each �rm. The black lines (left axis) show the average

on days with above-average IV and the grey lines (right axis) show the average for days

with below-average IV. Moneyness measured by S=K is on the horizontal axis.

Page 65: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

55

Figure 6.B: Average Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Volatility Smile.

High Volatility (black) and Low Volatility (grey) Days

0.9 1 1.134

39

44

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

23

28

33Home Depot

0.9 1 1.139

44

49

27

32

37Intel

0.9 1 1.128

33

38

18

23

28IBM

0.9 1 1.121

26

31

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

15

20

25Johnson & Johnson

0.9 1 1.125

30

35

21

26

31McDonald's

0.9 1 1.126

31

36

21

26

31Merck

0.9 1 1.131

36

41

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

20

25

30Microsoft

0.9 1 1.124

29

34

19

24

293M

0.9 1 1.128

33

38

21

26

31Pfizer

0.9 1 1.122

27

32

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

16

21

26Procter & Gamble

0.9 1 1.129

34

39

19

24

29Travellers

0.9 1 1.127

32

37

20

25

30United Technologies

0.9 1 1.127

32

37

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

18

23

28Verizon

Moneyness (S/K)0.9 1 1.1

27

32

37

19

24

29Walmart

Moneyness (S/K)0.9 1 1.1

20

25

30

13

18

23S&P500

Moneyness (S/K)

Notes to Figure: We plot the market IV (solid) and model IV (dashed) averaged over time

for di¤erent moneyness categories for each �rm. The black lines (left axis) show the average

on days with above-average IV and the grey lines (right axis) show the average for days

with below-average IV. Moneyness measured by S=K is on the horizontal axis.

Page 66: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

56

Figure 7.A: Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Term Structures for

At-the-Money Implied Volatility. Upward-Sloping (grey) and Downward-Sloping (black)

Days

2 4 638

43

48

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

31

36

41Alcoa

2 4 640

45

50

25

30

35American Express

2 4 641

46

51

26

31

36Bank of America

2 4 633

38

43

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

27

32

37Boeing

2 4 632

37

42

29

34

39Caterpillar

2 4 639

44

49

24

29

34JP Morgan

2 4 624

29

34

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

22

27

32Chevron

2 4 645

50

55

32

37

42Cisco

2 4 629

34

39

22

27

32AT&T

2 4 626

31

36

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

19

24

29Coca Cola

2 4 632

37

42

25

30

35Disney

2 4 628

33

38

23

28

33Dupont

2 4 624

29

34

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

21

26

31

Months to Maturity

Exxon Mobil

2 4 629

34

39

22

27

32

Months to Maturity

General Electric

2 4 637

42

47

28

33

38

Months to Maturity

Hewlett­Packard

Notes to Figure: The solid black line (left axis) shows the average market IV on days with

steeper-than-median downward-sloping term structures and the grey line (right axis) shows

the average market IV on days with steeper-than-median upward-sloping term structures.

The dashed lines show the corresponding average model IVs. Moneyness (S=K) is between

0:95 and 1:05.

Page 67: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

57

Figure 7.B: Market- (solid) and Model-Implied (dashed) Term Structures for

At-the-Money Implied Volatility. Upward-Sloping (grey) and Downward-Sloping (black)

Days

2 4 633

38

43

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

27

32

37Home Depot

2 4 638

43

48

30

35

40Intel

2 4 629

34

39

22

27

32IBM

2 4 622

27

32

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

18

23

28Johnson & Johnson

2 4 626

31

36

21

26

31McDonald's

2 4 626

31

36

24

29

34Merck

2 4 632

37

42

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

26

31

36Microsoft

2 4 624

29

34

22

27

323M

2 4 626

31

36

25

30

35Pfizer

2 4 625

30

35

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

19

24

29Procter & Gamble

2 4 627

32

37

22

27

32Travellers

2 4 628

33

38

23

28

33United Technologies

2 4 629

34

39

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

21

26

31

Months to Maturity

Verizon

2 4 629

34

39

22

27

32

Months to Maturity

Walmart

2 4 622

27

32

16

21

26

Months to Maturity

S&P500

Notes to Figure: The solid black line (left axis) shows the average market IV on days with

steeper-than-median downward-sloping term structures and the grey line (right axis) shows

the average market IV on days with steeper-than-median upward-sloping term structures.

The dashed lines show the corresponding average model IVs. Moneyness (S=K) is between

0:95 and 1:05.

Page 68: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

58

Figure 8: Implied Volatility Levels, Moneyness Slopes, and Term Structure Slopes Scatter

Plotted Against Beta. 29 Firms

0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.320

30

40

50

Ave

rage

 IV L

evel

0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.31

1.5

2

2.5

Ave

rage

 Mon

eyne

ss S

lope

0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.30.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

Option­Implied BetaAve

rage

 Abs

olut

e T

erm

 Slo

pe

Notes to Figure: We plot the average implied volatility (IV) levels (top panel), the average

moneyness slopes (middle panel), and the average absolute value of the term-structure

slopes (bottom panel) against the estimated betas from Table 4.

Page 69: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

59

Figure 9: Regression-based Betas versus Option-Implied Beta. 29 Firms

0.7 0.9 1.1 1.30.5

0.7

0.9

1.1

1.3

1.5

1.71.7

OL

S B

eta

0.7 0.9 1.1 1.30.5

0.7

0.9

1.1

1.3

1.5

1.71.7

Option­Implied Beta

OL

S B

eta 

with

 Shr

inka

ge

Notes to Figure: We plot the regression-based OLS beta estimates against option-implied

beta (top panel), and OLS beta with shrinkage against option-implied betas (bottom panel)

for 29 �rms. The OLS betas are obtained from a CAPM regression using daily returns

during January 4, 1996 to October 29, 2010. The betas with shrinkage are de�ned by

0:4 + 0:6 � �OLSj where �OLSj is the OLS beta. In both panels, the �tted line from the

regression is displayed in black while the grey line represents the 45�line.

Page 70: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

60

Page 71: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

61

Page 72: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

62

Page 73: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

63

Page 74: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

64

Page 75: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

65

Page 76: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

66

Page 77: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

67

Chapter 2

Inventory Risk, Market-Maker Wealth, and the

Variance Risk Premium

2.1 Introduction

The variance of the stock market evolves stochastically through time. Market variance is

thus itself risky. With a daily trading volume of more than 110 billion dollars, S&P 500

index (SPX) options are the most actively traded securities providing exposure to market

variance risk. These options are priced at a signi�cant premium over the realized variance

of the underlying S&P 500 index. This is commonly referred to as the (market) variance

risk premium. Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) demonstrate that the variance risk

premium predicts future stock market returns. The variance risk premium is thus a poten-

tial state variable for the economy, and a better understanding of the factors impacting it

is of signi�cant interest.

On average, the net demand of SPX option by end-users is positive (see, among others,

Bollen and Whaley, 2004, and Gârleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman, 2009). Market-makers

in these options thus act as net sellers and build up large negative inventories over time.

Through their inventory, intermediaries are exposed to market variance risk in addition to

the conventional equity market risk. While market-makers can e¢ ciently hedged equity

market risk using index future contracts, frictions impair their ability to eliminate their

billion dollars exposure to market variance.1 Consequently, market-makers bear large vari-

1Bates (2003) discusses the constraints faced by market-makers to hedge their aggregate exposure tovariance risk. Bakshi, Cao, and Chen (1997), Buraschi and Jackwerth (2001), and Bakshi and Kapadia

Page 78: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

68

ance risk and in�uence the variance risk premium. Focusing on the intermediation of SPX

options, our contribution is to demonstrate, empirically and theoretically, the joint impact

of market-makers�inventory risk and wealth on the variance risk premium.

We consider two factors in�uencing the required compensation of market-makers that

should help explain the variance risk premium. The �rst is the risk exposure of index

option market-makers to market volatility. We refer to it as inventory risk. The second

is market-maker wealth. Inventory risk measures the loading of market-makers� delta-

hedged inventory on the variance risk premium. A positive link between inventory risk and

the variance risk premium implies that a higher risk exposure results in higher expected

compensation for intermediaries. Moreover, wealth should also in�uence the variance risk

premium. As they become more constrained, risk-averse market-makers should require a

higher compensation. Surprisingly, little is known about the extent to which these variables

jointly explain the premium for market variance.

Our empirical analysis uses �fteen years of market-making activity for SPX options

and more than one million quotes. We establish our main empirical results using time-

series regressions of daily changes in variance risk premium controlling for lagged daily

changes. First, we show that both inventory risk and changes in market-maker wealth

are statistically signi�cant to explain the variance risk premium. The inclusion of both

variables leads to a 9% increase in the adjusted R-Squared at the daily frequency relative

to various controls.

When inventory risk decreases (i.e. becomes more negative) by one standard deviation,

it leads to a 1:2% decrease in the variance risk premium. Moreover, the e¤ect of inventory

on the variance risk premium is magni�ed when market-makers experience dramatic wealth

losses. When market-makers� loss is within its 90th percentile, a one standard deviation

decrease in inventory risk causes about a 9% decrease in next day�s variance risk premium.

These results are robust to subsample tests. They are also robust to various controls

(2003) argue that index options are non-redundant securities. Thus, in addition to illiquidity issues, hedgingSPX options using other assets introduces basis risk.

Page 79: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

69

including S&P 500 return, S&P 500 jump, investors�disagreement, and net buying pressure

for SPX options.

Bollen and Whaley (2004) demonstrate that net buying pressures are positively related

to changes in option implied volatilities. However, the channels by which net demand

impacts option implied volatilies and prices remain unclear. Our empirical analysis com-

plements their work by identifying and quantifying the e¤ect of one of these channels. When

SPX option net buying pressures are large and positive, market-makers�aggregate exposure

to market variance decreases (becomes more negative) on average. Because market-makers

exposure cannot be fully hedged, they command a higher compensation, which implies in a

more negative variance risk premium. Ultimately, a more negative variance risk premium

implies a higher level of risk-neutral volatility, and thus more expensive options.

Our work is related to the literature on the variance risk premium. For instance, Bakshi

and Kapadia (2003), Vilkov (2008), and Carr and Wu (2009) study the properties of the

variance risk premium for index and equity options. Eglo¤, Leippold, and Wu (2010), and

Todorov (2010) investigate the ability of a stochastic volatility-jump model to explain the

variance risk premium. Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) derive the implications of

a long-run risk model for the variance risk premium. More recently, Buraschi, Trojani,

and Vedolin (2014) relate investors�disagreement and the market price of volatility.2 This

paper contributes to this literature by documenting and modeling the impact of option

intermediation on the variance risk premium.

To further assess the robustness of our results, we investigate the ability of inventory

risk and changes in market-maker wealth to explain the daily changes in the variance

risk premium measured for various horizons. While robust to the entire term structure

of premia, the impact of inventory risk and market-maker wealth is prominent at short-

horizons. This �nding relates to Aït-Sahalia, Karaman, and Mancini (2014), who conclude

that investors�fear of a market crash is captured in short-term variance risk premia.

2See also Bakshi and Kapadia (2006) who relate the variance risk premium to investor risk aversionand the higher-order moments. Moreover, Driessen, Maenhout, and Vilkov (2009) explain the variance riskpremium by the correlation risk of individual equity.

Page 80: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

70

Theoretically, Gârleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009) set the stage for our analysis.

The authors establish that when perfect replication is not possible, net demand exerts pres-

sure on option prices. Their study demonstrates how demand impacts option prices under

various sources of incompleteness while leaving open the question of how intermediaries�

wealth and risk exposure interact to in�uence risk premia. Our work complements their

study by deriving the explicit relation between market-maker�s wealth, inventory risk, and

the variance risk premium in a fully speci�ed stochastic volatility (SV) framework.

We model a continuous-time economy in which the market variance has its own dynamic

and a risk-averse representative market-maker quotes index options. The time-varying

market variance causes part of the market-maker inventory to be a¤ected by unhedgeable

variance risk. To account for �uctuations in the market-maker�s variance risk exposure, we

allow inventory risk to vary over time. We solve for the endogenous variance risk premium,

that is, the utility-maximizing variance risk premium that clears the index option market.

Not only does the model show that inventory risk and the variance risk premium should

be positively related but it also demonstrates that the impact of inventory on the premium

is non-linearly decreasing in the market-maker�s wealth.

In standard SV models, researchers assume that the variance risk premium is the prod-

uct of a time-invariant parameter with the latent spot variance (see, among others, Heston,

1993, Bates, 2000, and Pan, 2002). This speci�cation attributes any discrepancy between

the objective properties of index returns and the risk-neutral probability measure implied

by option prices to the marginal investor�s preference over market variance. Our model

departs from this strand of literature by capturing the e¤ect of inventory risk and market-

maker wealth on the variance risk premium. Since inventory risk has its own dynamic and

the utility-maximizing wealth process is known, unlike Gârleanu, Pedersen, and Potesh-

man (2009) our model is straightforward to use for pricing. We estimate the model on

S&P 500 returns and a large panel of SPX puts. The model outperforms Heston (1993).

Interestingly and relative to Heston (1993), the model performs particularly well during

the crisis and when pricing out-of-the-money puts, which challenge traditional models.

Page 81: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

71

Surveying the empirical performance of various option pricing models, Bates (2003)

concludes that a focus on the explicit �nancial intermediation of the underlying risks by

option market-makers is needed. To the best of our knowledge, our model is the �rst to

address Bates (2003)�s challenge.

Most importantly, the model can be used to uncover the economic impact of inventory

risk and wealth on SPX option prices. During turbulent times, when market-maker loss is

within its 90th percentile, it causes up to 2:31% daily price increase.

This paper is related to the strand of literature that study option bid-ask spreads

and returns. Stoikov and Saglam (2009) propose a mean variance framework to ana-

lyze the optimal option bid-ask spread policy when markets are incomplete. Muravyev

(2013) demonstrates that selling pressure in�uences equity option returns. Christo¤ersen,

Goyenko, Jacobs, and Karoui (2014) study the e¤ect of stock and equity option illiquidity

on equity option returns. We contribute to this strand of the literature by showing the

impact of variations in market-makers�risk sharing capacity on the premium for market

variance, which is an important determinant of index option prices and returns.

Also related to our work is the literature that studies the e¤ect of intermediary con-

straints on option prices. Leippold and Su (2011) examine the in�uence of margin re-

quirements and funding costs on the implied-volatility smile in a constant volatility model.

Chen, Joslin, and Ni (2013) investigate the jump premium embedded in index options and

its predictive ability for stock market returns. To motivate their �ndings, the authors build

an equilibrium model in which the consumption process has a constant di¤usive volatility

and time-varying jumps. Moreover, intermediary constraints are captured in reduced form

through time-varying risk-aversion tied to the jump intensity. Our study contributes to

both of these papers by designing a model in which market variance is stochastic, and

the market-maker wealth is endogenous. Both of these features are needed to obtain ex-

plicit implications of intermediaries�risk exposure and wealth on the premium for market

variance.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present the data and the

Page 82: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

72

main variables used in this study. We also proceed to our main empirical tests. Section

3 formulates the theoretical analysis. In Section 4, we discuss the model implications. In

Section 5, we estimate the model and investigate its �t. Finally, we conclude in Section 6.

2.2 Empirical Analysis

2.2.1 Data

SPX options trade only at the Chicago Board Option Exchange (CBOE). To construct

the aggregate inventory of CBOE market-makers, we rely on the Market Data Express

Open/Close database for obtaining the daily non market-makers (end-users) order �ows

for SPX options starting on January 1, 1996 and ending on December 30, 2011. The data

divides the daily open/close buy and sell origins into two groups: �rm and customer. Cus-

tomer origin is further subdivided in three categories depending on order size. Since we are

interested in measuring SPX market-makers�aggregate inventory, we disregard individual

origins and group orders into buy and sell. More precisely, on each day we aggregate the

total buys and sells for each contract and take the di¤erence which corresponds to end-

users�net demand for that contract on that day. Because SPX options are European, the

time-series of market-makers�inventory for each contract can be reconstructed by summing

up the negative of end-users�net demand over time starting from the �rst day the contract

is quoted. We �lter out Leaps (options with more than one year to maturity), and restrict

the sample to start on January 1, 1997 to avoid biases in inventory measurement.3

For SPX option prices, we rely on end-of-day data from OptionMetrics starting on

January 1, 1997 and ending on December 30, 2011. From all the quotes provided, we

�lter out options that have moneyness (spot price over strike price) less than 0:8 and

larger than 1:2, those with a mid-quote< 3=8, those that do not satisfy the usual arbitrage

conditions, those with implied volatility less than 5% and greater than 150%, and those

3To correctly measure inventory for a given option, the full time-series of end-users�order �ows for thatoption must be observed. Because some options quoted at the beginning of 1997 have been issued at thebeginning of 1996, accurate measurement of inventories for these contracts constrains the empirical analysisto start on January 1, 1997.

Page 83: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

73

with less than ten days to maturity. For each option maturity, interest rates are estimated

by linear interpolation using zero coupon Treasury yields. The dividend yield is obtained

from OptionMetrics. We then merge the inventory data with the OptionMetrics database.

The �nal sample contains more than one million quotes for SPX puts and calls over the

1997-2011 period.

To construct the variance risk premium, we need daily estimates of realized variance. To

this end, we obtain high frequency data for S&P 500 index futures from Tickdata starting

on January 1, 1997 and ending on September 30, 2012.4 Based on multiple grids of intraday

squared returns, we construct daily measures of average realized variance following Zhang,

Mykland, and Aït-Sahalia (2005).

2.2.2 De�nition of Main Variables

Variance Risk Premium

The variance risk premium captures the di¤erence between physical and risk-neutral market

variances. At time t the variance risk premium with a horizon T is

V RP (t; T ) � RV (t; T )�RNV (t; T ) ; (2.1)

where RV (t; T ) � EPt [R t+Tt Vsds] denotes the expected integrated physical variance and

RNV (t; T ) � EQt [R t+Tt Vsds] is the expected integrated risk-neutral variance. Suppose

that we want to obtain a model-free estimate of the one-month variance risk premium on

day t, that is V RP (t; 30). Following Carr and Wu (2009), our �rst step is to compute

annualized RV (t; 30) from realized variances as

RV (t; 30) =365

30�

30Xi=1

RVt+i�1

!: (2.2)

4For some of our empirical tests, we need estimates of realized variance up to September 30, 2012 toconstruct a measure of the 9-month ex-post realized variance on December 30; 2011.

Page 84: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

74

As in Carr and Wu (2009), we follow the equity premium literature and proxy expected

physical variance by ex-post realized variances.5 To measure expected integrated risk-

neutral variance, we follow Britten-Jones and Neuberger (2000) and Bollerslev, Tauchen,

and Zhou (2009) among others. We compute RNV (t; 30) from a portfolio of SPX call

options as

RNV (t; 30) = 2 �1Z0

C(t; 30;Ke�r�30=365)� C(t; 0;K)K2

� dK; (2.3)

where C(t; T;K) is the price of a call observed at time t with time to maturity T and

strike price K, and r is the risk-free rate. We evaluate (2.3) using the trapezoidal rule.

Armed with the two measures of expected integrated variance, the one-month variance risk

premium on day t is V RP (t; 30) = RV (t; 30)�RNV (t; 30).

Table 1 presents the daily average of implied volatility, vega, days to maturity, number

of quotes, and volume.6 We also report the yearly averages of the one-month variance

risk premium. Market implied volatility is 22:28% on average. As found in earlier studies

(see, among others, Bakshi and Kapadia, 2003, Vilkov, 2008, and Carr and Wu, 2009), the

yearly averages of the variance risk premium are consistently negative. In our sample, the

risk-neutral variance exceeds the realized variance by 2:13%.

Figure 1 plots the time-series of the S&P 500 index level in the top panel, and of the

one-month variance risk premium expressed in percentage in middle panel. The variance

risk premium is mostly negative before 2008. Interestingly, during the �nancial crisis it

spikes to large positive and negative values contemporaneously to the abrupt price drop in

the S&P 500 index. To investigate if the large variations in variance risk premium during

the �nancial crisis are induced by measurement errors, we plot the weekly averages of daily

gains and losses of delta-hedged near-the-money options in the bottom panel of Figure

1. This exercise is motivated by Bakshi and Kapadia (2003), who show that the gains

and losses from delta-hedged positions in options are informative about the variance risk

5Note that on average ex-post realized variances are good proxies for expected realized variances.6The vega of an option measures the rate of change of the option price to a small increase in volatility.

Page 85: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

75

premium. For a given option f jt , the daily dollar gains and losses from delta-hedging it

from day t� 1 to t is

�Hedgejt � f jt ��f jt�1 +�

jt�1St + (f

jt�1 ��

jt�1St�1) � r�t+�

jt�1St�1 � q�t

�; (2.4)

where �jt is option j delta, St denotes the value of the S&P 500, q is the dividend yield, and

the time-step �t = 1=365. On each week, we average the daily �Hedgejt for all options

for which 0:98 6 St=Kj 6 1:02 to obtain the weekly average gain and loss. Interestingly,

the large �uctuations in V RP (t; 30) during the crisis period are also apparent from the

time-series of delta-hedged gains and losses.

Inventory Risk and Market-Maker Wealth

About 273 SPX calls and puts with distinct moneyness and maturities are quoted on

each day. To assess market-makers� inventory across options, Table 2 reports the daily

average of implied volatility, inventory, and delta-hedged gains and losses for di¤erent

moneyness and maturity categories. Note how market-makers�positions are consistently

negative across moneyness and maturities. Overall, SPX intermediaries are short about

one hundred thousand contracts on a daily basis.

Inventory risk measures the aggregate exposure of CBOE market-makers�inventory to

S&P 500 volatility. On each day, we calculate inventory risk as

InvRiskt �Pj�MM;jt V egajt ; (2.5)

where �MM;jt denotes market-makers�inventory for option j, and V egajt � @f jt =@

pVt is the

option vega, which we calculate using Black-Scholes.7 At any point in time, 1%� InvRisk

indicates the way inventory would respond in dollar terms to a 1% increase in market

7Black-Scholes�s vega has also been used as a proxy for option vega in a stochastic volatility frameworkin Carr and Wu (2007), Trolle and Schwartz (2009), and Christo¤ersen, Heston, and Jacobs (2009) amongothers.

Page 86: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

76

volatility.

Figure 2 plots the CBOE VIX index in the top panel, and the dynamic of inventory risk

in the bottom panel. Interestingly, no clear patterns are apparent between the VIX and

inventory risk time-series. Consistent with Table 2, we see that market-makers�exposure

to S&P 500 volatility is negative most of the time excepted during the �nancial crisis, and

in the beginning of 2011. Through their inventory, CBOE market-makers carry billion

dollars in risk exposure to market variance.

In order to measure the changes in market-makers�wealth overtime, we �rst compute

dealers�delta-hedged inventory pro�ts and losses as

P&Lt �Pj�MM;jt�1 �Hedgejt : (2.6)

Moreover, we estimate the bid-ask spread revenue of CBOE market-makers by calculating

for each day

BAt �Pjmin(BOjt ; SO

jt ) ��BidAskjt � 0:36

�; (2.7)

where BOjt denotes end-users� buy orders for option j, SOjt is end-users� sell orders,

BidAskjt denotes the option bid-ask spread, and $0:36 is the transaction fee charged to

dealers per contract traded.8 In our empirical analysis, we de�ne changes in wealth as the

sum of (2.6) and (2.7).

Figure 3 plots the daily pro�ts and losses from market-makers�delta-hedged inventory

in the top panel, the cumulative daily pro�ts and losses in the middle panel, and the

bid-ask spread revenue in the bottom panel. Market-makers face substantial risks. Their

daily pro�ts and losses �uctuate between +265 and �393 million dollars. Consistent with

the idea that large positions in options involve risks, the distribution of the daily delta-

hedged gains and losses is highly leptokurtic with an excess kurtosis of 73. Moreover, it is

asymmetric with a skewness coe¢ cient of �2:55. Market-makers have a 5% risk of losing

8This fee includes $0:33 charged by the CBOE and $0:03 charged by the Option Clearing Corporationfor clearing cost.

Page 87: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

77

at least 21 million dollars on any given day.

The fact that market-makers earn a pro�t on average from delta-hedging their inventory

generates the positive trend observed in the middle panel of Figure 3. In aggregate, market-

makers earn 9 million dollars monthly from their delta-hedged positions.

Finally, comparing the top panel with the bottom panel reveals the substantial impact

inventory risk has on dealers�wealth. Unlike equity stock market-makers, a large portion of

changes in option market-makers�wealth is driven by the �uctuations in their delta-hedged

inventory. In our sample, the absolute value of P&Lt is on average 1:5 times bigger than

BAt.

So far, we have established that the representative SPX market-maker faces substantial

variance risks from carrying large inventories over time. In option markets, dealers often

trade among themselves in order to manage part of the risks they face. However, whenever

end-users have large net exposure to market variance, so do SPX market-makers in the

aggregate. Because of market-makers large exposure to market variance, part of their

required compensation should be embedded in the variance risk premium.

2.2.3 Methodology and Predictions

Our empirical analysis is based on two di¤erent speci�cations for the variance risk premium.

Our �rst battery of tests is conducted on Carr and Wu (2009)�s log-variance risk premium,

LogV RP (t; T ) � ln (RV (t; T )=RNV (t; T )).9 We then investigate the robustness of our

results using V RP (t; T ) as de�ned by (2.1).

The methodology we follow is adapted from Bollen and Whaley (2004). More precisely,

we regress the changes in the variance risk premium against the explanatory variables and

9Because the distributions of the two measures of variance are positively skewed, the log-speci�cationalleviates the e¤ect of extreme values.

Page 88: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

78

lagged changes. When working with the log-speci�cation, we run

�LogV RP (t; T ) = Intercept+ �Inv1 InvRiskt�1 + �Inv2 (P&Lt +BAt) � InvRiskt�1

+�cControlt + �V RP�LogV RP (t� 1; T ) + "t;

(2.8)

where�LogV RP (t; T ) � LogV RP (t; T )�LogV RP (t�1; T ), and similarly for�V RP (t; T ).

If the variance risk premium captures part of dealers�required compensation, we should

expect a positive relationship between lagged inventory risk and changes in the variance

risk premium. The more negative (positive) inventory risk is the more negative (positive)

the variance risk premium should be as such a relationship implies positive returns for

dealers. Therefore, lagged inventory risk should positively impact changes in variance risk

premium. Our prediction is thus �Inv1 > 0.

As their wealth decreases, dealers should command a higher compensation. After con-

trolling for their lagged exposure, interacting cotemporaneous changes in wealth with

lagged inventory risk should capture the way dealers dynamically update their required

compensation as their wealth �uctuates. When market-makers are experiencing losses and

are negatively (positively) exposed to market variance, a higher compensation implies a

decrease (increase) in the variance risk premium. Therefore, our prediction is �Inv2 < 0.

Motivated by previous studies, we include a series of cotemporaneous control variables.

We discuss them in the next section.

2.2.4 Control Variables

Carr and Wu (2009) show that part of the variation in the variance risk premium are

related to market index returns. To control for the variation in variance risk premium

induced by contemporaneous changes in market conditions, we calculate the log-returns of

the S&P 500 index and denote this variable S&P500LogRett.

Eglo¤, Leippold, and Wu (2010), Todorov (2010), and Aït-Sahalia, Karaman, and

Mancini (2014) among others study the impact of jumps on the variance risk premium. We

follow Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2014) and construct an aggregate jump factor.

Page 89: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

79

On each day, we calculate the returns on two zero-beta at-the-money SPX straddles of

maturities T1 and T2 with T1 < T2. We denote by rS1t and rS2t the returns on the two

straddles.10 These daily returns are then combined such that

JumpFactort � rS1t ��V egaS1tV egaS2t

�� rS2t ; (2.9)

where V egaS1t and V egaS2t denote the vega of each straddle. By construction JumpFactort

has zero delta, zero vega, and positive gamma, and thus captures the large �uctuations in

the S&P500 index.11

Bollen and Whaley (2004) document the e¤ect of net buying pressures on options

implied-volatility. Through their impact on implied-volatility, net buying pressures po-

tentially in�uence the variance risk premium. To disentangle the e¤ect of inventory risk

relative to net buying pressures on the variance risk premium, we calculate on each day

Bollen and Whaley�s net buying pressure variable

NetByingPressuret �Pj

�BOjt � SO

jt

��

abs��jt

�SPXV olumet

; (2.10)

where SPXV olumet is the aggregate volume of SPX options, and abs(:) denotes the ab-

solute value.

Buraschi, Trojani, and Vedolin (2014) establish that investors�disagreement in�uence

the variance risk premium. To construct a daily measure of investors�disagreement, we rely

on S&P500 index volume data to compute unexpected changes in index trading volume.

More precisely, for every day we calculate the di¤erence between S&P 500 index volume

on that day, and the average volume of the last 90 trading days. We denote this variable

Disagreementt.

10When constructing the �rst straddle, we choose T1 to be in the month following the current month,and at least �fteen days to maturity. Similarly, T2 is chosen to be in the month following T1.11The gamma of an option is the second derivative of the option price with respect to the underlying

asset price.

Page 90: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

80

2.2.5 Results

Table 3 presents the results obtained from regressing the changes in the one-month log-

variance risk premium against the previous day�s inventory risk, the interaction of lagged

inventory risk with changes in market-makers�wealth, and the control variables. We report

the results for the full sample in regressions (1) and (2). To investigate the extent to

which the �nancial crisis drives the results obtained, we divide the sample in two sub-

samples of similar length, 1997-2004 and 2005-2011. To facilitate the interpretation of

the results, regressors are standardized to have unit variance. For each parameter, the

p-value is computed using Newey-West p-value with 8 lags to capture autocorrelation in

the residuals.

Regressions (2), (4), and (6) in Table 3 establish the importance of inventory risk

and market-maker wealth for explaining the variance risk premium. Both variables are

statistically signi�cant with their expected sign. For the two subsamples, their inclusion

results in a 9% increase in adjusted R-Squared relative to regressions (3) and (5).

Interestingly, it is for the sample period including the �nancial crisis that the impact of

inventory risk is the greatest. A one standard deviation decrease in inventory risk causes

a 1:2% decrease in the variance risk premium. When inventory risk equals its sample

average, a one standard deviation decrease in market-maker wealth is associated with a

4:47% decrease in the variance risk premium. The e¤ect of inventory is magni�ed when

market-makers experience dramatic losses. Conditioning on a market-makers� loss in its

90th percentile, a one standard deviation decrease in inventory risk results in a 9% decrease

in next day�s log-variance risk premium.12

The relation between S&P 500 log-returns and the variance risk premium is strongly

signi�cant. The variance risk premium tends to decrease when index returns decrease. In

regressions (1), (3), and (5) in Table 3, S&P 500 log-returns and lagged changes in variance

12The results documented in this section are robust and quantitatively similar when RV (t; T ) is set tothe one-step-ahead forecast of a time-series model in the spirit of Corsi (2009).

Page 91: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

81

risk premium jointly account for 80% of the R-Squared documented.13

Note the way aggregate jumps are negatively related to changes in variance risk pre-

mium. By construction, the returns of the jump factor are high whenever the S&P 500

abruptly decreases. Thus, the negative loading found for the jump factor is consistent with

Todorov (2010), who shows that negative jumps result in a more negative variance risk

premium.

Bollen and Whaley (2004) demonstrate that net buying pressures increase implied

volatility. Through their e¤ect on implied volatility, high buying pressures should result in

a lower variance risk premium. From Table 3, we see that net buying pressure is negatively

related to the variance risk premium. However, the variable is only signi�cant in regression

(5).

Consistent with Buraschi, Trojani, and Vedolin (2014), the loadings estimated for dis-

agreement are consistently negative. When investors�disagreement increases, the di¤erence

between realized and implied volatility tends to become more negative.

In Table 4, we presents the full sample results obtained when the variance risk premium

is constructed for various horizons. This exercise allows us to quantify the impact each

variable has on the term structure of variance risk premia. In addition to the one-month

horizon, we focus on four additional horizons of 60, 90, 180, and 270 days respectively.

Table 4:A reports the result obtained for the log-variance risk premium. Several inter-

esting �ndings emerge. Note that the e¤ect of inventory risk and �uctuations in market-

makers wealth are robust across horizons. Interestingly, there is a term structure of the

coe¢ cients estimated. For most variables, the magnitude of their in�uence on the variance

risk premium decreases as the horizon increases. Accordingly, the e¤ect of inventory risk

and market-makers wealth is most prominent for short-term variance risk premia. For hori-

zons of at least sixty days, the two variables appear to have the second greatest economic

impact after the index returns, and before aggregate jumps.

13Bivariate regressions of changes in log-variance risk premium on index log-returns and lagged changeshave an adjusted R-Squared of 30% on average for the full sample and subsample tests.

Page 92: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

82

In Table 4:B, we present the result obtained when the variance risk premium is mea-

sured as RV (t; T ) � RNV (t; T ). We see that the e¤ect of inventory risk and �uctuations

in market-makers wealth remain robust. Relative to inventory risk and market-makers�

wealth, the impact of jumps vanishes for the nine-month horizon. This result relates to

Aït-Sahalia, Karaman, and Mancini (2014), who conclude that investors�fear of a market

crash is captured in short-term variance risk premia.

2.2.6 The Financial Crisis

Typically, the index option market functions similarly to an insurance market. A clientele

of institutional investors predominantly buys SPX options, which causes market-makers�

inventory risk to be negative on average. On November 20, 2008, the VIX Index reached a

high of 80:86%. Around the same time, end-users are heavily shorting SPX options. These

large net sell orders resulted in an increase in inventory risk of more than 1:8 billion dollars

during the month of November. By November 20, CBOE market-makers carried more than

2:5 billion dollars positive exposure to market volatility. This risk exposure represents 8%

of the capitalization of SPX options at that time.

To understand the risk and reward incurred from being positively exposed to market

volatility during the �nancial crisis, Table 5 presents the return statistics of delta-hedged

near-the-money options. Because these options are close to the money, they are highly

sensitive to market variance. For comparison purposes, we report the statistics for the full

sample and the �nancial crisis separately.

While losing most of the time, the delta-hedged positions earn 6:26%monthly during the

crisis period. Thus, around the same time market-makers�exposure to market variance is

positive, long positions in near-the-money options are pro�table on average. Note however

the tremendous risk exposure from these options. During the �nancial crisis, the volatility

of daily returns peaks at 95%, and its excess kurtosis is about 11. This result further

stresses the critical role of SPX market-makers in undertaking large risk to allow end-users

to hedge against and speculate on market volatility.

Page 93: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

83

Overall, the evidences presented so far are consistent with the idea that part of the

variance risk premium captures CBOE market-makers� compensation for their exposure

to market variance. Motivated by these �ndings, we now develop a theoretical model in

which the physical market variance is dynamic and a risk-averse representative market-

maker endogenously quotes index options, and thus in�uences the variance risk premium.

2.3 The Model

The economy is cast in a continuous time framework in which the underlying source of

uncertainty is driven by two independent Brownian motions ZS and ZV .14 Market par-

ticipants have a �nite investment horizon T , and can invest in the market index St, which

evolves according to

dStSt

= �dt+pVt

�q1� �2V dZ

St + �V dZ

Vt

�; S0 known, (2.11)

where � is the market premium and Vt is the market variance which follows a CEV dynamic

dVt = �(� � Vt)dt+ �V �t dZVt ; V0 known, (2.12)

where � denotes the unconditional variance, � is the speed of mean reversion, � is the

volatility of volatility, and � determines the variance elasticity.15 In (2.11), �V captures

the correlation between market return and market variance innovations. In addition to the

market index, market participants can invest in a risk-free bond

dBtBt

= rdt; B0 = 1; (2.13)

14The information available to agents consists of the trajectories generated by the two Brownian motions(Brownian �ltration F). The underlying probability space is (;F ; P ), P being the physical probabilitymeasure.15Equation (2.12) nests many stochastic volatility models. For instance, Heston (1993) is obtained when

� = 1=2, and Jones (2003) discusses the model for � > 1.

Page 94: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

84

with constant interest rate r. The economy is endowed with a stochastic discount factor

(SDF) which is the pricing tool used to discount state contingent cash �ows. This SDF

followsd�t�t= �rdt� �St dZSt � �Vt dZVt ; �0 = 1; (2.14)

where �St and �Vt are the market prices of risks. As in the portfolio literature (see Detemple,

Garcia, and Rinsdisbacher, 2003 and 2005, Detemple and Rinsdisbacher, 2010, and Elkamhi

and Stefanova, 2011), the form of the SDF is exogenously given in the model. However,

both �St and �Vt are to be determined.

The investment opportunity set is further composed of European index calls and puts

denoted f jt where j identi�es a particular option. In the option market, two types of agents

interact. End-users have an exogenous need to get exposure to index options. We denote by

�EU;jt end-users�net demand for option j. To meet this demand, a representative market-

maker provides liquidity for index options. The next proposition presents the pricing rule

used by the market-maker to quote each option.

Proposition 5 Given (2.11), (2.12), and (2.14) applying Ito�s lemma to f jt and imposing

the no-arbitrage condition �tfjt = EPt [�T f

jT ] implies the following dynamic for the price of

option j under the P-measure

df jt = d�Repjt + #jt � dF Vt (2.15)

= d�Repjt + #jt ��V RPtdt+ �V

�t dZ

Vt

�; (2.16)

where �Repjt corresponds to the delta replication of fjt , #

jt � V egajt=

�2pVt�is the sensi-

tivity of option j to the market variance risk factor F Vt , V RPt � EPt [Vt+dt]�EQt [Vt+dt] is

the (instantaneous) variance risk premium, and �V �t dZVt is the aggregate variance risk.

Proof. See Appendix A.

Under the Black and Scholes (1973) assumptions, index options can be perfectly repli-

cated by holding the appropriate amount of the market index and the risk-free bond. When

Page 95: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

85

the market variance is stochastic, perfect replication is no longer achievable through the

trading of St and Bt only. As a result, the price dynamic of index options can be decom-

posed into two components. As in Black and Scholes (1973), the �rst component, denoted

d�Repjt , corresponds to the delta replication of fjt . In addition to d�Rep

jt , the entire

cross-section of index options is a¤ected by the market variance risk factor.

When �MM;jt denotes the market-maker�s inventory of option j, the market clearing

condition for index options is

�MM;jt +�EU;jt = 0 for all j: (2.17)

Equation (2.17) has an interesting implication. Whenever end-users�exposure to market

volatility,Pj �

EU;jt V egajt , does not cancel out across index options, then neither does

market-maker�s inventory risk (i.e.Pj �

MM;jt V egajt ). Consequently, the representative

market-maker will be non-trivially exposed to the market variance risk factor. In this

context, the variance risk premium can be interpreted as the market-maker�s compensation

for absorbing unhegeable variance risk.

As apparent in Figure 2, the time-series of inventory risk shares features with volatility

(i.e. clustering, autocorrelation, and reversal). To capture the �uctuations in the market-

maker�s variance risk exposure, we model inventory risk exogenously and adopt a mean-

reverting process in the spirit of stock volatility models

dInvRiskt = �(��InvRiskt)dt+ Vtdt+�InvRiskt�q

1� �2InvdZSt + �InvdZ

Vt

�; (2.18)

where InvRiskt =Pj �

MM;jt V egajt as in (2.5), � is the speed of mean reversion, � in�u-

ences the level of inventory risk, de�nes the loading on market variance, and � is the

volatility parameter. In previous equation, �Inv is the correlation of inventory risk with

the market variance risk factor.

We determine the variance risk premium through the maximization of the market-

maker�s expected utility of terminal wealth. For a given admissible investment strategy

Page 96: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

86

~�t ���Bt ; �

St ; f�

f;jt g�, the market-maker�s self-�nanced wealth dynamic is

dWt

Wt= �Bt �

dBtBt

+ �St �dStSt

+Pj�f;jt � df

jt

f jt; with W0 = w, (2.19)

where each � is expressed in percentage of wealth, and w denotes his initial endowment.

The problem faced by the market-maker can be written as

max~�

EP [U(WT )] subject to � (2.17) and (2.18)

� (2.19) with Wt > 0: t 2 [0; T ];(2.20)

where U(:) is the market-maker�s utility function. In the model, the representative market-

maker determines his trading strategy given prices. Our goal is to invert this mapping and

infer the variance risk premium in (2.16) that induces the market-maker to clear the index

option market.

2.4 Model Implications

2.4.1 The Structure of the Variance Risk Premium

To understand the way the variance risk premium depends on inventory risk and the

market-maker�s wealth, the following proposition is needed.

Proposition 6 At time t 2 [0; T ], when the market-maker is myopic with U(Wt) = ln(Wt),

the variance risk premium is given by

V RPt = �V �V�t (Sharpet) + 0:5(1� �2V )�2V

2��0:5t

�InvRiskt

Wt

�; (2.21)

where Sharpet � ��rpVtis the market Sharpe ratio, InvRiskt = �

Pj �

EU;jt V egajt captures

the sensitivity of the market-maker�s inventory to the variance risk factor F Vt de�ned in

Proposition 1, and Wt is market-maker wealth.

Proof. See Appendix B.

Page 97: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

87

This proposition provides several insights. The decomposition in (2.21) separates the

variance risk premium into two components. The �rst term is a function of the market

Sharpe ratio. Innovations in market variance are correlated with index returns. Conse-

quently, the variance risk premium inherits of the market Sharpe ratio. The greater the

abs(�V ) the higher the dependence of the variance risk premium on Sharpet is. Index

returns are in�uenced by the realisations of the market Sharpe ratio. Therefore, equa-

tion (2.21) helps understand the strong statistical signi�cance found when regressing the

changes in variance risk premium measures on S&P 500 log-returns.

Whenever abs(�V ) < 1, index options cannot be perfectly hedged through the trad-

ing of St and Bt. Consequently, the market is incomplete from the market-maker�s per-

spective. In this case, the market-maker requires an additional compensation relative to

�V �V�t (Sharpet). This additional premium is proportional to the ratio of inventory risk to

wealth. Since (1 � �2V )�2V 2��0:5t > 0 and Wt > 0, the variance risk premium is positively

in�uenced by inventory risk. The more negative is the exposure of market-maker to market

variance, the lower the variance risk premium will be. Consequently, the model captures

the positive sign of the coe¢ cient obtained when regressing the changes in variance risk

premium against market-makers�exposure to market variance.

Several studies have shown that the premium for market variance risk is negative on

average (see, among others, Bakshi and Kapadia, 2003, Vilkov, 2008, and Carr and Wu,

2009). Given (2.21), the variance risk premium is negative whenever

InvRisktWt

<��V (Sharpet)

0:5(1� �2V )�V��0:5t

: (2.22)

For the empirically relevant case �V < 0 and Sharpet > 0, a su¢ cient condition for

the variance risk premium to be negative is a negative inventory risk. Since SPX option

market-makers typically have a negative exposure to market variance, the model o¤ers an

interesting channel for explaining the negative variance risk premium found in previous

studies.

Page 98: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

88

As apparent in the middle and bottom panels of Figure 1, the variance risk premium is

sporadically positive. When inequality (2.22) is not satis�ed, and �V < 0 and Sharpet > 0,

a positive inventory risk exposure results in a positive variance risk premium. Hence, the

model can also explain a positive variance risk premium at times when option market-

makers are positively exposed to market variance.

Finally, note that a positive inventory risk will not result in a positive variance risk

premium as long as (2.22) is satis�ed.

2.4.2 Market-Maker Optimal Wealth

In Proposition 2, inventory risk is normalized by the market-maker�s wealth. Consequently,

inventory risk will matter the most when the market-maker is poor (i.e. for low values of

Wt). In contrast, the e¤ect of inventory risk on the variance risk premium vanishes when

the market-maker wealth goes to in�nity. This result justi�es the strong signi�cance found

in all the empirical tests for the interaction of inventory risk with changes in market-makers�

wealth.

In the model, market-maker�s wealth is endogenous and satis�es

Wt = 1= ( �t) ; (2.23)

when U(Wt) = ln(Wt). Since the market-maker�s marginal utility is strictly increasing,

is uniquely de�ned by the static budget constraintW0 = EP [�TWT ] = 1= )Wt =W0=�t.

Consequently, at any point of time, the market-maker�s wealth is proportionally related to

the ratio of his initial endowment W0 to the SDF. Given (2.14), we can apply Ito�s lemma

to Wt to obtain the dynamic of the market-maker�s optimal wealth

dWt =�r +

��St�2+��Vt�2�

Wtdt+ �StWtdZ

St + �

Vt WtdZ

Vt . (2.24)

Page 99: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

89

2.4.3 Risk-Neutral Dynamics

The model has implications for pricing. To discount the option payo¤ at maturity using

the risk-free rate, all underlying processes must be risk-neutralized.

Proposition 7 When the SDF follows (2.14), the risk-neutral processes driving the dy-

namic of the economy are

dSt = rStdt+pVtSt

�q1� �2V d ~Z

St + �V d ~Z

Vt

�(2.25)

dVt = �(� � Vt)dt� V RPtdt+ �V �t d ~ZVt (2.26)

dInvRiskt = �(�� InvRiskt)dt+ Vtdt+ �InvRiskt�q

1� �2Invd ~ZSt + �Invd

~ZVt

���InvRiskt

�q1� �2Inv�

St + �Inv�

Vt

�dt (2.27)

dWt = rWtdt+ �StWtd ~Z

St + �

Vt Wtd ~Z

Vt : (2.28)

where ~ZSt and ~ZVt are risk-neutral, �St = Sharpet=

q1� �2V � �V �

Vt =q1� �2V is obtained

by imposing the index no-arbitrage condition, �Vt = V RPt= (�V�t ), and V RPt satis�es

Proposition 2.

Proof. The Girsanov theorem implies that dZSt = d ~ZSt � �St dt and dZVt = d ~ZVt � �Vt dt.

Using this result in (2.11), (2.12), (2.18), and (2.24) delivers the risk-neutral processes.

The result in Proposition 3 can be used for pricing. When end-users�demand for SPX

options increases, it decreases inventory risk. A decrease in inventory risk implies a more

negative variance risk premium on average. From (2.26), we see that changes in the risk-

neutral market variance are negatively in�uenced by the variance risk premium. Thus,

an increase in end-users�demand will result in a higher risk-neutral variance. This model

prediction can be related to Bollen and Whaley (2004) who document that changes in the

implied volatility of SPX OTM puts are positively in�uenced by end-users� net buying

pressure. However, our model suggests that only the variance exposure of market-maker�s

total risk exposure should impact changes in risk-neutral volatility.

Page 100: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

90

Overall, the predictions delivered by the model are in line with the empirical �ndings

documented. In the next section, we estimate the model and assess the role of inventory

risk and market-maker wealth for the valuation of SPX options.

2.5 Estimation and Fit

In this section, we �rst describe our estimation methodology. Subsequently, we report

on parameter estimates and model �t. Finally we relate the estimated parameters to the

economic impact of inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth on index option prices.

2.5.1 Estimation Methodology

Several approaches have been proposed in the literature for estimating stochastic volatil-

ity models. Aït-Sahalia and Kimmel (2007) and Jones (2003) estimate volatility model

parameters using bivariate time-series of returns and at-the-money implied volatility. Pan

(2002) uses GMM to estimate the objective and risk-neutral from returns and option prices.

Christo¤ersen, Jacobs, and Mimouni (2010) adopt a particle �ltering approach to estimate

various alternatives to Heston (1993) based on returns and a large panel of option prices

combined.

For estimating the model, we adopt a two steps procedure. In a �rst step, we �lter the

physical parameters describing (2.12), along with the spot variances Vt. Taking the �ltered

spot variances and the objective variance parameters as given, we estimate the dynamic

of inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth using a large panel of SPX put prices. Both

InvRiskt, and Wt are latent variables in the model. However, to avoid over�tting the data

we constrain InvRiskt to be equal to its empirical value (2.5). In addition, we �x the

market-maker�s wealth to W0 = w at the beginning of every day. Based on these initial

values and on the �ltered Vt, we exploit the results in Proposition 2 and 3 to simulate the

economy forward and infer the dynamics (2.27) and (2.28) consistent with observed index

option prices.

For estimation purposes, we set the time-step �t to 1=365 and the expected return �

Page 101: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

91

to its sample average 1T�1

TPt=2(St � St�1) =St�1 � 365, where T denotes the last day in the

sample.

We now describe each step in more details.

Step 1: Filtering the Variance Dynamic Using S&P 500 Returns

We need to estimate the structural parameters �V � f�; �; �; �V ; �g in (2.12) along with the

vector of spot variances fVtgt=1;2;:::;T . To this end, we adopt the particle �ltering algorithm

(PF henceforth). The PF o¤ers a convenient way to estimate stochastic volatility models.

It has recently been applied in Johannes, Polson, and Stroud (2009), Christo¤ersen, Jacobs,

and Mimouni (2010), and Malik and Pitt (2011) among others.

LetnV jt

oNj=1

denotes the smooth resampled particles where N de�nes the number of

particles which is set to 10; 000. Using the algorithm described in Appendix C, we estimate

on each day the likelihood of observing St+1 given Vjt and St, and denote it ~P

jt

�V jt ;�

V�.

Based on the likelihood of each particle calculated on each day, the MLIS criterion applied

to estimate �V is

�V = argmax

TXt=1

Lt; (2.29)

where Lt � ln

1N

NPj=1

~P jt

�V jt ;�

V�!

is the model daily log-likelihood. On day t, the

�ltered spot variance is obtained by averaging the smooth particles

Vt =1

N

NXj=1

V jt : (2.30)

Next, we discuss the estimation of inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth based on SPX

options.

Step 2: Estimating Inventory Risk and Market-Maker�s Wealth

The model does not allow for closed-form solution for option prices. Consequently, we

rely on Monte-Carlo methods for estimating the inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth

Page 102: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

92

dynamic embedded in SPX options. Taking �V andnVt; InvRiskt

ot=1;2;:::;T

as given where

InvRiskt corresponds to (2.5), we estimate �Inv � f�; �; ; �; �Invg and w by minimizing

the sum of implied volatility squared errors (SIVSE)

n�Inv; w

o= argmin

NJXj;t

�IVj;t � IVMj;t

��Inv; w; �V ; Vt; InvRiskt

��2; (2.31)

where NJ is the total number of observations, IVj;t is the option j implied volatility on

day t, and IVMj;t is the model implied volatility. We use Black-Scholes to calculate implied

volatilities for both market and model prices. When calculating model prices, we follow

the algorithm described in Appendix D using 10; 000 Monte-Carlo paths.

2.5.2 Parameter Estimates

In Panel A of Table 6, we present descriptive statistics on the daily S&P 500 returns.

In-sample, the average market return is 5:86%. This low average return estimate is partly

in�uenced by the abrupt drop in the S&P 500 index during the crisis period (see Figure 1).

During the 1997-2011 period, the sample variance is 4:58% annually, which corresponds to

a 21% average volatility.

In Panel B, we report the estimated parameters for the CEV dynamic (2.12). The

sample MLIS is 11; 746. The estimated � is close to the sample variance in Panel A.

Moreover, �V is large and negative. In the model, a large and negative �V is important to

generate enough negative skewness in the S&P 500 return distribution. The estimate for

the CEV elasticity parameter is 90%. A high volatility of volatility generates additional

variance in the return process. Thus, the estimated � arguably captures the fat tails of

S&P 500 returns distribution. Finally, note how the index data require a slow variance

mean-reversion speed. The coe¢ cient of 2:91 corresponds to a daily variance persistence

of 1� �=365 = 0:9920.

For comparison purposes, we also report in Panel C the parameters obtained for the

Heston model for which � = 1=2. The model MLIS is lower than the likelihood obtained

Page 103: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

93

by the CEV dynamic. The two models require di¤erent structural parameters to explain

the data. For instance, note the di¤erences of mean reversion speed and unconditional

variance between the two models. The Heston dynamic requires a higher speed reversion

but has a lower long-term variance. Moreover, the two models also require substantially

di¤erent volatility of volatility parameters. However, it should be noted that the di¤erence

in � between the two models in�uences the magnitude of the other parameter estimates.

In Figure 4, we plot the time-series of �ltered spot volatilitiespVt annualized and

expressed in percentage for both models. As expected, the time-series of objective spot

volatilities share common features with the VIX Index in Figure 2.

When calibrating inventory risk and market-maker wealth, we rely on OptionMetrics�

volatility surface data. In order to speed up estimation, we restrict attention to puts

observed on the �rst Wednesday of each month with moneyness between 0:9 and 1:1,

and with 2, 3, and 6 months to maturity. The �nal option sample consists of 6; 292 put

observations during the 1997-2011 sample period.

In Panel A of Table 7, we report the estimated coe¢ cients for �Inv obtained from

minimizing the sum of squared errors (2.5). The daily inventory persistence is 1��=365 =

0:9706, which is slightly less than the persistence of market variance. A high mean reversion

speed is necessary to explain the abrupt reversal of inventory risk observed during the

crisis period in the bottom panel of Figure 2. Moreover, we saw that inventory risk is

negative most of the time. This stylized fact is captured by � estimated to be large

and negative. Note however, that the unconditional expectation of inventory risk is also

in�uenced by . Interestingly, the loading of inventory risk on lagged spot variance is

positive. Thus, inventory risk tends to increase with market uncertainty. In-sample, the

volatility parameter for inventory risk is 16:55%. Note that the correlation of inventory

risk with market variance is close to zero. While the changes in inventory risk depend

positively on the level of market variance through , inventory risk is nearly independent

of contemporaneous innovations in variance.

Interestingly, the estimated wealth level is about 440 million dollars. Since w captures

Page 104: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

94

the dealer�s initial wealth, the parameter estimated is comparable in magnitude to the

daily delta-hedged pro�ts and losses documented in Figure 3. Quantitatively, it represents

approximately 4 years of cumulative daily pro�t and losses. Finally, the model�s sum of

squared errors is about 6:40 at the optimum.

To benchmark the model performance, we �t Heston (1993) on option prices using a

similar methodology but for which we set the instantaneous V RPt = h � Vt, where h is a

constant to be estimated. This speci�cation for the variance risk premium is consistent

with Heston (1993), Bates (2000), and Pan (2002) among others. From Panel B, we see

that the variance risk premium parameter is �1:08. Note however that the �t obtained by

the Heston model is not as good as the �t of the inventory risk model. During our sample,

Heston�s sum of squared implied volatility errors is about 20% greater than the inventory

model.

2.5.3 Index Option Fit

To measure the performance of the model, we compute the percentage implied volatility

RMSE de�ned as

IV RMSE �

vuut 1

NJ

NJXj;t

�IVj;t � IVMj;t

�2� 100; (2.32)

where IVMj;t is the model implied volatility. We compute the performance criterion for

both models using all puts options with moneyness between 0:9 and 1:1, and with 2, 3,

and 6 months to maturity. The sample used to evaluate each model performance consists

of 131; 838 observations.

Table 8 presents the �t obtained for the inventory risk model and Heston. We report

the IVRMSE for all contracts for each year in Panel A, as well as separate results for in-,

at-, and out-of-the-money puts in Panel B. Several interesting �ndings emerge.

First, the average yearly IVRMSE for the inventory risk model is 3:14%, which is good

given that the sample includes the �nancial crisis. The �t of each model are close; however,

Page 105: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

95

the inventory model dominates the Heston model particularly in the second part of the

sample period. Relative to the inventory model, Heston�s best pricing performance is

obtained in 1999 with a IVRMSE di¤erence between the two model of 0:48%. In contrast,

the inventory risk model achieves its best �t relative to the Heston model in 2009 with an

IVRMSE lower by 1:95%. Since 2003, the IVRMSE of the inventory model is lower than

Heston by more than 0:90%.

Second, the inventory model achieves a better �t for ATM puts relative to the Heston

model. ATM options are the most sensitive to change in variance risk premium. Thus, this

result potentially uncovers the inability of the Heston model combined with the speci�cation

V RPt = h�Vt to adequatly captures the variations in the variance risk premium. To further

assess this, we regress the daily implied volatility root mean squared errors against the

empirical proxy of one-month variance risk premium, and the daily log-likelihood Lt of the

physical returns. For the inventory risk model, we obtain

IV RMSEt = 3:142(0:000)

+ 0:021(0:901)

� V RP (t; 30)� 0:266(0:006)

� Lt + "t; (2.33)

where the regressors are standardized, and the Newey-West p-values reported under each

parameters are calculated with 8 lags. The adjusted R-Squared of the regression is 1:77%.

Arguably, the mispricing of the inventory risk model is not related to the realization of

the variance risk premium. We see however that part of its IVRMSE is correlated with

its log-likelihood. When the likelihood decreases the pricing error of the model tends to

increase. For Heston (1993), we have

IV RMSEt = 3:562(0:000)

� 0:813(0:000)

� V RP (t; 30)� 0:022(0:752)

� Lt + "t; (2.34)

with an adjusted R-Squared of 17:93%. The result is striking. In contrast to the inventory

risk model, a large part of the pricing errors of the Heston model can be attributed by its

inability to fully capture the �uctuations in the variance risk premium.

Third, from Panel B in Table 8 we see that the inventory risk model �ts OTM puts

Page 106: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

96

better than Heston. Stochastic volatility models often have more di¢ culties in capturing

the implied volatility patterns of OTM option. Thus, the ability of the inventory model

to better price OTM options is particularly interesting. This result is partly due to the

non-linearities in the joint dynamic of risk-neutral variance, inventory risk, and market-

maker wealth. When volatility is high, the ratio of inventory risk to wealth tends to be

large and negative. This causes the variance risk premium to be large and negative, which

in turn implies an increase in risk-neutral volatility and a more negative ratio of inventory

risk to wealth through its feedback e¤ects on the risk-neutral dynamics (2.27) and (2.28).

A higher risk-neutral volatility during bad times increases the negative skewness in the

risk-neutral index returns distribution, which substantially improves the pricing of OTM

puts.

In Figure 5, we plot the daily one-month variance risk premium and IVRMSE for each

model. From Panel A, we see that the inventory risk model can deliver a wide range

of variance risk premium. In comparison, the one-month variance risk premium implied

by the Heston model is always negative. The ability of the inventory model to generate

substantial variation in the variance risk premium drives its performance.

The results suggest that accounting for inventory risk and market-maker wealth is

important to capture variation in the variance risk premium and thus explain index option

prices.

In the next section, we quantify the economic magnitude of the response of SPX option

prices to changes in inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth.

2.5.4 Economic Magnitude

Little is known about the way market-makers adjust their quotes when they absorb large

buy orders, which cause their exposure to market variance to become more negative (i.e.

decrease their inventory risk). Similarly, the magnitude of the impact of market-makers�

losses and gains on index option prices is also an open question.

To understand the way inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth in�uence market-

Page 107: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

97

makers�quotation behaviour, in Figure 6 we plot the dollar sensitivity of SPX put options

to a decrease in the state variables implied by the model. To calculate the model sensitivies

@Pt=@InvRiskt and @Pt=@Wt, we use the estimated parameters �V , �Inv, and w, and set

r = 4%, St = 1183 , and Vt = �: Moreover, inventory risk is set to its unconditional

mean InvRiskt = �9:03E + 09, and market-maker wealth is initialized to Wt = w. Based

on the sensitivities calculated, we then compute the dollar response of each option as

�InvRiskt � @Pt=@InvRiskt and �Wt � @Pt=@Wt, and plot the result across moneyness.

In both panels, each line corresponds to di¤erent level of decrease in inventory risk and

wealth. The circles correspond to the dollar response to an average decrease in the state

variables. The diamonds identify the response when the decrease of each latent variable is

within its 90th percentile decrease.

Figure 6 provides several insights. First, we see that a decrease in inventory risk results

in an increase in index option prices. This is consistent with the theoretical predictions in

Proposition 2. When market-makers�risk exposure decreases, they require a more negative

variance risk premium which translates into an increase in index option prices. Similarly,

market-makers� losses result in an increase in the price of index options. Interestingly,

market-maker�s wealth has the biggest impact on option prices.

Note also that the e¤ect of inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth on SPX options

across strike prices is non-linear, and is most prominent for at-the-money options. In-

terestingly, it is these options that make up most of market-makers�inventory (see Table

2).

When all variables are set to their mean values, the average decrease in inventory risk

and the average wealth loss cause between a 10 and 50 dollars increase in price. Given an

average option price of 6; 500 dollars, these e¤ects correspond to a 0:15% and 0:77% daily

increase in price. This result echoes the �ndings of Murayev (2013) who shows that the

average trade for equity option has inventory risk impact of 0:4%. Note however that this

study is the �rst to document and quantify the impact of option market-makers�wealth

on index option prices.

Page 108: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

98

During turbulent times, when market-makers� aggregate loss is within its 90th per-

centile decrease, it causes a 150 dollars increase in price, which corresponds to a 2:31%

daily increase. These results further highlight the non-trivial role of market-makers in the

determination of index option prices through their e¤ect on the variance risk premium.

2.6 Summary and Conclusions

Using aggregate market-makers�positions at the CBOE, we examine how inventory risk and

market-makers�wealth jointly determine the value of index options through their e¤ects

on the variance risk premium. The analysis demonstrates that part of the variance risk

premium corresponds to option market-makers�compensation for their exposure to market

variance. We �nd that inventory exposure to market variance and changes in market-

makers�wealth explain the variance risk premium. Using daily observations, we �nd that

a one standard deviation decrease in inventory risk causes a 1:2% decrease in the variance

risk premium next period. In addition, the interaction of lagged inventory risk with changes

in market-maker wealth is also strongly signi�cant.

Based on these �ndings, we then develop a model in which market variance is stochastic

and a representative market-maker accumulates inventory over time by absorbing end-

users�net demand for index options. Starting from the market-maker�s optimal trading

strategy, we derive an explicit formula linking the variance risk premium to inventory

risk and market-maker wealth. The model predictions provides several insights that help

understand empirical stylized facts.

Finally, we estimate the model on S&P 500 returns and options. Overall, the model

performs well. Our results suggest that accounting for inventory risk and market-maker�s

wealth in pricing models can help for index option valuation. Based on the estimated

parameters, we �nd that the e¤ect of inventory risk and market-maker�s wealth on SPX

options across strike prices is non-linear, and is most prominent for at-the-money options.

Several issues are left for future research. First, it would be interesting to develop

and test the implications of various inventory risk dynamics for option pricing. Second,

Page 109: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

99

it would be interesting to extend the model by allowing for jumps in the market price.

Finally, investigating the pricing implications inventory risk and market-makers�wealth

have for other derivative markets would also be of signi�cant interest.

Appendix

This appendix collects the proofs of the propositions and presents the algorithms used for

estimating the model.

A. Proof of Proposition 1

For ease of notation, we de�ne at � EPt [dVt]=dt, bt � �V �t , �jt � @f jt =@St (i.e. the

delta of option j), �jt � @�jt=@St (i.e. the gamma of option j), and #jt � @f jt =@Vt (i.e.

the sensitivity of option j to market variance). Applying Ito�s lemma to f j implies the

following dynamic under the P -measure

df jt =�@fjt@t +�

jtSt�+ #

jtat +

@�jt@Vt

�VpVtStbt +

12

��jtVtS

2t +

@#jt@Vt

b2t

��dt

+�jtStpVt

�q1� �2V dZSt + �V dZVt

�+ #jtbtdZ

Vt :

(2.35)

Given (2.14) and the no-arbitrage condition �tfjt = EPt [�T f

jT ], we have

rf jt ��jtStr � #

jtaQt =

@f jt@t

+@�jt@Vt

�VpVtStbt +

1

2

�jtVtS

2t +

@#jt@Vt

b2t

!; (2.36)

where aQt � EQt [dVt]=dt. Combining (2.35) with (2.36), we obtain

df jt =�rf jt +�

jtSt(�� r) + #

jt

�at � aQt

��dt+�jtSt

pVt

�q1� �2V dZ

St + �V dZ

Vt

�(2.37)

+#jtbtdZVt :

Since the delta replication of f j satis�es �Repjt = �Bt Bt+�St St where �

B and �S denote the

units of bond and market index to hold. For replication strategy with rebalancing horizon

Page 110: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

100

dt, we have �St St = �jtSt and �

Bt Bt = f jt ��

jtSt. Consequently,

d�Repjt =�rf jt +�

jtSt(�� r)

�dt+�jtSt

pVt

�q1� �2V dZ

St + �V dZ

Vt

�, (2.38)

with �Repjt = f jt . Combining (2.37) and (2.38), and the de�nition of b, we get

df jt = d�Repjt + #jt ��V RPtdt+ �V

�t dZ

Vt

�(2.39)

= d�Repjt + #jt � dF Vt ; (2.40)

where V RPt � at � aQt = EPt [Vt+dt] � EQt [Vt+dt] is the (instantaneous) variance risk pre-

mium, and dF Vt = V RPtdt + �V �t dZVt is the market variance risk factor. We can now

re-express #jt in terms of sensitivity to volatility

#jt =@f jt@Vt

=@f jt@pVt

@pVt

@Vt=V egajt2pVt; (2.41)

which completes the proof.

B. Proof of Proposition 2

The strategy we adopt is as follows. First, we solve the market-maker�s (unconstrained)

portfolio allocation when the market clearing condition is not imposed. Based on the

investment strategy obtained, we then require it to satisfy the market clearing condition

to infer the structure of the variance risk premium.

The static maximization

max~�

EP [U(WT )] subject to � W0 > EP [�TWT ]

� Wt > 0;(2.42)

is the dual problem of the unconstrained utility maximization (2.20) (see, among others,

Karatzas, Lehoczky, and Shreve, 1987, and Cox, and Huang, 1989). To solve this, we form

Page 111: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

101

the lagrangian

L( ) = EP [U(WT )] + (w � EP [�TWT ])

= EP [U(WT )� �TWT ] + w; (2.43)

where is the lagrangian coe¢ cient associated to the static budget constraint W0 >

EP [�TWT ]. A point wise maximization of (2.43) implies the following optimality condition

Wt = Iu( �t); (2.44)

where Iu(:) represents the inverse function of market-maker�s marginal utility. When

@U(:) > 0, is uniquely de�ned by W0 = EP [�TWT ] = EP [�T Iu( �T )]: Using the re-

sult in Proposition 1, the fact that �f;jt Wt = �MM;jt f jt , and the de�nition of inventory risk,

we can re-write the wealth process (2.19) as

dWt

Wt= ��Bt �

dBtBt

+ ��St �dStSt

+InvRiskt

2pVtWt

� dF Vt ; (2.45)

where ��Bt = �Bt �Pj �

MM;jt

�f jt ��

jtSt

�=Wt and ��St = �St �

Pj �

MM;jt �jtSt=Wt. In this

economy, the discounted wealth process is

d (�tWt)

�tWt=dWt

Wt+d�t�t+d h�;W it�tWt

; (2.46)

where d h:; :it is the covariance operator. Applying the previous equation on the SDF

dynamic (2.14) and the wealth process (2.45), we obtain

d (�tWt)

�tWt=

���StpVt

q1� �2V � �

St

�dZSt +

���StpVt�V + 0:5�V

��0:5t

InvRisktWt

� �Vt�dZVt ;

(2.47)

for which we have imposed the no-arbitrage conditions

�tSt = EPt [�TST ], Sharpet =q1� �2V �

St + �V �

Vt (2.48)

Page 112: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

102

�tfjt = EPt [�T f

jT ], �f;jt � r = gjt�

St + h

jt�Vt ; (2.49)

where Sharpet ����rpVt

�is the market Sharpe ratio, and

�f;jt � EPt [dfjt =f

jt ]

gjt � �jt

�St=f

jt

�pVt

q1� �2V

hjt � �jt

�St=f

jt

�pVt�V + #

jt

��V �t =f

jt

�:

By application of the Clark-Ocone formula, for a FT�measurable random variable F , we

have

F = EP [F ] +TR0

EPt [DSt (F )]dZ

St +

TR0

EPt [DVt (F )]dZ

Vt ; (2.50)

where Dit (F ) is the time t Malliavin derivative of F with respect to Z

i.16 This representa-

tion of F is unique and can be exploited to obtain explicit formulas for ��S . Using (2.47),

we can express �TWT in its integral form

�TWT = w +TR0

�tWt

���StpVt

q1� �2V � �

St dZ

St

�(2.51)

+TR0

�tWt

���StpVt�V + 0:5�V

��0:5t

InvRisktWt

� �Vt dZVt�;

Setting F = �TWT in (2.50) combined with w = EP [�TWT ], the uniqueness of (2.50)

requires the integrands in (2.50) and (2.51) to be equal. De�ningAit � EPt [Dit(�TWT )]=�tWt

for i = S; V implies

��StpVt

q1� �2V = ASt + �

St (2.52)

��StpVt�V + 0:5�V

��0:5t

InvRisktWt

= AVt + �Vt ; (2.53)

which jointly de�ne the market-maker�s investment strategy. In (2.52) and (2.53), the mar-

ket clearing condition imposes �MM;jt = ��EU;jt for all j and InvRiskt = �

Pj �

EU;jt V egajt

16The variable F must be FT�measurable and must belong to the stochastic Sobolev space (i.e. F 2D1;2). We refer to Di Nunno, Økskendal, and Proske (2009) for a formal description of the D1;2 space.

Page 113: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

103

in aggregate. Solving for ��S in (2.52) and using the result in (2.53), we get

�AVt + �

Vt

��m

�ASt + �

St

�= 0:5�V ��0:5t

�InvRiskt

Wt

�; (2.54)

where m � �V =q1� �2V .17 By the properties of Malliavin derivatives, we have

Dit(�TWT ) = Di

t(Iu( �T ))�T +Dit(�T )WT = (@Iu( �T ) �T +WT )D

it(�T ):

The facts that @U(Iu(y)) = y and @U(WT ) = �T imply

@Iu( �T ) =1

@2U(WT )) @Iu( �T ) �T =

@U(WT )

@2U(WT )= ��T ; (2.55)

where � is the Arrow-Pratt measure of market-maker�s absolute risk tolerance. Therefore,

Dit(�TWT ) = (WT � �T )Di

t(�T ): (2.56)

Combining (2.56) and the de�nition of Ai, we get

Ait = �EPt [�t;T(WT � �T )

WtDit(�T )];

where �t;T � �T =�t. When U(x) = ln(x), we have

@U(WT ) =1

WTand @2U(WT ) = �

1

W 2T

;

which implies

�T =WT ) ASt = AVt = 0:

Using this into (2.54), we obtain

�Vt �m�St = 0:5�V��0:5t

�InvRiskt

Wt

�: (2.57)

We also know from (2.48) that the market price of risks �S and �V are linked through the

17Note that m is well-de�ned whenever abs(�) 6= 1.

Page 114: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

104

market index no-arbitrage condition which can be re-written as

�St = Sharpet=q1� �2V �m�

Vt : (2.58)

Combining (2.57) and (2.58), we can express the market price of variance risk as

�Vt = �V (Sharpet) + 0:5(1� �2V )�V��0:5t

�InvRiskt

Wt

�: (2.59)

Now, we can make use of the de�nition of the variance risk premium when the physical

volatility process is described by (2.12) and the SDF takes the form (2.14), which is

V RPt = (�V�t )�

Vt : (2.60)

Combining (2.59) with (2.60), we �nally get

V RPt = �V �V�t (Sharpet) + 0:5(1� �2V )�2V

2��0:5t

�InvRiskt

Wt

�; (2.61)

where Sharpet =���rpVt

�, and InvRiskt = �

Pj �

EU;jt V egajt .

C. Particle Filter Estimation

The following algorithm describes the way we evaluate the likelihood ~P jt

�V jt ;�

V�of ob-

serving St+1 given the smooth resampled particles Vjt , and the structural parameters �

V .

For estimation purposes, we set the number of particles denoted N to 10; 000.

Using the Euler discretization for dln(St) and (2.12), one can simulate the state of the

N raw particlesn~V jt

oNj=1

forward givennV jt�1

oNj=1

according to

ZV;jt =

0B@ ln�

StSt�1

����� V jt

2

��tq

V jt

�q1� �2V Z

S;jt

1CA =�V (2.62)

~V jt = V jt�1 + �(� � Vjt�1)�t+ �

�V jt�1

��ZV;jt ; (2.63)

where ZS;jt is N(0;p�t), and � is �xed to the sample average. Using the set of raw

Page 115: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

105

particles, the likelihood of observing St+1 given ~Vjt and St is

~P jt

�~V jt ;�

V�=

1q2� ~V jt

exp

0B@��ln�St+1St

�����

~V jt2

��t�2

2 ~V jt

1CA : (2.64)

Based on the set of normalized weights

�P jt

�~V jt ;�

V�=

~P jt

�~V jt ;�

V�

Pj

~P jt

�~V jt ;�

V� ; (2.65)

and the raw ~V jt , the method of Pitt (2002) can be applied to resample the smoothed

particlesnV jt

oNj=1

and evaluate their corresponding weights ~P jt�V jt ;�

V�.18

D. Risk-Neutral Pricing

Suppose that we want to price an index put option on day t with T days to maturity and

strike price K based on N = 10; 000 simulations. For each simulation n, we initiate the

state variables St, Vt, and InvRiskt to their respective values on the day of the pricing.

Moreover, we initialize the market-maker wealth to w. For a given path n, the forward

state of the discretized processes in Proposition 3 given the information on day t is

ln(Snt+1) = ln(Snt ) + (r � V nt =2)�t+

pV nt

�q1� �2V ~Z

S;nt + �V ~Z

V;nt

�(2.66)

V nt+1 = V nt + �(� � V nt )�t� V RPnt �t+ � (V nt )� ~ZV;nt (2.67)

InvRisknt+1 = InvRisknt + �(�� InvRisknt )�t+ V nt �t

+�InvRisknt

�q1� �2Inv ~Z

S;nt + �Inv ~Z

V;nt

���InvRisknt

�q1� �2Inv�

S;nt + �Inv�

V;nt

��t (2.68)

18The method proposed in Pitt (2002) involves smoothing the �P jt to a continuous CDF from which theset of smooth particle V j

t can be resampled.

Page 116: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

106

ln(Wnt+1) = ln(W

nt ) +

�r �

���S;nt

�2+��V;nt

�2�=2

��t+ �S;nt

~ZS;nt + �V;nt~ZV;nt ; (2.69)

where ~ZS;nt and ~ZV;nt are independent N(0;p�t). In the previous system, we set

V RPnt = �V � (Vnt )

� Sharpent + 0:5(1� �2V )�2 (V nt )2��0:5

�InvRisknt

Wnt

�; (2.70)

where Sharpent =���rpV nt

�. Moreover, the prices of risk are calculated according to

�S;nt = Sharpent =q1� �2V � �V �

V;nt =

q1� �2V and �V;nt = V RPnt = (� (V

nt )

�) : (2.71)

Simulating the system forward from day t to T , the price of the index put option on day t

is equal to

P��Inv; w;�V ; Vt; InvRiskt

�=

NXn=1

max (K � SnT ; 0) � exp(�r � (T � t) =365)N

; (2.72)

where �V and �Inv are the structural parameters of the market variance and inventory

risk processes respectively, and w is the market-maker�s wealth parameter.

Combining (2.59) with (2.60), we �nally get

V RPt = �V �V�t (Sharpet) + 0:5(1� �2V )�2V

2��0:5t

�InvRiskt

Wt

�; (2.73)

where Sharpet =���rpVt

�, and InvRiskt = �

Pj �

EU;jt V egajt .

Page 117: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

107

ReferencesAït-Sahalia, Y., Karaman, M., Mancini, L. (2013) The term structure of variance swaps

and risk premia, Working Paper, Princeton University.

Aït-Sahalia, Y., Kimmel, R. (2007) Maximum likelihood estimation of stochastic volatil-

ity models, Journal of Financial Economics, 83, 413�452.

Bakshi, G., Cao, C., Chen, Z. (1997) Empirical performance of alternative option pric-

ing models, Journal of Finance, 52, 2003�2049.

Bakshi, G., Kapadia, N. (2003) Delta-hedged gains and the negative market volatility

risk premium, Review of Financial Studies, 16, 527�566.

Bakshi, G., Madan, D. (2006) A Theory of volatility spread, Management Science, 52,

1945�1956.

Bates, D. (2000) Post-�87 crash fears in the S&P 500 futures option market, Journal of

Econometrics, 94, 181�238.

Bates, D. (2003) Empirical option pricing: A retrospection, Journal of Econometrics,

116, 387�404.

Black, F., Scholes, M. (1973) Valuation of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of

Political Economy, 81, 637�654.

Bollen, N.P., Whaley, R.E. (2004) Does net buying pressure a¤ect the shape of implied

volatility functions?, Journal of Finance, 59, 711�53.

Bollerslev, T., Tauchen, G., Zhou, H. (2009) Expected stock returns and variance risk

premia, Review of Financial Studies, 22, 4463�4492.

Britten-Jones, M., Neuberger, A. (2000) Option prices, implied price processes, and

stochastic volatility, Journal of Finance 55, 839�866.

Buraschi, A., Jackwerth, J. (2001) The price of smile: Hedging and spanning in option

markets, Review of Financial Studies, 14, 495�527.

Buraschi, A., Trojani, F., Vedolin, A. (2014) When uncertainty blows in the orchard:

Comovement and equilibrium volatility risk premia, Journal of Finance, Forthcoming.

Page 118: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

108

Carr, P., Wu, L. (2007) Stochastic skew in currency options, Journal of Financial

Economics, 86, 213�247.

Carr, P., Wu, L. (2009) Variance risk premiums, Review of Financial Studies, 22, 1311�

1341.

Chen, H., Joslin, S., Ni, S. (2013) Demand for crash insurance and stock returns,

Working Paper, MIT.

Christo¤ersen, P., Goyenko, R., Jacobs, K., Karoui, M. (2014) Illiquidity premia in the

equity options market, Working Paper, University of Toronto.

Christo¤ersen, P., Heston, S., Jacobs, K. (2009) The Shape and term structure of the

index option smirk: Why multifactor stochastic volatility models work so well, Management

Science, 55, 1914�1932.

Christo¤ersen, P., Jacobs, K., Mimouni, K. (2010) Volatility dynamics for the S&P

500: evidence from realized volatility, daily returns, and option prices, Review of Financial

Studies, 23, 3141�3189.

Corsi, F. (2009) A simple approximate long-memory model of realized volatility, Journal

of Financial Econometrics, 7, 174�196.

Cox, J.C., Huang, C.F. (1989) Optimal consumption and portfolio plicies when asset

prices follow a di¤usion process, Journal of Economic Theory, 49, 33�83.

Cremers, M., Halling, M., Weibaum, D. (2014) Aggregate jump and volatility risk in

the cross-section of stock returns, Journal of Finance, Forthcoming.

Detemple, J. B., Rindisbacher, M. (2010) Dynamic asset allocation: portfolio decom-

position formula and applications, Review of Financial Studies, 23, 25�100.

Detemple, J., Garcia, R., Rindisbacher, M. (2003) A Monte carlo method for optimal

portfolios, Journal of Finance, 58, 401�446.

Detemple, J., Garcia, R., Rindisbacher, M. (2005) Intertemporal asset allocation: a

comparison of methods, Journal of Banking and Finance, 29, 2821�2848.

Di Nunno, G., Øksendal, B., Proske, F. (2009) Malliavin calculus for Lévy processes

with applications to �nance, Springer-Verlag.

Page 119: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

109

Driessen, J., Maenhout, P., Vilkov, G. (2009) The price of correlation risk: Evidence

from equity options, Journal of Finance, 64, 1377�1406.

Eglo¤, D., Leippold, M., and Wu, L. (2010) The term structure of variance swap rates

and optimal variance swap investments, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,

45, 1279�1310.

Elkamhi, R., Stefanova, D. (2011) Dynamic correlation or tail dependence hedging for

portfolio selection, Working Paper, University of Toronto.

Gârleanu, N., Pedersen, L.H., Poteshman, A. (2009) Demand-based option pricing,

Review of Financial Studies, 22, 4259�4299.

Heston, S. (1993) Closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility, with ap-

plication to bond and currency options, Review of Financial Studies, 6, 327�343.

Johannes, M., Polson, N., Stroud, J. (2009) Optimal �ltering of jump-di¤usions: Ex-

tracting latent states from asset prices, Review of Financial Studies, 22, 2759�2799.

Jones, C.S. (2003) The dynamics of stochastic volatility: evidence from underlying and

options markets, Journal of Econometrics, 116, 181�224.

Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J.P., Shreve, S. (1987) Optimal portfolio and consumption

decisions for a small investor on a �nite time-horizon, Journal on Control and Optimization,

25, 1557�1586.

Leippold, M., Su, L. (2011) Collateral smile, Working Paper, Swiss Finance Institute.

Malik, S., Pitt, M. (2011) Particle �lters for continuous likelihood evaluation and max-

imisation, Journal of Econometrics, 165, 190�209.

Muravyev, D. (2013) Order �ow and expected option returns, Working Paper, Boston

College.

Pan, J. (2002) The jump risk premia implicit in options: Evidence from an integrated

time series study, Journal of Financial Economics, 63, 3�50.

Pitt, M. (2002) Smooth particle �lters for likelihood evaluation and maximization,

Manuscript, University of Warwick.

Todorov, V. (2010) Variance risk premia dynamics: The role of jumps, Review of

Page 120: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

110

Financial Studies, 23, 345�383.

Trolle, A., Schwartz, E. (2009) Unspanned stochastic volatility and the pricing of com-

modity derivatives, Review of Financial Studies, 22, 4423�4461.

Stoikov, S., Saglam, M. (2009) Option market making under inventory risk, Working

Paper, Cornell University.

Vilkov, G. (2008) Variance risk premium demysti�ed, Working Paper, INSEAD.

Zhang, L., Mykland, P., Aït-Sahalia, Y. (2005) A Tale of two time scales: Determining

integrated volatility with noisy high-frequency data, Journal of the American Statistical

Association, 100, 1394�1411..

Page 121: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

111

Figure 1: S&P 500 Index, Variance Risk Premium, and Delta-Hedged Gains and Losses

of Near-the-Money Options

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012600

850

1100

1350

1600S&P 500 Index

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012­34

­17

0

17

34One­Month Variance Risk Premium

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012­175

0

175

350

525Weekly Delta­Hedged Gains and Losses of Near­the­Money Options

Notes to Figure: The top panel plots the time-series of the S&P 500 index. The middle

panel plots the one-month variance risk premium expressed in percentage and measured by

the di¤erence between the one-month ex-post realized variance and one-month expected

risk-neutral variance. In the bottom panel, we graph the weekly average of daily delta-

hedged gains and losses of all options with moneyness (S=K) between 0:98 and 1:02.

Page 122: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

112

Figure 2: CBOE VIX Index and

Market-Makers�Inventory Risk

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 20125

25

45

65

85CBOE VIX Index

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012­7500

­5000

­2500

0

2500Inventory Risk ($ Millions)

Notes to Figure: The top panel plots the CBOE VIX Index which represents the implied

volatility of an at-the-money option with exactly 30 days to maturity expressed in percent-

age. The bottom panel plots CBOE market-makers�inventory risk dynamic measured as

the vega-weighted sum of inventories across all contracts expressed in $ Millions.

Page 123: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

113

Figure 3: Market-Makers�Daily and Cumulative Pro�ts and Losses, and

Market-Makers�Bid-Ask Spread Revenue

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012­398

­199

0

199

398Profits & Losses of Delta­Hedged Inventory ($ Millions)

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012­500

0

500

1000

1500Cumulative Profits & Losses of Delta­Hedged Inventory ($ Millions)

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 20120

75

150

225

300Bid­Ask Spread Revenue ($ Millions)

Notes to Figure: The top panel plots the daily pro�ts and losses of market-makers�delta-

hedged inventory expressed in $ Millions. The middle panel graphs the cumulative daily

pro�ts and losses over the sample period of market-makers�delta-hedged inventory in $

Millions. In the bottom panel, we plot the SPX market-makers�bid-ask spread revenue

expressed in $ Millions.

Page 124: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

114

Figure 4: Filtered Spot Volatilities Using Daily S&P 500 Returns

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 20125

25

45

65

85CEV Spot Volatility

1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 20125

25

45

65

85Heston (1993) Spot Volatility

Notes to Figure: The �gure plots the daily spot volatilities �ltered from S&P 500 daily

returns using particle �ltering. In the top panel, we plot the spot volatilities estimated for

the CEV dynamic. In the bottom panel, we graph the �ltered spot volatilities obtained

for Heston (1993). For both panels, the daily volatilities are annualized and expressed in

percentage.

Page 125: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

115

Figure 5: One-Month Variance Risk Premium, IVRMSE, and

Implied Volatility Smile by Model

2000 2004 2008 2012­34

­17

0

17

34

VR

P

Panel A: VRP Inv. Risk Model

2000 2004 2008 20120

6

12

18

24

IVR

MSE

Panel C: IVRMSE Inv. Risk Model

0.90 0.95 1 1.05 1.1017

21

24

27

30

Impl

ied 

Vol

.

Moneyness (S/K)

Panel E: Market and Inv. Risk Model IV

Model IVMarket IV

2000 2004 2008 2012­34

­17

0

17

34Panel B: VRP Heston Model

2000 2004 2008 20120

6

12

18

24Panel D: IVRMSE Heston Model

0.90 0.95 1 1.05 1.1017

21

24

27

30

Moneyness (S/K)

Panel F: Market and Heston Model IV

Notes to Figure: For each model, we plot the daily one-month variance risk premium (VRP)

and IVRMSE expressed in percentage terms in Panel A to D. To obtain the models�one-

month VRP on each day, we simulate 10,000 paths, calculate the 30 days integrated VRP

for each path, and take the average. For the inventory risk model, the VRP is calculated

using estimated parameters and latent variables. For the Heston model, the instantaneous

VRP is set to h � Vt where h = �1:08. In Panel E and F, we graph market-implied (solid)

and model-implied (dashed) volatility smile.

Page 126: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

116

Figure 6: The Dollar Response of Index Options to Inventory Risk

and Market-Maker�s Wealth

0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.20

15

30

45

60 D

olla

r R

espo

nse

 Response to Inventory Risk Decrease

50th Quantile Decrease10th Quantile Decrease

0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.20

50

100

150

200

 Moneyness (S/K)

 Dol

lar 

Res

pons

e

 Response to Wealth Decrease

Notes to Figure: We plot the dollar response of SPX puts with 90 days to maturity to a

decrease in inventory risk (top panel), and to a decrease in market-maker wealth (bottom

panel). To calculate the model sensitivies @P@InvRisk and

@P@W , we use the estimated parame-

ters �V , �Inv, and w, and set r = 4%, St = 1183 , and Vt = �: Moreover, inventory risk

and market-maker wealth are set to InvRiskt = �9:03E+09 and Wt = w. Based on these

sensitivities, we then calculate the dollar response of each option as �InvRiskt � @P@InvRisk

and �Wt � @P@W , and plot the result across moneyness. In both panels, each line corresponds

to di¤erent level of decrease in inventory risk and wealth. The circles correspond to the

dollar response to an average decrease in the state variables. The diamonds identify the

response when the decrease of each latent variable is within its 90th percentile decrease.

Page 127: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

117

Page 128: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

118

Page 129: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

119

Page 130: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

120

Page 131: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

121

Page 132: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

122

Page 133: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

123

Page 134: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

124

Page 135: Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing · 2015. 6. 17. · Essays in Volatility Modeling and Option Pricing Mathieu Fournier Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of

125