2.4. factor markets

93
DEMAND AND SUPPLY IN FACTOR MARKETS

Upload: api-3696178

Post on 10-Apr-2015

523 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: 2.4. Factor Markets

DEMAND AND SUPPLY IN FACTOR

MARKETS

Page 2: 2.4. Factor Markets

Objectives

After studying this chapter, you will able to Explain how firms choose the quantities of labor, capital,

and natural resources to employ

Explain how people choose the quantities of labor, capital, and natural resources to supply

Explain how wages, interest, and natural resource prices are determined in competitive resource markets

Explain the concept of economic rent and distinguish between economic rent and opportunity cost

Page 3: 2.4. Factor Markets

Many Happy Returns

Some people make very happy returns, like Katie Couric’s $16 million a year.

Why aren’t all jobs well paid?

What determines wage rates?

What determines the returns to other factors of production?

Page 4: 2.4. Factor Markets

Prices and Incomes in Competitive Factor Markets

Factors of production are the resources used to produce goods and services.

The factors of production are

Labor

Capital

Land

Entrepreneurship

Page 5: 2.4. Factor Markets

Prices and Incomes in Competitive Factor Markets

Factor prices determine incomes:

Labor earns wages.

Capital earns interest.

Land earns rent.

Entrepreneurship earns normal profit.

Economic profit (loss) is paid to (borne by) the owner of the firm.

Page 6: 2.4. Factor Markets

Prices and Incomes in Competitive Factor Markets

Factors of production are traded in markets where their prices and quantities are determined by the market forces of demand and supply.

This chapter focuses on competitive factor markets.

The laws of demand and supply apply to a competitive factor market: the demand curve slopes downward and the supply curve slopes upward.

Page 7: 2.4. Factor Markets

Prices and Incomes in Competitive Factor Markets

The income earned by the owner of a factor of production equals the equilibrium price multiplied by the equilibrium quantity.

Figure 14.1 shows a factor market at its equilibrium price and quantity.

Page 8: 2.4. Factor Markets

Prices and Incomes in Competitive Factor Markets

An increase in the demand for a factor of production raises its equilibrium price, increases its equilibrium quantity, and increases its income.

An increase in the supply of a factor of production lowers its equilibrium price, increases its equilibrium quantity, and has an ambiguous effect on its income.

The effect of an increase in the supply of a factor of production on its income depends on the elasticity of demand.

Page 9: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Labor markets allocate labor and the price of labor is the wage rate.

In the United States, the real wage rate (the wage rate adjusted for inflation) has risen by 100 percent and the total quantity of labor hours has increased by over 100 percent.

Page 10: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Figure 14.2(a) shows these trends in wages and quantity of labor supplied over the last four decades.

Page 11: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Figure 14.2(b) shows the shifts in the demand and supply curves for labor.

Both labor supply and labor demand have increased since 1961.

The increase in labor demand exceeded the increase in labor supply, so the wage rate increased.

Page 12: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

The Demand for Labor

A firm’s demand for labor is a derived demand—a demand for a factor of production that is derived from the demand for the goods or services produced by the factor.

The firm compares the marginal revenue from hiring one more worker with the marginal cost of hiring that worker.

Page 13: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Marginal Revenue Product

The marginal revenue product of labor (MRP) is the change in total revenue that results from employing one more unit of labor.

The marginal revenue product of labor equals the marginal product of labor multiplied by marginal revenue.

MRP = MP MR

Page 14: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

For a perfectly competitive firm, marginal revenue equals price.

So the marginal revenue product of labor equals the marginal product of labor multiplied by the price of the product

MRP = MP P

Marginal revenue product diminishes as the quantity of labor employed increases because the marginal product of labor diminishes.

Page 15: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

For a firm in monopoly (or monopolistic competition or oligopoly) marginal revenue is less than price and marginal revenue decreases as the quantity sold increases.

So for a firm in a non-competitive market, MRP diminishes as the quantity of labor employed increases for two reasons:

the diminishing marginal product of labor

decreasing marginal revenue

Page 16: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

The Labor Demand Curve

The marginal revenue product curve for labor is the demand curve for labor.

If marginal revenue product exceeds the wage rate, the firm increases profits by hiring more labor.

Page 17: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

If marginal revenue product is less than the wage rate, the firm increases profits by hiring less labor.

If marginal revenue product equals the wage rate, the firm is employing the profit-maximizing quantity of labor.

Because the marginal revenue product of labor decreases as the quantity of labor employed increases, if the wage rate falls, the quantity of labor demanded increases.

Page 18: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Figure 14.3 shows the relationship between a firm’s marginal revenue product curve and demand for labor curve.

The bars show marginal revenue product, which diminishes as the quantity of labor employed increases.

Page 19: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

The marginal revenue product curve passes through the mid points of the bars.

The MRP of the 3rd worker is $12 an hour, so at a wage rate of $12 an hour, the firm hires 3 workers on its demand for labor curve.

Page 20: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Equivalence of Two Conditions for Profit Maximization

The firm has two equivalent conditions for maximizing profit. They are:

Hire the quantity of labor at which the marginal revenue product of labor (MRP) equals the wage rate (W).

Produce the quantity of output at which marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC).

Page 21: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Begin with the first condition: MRP = W.

This condition can be rewritten as: MR MP = W.

Divide both sides by MP to obtain MR = W/MP.

But W/MP = MC.

Replace W/MP with MC to obtain the second condition for maximum profit, MR = MC.

Page 22: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Changes in the Demand for Labor

The demand for labor changes and the demand for labor curve shifts if:

The price of the firm’s output changes

The prices of other factors of production change

Technology changes

Page 23: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Market Demand

The market demand for labor is obtained by summing the quantities of labor demanded by all firms at each wage rate.

Because each firm’s demand for labor curve slopes downward, so does the market demand curve.

Page 24: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Elasticity of Demand for Labor

The elasticity of demand for labor measures the responsiveness of the quantity of labor demanded in the market to a change in the wage rate.

The elasticity of demand for labor depends on:

The labor intensity of the production process

The elasticity of demand for the product

The substitutability of capital for labor

Page 25: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

The Supply of Labor

People allocate their time between leisure and labor and this choice, which determines the quantity of labor supplied, depends on the wage rate.

A person’s reservation wage is the lowest wage rate for which he or she is willing to supply labor.

As the wage rate rises above the reservation wage, the household changes the quantity of labor supplied.

Page 26: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Substitution effect

The opportunity cost of leisure increases with the wage.

The substitution effect describes how a person responds by increasing the quantity of labor supplied as the wage rate rises.

Page 27: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Income effect

An increase in income enables the consumer to buy more of all goods.

Leisure is a normal good, and the income effect describes how a person responds by increasing the quantity of leisure and decreasing the quantity of labor supplied.

Page 28: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Backward-bending supply of labor curve

At low wage rates the substitution effect dominates the income effect, so a rise in the wage rate increases the quantity of labor supplied.

At high wage rates the income effect dominates the substitution effect, so a rise in the wage rate decreases the quantity of labor supplied.

Page 29: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

The labor supply curve slopes upward at low wage rates but eventually bends backward at high wage rates.

Market supply

The market supply curve is obtained by summing each individual’s supply curve of labor.

Page 30: 2.4. Factor Markets

Figure 14.4 shows the backward-bending supply curve for individuals, and the eventually backward-bending market supply curve.

Labor Markets

Page 31: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Changes in the supply of labor

The supply of labor changes and the supply curve shifts if

The adult population changes

Technology and capital in the home change

Page 32: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

Labor Market Equilibrium

Wages and employment are determined by equilibrium in the labor market.

The demand for labor has increased because of technological change.

Technological change destroys some jobs but creates others.

Page 33: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

On the average, technological change creates more jobs than it destroys and the jobs that it creates pay higher wage rates than did the jobs that it destroys.

The supply of labor has increased because of an increase in population and technological change and capital accumulation in the home.

Page 34: 2.4. Factor Markets

Labor Markets

The demand for labor has increased by more than the supply of labor, so the equilibrium wage rate has increased and the quantity of labor employed has also increased.

But the high-skilled computer-literate workers have benefited from the information revolution while some low-skill workers have lost out.

Page 35: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

Capital markets are the channels through which firms obtain financial resources to buy physical factors of production that economists call capital.

The available financial resources come from savings.

The real interest rate is the return on capital and is the “price” determined in the capital market.

Page 36: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

Figure 14.5(b) shows the changes in the demand for and supply of capital that have changed the equilibrium quantity and real interest rate over the last four decades.

Page 37: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

The Demand for Capital

A firm’s demand for financial capital stems from its demand for physical capital.

The firm employs the quantity of physical capital that makes the marginal revenue product of capital equal to the price of the capital.

The returns to capital come in the future, but capital must be paid for in the present.

So the firm must convert the future marginal revenue product of capital to a present value.

Page 38: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

Discounting and Present Value

Discounting is converting a future amount of money into a present value.

The present value of a future amount of money is the amount that, if invested today, will grow to be as large as that future amount when the interest that it will earn is taken into account.

The easiest way to understand discounting is to begin with the relationship between an amount invested today, the interest that it earns, and the amount it grows to in the future.

Page 39: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

If the interest rate for one period is r, then the amount of money a person has one year in the future is:

Future amount = Present value + (r Present value) Future amount = Present value (1 + r)

So the present value of the future amount is:

Present value = Future amount/(1 + r)

Page 40: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

Similarly, the amount of money that a person has n years in the future is:

Amount n years in future = Present value (1 + r)n

So the present value is:

Present value = Amount n years in future/(1 + r)n

Because the return a firm earns from investing in capital accrues over a number of future years, the firm must calculate the present value of each year’s returns and then sum them.

Page 41: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

The net present value of an investment subtracts the cost of the capital good from the present value of its marginal revenue product.

If the net present value is positive, buying the capital is profitable for the firm, and the firm buys the capital.

Page 42: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

A rise in the interest rate lowers the net present value of the marginal revenue product of capital, which in turn lowers the net present value of the capital.

As the interest rate rises, fewer projects have positive net present value, other things remaining the same, and the quantity of capital demanded decreases.

Page 43: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

The Demand Curve for Capital

The quantity of capital demanded by a firm depends on the marginal revenue product of capital and the interest rate.

The demand curve for capital shows the relationship between the quantity of capital demanded by the firm and the interest rate, other things remaining the same.

Page 44: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

Two main factors that change the MRP of capital and the demand for capital are:

Population growth

Technological change

Page 45: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

The Supply of Capital

The quantity of capital supplied results from people’s savings decisions.

The main factors that determine savings are:

Income

Expected future income

The interest rate

Page 46: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

Supply Curve of Capital

The supply curve of capital shows the relationship between the interest rate and the quantity of capital supplied, other things remaining the same.

A rise in the interest rate brings an increase in the quantity of capital supplied and a movement along the saving supply curve.

Page 47: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

The main influences on the supply of capital are:

The size and age distribution of the population

The level of income

Page 48: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

The Interest Rate

The savings plans of households and the investment plans of firms are coordinated through the capital markets.

Adjustments in the real rate of interest make these plans compatible.

Page 49: 2.4. Factor Markets

Capital Markets

Figure 14.6 shows capital market equilibrium and changes in equilibrium.

Population growth and technological advances have increased the demand for capital.

Population growth and income growth have increased the supply of capital.

Page 50: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

Natural resources, or what economists call land, falls into two categories:

Renewable natural resources are resources that can be used repeatedly, such as land (in its everyday sense), rivers, lakes, rain, and sunshine.

Nonrenewable natural resources are natural resources that can be used only once and that cannot be replaced once they have been used, such as coal, oil, and natural gas.

Page 51: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

The Supply of Renewable Resources

The demand for natural resources as inputs into production is based on the same principle of marginal revenue product as the demand for capital.

But the supply of natural resources is special.

Page 52: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

The quantity of land (and other renewable natural resources) at any given time is fixed, which means the supply of land is perfectly inelastic.

Figure 14.7 illustrates this case.

Page 53: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

The quantity of land (and other renewable natural resources) at any given time is fixed, which means the supply of land is perfectly inelastic.

Figure 14.7 illustrates this case.

Page 54: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

The price (rent) for land and other renewable natural resources is determined solely by market demand.

The market supply curve for land is perfectly inelastic, but the supply curve facing any one firm in a competitive land market is perfectly elastic.

Each firm can rent as much land as it wants at the going market price.

Page 55: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

The Supply of a Nonrenewable Natural Resources

For a nonrenewable natural resource, there are three supply concepts:

The stock of a nonrenewable natural resource is the quantity in existence at any given time.

This quantity (like the quantity of land) is fixed and is independent of the price of the resource.

Page 56: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

The known stock of a nonrenewable natural resource is the quantity that has been discovered.

This quantity increases over time because advances in technology enable ever less accessible sources to be discovered.

The flow supply of a nonrenewable natural resource is the rate at which the resource is supplied for use in production during a given time period.

This supply is perfectly elastic at the price that equals the present value of the expected price of the resource next period.

Page 57: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

Figure 14.8 illustrates the flow supply of a nonrenewable natural resource.

The opportunity cost of selling a resource this year is the present value of the resource next year.

Page 58: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

If this year’s price exceeds the present value of next year’s price, owners sell this year.

If this year’s price is less than the present value of next year’s price, owners hold on to their stock this year and plan to sell next year.

Page 59: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

These actions make the flow supply perfectly elastic at the present value of next year’s expected price.

Page 60: 2.4. Factor Markets

Natural Resource Markets

Figure 14.9 shows how the average prices for the nine most used minerals in production have fallen over the last 30 years, rather than increased at a rate equal to the interest rate.

Page 61: 2.4. Factor Markets

Income, Economic Rent, and Opportunity Cost

Large and Small Incomes

Demand and supply in factor markets determine the equilibrium price and quantity of each factor of production and determine who receives a large income and who receives a small income.

Large incomes are earned by factors of production that have a high marginal revenue product and a small supply.

National news anchors are an example.

Page 62: 2.4. Factor Markets

Income, Economic Rent, and Opportunity Cost

Small incomes are earned by factors of production that have a low marginal revenue product and a large supply.

Fast-food workers are an example.

Page 63: 2.4. Factor Markets

Income, Economic Rent, and Opportunity Cost

Economic Rent and Opportunity Cost

The total income received by an owner of a factor of production is made up of its economic rent and its opportunity cost.

Economic rent is the income received by the owner of a factor of production over and above the amount required to induce that owner to offer the factor for use.

The opportunity cost of using a factor is the income required to induce its owner to offer the resource for use, which is the value of the factor in its next best use.

Page 64: 2.4. Factor Markets

Income, Economic Rent, and Opportunity Cost

Figure 14.10 illustrates the division of a factor income into economic rent and opportunity cost.

Page 65: 2.4. Factor Markets

Income, Economic Rent, and Opportunity Cost

The portion of income comprised of economic rent depends upon the elasticity of supply for the factor.

The less elastic is the supply for a factor, the greater is the share of income that is comprised by economic rent.

Page 66: 2.4. Factor Markets

Income, Economic Rent, and Opportunity Cost

When the supply is perfectly inelastic, then all of the income is economic rent.

The more elastic is the supply for a factor, the smaller is the share of income that is economic rent.

Page 67: 2.4. Factor Markets

Income, Economic Rent, and Opportunity Cost

When the supply is perfectly inelastic, then none of the income is economic rent.

Page 68: 2.4. Factor Markets

14

CHAPTER

THE END

DEMAND AND SUPPLY IN FACTOR

MARKETS

Page 69: 2.4. Factor Markets

DEMAND AND SUPPLY IN FACTOR

MARKETS: APPENDIX

14

CHAPTER

Page 70: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

Just as a monopoly firm can restrict output and raise price, so can a monopoly owner of a resource restrict supply and raise price.

The main source of market power in labor markets is a labor union, which is an organized group of workers that aims to increase wages and influence other job conditions.

Page 71: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

There are two types of unions:

A craft union is a group of workers who have a similar range of skills but work for many different industries and regions.

Examples include the carpenters’ union or electrical workers’ union.

An industrial union is a group of workers who have a variety of skills and job types but work for the same firm or industry.

Examples include the United Auto Workers and the Steelworkers Union.

Page 72: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

Union organization in the United States peaked in market strength in the 1950s when 35 percent of the non-agricultural workforce belonged to unions. Today that number has declined to 12 percent.

Page 73: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

There are three forms of union organization.

In an open shop, workers have the right to be employed by the firm without joining the union. There is no union restriction over who can work in the “shop,” or firm.

In a closed shop, workers must be union members in order to be employed by the company. The Taft–Hartley Act of 1947 made closed shop union arrangements illegal.

Page 74: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

In a union shop the firm may hire nonunion workers but the workers must join the union within a brief period of time after being hired. Twenty states have made union shops illegal by passing right-to-work laws, which give individuals the right to work for a firm without joining a union.

Unions and employers negotiate wages, benefits, and working conditions through a process called collective bargaining.

Page 75: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

The union and the employer use different methods to strengthen their respective positions in the bargaining process:

The union can call a strike where all union members are to refuse to work.

The employer can call a lockout where the firm refuses to operate its plant and allow its employees to work, depriving them of a paycheck.

Page 76: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

The employer and the union engage in binding arbitration to resolve a lengthy dispute--an independent third party enters the collective bargaining process to determine the wage rates to be paid and resolve any other issues being negotiated.

Page 77: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

Unions’ Objectives and Constraints

A union has three objectives:

Raise compensation

Improve working conditions

Expand job opportunities for its members

Page 78: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

Unions are constrained in their pursuit of these goals by:

The ability to restrict non-union labor from replacing union labor, which depends upon having a large fraction of the relevant labor force.

The ability to retain union jobs in the face of higher wages and benefits, which depends upon the elasticity of demand for the union labor.

Page 79: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

A Union in a Competitive Labor Market

Unions try to restrict the supply for union labor and raise the wage rate.

But this action also decreases the quantity of labor demanded.

Page 80: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

How Unions Try to Change the Demand for Labor

In order to retain the number of jobs offered by the firm, unions also try to increase the demand for union labor, as well as make the demand for labor less elastic (which decreases the reduction in quantity of labor demanded for any given wage increase).

Page 81: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

Increasing the marginal revenue product (MRP) of labor: Unions try to increase the marginal product of union labor, to make the firm’s demand for labor less elastic.

Encouraging import restrictions: Unions seek government assistance to reduce availability of substitute goods and services that are produced by non-union labor.

Supporting minimum wage laws: Unions seek to increase the cost of employing unskilled labor to replace higher- skilled union labor.

Unions try to increase the demand for union labor by:

Page 82: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

Supporting immigration restrictions: Unions seek to raise the wage rates of unskilled workers by restricting the supply of low-skilled, immigrant workers that can substitute for union labor.

Increasing the demand for the good or service produced by union labor: Unions realize that demand for labor is a derived demand based on the value of the goods and services that union labor produces. The unions attempt to influence consumer behavior by persuading them to buy only union-made goods and services.

Unions try to increase the demand for union labor by:

Page 83: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

Figure A14.1 shows the combined effect of restricting supply and increasing demand.

The wage rate might rise, and employment opportunities for union members might increase.

Page 84: 2.4. Factor Markets

Market Power in the Labor Market

The Scale of Union-Nonunion Wage Differentials

The average effect of union activity on wage rates in the United States has been a 30 percent increase in wages compared to non-union labor markets.

But not all unionized industries have achieved higher wages.

In mining and financial services, union wages are no different than non-union wages.

Union wages are 65 percent higher in the construction industry.

Page 85: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

A monopsony is a market with just one buyer.

Decades ago, large manufacturing plants, steel mills and coal mines were often the sole buyer of labor in their local labor markets.

Because a monopsonist firm controls the labor market, it has the market power to set the market wage rate.

In monopsony the firm’s marginal cost of labor (MCL) exceeds the average cost of labor (the wage rate) for all levels of labor employed.

Page 86: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

The wage rate increases with the quantity of labor supplied, which means the firm’s average cost curve is the supply curve for labor.

The MCL curve for the firm is upward sloping and higher than the supply curve for labor for all quantities of labor.

To maximize its profit, a monopsonist firm hires the quantity of labor where its MCL is equal to MRP.

At the profit-maximizing quantity of labor, marginal revenue product (MRP) exceeds minimum wage rate at which that quantity of labor is willingly supplied.

Page 87: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

A monopsonist hires less labor than it would if it were operating in a competitive labor market.

Figure A14.2 shows the impact of a monopsony firm on the wage rate and the quantity of labor hired.

Page 88: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

Monopsony Tendencies

Today monopsony is rare.

A large managed health-care organization might be the only employer of health-care workers in a local area.

But often, where a monopsony tendency is present, a union is also active.

Page 89: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

Monopsony and a Union

Sometimes both the firm and the employees have market power when a monopsony encounters a labor union, a situation called a bilateral monopoly.

Both the employer and the union must judge each other’s market power and come to an agreement on labor supplied and wages paid.

Depending on the relative costs that each party can inflict on the other, the outcome of this situation may favor either the union or the firm.

Page 90: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

Monopsony and the Minimum Wage

The imposition of a minimum wage may actually increase the level of labor hired by a monopsony.

Figure A14.3 shows why.

Page 91: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

The minimum wage makes the supply of labor perfectly elastic over some range of employment.

Along this part of the supply curve, the marginal cost of hiring an additional employee equals the minimum wage.

Page 92: 2.4. Factor Markets

Monopsony

The MCL curve is equal to the labor supply curve over this range of labor.

If this part of the supply curve of labor intersects the monopsony MRP curve, as a result of the minimum wage the monopsony increases the quantity of labor employed and pays a higher wage rate than if the minimum wage were not imposed.

Page 93: 2.4. Factor Markets

THE END